Dell 9322 Merits Final
Dell 9322 Merits Final
Dell 9322 Merits Final
)
IN RE: APPRAISAL OF DELL INC. ) C.A. No. 9322-VCL
)
MEMORANDUM OPINION
2013, the Company completed a merger that gave rise to appraisal rights (the ―Merger‖).
The petitioners sought appraisal. Based on the evidence presented at trial, the fair value
of the Company‘s common stock at the effective time of the Merger was $17.62 per
share.
I. FACTUAL BACKGROUND
Trial took place over four days. The parties introduced over 1,200 exhibits and
lodged seventeen depositions. Seven fact witnesses and five experts testified live. The
laudably thorough pre-trial order contained 542 paragraphs. The pre-trial and post-trial
A. An Evolving Company
In 1983, at the age of nineteen, Michael Dell started the Company in his freshman
dorm room at the University of Texas at Austin. Within two years, the Company
achieved annual sales of more than $40 million. On June 22, 1988, the Company went
public.
Over time, the Company expanded its operations to include sales of PCs, servers,
and storage devices to both consumers and businesses. Mr. Dell1 remained at the helm of
1
My usual practice is to identify individuals by their last names without
honorifics. In this case, the risk of confusion between Mr. Dell, the biological person, and
Dell, the corporate person, warrants an exception. The same risk does not exist for others,
who are identified without honorifics. No disrespect is intended.
1
After returning, Mr. Dell came to believe that the Company needed to evolve to
meet competitive threats. One threat came from the low-margin producers. The Company
sold primarily high-margin, premium-priced PCs. That market was shrinking as advances
Another threat was from new products. In 2007, Apple Inc. introduced the iPhone.
In 2010, Apple introduced the iPad. Consumers embraced smartphones and tablets. Both
A third threat affected the Company‘s server business. In 2007, Amazon.com, Inc.
introduced a cloud-based storage service. The Company sold servers to companies that
maintained their own technology infrastructure, and the cloud eliminated that need.
Mr. Dell believed that the Company needed to reduce its reliance on PC sales to
end users and increase its sales of software and services to enterprise customers. In 2009,
the Company started its transformation, which Mr. Dell planned to achieve through
acquisitions.
Between 2010 and 2012, the Company spent approximately $14 billion to acquire
eleven businesses. Mr. Dell believed that with these acquisitions, the Company‘s
transformation was complete, although it would take time to integrate the new businesses
and for them to perform in accordance with his expectations. Mr. Dell and his
management team were confident that the newly assembled enterprise division would
bear fruit, and they also believed that the Company would continue to grow its PC
2
2011, they valued the Company at $22.49 per share (by line of business) and $27.05 per
Management‘s internal valuations were significantly higher than the market price
of the Company‘s stock, which traded around $14 per share during the same period. Mr.
Dell lamented that the market just ―didn‘t get‖ the Company. Tr. 409 (Mr. Dell). He
thought that in spite of the Company‘s transformation, ―Dell [was] still seen as a PC
business.‖ JX 44 at 1.
Mr. Dell conferred with his management team and hired consultants to devise
strategies to help the market view the Company as ―a sum of the parts.‖ JX 46 at 1. Mr.
Dell regularly communicated his views to analysts. During a meeting with analysts on
June 12 and 13, 2012, management called for a strong performance from the enterprise
solutions and services division, projecting that it would account for 60% of the
sales and 22% growth in services revenue. At the same time, management projected that
growth annually, earnings and operating income from that division still would increase.
Earnings for the first quarter of FY 2013 were down 22% year over year and below
3
analysts‘ expectations. U.S. revenues declined for a fifth straight quarter. Revenues from
from Goldman Sachs opined that ―Dell‘s guidance is likely too aggressive on both the
questioned the cost-saving initiative, observing that ―historically . . . Dell‘s cost cutting
programs have been difficult to monitor, with no clear delineation between component
analyst from Indigo Equity Research remarked that the cost savings initiative ―sound[ed]
good,‖ but was ―unlikely to succeed well due to the execution hurdles.‖ JX 115 at 8.
The Company‘s market price suggested that the marginal purchaser shared the
analysts‘ skepticism. During the first half of 2012, the Company‘s stock declined from a
In June 2012, Staley Cates from Southeastern Asset Management asked Mr. Dell
Silver Lake approached Mr. Dell with the same idea. Mr. Dell decided to consider it. On
August 11 and again on August 13, Mr. Dell met with his friend George Roberts of
Kohlberg Kravis Roberts & Co. L.P. (―KKR‖) about whether an MBO made sense.
Roberts said he would look into it, and that if the numbers worked out, then KKR would
want to participate.
4
The numbers worked out. On Friday August 14, 2012, Mr. Dell called Alex
Mandl, the Company‘s lead independent director, and reported on his conversations with
Southeastern, Silver Lake, and KKR. He told Mandl that he wanted to pursue an MBO.
The Company‘s board of directors (the ―Board‖) met the following Monday. Mr.
Dell told the directors that he ―did not want to proceed further without approval of the
Board, and that he would not engage a financial advisor without first informing the
Board.‖ JX 106 at 1. After Mr. Dell left the meeting, the Board discussed establishing a
special committee.
After the meeting, Mandl told Mr. Dell that the Board would consider an MBO.
Mr. Dell passed on the news to Silver Lake and KKR. He did not contact Southeastern.
On August 20, 2012, the Board met by telephone. Mr. Dell did not attend. During
the meeting, the Board formed a special committee (the ―Committee‖) and granted to it
the full and exclusive power and authority of the Board to the fullest extent
permitted by law . . . to take any action in connection with [any potential
transaction involving Mr. Dell or any other strategic alternative that may be
considered by the Board] which the Committee determines in its sole
discretion to be advisable.
JX 107 at 3-4. The resolutions provided that the Board would not recommend any
The members of the Committee were Mandl, Laura Conigliaro, Janet F. Clark, and
Mandl was a successful businessman with experience on other Fortune 100 boards.
Conigliaro was a partner at Goldman Sachs who had covered the tech industry as a senior
5
analyst. Clark was a former CFO of Marathon Oil Corporation with extensive board
experience. Duberstein had been the lead independent director at Boeing, served on other
major boards, and was the White House Chief of Staff to President Ronald Reagan. None
of the members of the Committee had any financial or business ties to Mr. Dell other than
The Board authorized the Committee to hire its own advisors. The Committee
retained Debevoise & Plimpton LLP as its legal counsel and hired JPMorgan Chase &
On August 30, 2012, the Board adopted resolutions that expanded the scope of the
Committee‘s authority. Under the new resolutions, the Committee enjoyed the
full and exclusive power and authority of the Board to the fullest extent
permitted by law to
(1) review and to evaluate the terms and conditions, and determine the
advisability, of a Proposed Transaction and any alternatives thereto that the
Special Committee deems appropriate,
(2) establish, approve, modify, monitor and direct the process and
procedures related to the review and evaluation of a Proposed Transaction
and any alternatives thereto, including, but not limited to, the authority to
determine not to proceed with any such process, procedures, review or
evaluation, or to recommend any of the foregoing to the Board,
(4) negotiate with Mr. Dell or any other party that the [Committee] deems
appropriate with respect to the terms and conditions of a Proposed
Transaction or any alternative thereto and, if the [Committee] deems
appropriate, but subject to the limitations of applicable law, approve the
execution and delivery of documents in connection with a Proposed
Transaction or any alternative transaction on behalf of the Corporation,
6
(5) determine whether a Proposed Transaction or any alternative thereto
negotiated by the [Committee] is fair to, and in the best interests of, the
Corporation and its stockholders,
(6) with respect to any actions required to be taken by the full Board with
respect to a Proposed Transaction or any alternative thereto, recommend to
the full Board what action, if any, should be taken by the Board,
(8) take any other action which the [Committee] determines in its sole
discretion to be advisable . . . .
The day after the Board formed the Committee, the Company held its earnings call
for the second quarter of FY 2013. Compared to the prior year, revenue declined by 8%,
and earnings per share fell by 13%. The earnings result was consistent with analyst
forecasts, but revenue was below expectations. Management forecasted further short-term
declines, including a 20% downward revision for earnings per share in FY 2013, but
stressed that the Company was following ―a long-term strategy [that] will take time.‖ JX
109 at 7. Mr. Dell explained, ―We‘re transforming our business, not for a quarter or a
fiscal year, but to deliver differentiated customer value for the long term.‖ JX 110 at 1.
After the call, many analysts decreased their price targets. An analyst from Indigo
Equity Research described the Company as a ―sinking ship‖ and stated that ―Dell‘s
turnaround strategy is fundamentally flawed [and] the fundamentals are bad. Dell may
have responded too late to save itself.‖ JX 115 at 1. An analyst from Sterne Agee said
7
that the ―bottom line is that the transformation beyond PCs is tougher and taking much
During the first week of September 2012, the Committee entered into
confidentiality agreements with Silver Lake, KKR, and Mr. Dell. The Committee did not
contact Southeastern.
prevented them, for a period of eighteen months, from doing any of the following,
directly or indirectly:
working with any person or entity with respect to a possible transaction other than
Silver Lake or KKR, unless approved in advance in writing by the Company;
talking to any sources of debt financing without the prior approval of the
Company, and
8
taking any action that would prevent him from working with any potential
counterparty or financing source in connection with a transaction or alternative
transaction.
JX 125 at 2. The agreement provided affirmatively that ―You [Mr. Dell] agree to explore
in good faith the possibility of working with any such potential counterparty or financing
whether to work with any counterparty or financing source after such good faith
On September 13, 2012, management provided the Committee with their best
estimate for the Company‘s future performance. Mr. Dell told the Board to ―[e]xpect
[the] short term to be very challenging‖ and that achieving the full benefits of the
The Company‘s CFO, Brian Gladden, reviewed financial projections that management
The July Case supported valuations for the Company that were significantly
higher than the Company‘s stock price. As part of the July presentation, management had
used the July Case to estimate the Company‘s value as a stand-alone entity. Management
9
– ~$16B driven by higher revenue
JX 97 at 16. Put differently, management thought the Company was worth approximately
$25 billion more than its then-current market capitalization of approximately $15 billion.
Management noted that projecting the Company‘s past twelve months of free cash flow
into perpetuity would produce a share price of greater than $30, meaning the market price
implied that the Company would experience declines in free cash flow of 20% per year
into perpetuity.
The Committee members regarded the July Case as ―very optimistic‖ and even
―unrealistic.‖ Tr. 147 (Mandl). During the September meeting, the Committee told
Gladden to modify the July Case further to take into account a report on the PC industry
issued by analysts at the International Data Corporation (―IDC‖). The IDC report
contained a relatively pessimistic forecast for PC sales over the next five years.
Company‘s prospects.2
about the transaction process. JPMorgan noted that the Company‘s ―[s]tock price has
declined ~25% over the last year while the NASDAQ is up ~25%,‖ and that ―[m]issed
Street expectations have put investors in a ‗wait and see mode‘ with increased focus on
2
See, e.g., JX 155 at 1-3 (UBS Investment Research report noting that 55% of
analysts had a hold or sell rating on Dell, that the ―[t]echnicals [are] ugly,‖ and that
investors‘ concerns included ―(1) over half of operating profits still come from the
deteriorating PC business, and (2) skepticism that Dell can become a successful
enterprise player‖).
10
quarter-by-quarter execution and improved visibility.‖ JX 137 at 7. JPMorgan next
conveyed its views about the feasibility of an MBO in light of ―the basic math by which
financial sponsors determine what they are willing to pay in an acquisition transaction,‖
Mr. Dell‘s ownership of 15.4% of the Company‘s outstanding shares, and the Company‘s
ability to keep in place after a transaction approximately $5.9 billion of existing debt. JX
136 at 2. The Company‘s ability to keep approximately 65% of its debt in place
―materially reduc[ed] the debt commitments and inherent cost of capital‖ for a leveraged
structure:
―Sponsors seek to generate returns on their equity investment and use financial
leverage to increase potential returns‖;
―Multiple of cash invested (e.g. 2.0x) is also a key parameter, particularly for
larger transactions‖;
―IRR will be used as the primary means to determine the appropriate purchase
price by a sponsor . . . .‖
JX 137 at 21.
JPMorgan also reviewed with the Committee the likelihood of interest from other
financial sponsors or strategic bidders. The JPMorgan representatives ―noted their belief
11
that KKR and Silver Lake were among the best qualified potential acquirers.‖ JX 136 at
3. They also stated that ―there was a low probability of strategic buyer interest in
acquiring the Company.‖ Id. They nevertheless warned that limiting negotiations to KKR
Committee could then decide how to proceed, including by terminating the process or
inviting other potential buyers to participate in the process.‖ JX 136 at 3. After receiving
JPMorgan‘s advice, the Committee decided to ―refrain from contacting other sponsor
groups until an offer was received [from Mr. Dell and either KKR or Silver Lake] or
On September 17, 2012, and again on September 21, the Committee reconvened to
review management‘s forecasts. Gladden presented revised projections that adjusted for
the Company‘s performance to date, assumed lower customer demand, and reduced
margins (the ―September Case‖). The Committee viewed the September Case as ―more
realistic‖ than the July Case but still ―overly optimistic.‖ Tr. 147 (Mandl). The
Committee nevertheless authorized the September Case to be included in the online data
room for use by Silver Lake and KKR in evaluating the Company.
Company‘s share price had closed the previous day at $9.66. JPMorgan derived the
12
DCF using the September Case: $20.00 to $27.00 per share.
JX 162 at 15.
pay based on an industry-standard LBO pricing model. Using the September Case and
assuming that the buyer financed the transaction with 3.1x leverage, JPMorgan projected
recapitalizations at the Company. At higher prices, the sponsor could not achieve a
minimum five-year IRR of 20%. Assuming a financial sponsor wanted to achieve a range
of IRRs of 20% to 25%, JPMorgan placed the likely valuation range at $11.75 to $13.00,
The next day, October 10, 2012, the Committee received a presentation from
Goldman Sachs, which was ―assisting the Company‘s management in preparing for the
management presentations that had been made to financial sponsors.‖ JX 166 at 1. Like
13
September Case. Depending on the assumptions used, Goldman projected that a sponsor
could pay approximately $16.00 per share and still generate a five-year IRR of 20%.
On October 18, 2012, the Committee met again and received presentations from
both JPMorgan and Goldman. Goldman provided possible reasons why the Company‘s
stock price was disconnected from indications of the Company‘s fundamental value:
―Another reason for [the Company‘s] current valuation could be because investors
are not attributing full value to its significant cash balances‖;
– Investors are often reluctant to fight strong ‗secular headwinds‘ even when
values become attractive in absolute and relative terms; as a result,
valuations can remain depressed for protracted periods.‖
[Company] value outcomes that are significantly higher than the current share price.‖ Id.
at 4.
14
F. Silver Lake And KKR Provide Expressions Of Interest.
On October 23, 2012, Silver Lake and KKR provided the Committee with
$11.22 and $12.16 a share, excluding shares held by Mr. Dell. KKR proposed an all-cash
transaction valued at between $12.00 and $13.00 a share, excluding shares held by Mr.
Dell and Southeastern, and based its illustrative analysis on a price of $12.50 per share.
KKR‘s proposal also contemplated an additional $500 million investment by Mr. Dell.
JPMorgan. The 20-30% one-day premium from Silver Lake and the 28-39% one-day
premium from KKR were in line with the premiums offered in other large LBOs within
the last five years, but that was their only virtue. The ranges were far below all of
JPMorgan‘s DCF analyses except the Street low case. They were at the low end of the
valuations implied by JPMorgan‘s analysis of trading metrics. They even were below the
prices suggested by JPMorgan and Goldman‘s LBO models, implying IRRs for the
Mr. Dell had not been involved in determining the prices. He was content to
request, Mr. Dell sent identical emails to Silver Lake and KKR in which he encouraged
and the sponsors and asked them a series of questions including ―what factors could lead
15
G. The Company’s Performance For The Third Quarter Of 2012
During November 2012, market observers became more critical of the Company.
On November 9, 2012, Citi Research Equities issued a report that set a price target of
$8.50, described the outlook as ―muted,‖ and noted that ―[i]n addition to our negative
views on PCs, we believe [bring your own device] trends in the corporate PC segment
will materially pressure Dell‘s sales, margins and EPS in the future.‖ JX 1225 at 9. Mandl
forwarded the report to the Committee, remarking that it provided ―a very different
need for us to consider a very conservative forecast, possibly even one that we once may
have viewed as being close to ‗worst case‘ in order for us to get ahead of the downward
changes that we have been watching.‖ Id. Separately, Gladden agreed that ―[m]arket data
has deteriorated‖ and that ―many [peer] companies have announced weaker results and
optimistic given valuation & sell-side estimates of Dell future value.‖ Id. at 2. The
Committee decided to get external help from Boston Consulting Group, Inc. (―BCG‖).
They tasked BCG with creating an independent set of forecasts for the Company.
On November 15, 2012, the Company reported its financial results for the third
quarter. Revenue and earnings per share came in below the Company‘s guidance and the
Street consensus. Compared to the previous year, revenue was down 11%, and earnings
per share were down 28%. At this point, the Company had come in below consensus
estimates for revenue in six of the last seven quarters and below consensus estimates for
16
Analysts cut their price targets, citing structural problems in the PC market and
questions about the Company‘s transformation. JPMorgan noted, however, that there was
also ―[s]ignificant buying by long-only and value-oriented investors in the two weeks
On December 3, 2012, KKR dropped out, saying that it could not ―get [its] arms
around the risks of the PC business.‖ JX 224 at 1. KKR‘s investment committee had
concluded that the Company‘s recent operating performance validated analysts‘ concerns.
The Committee was disappointed, because it now only had one sponsor in the
process and therefore no direct source of pre-signing competition for Silver Lake. Mr.
Dell reiterated to Mandl that he was willing ―to join up with whoever,‖ but he had not
spoken with Southeastern since June. JX 224 at 1. Mr. Dell also told Mandl that he had
the ability to supply as much equity capital as was needed to complete a transaction.
for $12.70 per share, up from its previous range of $11.22 to $12.16 per share. The
On December 5, 2012, the Committee received its first presentation from BCG.
Like the Committee‘s financial advisors, BCG observed that the Company‘s low
valuation did ―not match apparent company strengths,‖ but rather reflected ―investor
concerns.‖ JX 344 at 42. BCG described the investors‘ concerns as either a belief that the
Company‘s cash flows were ―likely to decline rapidly‖ or a sense that the Company was
17
using its cash flow in ―value-destroying ways.‖ Id. BCG thought that the more likely
After hearing from BCG, the Committee heard from JPMorgan. Its representatives
agreed that investors seemed focused on the Company‘s short-term results at the expense
of its long-term value, commenting that ―[l]imited visibility and missed Street
226 at 5. JPMorgan also advised the Committee on whether to approach other suitors pre-
additional competitive tension,‖ but that ―[f]inancial buyers have similar return hurdles
that drive value‖ and the Committee was therefore ―[u]nlikely to see any material
On December 6, 2012, the Committee reported to the full Board regarding its
progress.
Mr. Dell stated his belief that all of these initiatives would likely be poorly
received by the public markets because they would dramatically reduce
near-term profitability and involve significant risk. He expressed the view
that the Company could find it difficult to retain its top people in such an
environment, and that it could also harm the Company‘s ability to make
18
acquisitions. According to Mr. Dell, these initiatives could best be
accomplished in an environment without quarterly earnings pressure and
the risk that shareholder activists might attempt to disrupt the Company‘s
plans. Mr. Dell stated that a transaction was in the best interests of the
Company‘s shareholders because they would receive a portion of the
potential upside from these initiatives without bearing the risk.
JX 231 at 2.
The Board decided to invite Texas Pacific Group (―TPG‖) to explore a potential
transaction. Mandl thought TPG might be interested because it had invested in Lenovo
Group Ltd., an increasingly dominant value-PC producer, and therefore understood the
PC market. Mandl knew TPG‘s CEO, so he called him. TPG executed a confidentiality
agreement, received access to the online data room, and received management
On December 23, 2012, TPG informed JPMorgan that it would not submit a bid.
TPG reported to the Committee that it believed the ―cash flows attached to the PC
business were simply too uncertain, too unpredictable to establish an investment case.‖
On January 2, 2013, BCG provided the Committee with a detailed set of financial
forecasts. At a meeting on January 15, BCG updated its projections slightly to account for
new information from the bankers and a new IDC data set.
BCG‘s projections included three different cases. The first was the ―BCG Base
Case,‖ which was ―more pessimistic than‖ management‘s September Case but ―in-line
with recent analyst reports.‖ JX 259 at 13. BCG‘s other two cases were based on the
19
likelihood of achieving $3.3 billion in cost-savings that management had identified in
connection with a $2 billion cost-savings initiative that the Company announced in June
2012. Management had not announced the full $3.3 billion to give itself a ―cushion.‖ JX
272 at 2. BCG‘s other two cases assessed the likelihood of attaining those savings
initiatives, which provided incremental value to the BCG Base Case. One assumed that
the Company would realize 25% of the savings (the ―BCG 25% Case‖). The other
assumed that the Company would realize 75% of savings (the BCG 75% Case).
BCG believed the BCG 25% Case was attainable and the most reasonable set of
projections in light of the Company‘s performance with past cost-saving initiatives. The
Committee doubted that the Company could achieve the BCG 75% Case, which implied
margins in FY 2015 higher than the Company or its competitors had ever achieved. The
20
J. Evercore Joins The Team.
financial advisor who could, if desired, conduct a go-shop. Evercore‘s materials included
a DCF valuation of the Company with a range of $14.27 to $18.40 per share. Evercore‘s
LBO analysis supported prices of $12.36 to $16.08 assuming sponsor IRR demands of
15% to 25%.
The Committee retained Evercore the next day. The engagement letter
contemplated a $400,000 monthly retainer and a success fee equal to 0.75% of the
incremental value of any superior proposal produced during a go-shop, capped at a total
of $30 million.
On January 15, 2013, the Committee met to receive updates from management,
BCG, JPMorgan, and Evercore. Silver Lake had informed the Committee that it would
increase its proposal to $12.90 per share. In their presentations, JPMorgan and Evercore
JPMorgan‘s analysis showed that Silver Lake‘s revised offer was towards the mid-
point or upper end of valuation ranges based on trading metrics, trading multiples, market
premia, and LBO premia. It was within or above the ranges of values generated by a DCF
analysis based on the market low case and the most conservative BCG case, but below
the ranges of values generated by a DCF analysis based on the market consensus case, the
more optimistic BCG projections, and the September Case. Using its LBO model,
21
JPMorgan prepared a chart showing what a sponsor could pay depending on its desired
level of IRR:
Company performed consistent with the September Case, then at the price it was
offering, Silver Lake would achieve a 5-year IRR of 45% and generate a 5.3x multiple on
its invested capital, even if Silver Lake exited in five years at the same transaction
multiple. Mr. Dell would achieve a 5-year IRR of 50.1% and generate a 6.2x multiple on
his invested capital. Evercore calculated that if the Company performed in between the
BCG 25% Case and BCG 75% Case, then Silver Lake would achieve a 5-year IRR of
39.8% and generate a 4.5x multiple on its invested capital. Mr. Dell would achieve a 5-
year IRR of 44.7% and generate a 5.3x multiple on his invested capital.
Evercore‘s presentation also addressed the potential for the Committee to generate
a higher proposal during a go-shop period. Evercore advised that ―[s]ince 2005, there
have been 137 transactions with equity values greater than $100 million with go-shop
offer,‖ and ―[t]he superior offers on average were 20% greater than the initial bid.‖ Id.
22
Evercore advised the Committee about various factors that would affect a go-shop. Id. at
25.
The Committee discussed recent news leaks about Mr. Dell‘s exploration of an
MBO. In response to the leaks, Blackstone Management Partners LLC had reached out to
Evercore about engaging with the Company. Evercore advised the Committee to wait for
the go-shop before engaging Blackstone or soliciting additional bids. The petitioners
observe correctly that Evercore would earn a contingency fee only from offers produced
during the go-shop period, so it had an incentive to prefer that any additional bidder
On January 18, 2013, the full Board met, except for Mr. Dell. During an executive
session that excluded Mr. Dell and management, the Committee provided an update on
its process. Mandl informed the Board of the Committee‘s recommendation ―to target a
sale price of $13.75 per share, with $13.60 per share as the minimum sale price for
recommendation.
After the meeting, Mandl told Mr. Dell that the Committee would not support a
deal below $13.75 per share. Durban then called Mandl and offered $13.25 a share.
Mandl told him that was inadequate. Durban threatened to walk, and Mandl ―told him to
go ahead.‖ Tr. 169 (Mandl). Silver Lake came back at $13.50, but the Committee stood
firm.
23
At this point, Mr. Dell feared the parties had reached an impasse. To resolve the
stalemate, Mr. Dell agreed to roll over his shares at a lower valuation than what the
With Mr. Dell‘s commitment, Silver Lake increased the price it would pay for the
public float. By letter dated February 3, 2013, Silver Lake and Mr. Dell gave the
Committee two alternatives: (i) an all-cash transaction at $13.60 per share with the
Company able to continue issuing its regular quarterly dividend until closing, or (ii) an
all-cash transaction at $13.75 per share with no further dividends. The Committee asked
for more, and Silver Lake increased the cash component of the first alternative to $13.65
per share. Silver Lake told the Committee that this was its best and final offer.
Evercore and JPMorgan opined that the transaction consideration of $13.65 per share in
cash (the ―Original Merger Consideration‖) was fair to the unaffiliated stockholders from
a financial point of view. The bankers‘ valuation ranges for the Company had not
changed materially since their January presentations. JPMorgan derived the following
DCF using the BCG 75% Case: $15.00 to $21.25 per share.
DCF using the BCG 25% Case: $12.00 to $16.50 per share.
24
DCF using the BCG Base Case: $10.50 to $14.25 per share.
JX 331 at 21-22. JPMorgan dropped the discounted equity value approach that it had
Evercore updated its analysis of the expected return that Silver Lake and Mr. Dell
The Committee recommended that the Board accept Silver Lake‘s offer, which it
did. The transaction was documented in an agreement and plan of merger dated February
6, 2013 (together with amendments, the ―Merger Agreement‖) between the Company and
three counterparties: Denali Holding Inc., Denali Intermediate Inc., and Denali Acquiror
Inc., which were affiliates of Mr. Dell and Silver Lake (together, the ―Buyout Group‖).
Mr. Dell entered into a voting agreement in support of the transaction that required
Mr. Dell and his affiliates to vote their shares ―in the same proportion as the number of
25
[s]hares voted by the [u]naffiliated [s]tockholders . . . that are voted in favor of the
adoption‖ of either (i) a superior proposal if the Merger Agreement was terminated or (ii)
the adoption of the Merger Agreement in the event the Board changed its
recommendation. JX 355 at 2. Mr. Dell also agreed to roll over his shares at $13.36 per
share and to invest up to $500 million in additional equity. An affiliate of Mr. Dell agreed
to invest up to $250 million in additional equity. Post-closing, Mr. Dell would own
The Merger Agreement provided for (i) a forty-five day go-shop period that would
expire on March 23, 2013, (ii) a one-time match right for the Buyout Group that would
apply until the stockholder vote, and (iii) a $180 million termination fee if the Company
agreed to a Superior Proposal derived from a bid produced during the go-shop. For non-
Superior Proposals and bids produced after the go-shop period, the termination fee
a bona fide written Acquisition Proposal (with the percentages set forth in
clauses (ii) and (iii) of the definition of such term changed from 20% to
50% and it being understood that any transaction that would constitute an
Acquisition Proposal pursuant to clause (ii) or (iii) of the definition thereof
cannot constitute a Superior Proposal under clause (i) under the definition
thereof unless it also constitutes a Superior Proposal pursuant to clause (ii)
or (iii), as applicable, after giving effect to this parenthetical) that the
Company Board has determined in its good faith judgment . . . is more
favorable to the Company‘s stockholders than the Merger and the other
transactions contemplated by this Agreement, taking into account all of the
terms and conditions of such Acquisition Proposal (including the financing,
likelihood and timing of consummation thereof) . . . , provided that
notwithstanding the foregoing, an extra-ordinary dividend or share
repurchase (or any merger or consolidation that is the economic equivalent
of an extra-ordinary dividend or share repurchase) shall not constitute a
26
Superior Proposal unless it constitutes a Superior Proposal by virtue of
clause (iii) of the definition of Acquisition Proposal and the first
parenthetical above, and the Person acquiring such shares is not the
Company or any of its Subsidiaries.
any bona fide inquiry, proposal or offer made by any Person for, in a single
transaction or a series of transactions, (i) a merger, reorganization, share
exchange, consolidation, business combination, recapitalization, extra-
ordinary dividend or share repurchase, dissolution, liquidation or similar
transaction involving the Company, (ii) the direct or indirect acquisition by
any Person or group of twenty percent (20%) or more of the assets of the
Company and its Subsidiaries, on a consolidated basis or assets of the
Company and its Subsidiaries representing twenty percent (20%) or more
of the consolidated revenues or net income (including, in each case,
securities of the Company‘s Subsidiaries) or (iii) the direct or indirect
acquisition by any Person or group of twenty percent (20%) or more of the
voting power of the outstanding shares of Common Stock, including any
tender offer or exchange offer that if consummated would result in any
Person beneficially owning Shares with twenty percent (20%) or more of
the voting power of the outstanding shares of Common Stock.
Id. § 5.3(h).
On February 5, 2013, Evercore began the go-shop process. Within ten days,
Evercore had reached out to sixty parties. Evercore believed that the most promising
sophisticated technology group and one of its partners, David Johnson, had recently
HP was the Company‘s closest competitor and peer. Evercore reached out to HP
on the first day of the go-shop period, and Evercore met with HP on February 13, 2013.
At that meeting, Evercore told HP that a Dell-HP combination could achieve $3-4 billion
27
in annual cost synergies. On February 24, HP executed a confidentiality agreement.
Evercore believed HP was ―actively deliberat[ing]‖ about making a run at the Company.
JX 395 at 2. In reality, HP never accessed the data room and did not submit an indication
of interest.
Evercore insisted that Mr. Dell continue to support the process during the go-shop
period. When Mr. Dell proposed taking a two-week vacation, Roger Altman of Evercore
objected, noting that Mr. Dell ―wasn‘t unavailable to Silver Lake at any point during their
final 2 pre-offer weeks.‖ JX 385 at 2. Altman insisted that Mr. Dell ―must be available to
any other serious party which requests it.‖ Id. Mr. Dell complied.
On March 5, 2013, Carl Icahn and Icahn Enterprises L.P. (together, ―Icahn‖) sent a
letter to the Board expressing opposition to the Merger and proposing a leveraged
recapitalization. The Company would borrow funds sufficient to pay a special dividend
of $9 to the Company‘s stockholders, and Icahn estimated that the stock would trade at
approximately $13.81 per share after the transaction, generating aggregate value of
$22.81 per share. Evercore representatives thought Icahn‘s ―total value—$9 plus $13—
seems crazy‖ because the ―stub value [was] too high,‖ but otherwise Icahn had ―the right
Evercore had invited Icahn to participate in the go-shop before the March 5 letter.
On March 10, 2013, Icahn and the Company executed a confidentiality agreement, and
Icahn accessed the data room the next day. Icahn later had discussions with members of
28
On March 21, 2013, GE Capital submitted a bid to acquire the Company‘s
financial services unit for $3.6 billion in cash. GE Capital said it was happy to have the
stockholders a choice. They could roll over their shares into a new entity on a one-to-one
basis, or they could elect to receive $15.00 per share in cash, subject to a cap of $15.6
billion on the total cash payments. If the demands for cash payouts exceeded the cap,
then stockholders would receive their pro rata share. Evercore valued Icahn‘s proposal at
transaction that similarly gave stockholders a choice. Under Blackstone‘s proposal, the
Company‘s existing stockholders could elect to receive either a cash payment of at least
$14.25 per share or a package of stock in a new entity valued at $14.25 per share, subject
to a cap on the total amount of equity that the new entity would issue. Morgan Stanley &
Co. LLC provided Blackstone with a letter stating it was ―highly confident‖ it could raise
the financing for the transaction. JX 422 at 6. But Blackstone also stated that it was
―unwilling to expend additional time and resources‖ pursuing the transaction without ―a
more level playing field.‖ Id. Blackstone asked the Committee to reimburse its out-of-
pocket due diligence expenses and said that otherwise it would withdraw its offer.
Evercore and JPMorgan valued Blackstone‘s proposal at face value, or $14.25 per share.
On March 23, 2013, the go-shop period ended. The Committee determined that the
Icahn and Blackstone offers were, or could reasonably be expected to lead to, Superior
29
Proposals. This meant that each qualified as an ―Excluded Party,‖ and the Company only
would have to pay a $180 million termination fee if it entered into a transaction with
either of them.
The Committee considered Blackstone‘s request for fee reimbursement but did not
want to risk breaching the Merger Agreement and giving the Buyout Group a chance to
walk. The Committee therefore asked that the Buyout Group consent to the
reimbursement. The Buyout Group agreed on the condition that Silver Point receive a
similar payment. The Committee obliged and authorized the Company to reimburse
Silver Lake‘s and Blackstone‘s actual due diligence expenses up to a cap of $25 million
On April 2, 2013, Icahn asked for the same type of expense reimbursement. At the
time, Icahn and the Committee were negotiating over Icahn‘s request for a waiver of the
interested stockholder limitations under 8 Del. C. § 203, and the Committee‘s request in
response that Icahn agree not to acquire any additional shares. Fearing that Icahn might
turn hostile, the Committee decided to condition any expense reimbursement on Icahn
During this period, the Committee and Mr. Dell seemed receptive to an alternative
transaction involving Blackstone. In an email, Mr. Dell told Blackstone that he felt they
were ―substantially in agreement‖ on a vision for the Company and that he was ―open to
considering all alternatives.‖ JX 430 at 1. Mr. Dell‘s outstanding issues were ―the capital
Mr. Dell, but Blackstone was also prepared to proceed without him. According to a
30
Reuters report, Blackstone began vetting alternative CEO candidates. Mr. Dell took
offense at the perceived snub and communicated his feelings to Blackstone. Blackstone‘s
associated with Blackstone accessed the virtual data room. Approximately forty
additional diligence. The room was so large that directions had to be given over a
microphone. Mr. Dell noted that he ―spent more time with Blackstone than any of the
On April 10, 2013, IDC published a report stating that worldwide PC shipments
had declined 13.9% year over year and 13.2% quarter over quarter. Those numbers
―stunned‖ the Committee. Tr. 182 (Mandl). Conigliaro asked BCG to re-evaluate its
previously expressed view that market trends in the PC business were having only a
―relatively modest impact on the Dell earnings power‖; Conigliaro believed that IDC‘s
Mr. Dell had a different reaction. Although the Company‘s sales of PCs had
declined by 10.9% year over year and 4.9% quarter over quarter, the Company had
increased its market share by 0.4% and 1% respectively during the same periods. Mr.
Dell viewed market share as more important, and he reacted to the report by explaining,
―This is what we love to see!! Let‘s keep it going!!‖ JX 458 at 1. Mr. Dell‘s comment
31
confirms that he was focused on a long-term strategy of stabilizing revenues and
capturing market share at the expense of short-term margins, just as he repeatedly had
On April 18, 2013, Blackstone dropped out of the sale process. Its letter to the
JX 476 at 2. Notably, Blackstone had not been given the internal forecasts for the
Company that BCG had prepared, so it did not have access to that alternative view of the
Company‘s projected cash flows. Blackstone first learned of the projections when they
recapitalization in which stockholders would retain their current holdings and could elect
to receive either (i) a distribution of $12.00 per share in cash or (ii) $12.00 worth of
additional shares of stock, with the new equity issued at a value of $1.65 per share. Icahn
and Southeastern proposed replacing the Board with a slate of new directors who they
recapitalization, Evercore thought it was unlikely that Icahn‘s new proposal could qualify
32
On May 16, 2013, the Company released its results for the first quarter of FY
2014. Revenue declined just 2% from the previous year, but net income declined by 79%.
GAAP earnings per share fell 81% year over year, and non-GAAP earnings fell 51%.
According to an analyst from Bernstein Research, the margins for the enterprise solutions
and services segment were ―woeful, and well below industry peers.‖ JX 515 at 3. Even
Gladden expressed doubts, commenting on the Bernstein report that ―[i]t‘s not apparent
that the shift to growth will bring profit and cash in the short or long term.‖ Id. at 1.
―Most [analysts] were shocked at the profitability results.‖ Id. at 1. Revenues beat
Street estimates by about 4%, but earnings per share came in approximately 29% below
the consensus. According to BCG, the quarter ―miss [was] HUGE.‖ JX 513 at 1. Analysts
disagreed about the long-term implications for the Company. The Bernstein analyst
focused on the enterprise solutions and services division, noting that it generated
―essentially no profits,‖ which was ―a sober finding, given the company‘s strategic intent
is to migrate the company to enterprise offerings.‖ JX 515 at 3. The analyst attributed the
division‘s poor performance to ―myriad factors – none of which have easy fixes.‖ Id.
After the Company‘s poor quarter, the market consensus for FY 2014 operating
income dropped by 24% from $3.3 billion to $2.5 billion. By contrast, analysts increased
their expectations for HP by 3% during the same period, suggesting that they had
particular concerns about the Company. The market consensus forecast for operating
income during FY 2014 fell short of the BCG Base Case by approximately $800 million.
The Company‘s earnings release indicated annualized EBITA for FY 2014 was trending
to $2.54 billion, also about $800 million below the BCG Base Case.
33
Despite the Company‘s poor quarterly performance, BCG continued to believe
that the Company‘s long-term earnings power would not be adversely affected by the
market trends. BCG believed that the market had not deteriorated more than that
projected in the BCG Base Case and attributed the Company‘s poor results to
―[p]roductivity cost take out‖ was ―not on track and will not deliver bottom line benefits
in FY14.‖ JX 536 at 19. Although the costs savings underlying the BCG 25% Case
remained ―achievable,‖ they were ―unlikely to be realized in [this] year under current
strategy.‖ Id. at 23. This made the BCG 75% Case even less likely.
The Board scheduled a special meeting of stockholders to vote on the Merger for
July 18, 2013. The Board set a record date for the meeting of June 3. Icahn opposed the
Merger. Many value-based investors, including T. Rowe Price, also opposed the Merger.
They had bought stock believing that the market was under-valuing the non-PC-related
businesses. These stockholders had the same investment thesis as Mr. Dell.
On May 31, 2013, the Company filed its definitive proxy statement. In the proxy
statement, the directors disclosed that the ―Committee did not seek to determine a pre-
merger going concern value for the Common Stock to determine the fairness of the
Committee instead cited other reasons for recommending the transaction, such as the (i)
the certainty of cash consideration, (ii) the approximately 37% premium over the ninety-
34
day-average unaffected trading price of $9.97, and (iii) the approximately 25% premium
over the one-day unaffected trading price of $10.88. The Committee also cited the
declining Street consensus for the Company‘s earnings per share, which had been $2.02
in August 2012 and had fallen to $1.66 by February 2013, when the Merger was
announced. In June 2013, after the proxy statement was issued, the Street consensus fell
to $1.00.
On June 6, 2013, Icahn filed his preliminary proxy statement. On June 18, Icahn
disclosed that his affiliates had purchased approximately 72 million shares of common
On June 19, 2013, Icahn wrote to the Company‘s stockholders to say he would run
an alternate slate of directors at the annual meeting. Once his slate won, the new directors
would jettison the Merger and implement a self-tender at $14 per share for approximately
1.1 billion shares. Icahn represented that he would not tender. On July 1, he announced
lender commitments for $5.2 billion in debt financing for the tender offer.
Shareholder Services, Glass Lewis & Co. and Egan-Jones Rating Company
On July 12, 2013, Icahn revised his self-tender proposal to add one warrant for
every four shares tendered. Each warrant would entitle the holder for a period of seven
35
On July 17, 2013, the Committee learned from its proxy solicitor that stockholders
were not likely to approve the Merger at the special meeting on the next day. Rather than
holding the vote, the Committee convened the meeting and adjourned it until July 24.
Seeking to avoid defeat at the polls, the Buyout Group delivered a revised
proposal to the Committee on July 23, 2013. The original Merger Agreement required
that a majority of all unaffiliated stockholders approve the Merger. The revised proposal
called for reducing the requirement to a majority of the unaffiliated stockholders present
at the meeting or voting by proxy. In exchange, the Buyout Group proposed to increase
On July 24, 2013, the Committee convened the meeting and adjourned it until
August 2. On July 30, the Committee rejected the revised proposal as inadequate. The
market price of the Company‘s common stock fell 2.55% on the news. Some observers
On July 31, 2013, the Buyout Group offered a package of additional consideration
an additional $0.10 per share in merger consideration, increasing the total merger
consideration to $13.75,
a commitment that the Company would pay its third quarter dividend of $0.08 per
share, regardless of the closing date, and
a reduction in the termination fee from $450 million to $180 million if a leveraged
recapitalization or similar transaction occurred within twelve months after
stockholders voted down the Merger.
36
The Committee countered, saying it would accept the revised offer if the special cash
dividend was raised to $0.13. The Buyout Group agreed. Taking into account the
dividends, the total value of the package was $13.96 per share. Mr. Dell financed the
change by agreeing to reduce the value attributed to his rollover shares from $13.36 to
$12.51.
On August 2, 2013, the Committee met. JPMorgan and Evercore opined that the
increased merger consideration of $13.75 per share (the ―Final Merger Consideration‖)
was fair from a financial point of view to the unaffiliated holders of the Company‘s
common stock. JPMorgan relied on the same projections it used in February when
opining that the Original Merger Consideration was fair. JPMorgan observed that since
then, the PC industry had shown ―continued softness and deterioration,‖ making the
increased offer superior compared to its earlier opinion. Tr. 742 (Rajkovic).
relied on a forecast projecting annual operating income for FY 2014 of $3.7 billion. The
billion. The first six months of FY 2014 resulted in annualized operating income of $2.2
billion. As a result, Evercore ―had no confidence in‖ the projections, so it used primarily
market-based metrics to opine that the Final Merger Consideration was fair. Tr. 408
(Hiltz).
The Committee recommended that the Board approve the revised transaction,
which it did. By agreement dated August 2, 2013, the Buyout Group and the Company
amended the Merger Agreement to account for the changed voting condition and the
37
additional consideration. Also on August 2, the Committee convened and adjourned the
On August 15, 2013, the Company reported its financial results for the second
quarter of FY 2014. Revenue increased but margins suffered. For a second consecutive
quarter, net income declined, this time by more than 70% year over year.
The next day, IDC issued a public report in which it lowered its five-year forecast
for PC shipments to negative 8%. This was 62 basis points lower than its August 2011
forecast and 41 basis points lower than its August 2012 forecast. IDC opined that the
Company‘s enterprise solutions and services division would face ―intense competition.‖
JX 660 at 2-3.
Mr. Dell took an optimistic view of the IDC report. In an email to Silver Lake, he
expressed pride that IDC continued to identify the Company as the largest and most
profitable supplier of computers to end users. Although Lenovo and HP sold more units,
the Company continued to dominate in premium products. Mr. Dell compared the
Around this time, the Company‘s management and the Buyout Group made a
presentation to the rating agencies on the Company‘s post-acquisition debt. They used a
set of projections that were more optimistic than analyst forecasts or the IDC report and
contemplated 2-3% growth over the long term. Management told the rating agencies that
the Company was ―well on [its] way‖ to achieving $1.3 billion out of a targeted $3.5
billion in cost-savings, and they were ―very confident‖ that the Company would deliver
38
the remaining savings. JX 669 at 27. Management recognized that ―[f]inancial
performance has been mixed over the past 5 years‖ and explained that it was the result of
In September 2013, Silver Lake and Mr. Dell made a presentation to the banks that
would finance the Merger. The materials included a revised set of projections that
contemplated lower gross profit and EBITA relative to an earlier set of projections it
submitted to banks, but increased revenues (the ―Bank Case‖). The Bank Case also
projected that the Company‘s margins would increase over of next five years. The Bank
Case modeled $3.6 billion in cost savings, with $2.6 billion appearing in the forecasts and
another $1 billion as a separate line item. The ―cumulative realized incremental cost
savings‖ identified $500 million in savings in FY 2015, and $1 billion in each the
following three years. JX 678 at 13. The Bank Case included the following key metrics.
Bank Case
(in billions) FY 2014 FY 2015 FY 2016 FY 2017 FY 2018
Revenue $ 57.20 $ 58.71 $ 60.24 $ 62.03 $ 63.15
Gross Profit $ 11.64 $ 12.42 $ 12.98 $ 13.56 $ 13.93
EBITA $ 2.76 $ 3.15 $ 3.53 $ 3.90 $ 4.14
While presenting the Bank Case, Silver Lake produced a chart that modeled its
expected IRRs depending on the degree to which the Company achieved its cost-savings
goals and the EBITDA multiple for an anticipated exit. The chart emphasized an exit
multiple of 4.5x and asked the banks to treat that outcome as the model case:
39
With zero incremental cost savings, Silver Lake anticipated achieving an IRR of 29.2%,
indicating that even for purposes of the LBO pricing model, the Final Merger
Consideration was a great deal for the Buyout Group. JX 679 at 96-97.
The special meeting took place on September 12, 2013. Under Delaware law, a
merger requires the approval of holders of a majority of the outstanding shares, making
that the appropriate denominator for consideration. In the Company‘s case, holders of
57% of the Company‘s shares voted in favor of the Merger. Because not all stockholders
vote, and because a non-vote counts the same as a ―no‖ vote, the percentage always will
be higher for the shares that actually voted. In the Company‘s case, holders of
approximately 70% of the shares present at the meeting voted in favor. Both are
Icahn and Southeastern indicated originally that they would seek appraisal if the
Merger was approved, and they encouraged other stockholders to do so. Instead, Icahn
and Southeastern withdrew their appraisal demands. Icahn withdrew his competing
director nominations.
Committee with a final report on the Company. Because the Committee did not ask, BCG
did not update its forecasts. But BCG noted that it expected that end-user computing,
which accounted for two-thirds of the Company‘s operating income, to decline between
8% and 15% per year. BCG also noted that the ―PC market has been unusually turbulent‖
and its ―modeling indicates there is a potential for rapid ~$1.5B decline in‖ the end-user
40
computing division‘s operating income by FY 2017. JX 721 at 4. BCG expected that
enterprise solutions and services, which accounted for the other third of the Company‘s
operating income, would grow between 5 and 8% per year, but BCG did not think the
growth would ―close [the] gap‖ in operating income caused by the weakening end-user
computing division. JX 721 at 4. To ―close the gap,‖ the Company would have to rely on
cost-savings initiatives. BCG repeated its assessment from May that the BCG 25% Case
remained achievable, but given management execution, the Company was not likely to
realize the necessary savings to support the projections until the end of the fiscal year.
On October 28, 2013, the Company issued a $0.13 special dividend to all
stockholders. The Merger closed the next day. By operation of law, any shares of
common stock held by public stockholders who did not seek appraisal and perfect their
appraisal rights properly were converted into the right to receive the Merger
with a judicial determination of the intrinsic worth (fair value) of their shareholdings.‖
Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc. (Technicolor I), 542 A.2d 1182, 1186 (Del. 1988).
Section 262(h) of the Delaware General Corporation Law (the ―DGCL‖) states that
the Court shall determine the fair value of the shares exclusive of any
element of value arising from the accomplishment or expectation of the
merger or consolidation, together with interest, if any, to be paid upon the
amount determined to be the fair value. In determining such fair value, the
Court shall take into account all relevant factors.
41
8 Del. C. § 262(h). The statute thus places the obligation to determine the fair value of the
shares squarely on the court. Gonsalves v. Straight Arrow Publ’rs, Inc., 701 A.2d 357,
proceeding, both sides have the burden of proving their respective valuation positions by
a preponderance of evidence.‖ M.G. Bancorporation, Inc. v. Le Beau, 737 A.2d 513, 520
valuation.‖ Pinson v. Campbell–Taggart, Inc., 1989 WL 17438, at *6 (Del. Ch. Feb. 28,
1989).
Each party also bears the burden of proving the constituent elements of its
valuation position by a preponderance of the evidence, including the
propriety of a particular method, modification, discount, or premium. If
both parties fail to meet the preponderance standard on the ultimate
question of fair value, the Court is required under the statute to make its
own determination.
In re Appraisal of Dole Food Co., Inc., 114 A.3d 541, 550 (Del. Ch. 2014) (quoting Jesse
Appraisal Rights]).
―In discharging its statutory mandate, the Court of Chancery has discretion to
select one of the parties‘ valuation models as its general framework or to fashion its
own.‖ M.G. Bancorporation, 737 A.2d at 525-26. ―The Court may evaluate the valuation
opinions submitted by the parties, select the most representative analysis, and then make
42
appropriate adjustments to the resulting valuation.‖3 The court also may ―make its own
the parties‘ experts.‖ M.G. Bancorporation, 737 A.2d at 524. It is also ―entirely proper
for the Court of Chancery to adopt any one expert‘s model, methodology, and
withstands a critical judicial analysis on the record.‖ Id. at 526. ―When . . . none of the
parties establishes a valuation that is persuasive, the Court must make a determination
The standard of ―fair value‖ is ―a jurisprudential concept that draws more from
judicial writings than from the appraisal statue itself.‖ Del. Open MRI, 898 A.2d at 310.
―The concept of fair value under Delaware law is not equivalent to the economic concept
of fair market value. Rather, the concept of fair value for purposes of Delaware‘s
3
Appraisal Rights, supra, at A-31 (citing Onti, Inc. v. Integra Bank, 751 A.2d 904,
907 (Del. Ch. 1999) (basing fair value calculation on one expert‘s valuation, ―modifying
it where appropriate by the primary adjustment claims asserted by [the company]‖);
Kleinwort Benson Ltd. v. Silgan Corp., 1995 WL 376911, at *5 (Del. Ch. June 15, 1995)
(―I will not construct my own DCF model. From the evidence presented by [the] experts,
I will choose the DCF analysis that best represents Silgan‘s value. Next, . . . I will
scrutinize that DCF analysis to remove the adversarial hyperbole that inevitably
influences an expert‘s opinion in valuation proceedings.‖ (citation omitted))).
4
Cooper v. Pabst Brewing Co., 1993 WL 208763, at *8 (Del. Ch. June 8, 1993);
accord Del. Open MRI Radiology Assocs. P.A. v. Kessler, 898 A.2d 290, 310-11 (Del.
Ch. 2006) (Strine, V.C.) (―I cannot shirk my duty to arrive at my own independent
determination of value, regardless of whether the competing experts have provided
widely divergent estimates of value, while supposedly using the same well-established
principles of corporate finance.‖).
43
Finkelstein v. Liberty Digital, Inc., 2005 WL 1074364, at *12 (Del. Ch. Apr. 25, 2005)
(Strine, V.C.). In Tri-Continental Corp. v. Battye, 74 A.2d 71 (Del. 1950), the Delaware
Supreme Court explained in detail the concept of value that the appraisal statute employs:
The basic concept of value under the appraisal statute is that the
stockholder is entitled to be paid for that which has been taken from him,
viz., his proportionate interest in a going concern. By value of the
stockholder‘s proportionate interest in the corporate enterprise is meant the
true or intrinsic value of his stock which has been taken by the merger. In
determining what figure represents the true or intrinsic value, . . . the courts
must take into consideration all factors and elements which reasonably
might enter into the fixing of value. Thus, market value, asset value,
dividends, earning prospects, the nature of the enterprise and any other facts
which were known or which could be ascertained as of the date of the
merger and which throw any light on future prospects of the merged
corporation are not only pertinent to an inquiry as to the value of the
dissenting stockholder‘s interest, but must be considered . . . .5
definition of value.6
―The time for determining the value of a dissenter‘s shares is the point just before
the merger transaction ‗on the date of the merger.‘‖ Appraisal Rights, supra, at A-33
5
Id. at 72. Although Battye is the seminal Delaware Supreme Court case on point,
Chancellor Josiah Wolcott initially established the meaning of ―value‖ under the
appraisal statute in Chicago Corp. v. Munds, 172 A. 452 (Del. Ch. 1934). Because there
was a ―material variance‖ between the Delaware appraisal statute, which used ―value,‖
and the comparable New Jersey statute that served as a model for the Delaware statute,
which used ―full market value,‖ Chancellor Wolcott held the plain language of the statute
required ―value‖ to be determined on a ―going concern basis.‖ Id. at 453-54.
6
See, e.g., Montgomery Cellular Hldg. Co., Inc. v. Dobler, 880 A.2d 206, 222
(Del. 2005); Paskill Corp. v. Alcoma Corp., 747 A.2d 549, 553 (Del. 2000); Rapid-Am.
Corp. v. Harris, 603 A.2d 796, 802 (Del. 1992); Cavalier Oil Corp. v. Hartnett, 564 A.2d
1137, 1144 (Del. 1989); Bell v. Kirby Lumber Corp., 413 A.2d 137, 141 (Del. 1980);
Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Francis I. duPont & Co., 334 A.2d 216, 218 (Del. 1975).
44
(quoting Technicolor I, 542 A.2d at 1187). Put differently, the valuation date is the date
on which the merger closes.7 Consequently, if the value of the corporation changes
between the signing of the merger and the closing, the fair value determination must be
measured by the ―operative reality‖ of the corporation at the effective time of the
merger.8
corporation is not a point on a line, but a range of reasonable values, and the judge‘s task
is to assign one particular value within this range as the most reasonable value in light of
all the relevant evidence and based on considerations of fairness.‖ Cede & Co. v.
Technicolor, Inc., 2003 WL 23700218, at *2 (Del. Ch. July 9, 2004), aff’d in part, rev’d
7
Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc. (Technicolor II), 684 A.2d 289, 298 (Del. 1996)
(―[T]he dissenter in an appraisal action is entitled to receive a proportionate share of fair
value in the going concern on the date of the merger . . . .‖); Universal Studios, 334 A.2d
at 221 (explaining that making a ―determination of value as of the day of merger [is] the
Court‘s endeavor‖).
8
Technicolor II, 684 A.2d at 298; accord M.G. Bancorp., 737 A.2d at 525 (―[T]he
corporation must be valued as a going concern based upon the operative reality of the
company as of the time of the merger.‖ (quotation marks omitted)); Gonsalves v. Straight
Arrow Publ’rs, Inc. (Gonsalves III), 793 A.2d 312, 316 (Del. Ch. 1998) (―Overall, the
focus is on the operative reality on the date of the merger.‖ (quotation marks and footnote
omitted)), aff’d in pertinent part, rev’d on other grounds, 725 A.2d 442 (Del. 1999)
(TABLE).
45
A. The Final Merger Consideration As The Best Evidence Of Fair Value
The Company contends that the Final Merger Consideration is the best evidence of
the Company‘s fair value on the closing date. As the proponent of this valuation
methodology, the Company bears the burden of establishing its reliability and
persuasiveness. In this case, the Final Merger Consideration is certainly a relevant factor,
The consideration that the buyer agrees to provide in the deal and that the seller
agrees to accept is one form of market price data, which Delaware courts have long
59. Traditionally, Delaware decisions focused on stock market prices, rather than the deal
price. ―[T]here is extensive case law on [the use of stock] market value because of its role
as one of the three elements of the Delaware Block Method.‖ Id. at A-57. Chancellor
Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc., 1990 WL 161084, at *31 (Del. Ch. Oct. 19, 1990)
(quoting In re Del. Racing Ass’n, 213 A.2d 203, 211 (Del. 1965) (citing Tri-Cont’l and
Munds)), rev’d on other grounds, 636 A.2d 956 (Del. 1994). Numerous cases support
46
Chancellor Allen‘s observations that (i) pricing data from a thick and efficient market
market price data generated not only by the market for individual shares but also by the
market for the company as a whole. If the merger giving rise to appraisal rights ―resulted
impediments existed that might materially distort the ‗crucible of objective market
9
See Gonsalves III, 793 A.2d at 326 (noting that the ―market value model[ ] . . .
may be used, in an appropriate situation, to provide a relevant estimate of fair value‖);
ONTI, 751 A.2d at 915 (considering stock price by valuing the shares at a discount to that
price to ―factor in this limited market for the shares‖); Cooper v. Pabst Brewing Co.,
1993 WL 208763, at *8 (Del. Ch. June 8, 1993) (determining value of shares ―primarily
based upon an estimated actual market value of the stock‖). Relatedly, when this court
has considered comparable company analyses in valuations, it has relied in part upon the
market prices of other companies that were found to be similar to the company at issue.
See, e.g., Andaloro v. PFPC Worldwide, Inc., 2005 WL 2045640, at *18-20 (Del. Ch.
Aug. 19, 2005) (Strine, V.C.); Doft & Co. v. Travelocity.com Inc., 2004 WL 1152338, at
*8 (Del. Ch. May 20, 2004); Taylor v. Am. Specialty Retailing Gp., Inc., 2003 WL
21753752, at *9 (Del. Ch. July 25, 2003).
10
See, e.g., Rapid–Am. Corp., 603 A.2d at 806 (―[T]he Court of Chancery long
ago rejected exclusive reliance upon market value in an appraisal action.‖); Kirby
Lumber, 413 A.2d at 141 (―[M]arket value may not be taken as the sole measure of the
value of the stock.‖); Del. Racing, 213 A.2d at 211 (―It is, of course, equally axiomatic
that market value, either actual or constructed, is not the sole element to be taken into
consideration in the appraisal of stock.‖); Jacques Coe & Co. v. Minneapolis–Moline Co.,
75 A.2d 244, 247 (Del. Ch. 1950) (observing that market price should not be exclusive
measure of value); Munds, 172 A. at 455 (―There are too many accidental circumstances
entering into the making of market prices to admit them as sure and exclusive reflectors
of fair value.‖).
47
reality,‘‖ then ―a reviewing court should give substantial evidentiary weight to the merger
Here too, however, the Delaware Supreme Court has eschewed market
Section 262(h) neither dictates nor even contemplates that the Court of
Chancery should consider the transactional market price of the underlying
company. Rather, in determining ―fair value,‖ the statute instructs that the
court ―shall take into account all relevant factors.‖ Importantly, this Court
has defined ―fair value‖ as the value to a stockholder of the firm as a going
concern, as opposed to the firm‘s value in the context of an acquisition or
other transaction. Determining ―fair value‖ through ―all relevant factors‖
may be an imperfect process, but the General Assembly has determined it
to be an appropriately fair process. . . .
11
Highfields Capital, Inc. v. AXA Fin., Inc., 939 A.2d 34, 42 (Del. Ch. 2007); see
also M.P.M. Enters., Inc. v. Gilbert, 731 A.2d 790, 796 (Del. 1999) (―A merger price
resulting from arms-length negotiations where there are no claims of collusion is a very
strong indication of fair value.‖); Prescott Gp. Small Cap, L.P. v. Coleman Co., 2004 WL
2059515, at *27 (Del. Ch. Sept. 8, 2004) (explaining that ―the price actually derived from
the sale of a company as a whole . . . may be considered as long as synergies are
excluded‖); see also Van de Walle v. Unimation, Inc., 1991 WL 29303, at *17 (Del. Ch.
Mar. 6, 1991) (commenting in an entire fairness case that ―[t]he fact that a transaction
price was forged in the crucible of objective market reality (as distinguished from the
unavoidably subjective thought process of a valuation expert) is viewed as strong
evidence that the price is fair‖).
48
―fair value‖ from the court to the private parties. Also, while it is difficult
for the Chancellor and Vice Chancellors to assess wildly divergent expert
opinions regarding value, inflexible rules governing appraisal provide little
additional benefit in determining ―fair value‖ because of the already high
costs of appraisal actions. . . . Therefore, we reject . . . [the] call to establish
a rule requiring the Court of Chancery to defer to the merger price in any
appraisal proceeding.
Golden Telecom, Inc. v. Glob. GT LP (Golden Telecom II), 11 A.3d 214, 217-18 (Del.
Since Golden Telecom II, and consistent with the Delaware Supreme Court‘s
teaching in that decision, the Court of Chancery has considered the deal price as one of
the ―relevant factors‖ when determining fair value.12 In at least five decisions, the Court
12
See Merion Capital LP v. BMC Software, Inc., 2015 WL 6164771 (Del. Ch.
Oct. 21, 2015); LongPath Capital, LLC v. Ramtron Int’l Corp., 2015 WL 4540443 (Del.
Ch. June 30, 2015); Merlin P’rs LP v. AutoInfo, Inc., 2015 WL 2069417 (Del. Ch. Apr.
30, 2015); In re Appraisal of Ancestry.com, Inc., 2015 WL 399726 (Del. Ch. Jan. 30,
2015); Huff Fund Inv. P’ship v. CKx, Inc., 2013 WL 5878807 (Del. Ch. Nov. 1, 2013).
Court of Chancery decisions took the same approach before Golden Telecom. See
Highfields Capital, 939 A.2d at 59 (deferring to the merger price where an arms‘ length
process was conducted, and no material impediments prevented another bidder from
entering the sale process during an eight-month market check period); Union Ill. 1995
Inv. Ltd. P’ship v. Union Fin. Gp., Ltd., 847 A.2d 340, 358 (Del. Ch. 2003) (Strine, V.C.)
(holding that the merger price was the best indication of fair value for purposes of an
appraisal because the merger ―resulted from a competitive and fair auction, which
followed a more-than-adequate sales process and involved broad dissemination of
confidential information to a large number of prospective buyers‖); see also Van de
Walle, 1991 WL 29303, at *17 (holding in breach of fiduciary duty case that ―[t]he most
persuasive evidence of the fairness of the . . . merger price is that it was the result of
arm‘s length-negotiations between two independent parties, where the seller . . . was
motivated to seek the highest available price, and a diligent and extensive canvass of the
market had confirmed that no better price was available‖).
49
of Chancery has found the deal price to be the most reliable indicator of the company‘s
fair value, particularly when other evidence of fair value was weak.13
Depending on the facts of the case, a variety of factors may undermine the
potential persuasiveness of the deal price as evidence of fair value. For one, in a public
company merger, the need for a stockholder vote, regulatory approvals, and other time-
intensive steps may generate a substantial delay between the signing date and the closing
date. The deal price provides a data point for the market price of the company as of the
date of signing, but as discussed above, the valuation date for an appraisal is the date of
13
BMC, 2015 WL 6164771, at *18 (finding merger price to be best indicator of
value because of the ―uncertainties in the DCF analysis‖ and because there was an
―arm‘s-length transaction negotiated over multiple rounds of bidding among interested
buyers‖); Ramtron, 2015 WL 4540443, at *20 (finding merger price to be the most
reliable evidence of value after deeming management forecasts unreliable and noting that
―[a]ny impediments to a higher bid resulted from Ramtron‘s operative reality, not
shortcomings of the Merger process‖); AutoInfo, 2015 WL 2069417, at *17-18 (deferring
to merger price after finding projections unreliable in the context of a ―competitive and
fair auction‖); Ancestry.com, 2015 WL 399726, at *23 (finding merger price to be best
indicator of value because of weak forecasts and a ―robust‖ sale process); CKx, 2013 WL
5878807, at *13 (finding that the merger price was the ―most reliable indicator of value‖
in a case ―where no comparable companies, comparable transactions, or reliable cash
flow projections exist‖). Unlike the current case, none of these decisions involved an
MBO. And unlike the current case, reliable projections and persuasive evidence of a
significant valuation gap did not exist. In BMC, the court found that ―the sales process
was sufficiently structured to develop fair value of the Company,‖ which is different than
the facts of this case. 2015 WL 6164771, at *16. All the cases either involved a more
active pre-signing market check or the process was kicked off by an unsolicited third-
party bid.
50
closing. See Part II, supra. Market pricing indications can change rapidly, whether in the
Another issue is the reality that the M&A market for an entire company has
different and less confidence-promoting attributes than the public trading markets:
Among the other requirements for market efficiency are liquidity and
fungibility. Public stock market prices are generally efficient because large
numbers of identical shares of stock in a given company trade on a highly
liquid market with millions of participants. The deal market, however—
dealing as it does with entire companies, rather than individual shares—
often lacks both qualities. No two companies are exactly alike, and the
market for whole companies is unavoidably chunky, rather than liquid. As
such, the deal market is unavoidably less efficient at valuing entire
companies (including the value of control) than the stock market is at
valuing minority shares.15
14
In the Dollar Thrifty litigation, Chief Justice Strine (then a Vice Chancellor)
noted that the price of Dollar Thrifty, the target company, rose from $26.97 in December
2009 to $38.85 in April 2010, with no other fundamental changes in its outlook except
for the possibility of an M&A deal. In re Dollar Thrifty S’holder Litig., 14 A.3d 573,
611-12 (Del. Ch. 2010). He commented that ―if the stock market is actually pricing
Dollar Thrifty on its future expected cash flows, the market has had a rather rapidly
shifting sense of what those future cash flows are.‖ Id. During the fifty-two weeks before
news of the Merger leaked, the Company‘s stock price varied within a range which, in
percentage terms, was more than twice as wide as in Dollar Thrifty, trading between a
low of $8.86 and a high of $18.32 per share.
15
Charles Korsmo & Minor Myers, Reforming Modern Appraisal Litigation, 41
Del. J. Corp. L. (forthcoming 2016) (manuscript at 50), available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2712088 [hereinafter Modern
Appraisal Litigation]; accord James R. Repetti, Management Buyouts, Efficient Markets,
Fair Value, and Soft Information, 67 N.C. L. Rev. 121, 128-37 (1988) (distinguishing
between the ―first tier‖ market for shares and the ―second tier‖ market for corporate
control; collecting studies indicating that the market for control is less efficient than the
market for shares and that the divergence is pronounced for MBOs; arguing as a result
that deal price is therefore an unreliable measure of fair value in MBO transactions).
51
The limitations on efficient pricing in the market for corporate control ―are especially
Writing as a Vice Chancellor, Chief Justice Strine observed that even for purposes
of determining the value of individual shares, where the stock market is typically thick
and liquid, the proponents of the efficient capital markets hypothesis no longer make the
strong-form claim that the market price actually determines fundamental value; at most
they make the semi-strong claim that market prices reflect all available information and
are efficient at incorporating new information.16 The M&A market has fewer buyers and
16
Dollar Thrifty, 14 A.3d at 611 (citing Michael L. Wachter, Takeover Defenses
When Financial Markets Are (Only) Relatively Efficient, 161 U. Pa. L. Rev. 787, 792
(2003) (―Specifically, when financial markets are relatively efficient, while investors
cannot expect to outperform the market on an ongoing basis, individual stock prices can
still be incorrect at any point in time—either under- or overestimating the value of the
corporation.‖ (citing John Y. Campbell, Andrew W. Lo & A. Craig Mackinlay, The
Econometrics of Financial Markets 24–25 (Princeton Univ. Press, 1997)))); Anabtawi,
supra, at 1301 (―Stock market prices can depart substantially from their fundamental
value for extended periods of time.‖); Richard A. Brealey & Stewart C. Meyers,
Principles Of Corporate Finance 368 (9th ed. 2008) (―[M]ost of the tests of market
efficiency are concerned with relative prices and focus on whether there are easy profits
to be made. It is almost impossible to test whether stocks are correctly valued, because no
one can measure true value with any precision.‖); Lynn A. Stout, Inefficient Markets and
the New Finance 7 (Univ. of Cal. L.A., Research Paper No. 05–11, 2005), available at
http://ssrn.com/abstract=729224 (―[I]n a world of disagreement we must question
whether securities markets can be efficient in a fundamental value sense. As noted
earlier, however, fundamental value efficiency is not the only possible understanding of
efficiency. Many theorists who speak of ‗efficient markets‘ seem to be relying on the
alternate idea of informational efficiency—that prices respond so quickly to new
information it is impossible for traders to make profits on the basis of the information.
Indeed, it has become common for finance economists whose faith in fundamental value-
efficiency has been beaten out of them by market events and the accumulating evidence
on anomalies to retreat to this intellectual position [Brealey & Meyers (2000, p. 377);
52
one seller, and the dissemination of critical, non-public due diligence information is
―conflate the stock market (which is generally highly efficient) with the deal market
(which often is not).‖ Modern Appraisal Litigation, supra, at 50. It is perhaps more
erroneous to claim that the thinner M&A market generates a price consistent with
fundamental efficiency, when the same claim is no longer made for the thicker markets in
individual shares.
There is also the recognized problem that an arms‘ length deal price often includes
synergies. This can be true even for a financial buyer, because ―the aggregation of shares,
Buyouts, 50 B.C. L. Rev. 1021, 1050 (2009). The value of synergies ―would not
otherwise exist in the enterprise itself‖ and therefore represent an ―‗element of value
arising from the accomplishment or expectation of the merger or consolidation‘ that must
53
be excluded‖ Id. at 1029 (quoting 8 Del. C. § 262). Consequently, ―the appraisal statute
requires that the Court exclude any synergies present in the deal price—that is, value
These three factors suggest that even with a public company target, deal price will
not inevitably equate to fair value. It could be higher or lower. Doubtless other factors,
some of which favor the deal price and others which cut against it, will emerge from
still may be able to establish that the merger price is the best evidence of fair value—and
it often will be—but the corporation must carry its burden on that point. See Golden
price for establishing fair value is the nature of the court‘s review of the process that led
to the transaction. Here, the distinction between a breach of fiduciary duty case and an
54
Modern Appraisal Litigation, supra, at 48 (footnote omitted). The two inquiries are
different, so a sale process might pass muster for purposes of a breach of fiduciary claim
The central question in a breach of fiduciary duty case is whether the defendant
fiduciaries acted in a manner that should subject them personally to a damages award. To
determine whether a breach of duty occurred, a court applying Delaware law evaluates
the directors‘ conduct through the lens of a standard of review. ―Delaware has three tiers
of review for evaluating director decision-making: the business judgment rule, enhanced
scrutiny, and entire fairness.‖ Reis v. Hazelett Strip–Casting Corp., 28 A.3d 442, 457
re Trados Inc. S’holder Litig. (Trados II), 73 A.3d 17, 43 (Del. Ch. 2013).
Framed for purposes of an M&A transaction, enhanced scrutiny places the burden
on the defendant directors to show that they sought ―to secure the transaction offering the
best value reasonably available for the stockholders.‖ Paramount Commc’ns Inc. v. QVC
Network Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 44 (Del. 1994). In this formulation, ―[t]he key verb is
‗sought.‘ Time-bound mortals cannot foresee the future. The test therefore cannot be
whether, with hindsight, the directors actually achieved the best price.‖ In re Del Monte
Foods Co. S’holders Litig., 25 A.3d 813, 830 (Del. Ch. 2011). ―Rather, the duty can only
55
be to try in good faith, in such a setting, to get the best available transaction for the
setting, the enhanced scrutiny standard of review examines (i) the reasonableness of ―the
the directors based their decision,‖ and (ii) ―the reasonableness of the directors‘ action in
light of the circumstances then existing.‖ QVC, 637 A.2d at 44. ―Through this
examination, the court seeks to assure itself that the board acted reasonably, in the sense
of taking a logical and reasoned approach for the purpose of advancing a proper
objective, and to thereby smoke out mere pretextual justifications for improperly
enables a reviewing court ―to address inequitable action even when directors may have
subjectively believed that they were acting properly.‖ Del Monte, 25 A.3d at 830-31. The
objective standard does not permit a reviewing court to freely substitute its own judgment
17
Citron v. Fairchild Camera & Instrument Corp., 1988 WL 53322, at *16 n.17
(Del. Ch. May 19, 1988) (Allen, C.); accord Dollar Thrifty, 14 A.3d at 617 (expressing
skepticism about an approach that would require directors to predict the future); In re
Fort Howard Corp. S’holders Litig., 1988 WL 83147, at *14 (Del. Ch. Aug. 8, 1988)
(Allen, C.) (―Revlon explicitly recognized that a disinterested board acting in good faith
and in an informed manner may enter into lock-up agreements if the effect was to
promote, not impede, shareholder interests. (That can only mean if the intended effect is
such, for the validity of the agreement itself cannot be made to turn upon how accurately
the board did foresee the future).‖).
56
There are many business and financial considerations implicated in
investigating and selecting the best value reasonably available. The board
of directors is the corporate decisionmaking body best equipped to make
these judgments. Accordingly, a court applying enhanced judicial scrutiny
should be deciding whether the directors made a reasonable decision, not a
perfect decision. If a board selected one of several reasonable alternatives, a
court should not second-guess that choice even though it might have
decided otherwise or subsequent events may have cast doubt on the board‘s
determination. Thus, courts will not substitute their business judgment for
that of the directors, but will determine if the directors‘ decision was, on
balance, within a range of reasonableness.
QVC, 637 A.2d at 45 (emphasis removed). Enhanced scrutiny ―is not a license for law-
trained courts to second-guess reasonable, but debatable, tactical choices that directors
have made in good faith.‖ In re Toys ―R‖ Us, Inc. S’holder Litig., 877 A.2d 975, 1000
(Del. Ch. 2005); accord Dollar Thrifty, 14 A.3d at 595-96 (―[A]t bottom Revlon is a test
of reasonableness; directors are generally free to select the path to value maximization, so
As these passages show, enhanced scrutiny requires an inquiry into the ends the
directors pursued and the means they chose to achieve them. ―[T]he reasonableness
standard requires the court to consider for itself whether the board is truly well motivated
(i.e. is it acting for the proper ends?) before ultimately determining whether its means
were themselves a reasonable way of advancing those ends.‖ Dollar Thrifty, 14 A.3d at
599. Enhanced scrutiny ―mandates that the court look closely at the motivations of the
board.‖ Id. at 598. What typically generates a finding of breach ―is evidence of self-
stockholder-motivated influence that calls into question the integrity of the process.‖ Del
Monte, 25 A.3d at 831. The test is not whether the outcome was in fact the best
57
transaction reasonably available, and the failure to achieve what actually would have
been the best transactional outcome, standing alone, is not a basis for liability. The
outcome that the directors achieved will figure into the damages calculation, but only if
the matter reaches that phase. The outcome is not part of the liability case.
In an appraisal proceeding, by contrast, the opposite is true. The court does not
judge the directors‘ motives or the reasonableness of their actions, but rather the outcome
they achieved. The price is all that matters because the court‘s inquiry focuses
exclusively on the value of the company. How and why the directors achieved fair value
or fell short is not part of the case. The sale process is useful to the extent—and only to
the extent—that it provides evidence of the company‘s value on the date the merger
closed.
Because the standards differ, it is entirely possible that the decisions made during
a sale process could fall within Revlon‘s range of reasonableness, and yet the process still
could generate a price that was not persuasive evidence of fair value in an appraisal.18 Put
18
See In re Appraisal of Ancestry.com, Inc., 2015 WL 399726, at *16 (Del. Ch.
Jan. 30, 2015) (―Of course, a conclusion that a sale was conducted by directors who
complied with their duties of loyalty is not dispositive of the question of whether that sale
generated fair value.‖); In re Appraisal of Orchard Enters., Inc., 2012 WL 2923305, at *5
(Del. Ch. July 18, 2012) (Strine, C.) (―[T]his is an appraisal action, not a fiduciary duty
case, and although I have little reason to doubt Orchard‘s assertion that no buyer was
willing to pay Dimensional $25 million for the preferred stock and an attractive price for
Orchard‘s common stock in 2009, an appraisal must be focused on Orchard‘s going
concern value.‖).
58
differently, even if a transaction passes fiduciary muster, an appraisal proceeding could
To be sure, the questions in the two kinds of actions are frequently related.
Often, when stockholders do not get fair value for their shares, it will be
because the board has breached its fiduciary duties. . . . [T]he strongest
appraisal claims [should] also present strong fiduciary duty claims, and vice
versa. But forcing both types of claims into the same analytical box is a
self-evident mistake. Many types of managerial sloth, incompetence,
pressure, or collusion that courts have been understandably hesitant to
characterize as breaches of fiduciary duty can nonetheless lead to . . .
stockholders receiving well below fair value for their shares. In such
situations, appraisal constitutes a useful middle course between holding
directors personally liable (and potentially granting injunctions) and
allowing unfair transactions to escape meaningful scrutiny.
Modern Appraisal Litigation, supra, at 48. ―Satisfying one of the various Revlon-type
tests . . . is not necessarily a market test‖ sufficient to establish fair value for purposes of
appraisal. Charles R. Korsmo & Minor Myers, Appraisal Arbitrage and the Future of
19
M.P.M. Enters., Inc. v. Gilbert, 731 A.2d 790, 797 (Del. 1999) (―A fair merger
price in the context of a breach of fiduciary duty claim will not always be a fair value in
the context of determining going concern value.‖); In re Orchard Enters., Inc. S’holder
Litig., 88 A.3d 1, 30 (Del. Ch. 2014) (―A price may fall within the range of fairness for
purposes of the entire fairness test even though the point calculation demanded by the
appraisal statute yields an award in excess of the merger price.‖); Trados II, 73 A.3d at
78 (―A court could conclude that a price fell within the range of fairness and would not
support fiduciary liability, yet still find that the point calculation demanded by the
appraisal statute yields an award in excess of the merger price.‖); Reis, 28 A.3d at 466
(―A court readily could conclude that a price fell within the range of fairness and would
not support fiduciary liability, and yet the point calculation demanded by the appraisal
statute could yield an award in excess of the merger price.‖). Compare Cinerama, Inc. v.
Technicolor, Inc., 663 A.2d 1156, 1176-77 (Del. 1995) (affirming that merger
consideration of $23 per share was entirely fair), with Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc.,
884 A.2d 26, 30 (Del. 2005) (awarding fair value in appraisal of $28.41 per share).
59
3. MBO Status As An Additional Factor
A third factor when considering the persuasiveness of the deal price is the fact that
the Merger was an MBO. Because of management‘s additional and conflicting role as
buyer, MBOs present different concerns than true arms‘ length transactions. A vast
amount of case law20 and scholarship (both legal21 and empirical22) has addressed MBOs.
20
In Delaware, seminal cases addressing challenges to MBOs on fiduciary
grounds include the Delaware Supreme Court‘s decisions in Revlon and Macmillan and
Chancellor Allen‘s decisions in Fort Howard and RJR Nabisco. See Mills Acq. Co. v.
Macmillan, Inc., 559 A.2d 1261 (Del. 1989); Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes
Hldgs., Inc., 506 A.2d 713 (Del. 1986); In re RJR Nabisco, Inc. S’holders Litig., 1989
WL 7036 (Del. Ch. Jan. 31, 1989); In re Fort Howard Corp. S’holders Litig., 1988 WL
83147 (Del. Ch. Aug. 8, 1988). More recent treatments include a series of opinions
authored by Chief Justice Strine while serving as a member of this court. See In re Lear
Corp. S’holder Litig., 926 A.2d 94 (Del. Ch. 2007); In re Topps Co. S’holders Litig., 926
A.2d 58 (Del. Ch. 2007); In re Netsmart Techs., Inc. S’holders Litig., 924 A.2d 171 (Del.
Ch. 2007). This court‘s rejection of a settlement in SS&C Technologies likewise
identifies some of the complications raised by an MBO. See In re SS&C Techs., Inc., 911
A.2d 816, 820-22 (Del. Ch. 2006) (rejecting as inadequate a proposed settlement of
breach of fiduciary duty claims challenging an MBO; identifying issues that plaintiffs‘
counsel failed to address adequately).
21
A number of authorities are cited in this decision. There are many others. See,
e.g., Tom Ablum & Mary Beth Burgis, Leveraged Buyouts: The Ever Changing
Landscape, 13 DePaul Bus. L.J. 109 (2001); William T. Allen, Independent Directors In
MBO Transactions: Are They Fact or Fantasy?, 45 Bus. Law. 2055 (1990); Jason M.
Klein, When the Board Should Just Say Yes to Management: The Interplay Between the
Decision of Whether to Conduct an Auction and Transaction Structure, 5 Stan. J.L. Bus.
& Fin. 45 (1999); Louis Lowenstein, Management Buyouts, 85 Colum. L. Rev. 730
(1985); Dale Arthur Oesterle & Jon R. Norberg, Management Buyouts: Creating or
Appropriating Shareholder Wealth, 41 Vand. L. Rev. 207 (1988); Bill Shaw, Resolving
the Conflict of Interest in Management Buyouts, 19 Hofstra L. Rev. 143 (1990); David B.
Simpson, The Management Buyout: An Idea Whose Time May Have Passed, 17 Seton
Hall Legis. J. 137 (1993).
22
The economic literature on stockholder returns in MBOs through 2011 is
surveyed helpfully in Matthew D. Cain & Steven M. Davidoff, Form Over Substance?
60
Although the literature is far from unanimous in its analysis and policy
recommendations,23 the weight of authority suggests that a claim that the bargained-for
price in an MBO represents fair value should be evaluated with greater thoroughness and
care than, at the other end of the spectrum, a transaction with a strategic buyer in which
In this case, the Company‘s process easily would sail through if reviewed under
enhanced scrutiny. The Committee and its advisors did many praiseworthy things, and it
would burden an already long opinion to catalog them. In a liability proceeding, this court
could not hold that the directors breached their fiduciary duties or that there could be any
basis for liability. But that is not the same as proving that the deal price provides the best
evidence of the Company‘s fair value. In this case, a combination of factors undercut the
The Value of Corporate Process and Management Buy-Outs, 36 Del. J. Corp. L. 849,
867-71 (2011). Cain and Davidoff also provide empirical evidence of their own.
23
Compare Yakov Amihud, Leveraged Management Buyouts and Shareholders’
Wealth, in Leveraged Management Buyouts: Causes and Consequences 3, 24 (Yakov
Amihud ed., 1989) (concluding that MBOs increase shareholders‘ wealth by increasing
stock prices), with Robert L. Kieschnick, Jr., Management Buyouts of Public
Corporations: An Analysis of Prior Characteristics, in Leveraged Management Buyouts:
Causes and Consequences 35, 57 (Yakov Amihud ed., 1989) (concluding that the benefit
of MBOs cannot be established), with Kai Chen, Yong-Cheol Kim & Richard D. Marcus,
Hands in the Cookie Jar? The Case of Management Buyouts 28 (2009) (finding evidence
that management acts opportunistically in MBOs but that effect is mitigated by option
holdings), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1364655, published in 3 Int‘l Rev. Acct.,
Banking & Fin. 19 (2011).
61
relationship between the Final Merger Consideration and fair value, undermining the
The sale process in this case had two phases: (i) a pre-signing phase and (ii) a
post-signing go-shop period. The Original Merger Consideration was the product of the
pre-signing phase, and the evidence established that it was below fair value. Three factors
contributed to this outcome: (i) the use of an LBO pricing model to determine the
Original Merger Consideration, which had the effect in this case of undervaluing the
Company, (ii) the compelling evidence of a significant valuation gap driven by the
market‘s short-term focus, and (iii) the lack of meaningful pre-signing competition.
The first factor that undermined the persuasiveness of the Original Merger
Consideration was the use of an LBO pricing model. Delaware case law recognizes that
the highest price a bidder is willing to pay is not the same as fair value. See, e.g.,
Appraisal of Orchard, 2012 WL 2923305, at *5. Although the Delaware Supreme Court
has recognized that ―[a] merger price resulting from arms-length negotiations . . . is a
very strong indication of fair value,‖ it has also cautioned that the merger price ―must be
accompanied by evidence tending to show that it represents the going concern value of
the company rather than just the value of the company to one specific buyer.‖ M.P.M.
Enters., 731 A.2d at 797. The fact that a board has extracted the most that a particular
buyer (or type of buyer) will pay does not mean that the result constitutes fair value.
62
In this case, the Committee only engaged during the pre-signing phase with
financial sponsors. When proposing an MBO, a financial sponsor determines whether and
how much to bid by using an LBO model, which solves for the range of prices that a
financial sponsor can pay while still achieving particular IRRs.24 What the sponsor is
willing to pay diverges from fair value because of (i) the financial sponsor‘s need to
achieve IRRs of 20% or more to satisfy its own investors and (ii) limits on the amount of
leverage that the company can support and the sponsor can use to finance the deal. 25
Although a DCF methodology and an LBO model use similar inputs, they solve for
different variables: ―[T]he DCF analysis solves for the present value of the firm, while
the LBO model solves for the internal rate of return.‖ Donald M. DePamphilis, Mergers,
Acquisitions, and Other Restructuring Activities 506 (7th ed. 2014). The Company
concedes that an LBO model is not ―oriented toward solving for enterprise value.‖ Dkt.
373 at 27. Sell-side financial advisors can use an LBO model to predict with a high
24
See Joshua Rosenbaum & Joshua Pearl, Investment Banking: Valuation,
Leveraged Buyouts, and Mergers & Acquisitions 195-96 (2009) (―[An LBO model] is
used . . . to determine an implied valuation range for a given target in a potential LBO
sale based on achieving acceptable returns. . . .‖).
25
Id. at 235-36 (―Traditionally, the valuation implied by LBO analysis is toward
the lower end of a comprehensive analysis when compared to other methodologies,
particularly precedent transactions and DCF analysis. This is largely due to the
constraints imposed by an LBO, including leverage capacity, credit market conditions,
and the sponsor‘s own IRR hurdles.‖)
63
degree of accuracy the range of offers that a target corporation can expect from financial
sponsors.26
The factual record in this case demonstrates that the price negotiations during the
pre-signing phase were driven by the financial sponsors‘ willingness to pay based on
their LBO pricing models, rather than the fair value of the Company. JPMorgan,
Goldman, and Evercore advised the Committee that the financial sponsors would
determine how much to pay by solving for their required IRRs using an LBO pricing
Committee that
―Multiple of cash invested (e.g. 2.0x) is also a key parameter, particularly for
larger transactions‖;
―IRR will be used as the primary means to determine the appropriate purchase
price by a sponsor. . . .‖
JX 137 at 19. JPMorgan did not anticipate competition from strategic bidders and told the
Committee that ―there was a low probability of strategic buyer interest in acquiring the
JPMorgan did not include the results of its LBO pricing model in the football field of
26
Rosenbaum & Pearl, supra, at 195-96 (―In an M&A sell-side advisory context,
the banker conducts LBO analysis to assess valuation from the perspective of a financial
sponsor. This provides the ability to set sale price expectations for the seller and guide
negotiations with buyers accordingly. . . .‖ (emphasis added)).
64
valuation observations, which was consistent with the fact that an LBO pricing model
Using the same set of projections for both a DCF analysis and an LBO analysis,
JPMorgan showed why a financial sponsor would not be willing to pay an amount
approaching the Company‘s going-concern value. Using the September Case and a DCF
analysis, JPMorgan valued the Company as a going concern at between $20 and $27 per
share. But using the same projected cash flows in an LBO model, JPMorgan projected
that a financial buyer‘s willingness to pay would max out at approximately $14.13 per
share, because at higher prices, the sponsor could not achieve a minimum return hurdle of
a 20% IRR over five years. That $14.13 figure also assumed the sponsor engaged in
achieve IRRs in the range of 20% to 25%, JPMorgan placed the likely range of prices at
of the Company.
Even if a financial sponsor was willing to accept a lower IRR such that it ―could
have‖ paid more for the Company, JPMorgan concluded that an MBO ―would not have
been possible for the company‖ at prices of $19 or more because it would require a level
of leverage ―that you could not get in the marketplace.‖ Rajkovic Dep. 106-07. The issue
JPMorgan‘s analysis showed, the very same projections generated lower prices when run
65
The factual record established that the financial sponsors behaved as the
Committee‘s advisors‘ predicted. When Silver Lake and KKR provided their initial
expressions of interest, they bid at the low end of what the LBO model suggested. Silver
Lake proposed an all-cash transaction valued at between $11.22 and $12.16 a share,
excluding shares held by Mr. Dell, and KKR proposed an all-cash transaction valued at
between $12.00 and $13.00 a share, excluding shares held by Mr. Dell and Southeastern.
The financial sponsors opened at levels that gave them room to negotiate, while staying
When advising the Committee about what to do next, JPMorgan recognized that
financial sponsors use similar LBO models. JPMorgan told the Committee in December
2012 that ―given comparable LP make-up and return hurdles,‖ it was ―unlikely to see any
material difference‖ between Silver Lake‘s offer and what other financial sponsors would
pay. JX 226 at 22. When Evercore joined the sell-side team in January, it came to similar
conclusions. At trial, JPMorgan‘s lead banker confirmed that LBO shops use essentially
the same model.27 In other words, the outcome of competition between financial sponsors
27
Tr. 751: (Rajkovic) (―Q. So among the big boys in private equity, and I know
you don‘t want to hear this, they basically have the same models, the same hurdle rates,
the same returns and, in fact, often the same clients. Correct? A. They come fairly close
unless - they come fairly close in most situations. Yes they do.‖); Tr. 749-50 (Rajkovic)
(―Q. And you guys have a lot of experience with LBOs there at JPMorgan. Right? A. We
do. Q. And you know what kind of IRRs these firms try to achieve. Right? A. We do. Q.
And you know the time frame at which they try to get out. Correct? A. We do. Q. And
you know the leverage that they try to put on, both their ability to get the amount of
leverage but also the amount of leverage they need to get certain returns. Correct? A.
Yes. Q. And you took all that into account, and you said based on the September 21 most
current management forecasts, with no inversions, that the implied maximum price to pay
66
primarily depends on their relative willingness to sacrifice potential IRR. It does not lead
to intrinsic value.
As the pre-signing process unfolded, Silver Lake continued to base its bids on its
LBO model. Durban agreed that Silver Lake determined what to bid using a model that
calculated the maximum price Silver Lake could pay and still hit its IRR target. Silver
Lake was ―not concerned at all . . . with the intrinsic value analysis of the business.‖
Durban Dep. 12. Silver Lake analyzed the Company‘s value only to ―understand how
[its] actual investment [would] perform.‖ Id. Silver Lake similarly did not form any view
about whether the market price of the Company‘s common stock reflected the
Mr. Dell did not focus on fair value either. He initially went along for the ride and
agreed to invest his capital alongside Silver Lake at whatever price it was willing to pay.
Tr. 465-467 (Mr. Dell). But when the Committee eventually insisted on $13.65 per share
and Silver Lake balked, Mr. Dell agreed to invest at a lower valuation of $13.36 to make
the higher price work for Silver Lake and preserve his control over the post-transaction
entity.
Even the Committee did not focus on fair value. In the proxy statement, the
directors disclosed that the ―Committee did not seek to determine a pre-merger going
would be $14.13 in an LBO. Right? . . . A. Yes. Correct. Q. Okay. And so you basically
told the board, ‗Look, in an LBO, don‘t expect anything that‘s going to come in above
that.‘ Right? A. We told them that using this model and with the assumptions around
leverage and return, that is what value the model would indicate . . . .‖); Rajkovic Dep.
108 (―Q. This isn‘t Michael Dell or Silver Lake[] specific? A. Just for anybody. . . .‖).
67
concern value for the Common Stock to determine the fairness of the merger
instead negotiated based on a variety of metrics, including what the LBO models
prepared by its financial advisors indicated was the most that Silver Lake would pay. As
a practical matter, the Committee negotiated without determining the value of its best
After Silver Lake raised its bid to $12.90 per share in January 2013, Evercore
calculated that if the Company performed consistent with the September Case, then at the
price it was offering, Silver Lake would achieve a 5-year IRR of 45% and generate a 5.3x
multiple on its invested capital, even if Silver Lake exited in five years at the same
transaction multiple. Mr. Dell would achieve a 5-year IRR of 50.1% and generate a 6.2x
multiple on his invested capital. Evercore calculated that if the Company performed
consistent with the BCG 25% Case, which the Committee believed was most likely, then
Silver Lake would achieve a 5-year IRR of 39.8% and generate a 4.5x multiple on its
invested capital. Mr. Dell would achieve a 5-year IRR of 44.7% and generate a 5.3x
multiple on his invested capital. After receiving this advice, the Committee advised the
Board that it would ―target a sale price of $13.75 per share, with $13.60 per share as the
minimum sale price for agreeing to a deal.‖ JX 315 at 2. Silver Lake eventually offered
This was not a case in which the Buyout Group intended to make changes in the
intended to achieve its returns simply by executing the Company‘s existing business
68
strategy and meeting its forecasted projections. Mr. Dell identified for the Committee the
strategies that he would pursue once the Company was private, and the record establishes
that all of them could have been accomplished in a public company setting. BCG
recognized and advised the Committee that the only benefits Mr. Dell could realize by
taking the Company private that were not otherwise available as a public company were
(i) accessing offshore cash with less tax leakage (to pay down the acquisition debt) and
(ii) arbitraging the value of the Company itself by buying low and selling high.28
Taken as a whole, the foregoing evidence, along with other evidence in the record,
establishes that the Original Merger Consideration was dictated by what a financial
sponsor could pay and still generate outsized returns. This fact is a strong indication that
28
JX 229 at 60. Academic scholarship suggests this is true of private equity deals
more broadly. See Steven N. Kaplan & Per Strömberg, Leveraged Buyouts and Private
Equity, 23 J. Econ. Perspectives 121, 122 (2009) (―[T]here is also evidence consistent
with private equity investors taking advantage of market timing (and market mispricing)
between debt and equity markets particularly in the public-to-private transactions of the
last 15 years.‖); id. at 136 (―[P]rivate equity firms pay lower premiums than public
company buyers in cash acquisitions. These findings are consistent with private equity
firms identifying companies or industries that turn out to be undervalued. Alternatively,
this could indicate that private equity firms are particularly good negotiators, and/or that
target boards and management do not get the best possible price in these acquisitions.‖);
id. at 135-36 (―[P]ost-1980s public-to-private transactions experience only modest
increases in firm operating performance, but still generate large financial returns to
private equity funds. This finding suggests that private equity firms are able to buy low
and sell high.‖).
69
ii. The Valuation Gap
Consideration as evidence of fair value was the widespread and compelling evidence of a
valuation gap between the market‘s perception and the Company‘s operative reality. The
gap was driven by (i) analysts‘ focus on short-term, quarter-by-quarter results and (ii) the
Company‘s nearly $14 billion investment in its transformation, which had not yet begun
to generate the anticipated results. A transaction which eliminates stockholders may take
the Company‘s prospects (a so-called anti-bubble). Indeed, the optimal time to take a
company private is after it has made significant long-term investments, but before those
investments have started to pay off and market participants have begun to incorporate
those benefits into the price of the Company‘s stock.29 In Glassman v. Unocal
29
See Cain & Davidoff, supra, at 862 (―There is a more concrete argument against
MBOs on fairness grounds. It is the prospect that management is utilizing inside
information when it arranges an MBO. Management by its inherent position has in its
possession non-public knowledge of the corporation, and management can use this
informational asymmetry between itself and public shareholders to time the buy-out
process. MBOs can thus be arranged at advantageous times in the business cycle or
history of the corporation.‖ (footnotes omitted)); Marcel Canoy, Yohanes E. Riyanto &
Patrick van Cayseele, Corporate Takeovers, Bargaining and Managers’ Incentives to
Invest, 21 Managerial & Decision Econs. 1, 2, 14 (2000) (―Long-term investments, such
as R&D investments, are slow yielding and more difficult to be evaluated by the market,
despite the fact that they could generate higher profits. Consequently, firms investing
heavily in long-term projects may be more susceptible to a takeover attempt. . . . If being
taken over is better than taking over [for target management] . . . then obviously,
[management] would like to overinvest to facilitate a takeover . . . .‖); Deborah A.
DeMott, Directors’ Duties in Management Buyouts and Leveraged Recapitalizations, 49
Ohio St. L.J. 517, 536 (1988) (explaining that overhang from past acquisitions may
artificially depress a company‘s stock market price and make the buyout price appear
70
Exploration Corp., 777 A.2d 242 (Del. 2001), the Delaware Supreme Court
acknowledged that an appraisal proceeding can and should address the problem of
opportunistic timing:
Id. at 248; cf. Del. Open MRI Radiology Assocs., P.A. v. Kessler, 898 A.2d 290, 314-15
(Del. Ch. 2006) (Strine, V.C.) (―Obviously, when a business has opened a couple of
facilities and has plans to replicate those facilities as of the merger date, the value of its
expansion plans must be considered in determining fair value. To hold otherwise would
generous); Repetti, supra, at 125 (―Other methods for management to realize large gains
in management buyouts are not as innocuous as the use of leverage or as apparently
innocuous as increasing cash flow. Management may actively depress the price of the
shares prior to the management buyout in order to reduce the price they have to pay.
Management may accomplish this by . . . channeling investments into long-term projects
which will not provide short-term returns.‖); James Vorenberg, Exclusiveness of the
Dissenting Stockholder’s Appraisal Right, 77 Harv. L. Rev. 1189, 1202-03 (1964) (―Far
more difficult is ensuring to departing stockholders the benefit of improved prospects,
where, at the time of appraisal, the evidence of improvement is more intuitive than
tangible. . . . The appraisal process will tend to produce conservative results where the
values are speculative, and the majority‘s power to pick the time at which to trigger
appraisal may encourage them to move when full values may be temporarily obscured.‖
(footnote omitted)); see also Benjamin Hermalin & Alan Schwartz, Buyouts in Large
Companies, 25 J. Legal Stud. 351, 356 (1996) (―With respect to timing, the firm could
initiate a freeze-out (i) before it invests effort, (ii) after it invests effort but before the
value of the firm conditional on effort is revealed, or (iii) after the value of the firm is
revealed but before earnings are realized. We generally assume that the firm would wait
until point iii because waiting in the model is costless but produces gains: were the firm
to initiate a freeze-out before it learns its value, it might have to pay too much.‖).
71
be to subject our appraisal jurisprudence to just ridicule. The dangers for the minority
arguably are most present when the controller knows that the firm is on the verge of
break-through growth, having gotten the hang of running the first few facilities, and now
or Starbucks.‖).
Proposing an MBO when the stock price is low has the further effect of using the
depressed stock price to anchor price negotiations.30 Empirical evidence confirms the
experiential insight that both targets and acquirers use the market price of the target‘s
30
David A. Lax & James K. Sebenius, 3-D Negotiation: Powerful Tools to
Change in Your Most Important Deals 189 (2006) (―[I]n [the] auction setting, higher
anchors—in the form of minimum bid prices—tend to increase the valuation bidders
place on the objection being auctioned.‖); G. Richard Shell, Bargaining For Advantage
159 (1999) (explaining that the ―anchor and adjustment effect . . . refers to a human
tendency to be affected by ‗first impression‘ numbers thrown into our field of vision
[and] [w]e tend to make adjustments from these often arbitrary reference points‖); Guhan
Subramanian, Negotiauctions 16-18 (2010) (explaining that anchoring ―works by
influencing your perceptions of where the [zone of possible agreement] lies‖).
31
Malcom Baker, Xin Pan, & Jeffery Wurgler, The Effect of Reference Point
Prices on Mergers and Acquisitions, 106 J. Fin. Econ. 49, 50 (2012) (finding the ―26-
week high price [of a particular stock] has a statistically and economically significant
effect on offer prices [in mergers and acquisitions], and the 39-, 52-, and 65-week high
prices also have independent explanatory power‖ and speculating as to the causes of this
reference point effect); id. at 64-65 (finding that deals with higher premiums tend to close
more often, which is ―consistent with reference point behavior.‖); Inga Chira & Jeff
Madura, Reference Point Theory and Pursuit of Deals, 50 Fin. Rev. 275, 277, 299 (2015)
(―Our analysis reveals that a higher target 52-week reference point, relative to the target‘s
current stock price, . . . increases the likelihood of a management buyout (MBO). . . .
Overall, the results from our analyses offer strong evidence that target and bidder
reference points serve as potent anchors that shape the outcomes and structures of
mergers.‖); Sangwon Lee & Vijay Yerramilli, Relative Values, Announcement Timing,
72
market price starts a sale process, the anchoring effect makes the process intuitively more
likely to generate an undervalued bid. Market myopia can accentuate this problem.32
Investors focused on short-term, quarterly results can excessively discount the value of
long-term investments.33
The record at trial demonstrated that a significant valuation gap, investor myopia,
and anchoring were all present in this case. Mr. Dell identified the opportunity to take the
Company private after the stock market failed to reflect the Company‘s going concern
value over a prolonged period. He managed the Company for the long-term and
understood that his strategic decisions would drive the stock price down in the short-term.
73
The Company‘s management team recognized the valuation gap as early as January
2011, when they prepared a sum-of-the-parts analysis that valued the company at
between $22.49 and $27.05 per share and its stock was trading around $14 per share. The
Committee‘s advisors reached a similar conclusion. In October 2012, Dell‘s stock was
trading between $9 and $10 per share, yet JPMorgan generated multiple valuation
methodologies that implied a fundamental valuation exceeding that price, and its DCF
analysis valued the Company at between $20 and $27 per share. Goldman
result in [Dell] value outcomes that are significantly higher than the current share price.‖
JX 170 at 4-6. BCG made the same observation, commenting that the Company‘s ―low
valuation does not match apparent company strengths and reflects investor concerns.‖ JX
It bears emphasizing that unlike other situations that this court has confronted, 34
there is no evidence that Mr. Dell or his management team sought to create the valuation
34
See, e.g., In re Dole Food Co., Inc. S’holder Litig., 2015 WL 5052214, at *27
(Del. Ch. Aug. 27, 2015) (finding that defendant fiduciaries engaged in ―a calculated
effort to depress the market price‖ as part of a plan to take the company private
(quotation marks omitted)); In re Emerging Commc’ns, Inc. S’holders Litig., 2004 WL
1305745, at *32 (Del. Ch. May 3, 2004) (―Because ECM‘s stock price was depressed,
Prosser abandoned that proposal at the eleventh hour and ‗flipped‘ the deal for his sole
personal benefit to take advantage of the temporarily and artificially depressed stock
price. That stock price then became the ‗floor‘ for the equally depressed and unfair
Privatization price . . . .‖); Sealy Mattress Co. of N.J. v. Sealy, Inc., 532 A.2d 1324, 1336
(Del. Ch. 1987) (finding the defendants engaged in a ―calculated effort to depress the
price of Sealy until the minority stockholders were eliminated by merger or some other
form of acquisition‖ and that ―[s]uch behavior by a majority stockholder constitutes
unfair dealing‖).
74
disconnect so that they could take advantage of it. To the contrary, they tried to convince
the market that the Company was worth more. Only when the gap persisted despite their
efforts, and after both Southeastern and Silver Lake suggested the possibility of an MBO
to Mr. Dell, did he eventually decide to pursue the opportunity that the market price was
presenting.
As Mr. Dell and the Committee‘s advisors recognized, the valuation gap existed
because Dell‘s stockholders were focused on the short-term. Mr. Dell made clear that he
was investing in the Company for the long-term. The Company spent nearly $14 billion
in acquisitions in the three years preceding the Merger as part of Mr. Dell‘s
transformation strategy. Mr. Dell told the Board that to ―[e]xpect [the] short term to be
very challenging‖ and that the transformation strategy would require ―sacrific[ing] short
term results.‖ JX 96 at 2. He also believed the plan was working and would fuel long-
term growth. Mr. Dell made the same points publicly. In May 2013, he explained at an
[i]n recent years, Dell has emerged as a new company. We have our
strongest-ever product and services portfolio, and have acquired significant
new skills and capabilities, reorganized our operations, optimized our
global supply chain and put in place a world-class management team. . . .
Today‘s Dell is a customer-inspired end-to-end solutions provider. One that
has evolved from a PC manufacturer to a true IT solutions partner – one
that offers a differentiated view of the enterprise.
JX 530 at 6. In September 2012, management again stressed that it was pursuing ―a long-
term strategy [that] will take time.‖ JX 109 at 7. Mr. Dell stated: ―We‘re transforming our
business, not for a quarter or a fiscal year, but to deliver differentiated customer value for
75
The Committee‘s advisors recognized the disconnect. In one presentation,
JPMorgan noted that ―[m]issed Street expectations have put investors in a ‗wait and see
137 at 7. In another, JPMorgan observed that ―[l]imited visibility and missed Street
226 at 5. Goldman cited a series of reasons for the disconnect, including that
– Investors are often reluctant to fight strong ―secular headwinds‖ even when
values become attractive in absolute and relative terms; as a result,
valuations can remain depressed for protracted periods.
JX 170 at 6. BCG similarly observed that the Company‘s low valuation reflected
During the sale process, despite the Company‘s depressed and erratic stock price,
the Committee and its advisors used the Company‘s market price as a key input. In fact,
trading price was the only quantitative metric the Committee cited in the Company‘s
proxy statements when explaining its recommendation that stockholders approve the
Merger. The Committee noted that it had not considered net book value, comparable
transactions, or ―a pre-merger going concern value‖ because it believed ―that the trading
price of the Common Stock at any given time represents the best available indicator of
the Company‘s going concern value at that time.‖ JX 532 at 71 (emphasis added).
76
Accordingly, the proxy statement cited only metrics based on the trading price, including
(i) the approximately 44% premium over the one-day trading price of $9.64 per share on
November 11, 2012, they day before an analyst report first suggested that the Company
might be a target for an LBO, (ii) the approximately 28% premium over the unaffected
one-day trading price of $10.88 per share on January 11, 2013, the last trading day before
media outlets leaked news of the Merger, and (iii) the approximately 39% premium over
the average trading price of $9.97 per share during the ninety days preceding January 11.
The Committee also cited the ―the current and historical market prices of the Common
Stock, including the market performance of the Common Stock relative to the common
stock of other participants in the industries in which the Company operates and general
market indices‖ as proof of the Final Merger Consideration‘s fairness. JX 654 at 57.
In the proxy statement, the Committee also cited its financial advisors‘ opinions.
The summary of JPMorgan‘s work identified two DCF valuations: one derived from the
BCG Base Case, which valued the Company at between $11.25 and $15.00 per share, and
one derived from the BCG 25% Case, which valued the Company at between $13.00 and
But JPMorgan provided significantly more data for its market-based approaches,
which included the Company‘s 52-week trading range, enterprise value as a function of
the Company‘s EBITDA multiple using four sets of projections, and enterprise value as a
function of the Company‘s earnings multiple using four sets of projections. JPMorgan
also compared the premium over market to similar premiums offered in other large
LBOs. Evercore relied almost entirely on the ―non-DCF elements of [its] analysis,‖
77
which were primarily market-based. Tr. 408 (Hiltz). They included the Company‘s 52-
week trading range, analyst twelve-month price targets, the present value of the
Company‘s future stock price, and comparisons of the Merger‘s premium over market to
Taken as a whole, the foregoing evidence, along with other evidence in the record,
establishes the existence of a significant valuation gap between the market price of the
Company‘s common stock and the intrinsic value of the Company. The anti-bubble both
facilitated the MBO and undermined the reliability of the market price as a measure of
the Company‘s value. In reaching this finding, I recognize that ―[t]here is virtually no
CEO in America who does not believe that the market is not valuing her company
properly.‖ Chesapeake Corp. v. Shore, 771 A.2d 293, 327 (Del. Ch. 2000) (Strine, V.C.).
In this case, however, the evidence of a significant valuation gap was both extensive and
compelling.
Consideration as evidence of fair value was the lack of meaningful price competition
during the pre-signing phase. Go-shops in MBO transactions rarely produce topping
bids,35 so the bulk of any price competition occurs before the deal is signed. 36 The
35
Tr. 366 (Hiltz) (―[T]he mathematical chances of producing a higher bid [were]
low based on the history of go-shops‖); JX 301 at 19 (Evercore advising the Committee
that ―[s]ince 2005, there have been 137 transactions with equity values greater than $100
million with go-shop provisions‖ and that of those transactions, ―only 16 or 12% resulted
in a superior offer‖); see Guhan Subramanian, Go-Shops vs. No-Shops in Private Equity:
78
competition does not have to be direct and overt; and the prospect of post-signing
Deals Evidence & Implications, 63 Bus. Law. 729, 750-51 (2008) [hereinafter Go-Shops
vs. No-Shops] (finding that there is ―no post-signing competition in go-shop MBOs
during my sample period, consistent with practitioner wisdom that MBOs give incumbent
managers a significant advantage over other potential buyers‖); Brian JM Quinn,
Omnicare: Coercion and the New Unocal Standard, 38 J. Corp. L. 835, 844 (2013)
[hereinafter New Unocal Standard] (―A more pessimistic interpretation of the widespread
adoption of go-shop provisions is that go-shop provisions are not truly effective at
generating post-signing competition and that buyers understand as much.‖); J. Russel
Denton, Note, Stacked Deck: Go-Shops and Auction Theory, 60 Stan. L. Rev. 1529, 1549
(2008) (―[A]uction theory does suggest that target boards of directors should push for
conducting a true pre-signing auction rather than quickly signing a deal containing a go-
shop granting the initial buyer information rights, a termination fee, expense
reimbursement, and matching rights. This is especially true for companies that are selling
themselves to financial buyers, since go-shops have structures that discourage bidding
wars between financial buyers.‖); see also Steven Davidoff Solomon, Flawed Bidding
Process Leaves Dell at a Loss, N.Y. Times (Apr. 23, 2013) at 2 (citing FactSet
MergerMetrics showing that ―[s]ince 2004, there have been 196 transactions with go-
shops . . . . [i]n only 6.6 percent of these did another bidder compete during the go-shop
period‖).
In his expert report for this case, Subramanian updated his empirical study from
2008. The original study identified six go-shops for MBOs, and found that none led to a
superior offer. Go-Shops vs. No-Shops, supra, at 750. Since then, there have been two
MBOs with go-shops. Both produced superior bids. See JX 909 ¶¶ 66-67. Subramanian
distinguished both cases, noting that management was not key in either situation, and
stood by his opinion that go-shops are generally ineffective in MBOs.
36
See Del Monte, 25 A.3d at 840 n.5 (noting ―the importance of the pre-signing
phase to developing price competition among private equity bidders‖). Renowned M&A
practitioner Marty Lipton has contrasted the effects of adding another interested party at
the front end of a deal negotiation with the effect of bargaining more vigorously with a
single counterparty at the back end of the process. Lipton even roughly quantified the
added value of adding a competing negotiator relative to greater negotiating skill in the
initial two-party deal: ―The ability to bring somebody into a situation is far more
important than the extra dollar a share at the back end. At the front end, you‘re probably
talking about 50%. At the back end, you‘re talking about 1 or 2 percent.‖ Guhan
Subramanian, The Drivers of Market Efficiency in Revlon Transactions, 28 J. Corp. L.
691, 691 (2003) (quoting Author‘s Interview with Martin Lipton, Senior Partner,
Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, in New York, NY (June 14, 2000)).
79
competition can help raise the prices offered during the pre-signing phase.37 But the
shadow of competition is more spectral and less efficacious than its reality: ―Whether it
should be so or not, human beings often value things—even other human beings like
below, the similarities among financial bidders make them particularly susceptible to the
winner‘s curse during a go-shop phase. See infra Part II.A.3.b.ii.b. There is also the
―reality that there is not a culture of rampant topping among the larger private equity
37
Go-Shops vs. No-Shops, supra, at 753 (arguing from sample transactions that
because of the prospect of post-signing competition, pure go-shop transactions result in
higher sales prices than single-bidder negotiations); see New Unocal Standard, supra, at
844 (―Knowing that a transaction will include a go-shop, wherein the seller will treat the
initial bidder as a stalking horse to generate an active post-signing auction, may incent
initial bidders to offer a preemptive bid to deter subsequent bids. In that view, the
prospect of competition, even if no competition subsequently emerges, should be
sufficient incentive for a bidder to shift transaction surplus to the seller.‖); Brian JM
Quinn, Bulletproof: Mandatory Rules for Deal Protection, 32 J. Corp. L. 865, 879-80
(2007) [hereinafter Bulletproof] (surveying literature on auction theory and concluding
that ―[t]he two key insights are that competition, or the threat of competition, will lead to
a price closer to the buyer‘s reservation price and that the price effect of one additional
competitor is greater than the price effects attributable to bargaining‖).
38
Dollar Thrifty, 14 A.3d at 615. See Nihat Aktas et al., Negotiations Under the
Threat of Auction, 98 J. Fin. Econ. 241, 242 (2010) (―Our empirical results confirm the
existence of latent competition on acquirers‘ bidding in one-on-one negotiations: More
potential competitors are associated with higher bids.‖); John C. Easterwood et al.,
Controlling the Conflict of Interest in Management Buyouts, 76 Rev. Econ. & Stat. 512,
513 (1994) (recognizing that ―[b]oth actual and potential competing offers could limit the
ability of managers to underbid‖ in MBOs); id. at 515 (analyzing sample of transactions
and finding that ―implicit outside competition is not associated with higher abnormal
returns compared to the returns experienced by stockholders of [MBOs] involving no
competition whatsoever‖); id. at 520 (concluding that ―explicit competition from outside
bidders is more effective than implicit competition‖).
80
players, who have relationships with each other that might inhibit such behavior.‖ 39 The
price established during the pre-signing phase is therefore critical, and it is the presence
or realistic threat of competition during this period that drives up the price. 40
39
In re Lear Corp. S’holder Litig., 926 A.2d 94, 121 (Del. Ch. 2007) (Strine,
V.C.). Consistent with the professional culture of not topping other firms‘ deals, Silver
Lake, KKR, Blackstone, and TPG were among the sponsors who settled a lawsuit
alleging they and other private equity firms conspired to fix prices in LBOs. See Henry
Sender, KKR, Blackstone and TPG Pay $325m to Settle Collusion Lawsuit, Fin. Times
(Aug. 7, 2014), http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/0cee0c66-1e3e-11e4-bb68-
00144feabdc0.html. Evidence from the suit included an email from the co-head of US
buyouts at Carlyle, who allegedly wrote ―KKR asked the industry to step down on HCA
[Holdings Inc.]!‖ Id. KKR later withdrew and allegedly told Blackstone it was ―standing
down because [it] would not jump a signed deal of [Blackstone‘s].‖ Id. Blackstone
allegedly responded that ―[t]ogether, we can be unstoppable, but in opposition, we can
cost each other a lot of money.‖ Id.
Andrew Ross Sorkin of the New York Times made a similar point about
Blackstone‘s involvement in the Company‘s go-shop, which Mandl described as ―a pretty
thoughtful commentary.‖ JX 448 at 1. Sorkin wrote,
The real question is why, despite the $25 million reimbursement guarantee,
Blackstone is risking its reputation to even contemplate a deal for Dell.
JX 446 at 3 (Andrew Ross Sorkin, A $25 Million Question Over A Bid For Dell, N.Y.
Times (Apr. 1, 2013)).
40
See Aktas et al., supra, at 242; Jeremy Bulow & Paul Klemperer, Why Do
Sellers (Usually) Prefer Auctions?, 99 Am. Econ. Rev. 1544, 1568 (2009).
81
In this case, the record established that there was minimal competition during the
pre-signing phase. The Committee initially engaged with only two financial sponsors,
and KKR dropped out after providing its initial expression of interest. At that point, the
Committee brought in TPG, but that firm dropped out as well. It is certainly true, as the
Company argues, that the decisions that KKR and TPG made can be viewed as indicating
that the Company was risky and difficult to value, but it also left the Committee
negotiating with a single bidder. The Committee did not engage with Blackstone before
signing, even though Blackstone approached the Company in January about a possible
transaction.
During the pre-signing phase, the Committee did not contact any strategic buyers.
HP was the obvious choice, and Evercore would later estimate that a deal between the
Company and HP could generate between $3 and 4 billion in annual cost savings.
Evercore doubted whether any other strategic bidders could acquire the Company given
its size, and JPMorgan doubted that any strategic bidders would be interested. A direct,
pre-signing outreach to HP therefore might well have been warranted. The Committee
chose not to contact HP. The lack of any outreach to strategic bidders and the assessment
that strategic interest was unlikely meant that the financial sponsors did not have to push
powerful tool that a seller can use to extract a portion of the bidder‘s anticipated surplus.
The Committee had the ability to say no, and it could demand a higher price, but it could
not invoke the threat of an alternative deal. When the Committee made its final demand,
82
Silver Lake stood firm. It was Mr. Dell who bridged the gap by accepting a lower
valuation for his rollover shares. Although he sacrificed some value by doing so,
Evercore‘s analysis indicates that it was a good decision, and that he stands to enjoy
Taken as a whole, the foregoing evidence, along with other evidence in the record,
establishes that there was a lack of meaningful price competition during the pre-signing
phase. This factor undermined the reliability of the Original Merger Consideration as a
measure of the Company‘s value, and because the offers received in the go-shop period
keyed off the Original Merger Consideration, this factor also undermines the reliability of
Although the evidence proved that the Original Merger Consideration was not the
best evidence of fair value, the sale process did not stop there. The process entered a
second phase, during which Evercore conducted a go-shop. Two higher bids emerged,
one from Blackstone and another from Icahn. Blackstone eventually withdrew its bid, but
Icahn continued to compete. When it appeared that stockholders would vote down the
original deal, the Committee and the Buyout Group amended the Merger Agreement. The
counterintuitive and illogical—to the point of being incredible—to think that another
83
party would not have topped Mr. Dell and Silver Lake if the Company was actually worth
more. In my view, this argument has force for large valuation gaps, and is sufficiently
persuasive to negate the valuation of $28.61 per share that the petitioners advanced. If the
Company was really worth more than double what the Buyout Group was paying, then a
strategic bidder like HP would have recognized a compelling opportunity and intervened.
But the go-shop process was not sufficiently persuasive to rule out smaller
valuation gaps. Financial sponsors—the only parties who showed interest in this case—
faced the same leverage constraints and IRR hurdles as the Buyout Group, and the record
demonstrated that a buyer using a leverage-based model would not bid high enough to
generate fair value. The fact that two competing financial sponsors proposed higher-
valued, debt-fueled alternatives indicates that the Original Merger Consideration was
low, even when evaluated from the standpoint of the returns that a leverage-based model
could generate. The topping bids also exceeded the Final Merger Consideration. They not
only help confirm that the Original Merger Consideration did not provide fair value, but
they also undercut the notion that the Final Merger Consideration provided fair value.
Although the go-shop phase in this case did increase the amount of consideration
that the Company‘s stockholders received, that fact did not establish that the stockholders
received fair value either. In this case, it demonstrated only that the stockholders received
an amount closer to the highest price that a bidder whose valuation was derived from and
84
i. The Results of the Go-Shop
The actual results of the go-shop process provide a starting place for analysis. To
the good, it did generate two higher indications of interest for the whole Company.
Blackstone, one of the world‘s largest and most sophisticated financial institutions,
proposed to acquire the Company in a transaction that would give the Company‘s
existing stockholders a choice between a cash payment of at least $14.25 per share or
shares in a new entity valued at $14.25 per share, subject to a cap on the total amount of
equity that the new entity would issue. Icahn, also a financially strong and highly
receive a combination of cash and stock, subject to a cap on the amount of cash. Evercore
valued Icahn‘s proposal at between $13.37 and $14.42 per share. Both transactions
the Company‘s financing arm to help pay down the acquisition debt.
As previously discussed, MBO go-shops rarely generate topping bids. Given that
fact, for two higher bids to have emerged suggests that the Original Merger Consideration
was relatively low. That conclusion is consistent with the evidence and the analysis of the
pre-signing process conducted above. The fact that two higher bids emerged from
financial sponsors suggests that the Original Merger Consideration was sufficiently low
Both Blackstone and Icahn were financial sponsors, and both were proposing leveraged
transactions. Each planned to lever up a still-public company, return the resulting cash to
85
the public stockholders, and keep a public stub outstanding, but the underlying financial
engineering paralleled what the Buyout Group was proposing. Both topping bidders were
therefore constrained by the LBO model, both in terms of limits on the availability of
leverage and the pricing necessary to generate the required IRRs over the anticipated
investment period. The fact that they emerged indicates that the Original Merger
Consideration was low not only when judged against a fair value metric, but also when
In this case, therefore, one evidentiary implication of the results of the go-shop is
to reinforce the conclusion that the Original Merger Consideration did not equate to fair
value. It has similar evidentiary implications for the Final Merger Consideration.
Although Blackstone later withdrew its bid, Icahn continued to advance its proposal.
When it appeared that stockholders would vote down the Merger if all the Buyout Group
offered was the Original Merger Consideration, the Buyout Group increased its price.
The question then becomes whether the increase was sufficient to establish the Final
Merger Consideration as fair value. This decision finds that the answer is ―no.‖
have induced the Buyout Group to increase its bid within the confines of the LBO model,
but it did not lead to competition at a level indicative of fair value. When it appeared that
stockholders would vote down the deal, the Buyout Group increased its offer by 23 cents,
with an increase within the confines of the LBO model. Notably, both Blackstone‘s
proposal and the upper range of Icahn‘s proposal exceeded the Final Merger
86
Consideration as well. The fact that the holders of just over half of the unaffiliated shares
outstanding took the price does not mean it is equivalent to fair value. ―[C]ertain
for quarterly reporting purposes, or to offset other losses, even if that gain is not
process.‖ Glob. GT LP v. Golden Telecom, Inc. (Golden Telecom I), 993 A.2d 497, 508-
09 (Del. Ch. 2010) (Strine, V.C.), aff’d, 11 A.3d 214 (Del. 2010).
The 2% increase that the Buyout Group offered to secure a favorable vote was all
that the go-shop process achieved. Given the evidence that the pre-signing phase did not
generate a price that was equivalent to fair value, and in light of the nature of the
competition that took place during the go-shop phase, the 2% bump was not sufficient to
prove that the Final Merger Consideration was the best evidence of fair value.
Subramanian gave persuasive testimony about various factors that generally limit the
efficacy of MBO go-shops, and he explained why those factors were present to a
significant degree in this case. Notably, the framework for analyzing the go-shop is not
the standard that would apply in a fiduciary duty case, viz. whether the go-shop was
preclusive or whether the decision to include the structure fell within the range of
reasonableness. In other words, the operative question is not answered by showing that a
particularly strong and determined bidder could overcome the structural and functional
87
disincentives and make a topping bid, meaning that that the go-shop was not preclusive,
nor by explaining why a transaction that included a go-shop was a proportionate means of
pursuing the best transaction reasonably available for the stockholders, regardless of
whether or not it actually succeeded, meaning that the go-shop fell within the range of
reasonableness. The question for appraisal is whether the Company showed that the
structure in fact generated a price that persuasively established the Company‘s fair value.
the standpoint of fiduciary duty analysis, can function inadequately for purposes of price
leaving money on the table by allowing the initial bidder to secure an asset at a beneficial
price.
At the heart of Subramanian‘s analysis is the recognition that before making a bid,
[I]n this chess game of M&A, most of these parties being very
sophisticated, don‘t just think incrementally one step ahead. They‘re
thinking two, three, four, five moves ahead. Any third party looking at this
would say, ―What is my pathway to success?‖ So even if you value this
thing at a very high number, you might reasonably say there‘s no pathway
to success and, therefore, I‘m not going to start on this process because
there‘s no finish line.
Tr. 811 (Subramanian). The pathway to success must be sufficiently realistic to warrant
incurring the time and expense to become involved in a contested situation, as well as the
88
a) Structural Issues
pathway to success. In a presentation in January 2013, Evercore gave the Committee the
―A longer go-shop period increases the amount of time that potential third parties
have to evaluate a possible transaction.‖
―A lower termination fee in effect during the go-shop period reduces the value
leakage to shareholders.‖
With the benefit of advice from Evercore, the Committee negotiated a go-shop
that raised fewer structural barriers than the norm. One critical issue is the length of the
go-shop period, which defines the amount of time that a bidder has to understand the
target company and decide whether to proceed. The issue is more complex than simply
counting the number of days that the go-shop provides. An equally important factor is
what a bidder must do before the end of the go-shop period to be defined as an ―Excluded
Party,‖ which is the status that allows the bidder to continue negotiating with the target
89
after the go-shop time period runs out and still receive the benefit of a lower termination
fee. More flexible go-shops only require an acquirer to provide a non-binding indication
of interest in a transaction that could lead to a Superior Proposal, and they define the
concept of ―Superior Proposal‖ broadly. More restrictive go-shops demand more, such as
a bona fide offer that qualifies as a Superior Proposal, a fully financed bid, or even a fully
negotiated merger agreement. A nominally shorter go-shop that requires less to qualify as
an Excluded Party may be more open as a practical matter than a nominally longer go-
shop that imposes tougher criteria for Excluded Party status. The sufficiency of the
amount of time also varies with the size and complexity of the target. A deal involving a
bigger and more complex target requires more diligence, is more difficult to finance, and
may require the bidder to assemble a consortium, which takes additional time.
In this case, the structure of the go-shop was relatively open. The length of the go-
shop period was forty-five days, which Subramanian testified was ―about average‖ for
the sample deals he studied. Tr. 786 (Subramanian). The steps required to become an
―Excluded Party‖ were also relatively few: A bidder only needed to submit a letter with a
general outline of the structure of a transaction sufficient for the Committee to conclude
§ 5.3(i). A party who satisfied that standard would achieve Excluded Party status and
could continue to negotiate with the Committee, theoretically until stockholders approved
the deal. In this case, an Excluded Party at the end of the forty-five day go-shop period
would have had another four months before the special meeting, originally scheduled for
July 18.
90
Other structural features of the go-shop were also relatively flexible. The
termination fee during the go-shop period for an Excluded Party was $180 million,
representing approximately 1% of equity value of the original deal and 40% of the $450
termination fee that otherwise would apply. An Evercore banker testified that usually the
lowered termination fee is half of the base termination fee, so the Merger Agreement was
a little better on that score. More importantly, the Merger Agreement only contemplated a
single opportunity for the Buyout Group to match a higher bid, after which the match
right in the Merger Agreement expired. The one-time match is more favorable to a
topping bidder than an unlimited match right, which is a powerful disincentive. 41 At the
41
A matching right is the functional equivalent of a right of first refusal, and
scholars have analyzed them as such. See Bulletproof, supra, at 870 (―The presence of
rights of first refusal can be a strong deterrent against subsequent bids and is therefore a
potentially potent protective measure in the non-Revlon context. . . . Success under these
circumstances may involve paying too much and suffering the ‗winner‘s curse.‘‖); see
also Frank Aquila & Melissa Sawyer, Diary Of A Wary Market: 2010 In Review And
What To Expect In 2011, 14 M & A Law. Nov.-Dec. 2010, at 1 (―Match rights can result
in the first bidder ‗nickel bidding‘ to match an interloper‘s offer, with repetitive rounds of
incremental increases in the offer price. Targets and buyers are starting to question
whether this dynamic produces the best results. One alternative would be for the initial
bidder to make a sizeable topping bid instead of a matching bid, but demand a higher
break fee as the quid pro quo. if [sic] the bidder, as part of that package, announces that it
is making its ‗best and final bid,‘ then the target may conclude there is no justification for
granting continuing match rights as part of the package. In addition, targets are starting to
question whether it makes sense for initial bidders to have match rights when the merger
agreement contains an explicit go-shop. Few go-shops are successful as it is . . . and
match rights are just one more factor that may dissuade a potential competing bidder
from stepping in the middle of an already-announced transaction.‖); Marcel Kahan &
Rangarajan K. Sundaram, First-Purchase Rights: Rights of First Refusal and Rights of
First Offer, 14 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 331, 331 (2012) (finding ―that a right of first refusal
transfers value from other buyers to the right-holder, but may also force the seller to
make suboptimal offers‖); David I. Walker, Rethinking Rights of First Refusal, 5 Stan.
J.L. Bus. & Fin. 1, 20-21 (1999) (discussing how a right of first refusal affects bidders);
91
same time, it presents more of a hurdle than simple information rights. See Go-Shops vs.
The main structural problem that Subramanian identified did not result from the
terms of the go-shop in the abstract, but rather stemmed from the size and complexity of
the Company. The Merger was twenty-five times larger than any transaction in
Subramanian‘s sample of ―jumped‖ deals, meaning that a successful topping bid literally
would have been unprecedented. The extent of Blackstone‘s efforts gives a sense of what
was required. To get to Excluded Party status, Blackstone had to spend in excess of $25
million and assemble a due diligence team that filled a ballroom, and Blackstone is one of
the world‘s most sophisticated private equity firms. Blackstone also retained Dell‘s
cf. Steven J. Brams & Joshua R. Mitts, Mechanism Design in M&A Auctions, 38 Del. J.
Corp. L. 873, 879 (2014) (―The potential for a bidding war remains unless interlopers are
restricted-say, to one topping bid, which then can be matched.‖). Unlimited matching
rights have a particularly strong deterrent effect on financial sponsors. Brian JM Quinn,
Re-Evaluating the Emerging Standard of Review for Matching Rights in Control
Transactions, 36 Del. J. Corp. L. 1011, 1027-28 (2011) (―[T]he presence of a matching
right in the hands of an initial common value bidder will deter other common value
bidders from making bids. Financial buyers have a well-known aversion for engaging in
bidding contests. Consequently, it appears that the threat of the winner‘s curse is at least
implicitly understood by market participants. Finally, the direct effect of the matching
rights in the context of a common value auction is to appropriate transaction gains from
the seller to the right-holder. Because other market participants are hesitant to offer
topping bids in the common value context, this permits the right-holder to offer low-ball
bids and thereby extract transaction surplus at the expense of selling shareholders. . . .
The common value bidder is able to create private value by offering a bid lower than its
full valuation of the seller.‖ (footnotes omitted)). Evercore advised the Committee that
―[m]atching rights, unless limited, serve to discourage bidders and should be avoided.‖
JX 266 at 35.
92
former head of M&A and strategy, Dave Johnson, to lead its acquisition team and had the
At bottom, the evidence in this case shows that it was possible to achieve
Excluded Party status. Blackstone, Icahn, and GE Capital all provided initial expressions
of interest within the forty-five day go-shop period. But that does not mean that the
magnitude of the task did not have a chilling effect on other parties. The size and
complexity of the Company remains a factor for purposes of analyzing the go-shop.
management has the best insight into the Company‘s value, or at least is perceived to
have an informational advantage. Competing bidders therefore face threat of the winner‘s
curse:
As a third party, the implication is if you bid and you win, you‘ve just
learned that you think this company is worth more than management. Now,
maybe you‘re really smart. Maybe you have some source of synergy or
something else that makes you smarter than management; but absent that
kind of edge, . . . you‘d have to say to yourself ―I‘ve almost certainly
overpaid because the inside bidder, they looked at my offer and they
decided not to match it. So either I‘m very smart, smarter than the inside
people,‖ which [is] unlikely to be the case, ―or I‘ve just overpaid.‖
Strategic buyers are less subject to the winner‘s curse because they typically possess
93
Financial sponsors are ―much more concerned about a winner‘s curse‖ because they price
deals using similar financial models and seek to generate value from portfolio companies
using similar techniques. Tr. 783 (Subramanian). ―Just as Person B would not want to bid
against Person A for the contents of Person A‘s wallet, no financial buyer would want to
bid against a financial buyer working with management.‖ Denton, supra, at 1546.
In this case, the threat of the winner‘s curse rendered questionable the existence of
a pathway to success. As the Company‘s founder and longtime CEO, Mr. Dell knew
more about the Company than anyone else. Before any bidder would become involved,
they had to have a strategy for dealing with Mr. Dell‘s superior knowledge.
For those bidders who became involved during the go-shop period, the Committee
sought to address the information asymmetry issue by providing extensive due diligence.
Although Blackstone had to push for certain information that Silver Lake was given
voluntarily, all of the bidders received access to the data they requested. The Committee
and Evercore also ensured that Mr. Dell was available. Mr. Dell personally provided all
of the bidders with management presentations, and he ultimately spent more time with
Blackstone than any of the other participants, including Silver Lake. The record provided
no reason to harbor any concern about Mr. Dell‘s level of cooperation or responsiveness.
In the end, for the bidders who actually engaged during the go-shop period, the
Committee appears to have addressed the problem of information asymmetry and the risk
of the winner‘s curse as best they could. The problems are endemic to MBO go-shops
and create a powerful disincentive for any competing bidder—and particularly competing
94
financial bidders—to get involved. It can happen, as Blackstone and Icahn demonstrated,
A third impediment to competitive bidding was Mr. Dell‘s value to the Company.
Subramanian showed that the Company‘s relationship with Mr. Dell was an asset in
itself. To illustrate Mr. Dell‘s value, Subramanian conducted two event studies. He
determined the stock price effect of Mr. Dell‘s departure from the Company in March
2004, and he measured the stock price effect of his return in 2007. Subramanian
calculated that in March 2004, the Company lost $1.2 billion in market value. In January
2007, the Company gained $2.5 billion in market value. Subramanian concluded from
these studies that Mr. Dell‘s association with the Company contributed significant
value.42
42
Mr. Dell‘s relationships with customers may have been one of the sources of his
value. During the go-shop process, a news report suggested that Blackstone was vetting
candidates to replace Mr. Dell. After reading the account, Mr. Dell sent an email to
Blackstone, which stated:
This evening I was having dinner with a potential customer worth over
$600 million in revenue to our company. They were reacting quite
negatively to the story and others like it. The customer was suggesting
ways to contractually protect themselves from the risk associated with . . .
the kinds of changes suggested in press speculation. I am disappointed by
the real damage[] stories like this and others are inflicting on our business.
JX 449 at 1. The email suggests that customers valued Mr. Dell‘s involvement and would
take their business elsewhere if he left.
95
To perceive a path to success, a competing bidder had to account for Mr. Dell‘s
value. Mr. Dell was part of the Buyout Group, so the incumbent party to the Merger
Agreement had the benefit of that asset. A competing bidder that did not have Mr. Dell as
part of its buyout group would be bidding for a company without that asset and would
There was also the problem of Mr. Dell‘s financial incentives. He was a net
purchaser in the transaction, meaning he was buying more equity in the post-MBO
Company than he was selling. Mr. Dell rolled over his entire 16% equity stake into the
new company and contributed $750 million in cash. Through the transaction, he
Because Mr. Dell was a net purchaser, any increase in the deal price would cost
him money. If Mr. Dell kept the size of his investment constant as the deal value
increased, then Silver Lake would have to pay more and would demand a greater
ownership stake in the post-transaction entity. Subramanian showed that if Mr. Dell
wanted to maintain 75% ownership of the post-transaction entity, then he would have to
contribute an additional $250 million for each $1 increase in the deal price.43 If Mr. Dell
did not contribute any additional equity and relied on Silver Lake to fund the increase,
then he would lose control of the post-transaction entity at a deal price above $15.73 per
43
This calculation assumes that the amount of debt financing increased
proportionately. If the debt level remained constant and all of the price increase had to be
funded with equity, then each $1 increase in the deal price would cost Mr. Dell more than
$1 billion. Tr. 794-96 (Subramanian).
96
share. Because Mr. Dell was a net buyer, any party considering an overbid would
understand that a higher price would not be well received by the most important person at
the Company.
The Committee commendably tried to address Mr. Dell‘s role and the advantage
that his participation conferred on the Buyout Group. In the confidentiality agreement
that Mr. Dell signed, he agreed ―to explore in good faith the possibility of working with
being understood that your decision as to whether to work with any counterparty or
financing source after such good faith exploration shall be within your discretion.‖ JX
125 at 2. The Company oversold this provision during the trial as a binding requirement
that Mr. Dell work with any bidder, which it was not, but the contract term was
nevertheless helpful. It could have been more specific,44 but it was better than no
commitment at all.
More importantly, the record indicated that Mr. Dell actually was willing to work
with other buyout groups. Mr. Dell testified credibly on that point, and his
contemporaneous actions during the sale process were consistent with his testimony. In a
44
Cf. J.Crew Group Inc., Definitive Proxy Statement (Schedule 14A) 91 (Jan. 25,
2011) (noting cooperation agreement with CEO/Chairman that included promise to: ―[1]
participat[e] in meetings, presentations, due diligence sessions and other sessions with
persons interested in making a takeover proposal; [2] assist[] in the preparation of
solicitation materials, offering documents and similar documents to be used in connection
with such efforts; and [3] cooperat[e] and assist[] in obtaining any consents, waivers,
approvals and authorizations for and in connection with any takeover proposal‖).
97
different case in which a key employee was less forthcoming, a comparable commitment
There is also evidence that Blackstone and Icahn did not regard Mr. Dell as
essential to their bids. Blackstone explored alternative CEO candidates. Icahn described
Perhaps the most important reason [the Silver Lake bid undervalues the
Company] is Dell has a major liability that can be easily removed and that I
believe would make the company a great deal of value. It is the CEO,
Michael Dell. If Dell can replace Michael Dell, I think that the company
would be worth far, far more. I do not say this facetiously. I fully expect to
be able to identify a first class person to run Dell if our slate of directors are
elected at the annual meeting.
Dell, Inc., Carl C. Icahn Issues Open Letter to Stockholders of Dell (Schedule 14A) (July
29, 2013). Icahn thought that ―[a]ll would be swell at Dell if Michael and the board bid
farewell.‖ JX 730 at 1.
As with the other go-shop considerations, Mr. Dell‘s value to the Company and
his association with the Buyout Group were impediments, but not insuperable ones.
Exceptional bidders like Blackstone and Icahn could overcome them, but Mr. Dell‘s
unique value and his affiliation with the Buyout Group were negative factors that
Taken as a whole, the Company did not establish that the outcome of the sale
process offers the most reliable evidence of the Company‘s value as a going concern. The
market data is sufficient to exclude the possibility, advocated by the petitioners‘ expert,
that the Merger undervalued the Company by $23 billion. Had a value disparity of that
98
magnitude existed, then HP or another technology firm would have emerged to acquire
the Company on the cheap. What the market data does not exclude is an underpricing of a
smaller magnitude, given that all of the participants constructed their bids based on a
Court because it is the approach that merits the greatest confidence within the financial
community.‖ Owen v. Cannon, 2015 WL 3819204, at *16 (Del. Ch. June 17, 2015)
Put in very simple terms, the basic DCF method involves several discrete
steps. First, one estimates the values of future cash flows for a discrete
period . . . . Then, the value of the entity attributable to cash flows expected
after the end of the discrete period must be estimated to produce a so-called
terminal value, preferably using a perpetual growth model. Finally, the
value of the cash flows for the discrete period and the terminal value must
be discounted back . . . .
Andaloro v. PFPC Worldwide, Inc., 2005 WL 2045640, at *9 (Del. Ch. Aug. 19, 2005)
The petitioners‘ expert, Professor Bradford Cornell, used a DCF analysis to opine
that the Company had a fair value of $28.61 per share on the closing date. The
respondent‘s expert, Professor Glenn Hubbard, used a DCF analysis to opine that the
Company had a fair value of $12.68 per share on the closing date. Two highly
99
recurring problem. See Modern Appraisal Litigation, supra, at 19-20 (reviewing appraisal
decisions and finding that ―for respondents‘ experts, the median valuation was 16%
below the merger price, and the mean was 22% below. For petitioners‘ experts, the
median valuation was 78% above the merger price, and the mean was 186% above.‖).
This decision does not exhaustively describe the DCF methodology; it only addresses the
1. Forecasts
The difference in the experts‘ DCF valuations was driven primarily by the
projected cash flows they used. Cornell weighted equally the BCG 25% Case and the
BCG 75% Case, effectively creating a BCG 50% Case. Cornell then gave equal weight to
the BCG 50% Case and the Bank Case, with an additional $1 billion in cost savings
added to the Bank Case. Hubbard used an adjusted version of the BCG 25% Case. Both
experts regarded the July and September Cases as overly optimistic and, in any event,
Both experts treated the BCG 25% Case as reliable. BCG was an unbiased third-
party expert. The Committee hired BCG to prepare a detailed set of forecasts that valued
the Company as a going concern. BCG built its forecasts from the bottom up with input
from management and took into account the Company‘s historical performance and
Street projections. The forecasts comported with the evidence presented at trial, in that
they projected declining margins for the end-user computing business and increasing
margins for the enterprise service and solutions business. The projections were
impressively thorough, with over 1,100 specific assumptions. The resulting model was
100
dynamic and transparent. The Committee, BCG, and J.P. Morgan regarded the BCG 25%
For purposes of a valuation as of the Merger date, the BCG 25% Case has some
weaknesses. The projections were prepared in January 2013 and never updated. The
Company‘s actual operating income for FY 2014 was more than 36% below the BCG
25% Case. In addition, BCG‘s projections for revenue from PC sales in FY 2015 and FY
2016 appeared high once IDC reported lower rates of PC shipments in August 2013.
Hubbard adjusted the BCG 25% Case to account for these weaknesses. First, he
updated the revenue projections to incorporate the results of the August 2013 IDC report,
which implied a 10% decline in shipments for desktop PCs and a 23% decline for
means of addressing the concern that the BCG 25% Case had become stale by the time of
the closing date. To make these adjustments, Hubbard used current IDC data and
Consistent with the Company‘s experience through closing, Hubbard maintained the
Second, because of the adjustment to projected sales for the Company‘s primary
products in the end-user computing business, Hubbard updated the revenues that would
flow from sales of secondary products (i.e., the attachment rates). He relied on figures
Third, Hubbard adjusted for stock-based compensation. The experts agreed on the
pre-tax figure for the adjustment. See also Merion Capital, L.P. v. 3M Cogent, Inc., 2013
101
WL 3793896, at *12 (Del. Ch. July 8, 2013) (collecting cases supporting treating stock-
2018 through FY 2022. The resulting three-stage model better captured the operative
reality of the Company and the likely schedule for the transformation plan to generate
results. See Andaloro, 2005 WL 2045640, at *12-13 (adding a stage to create a three-
tiered DCF so as to make the calculation of cash flows ―a bit more explicit‖ and noting
that ―[a]s a general matter, neither a [two stage nor a three stage DCF] is inherently
preferable‖).
*5 (Del. Ch. May 20, 2004). Generally speaking, our appraisal jurisprudence is skeptical
Hubbard persuasively justified his changes, and this court has used adjusted projections
45
E.g., Cede & Co. v. JRC Acq. Corp., 2004 WL 286963, at *2 (Del. Ch. Feb. 10,
2004) (―[T]his Court prefers valuations based on management projections available as of
the date of the merger and holds a healthy skepticism for post-merger adjustments to
management projections or the creation of new projections entirely.‖); Cede & Co. v.
Technicolor, Inc., 2003 WL 23700218, at *7 (Del. Ch. Dec. 31, 2003) (―Contemporary
pre-merger management projections are particularly useful in the appraisal context
because management projections, by definition, are not tainted by post-merger hindsight
and are usually created by an impartial body. In stark contrast, post hoc, litigation-driven
forecasts have an ‗untenably high‘ probability of containing ‗hindsight bias and other
cognitive distortions.‘‖ (quoting Agranoff v. Miller, 791 A.2d 880, 892 (Del. Ch. 2001))),
aff’d in pertinent part, rev’d in part, 875 A.2d 602 (Del. 2005).
102
when the expert has provided sufficient support for the modifications.46 The BCG 25%
Case with Hubbard‘s adjustments is a reliable set of forecasts for the Company. Given
the Company‘s litigation incentives, however, it likely represents (on the margin) a
Cornell also used the BCG 75% Case. The cost-savings in the BCG 75% Case
bore few indicia of reliability. One was vaguely labeled ―client reinvention initiative,‖
which no one at trial explained. Due to the aggressive initiatives it contemplated, the
BCG 75% Case ―impl[ied] margins in fiscal year 2016 that are higher than those ever
Cornell also used the Bank Case. That set of projections was completed in
September 2013, closer in time to the closing date than any of the other projections. It is a
federal felony ―to knowingly obtain any funds from a financial institution by false or
projections that is provided to a financial institution. Del. Open MRI Radiology Assocs.,
P.A. v. Kessler, 898 A.2d 290, 317 n.57 (Del. Ch. 2006) (Strine, V.C.) (citing 18
U.S.C.A. § 1344 (2006)). Silver Lake prepared the projections, but Company
management provided key inputs, and Mr. Dell implicitly approved the projections by
46
See Highfields Capital, Ltd. v. AXA Fin., Inc., 939 A.2d 34, 62 (Del. Ch. 2007)
(adopting reasonable updates to management projections); Andaloro, 2005 WL 2045640,
at *11 (adjusting management forecasts to exclude revenue from division deemed likely
to be sold); In re U.S. Cellular Operating Co., 2005 WL 43994, at *11-15, *19 (Del. Ch.
Jan. 6, 2005) (building projections based on expert-created forecasts and finding DCF
most reliable evidence of value).
103
endorsing them at a rating agency presentation. Hubbard regarded the projections as
reasonable.
At the same time, the Bank Case was relatively optimistic. Silver Lake‘s forecasts
projected increasing margins for the PC business, despite the Company‘s near-term
strategy of sacrificing margin to retain market share and market evidence showing a shift
to low-margin value PCs. Silver Lake also based its projections on the private company
status of the post-transaction entity. That is not a significant concern in this case, because
the Buyout Group planned to continue managing the Company‘s business after closing
using the same business plan, and the quantum of administrative savings resulting from
no longer being a public company was not material to a corporation of the Company‘s
magnitude.
expenses and for stock-based compensation. This decision adopts these changes, as well
This decision concludes that there are two sets of reliable forecasts for the
Company: Hubbard‘s adjusted BCG 25% Case, which was likely somewhat conservative,
and Hubbard‘s adjusted Bank Case, which was likely somewhat optimistic.
Cornell used a perpetuity growth rate of 1%. Hubbard used 2%. This court has
held that ―the rate of inflation is the floor for a terminal value estimate for a solidly
profitable company that does not have an identifiable risk of insolvency.‖ Glob. GT LP v.
Golden Telecom, Inc. (Golden Telecom I), 993 A.2d 497, 511 (Del. Ch. 2010) (Strine,
104
V.C.), aff’d, 11 A.3d 214 (Del. 2010). Cornell‘s 1% perpetuity growth rate is lower than
inflation. Even Hubbard‘s 2% growth rate is arguably too low. Given the Company‘s
status as a mature Company whose growth rate should fall somewhere above inflation
and close to GDP, a 3% rate could be more appropriate. See id. (―Generally, once an
industry has matured, a company will grow at a steady rate that is roughly equal to the
rate of nominal GDP growth.‖). This decision nevertheless uses the 2% rate.
3. Taxes
The experts disagree about the appropriate tax rate to apply to the Company‘s cash
flows. Cornell used a 21% tax rate throughout his forecast period, which he drew from
the September Case and the valuation models prepared by the Company‘s financial
advisors. Hubbard used two different tax rates. He used a 17.8% tax rate during the
projection and transition periods, which he drew from the report of a tax expert, Stephen
Shay. He used the 35.8% marginal tax rate for the terminal period, which he justified
The Company has not paid taxes at the marginal rate since at least 2000. In the
five years leading up to the Merger, the Company paid taxes at effective rates that varied
between 16.5% and 29.2%. For the same period, the Company‘s cash tax rates (i.e., the
The Company‘s low effective tax rate is due, in part, to its ability to defer payment
of domestic taxes on income earned overseas. The Company has made an ―indefinite
reinvestment election,‖ meaning that it has represented to its auditors that it intends to
indefinitely reinvest its earnings overseas. Tr. 934 (Shay). The election allows the
105
Company to defer paying U.S. taxes on approximately $19 billion in overseas profits. For
its auditors to approve this election, they needed ―evidence of specific plans for
Accounting for Income Taxes—Special Areas 4 (1972). At the time of the Merger, there
The Company will never pay domestic taxes on profits attributable to offshore
income unless and until it actually repatriates them. The only time the Company
repatriated significant overseas income was in 2004 and 2013, during U.S. tax holidays
that made the repatriations effectively tax free. In 2004, the Company repatriated $4
billion. In 2013, it repatriated $9 billion. The Company also had used earnings from
The Company has not deviated from its representation that it will continue to
reinvest its overseas earnings indefinitely in foreign projects. The Company instructed
Houlihan Lokey, Inc. to use a 17% tax rate when conducting a post-closing valuation.
Management told bidders during due diligence to expect the difference between the
Company‘s effective tax rate and its cash rate to continue for the foreseeable future.
47
Tr. 331-332 (Sweet) (testifying that at the time of the Merger, the Company had
opportunities for overseas growth and planned to increase its presence in the BRIC
countries, the Asia Pacific region, and other emerging markets); JX 161 at 20
(management presentation noting plans to ―[c]apitalize on the shift of geographic wealth
to emerging countries‖); JX 534 at 2 (proxy statement noting that ―following the merger,
the Company will make significant investments to enhance its presence and ability to
compete in emerging markets, including the BRIC countries . . . [and will] expand
aggressively in other parts of Asia, Latin and South America, Central and Eastern
Europe, the Middle East and Africa‖).
106
Hubbard‘s model implies that, beginning in 2023, Dell will begin paying taxes on
all of its global profits at the U.S. marginal tax rate of 35.8% and will continue doing so
perpetually. The factual record establishes the opposite. In fact, it would be highly
speculative for this court to choose a date when, contrary to its historical practice, the
Company would begin to repatriate foreign earnings.48 Cornell‘s tax estimate is more
To discount the cash flow projections to their present value, the experts computed
the Company‘s weighted average cost of capital (―WACC‖). The parties dispute every
48
See Paskill Corp. v. Alcoma Corp., 747 A.2d 549, 552 (Del. 2000) (―[T]the
Court of Chancery should have excluded any deduction for the speculative future tax
liabilities‖); Ng v. Heng Sang Realty Corp., 2004 WL 885590, at *6 (Del. Ch. Apr. 22,
2004) (―In determining fair value, this Court cannot consider speculative tax liabilities.‖),
aff’d, 867 A.2d 901 (Del. 2005) (TABLE).
49
In re AT&T Mobility Wireless Operations Hldgs. Appraisal Litig., 2013 WL
3865099, at *4 (Del. Ch. Jun. 24, 2013) (adopting effective tax rate that was ―[c]onsistent
with the Companies‘ operative reality‖). For decisions using the effective tax rate rather
than the marginal tax rate, see Owen v. Cannon, 2015 WL 3819204, at *24 (Del. Ch. June
17, 2015) (adopting 22.71% tax rate); Golden Telecom I, 993 A.2d at 513 (adopting
31.6% tax rate based on predictions of management and company‘s historical tax rate),
aff’d, 11 A.3d 214 (Del. 2010); Del. Open MRI., 898 A.2d at 330 (adopting 29.4% tax
rate); Ng, 2004 WL 885590, at *6 (adopting 11% tax rate), aff’d, 867 A.2d 901 (Del.
2005) (TABLE) (―[I]t appears to the Court that the Court of Chancery‘s factual
determination as to the appropriate tax rate to apply to projected future earnings in a
discounted cash flow valuation was supported by the record.‖). But see In re Appraisal of
Ancestry.com, Inc., 2015 WL 399726, at *20 (Del. Ch. Jan. 30, 2015) (holding that it was
―overly speculative to apply the current tax rate in perpetuity . . . ‗[b]ecause of the
transitory nature of tax deductions and credits‘‖ (quoting Henke v. Trilithic Inc., 2005
WL 2899677, at *9 (Del. Ch. Oct. 28, 2005))).
107
input except for the risk-free rate of 3.31%. The inputs selected below generate a WACC
of 9.46%.
The experts disagreed about the cost of debt. Before the Merger, the Company had
an ―A‖ credit rating. In May 2013, Standard & Poor‘s downgraded the Company‘s credit
rating to ―BBB‖ after poor first-quarter results. The ―rating downgrade reflect[ed]
segment,‖ not the impending buyout. JX 523 at 2. As of October 29, 2013, long-term
BBB rated bonds had a 4.95% yield to maturity. JX 897A ¶ 104. This decision adopts
b. Capital Structure
The experts disagreed about the Company‘s capital structure. Cornell used the
75.25% of the capital structure was equity. Hubbard used the Company‘s average ratio of
equity to total capital calculated on a quarterly basis between January 12, 2011, and
January 11, 2013, to conclude that 74.75% of Dell‘s capital structure was equity. Both
c. Beta
The experts disagreed about beta. Cornell derived a beta of 1.35 by analyzing the
Company‘s peers. Hubbard derived a beta of 1.31 by analyzing weekly observations over
a two-year period. A beta specific to the Company is more targeted than a blended beta
calculated from peer companies, particularly when both experts opined that the Company
108
had few peers. See Merion Capital, L.P. v. 3M Cogent, Inc., 2013 WL 3793896, at *18
The experts disagreed about the appropriate equity risk premium. Cornell used a
forward-looking equity risk premium of 5.50%. Hubbard used a blended historical and
supply-side equity risk premium of 6.41%. This decision uses the supply-side equity risk
premium of 6.11%. See Golden Telecom I, 993 A.2d at 516; see also Merion Capital LP
v. BMC Software, Inc., 2015 WL 6164771, at *12 (Del. Ch. Oct. 21, 2015) (collecting
cases).
5. Adjustments To Cash
The experts agreed that excess cash should be added to the valuation, but they
disagreed about how much cash was excess. At the time of the Merger, the Company had
$11.040 billion in cash and $5.054 billion in debt on its balance sheet. After adding back
$172 million in transaction-related expenses, the Company had net cash of $6.158 billion.
Cornell added the full amount of net cash to Dell‘s enterprise value. Hubbard made four
deductions: (i) $3 billion for working capital, (ii) $2 billion for restricted cash, (iii) $2.24
billion for deferred taxes, and (iv) $3 billion for contingent taxes.
Working capital and restricted cash can be addressed together. The witness
the Company required at least $3 billion in working capital. Silver Lake left $5.665
109
billion in cash on the balance sheet after closing. The $3 billion working capital figure is
reasonable.
restricted cash. A single adjustment is necessary, however, to account for a rating agency
presentation in April 2014, where the Company stated that it had obtained access to $0.8
This decision deducts working capital of $3 billion and restricted cash of $1.2
billion from the Company‘s available cash for purposes of determining its enterprise
value.
b. Deferred Taxes
The experts disagreed about deferred taxes. Hubbard deducted $2.24 billion for
deferred taxes attributable to the Company‘s foreign earnings and profits. This decision
has already resolved this issue by accepting the Company‘s representation that it will
reinvest its overseas earnings indefinitely in overseas projects, meaning it will not have to
pay any U.S. taxes on that income. If anything, this approach is conservative. The
Company‘s CFO testified that the effective tax rate includes deferred taxes, and that the
Company‘s cash tax rate is lower than the effective rate because the effective tax rate
includes substantial deferred tax liabilities. In other words, the effective tax rate accounts
for the deferred taxes, and because the Company never plans to repatriate those funds, a
proper valuation would have to back out any deferred taxes on foreign earnings from its
110
c. Liability From Unrecognized Tax Benefits
enterprise value for unrecognized tax benefits. Under FASB Interpretation No. 48 (―FIN
48‖), a company must have a reserve on its balance sheet for unpaid taxes it may have to
pay for taking a tax position on a prior return that may prove incorrect. See Fin.
Accounting Standards Bd., FASB Interpretation No. 48: Accounting for Uncertainty in
48 ―requires the affirmative evaluation that it is more likely than not, based on the
resulting from positions taken in income tax returns.‖ Id. at 3-4. That is, the FIN 48
reserve measures the tax payment a company expects to pay if a taxing authority
disagrees with its position even though it thinks it is more likely than not that its position
is correct. The liability that Hubbard deducted equaled 100% of the Company‘s FIN 48
reserve.
Subtracting the full FIN 48 liability from the Company‘s enterprise value would
be excessive. Under penalty of law, Company and its advisors deemed it more likely than
not that their prior tax positions were reasonable. Tr. 302, 314 (Sweet) (testifying that the
full FIN 48 reserve remains on the Company‘s books and reflects ―the best estimate‖ of
Dell‘s FIN 48 liability and that outside advisors vet that position); see also Tr. 937-38
(Shay). Subtracting the $3.01 billion from the DCF would imply that this court better
understands the merits of the Company‘s tax positions than the Company does—without
even having the opportunity to look at the underlying tax positions. The more persuasive
111
view is that the Company and its auditors correctly determined the Company‘s tax
positions.
The analysis differs as to one item where Houlihan Lokey opined that it was
―probable‖ and ―reasonably estimable‖ that the Company would pay out $650 million
from the FIN 48 reserve. JX 725 at 2, 11. That $650 million was ―in the most mature
operating liability. Id. at 11. The Bank Case included the $650 million outflow in its
projections.
This decision deducts $650 million from the Company‘s excess cash.
This decision adopts the parties‘ agreed upon calculation of 1,765,369,276 fully
diluted shares outstanding. Using Hubbard‘s adjusted BCG 25% Case, which was likely
somewhat conservative, a DCF analysis that incorporates the foregoing inputs generates a
fair value per share of $16.43. Using Hubbard‘s adjusted Bank Case, which was likely
somewhat optimistic, a DCF analysis that incorporates the foregoing inputs generates a
Having no reason to prefer one realistic case over the other, this decision weights
them equally. This approach has the additional benefit of arriving at a cost-savings
number that is closest to management‘s best estimate of what the Company believed was
attainable at the time of the Merger. In April 2014, after the Merger closed, the Company
made a presentation to the rating agencies in which management stated that the Company
had realized $1.6 billion in cost-savings in FY 2014. See JX 807. The Bank Case
112
assumed $2.6 billion in cost savings. Hubbard‘s adjusted BCG 25% case appears to have
assumed approximately $660 million in savings. Averaging the two implies $1.63 billion
in cost savings, which matches the figure management provided in April 2014.
Giving equal weight to the two DCF valuations generates a fair value of $17.62
per share.
C. The Relationship Between The DCF Valuation And The Merger Price
The fair value generated by the DCF methodology comports with the evidence
regarding the outcome of the sale process. The sale process functioned imperfectly as a
price discovery tool, both during the pre-signing and post-signing phases. Its structure
and result are sufficiently credible to exclude an outlier valuation for the Company like
the one the petitioners advanced, but sufficient pricing anomalies and dis-incentives to
bid existed to create the possibility that the sale process permitted an undervaluation of
several dollars per share. Financial sponsors using an LBO model could not have bid
close to $18 per share because of their IRR requirements and the Company‘s inability to
support the necessary levels of leverage. Assuming the $17.62 figure is right, then a
strategic acquirer that perceived the Company‘s value could have gotten the Company for
what was approximately a 25% discount. Given the massive integration risk inherent in
such a deal, it is not entirely surprising that HP did not engage and that no one else came
forward. Had the valuation gap approached what the petitioners‘ expert believed, then the
113
Because it is impossible to quantify the exact degree of the sale process
mispricing, this decision does not give weight to the Final Merger Consideration. It uses
III. CONCLUSION
The fair value of the Company on the closing date was $17.62 per share. The legal
rate of interest, compounded quarterly, shall accrue on this amount from the date of
closing until the date of payment. The parties shall cooperate on preparing a final order
for the court. If there are additional issues for the court to resolve before a final order can
be entered, the parties shall submit a joint letter within two weeks that identifies them and
recommends a schedule for bringing this case to conclusion, at least at the trial court
level.
114