SSRN Id87811
SSRN Id87811
SSRN Id87811
2 May 1998
The Dumont Institute for Public Policy Research
236 Johnson Avenue, Dumont, NJ 07628 USA [email protected]
Telephone: (201) 501-8574
Robert W. McGee
Seton Hall University
Yeomin Yoon
Seton Hall University
Abstract
The People's Republic of China has been the number one target of
antidumping actions filed by the U.S. Commerce Department on behalf
of various domestic industries. One reason for this special status is
because the PRC is one of the world's lowest cost producers. Because
of the cost structure of its industries and economy, as well as the fact
that it tends to manufacture products at the low end of the quality scale,
it is able to sell a wide range of products for lower prices than most
competitors. Furthermore, because it is classified as a nonmarket
economy, special rules must be used to determine the cost of
production.
Introduction
Antidumping laws, which punish foreign producers for selling their
products on domestic markets at low prices (McGee 1993), have been in existence
2
for decades. Since the finalization of the Uruguay Round of GATT they have taken
provision that all signatories must adhere to. Before the recent GATT agreement
domestic laws. After the Uruguay Round, more than 120 countries agreed to adopt
and enforce the GATT antidumping laws. In the past few years, the People’s
Republic of China has been the most frequent target of antidumping actions initiated
This paper will examine some recent case studies involving antidumping
actions initiated in the USA against the PRC and attempt to determine what the
frequent exercise of the antidumping laws might mean for the future.
In the past, there have been many problems with both the theory and
matters, the antidumping provisions adopted by GATT are somewhat different than
the provisions in U.S. law, and it has not yet been determined which set of laws
would amount to a partial abrogation of U.S. sovereignty. Others deny that this
many common features between the GATT rules and the U.S. rules. Many of the
2
3
One of the major criticisms leveled against the U.S. antidumping rules is the
subjectivity with which they are applied. In a case involving some Brazilian
companies, more than ten different methods were used to determine the cost of
production (Bovard 1991: 129). The use of some methods resulted in finding that
dumping had occurred, since the selling price in the domestic market was less than
the cost of production. Yet if other methods were used, no dumping was found
because the cost of production was less than the selling price. Potential targets of
antidumping actions never know in advance which cost of production methods will
Another major criticism of the U.S. rules is the arbitrariness, and the
potential abuse that goes with it (McGee 1994: 92-111). The government can
demand practically anything and the target of the investigation must comply or face
demanded in the format requested, the Commerce Department can reject the entire
submission and instead use what it labels the "best information available" (BIA)
initiated the antidumping action. This BIA is often not the best information
available, in spite of the name. It is often biased against the target of the
3
4
translated into English. The demand was made on a Friday afternoon; the deadline
was the following Monday morning (Bovard 1991: 136). Rather than comply with
this impossible request, Matsushita withdrew the product from the domestic
market, which pleased the domestic companies that initiated the action.
English) to six former Soviet republics and demanded information about their
uranium production (Bovard 1992). Aside from the fact that they did not have the
information, it would have been illegal to supply it if they did have it. Yet they
has occurred is the method by which prices are determined in an environment with
rapidly changing exchange rates (Palmeter 1988). Sometimes, the methods used to
compare the foreign currency to the dollar will result in a finding of dumping where
major problem in many Latin American countries, where inflation has been
institutionalized, but could be a problem in China as well, which has a much lower
rate of inflation.
Many antidumping actions in the past have compared products that are not
strictly comparable, with the result that an antidumping action might find a party
guilty where a guilty finding is not warranted. For example, Product A in China
might be compared to Product B in the United States even though Product A might
be different qualitatively from Product B. The fact that the products are
qualitatively different does not mean that there will automatically be some
4
5
discounting applied to account for the qualitative difference. Where differences are
taken into account, the Commerce Department sometimes uses strange comparisons
perhaps with adjustment, as a substitute for the alleged offender's costs, in an effort
to determine whether the foreign producer has sold products on the domestic market
for less than cost. This faulty methodology invites abuse, and is compounded by
the fact that the petitioners are often the ones that choose which country is to be
used as a surrogate, and which data from the surrogate country are to be examined.
China, since the Commerce Department has on many occasions classified the PRC
as a nonmarket economy.
The whole concept of selling consistently for less than fair value, or for less
than the cost of production, is a curious one. First of all, fair value is determined
willing to pay for it. So asserting that a product can be consistently sold for less
than fair value, when buyers and sellers are free to negotiate, is ridiculous on its
face. Yet the view that something can be sold for less than fair value is not only the
basis for the underlying antidumping theory, but is also punishable, even though
both parties to the transaction benefit as a result of the sale. Otherwise, there would
be no sale, since parties to a sale do not go into it with the idea of making
themselves worse off. Consumers benefit, of course, and antidumping laws were
5
6
Selling a product for less than the cost of production is almost never done,
and when it is done, it is for a good reason. Any company that sells for less than
Furthermore, if something is sold for less than the cost of production, consumers
benefit, and since the antidumping laws were passed to benefit consumers, no one
should complain, and certainly companies that sell their products to domestic
consumers for low prices should not be punished. Yet that is exactly what happens
The problem with antidumping laws is that they are used by domestic
either prevent foreign competitors from entering the domestic market, or if they do
enter, they must either charge high prices or pay a high tariff to the government as a
One reason why the antidumping laws were passed was to prevent
predatory pricing. Yet the antitrust literature of the past few decades has concluded
that predatory pricing either doesn't exist, or if it could exist, would benefit
consumers (R. McGee 1994:138-9; Koller 1971; J. McGee 1958; Fisher 1987;
company drops its price so low as to drive out all competitors, it will gain market
share and lose money on every sale. If it is able to force out all competitors, they
will stay out only as long as prices remain so low that they would not be able to
make a profit by re-entering the market. The only way a predator can prevent
competitors from re-entering the market is by keeping its prices abnormally low.
6
7
It would probably go out of business if it kept its prices low. But let's say
that it was somehow able to stay in business. Consumers would benefit by the
exist in a free market, or if it did exist, it would benefit consumers. Thus, the a
priori approach meshes completely with the empirical antitrust literature on this
point.
Cases
Preserved Mushrooms
by the Coalition for Fair Preserved Mushroom Trade, which is comprised of L.K.
Bowman, Inc., Nottingham, PA; Modern Mushroom Farms, Inc., Avondale, PA;
Temple, PA; Mushroom Canning Co., Kennett Square, PA; Sunny Dell Foods,
Inc., Oxford, PA; and United Canning Corp., North Lima, OH. (USITC 1998: A-
3, 6). Thirty-six potential PRC exporters and mushroom producers were targeted
surrogate country costs were used to estimate the costs of production. In this case,
Indian consumption data for materials, labor and energy were used. The petitioners
alleged that the mushrooms were being sold for less than the cost of production.
concluded that there was reason to believe that the Chinese mushroom imports
were, or were likely to be, sold at less than fair value (A-8).
7
8
Carbon steel plate investigations are quite popular with the USITC. Since
countries that export this product to the United States (USITC 1997a: D-3-6). In
Chinese carbon steel plate as a result of petitions filed by Geneva Steel Company
and Gulf States Steel, Inc., which alleged that imports from the People's Republic
of China, Russia, Ukraine and South Africa are being, or are likely to be, sold in
the United States at less than fair value, and that such imports are materially
first, it was questionable whether there was sufficient support for the petition, since
Section 732(c)(4)(A) of the Tariff Act of 1930 requires that the petition be
domestic like product and more than 50 percent of the production of the domestic
like product produced by that portion of the industry expressing support for, or
opposition to, the petition. That question was laid to rest when the petition was
amended to include support from Bethlehem Steel Corporation, the U.S. Steel
country. The petitioners selected Indonesia as the primary surrogate country, since
obtain port unloading charges for Indonesia, so they used the lowest charge
percentages were estimated using India as the surrogate country. Based on these
data, the Commerce Department estimated the dumping margins to range from
8
9
10.01% to 45.84% (USITC 1996a: A-7). Under the terms of the final agreement,
Chinese plate exports are limited to 150,000 metric tons between November 1,
1997 and October 31, 1998. Weighted average dumping margins at the final stage
petition filed in November, 1996 by the Paslode Division of Illinois Tool Works,
Inc, which alleged that Chinese collated roofing nails are, or are likely to be, sold in
the United States at less than fair value, and that a U.S. industry is likely to be
be chosen for cost comparisons. India was chosen because its per capita gross
national product is relatively close to that of China, and because India produces
margins ranged from 106.08% to 118.41% (USITC 1997e: A-5 & 6). Final
dumping margins ranged from 0 percent to 40.28 percent (USITC 1997b: A-17).
Persulfates
Chinese persulfate industry as the result of a petition filed in July, 1996 by FMC
there was a reasonable indication that an industry in the United States was
threatened with material injury by reason of imports from China (USITC 1996b: v).
9
10
chosen in order to determine equivalent costs. The petitioner chose India to value
factors of production, in this case, since India is the only persulfate producer
among surrogate countries that the Commerce Department typically uses for the
PRC. Based on comparisons of export prices with the normal values the petitioner
from 15.87% to 182.37% (USITC 1996b: A-6). The final determination found that
Chinese persulfates were being, or were likely to be, sold in the United States for
less than fair value (USITC 1997c: A-5). Dumping margins in the final
Coalition for the Preservation of American Brake Drum and Rotor Aftermarket,
Missouri (USITC 1996c: B-3). The Coalition alleged that Chinese brake drums and
rotors were, or were likely to be, sold in the United States at less than fair value.
was used as a surrogate country to estimate some Chinese costs (USITC 1997d: A-
found, at the preliminary level, that the Chinese were guilty, and calculated
dumping margins ranging from 46.76 percent to 105.56 percent for brake drums
and from 52.08 percent to 62.55 percent for brake rotors (USITC 1996c: B-5). At
the final stage, termination agreements were entered into. Dumping margins for
brake drums ranged from 0 percent to a China-wide rate of 86.02 percent. For
brake rotors, the final margins ranged between zero and 43.32 percent (USITC
1997d: A-17).
10
11
Concluding Comments
The antidumping laws are based on a number of faulty premises. For one
thing, actual dumping rarely occurs, because if it did, the company that does the
dumping would probably go out of business. There are instances where a company
sells its products, either in foreign or domestic markets, at less than the cost of
production. Where this practice does occur, it is usually for good business reasons
-- the alternative to selling below cost may be to not sell at all. This is certainly the
case for wilting flowers or aging tomatoes. Very seldom do companies sell at less
than cost to drive out the competition with the intent of later capturing market share.
The numerous studies that have been done on predatory pricing have either found
that predatory pricing does not exist, or if it does exist, it benefits consumers.
Another faulty premise is that dumping is bad for the economy. If a foreign
producer does sell below cost, or for a lower price than in its home market (these
are the two criteria for dumping), the practice benefits consumers -- the general
public. Domestic producers are harmed, but domestic producers constitute a small
minority, although a concentrated one. In practice, the antidumping laws have been
Another flaw, a philosophical one, is the concept that one producer should
being harmed and having your rights violated. For example, if a supermarket
opens up across the street from a small, mom and pop grocery store, mom and pop
will likely be harmed, but they will not have their rights violated. They have no
right to sell products to consumers who do not want to buy from them. But the
11
12
antidumping laws go a step further down this illogical road. They would punish
foreign producers for doing business domestically if there is a mere threat of harm
to a domestic industry. Thus, they are punished for something that they merely
might do in the future. If such a theory were applied to criminal law in the United
States, it would lead to the incarceration of anyone who fits a criminal profile
whether they were actually guilty of breaking the law or not. Yet the antidumping
laws regularly use such a yardstick to determine whether a foreign producer should
be punished.
antidumping laws. But these flaws have been pointed out elsewhere (McGee 1993;
1994). The main point is that antidumping laws have become much more important
since the conclusion of the Uruguay Round and the founding of the World Trade
Organization. Now, more than 120 countries have these laws at their disposal.
The potential for abuse is great and growing. It is reasonable to expect that, as
domestic producers in these countries become aware that they can use these laws to
prevent foreign producers from offering their goods in domestic markets at low
prices, they will make use of these laws, which benefit domestic producers at the
expense of the general public. The antidumping laws will become the biggest
weapon of protectionists as tariffs and quotas fade away. Reform is not the
answer, since these laws are based on incorrect premises. The only solution is
the WTO and its 120+ signatories in the near future. As a result, antidumping laws
will have an increasingly important effect on world trade, especially in the case of
China, since the PRC is the number one target of antidumping actions.
12
13
Antidumping laws can become one of the major challenges to trade with China in
Antidumping laws are likely to become the protectionist tool of choice, and will
likely be used to keep Chinese goods out of foreign markets. Thus, a major
challenge to trade with China will be how to find ways to conduct business with
China without running afoul of the antidumping laws, or how to circumvent the
antidumping laws when they are used to block trade. These laws will likely result
in high antidumping duties in many cases. These duties will have exactly the same
effect that tariffs had in the past -- they will increase prices to consumers and make
goods will not be able to cross borders at all, and thus will have the same effect on
The best solution to this impending problem is outright repeal, as was stated
previously. However, until repeal can be accomplished, ways must be found to
minimize the adverse effects that the implementation of antidumping laws will have
on international trade.
References
Armentano, D.T. (1972). The Myths of Antitrust. New Rochelle, NY: Arlington
House.
Bovard, James (1992, June 8). U.S. Protectionists Claim a Russian Victim. Wall
Street Journal, p. A-10.
Bovard, James (1991). The Fair Trade Fraud. New York: St. Martin's Press.
13
14
Brown, Terry (1997). Chinese Crawfish: Let Them Dump. Loyola Student
Journal of Economics, 10:2, 7-8 (Spring).
Kaplan, Gilbert B.; Lynn G. Kamarck and Marie Parker. Cost Analysis under the
Antidumping Law. George Washington Journal of International Law &
Economics, 21, 357-418.
McGee, John S. (1958). Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (N.J.) Case.
Journal of Law & Economics 1, 139-169 (October).
McGee, Robert W. (1994). A Trade Policy for Free Societies: The Case Against
Protectionism. New York and Westport, CT: Quorum Books.
United States International Trade Commission. 1997a. Certain Carbon Steel Plate
From China, Russia, South Africa, and Ukraine. Investigations Nos. 731-TA-
753-756 (Final), Pub. 3076 (December).
United States International Trade Commission. 1997d. Certain Brake Drums and
Rotors From China. Investigation No. 731-TA-744 (Final), Pub. 3035 (April).
14
15
United States International Trade Commission. 1996c. Certain Brake Drums and
Rotors From China. Investigation No. 731-TA-744 (Preliminary), Pub. 2957
(April).
15