9 - CH10 - Monopoly
9 - CH10 - Monopoly
9 - CH10 - Monopoly
As Q is increased from zero, profit will increase until it reaches a maximum and then begin
to decrease. Thus the profit-maximizing Q is such that the incremental profit resulting from
a small increase in Q is just zero (i.e., Δπ /ΔQ = 0). Then
But ΔR/ΔQ is marginal revenue and ΔC/ΔQ is marginal cost. Thus the profit-maximizing
condition is that
MR − MC = 0, or MR = MC
FIGURE 10.3
Part (a) shows total revenue R, total cost C, and profit, the difference
between the two.
Part (b) shows average and marginal revenue and average and
marginal cost.
At this output level, the slope of the profit curve is zero, and the
slopes of the total revenue and total cost curves are equal.
The profit per unit is $15, the difference between average revenue
and average cost. Because 10 units are produced, total profit is $150.
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd, All Rights Reserved
10.1 Monopoly (6 of 15)
A Rule of Thumb for Pricing
With limited knowledge of average and marginal revenue, we can derive a rule of thump
that can be more easily applied in practice. First, write the expression for marginal revenue:
Note that the extra revenue from an incremental unit of quantity, Δ(PQ)/ΔQ, has two
components:
1. Producing one extra unit and selling it at price P brings in revenue (1)(P) = P.
2. But because the firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve, producing and selling
this extra unit also results in a small drop in price ΔP/ΔQ, which reduces the revenue
from all units sold (i.e., a change in revenue Q[ΔP/ΔQ]).
Thus
Now, because the firm’s objective is to maximize profit, we can set marginal revenue equal
to marginal cost:
(10.
2)
The reason is that the monopolist’s output decision depends not only on marginal
cost but also on the shape of the demand curve.
As a result, shifts in demand do not trace out the series of prices and quantities
that correspond to a competitive supply curve. Instead, shifts in demand can lead
to changes in price with no change in output, changes in output with no change in
price, or changes in both price and output.
Shifts in demand usually cause changes in both price and quantity. A competitive
industry supplies a specific quantity at every price. No such relationship exists for a
monopolist, which, depending on how demand shifts, might supply several different
quantities at the same price, or the same quantity at different prices.
FIGURE 10.5
• Step 1. Whatever the total output, it should be divided between the two plants
so that marginal cost is the same in each plant. Otherwise, the firm could reduce
its costs and increase its profit by reallocating production.
• Step 2. We know that total output must be such that marginal revenue equals
marginal cost. Otherwise, the firm could increase its profit by raising or lowering
total output.
The firm should increase output from each plant until the incremental profit from the last
unit produced is zero. Start by setting incremental profit from output at Plant 1 to zero:
Here Δ(PQT)/ΔQ1 is the revenue from producing and selling one more unit—i.e.,
marginal revenue, MR, for all of the firm’s output.
Putting these relations together, we see that the firm should produce so that
In figure 10.7, although Firm A is not a pure monopolist, it does have monopoly power—
it can profitably charge a price greater than marginal cost. Of course, its monopoly power is
less than it would be if it had driven away the competition and monopolized the market, but
it might still be substantial.
1. How can we measure monopoly power in order to compare one firm with another?
(So far we have been talking about monopoly power only in qualitative terms.)
2. What are the sources of monopoly power, and why do some firms have more monopoly
power than others?
We address both these questions below, although a more complete answer to the
second question will be provided in Chapters 12 and 13.
Remember the important distinction between a perfectly competitive firm and a firm with
monopoly power: For the competitive firm, price equals marginal cost; for the firm with
monopoly power, price exceeds marginal cost.
Mathematically:
This index of monopoly power can also be expressed in terms of the elasticity of demand
facing the firm.
(10.
4)
FIGURE 10.8
1. The elasticity of market demand. Because the firm’s own demand will be at least
as elastic as market demand, the elasticity of market demand limits the potential
for monopoly power.
2. The number of firms in the market. If there are many firms, it is unlikely that any
one firm will be able to affect price significantly.
3. The interaction among firms. Even if only two or three firms are in the market,
each firm will be unable to profitably raise price very much if the rivalry among
them is aggressive, with each firm trying to capture as much of the market as it
can.
If there is only one firm—a pure monopolist—its demand curve is the market
demand curve. In this case, the firm’s degree of monopoly power depends
completely on the elasticity of market demand.
When several firms compete with one another, the elasticity of market demand
sets a lower limit on the magnitude of the elasticity of demand for each firm.
A particular firm’s elasticity depends on how the firms compete with one another,
and the elasticity of market demand limits the potential monopoly power of
individual producers.
Because the demand for oil is fairly inelastic (at least in the short run), OPEC could
raise oil prices far above marginal production cost during the 1970s and early
1980s. Because the demands for such commodities as coffee, cocoa, tin, and
copper are much more elastic, attempts by producers to cartelize these markets
and raise prices have largely failed. In each case, the elasticity of market demand
limits the potential monopoly power of individual producers.
Other things being equal, the monopoly power of each firm will fall as the number
of firms increases.
When only a few firms account for most of the sales in a market, we say that the
market is highly concentrated.
Economies of scale may make it too costly for more than a few firms to supply the
entire market. In some cases, economies of scale may be so large that it is most
efficient for a single firm—a natural monopoly—to supply the entire market.
Other things being equal, monopoly power is smaller when firms compete
aggressively and is larger when they cooperate. Because raising prices in concert
rather than individually is more likely to be profitable, collusion can generate
substantial monopoly power.
Remember that a firm’s monopoly power often changes over time, as its operating
conditions (market demand and cost), its behavior, and the behavior of its
competitors change. Monopoly power must therefore be thought of in a dynamic
context.
Furthermore, real or potential monopoly power in the short run can make an
industry more competitive in the long run: Large short-run profits can induce new
firms to enter an industry, thereby reducing monopoly power over the longer term.
Rent Seeking
rent seeking Spending money in socially unproductive efforts to acquire, maintain, or exercise
monopoly.
We would expect the economic incentive to incur rent-seeking costs to bear a direct relation
to the gains from monopoly power (i.e., rectangle A minus triangle C.)
PRICE REGULATION
PRICE REGULATION
FIGURE 10.12
Although it is a key element in determining the firm’s rate of return, a firm’s capital
stock is difficult to value.
Another approach to regulation is setting price caps based on the firm’s variable
costs. A price cap can allow for more flexibility. For example, a firm could raise its
prices each year (without having to get approval from the regulatory agency) by
an amount equal to the actual rate of inflation, minus expected productivity
growth.