Dechezlepretre Et Al Policy Brief Jan 2016
Dechezlepretre Et Al Policy Brief Jan 2016
Dechezlepretre Et Al Policy Brief Jan 2016
and growth
Antoine Dechezleprêtre, Ralf Martin, Samuela Bassi
Policy brief
January 2016
The Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and
the Environment was established in 2008 at the London
School of Economics and Political Science. The Institute
brings together international expertise on economics, as
well as finance, geography, the environment, international
development and political economy to establish a world-
leading centre for policy-relevant research, teaching and
training in climate change and the environment. It is
funded by the Grantham Foundation for the Protection
of the Environment, which also funds the Grantham
Institute for Climate Change at Imperial College London.
It is also supported by the Global Green Growth Institute
through a grant for US$2.16 million (£1.35 million) to fund
several research project areas from 2012 to 2014. More
information about the Grantham Research Institute can
be found at: http://www.lse.ac.uk/grantham/
Contents
Executive summary 3
1. Introduction 5
2. The impact of climate change policy on innovation 6
3. The impact of low-carbon innovation on profits,
competitiveness and growth 9
4 How to best incentivise low-carbon innovation? 16
5. Conclusion 22
References 24
The authors
Samuela Bassi is a Statkraft Policy Analyst at the Grantham Research Institute on Climate
Change and the Environment at the London School of Economics and the Centre for Climate
Change Economics and Policy (CCCEP), which she joined in 2012. Her work focuses in
particular on climate change and energy policy, and green growth. Previously she was as a
Senior Policy Analyst at the Institute for European Environmental Policy (IEEP) in London and in
Brussels. She also worked for a private environmental consultancy in Venice and for the Italian
Permanent Mission to the United Nations in New York. She holds a degree in economics from
University of Trieste (Italy) and an MSc in economics from Birkbeck College, London.
Antoine Dechezleprêtre is a Associate Professorial Research Fellow and Head of the Energy,
Technology and Trade research programme at the Grantham Research Institute on Climate
Change and the Environment, London School of Economics and Political Science, as well as
the Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy. His work deals principally with the impact
of environmental and climate change policies on businesses, in particular on the development
and the international diffusion of low-carbon technologies. His research has been published in
international scientific journals in the field of applied microeconomics, environmental economics
and energy economics. He has worked as an external consultant for the OECD Environment
Directorate, the UK Committee on Climate Change, the French Environment and Energy
Management Agency (ADEME), International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development
(ICTSD) and the French patent office. He holds a PhD in economics from Ecole des Mines de
Paris (France).
Acknowledgements
This policy brief draws on material from Dechezleprêtre and Popp (2015). We thank Stefan Ambec,
Simon Bennett, Maria Carvalho, Chris Duffy, David Hemous, Yang Liu and Dimitri Zenghelis for
very helpful comments. Financial support has come from the Global Green Growth Institute,
the Grantham Foundation for the Protection of the Environment, as well as the UK Economic and
Social Research Council through the Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy.
Executive summary
Actions to stimulate low-carbon innovation – a global policy priority – are moving full
speed ahead. Twenty countries from across the developed and developing world, including the
UK, the US, China, India, the United Arab Emirates and Australia, recently signed up to ‘Mission
Innovation’ at the 2015 United Nations Climate Change Conference in Paris, promising to double
their public investment in low-carbon energy innovation and to promote increased international
cooperation. Alongside this, a global group of 28 key investment players from 10 countries,
including Bill Gates, Mark Zuckerberg and Richard Branson, are mobilising to deliver ‘truly
transformative energy solutions for the future’ as part of the new ‘Energy Breakthrough
Coalition’. In addition, the European Commission is developing a strategy to support low-carbon
innovation, to be published with the second State of the Energy Union report in late 2016.
This policy brief provides evidence to inform these and other initiatives seeking to
stimulate low-carbon innovation. Key findings include:
Public policies that put a price on carbon (emissions trading systems, carbon taxes or
energy efficiency mandates) are a crucial driver for the adoption of environmentally
friendly technologies and induce innovation in low-carbon technologies. The impact
appears both large and rapid: much of the innovative response to climate change policy
measures occurs within five years or less. Thus, climate change regulations can help economies
break away from a polluting economic trajectory and move to a low-carbon one.
A crucial challenge for climate change policies is ensuring that low-carbon innovation
activity is either additional to current research and development (R&D) expenditures,
or at least displaces innovation in polluting technologies rather than other socially
valuable innovation. Policies that change the relative price of low-carbon and high-carbon
inputs, such as carbon markets or fuel taxes, can play this role effectively.
Current deployment efforts should be augmented with additional R&D support, such that
the marginal euro spent on low-carbon technologies should go to R&D rather than
deployment. European countries have been emphasising technology deployment through
feed-in tariffs for renewable energy production over direct R&D support, but this approach may
not provide sufficient stimulus to develop the next generation of low-carbon technologies. From
a political point of view, an additional advantage of direct support to R&D is that by definition it is
targeted at domestic manufacturers, while feed-in tariffs may encourage innovation activity
mostly in foreign countries.
Public spending on low-carbon R&D needs to increase significantly over the next few
decades if the world is to realise the goals of the Paris Agreement to limit global warming to well
below 2°C and to achieve net zero global emissions of greenhouse gases in the second half of this
century. It is difficult to give a precise figure for increased public investment, but the literature agrees
that it should at least double. Some of the greatest funding increases are needed in low-carbon
transportation, carbon capture and storage (CCS), smart grids and industrial energy efficiency.
For instance, in Europe, a doubling of public R&D expenditures over the next 10 years (from €4bn
to €8bn a year) corresponds to the growth that was observed between 2001 and 2011 and thus
seems achievable. Assuming an average carbon price of €11 per tonne, a doubling of public
R&D funding for low-carbon technologies represents only 10 per cent of the expected revenues
from auctioned emissions allowances over the next decade.
Increasing public support for low-carbon R&D may also be politically attractive because
low-carbon innovations have larger economic benefits than the carbon-intensive
technologies they replace. Low-carbon patents have been found to be of high social value.
They have broad application across the whole economy (i.e. they have high ‘knowledge
spillovers’). Their application is similarly wide to patents in other growth sectors such as
information and communications technology (ICT) and nanotechnologies. Taken together,
this means that innovation induced by climate change regulations can help to boost economic
growth and offset the policy costs for firms.
Moreover, the knowledge spillovers from low-carbon technologies have a strong local
component. For Europe as a whole, 61 per cent of spillovers occur domestically. However,
European countries with smaller or more open economies retain a smaller share of spillovers
domestically: 28 per cent for France, 15 per cent for the UK, 10 per cent for the Netherlands.
As such, coordination of European Union research policy is theoretically justified and
there is a strong case for European institutions to fund R&D.
There is scope for increasing investment in several Member States if the European Union
is keen to strengthen its competitive advantage on low-carbon innovation. Ranking
European Union Member States by the number of low-carbon inventions per billion US dollars
of GDP shows that Germany and the Scandinavian countries are at the forefront of innovation.
The UK is approximately midway in the ranking, ahead of countries such as Belgium, Norway,
Italy, Spain and Poland, but behind France, the Netherlands and others (see Figure 8 on page 16).
Increased investment in low-carbon R&D should be slow and sustained. While it is welcome
that countries such as the UK have committed to doubling public funding for low-carbon R&D by
2020 as part of ‘Mission Innovation’; countries should be encouraged to set public R&D
targets as far ahead as 2030. Targets would vary between countries and may need to be set
within a range, but such long-term targets would reduce public funding spikes and associated
adjustment costs, and ultimately could reduce the overall cost of decarbonisation.
1. Introduction
According to the latest report by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, (IPCC, 2014)
stabilising global carbon emissions in 2050 requires a 60 per cent reduction in the carbon
intensity of global GDP (assuming a 2.5 per cent annual GDP growth). To achieve this long-term
decarbonisation of the economy, the world needs to implement a radical change in the mix of
technologies used to produce and consume energy. This in turn will likely require massive
investments in innovation activities. The IPCC also made it clear that future investments in
research, development and demonstration (RD&D) will be the determining factor for the cost of
emissions reductions policies.
Importantly, the diversity of energy uses, systems, resources and national contexts means that
addressing climate change and other environmental issues will require innovation across the
whole range of existing and potential low-carbon technologies and at all stages of technological
change – from the creation of new ideas (e.g. invention and innovation) to the diffusion and
adoption of new technologies throughout the economy (IEA, 2008). The cost of existing low-
carbon technologies, such as offshore wind turbines or solar panels, needs to be brought down
so that they can be deployed on a large scale, while fundamental research needs to advance
the frontiers of technologies such as smart grids or energy storage.
With a global agreement on climate change now in place,1 low-carbon innovation is likely to
become a high priority for policymakers worldwide. Individual countries and multilateral
organisations such as the European Union already have policies in place to support low-carbon
innovation. This policy brief evaluates these policies to provide insights and lessons to aid future
policy development. Questions considered are: what impact do these policies have on the
development of new low-carbon technologies? What policies should be adopted to provide the
highest encouragement to cost-effective low-carbon innovation? What could be the impact of
the increased volume of innovation activity directed at low-carbon technologies on economic
growth? What level of resources should be allocated to directly supporting innovation activities
in low carbon technologies? What is the right balance between research and development
(R&D) and deployment budgets?
The brief is divided into three main sections. The first part analyses the impact of climate change
policies on innovation. The second part explores the implications of policy-induced innovation
activity in the low-carbon sector for economic growth. The third part discusses which policies
should be adopted to support the development and deployment of low-carbon technologies.
A final section summarises the main findings and presents policy recommendations.
1 The Paris Agreement, adopted by 196 Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
in December 2015.
Interestingly, the effect of policy on innovation happens very quickly, even within two to three years.
This can be particularly valuable for local or national governments which tend to be in place for no
more than four or five years and are therefore keen to see short-term results.
The change in relative prices due to climate change regulation spurs so-called ‘induced
innovation’ (Acemoglu, 2002; Acemoglu et al., 2012; Hicks, 1932). Because research and
development (R&D) is a profit-motivated investment activity, inventors respond to the expected
increased diffusion of environmental technologies induced by regulations by developing low-
carbon technologies. This finding is supported by a large body of evidence (for recent surveys
of relevant literature see Popp et al., 2010; Popp, 2010; and Ambec et al., 2013).
To illustrate this point, Figure 1 shows number of low-carbon inventions for which patent protection
has been sought by inventors located in OECD countries between 1990 and 2012, along with an
indicator of the stringency of climate change policy developed by the OECD (Botta and Kozluk,
2014).2 The graph shows a striking correlation between innovation efforts, as measured by patent
filings, and the stringency of policy.
Analyses of this phenomenon include Lanjouw and Mody (1996), Jaffe and Palmer (1997), and
Brunnermeier and Cohen (2003) who show a significant correlation within industries over time
between innovative activity and environmental regulatory stringency (proxied by pollution control
expenditures). Similarly, Johnstone et al. (2010) find that patenting activity for renewable energy
technologies, measured by applications for renewable energy patents submitted to the European
Patent Office (EPO), has increased dramatically in recent years, as both national policies and
international efforts to combat climate change begin to provide incentives for innovation.
Dechezleprêtre and Glachant (2014) show that public policies that encourage the diffusion of
renewable energy technologies, such as feed-in tariffs and renewable energy certificates, induce
technological change, so that for every 100 MW of new wind power capacity installed in OECD
countries, three new inventions are patented on average.
2 The indicator of environmental policy stringency is a composite index of various environmental policy
instruments, primarily related to climate and air pollution. See Botta and Kozluk (2014) for details over the
construction of the indicator.
35000 3
Number of annual low-carbon inventions
30000
25000
2
20000
1.5
15000
1
10000
Source: Number of inventions: authors’ own calculations from the PATSTAT database; Climate policy stringency
indicator: OECD (2014). Individual countries are weighted by their GDP in order to calculate the average policy
stringency across the OECD.
Other studies provide evidence on how innovation reacts to higher energy prices resulting from
various policies. Newell et al. (1999) show that the energy efficiency of air conditioners and gas
water heaters in 1993 would have been one-quarter to one-half lower if energy prices had stayed
at their 1973 levels, rather than rising along their historical path. Similarly, both Popp (2002) and
Verdolini and Galeotti (2011) find that a 10 per cent increase in energy prices raises energy
patenting in the long run by around 4 per cent. Aghion et al. (2016) examine innovation activity
in the car industry and show that firms tend to innovate more in low-carbon technologies (i.e.
electric, hybrid and hydrogen cars) and less in high-carbon technologies (i.e. internal combustion
engines) when they face higher fuel prices. A 10 per cent higher fuel price is associated with about
10 per cent more low-carbon patents and 7 per cent less high-carbon patents.
Moreover, the innovative response to policy happens quickly. Evidence suggests that much
of the innovative response to higher energy prices occurs within five years or less. Popp (2006)
finds an almost immediate innovative response to the passage of low-carbon air regulations in the
US, Japan and Germany. Similarly, Calel and Dechezleprêtre (2014) show that the European Union
Emission Trading System (EU ETS) has increased innovation activity (measured by the number of
patents) in low-carbon technologies3 among participating companies. Participants in the scheme
and non-participants exhibited roughly comparable innovation activity before the introduction of
the EU ETS, but they start diverging quickly after the new policy was put in place (see Figure 2).
To sum up, there is ample empirical evidence that climate change regulations, either directly or
through their impact on energy prices, encourage the diffusion of environmentally-friendly
technologies and drive innovation activity further up the technology supply chain, favouring R&D
in low-carbon technologies. The impact on innovation appears both large and rapid. Thus, climate
change regulations can help economies break away from a polluting economic trajectory and
move to a low-carbon one.
EU ETS
80 companies
EU ETS
introduction
Low-carbon patents
60
Non EU ETS
40 companies
20
0
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Year
Source: Calel & Dechezleprêtre, 2014. Around 3000 companies regulated under the EU ETS are included in the
sample. “Non EU ETS companies” are a group of 3000 European companies that are not regulated under the
EU ETS but operate in the same country and the same economic sector and are comparable in size and
innovation capacity to companies regulated under the EU ETS.
3 Low-carbon patents are defined based on the Cooperative Patent Classification “Y02” class, which covers
“technologies or applications for mitigation against climate change. It includes: efficient combustion
technologies (e.g. combined heat and power generation); renewable energy technologies, carbon capture and
storage, efficient electricity distribution (e.g. smart grids); and energy storage (e.g. fuel cells). See Calel and
Dechezleprêtre (2014) for a complete list of the sub-classes of low-carbon patents used in the paper.
Therefore, recent research suggests there is a crowding out effect and that low-carbon innovations
tend to crowd out high-carbon innovations in the same sector. These results imply that climate
change policies play a crucial role in ensuring that low-carbon innovation activity comes at
the expense of innovation in more polluting technologies rather than of other, potentially
socially valuable, innovation. Policies that change the relative price of low-carbon and high-
carbon inputs, such as carbon markets or fuel taxes, can play this role effectively. Another
implication is that the welfare impacts of induced low-carbon innovation will depend partly on the
relative size of the social benefits coming from knowledge spillovers in low-carbon and high-
carbon innovation. This question is addressed in the next section.
This chapter presents the evidence on the impact of low-carbon innovation on firms’ profits.
It also investigates the potential of low-carbon innovation to stimulate technological
improvements in a broad range of sectors beyond what is typically regarded as the ‘green’
economy and, in doing so, be a driver of economic growth.
Evidence can be found to support this statement to an extent. For example, Rexhauser and
Rammer (2014) find that regulation-induced innovations which improve a firm’s resource
efficiency in terms of material or energy consumption have a positive impact on profitability,
as measured by pre-tax profits over sales.
Lanoie et al. (2011) also find that regulation-induced, low-carbon innovation improves business
performance, though not enough to offset the costs of complying with climate change
regulations. They conclude that the net effect is negative—that is, the positive effect of
innovation on business performance does not outweigh the negative effect of the regulation
itself. These results suggest that climate change regulation is costly, but less so than if one
was to consider only the direct costs of the regulation itself, without the ability of
innovation to mitigate those costs.
It is well established in the economic literature that R&D activities provide not only private returns
to inventors, but also returns to society which are not captured by inventors (Geroski, 1995).
In most cases, new technologies must be made available to the public for the inventor to reap
the rewards of invention. However, by making new inventions public, some (if not all) of the
knowledge embodied in the invention becomes public knowledge. This public knowledge may
lead to additional innovations.4 These knowledge spillovers provide benefits to the public as a
whole, but not to the innovator. An obvious example of such a spillover is Android-based smart
phones. Apple first launched the now dominant design of smart phones. However, other
companies such as Google were also able to benefit from Apple’s original R&D investments by
copying or improving the original design.5 Economists studying the returns to research
consistently find that knowledge spillovers result in a large wedge between private and social
rates of return to R&D.6 Typical results include marginal social rates of return between 30 and
50 per cent. In comparison, estimates of private marginal rates of return on investments range
from 7 to 15 per cent (Hall et al., 2010).
4 Intellectual property rights, such as patents, are designed to protect inventors from such copies. However, their
effectiveness varies depending on the ease in which inventors may ‘invent around’ the patent by making minor
modifications to an invention. See, for example, Levin et al. (1987).
5 Sticking to energy, an example is the massive social benefits (and smaller emissions benefits) in the near term
that are accruing due to the development of lithium ion technology. Note that private returns are harder to
capture in sectors such as energy as, for example, a green electron is no more attractive than a high-carbon
one to the end-user. By contrast, innovation can demonstrably improve the quality of a mobile phone and
differentiate it from its competitors, allowing greater scope for returns to innovation to be captured.
6 Sticking to energy, an example is the massive social benefits (and smaller emissions benefits) in the near term
that are accruing due to the development of lithium ion technology. Note that private returns are harder to
capture in sectors such as energy as, for example, a low-carbon electron is no more attractive than a high-
carbon one to the end-user. By contrast, innovation can demonstrably improve the quality of a mobile phone
and differentiate it from its competitors, allowing greater scope for returns to innovation to be captured.
Since firms make investment decisions based on their private returns, the wedge between private
and social rates of return suggests that socially beneficial research opportunities are ignored
by firms because they are unable to fully capture the rewards of such innovations.7 As a
consequence, innovation in low-carbon technologies induced by climate change policies can
increase welfare. However, this depends crucially on whether new R&D investments in low-carbon
technologies come at the expense of innovation in other technologies.8
Consider two scenarios (A and B) that might present themselves to a firm deciding about its next
R&D investment project, as illustrated in Figure 3. In both cases two R&D investment opportunities
are compared: a low-carbon option and a high-carbon option.9 In both cases the combined
private and non-private return of the low-carbon project are higher. However, in scenario A
combined returns are higher because of higher private returns. In scenario B non-private returns
are higher, whereas private returns are lower for the low-carbon project. Now consider a climate
policy that requires firms to invest in the low-carbon option. In scenario A this would not have an
impact on growth or economic value, as the firm would already choose the low-carbon option in
the absence of the regulation. The climate policy would not be necessary at all in this scenario,
since the market would redirect the economy toward low-carbon technologies by itself. In scenario
B the climate policy would be binding, as the private returns are lower in the low-carbon R&D
project, and hence low-carbon innovation is only conducted in the presence of climate change
policy. As a consequence of being forced to invest in the low-carbon R&D project, rather than in
the high-carbon R&D project, the value of the firm would drop but the social economic value
would increase.
Scenario A Scenario B
140 140
120 120
100 100
80 80
60 60
40 40
20 20
0 0
Low-carbon High-carbon Low-carbon High-carbon
R&D Project R&D Project R&D Project R&D Project
Private returns Non private returns Private returns Non private returns
7 A central problem in the literature on spillovers is that firm performance is affected by two countervailing
effects: a positive effect from knowledge spillovers and a negative effect from businesses stealing products
from market rivals. Bloom et al. (2013) incorporate these two types of spillovers and show that technology
spillovers quantitatively dominate, so that the gross social returns to R&D are at least twice as high as the
private returns even when taking product rivalry into account.
8 For example, Popp (2004) estimates that, in case of no crowding-out (new R&D investments in low-carbon
technologies come at the expense of investments in physical capital but not at the expense of other R&D
activities), innovation induced by climate change policy increases welfare by 45 per cent compared to a
situation without induced innovation activity. However, if one-half of new low-carbon R&D crowds out other
R&D, induced innovation increases welfare by only 9 per cent, and if new low-carbon R&D fully crowds out
other R&D, welfare gains decrease by 2 per cent.
9 An example in the automobile sector would be an innovation in a new electric motor or an innovation to
produce a larger vehicle, hence less energy efficient. The low-carbon or the high-carbon option could also be
energy efficiency innovations on combustion engines. The key point is that one innovation is more carbon-
intensive than the other.
An argument in favour of public intervention is therefore that policy can help realise those societal
benefits from innovation, or technology spillovers, that may not be triggered by private
interest alone. Thus, higher spillovers for low-carbon technologies compared to high-carbon
technologies can in theory generate positive growth effects from climate policies if they are
sufficiently high to compensate for the lower private value of low-carbon innovation.
Dechezleprêtre et al. (2014) measure knowledge spillovers coming from low-carbon and high-
carbon patents using a global dataset of patent citations.10 The analysis focuses on two sectors:
transport and electricity production, which jointly account for the bulk of carbon emissions.
In the electricity generation sector, low-carbon technologies cover renewable energy sources,
while high-carbon technologies are those based on fossil fuels (mostly coal and gas). In the
automotive sector, low-carbon technologies encompass electric, hybrid and hydrogen vehicles,
while high-carbon technologies are associated to internal combustion and gasoline engines.
Figure 4 reports the number of innovations in the different categories between 1950 and 2005.
The key finding by Dechezleprêtre et al. (2014) is that knowledge spillovers are much larger
for low-carbon than for high-carbon technologies. This is shown graphically in Figure 5
and confirmed by a large set of statistical analyses which account for a large number of
potentially confounding factors, including the fact that low-carbon patents may have higher
chance of being cited simply because there are fewer of them (see the full paper for details
on these analyses).
15000
Number of inventions
10000
5000
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
Year
10 Any innovator applying for a patent is required to reference all previous innovations – so called prior art – on
which the new innovation is based. A citation indicates that the knowledge contained in the cited document
has been useful in the development of the new knowledge laid out in the citing patent and thus represents a
knowledge flow. For this reason, patent citations have been used frequently to measure knowledge spillovers.
Notes: The figure visualises all citations to a sample of 1000 high-carbon (left panel) and 1000 low-carbon (right
panel) innovations. Each node represents an innovation (black=high-carbon innovation, green=low-carbon
innovation, orange=other innovation), edges represent citations. The samples were drawn among innovations
applying for patent protection in 1995. Interactive versions of these figures can be found online.11
11
While the main distinction in this analysis is between low-carbon and high-carbon technologies,
there are many technologies within the high-carbon category that make fossil fuels more
efficient. These can be viewed as another alternative to low-carbon (zero-carbon) technologies
and are termed as ‘grey’.12 From a climate point of view these are helpful, but, as they rely on
fossil fuels, they might not be sufficient to achieve a fully decarbonised economy and might also
promote the lock-in of fossil fuel infrastructure (see Aghion et al., 2014). Comparing the intensity
of spillovers between low-carbon and grey technologies, Dechezleprêtre et al. (2014) still find
that low-carbon technologies generate significantly larger spillovers than grey
technologies. This means that R&D activities in zero-carbon technologies, such as
electric and hydrogen cars or renewable energy technologies, should receive larger
public support than R&D activities in energy-efficiency technologies.
Although patent citations provide a measure of knowledge spillovers, they do not tell us anything
about the associated economic value. If low-carbon citations reflect spillovers that are less
economically valuable, finding higher citation counts would be of little economic relevance.
However, Dechezleprêtre et al. (2014) look at the change of a firm’s stock market value as they
innovate (measured by patent applications) and find that, all else equal, a firm’s value increases
by more if they apply for a patent that cites a low-carbon patent rather than a high-carbon patent.
In other words: spillovers from low-carbon technologies are more economically valuable
than spillovers from high-carbon technologies. However, Dechezleprêtre et al. (2014) are not
able to assess whether this economic gain is sufficient to offset the costs of regulation.
11 http://www.eeclab.org.uk/forcedirect_arx.html?tojson_dirlinks0_1995_15_1000_0.json
http://www.eeclab.org.uk/forcedirect_arx.html?tojson_dirlinks0_1995_15_1000_2.json
12 Note that since the data stops in 2005, fracking technologies are not included in the ‘grey’ category.
Where does the low-carbon advantage come from? One potential explanation is that low-
carbon technologies are by and large new technology fields. New technology fields offer
potentially high marginal private returns to first movers and might thus generate large knowledge
spillovers. Dechezleprêtre et al. (2014) compare the spillovers from low-carbon and high-carbon
technologies to a range of other emerging technologies, such as IT and biotechnologies.
They find that the intensity of spillovers from low-carbon technologies is comparable to other
emerging technologies (see Figure 6). Knowledge spillovers from high-carbon technologies are
lagging behind.
To sum up, while environmental policies are unlikely to be beneficial for companies facing new
regulatory costs, they can have economy-wide benefits through increased innovation spillovers.
An important implication of this finding is that seeking only ‘win-win’ solutions with no losers
would risk leaving many socially beneficial policies off the table.
The evidence on competitiveness impacts from unilateral climate change policy is mixed,
with empirical analysis indicating that existing policies have small effects on companies’
performance and relocation (or ‘carbon leakage’), at least in most sectors (for a review of the
most recent literature see Bassi & Zenghelis, 2015; Dechezleprêtre & Sato, 2015).
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
IT 3D
Car Robot Nano
0.2
low-carbon
0.1
Electricty
low-carbon
0
Biotechs
-0.1
Car high-carbon
Electricty
-0.2
high-carbon
-0.3
Note: The figure compares the intensity of knowledge spillovers (as measured by patent citations) in a number
of technologies, compared to the average patented technology. The y-axis represents the percentage
difference in the intensity of knowledge spillovers. For example, a value of 0.2 means that the technology
induces 20% more knowledge spillovers than the average patented technology. Red dots are point estimates;
the black lines show 95% confidence intervals. Source: Dechezleprêtre et al. (2014)
If there are sufficiently strong localised spillovers, such negative effects on economic
outcomes could potentially be offset. Hence, the incentives to adopt climate change policies
are much higher when local knowledge spillovers from low-carbon technologies are factored in.
Dechezleprêtre et al. (2014) examine this by looking separately at spillovers that occur within the
same country where the original innovation emerged and spillovers elsewhere. They find that
low-carbon innovations generate knowledge spillovers both locally and across borders,
with a somewhat larger advantage for local benefits. Hence, this provides a potential
channel for positive home country effects from unilateral policies. Moreover, they find that on
average, 52 per cent of spillovers in low-carbon technologies patented since the year 2000
occur within the inventor’s country. This proportion of local spillovers depends on the size and
the openness of the economy: 61 per cent for Japan, 59 per cent for the US, 44 per cent for
Germany but 28 per cent for France, 15 per cent for the UK and 10 per cent for the Netherlands
(see Figure 7). For the European Union as a whole (i.e. considering Europe as a single entity),
61 per cent of knowledge spillovers occur domestically. These numbers all suggest that the
local benefits from induced low-carbon innovation are far greater than the local benefits
of carbon emissions reductions alone, since the benefits of avoided climate change are
essentially equally shared among all countries around the world.
%
0 − .05
.05 − .1
.1 − .25
.25 − .5
.5 − 1
No data
Japan
Denmark
S Korea
Germany
Taiwan
Finland
Israel
Sweden
Austria
France
Switzerland
USA
Netherlands
UK
Canada
Belgium
Norway
Italy
Spain
Singapore
Australia
China
Poland
India
Russia
Brazil
0 .5 1 1.5 2 2.5
Source: Source: authors’ own calculations from the Patstat database. Only high-value patents taken out in at
least two patent offices in the world are included. Real GDP at chained PPPs in billion 2005 US$ is from the
Penn World Table. We group five years to mitigate the effect of annual fluctuations.
The Fraunhofer Institute also provides information and policy advice to the German
government with regards to developments in the technological landscape and the viability of
different technological options. The Fraunhofer Institute for Solar Energy Systems is especially
important in supporting high-level solar PV innovation for the solar PV industry – particularly in
helping domestic semi-conductor companies retool and sell the equipment used for
crystalline PV factories. This Institute also holds the world record for the most efficient silicon
solar cells (in lab settings). Fraunhofer’s engineering and economics research also provides
technical and policy assistance in managing electricity market and grid instability caused by
sudden increases to the renewable energy generation feed into the German electricity grid.
16
Public R&D expenditures (billion 2012 €)
14
12
10
0.12%
0.1%
Public low-carbon R&D expenditures in GDP
0.08%
0.06%
0.04%
OECD average
0.02%
0
FIN
JPN
NOR
DNK
CAN
AUS
FRA
CHE
HUN
SWE
PRT
AUT
USA
KOR
DEU
NLD
UK
SVK
ITA
BEL
ESP
NZL
IRL
GRC
POL
TUR
LUX
CZE
Determining how much government R&D money to spend on low-carbon innovation is an important
question for policymakers. Here, economics provides less of an answer, as estimating the potential
benefits from new R&D spending is a difficult task and engineers are better suited than economists
to determine which projects are most deserving from a technical standpoint. However, given the
need for a diversified energy portfolio to address climate change, it is hard to imagine that there
would not be enough deserving technologies for the research funding available. Rather, economic
analysis suggests that the constraints for funding are likely to come from other sources, such as the
current pool of scientists and engineering personnel available to work on low-carbon projects,
and how quickly it can be expanded. That is, the spending limits come not from the number of
deserving projects, but rather the limits of the existing research infrastructure.
Recent papers show that the optimal climate policy heavily relies on research subsidies.
For example, Acemoglu et al. (2014) suggest that 90 per cent of all R&D expenditures in low-carbon
technologies should be funded by the government during a couple of decades, so that the
productivity of low-carbon technologies quickly catches up with that of high-carbon technologies.
Recent IEA estimates suggest that achieving global energy and climate change ambitions consistent
with a 50 per cent reduction of energy-related carbon dioxide emissions in 2050 with respect to
2007 (the 2010 BLUE Map scenario) would require a two to fivefold increase in public R&D spending
(IEA, 2010). The gap between current public R&D and the funding needed is particularly large in
low-carbon transportation, CCS, smart grids and energy efficiency in industry (IEA, 2010).
However, growth in low-carbon R&D budgets should be slow and steady, allowing time for the
development of young researchers in the field. In Europe, a doubling of public R&D expenditures
over 10 years (from €4bn to €8bn a year) corresponds to what was observed between 2001
and 2011 and thus seems achievable. Experience from the US National Institutes of Health
(NIH), for instance, shows that rapidly doubling and subsequently decreasing budget on the
bio-medical sciences between 1998 and 2007 led to high adjustment costs (linked with hiring
new staff, buying new equipment, and so on), a career crisis (young persons trained during the
upsurge in spending had to compete with a larger supply of young biomedical researchers after
the upsurge when there were fewer research opportunities than when they were attracted to the
field) and wasteful uses of resources (Freeman and Van Reenen, 2009).
It is also important that any policy effort to accelerate innovation in low-carbon technologies
includes a component to train new scientists and technical workers, in order to increase the
supply of qualified scientists in the long run. In this respect, the 2009 spike in R&D funding in
the US and elsewhere can be counterproductive. What is needed is a slow but sustained
growth in public R&D funding over the next decade. Commitments to fund R&D should have a
long-term component (until at least 2030) just like carbon emission caps. So while it is welcome
that countries such as the UK have committed to doubling public funding for low-carbon R&D
by 2020 as part of ‘Mission Innovation’13; countries should be encouraged to set public R&D
targets as far ahead as 2030. Targets would vary between countries and may need to be set
within a range, but such long-term targets would reduce public funding spikes and associated
adjustment costs, and ultimately could reduce the overall cost of decarbonisation.
To provide such a long-term commitment, revenues from auctioned carbon permits in the many
carbon markets that now exist around the world could provide a source of sustained funding for low
carbon R&D. For example, to fund a doubling of public R&D in Europe over the next decade, it would
be enough to allocate 10 per cent of the revenues from auctioned emissions allowances (assuming
an average carbon price of €11/tonne) to low-carbon innovation (Dechezleprêtre and Popp, 2015).14
Historically, economists have argued that market-based policies provide greater incentives for
innovation, while command-and-control measures (such as performance or technology
standards) can be too rigid and cost inefficient. Market-based policies provide rewards for
continuous improvement in environmental quality, whereas command-and-control policies
penalise polluters who do not meet the standard, but do not reward those who do better than
mandated (Magat, 1978; Milliman and Prince, 1989).
13 Mission Innovation is a global initiative to accelerate public and private clean energy innovation to address
climate change, make clean energy affordable to consumers, and create green jobs and commercial
opportunities. Through the initiative, 20 countries representing 80 per cent of global clean energy research and
development (R&D) budgets are committing to double their respective R&D investments over five years.
14 To efficiently allocate public spending, one would need to equate the marginal social benefit of projects with the
marginal social cost of revenue raising methods, and there is no reason why green R&D and emissions permits
would meet this except by coincidence. However, from a political economy point of view, hypothecation could
help securing buy-in and credibility.
However, recent research suggests that the effects are more nuanced. For example, standards
can be of use in case of anomalies in the behavioural response to market-based
instruments. A typical example is the ‘energy efficiency paradox’, where seemingly cost-
effective energy-efficient technologies diffuse slowly, even if they provide cost-saving benefits
to the users. Several researchers have examined this paradox, offering explanations including:
consumers using high discount rates (Train, 1985); credit-constrained consumers caring more
about up-front costs than lifetime cost savings (Jaffe and Stavins, 1994); agency problems such
as landlord/tenant relationships (Levinson and Niemann, 2004); and uncertainty over future
costs (Anderson and Newell, 2004).
To the extent that diffusion is limited by other market failures, market-based instruments that
simply increase the economic incentive to adopt environmentally-friendly technologies will be
insufficient. Additional command-and-control policies focused directly on the correction of
market failures and other government/institution failure can therefore be needed. In a recent
review, Vollebergh and Van der Werf (2014) show that, in appropriate conditions, standards are
key complements to market-based instruments. For example, to promote the development
of electric vehicles, charging stations must be in place. However, the private sector has little
incentive to provide charging stations without existing demand from electric vehicles. In the
case of such network externalities, clear technology standards provide guidance to firms as to
the expected future direction of technology. These policy signals must be clear, to avoid
unintended consequences.
Among market-based policies, differences between policies also matter. Johnstone et al. (2010)
compare quantity-based policies, such as renewable energy certificates, to price-based policies
to promote renewable energy, such as tax credits and feed-in tariffs.15 Quantity-based policies
tend to favour the development of lowest cost technologies which are closest to being
competitive with traditional energy sources, such as onshore wind energy. This leads to lower
compliance costs in the short-run, as firms choose the most effective short-term strategy.
However, since firms focus on those technologies closest to market, quantity-based incentives
do not provide as much incentive for research on longer-term needs. By contrast, price-based
incentives that differentiate between technologies (for example feed-in tariffs that differ across
types of renewable energy technologies) can be more effective in supporting innovation in
emerging technologies which are further from being competitive with traditional energy sources,
such as marine energy. However, this raises the costs of regulation, as firms are forced to use
technologies that are not cost-effective.
The perceived stability of the policy is also important. Since expectations over future prices
determine innovation, long-term regulatory consistency is crucial for new technology development
(Held et al., 2009). For example, Butler and Neuhoff (2008) show how German feed-in tariffs
stimulated overall investment quantity more than UK renewable energy quotas because the
guaranteed revenues associated with feed-in tariff reduced risks from the project investment.
15 Feed-in tariffs, used in various European countries, guarantee renewable energy producers a minimum price
for the electricity they produce.
One possible solution to overcome this is to use a portfolio of policies – including carbon
markets, taxes, targets, feed-in tariffs, etc. – to ensure short-run compliance at low costs,
as well as providing public funding to low-carbon R&D that supports emerging technologies.
A study by Zachmann et al. (2014) shows that the six largest European countries spent €315 million
in 2010 to support R&D in wind and solar power. The cost to society implied by the deployment of
wind and solar technologies16 that same year represented €48,300 million (see Figure 11).
According to Fischer, Newell & Preonas (2013) the optimal ratio of deployment spending to R&D
spending does not exceed one for wind energy. With extreme assumptions on learning-by-doing this
ratio goes to 6.5-to-1. The ratio of public spending on deployment to R&D exceeds one for solar
energy, but not by much. The ratio reaches 10-to-1 under the ‘high learning-by-doing’ scenario.
The optimal policy mix varies across low-carbon technologies, depending on their degree of maturity.
The relative importance of market ‘pull’ vis-à-vis technology ‘push’ decreases as technologies
mature (Grubb, 2004). However, the public spending ratio in European countries for deployment
vs R&D of 150-to-1 (see Figure 11) seems completely disconnected from the most optimistic
assumptions on the rate of learning-by-doing which usually serves as the main justification for
deployment policies. It appears, then, that European countries have been emphasising technology
deployment through feed-in tariffs for renewable energy production, over direct R&D support.
This suggests that current efforts on deployment should be augmented with additional
R&D support, such that the marginal euro spent on low-carbon technologies should go
to R&D rather than deployment. From a political point of view, an additional advantage of
direct support to R&D over demand-pull instruments such as feed-in tariffs is that, although
feed-in tariffs incentivise innovation activity since the return from, for example a wind farm,
depends on electricity production related to the performance of wind turbines, direct support to
R&D is by definition targeted at domestic manufacturers while feed-in tariffs may encourage
innovation activity mostly in foreign countries, as shown by Dechezleprêtre and Glachant (2014).
Figure 11. Public support to R&D vs deployment in wind and solar energy in the six largest
European economies in 2010 (million euros)
RDD Deployment
315
48298
16 Net deployment costs are calculated as the difference between the deployment costs and the net present
value of the future electricity generated, so it does not only include direct support (e.g. loans, tax credits), but it
also places a value on support mechanisms such as feed-in tariffs and RPS.
5. Conclusion
It is widely recognised that innovation is essential for the development of new low-carbon
technologies and the improvement of existing technologies. As such, it is key to any carbon
emissions mitigation scenario.
There is ample empirical evidence that climate change policies induce innovation in low-
carbon technologies. The impact of policies on innovation appears to be both large and rapid.
Thus, climate change regulations can help economies break away from a polluting economic
trajectory and move to a low-carbon one.
The public goods nature of knowledge implies that socially beneficial research opportunities
are ignored by firms because they are unable to fully capture the rewards of such innovations.
Consequently, too little innovation is carried out in the economy compared to a socially optimal
situation. Hence, innovation in low-carbon technologies induced by climate change
policies can increase welfare.
However, this depends on whether new research and development (R&D) investments in low-carbon
technologies come at the expense of innovation in other technologies. Empirical evidence suggests
that some degree of crowding-out does occur. However, low-carbon innovations tend to crowd out
high-carbon innovations in the same sector. A crucial role for climate change policies is to make
sure that low-carbon innovation activity comes at the expense of innovation in polluting
technologies and not of other socially valuable innovation. Policies that change the relative price of
low-carbon and high-carbon inputs, such as carbon markets or fuel taxes, can play this role effectively.
Another implication is that the welfare impacts of induced low-carbon innovation depend on the
relative size of the social benefits coming from knowledge spillovers in low-carbon and high-
carbon innovation. Recent evidence shows that low-carbon innovations induce larger
economic benefits, in terms of knowledge spillovers, than the high-carbon technologies
they replace. This supports the idea that directed technological change could help offset the
costs of climate change regulations or even encourage economic growth.
Currently, R&D support has been disproportionately low compared to deployment support,
especially in Europe. There is a strong argument therefore to increase the size of public
R&D support. It is difficult to give a precise figure for increased public investment, but the
literature agrees that it should at least double. Some of the greatest funding increases are needed
in low-carbon transportation, carbon capture and storage (CCS), smart grids and industrial
energy efficiency.
Increased investment in low-carbon R&D should be slow and sustained. While it is welcome
that countries such as the UK have committed to doubling public funding for low-carbon R&D by
2020 as part of ‘Mission Innovation’; countries should be encouraged to set public R&D
targets as far ahead as 2030. Targets would vary between countries and may need to be set
within a range, but such long-term targets would reduce public funding spikes and associated
adjustment costs, and ultimately could reduce the overall cost of decarbonisation.
– There is scope for increasing investment in several Member States if the European
Union is keen to strengthen its competitive advantage on low-carbon innovation.
Ranking European Member States by the number of low-carbon inventions per billion US
dollars of GDP shows that Germany and the Scandinavian countries are at the forefront of
innovation. The UK is approximately midway in the ranking, ahead of countries such as
Belgium, Norway, Italy, Spain and Poland, but behind France, the Netherlands and others.
– Additional direct support for R&D is vital to meet emissions reduction targets cost
effectively. In the past years European Member States have put a strong emphasis on
deployment policies, especially through feed-in tariffs for renewable energy. This has
resulted in a strong imbalance between deployment and R&D measures across the
European Union, with deployment policy outweighing direct R&D support by 150 to 1.
While there is no agreement of what the optimal mix between R&D and deployment
spending should be, the European ratio appears completely disconnected from the ratio
suggested in the literature, which even under extreme assumptions should not go beyond
10 to 1. This suggests that current efforts on deployment should be augmented with
additional direct support to R&D activities such that the marginal Euro spent on clean
technologies should go to R&D rather than deployment.
References
Acemoglu, D., 2002. Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies, 69, pp.781–809.
Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., Bursztyn, L., and Hemous, D., 2012. The Environment and directed technical
change. American Economic Review, 102 (1), pp.131–166.
Acemoglu, D., Akcigit, U., Hanley, D., and Kerr, W., 2014. Transition to low-carbon technology. Journal of
Political Economy, forthcoming.
Aghion, P., Hepburn, C., Teytelboym, A., and Zenghelis, D., 2014. Path-dependency, innovation and the
economics of climate change. Supporting paper for New Climate Economy. London: Grantham Research
Institute on Climate Change and the Environment, London School of Economics and political Science. [pdf]
Available here: http://2014.newclimateeconomy.report/wp-content/uploads/2014/11/Path-dependence-and-
econ-of-change.pdf
Aghion, P., Dechezleprêtre, A., Hémous, D., Martin, R., & Van Reenen, J. 2016. Carbon taxes, path
Dependency, and Directed Technical Change: Evidence from the Auto Industry. Journal of Political Economy,
forthcoming.
Ambec, S., Cohen, M., Elgie, S., and Lanoie, P., 2013.The Porter hypothesis at 20: Can environmental
regulation enhance innovation and competitiveness? Review of Environmental Economics and Policy,
7(1), pp.2–22.
Anderson, S.T., and Newell, R.G., 2004. Information programs for technology adoption: the case of energy-
efficiency audits. Resource Energy Economics, 26, pp.27–50.
Bassi, S., and Zenghelis, D., 2014. Burden or opportunity? How UK emission reduction policies affect the
competitiveness of businesses. Policy paper. London: Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy and
Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment. [pdf] Available at: http://www.lse.ac.
uk/GranthamInstitute/publication/burden-or-opportunity-how-uk-emissions-reductions-policies-affect-the-
competitiveness-of-businesses/
Bloom, N., Van Reenen, J., and Shankerman, M., 2013. Identifying technology spillovers and product market
rivalry. Econometrica, 81(4), pp.1347–1393.
Botta, E., and Kozluk, T., 2014. Measuring environmental policy stringency in OECD countries. A composite
index approach. OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 1177. [pdf] Available at: http://www.
oecd-ilibrary.org/docserver/download/5jxrjnc45gvg.pdf?expires=1452603396&id=id&accname=guest&checks
um=82CA61FB36402F2CE8BC745EB0AAC716
Brunnermeier, S. B. and Cohen, M. A., 2003. Determinants of environmental innovation in US manufacturing
industries. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45(2), pp.278–293.
Brunnermeier, S. B. & Levinson, A., 2004. Examining the evidence on environmental regulations and industry
location. The Journal of Environment & Development, 13(1), pp.6–41.
Butler, L., and Neuhoff, K., 2008. Comparison of feed-in tariff, quota and auction mechanisms to support
wind power development. Renewable Energy, 33, pp1854–1867.
Calel, R. and Dechezleprêtre, A., 2014. Environmental policy and directed technological change: Evidence
from the European carbon market. Review of Economics and Statistics. [online] Available at: http://www.
mitpressjournals.org/doi/abs/10.1162/REST_a_00470#.Vo-mjvmLSHs
Dechezleprêtre, A., 2011. Invention and transfer of climate change mitigation technologies: a global analysis.
Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 5(1), pp.109–130.
Dechezleprêtre, A., and Glachant, M., 2014. Does foreign environmental policy influence domestic innovation?
Evidence from the wind industry. Environmental Resource Economics, 58, pp.391–413.
Dechezleprêtre, A., Martin, R., and Mohnen, M., 2014. Knowledge spillovers from low-carbon technologies:
A patent citation analysis. Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment Working
Paper 135.
Dechezlepretre, A., and Popp, D., 2015. Fiscal and regulatory instruments for low-carbon technology
development in the European Union. CESifo Working Paper No. 5361. [online] Available at: http://personal.lse.
ac.uk/dechezle/cesifo1_wp5361.pdf
Dechezleprêtre, A., and Sato, M., 2014. The impacts of climate change regulations on competitiveness.
Policy brief. London: Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment and Global Green
Growth Institute. Available at: http://www.lse.ac.uk/GranthamInstitute/wp-content/uploads/2014/11/Impacts_
of_Climate change_Regulations.pdf
Freeman, R., and Reenen, J. Van., 2009. What if congress doubled R&D spending on the physical sciences?
Innovation Policy and the Economy, 9(1), pp.1–38.
Fischer, C., Newell, R. G., and Preonas, L., 2013. Environmental and technology policy options in the
electricity sector: Interactions and outcomes. Resources for the Future Discussion Paper Series, 13(20).
Geroski, P., 1995. Markets for technology: knowledge, innovation, and appropriability. In: Stoneman, P. (ed).
Handbook of the Economics of Innovation and Technological Change. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers, pp.
90– 131.
Griliches, Z., 1992. The search for R&D spillovers. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 94(0), S29–47.
Grubb, M., 2004. Technology innovation and climate change policy: an overview of issues and options.
Keio Economic Studies, 41(2), pp.103-132.
Hall, B.H., Mairesse, J., Mohnen, P., 2010. Measuring the returns to R&D. Handbook of the Economics of
Innovation, 2, pp.1033–1082.
Hall, B. H., 1996. The private and social returns to research and development. In: Bruce L.R. Smith and
Claude E. Barfield (eds). Technology, R&D, and the Economy. Washington D.C: Brookings Institution.
Held, A., Ragwitz, M., Haas, R., 2009. On the success of policy strategies for the promotion of electricity
from renewable energy sources. Energy and Environment, 17(6), pp.849-868.
Hicks, J. R., 1932. The theory of wages. MacMillan.
Hottenrott, H. and Rexhäuser, S., 2013. Policy-induced environmental technology and inventive efforts:
Is there a crowding out? ZEW Discussion Paper No. 13-115, Mannheim.
IEA, 2010. Global gaps in low-carbon energy RD&D: Update and recommendations for international
collaboration. Report for the Low-carbon Energy Ministerial. Paris: International Energy Agency.
IEA, 2008. Energy technology perspectives: Scenarios & strategies to 2050. [pdf] Available at:
http://www.iea.org/media/etp/etp2008.pdf
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), 2014. Summary for Policymakers. In S. Edenhofer, O., R.
Pichs-Madruga, Y. Sokona, E. Farahani (ed). Climate Change 2014, Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution
of Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. [pdf]
Cambridge (UK) and New York (NY, USA): IPCC. [online] Available at: http://report.mitigation2014.org/spm/
ipcc_wg3_ar5_summary-for-policymakers_approved.pdf
Jaffe, A. B., 1986. Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: evidence from firms’ patents, profits,
and market value. The American Economic Review, 76(5), pp.984–1001.
Jaffe, A. B., Peterson, S. R., Portney, P. R., and Stavins, R. N., 1995. Environmental regulation and the
competitiveness of US manufacturing: What does the evidence tell us? Journal of Economic Literature, 33(1),
pp.132–163.
Jaffe, A. B. and Palmer, K., 1997. Environmental regulation and innovation: A panel data study. The Review of
Economics and Statistics, 79(4), pp.610–619.
Jaffe, A.B., and Stavins, R.N., 1994. The energy-efficiency gap: what does it mean? Energy Policy, 22 (10),
pp.804–810.
Johnstone, N., Hascic, I., and Popp, D., 2010. Renewable energy policies and technological innovation:
evidence based on patent counts. Environmental and Resource Economics, 45(1), pp.133–155.
Jones, C. I., and Williams, J. C., 1998. Measuring the social return to R&D. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 113(4), pp.1119–1135.
Kerr, S., and Newell, R.G., 2003. Policy-induced technology adoption: Evidence from the US lead phasedown.
Journal of Industrial Economics, 51(3), pp.317–343.
Krugman, P., 1994. Competitiveness: A dangerous obsession. Foreign Affairs [online] March/April. Available at:
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/1994-03-01/competitiveness-dangerous-obsession
Lanjouw, J.O., and Mody, A., 1996. Innovation and the international diffusion of environmentally responsive
technology. Research Policy, 25(4), pp.549-571.
Lanoie, P., Laurent-Luccheti, J., Johnstone, N. and Ambec, S., 2011. Environmental policy, innovation and
performance: New insights on the Porter hypothesis. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy,
Vol. 20, No. 3, pp. 803-842.
Levinson, A., Niemann, S., 2004. Energy use by apartment tenants when landlords pay for utilities. Resource
and Energy Economics, 26, pp.51–75.
Mansfield, E., Rapoport, J., Romeo, A., Wagner, S., and Beardsley, G., 1977. Social and private rates of return
from industrial innovations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91(2), pp.221-240.
Magat, W.A., 1978. Pollution control and technological advance: A dynamic model of the firm. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 5(1), pp.1–25.
Martin, R., Muûls, M., De Preux, L., and Wagner, U., 2014. Industry compensation under the risk of relocation:
A firm-level analysis of the EU emissions trading scheme. American Economic Review, 104, pp.2482-2508
Milliman, S.R., Prince, R., 1989. Firm incentives to promote technological change in pollution control.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 17(30), pp.247–265.
Newell, R., Jaffe, A., and Stavins, R., 1999. The induced innovation hypothesis and energy saving
technological change. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3) pp.941– 975.
Pakes, A., 1985. On patents, R&D and the stock market rate of return. Journal of Political Economy, 93(2),
pp.390–409.
Porter, M., E. and Van der Linde, C., 1995. Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness
relationship. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), pp.97–118.
Popp, D., 2002. Induced innovation and energy prices. The American Economic Review, 92(1), pp.160–180.
Popp, D., 2004. ENTICE: endogenous technological change in the DICE model of global warming. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 48(1), pp.742-768.
Popp, D., 2006. International innovation and diffusion of air pollution control technologies: The effects of NOX
and SO2 regulation in the US, Japan, and Germany. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
51(1), pp.46-71.
Popp, D., 2010. Innovation and climate policy. In: (Eds) Gordon C. Rausser, V. Kerry Smith and David
Zilberman, Annual Review of Resource Economics, vol. 2, 2010. Annual Reviews, Palo Alto, CA, pp. 275- 298.
Popp, D., Newell, R. and Jaffe, A., 2010. Energy, the environment, and technological change. Handbook of the
Economics of Innovation: vol. 2, Bronwyn Hall and Nathan Rosenberg, eds., Academic Press/Elsevier, pp.873-937.
Popp, D. and Newell, R., 2012. Where does energy R&D come from? Examining crowding out from energy
R&D. Energy Economics, 34(4), pp.980–991.
Porter, M. E., 1991. Towards a dynamic theory of strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 12, pp.95–117.
Rexhäuser, S. and Rammer, C., 2014. Environmental innovations and firm profitability: unmasking the Porter
Hypothesis. Environmental and Resource Economics, 57, pp.145–167
Snyder, L., Miller, N., and Stavins, R., 2003. The effects of environmental regulation on technology diffusion:
The case of chlorine manufacturing. American Economic Review, 93(2), pp. 431-435.
Train, K., 1985. Discount rates in consumers’ energy-related decisions: a review of the literature. Energy,
10(12), pp.1243–1253.
Verdolini, E., & Gaelotti, M., 2011. At home and abroad: an empirical analysis of innovation and diffusion in
energy-efficient technologies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 61, pp.119–134.
Vollebergh, H.R.J., and Van der Werf, E., 2014. The role of standards in eco-innovation: Lessons for
policymakers. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 8(2), pp.230–248.
Zachmann, G., Serwaah, A., and Peruzzi, M., 2014. When and how to support renewables? Letting the data
speak. Bruegel Working Paper 2014/01.