Crowding Out (Economics)

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

Crowding out (economics)

In economics, crowding out is a phenomenon that occurs when increased government involvement in a
sector of the market economy substantially affects the remainder of the market, either on the supply or
demand side of the market.

One type frequently discussed is when expansionary fiscal policy reduces investment spending by the
private sector. The government spending is "crowding out" investment because it is demanding more
loanable funds and thus causing increased interest rates and therefore reducing investment spending. This
basic analysis has been broadened to multiple channels that might leave total output little changed or even
smaller.[1]

Other economists use "crowding out" to refer to government providing a service or good that would
otherwise be a business opportunity for private industry, and be subject only to the economic forces seen in
voluntary exchange.

Behavioral economists and other social scientists also use "crowding out" to describe a downside of
solutions based on private exchange: the crowding out of intrinsic motivation and prosocial norms in
response to the financial incentives of voluntary market exchange.

History
The idea of the crowding out effect, though not the term itself, has been discussed since at least the 18th
century.[2] Economic historian Jim Tomlinson wrote in 2010: "All major economic crises in twentieth
century Britain have reignited simmering debates about the impact of public sector expansion on economic
performance. From the 'Geddes Axe' after the First World War, through John Maynard Keynes' attack on
the 'Treasury view' in the interwar years, down to the 'monetarist' assaults on the public sector of the 1970s
and 1980s, it has been alleged that public sector growth in itself, but especially if funded by state
borrowing, has detrimental effects on the national economy." Much of the debate in the 1970s was based
on the assumption of a fixed supply of savings within a single country, but with the global capital markets
of the 21st century "...international capital mobility completely undermines a simple model of crowding
out".[3]

Crowding out from government borrowing


One channel of crowding out is a reduction in private investment that occurs because of an increase in
government borrowing. If an increase in government spending and/or a decrease in tax revenues leads to a
deficit that is financed by increased borrowing, then the borrowing can increase interest rates, leading to a
reduction in private investment. There is some controversy in modern macroeconomics on the subject, as
different schools of economic thought differ on how households and financial markets would react to more
government borrowing under various circumstances.

The extent to which crowding out occurs depends on the economic situation. If the economy is at capacity
or full employment, then the government suddenly increasing its budget deficit (e.g., via stimulus programs)
could create competition with the private sector for scarce funds available for investment, resulting in an
increase in interest rates and reduced private investment or consumption. Thus the effect of the stimulus is
offset by the effect of crowding out. On the other hand, if the economy is below capacity and there is a
surplus of funds available for investment, an increase in the government's deficit does not result in
competition with the private sector. In this scenario, the stimulus program would be much more effective. In
sum, changing the government's budget deficit has a stronger impact on GDP when the economy is below
capacity. In the aftermath of the 2008 subprime mortgage crisis, the U.S. economy remained well below
capacity and there was a large surplus of funds available for investment, so increasing the budget deficit put
funds to use that would otherwise have been idle.[4]

The macroeconomic theory behind crowding out provides some useful intuition. What happens is that an
increase in the demand for loanable funds by the government (e.g. due to a deficit) shifts the loanable funds
demand curve rightwards and upwards, increasing the real interest rate. A higher real interest rate increases
the opportunity cost of borrowing money, decreasing the amount of interest-sensitive expenditures such as
investment and consumption. Thus, the government has "crowded out" investment.

What factors determine how much


crowding out takes place?

The extent to which interest rate adjustments dampen the


output expansion induced by increased government
spending is determined by:

Income increases more than interest rates


increase if the LM (Liquidity preference—Money
supply) curve is flatter.
Income increases less than interest rates increase
if the IS (Investment—Saving) curve is flatter.
Income and interest rates increase more the
larger the multiplier, thus, the larger the horizontal The IS curve moves to the right, causing
shift in the IS curve.
higher interest rates (i) and expansion in the
"real" economy (real GDP, or Y).
In each case, the extent of crowding out is greater the more
interest rate increases when government spending rises.

Economist Laura D'Andrea Tyson wrote in June 2012: "By itself an increase in the deficit, either in the
form of an increase in government spending or a reduction in taxes, causes an increase in demand. But how
this affects output, employment and growth depends on what happens to interest rates. When the economy
is operating near capacity, government borrowing to finance an increase in the deficit causes interest rates to
rise. Higher interest rates reduce or “crowd out” private investment, and this reduces growth. The
“crowding out” argument explains why large and sustained government deficits take a toll on growth; they
reduce capital formation. But this argument rests on how government deficits affect interest rates, and the
relationship between government deficits and interest rates varies. When there is considerable excess
capacity, an increase in government borrowing to finance an increase in the deficit does not lead to higher
interest rates and does not crowd out private investment. Instead, the higher demand resulting from the
increase in the deficit bolsters employment and output directly, and the resulting increase in income and
economic activity in turn encourages or 'crowds in' additional private spending. The crowding-in argument
is the right one for current economic conditions."[4]

Two extreme cases

Liquidity trap

If the economy is in a hypothesized liquidity trap, the "Liquidity-Money" (LM) curve is horizontal, an
increase in government spending has its full multiplier effect on the equilibrium income. There is no change
in the interest associated with the change in government spending, thus no investment spending cut off.
Therefore, there is no dampening of the effects of increased government spending on income. If the
demand for money is very sensitive to interest rates, so that the LM curve is almost horizontal, fiscal policy
changes have a relatively large effect on output, while monetary policy changes have little effect on the
equilibrium output. So, if the LM curve is horizontal, monetary policy has no impact on the equilibrium of
the economy and the fiscal policy has a maximal effect.

The Classical Case and crowding out

If the LM curve is vertical, then an increase in government spending has no effect on the equilibrium
income and only increases the interest rates. If the demand for money is not related to the interest rate, as
the vertical LM curve implies, then there is a unique level of income at which the money market is in
equilibrium.

Thus, with a vertical LM curve, an increase in government spending cannot change the equilibrium income
and only raises the equilibrium interest rates. But if government spending is higher and the output is
unchanged, there must be an offsetting reduction in private spending. In this case, the increase in interest
rates crowds out an amount of private spending equal to increase in government spending. Thus, there is
full crowding out if LM is vertical.

Crowding out sources


If increased borrowing leads to higher interest rates by creating a greater demand for money and loanable
funds and hence a higher "price" (ceteris paribus), the private sector, which is sensitive to interest rates, will
likely reduce investment due to a lower rate of return. This is the investment that is crowded out. The
weakening of fixed investment and other interest-sensitive expenditure counteracts to varying extents the
expansionary effect of government deficits. More importantly, a fall in fixed investment by business can
hurt long-term economic growth of the supply side, i.e., the growth of potential output. Thus, the situation
in which borrowing may lead to crowding out is that companies would like to expand productive capacity,
but, because of high interest rates, cannot borrow funds with which to do so. According to American
economist Jared Bernstein, writing in 2011, this scenario is "not a plausible story with excess capacity, the
Fed funds [interest] rate at zero, and companies sitting on cash that they could invest with if they saw good
reasons to do so."[5] Another American economist, Paul Krugman, pointed out that, after the beginning of
the recession in 2008, the federal government's borrowing increased by hundreds of billions of dollars,
leading to warnings about crowding out, but instead interest rates had actually fallen.[6] When aggregate
demand is low, government spending tends to expand the market for private-sector products through the
fiscal multiplier and thus stimulates – or "crowds in" – fixed investment (via the "accelerator effect"). This
accelerator effect is most important when business suffers from unused industrial capacity, i.e., during a
serious recession or a depression.
Crowding out can, in principle, be avoided if the deficit is financed by simply printing money, but this
carries concerns of accelerating inflation.

Chartalist and Post-Keynesian economists question the crowding out thesis because government bonds
sales have the actual effect of lowering short-term interest rates, not raising them, since the rate for short-
term debt is always set by central banks. Additionally, private credit is not constrained by any "amount of
funds" or "money supply" or similar concept. Rather, banks lend to any credit-worthy customer,
constrained by their capitalization level and risk regulations. The resulting loan creates a deposit
simultaneously, increasing the amount of endogenous money at that time. Crowding out is most plausibly
effective when an economy is already at potential output or full employment. Then the government's
expansionary fiscal policy encourages increased prices, which lead to an increased demand for money. This
in turn leads to higher interest rates (ceteris paribus) and crowds out interest-sensitive spending. At potential
output, businesses are in no need of markets, so that there is no room for an accelerator effect. More
directly, if the economy stays at full employment gross domestic product, any increase in government
purchases shifts resources away from the private sector. This phenomenon is sometimes called "real"
crowding out.

Crowding out of another sort (often referred to as international crowding out) may occur due to the
prevalence of floating exchange rates, as demonstrated by the Mundell–Fleming model. Government
borrowing leads to higher interest rates, which attract inflows of money on the capital account from foreign
financial markets into the domestic currency (i.e., into assets denominated in that currency). Under floating
exchange rates, that leads to appreciation of the exchange rate and thus the "crowding out" of domestic
exports (which become more expensive to those using foreign currency). This counteracts the demand-
promoting effects of government deficits but has no obvious negative effect on long-term economic growth.

Crowding out demand


In terms of health economics, "crowding-out" refers to the phenomenon whereby new or expanded
programs meant to cover the uninsured have the effect of prompting those already enrolled in private
insurance to switch to the new program. This effect was seen, for example, in expansions to Medicaid and
the State Children's Health Insurance Program (SCHIP) in the late 1990s.[7]

Therefore, high takeup rates for new or expanded programs do not merely represent the previously
uninsured, but also represent those who may have been forced to shift their health insurance from the
private to the public sector. As a result of these shifts, it can be projected that healthcare improvements as a
result of policy change may not be as robust. In the context of the CHIP debate, this assumption was
challenged by projections produced by the Congressional Budget Office, which "scored" all versions of the
CHIP reauthorization and included in those scores the best assumptions available regarding the impacts of
increased funding for these programs. CBO assumed that many already eligible children would become
enrolled as a result of the new funding and policies in CHIP reauthorization, but that some would be
eligible for private insurance.[8] The vast majority, even in states with enrollments of those above twice the
poverty line (around $40,000 for a family of four), did not have access to age-appropriate health insurance
for their children. New Jersey, supposedly the model for profligacy in SCHIP with eligibility that stretched
to 350% of the federal poverty level, testified that it could identify 14% crowd-out in its CHIP program.[9]

In the context of CHIP and Medicaid, many children are eligible but not enrolled. Thus, in comparison to
Medicare, which allows for near "auto-enrollment" for those over 64, children's caregivers may be required
to fill out 17-page forms, produce multiple consecutive pay stubs, re-apply at more than yearly intervals and
even conduct face-to-face interviews to prove the eligibility of the child.[10] These anti-crowd-out
procedures can fracture care for children, sever the connection to their medical home and lead to worse
health outcomes.[11]

Crowding out supply


Crowding out is also said to occur in charitable giving when government public policy inserts itself into
roles that had traditionally been private voluntary charity,[12] rendering private charity unnecessary.

Crowding out has also been observed in the area of venture capital, suggesting that government
involvement in financing commercial enterprises crowds out private finance.[13]

References
1. • Olivier Jean Blanchard (2008). "crowding out," The New Palgrave Dictionary of
Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract. (http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde200
8_C000452&edition=current&q=)
  • Roger W. Spencer & William P. Yohe, 1970. "The 'Crowding Out' of Private Expenditures
by Fiscal Policy Actions," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, October, pp. 12-24 (htt
p://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/70/10/Expenditures_Oct1970.pdf)
2. Michael Hudson, “How economic theory came to ignore the role of debt (http://www.paecon.
net/PAEReview/issue57/Hudson57.pdf)”, real-world economics review, issue no. 57, 6
September 2011, pp. 2–24, comments (http://rwer.wordpress.com/2011/09/06/rwer-issue-57-
michael-hudson/), cited at bottom of page 5
3. History and Policy.org-Jim Tomlinson-Crowding Out-December 5, 2010 (http://www.historya
ndpolicy.org/opinion-articles/articles/crowding-out)
4. Laura D'Andrea Tyson (2012-06-01). "Confusion about the Deficit" (https://economix.blogs.n
ytimes.com/2012/06/01/confusion-about-the-deficit/). New York Times. Retrieved
2013-05-16.
5. Bernstein, Jared (May 25, 2011). "Cut and Grow? I Say No" (http://jaredbernsteinblog.com/c
ut-and-grow-i-say-no/). Retrieved 2011-05-28.
6. Krugman, Paul (August 20, 2011), "Fancy Theorists of the World Unite" (https://krugman.blo
gs.nytimes.com/2011/08/20/fancy-theorists-of-the-world-unite/), The New York Times,
retrieved 2011-08-22
7. David M. Cutler & Jonathan Gruber (2 February 1995). "Does Public Insurance Crowd Out
Private Insurance?" (http://ideas.repec.org/p/nbr/nberwo/5082.html). Ideas.repec.org.
Retrieved 9 November 2014.
8. "Congressional Budget Office" (https://web.archive.org/web/20090611020433/http://www.cb
o.gov/ftpdocs/99xx/doc9963/hr2.pdf) (PDF). Archived from the original (http://www.cbo.gov/ft
pdocs/99xx/doc9963/hr2.pdf) (PDF) on 11 June 2009. Retrieved 2 May 2022.
9. [1] (http://energycommerce.house.gov/cmte_mtgs/110-he-hrg.012908.Kohler-testimony.pdf)
Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/20090326033903/http://energycommerce.house.gov/c
mte_mtgs/110-he-hrg.012908.Kohler-testimony.pdf) March 26, 2009, at the Wayback
Machine
10. "American Public Health Association - Barriers to Medicaid Enrollment:…" (https://archive.to
day/20130223150817/http://www.ajph.org/cgi/content/full/95/2/292). Archived from the
original (http://www.ajph.org/cgi/content/full/95/2/292) on 23 February 2013.
11. "Simplifying Children's Medicaid and SCHIP" (https://archive.today/20140112145840/http://c
ontent.healthaffairs.org/cgi/content/full/23/3/233?maxtoshow=&HITS=10&hits=10&RESULT
FORMAT). Archived from the original (http://content.healthaffairs.org/cgi/content/full/23/3/23
3?maxtoshow=&HITS=10&hits=10&RESULTFORMAT) on 2014-01-12. Retrieved
2009-05-08.
12. Eckel; et al. (2005). "An experimental test of the crowding out hypothesis" (http://econ.ucsd.e
du/%7Ejandreon/Econ264/papers/Eckel%20JPubE%202005.pdf) (PDF). Journal of Public
Economics. 89 (8): 1543–1560. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.05.012 (https://doi.org/10.1016%
2Fj.jpubeco.2004.05.012). S2CID 18596673 (https://api.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:1859
6673).
13. Cumming; et al. (2006). "Crowding out private equity: Canadian evidence". Journal of
Business Venturing. 21 (5): 569–609. doi:10.1016/j.jbusvent.2005.06.002 (https://doi.org/10.
1016%2Fj.jbusvent.2005.06.002).

Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Crowding_out_(economics)&oldid=1133811163"

You might also like