Yue Zhang
Yue Zhang
Yue Zhang
Yue Zhang
Department of Political Science
University of Illinois at Chicago
Abstract
As the largest democracy and one of the most vibrant emerging economies in the world, India is
experiencing sustained economic growth hand in hand with urbanization. A major challenge
facing Indian cities is the expansion of informal housing beyond state control or regulation. In
Mumbai, the financial capital and most populous city of India, forty-two percent of the
population lives in slums. What explains the informal urbanization in India characterized by the
proliferation and persistence of informal settlements? This paper argues that informality must
be understood not as the object of state regulation but rather as produced and institutionalized by
the state itself. It is the institutional structure of the state that shapes state actors’ intentionality
and preferences and in turn affects their decisions about urbanization and informality.
Specifically, the paper demonstrates how fragmented intergovernmental relations and contested
party politics, as two major defining variables of the institutional structure of the Indian state,
influence the formation, persistence, and redevelopment of slums in Mumbai. Using the case of
Mumbai, the paper challenges the notion that informality is caused by a lack of state control and
spatial discipline. Instead, it shows that informality is the product of deliberate political and
social construction and has become the new normal in Southern cities.
*Paper prepared for Conference on the Political Economy of Contemporary India, January 9-10,
2017, Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai, India. Research presented in
the paper is part of the author’s book project on informal housing and urban governance in
China, India, and Brazil.
Introduction
As the largest democracy and one of the most vibrant emerging economies in the world,
India is experiencing sustained economic growth hand in hand with urbanization. While only
18% percent of the Indian population lived in cities in 1950, the country’s level of urbanization
has increased to 32% in 2013 and is expected to reach 55% by 2050. In India as well as many
other developing countries, one of the most important and common characteristics of
urbanization is the expansion of informal housing settlements that fall outside of government
control or regulation. According to UN-Habitat (2009), one third of the world’s urban
population lives in “slums.” In Mumbai, the financial capital and most populous city of India,
42% of the city population lives in slums and the number is still increasing.1
The definition of a slum has two dimensions. From a legal perspective, slums are
unauthorized and illegal structures, where inhabitants do not have legal title to the land that they
occupy. In Mumbai, nearly 50% of these slums are built on encroached land of private
landlords, whereas the rest are on the land of the central government, state government and
municipal corporation (MTSU 2015). In terms of living conditions, slums are areas that are
short of basic amenities and characterized by the prevalence of insanitary, squalid, overcrowded
conditions, and hence become a source of danger to their inhabitants’ health, safety, or
convenience. Apparently, urbanization has taken place in India in an informal fashion in the
sense that large numbers of urban households do not have legal property rights or proper urban
urbanization not only undermines urban residents’ quality of life, but also limits the
1
In the first official survey that Mumbai conducted in 1956, 8 percent of the total population lived in slums. Over
the years, the population of the city grew at a high speed and so did the number of slum dwellers. According to the
2011 Census, Mumbai has a total population of 12.44 million, and 42% of them – nearly 5.2 million people – lives
in slums.
1
improvement in other aspects of development, such as education, welfare, and access to jobs in
What causes the informal urbanization in India? This is the central research question this
paper seeks to address. Using the case of informal settlements in Mumbai, the paper
operationalizes the question into a series of more specific questions. First, why are informal
settlements so prevalent and persistent in Mumbai? Second, how does the state respond to the
informal housing sector? And third, what explains the outcomes of state intervention? Answers
to these questions will help illuminate the bigger picture of India’s urbanization and mechanism
of urban governance.
Whereas informality is often associated with weak state capacity, this paper challenges
the capacity-based approaches by presenting a theory of the institutional structure of the state. It
argues that informality must be understood not as the object of state regulation but rather as
produced and institutionalized by the state itself. The institutional structure of the state shapes
state actors’ intentionality and preferences and in turn affects their decisions about urbanization
and informality. The most salient characteristics of the institutional structure of the India state
are fragmented intergovernmental relations with the consolidation of state power and the rise of
regional political parties and intense interparty competition. These characteristics shape the
intentionality and preferences of state actors by creating a policy orientation that deprioritize
urbanization and a close interdependence between political parties and the urban poor, which
result in a series of political decisions that affect the proliferation, persistence and governance of
slums in Mumbai. Using the case of Mumbai, the paper challenges the notion that informality is
caused by a lack of state control and spatial discipline. Instead, it shows that informal
2
This is a qualitative study and it employs multiple qualitative research methods, including
case studies, comparative historical analysis, and process tracing. While the paper focuses on
Mumbai, the proliferation and persistence of informal settlements is a chronic problem facing
entire India as well as most developing countries. Hence, findings from the case study of
Mumbai can help us better understand urban informality in other places. On the other hand,
Mumbai is chosen because it is the economic center and most populous city of India, with a large
number of industrial workers and migrants, so that the demand for housing and the level of urban
informality are magnified there. Meanwhile, the market-driven model of slum redevelopment is
combination of representativeness and uniqueness that makes Mumbai an ideal case for the study
of informal housing.
Data presented in the paper are collected from fieldwork and archival research in
Mumbai in January 2-16, 2016. Fieldwork includes interviews and participatory observation. I
conducted thirty in-depth, semi-structured interviews, which lasted anywhere from an hour to
three hours. My interviewees include public officials, developers, slum leaders, NGOs activists,
urban planners and architects, intellectuals, and local residents. Public officials are from
Mumbai Transformation Support Unit, and Municipal Corporation of Greater Mumbai. These
interviewees were chosen because their professional or personal experiences are intimately
related to various aspects of the growth, governance, or redevelopment of slums, and thus
interviews, I visited nine sites, including Dharavi, Mahila Milan Nagar, Mankhurd, Karma
3
Sankalp, Shivnagar Pranay Bhoomi, Pranay Landmark, Santacruz, Adarsha Nagar, and Omkar
1973 Worli. These are either slums that are undergoing redevelopment or former slums that
were already redeveloped. During my visits in these communities, I spoke with leaders and
residents and attended community meetings. These experiences provided me with first-hand
information about the processes of slum redevelopment. Finally, I have supplemented fieldwork
with extensive archival research on government report, local newspapers, and professional
journals. These materials help me reconstruct the picture of urbanization and urban governance
in India, which provide an important backdrop for understanding the prevalence and persistence
of slums in Mumbai.
The paper consists of six parts. The first part following the introduction reexamines the
literature on urban informality from the perspective of the institutional structure of the state. The
second part investigates the institutional structure of the Indian state with a focus on its two
major characteristics and their implications for urbanization and informality. Parts Three, Four,
and Five discuss how the institutional structure of the state affects the formation, persistence, and
redevelopment of slums in Mumbai, respectively. The paper concludes in Part Six by reflecting
on the model of slum redevelopment and discussing the possibilities for improvement.
Informality is not a new phenomenon, nor does it seem to diminish over time. Informal
economies have persisted in many rural areas, particularly in the developing world. Reality
shows that informality does not disappear as economies matured. Even more, at this moment of
rapid urbanization at the global level, we can witness the reemergence and retrenchment of urban
informality as a way of life (Davis 2006; Roy and AlSayyad 2004; Fischer, McCann, and Auyero
4
2014). The prevalence of informality has also engendered a large body of scholarly literature.
There are different schools for understanding the formation and persistence of informality. In
the section below, I will briefly review each school and present a different perspective to
understand informality from the intentionality and institutional structure of the state.
The first school in the study of urban informality is dualism, featured by Hart’s (1973)
seminal article on economic sectors in Ghana and the International Labor Organization (ILO)’s
(1972) work on Kenya. The dualist approach highlights the differences between the formal and
the informal sectors, with a focus on their different relations to the state. The second school is
structuralism, which focuses on the connection between the formal and the informal sectors. For
instance, Portes, Castells, and Benton (1989: 12) argue that informal economy is an integral part
of the formal economy, differentiated only in that informality is unregulated economic activity
which occurs within a given set of governing institutions that typically regulate similar economic
activities. And finally, the school of legalism conceptualizes informality on a scale of legality,
categorizing economic activities and property rights as legal, extra-legal (informal), and illegal.
As the founder and most prominent scholar of the school, Hernando de Soto (1989: 5) argues
that informality or extra-legality is the result of the “inability to produce capital” which is an
effect of a legal system that lacks formal property rights. The solution according to de Soto
(2000) is for governments to produce reforms geared towards deregulation and privatization
Despite their different theoretical focuses, the three major schools of informality share
the similar view that informality is associated with weak state capacity. The basic assumption is
that the state attempts to provide formal welfare or eliminate informality but fail due to resource
constraints or inadequate control of the bureaucracy. For instance, De Soto (1989) argues that
5
the informal economy is the people’s spontaneous and creative response to the state’s incapacity
to satisfy the basic needs of the impoverished masses. In regard to housing, he contends that it is
the inefficient legal and bureaucratic system that made it difficult for the poor to obtain legal
housing, so that they build their houses on the hillsides or in vacant lots. Similarly, Polidano
(2000) considers the size of informal economies as proxies for state capacity. Chattaraj (2012)’s
work on urban development and informal settlements in Mumbai presents the view that the weak
capacity of the local state in Mumbai leads to insufficient investment in urban infrastructure and
argue that it is the intentionality of the state, rather than the institutional weakness of the state,
that leads to the nonenforcement of laws and in turn increases the level of informality. In order
to explain why laws go unenforced in developing countries, Holland (2016: 232) argues that, in
contexts of inadequate social policy, politicians often withhold sanctions to mobilize voters and
signal their distributive commitments. Her argument is supported by various empirical research
on topics from the regressive consumption taxes in Peru (Jaramillo 2014) to the government’s
tolerance of squatter settlements in Turkey (Keyder 1999) and Zambia (Resnick 2013).
Some studies on urban informality in India echo the literature on state intentionality,
demonstrating the significance of the Indian state in governing the informal sector. In her study
on urban informality in Calcutta, Roy (2004: 159) considers informality as inhering in the state,
that it is the informalized state that allows the unceasing negotiation of land claims, but never the
full resolution of such claims. To explain the durability of slums in Mumbai, Weinstein (2014)
names the strategy of the state “supportive neglect,” arguing that it is the low-cost solution that
6
squatting provided to the critical problem of housing shortage facing the growing industrial city
that explains the state’s willful ignorance of slum formation and proliferation. Using the case of
Delhi, Ghertner (2015) questions conceptions of the Third World megacity that emphasize a lack
of state control and spatial discipline. He focuses on the management of slums in Delhi and
reveals that the state knows and directs its object through an aesthetic normativity, i.e., an
Focusing on the intentionality and preferences of the state, both the general studies on
urban informality and the specific ones on India provide nuanced understanding of the
production, persistence, and governance of informality. However, this literature falls short in
explaining why state intentionality and preferences are formed as such, and more importantly,
why state preferences change over time. Building on the rich literature of state and state-society
relations, I argue that it is the institutional structure of the state that limits state actors’ choices
and shapes their decisions, thus leading to different political decision about the informal sector.
As the literature reveals, the state is not a unitary entity but a complex, fragmented system (Kohli
2012, 2004; Zhang 2013; Migdal, Kohli, and Shue 1994). In order to understand the
construction of state intentionality, we need to first tease out the institutional structure of the
state. In the following section, I examine the two major characteristics of the institutional
structure of the India state and discuss their implications for urban governance.
The institutional structure of the Indian state has two major characteristics relevant to
urban governance. First, the Indian state is fragmented along intergovernmental lines and has a
limited downward reach. While state governments play the central role in urban policymaking
7
and implementation, the role of municipal governments is limited. Second, regional parties have
become key political players in India and there is intense interparty competition. As important
sources of political power and economic vitality, cities have increasingly become major stages of
interparty competition over votes and resources. This section discusses the two characteristics of
the institutional structure of the Indian state as well as their implications for India’s urbanization
Intergovernmental relations, defined as the relations between the central and subnational
levels of government, are an important variable in shaping municipal finance and the process of
administration at the state level, but it lacks fiscal power and autonomy at the municipal level.
Indian mayors are relatively weak compared to their counterparts in other parts of the Global
South, such as China2 and Brazil. The control over urban policymaking and implementation is
As Kohli (2004) insightfully points out, basic patterns of state authority were often
established well before state elites chose to intervene in their respective economies, especially
during the colonial phase. The limited role of the local state has its root in the modern Indian
state formation, which is a product of both colonial construction and nationalist modification. In
the colonial era, the British rulers constantly imposed political centralization in India. After the
2
While China is a centralized state, municipal governments in China have a high level of autonomy. This is largely
due to the fact that the selection of mayors is controlled by the Chinese Communist Party. All big city mayors are
party members and hold important positions in the party. In other words, they are chosen and therefore trusted by
the party. Meanwhile, besides the executive line, there is a party line in each municipality. The party boss have a
more superior position than the mayor and controls the direction of urban policy. The two arrangements make it
possible for the party state to devolve significant autonomy to municipal governments.
8
British Crown took over power from the East India Company in 1857, control of India was
further centralized in London in the hands of the Secretary of State for India. An elite civil
Despite the centralized control at the apex, the colonial state’s downward reach to the
local level was limited due to the ruling alliance between the colonizers and traditional Indian
elite. To effectively govern a large country like India, the British needed local allies to wield
influence and provide local knowledge, so that they adopted the strategy to ally with and
strengthen the position of traditional Indian elites, including Indian princes, landlords, and other
local notables. As long as the local elite were able to collect revenues or taxes and to maintain
order within their domains, the British allowed them considerable latitude on their territories
(Kohli 2004). The result was limited penetration of the colonial state. While the colonial state
was autocratic and bureaucratic at the apex, state authority below the apex was fragmented into
India’s nationalist movement of the 20th century successfully ended the colonial rule, but
did not make fundamental change to the colonial state structure. The core of the state that the
Indian National Congress (INC) inherited and maintained was essentially the colonial construct
(Kohli 2004). Ironically, while the nationalist made demands to the British to decentralize state
power during the colonial era, which was never permitted, they themselves shielded away from
decentralization reform after came into power. Due to the lack of decentralization, urban local
governments in India were considered creatures of the state government, which could extend or
control their functions through executive decisions rather than legislation (Mathur 2007; Pethe
2011; Pethe et al. 2010). Most cities were governed, planned, and financed through line
9
The autonomy of the local state in urban areas was formally enhanced by the 74th
Amendments to the Indian Constitution of 1992 that established a third tier of government below
the subnational level (Acolin, Chattaraj, and Wachter 2016). Following the 74th Amendment, the
central government launched the Jawaharlal Nehru National Urban Renewal Mission
decentralization. One of the mandatory reforms under the JNNURM is the implementation of
the decentralization initiatives articulated in the 74th Amendment, in order to increase the
responsibility and authority of elected municipal governments over urban planning and decision-
Despite the formal legislative changes, the implementation of decentralization has been
left to the discretion of state governments, and the situation varies from state to state. In general,
there is little evidence that powers have been decentralized to municipal governments to a
significant extent. Various studies show that, in major cities, the state government has
consolidated rather than devolved powers over urban development and planning as control over
urban land becomes increasingly important for political power and resources (Acolin, Chattaraj,
and Wachter 2016; Mathur 2007; Chattaraj 2012). Municipalities still suffer from the short of
autonomy, mainly responsible for the delivery of local services and local-level planning.
Meanwhile, there is a significant level of overlap between state-level parastatal agencies and
municipal governments in the area of urban planning and development. Such a system of urban
governance, land-use control, and infrastructure development has been unable to meet the
increased demand for housing and other infrastructure in the process of rapid urbanization
10
Similar to other Indian cities, Mumbai is governed by a complex multi-level
governmental system and the autonomy of the municipal government is limited (Segbers 2007).
The management of Mumbai is divided among three political bodies, including the Municipal
Corporation of Greater Mumbai, the State of Maharashtra, and the government of India. The
central government wields power over the city in terms of its financial powers and its overall
economic planning structures through various Five Year Plans. The Municipal Corporation of
Greater Mumbai has a long history in India, but its power is still limited to only certain
administrative issues, including sanitation, sewerage, school education, and bus transport. On all
key issues pertaining to the city, including economic development, land and housing, slum
redevelopment, and law and order, the state government has the decisive power.
To exercise its power over the city, the state government has set up autonomous public-
sector corporations. The most important ones include the Maharashtra Housing and Area
(MMRDA). While the MHADA constructs houses in Mumbai and other cities in the region, the
MMRDA has an overall planning role for the region, determining the form the city should
assume into the future. Meanwhile, MMRDA is empowered to coordinate a number of projects
such as the Mumbai Urban Infrastructure Project, the Mumbai Urban Transport Project, and the
Backbay Reclamation area. The chairs of both authorities are appointed by the state government.
In 1997, the Government of Maharashtra created the Slum Redevelopment Authority (SRA) as
the central agency to lead slum redevelopment in Mumbai. As the following sections
11
Multiparty System and Interparty Competition: Mobilizing the Grassroots
Intertwined with the structure of the fragmented state is the multiparty system and
interparty competition. While the Congress Party ran the entire country in the first two decades
after Independence, it started to decline in the late sixties and saw the rise of regional political
parties. In today’s India, there are seven national parties and 48 regional parties. The regional
parties have become key political players in India and they are actively pursuing control over the
state governments, which in turn increases the political centrality of states in Indian politics. In
Maharashtra and Mumbai, the main competition is between the centrist Congress-I and the
center-right Shiv Sena, a regional party. While the Congress-I and its coalition partners have
been long in power at the state level, the Shiv Sena and its allies have usually led the
administration in Mumbai (Mukhija 2016). As the following sections of the paper demonstrate,
the interparty competition has largely shaped the policy of slum redevelopment in Mumbai.
One of the most important targets of interparty competition are voters. In order to
achieve this goal, parties are making constant efforts to reach and mobilize constituency at the
grassroots level. They mobilize voters through the reciprocal, yet asymmetric clientelistic
relationship between politicians and citizens, in which votes are exchanged for goods, jobs, and
protection. In studies on developing democracies across the globe, scholars have documented
that political parties seek to mobilize the urban poor by providing them with patronage and social
services (Thachil 2014; Calvo and Murillo 2004; Gonzalez-Ocantos et al. 2012; Nichter 2008;
Stokes 2005). Chatterjee (2004) coined the term “political society” to describe the political
relationship between most of the Indian inhabitants and governmental agencies pursuing multiple
policies of security and welfare. While his work is mainly based on India, it provides insights to
12
It is important to note that Indian political parties, especially regional parties, demonstrate
a strong need and capability of mobilizing voters in the urban areas. Compared to rural
population, urban population is characterized by higher levels of diversity and mobility. Hence,
it is impossible for politicians to rely on stable social structures or groups, as they do in rural
areas. On the other hand, due to the higher population density and more regulated spatial
arrangement of urban areas, it is easier for politicians to reach out to local communities in the
urban areas than the rural areas. These two conditions, as Auerbach (2013: 95-96) emphasizes,
have both compelled and allowed parties to extend their reach deep into the neighborhoods,
In Mumbai, parties have a deep downward reach at the community level. As the rest of
the paper shows, slum dwellers in Mumbai have become a major constituency in the state and
city’s competitive electoral politics. To attract votes, political parties invest time and effort in
building partisan leadership in slums, incorporating slum leaders into the party machine, and
providing patronage and infrastructural improvement to slum dwellers (Auerbach 2013: 92).
In sum, this section discusses the two major characteristics of the institutional structure of
the Indian state, namely, the fragmented intergovernmental relations with the consolidation of
state power and the rise of regional political parties and intense interparty competition in
electoral politics. The characteristics have the following implications for the process of
governments that control the power of urban policy making and implementation. Despite the
increased importance of cities in Indian economy and politics, urban areas are not the sole focus
of state governments. Hence, this power arrangement may lead to a policy orientation that
13
deprioritizes urbanization and undermines the general interests of cities, thus preventing
to reach and mobilize voters at the grassroots level, thus may increase the interdependence
between parties and the urban poor whose needs cannot be met in the policy agenda that
deprioritize urbanization. Third, interparty competition and electoral policies may shape urban
policies and generate uncertainty in the trajectory of urbanization. The following sections
elaborate how the institutional structure of the India state has affected the proliferation and
scarcity of land, dictated by Mumbai’s peculiar geography and heightened by the competition
from other economic activities, is one factor that has made formal housing unaffordable for most
function of a series of restrictive rent control and land use policies that aim to constrain the pace,
scale, and density of urbanization. Unlike China where urbanization is one of its top priorities to
absorb surplus rural labor and ensure economic growth, India has only recently made
urbanization a priority on its development agenda, and there is still support in India to limit
urbanization.3 For a long time, the general interests of the Indian cities had been overlooked and
marginalized by policymakers at the state level. As a reflection of the policy orientation that
deprioritizes urbanization, the restrictive rent control and land use policies effectively
3
There are different arguments why rural activities should be more favored than urbanization. See, for example,
Mishra (2013).
14
disincentivized the private sector in creating rental and affordable housing units in urban areas,
thus pushing large numbers of urban inhabitants into the informal housing market.
One of the most important policies that have restricted the supply of affordable housing
in Mumbai is the rent control policy. Rent control has been destructive for the housing market as
it has led to the emergence of primarily only two types of housing: the first is expensive housing
for the upper and upper middle class, and the other is slum housing for the majority of the urban
population. The policy neglects inflation rates, does not provide incentives for maintenance of
rental property, and fails to offer reasonable returns to landlords. As a result, there has been a
lack of investment in rental housing market and severe dilapidation of existing rent-controlled
units (Patel 2005, 2013). Rent control has exacerbated the problem of affordable housing,
making it extremely difficult for middle- or low-income families to find housing options on the
formal market.
Rent control was first introduced in India in the post-World War I era. While the initial
goal of the policy is to protect the tenants from inflation and eviction, it does not take into
account the conditions for the growth of a healthy rental market and its role in urbanization. It
reflects that policy makers at the state level have largely overlooked the general interest of the
city and lacked a long-term vision for urban development (Dev and Dey 2006). In 1947, the
state passed the Bombay Rents, Hotel and Lodging House Rates Control Act (Bombay Rent Act
of 1947). Under this Act, rents in rent-controlled properties were to remain at or below standard
rents. These standard rents were either determined by the Court or the Controller or they were
the rents at which properties were let on September 1, 1940. The Rent Control Act severely
15
restricted the growth rate of rents and provided minimal increases in rents even if landlords
In 1999, the Maharashtra Rent Control Act was passed by the state government. It
continued the terms of the 1947 Rent Control Act and applied them to the entire state (Gandhi et
al. 2013). According to several detailed reports on the rent control policy created by the
in Mumbai were protected under rent control, and buildings for residential purposes accounted
for 75 percent of total units (Gandhi et al. 2013). These restrictive policies discouraged
landlords to construct rental housing. Meanwhile, neither the state nor the central government
was able to provide sufficient affordable housing to urban residents. As a result, a large section
of the population has been pushed out of the formal housing market forced into the informal
housing sector.
Rent control in Mumbai has not only disincentivized the construction of new rental units,
but also led to the deterioration of the existing rental housing units (Bertaud 2011). The
deterioration is particularly salient in so-called cessed buildings. These buildings were mostly
constructed before 1969, with many of them constructed before 1940, by private landowners as
rental housing (Gandhi et al 2013). Since rent in these buildings has been freezing since 1947,
landlords have little incentive to repair or maintain their properties. As a result, living conditions
in these buildings deteriorated over years. To deal with the continuing dilapidation of rent
controlled properties, the state government set up the Mumbai Building Repairs and
Reconstruction Board. The duty of the Board is to collects a ‘cess’ (tax) from rents and use it to
repair and improve the conditions of these buildings. However, the progress of renovation has
been very slow. Most rent-controlled buildings continue to deteriorate (Gandhi et al. 2013).
16
Floor Space Index: The Effort to Control Urban Density
In order to control urban population growth, the Mumbai Development Plan began to
control the density of built-up areas in the island city in 1964. However, urban planners and
policy makers largely ignored the fact that population growth in cities is not dictated by building
control regulations, but a function of economic opportunities. Without systematic public policies
to provide affordable housing, slums began to proliferate in the city. In 1967, the concept of
Floor Space Index (FSI) was formally introduced in Mumbai as a tool to control the tenement
density (MTSU 2015). FSI is measured by the ratio of a building’s total floor area to the size of
Under the impact of the FSI and other density control rules, developers are only
interested in building large-sized tenements as these tenements allow them to make full use of
permissible FSI and maximize profit. The Urban Land Ceiling and Regulation Act was passed in
1976. It puts several tracts of land under litigation and therefore further restricted the supply of
large tracts of land for housing construction (MTSU 2015). Various studies show that these
restrictive development policies have pushed the city’s property value to constantly go higher
The above discussion reveals the housing shortage and large-scale slum proliferation in
Mumbai are closely related to the restrictive rent and land development policies. Made in the
institutional context of a fragmented state with limited local authority, these policies reflect the
policy orientation at the state level that deprioritizes urbanization. The policies overlooked the
general interests of the cities and lacked a long-term vision for urban growth. Paradoxically,
while 5.2 million people live in slums, 0.318 million (16%) of the total 1.935 million housing
units in Mumbai are unoccupied (Gandhi et al. 2013; MTSU 2015). A large number of city
17
residents are deprived of housing options on the formal market and forced to enter the informal
housing sector. As a former official of the Maharashtra Housing and Area Development
Authority put it, “The endless expansion of slums in Mumbai indicates a policy failure.”4
The previous section demonstrates that the policy orientation to deprioritize urbanization,
as a result of the fragmented intergovernmental relations with limited municipal authority, led to
the employment of the rent control and restrictive land development policies, and these policies
play a critical role in the formation of slums. Following the discussion of the formation of
slums, this section explains the persistence of slums in Mumbai by highlighting the impact of
India’s party politics. Specifically, it demonstrates how electoral politics stabilizes the existence
of slums by enhancing the physical conditions and organizational capacity of slums through
clientelism.
The rise of regional parties and interparty competition require politicians to mobilize
voters at the grassroots level. This feature of the institutional structure of the Indian state gives
slums an important place in India’s electoral politics. Auerbach (2013: 97) explains the intimate
connections between slum dwellers and political parties as follows: “Slum dwellers are a key
demographic focus of political parties. Politicians know that effort in building a following in a
slum has far higher returns than in a secure, wealthier neighborhood. These latter areas already
have been provided basic infrastructure and services, and residents are less likely to be cajoled
by petty patronage.” In other words, it is largely the votes of slum dwellers that determine who
wins the election. Slums have an especially important position at the state and municipal level
4
Interview with a former official of the Maharashtra Housing and Area Development Authority, January 8, 2016.
18
elections, where a locality’s vote could be particularly influential in determining the outcomes of
election.
To capture the votes of slum dwellers, politicians allow new settlements to arise and
legalize illegal settlements wherever there has been a protest against eviction. For example, the
decision in late 2001 to clear slums immediately adjacent to Mumbai’s international airport was
not implemented because of the effect it would have upon voting in the coming municipal
elections in early 2002 (Sharma 2001). When a new slum emerges, the first thing politicians
would do is to help slum dwellers register as voters.5 Meanwhile, they periodically provide
patronage to slum dwellers during election seasons. Patronage goods have two major forms:
private and “more broad-based club goods” (Auerbach 2013: 94). Private goods are distributed
to individuals and broadly include “money, liquor, jobs, pensions, or government ration cards,”
whereas club goods target at the entire settlement and include “roads, streetlights, sewer lines,
Various studies show the strong connection between votes a slum offers and the
development of the area. If a slum offers a politician more votes, it receives more infrastructural
development and service in return (Auerbach 2016; Weinstein 2014; Srinivas 1955). Roy (2004:
149) provides detailed analysis of how the cadres of the dominant local Communist Party of
India Marxist in Calcutta engaged in a constant search for new voters and new territories of
support in squatter settlements. She argues that such a pattern implies a constant recharging of
patronage, and not surprisingly, “before each major election, the colonies are treated to
infrastructural improvements, such as the provision of qausi-legal electricity and the paving of
roads.” It is a regime created through the “coupling of party and state, the combining of informal
5
Interview with the president of Society for the Promotion of Area Resource Centers, January 9, 2016. Interview
with slum dwellers in Mahila Milan Nagar, January 9, 2016.
19
party tactics of mobilization with the formal state apparatus of infrastructure provision” (Roy
2004: 149).
Besides the provision of infrastructural improvements during regular election seasons, the
allocation of special funds is closely related to how slum dwellers caste their votes. The special
funds include discretionary budgets at the municipal, state, and national levels, as well as
resources provided by various slum development and poverty alleviation programs, such as the
Basic Services for the Urban Poor, Jawaharlal Nehru National Urban Renewal Mission, and
Rajiv Awas Yojana. As Auerbach (2013: 44) explained in his work, since the resources are
scarce, it is important for elected representative and officials to prioritize some slums over others.
The major criteria for allocating the funds are whether the slums can provide support to the
In order to increase voter turnout, distribute patronage, and monitor the electoral behavior
of residents, politicians need to build hierarchical organizational networks in slums (Hicken 2011;
Kitschelt and Wilkinson 2007; Brusco et al. 2004; Calvo and Murillo 2004; Stokes 2005; Nichter
2008). These networks provide day-to-day connections between political parties and slum
dwellers. In the process of interacting with politicians, some community members rise to the top
as slum leaders and they bargain with politicians for development on behalf of the whole
community. While the extension of party organizational networks is highly uneven across slum
settlements in India (Auerbach 2016), the informal leadership serves two major functions. On
the one hand, the social obligation pushes leaders into providing services and fighting for the
improvement of the settlement, thus enhancing and stabilizing the physical conditions of the
slums. On the other, the existence of the informal leadership increases the strength of the slums
20
in social mobilization and organization, and therefore stabilizing the social conditions of the
slums.
This section demonstrates that party politics plays a critical role in the stabilization and
institutionalization of slums. First, politicians granted slum dwellers the rights to stay and
brought incremental improvement of their living conditions in order to garner votes. Second, the
party networks in slums enhance the organizational capacity and social strength of slums. The
political exchange between political parities and urban residents largely institutionalizes existing
slums and provides incentives for the creation of new ones. While the arrangement may be
considered as the Indian state’s informal welfare provision, it cannot cover up the precarious and
dangerous living conditions of slum dwellers, nor does it solve the problem of housing shortage
in Mumbai.
Under the arrangement of political exchange, slum dwellers’ “access to basic goods and
services is mediated, conditional on political support, and brokered through complex, vertical
networks of intermediaries and community leaders” (Auerbach 2013: 49). Roy (2004: 150) calls
the governance model in slums “a regime reproduced through uncertainty.” In other words, “the
the lack of legal land title makes slum dwellers depend on politicians and political parties.
However, the formalization of property rights does not prevent political parties from maintaining
clientelistic connections with former slum dwellers. I will further elaborate this point in the next
21
The Redevelopment of Slums: A Battlefield of Political Interests
The previous two sections explained the formation and persistence of slums. The
following section will investigate the processes and impacts of state intervention in slums. In
Mumbai, the government’s responses to slums have gone through several changes. This section
discusses the changes in state intervention and their varied consequences, with a focus on the
interparty competition and serves the purpose to increase political support and revenue. The
project does not reduce former slum dwellers’ dependency on political parties and patronage
networks despite the formalization of property rights and service provision. Instead of
improving socioeconomic equality among urban residents, the project of slum redevelopment
In the 1950s and 1960s, the initial government reaction was to clear slums and rehouse
slum dwellers in subsidized rental housing in alternative locations. For instance, in 1956, the
central government approved the Slum Clearance Plan, and Mumbai was one of the six pilot
cities covered under this scheme (MTSU 2015). This approach did not succeed due to the
shortage of resources to build and maintain housing stocks and the lack of political will to do so.
Meanwhile, it was realized that slum dwellers contribute significantly to the local economy, so
In the 1970s and 1980s, the government changed its approach from slum clearance to
slum upgrading upgrade. The Slum Improvement Programmes were implemented under the
Maharashtra Slum Areas (Improvement, Clearance and Redevelopment) Act. The approach of
22
the program is to provide basic services, primary health and education to slum dwellers. The
World Bank assisted project called Mumbai Urban Development Project (MUDP) was
implemented during 1985-1994. Besides upgrading the physical conditions of slums and
improving basic services, MUDP offered a thirty-year renewable leasehold tenure to the Co-
operative Housing Societies (CHS) of slum dwellers on cost recovery basis (Mukhija 2016;
MTSU 2015). Despite the innovative nature of the programs, the scale of the programs at this
Slum Redevelopment
After the previous two phases of slum clearance and slum upgrading, the state
government initiated a more radical approach of slum redevelopment, which was significantly
interparty competition affected the approach of slum redevelopment in Mumbai. In the election
of the Maharashtra state assembly in 1990, the Shiv Sena’s leader made an election promise that
if his party won the election it would provide “free housing” to Mumbai’s slum dwellers. While
the Shiv Sena lost the election to an alliance led by the Congress-I, its campaign promise
significantly influenced the new state government led by the Congress-I. The state government
introduced a market-driven model in 1992 and invited private developers to redevelop the city’s
slums. Slum dwellers needed to pay a part of the construction cost in order to be resettled. The
government also placed a cap on developers’ profit. The project was not fully implemented
In 1995, the Shiv Sena won the Maharashtra state assembly elections for the first time,
and started to implement its plan of slum redevelopment. Under the new redevelopment scheme,
23
private developers can purchase slum land from the government at a relatively low price —
25 percent of the fair market value of the land. The cap on profit was removed. The
Government of Maharashtra created the Slum Redevelopment Authority (SRA) in 1997, as the
agency responsible for evaluating and approving slum redevelopment proposals submitted by
According to the model, the developer must obtain the consent of 70 percent of the slum
dwellers in the community to start the redevelopment. After purchasing the slum land and
obtaining the consent of slum dwellers, the developer will clear the land and rehouse the eligible
slum dwellers free of cost in multistory-building tenements of 269 square feet (upgraded from
225 square feet) carpet area per household. Only slum dwellers who have documents to prove
that they have been living in the slum prior to the cut-off date of January 1, 2000, are eligible for
The rehabilitation buildings are on a part of the land occupied by the slum. This kind of
in-situ arrangement is due to the fact that politicians do not want to lose their “vote banks” after
slum redevelopment.7 The previous section introduced Roy’s (2004: 150) argument that “the
managed to maintain former slum dwellers’ political obedience through the in-situ arrangement.
As the rest of the section shows, clientelistic relations are still active in the communities after
slum redevelopment, even though redevelopment brings the formalization of property rights and
services.
Besides providing in-situ relocation housing to slum dwellers for free, the developer has
to deposit 20,000 rupees per tenement as maintenance deposit to the Co-operative Housing
6
The original cut-off date was January 1, 1995. It was later extended to January 1, 2000.
7
Interview with the chief of Social Development Cell, Mumbai Metropolitan Region Development Authority,
January 5, 2016.
24
Societies of the slum dwellers. The residents are not allowed to transfer the free housing in ten
years (Mukhija 2016; MTSU 2015). In return, the developer can construct market-rate housing
on the rest of the slum land and sell them, which not only recovers the cost but can results in
high profits. A developer reveals the profit rate of slum redevelopment can be as high as 200
percent.8
Through this model, some of Mumbai’s most prominent real estate development projects
have been built on former slum land. One of the most high-profile examples are Imperial
Designed by Mumbai architect Hafeez Contractor as his most recognizable project, the Imperial
Towers are among the tallest buildings in Mumbai and one of the most expensive real estate
projects in India. Inaugurated in 2010, the towers were built on former slum land where the
current model of slum redevelopment was first put into large-scale practice. While the twin
towers are built on the same lot as the rehabilitation building, there are completely separate
entrances to get even close to the two different properties, divided by a wall. On the wall of the
hallway right outside the management office prints the words of Angelo Bonati, CEO of luxury
Swiss watch brand Panerai, “Luxury is attention to detail, originality, exclusivity, and above all
quality.” The average size of a unit in the Imperial Towers is 4,000 square feet at a price of 3-5
million US dollars. According to the property manager, most units are sold out.9
Even after slum redevelopment, clientelism still plays a critical role for residents to have
their needs met in terms of infrastructural development and service provision. This is facilitated
by the fact that the rehabilitation of slum dwellers is in-situ, so that their clientelistic relations
with the local politicians are maintained. During my fieldwork in Mumbai in January 2016, I
8
Interview with a Mumbai-based developer, January 7, 2016.
9
Interview with the manager of Sales and Marketing, Shapoorji Pallonji Group, January 13, 2016.
25
went to a rehabilitation building with an engineer of SRA and his assistant. They made the visit
because they received phone calls from the party leader of the area about the problem of water
leakage in the building. When we arrived, a party worker was already there waiting with many
residents. He apparently played the role of a leader among the crowds. He took us into three
units, explained the problem to us, and urged the SRA officials to solve the problem as soon as
possible.
After the visit, the engineer revealed to me that they would have not come to the building
so promptly if the party leader had not called their office.10 While the clientelistic relations
between politicians and slum dwellers in India are well documented in a rich body of literature
(Auerbach 2013: 45; Roy 2004; Weinstein 2014), the telling aspect of the story is that such
relations have remained even after slum redevelopment. Despite the fact that slum
redevelopment leads to the formalization of property rights and service provision, it does not
reduce the political dependency of former slum dwellers to political parties. This raises serious
questions about the model of slum redevelopment and its impact on inequality.
The market-dominant model of slum redevelopment has several problems. First, the
direct negotiation between slum dwellers and developers often leads to rent seeking and vicious
competition between developers. Second, the model does not provide specific standards on the
buildings are designed and constructed in a way that compromises the living standards of
inhabitants and are becoming “vertical slums.” This problem, as the previous paragraph shows,
reinforces former slum dwellers’ impendence on politicians. Third, because of the cut-off date
for eligibility of rehabilitation, the ineligible population is left with no option but to stay in
unauthorized manner in slums. Many of them have to settle in a new slum after their previous
10
Interview with an engineer of SRA, January 13, 2016.
26
slum is demolished by the government. Fourth, the model provides free housing to slum
dwellers, and developers have to load the cost of rehabilitation on the saleable component. Such
an approach does not encourage the construction of housing at various price levels and ultimately
leads to the increase of housing prices on the formal market. Fifth, the model is built on market
return, so that slums that are not financially attractive are left behind. Some developers
suggested that nearly fifty percent of the slums, i.e. most of the remaining slums in the city, may
The process of slum redevelopment is slow and fraught with conflicts. In the past two
decades, 0.15 million tenements have been rehabilitated in this model, against the target of 1
million in the first decade. Another 0.12 million tenements have been approved for rehabilitation,
but construction is yet to begin (MTSU 2015). In an interview with the chief executive officer of
SRA, he reveals that SRA will expedite the process by giving slum dwellers an ultimatum to
select a developer to work with. If they fail to do so before the required date, SRA would
mechanism to protect the interest of slum dwellers in the process of redevelopment is the
requirement of their consent in order to start the project. By depriving them the opportunity to
approve or reject redevelopment proposals, the plan may undermine the interest of slum dwellers
Conclusion
Through the case study of the informal housing sector in Mumbai, the paper demonstrates
that the institutional structure of the state is deeply consequential for the trajectory of
27
relations and limited power of the municipal governments not only leads to insufficient
investment in urban infrastructure and housing but also creates a policy orientation that
deprioritizes urbanization, which led to the creation of a series of restrictive land development
policies. These policies dismantled the rental market and disincentivized the private sector in
housing construction, thus pushing a large number of the urban residents into the informal
housing market and causing the proliferation of slums. The rise of the regional political parties
and intense interparty competition, on the other hand, motivate politicians to mobilize voters at
the grassroots level, thus strengthening the interdependence between parties and slum dwellers.
By offering slum dwellers infrastructural improvements and building informal leadership in the
communities in exchange for votes, political parties help stabilize and institutionalize the slums.
Meanwhile, the consolidation of state power over land development and the interparty
competition has significantly shaped the programs of slum redevelopment, turning them into
tools for politicians to garner continuing political support and increase revenue.
The paper contributes to the study of urban informality is two major ways. First, it
provides a theoretical framework for understanding the role of the state in the production and
governance of informality. It reveals that it is not the incapability or inefficiency of the state, but
the rational choice of the state to reserve the informal settlements as they serve the interests and
preferences of political actors. More importantly, and different from most existing studies on
urban informality, the paper teases out the institutional structure of the state and demonstrates
how the form of state authority shapes the intentionality of state actors and in turn affect the
policy decisions about the informal sector. Second, building on the understanding of the intricate
relations between the state and the informal sector, the paper challenges the dichotomy between
the formal and the informal. It suggests that informality has become the new normal in emerging
28
cities, and that urban policy should reflect this notion in order to create more livable and
inclusive cities. These findings not only contribute to our understanding of the proliferation and
persistence of slums in Mumbai, but also illuminate the factors underlying the informal
The Government of Maharashtra has set a goal to make Mumbai slum-free by 2022. This
is an ambitious goal given the current pace of slum redevelopment. What is more important than
the pace of intervention are the motivation and approach of intervention. In Mumbai, slum
redevelopment is motivated by interparty competition and serves the purpose to increase political
support and revenue. The project does not reduce former slum dwellers’ dependency on political
parties and patronage networks despite the formalization of property rights and service provision;
hence, it creates a symbolic formalization. Smith (2002) argues that the urbanization of
slum redevelopment is a good case in point to demonstrate this point. Through the redistribution
of land and housing, the project can potentially reduce the high socioeconomic inequality in the
society. However, as the paper shows, the project does not reduce inequality or enhance political
The following policy recommendations can be made in order to improve the process and
redevelopment and guarantee the quality of rehabilitation units, the SRA should act as a planner,
facilitator, and anchor, not nearly as an approving authority that completely takes backseat in the
process. Second, under the current model of slum redevelopment, the housing stock being
created in the market outside of the rehabilitation component is mostly in the luxury or high-cost
segment, which is not catering to the demand for affordable housing of the low- and middle-
29
income groups of the population. The government should more systematically create housing
stock for low- and middle-income groups. Third, the current regressive rent control policy has
prohibited private landowners from creating more rental housing or investing in repairing and
maintaining existing rental units. The government must create an enabling environment to
revitalize the Mumbai rental market, both private and public. Fourth, it is critical to empower
the municipal government in slum redevelopment. While the vision and support of the national
and state governments are important in regional and metropolitan development, to streamline the
governance structure and enhance the autonomy of the local state is indispensible for improving
the quality of land development, housing, and other urban policy issues in Mumbai as well as
30
References
Acolin, Authur, Shahana Chattaraj, and Susan M. Wachter. 2016. “Urban Governance and
Development of Informality in China and India.” In Eugenie L. Birch, Shahana Chattaraj,
and Susan M. Wachter eds. Slums: How Informal Real Estate Markets Work.
Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, pp. 4-23.
Auerbach, Adam. 2016. “Clients and Communities: The Political Economy of Party Network
Organization and Development in India’s Urban Slums.” World Politics, 68 (1): 111-148.
Bertaud, Alain. 2011. “Mumbai FAR/FSI Conundrum: The Perfect Storm: the Four Factors
Restricting the Construction of New Floor Space in Mumbai.”
Brusco, Valeria, Marcelo Nazareno, and Susan Stokes. 2004. “Vote Buying in Argentina.” Latin
American Research Review, vol. 39, pp. 66-88.
Calvo, Ernesto and Maria Victoria Murillo. 2004. “Who Delivers? Partisan Clients in the
Argentine Electoral Market.” American Journal of Political Science, 48 (4): 742-757.
Chattaraj, Shahana. 2012. Shanghai Dreams: Urban Restructuring din Globalizing Mumbai.
Ph.D. dissertation, Princeton University.
Chatterjee, Partha. 2004. Politics of the Governed: Popular Politics in Most of the World. New
York: Columbia University Press.
Davis, Mike. 2006. Planet of Slums. London and New York: Verso.
De Soto, Hernando. 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and
Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books.
--------. 1989. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. New York: Harper &
Row.
Dev, Satvik and Pramila Datta Dey. 2006. “Rent Control Laws in India: A Critical Analysis,
NIUA WP 06-04.” New Delhi: NIUA.
Dowall, David. 1992. The Benefits of Minimal Development Regulation. Habitat International
16 (4): 15-26.
Fischer, Brodwyn, Bryan McCann, and Javier Auyero eds. 2014. Cities From Scratch: Poverty
and Informality in Urban Latin America. Durham, North Carolina: Duke University
Press.
31
Gandhi, Sahil, Shirish Patel, Abhay Pethe, Vaidehi Tandel and Kabir Agarwal. 2013.
“Reforming Rent Control in Mumbai: Moving Towards Second Generation Controls.”
Department of Economics, University of Mumbai, Working Paper No. 48.
Ghertner, D. Asher. 2015. Rule by Aesthetics: World-Class City Making in Delhi. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Gonzalez-Ocantos, Ezequiel, Chad Kiewiet de Jonge, Carlos Melendez, Javier Osorio, and David
W. Nickerson. 2012. “Vote Buying and Social Desirability Bias: Experimental Evidence
from Nicaragua.” American Journal of Political Science, 56 (1): 202-217.
Hart, Keith. 1973. “Informal Income Opportunities and Urban Employment in Ghana.” Modern
African Studies 11 (1): 61-89.
Hicken, Allen. 2011. “Clientelism.” Annual Review of Political Science, vol. 14, pp. 289-310.
International Labour Office (ILO). 1972. Employment, Incomes and Equality: Strategy for
Increasing Productive Employment in Kenya. Geneva: International Labour Office.
Jaramillo, Miguel. 2014. “The Incidence of Social Spending and Taxes in Peru.” Public Finance
Review 42 (3): 391-412.
Keyder, Çağlar. 1999. Istanbul: Between the Global and the Local. New York: Rowman &
Littlefield.
Kitschelt, Herbert and Steven Wilkinson. 2007. Patrons, Clients, and Policies: Patterns of
Democratic Accountability and Political Competition. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Kohli, Atul. 2012. Poverty Amid Plenty in the New India. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
--------. 2004. State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global
Periphery. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mathur, Mukesh. 2007. Impact of the Constitution (74th Amendment) Act on the Working of
Urban Local Bodies. New Delhi: NIUA.
Migdal, Joel, Atul Kohli, and Vivienne Shue eds. 1994. State Power and Social Forces:
Domination and Transformation in the Third World. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Mishra, Pankaj. 2013. “India’s Path to Prosperity Doesn’t Run Through Cities.” Bloomberg
View, August 8. https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2013-08-11/india-s-path-to-
prosperity-doesn-t-run-through-cities.
32
Mukhija, Vinit. 2016. “Rehousing Mumbai: Formalizing Slum Land Markets Through
Redevelopment.” In Eugenie L. Birch, Shahana Chattaraj, and Susan M. Wachter eds.
Slums: How Informal Real Estate Markets Work. Philadelphia: University of
Pennsylvania Press, pp. 125-139.
Nichter, Simeon. 2008. “Vote Buying or Turnout Buying? Machine Politics and the Secret
Ballot.” American Political Science Review, 102 (1): 19-31.
Patel, Shirish. 2005. “Housing Policies for Mumbai.” Economic and Political Weekly, 40 (33):
3669-76.
--------. 2013. “Life between Buildings: The Use and Abuse of FSI.” Economic and Political
Weekly, 48 (36): 68-74.
Pethe, Abhay. 2011. “Metropolitan Public Finances: The Case of Mumbai.” Department of
Economics, University of Mumbai, Working Paper No. 41.
Pethe, Abhay, Sahil Gandhi, and Vaidehi Tandel. 2010. “Assessing the Situation in Mumbai
Metropolitan Region: A Governance Perspective.” Department of Economics, University
of Mumbai, Working Paper No. 38.
Polidano, Charles. 2000. “Measuring Public Sector Capacity.” World Development 28 (5): 805-
22.
Portes, Alejandro, Manuel Castells, and Lauren A. Benton eds. 1989. The Informal Economy:
Studies in Advance and Less Developed Countries. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University
Press.
Resnick, Danielle. 2013. Urban Poverty and Party Populism in African Democracies. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Roy, Ananya. 2004. “The Gentlemen’s City: Urban Informality in the Calcutta of New
Communism.” In Ananya Roy and Nezar AlSayyad eds. Urban Informality:
Transnational Perspectives from the Middle East, Latin America, and South Asia.
Oxford, UK: Lexington Books, pp. 147-170.
Roy, Ananya and Nezar AlSayyad eds. 2004. Urban Informality: Transnational Perspectives
from the Middle East, Latin America, and South Asia. Oxford, UK: Lexington Books.
Segbers, Klaus ed. 2007. The Making of Global City Regions: Johannesburg, Mumbai/Bombay,
São Paulo, and Shanghai. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
33
Sharma, Archana. 2001. “Politicians Did Not Want to Alienate Airport Slum Dwellers before
Civic Polls.” Times of India (Mumbai), 7 December 2001, 7.
Smith, Neil. 2002. “New Globalism, New Urbanism: Gentrification as Global Urban Strategy.”
Antipode, 34 (3): 427-450.
Srinivas, M. N. 1955. “The Social System of a Mysore Village.” In M. Marriott, ed., Village
India. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1-35.
Stokes, Susan. 2005. “Perverse Accountability: A Formal Model of Machine Politics with
Evidence from Argentina.” American Political Science Review, 99 (3): 315-325.
Thachil, Tariq. 2014. Elite Parties, Poor Voters: How Social Services Win Votes in India. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
UN-Habitat. 2009. Global Report on Human Settlements 2009 – Planning Sustainable Cities.
London: Earthscan.
Weinstein, Liza. 2014. The Durable Slum: Dharavi and the Right to Stay Put in Globalizing
Mumbai. Minnesota: University of Minnesota Press.
Zhang, Yue. 2013: The Fragmented Politics of Urban Preservation: Beijing, Chicago, and Paris.
Minnesota: University of Minnesota Press.
34