Session1 Solutions
Session1 Solutions
Session1 Solutions
19 December 2021
i=1
Pn
where A > 0 is a scale factor, and i=1 αi = 1. Prices are p = (p1 , p2 , ..., pn ) and the income is w.
1.1 Solve the Utility Maximization Problem (UMP) to derive the Walrasian demand function. Find
the indirect utility function.
1.2 Solve the Expenditure Maximization Problem (EMP) and derive the Hicksian demand function.
Find the expenditure function.
ANSWER
We solve the utility maximisation problem (UMP) and we derive the Walrasian demand Function:
n
Y
max A xα
i ,
i
x1 ;x2 ;...;xn
i=1
subject to
X
pi xi ≤ w, (budget constraint)
xi ≥ 0∀i, (non negativity constraint)
∂L(.)
∂xi = 0 for i = 1, ..., n
λ ∂L(.)
P
∂λ = λ(w − pi xi ), with complementary slackness
∂L(.)
• λ = 0; ∂λ ≥ 0 (unconstrained maximization)
∂L(.)
• λ > 0; ∂λ = 0 (constrained maximization)
1
µi ∂L(.)
∂µi = µi xi = 0, with complementary slackness
• µi = 0; ∂L(.)
∂µi ≥ 0 (interior solution, non negativity constraints do not bind)
• µi > 0; ∂L(.)
∂µi = 0 (corner solution, non negativity constraints bind)
Notice that if λ = 0 the Budget constraint does not enter in the Lagrangean, if λ > 0 we have constrained
optimization, that is
• ∂L(.)
P P
∂λ = 0 ⇒ w − p i xi = 0 ⇒ w = pi xi i.e. Walras Law
∂L(.)
• ∂w = λ i.e. marginal rate of income equals λ (i.e shadow value of constraint or marginal benefit
of relaxing the constraint)
• xi = 0 ⇒ U (.) = 0, it is always possible to get U > 0 if xi > 0 (i.e the non-negativity constraint
never binds, there is always an interior solution µi = 0; xi > 0∀i)
∂U (.)
• ∂xi > 0, which implies monotonicity, i.e. the agent always spends the entire income and the
budget constraint binds, λ > 0
∂L(.) P P
• B: ∂λ =0⇒w− pi xi = 0 ⇒ w = pi xi
xα i
αi −1
Y α Qn
From A it holds that i
αi Aαi xi xj j = λpi ⇒ Aαi
xi i=1 xα
i = λpi
i
xi
|{z} j6=i
=1
| {z }
(∗)
Then for every i and j we have
n n
1 Aαi Y αi 1 Aαj Y αj
( xi ) = λ = ( x )
Pi xi i=1 Pj xj j=1 j
αi xi Pi
⇒ = ≡C
α j xj Pj
| {z }
M RSij
2
X
αi Pi xi + Pi xi αj = αi w
j6=i
∂λ i=1 i=1
n =0 n
∂L(.) Y α αi Y αi
= Pi = λAαi xiαi −1 xj j + µi = 0 ⇒ Pi = λA
z}|{
B:− x
∂xi xi i=1 i
j6=i
Plug A in B so that ⇒ Pi = λA αxii v̄. Next, we want to remove λ. Solve the last condition for xi = λαi v̄
Pi ≡C
and plug in it back in condition (A) to get.
n n
Y i i α i αi 1 1 Y αi i 1
v̄ = A [λα v̄ α ( ) ] ⇒ v̄ = Aλ αi v̄ αi [( )α ] ⇒ λ = Qn αi i
P P
i=1
Pi i=1
Pi A i=1 ( Pi )α
n α n α !
v̄ αi Y Pi i v̄ α Y Pi i
h(P ; v̄) = ; ...;
A Pi αi A Pn αi
3
Indirect Utility
N α αi
αi w i
Y αi
v(p; w) = v(x1 (p; w); ...; xN (p; w)) = A = AwP iN
i
i=1
Pi Pi
Expenditure Function
N N N
Y αi ! N αi
X X v̄ αi Pi v̄ Y Pi
e(P ; u) = pi hi (p; v̄) = Pi =
i=1 i=1
A Pi i=1
αi A i=1 αi
Notice that:
v (P ; e(P ; u)) = v̄
e (P ; v(P ; w)) = w
∂e(P ; u)
= hi (P ; v̄)
∂Pi
4
2 Quasi-Linear Utility Function
Let the consumer’s preferences be described by the following quasi-linear utility function:
u(x1 , x2 ) = xα
1 + x2
ANSWER
Assume preferences are given by:
max xα
1 + x2
x1 ;x2
P1 x1 − P2 x2 ≤ w ; x1 ≥ 0, x2 ≥ 0
L(.) = xα
1 + x2 + λ[w − P1 x1 − P2 x2 ] + µ1 x1 + µ2 x2
λ (w − P1 x1 − P2 x2 ) = 0
µ1 x1 = 0; µ2 x2 = 0; µ1 ≥ 0; µ2 ≥ 0; λ ≥ 0
CASE 1
x2 = 0; x2 = 0 ⇒ w = 0 (uninteresting case)
CASE 2
x1 > 0; x2 > 0 ⇒ µ1 = 0; µ2 = 0; λ = 0
From the FOCs we have that
1
αxα−1
1 − λP1 = 0 ⇒ λ = αxα−1
P1 1
5
1
1 − λP2 = 0 ⇒ λ =
P2
Dividing by parts the two conditions above we get:
P1
= αx1α−1
P2
1
P2 1−α
x1 = α
P1
1
1−α
w − αP 2
P1
x2 =
P2
CASE 3
x1 > 0; x2 = 0 ⇒ µ1 = 0; µ2 ≥ 0; λ > 0
1
αxα−1
1 − λP1 = 0 ⇒ λ = αxα−1
P1 1
1
1 − λP2 ≤ 0 ⇒ λ ≥
P2
Dividing by parts
P1
≤ αx1α−1
P2
x2 = 0
w
w − P1 x 1 − P2 x 2 = 0 ⇒ x 1 =
P1
CASE 4
x1 = 0; x2 > 0 ⇒ µ1 ≥ 0; µ2 = 0; λ > 0
6
1
αxα−1
1 − λP1 ≤ 0 ⇒ λ ≥ αxα−1
P1 1
1
1 − λP2 = 0 ⇒ =λ
P2
Dividing by parts
P2 x1−α
≤ 1
P1 α
Walrasian Demand
w P1
x1 (P, w) = if < αx1α−1
P1 P2
1
1−α
P2 P1
x1 (P, w) = α if = αx1α−1
P1 P2
P1
x2 (P, w) = 0 if < αxα−1
1
P2
1
1−α
w − αP
P1
2
P1
x2 (P, w) = if = αxα−1
1
P2 P2
7
3 Kinked Preferences
Consider a consumer whose preferences are kinked and are described by the following utility function:
Consider x1
P1 1
• if P2 > α ⇒ x1 = 0
P1 1 w w
• if P2 = α ⇒ P2 = αP1 ⇒ x1 = P1 (1+α) ⇒ x1 ∈ 0;
P1 (1 + α)
P1 P1 w w αw w αw
• if P2 = α ⇒ P2 = α ⇒ x1 = P1 +P2 ⇒ x1 = 1
P1 (1+ α )
= P1 (1+α) ⇒ x1 ∈ ;
P1 P1 (1 + α)
P1 w
• if P2 < α ⇒ x1 =
P1
P1 1 w
• if α < P2 < α ⇒ x1 =
P1 + P2
8
P1 1
0
→ P2 α >
w P1
= α1
∈ 0; P (1+α)
→ P2
1
w P1 1
x1 (P ; w) = →α <P <
P1
+P2 2 α
αw w P1
∈ →
P1 (1+α) ; P1 =α
P2
w P1
P1 → P2 <α
w P1 1
P2 → P2 α >
αw w P1
= α1
∈ ;
P2 (1+α) P2 → P2
w P1 1
x2 (P ; w) = →α <P <
P1
+P2 2 α
w P1
∈ 0; P1 (1+α) →
P2 =α
P1
0 → <α
P2
——
V (p; w) = U (x1 (P ; w); x2 (P ; w))
P1 1
• if P2 > α ⇒ V (.) = max{0; αw αw
P2 } + min{0; P2 } =
αw
P2
P1 1 w(1+α)
• if α < P2 < α ⇒ V (.) = max{ P1αw αw αw αw
+P2 ; P1 +P2 } + min{ P1 +P2 ; P1 +P2 } = P1 +P2
P1
• if P2 < α ⇒ V (.) = max{ αw w
P1 ; 0} + min{ P1 ; 0} =
αw
P1
P1 1 w
• if P2 = α ⇒ V (.) = max{αx1 ; αx2 } + min{x1 ; x2 } = αx2 +x1 = α
| {z } | {z } P2
always x2 always x1
|{z}
plugging in the Walrasian demands at the two extremes
P1 w
• if P2 = α ⇒ V (.) = max{αx1 ; αx2 } + min{x1 ; x2 } = αx1 +x2 = α
| {z } | {z } P1
always x1 always x2
|{z}
plugging in the Walrasian demands at the two extremes
αw
P2
→P 1
P2 ≥ α
1
(1+α)w
V (P ; w) = P +P →α< P P2 ≥
1 1
α
αw1 2
P1
P1 → P2 ≤ α
9
4 Slutsky Decomposition (Based on MWG 3.G.15)
4.2 Compute the Slutsky equation when all prices change simultaneously.
The utility function is given by:
1 1
U = 2x12 + 2x22
and !2
1
U − 2x12
x2 =
2
is the indifference curve
The utility maximization problem then is:
max U s.t p1 x1 + p2 x2 = w
10
Expenditure Minimization Problem
The problem is to:
1 1
min p1 x1 + p2 x2 s.t U = 2x12 + 2x22 ⇒ (no excess utility)
1 U p2
x12 = ⇒
2p2 + 2p1
2
U p2
h1 (p, U ) =
2(p1 + p2 )
1 p21 U 2 p22
x22 = ⇒
p22 2p2 + 2p1
2
U 2 p21
h2 (p, U ) =
2(p1 + p2 )
So the Hicksian demands are:
2 2 !
U p2 U p1
= (U p2 )2 · (p1 + p2 )−2 /4, (U p1 )2 · (p1 + p2 )−2 /4
h(p, U ) = ,
2(p1 + p2 ) 2(p1 + p2 )
2 2
p1 u2 p22 + p2 u2 p21
U p2 U p1
e(p, U ) = p1 + p2 =
2(p1 + p2 ) 2(p1 + p2 ) 4(p1 + p2 )2
So the expenditure function is given by
U 2 p1 p2
e(p, U ) =
4(p1 + p2 )
12
4(p1 + p2 )w
v(p, w) = ⇒
p1 p2
Slutsky Equation
It holds that ∂x
∂w > 0 (NORMAL GOOD),
e ∂xe
∂w < 0 (INFERIOR GOOD), ∂xe
∂pe > 0 (GIFFEN GOOD)
where I.E stronger than S.E. In matrix form :
11
Dp h(p, U ) = Dp x(p, w) + Dw x(p, e) x(p, e)
| {z } | {z } | {z } | {z }
(N ×N ) (N ×N ) (N ×1) (1×N )
12
4(p1 + p2 )w
u = v(p, m) =
p1 p2
∂x1 wp2 [2p1 + p2 ]
= wp2 (−1) · [p21 + p1 p2 ]−2 [2p1 + p2 ] = − 2
∂p1 [p1 + p1 p2 ]2
∂x2 wp1 [p1 + 2p2 ]
= wp1 (−1) · [p22 + p1 p2 ]−2 [p1 + 2p2 ] = − 2
∂p2 [p2 + p1 p2 ]2
∂x1 w wp1 p2 w
= w · [p21 + p1 p2 ]−1 + wp2 (−1)[p21 + p1 p2 ]−2 p1 = 2 − 2 =
∂p2 p1 + p1 p2 [p1 + p1 p2 ]2 (p1 + p2 )2
∂x1 p2
=
∂w p1 (p1 + p2 )
∂x2 p1
=
∂w p2 (p1 + p2 )
Properties:
S(p, w) is SYMMETRIC
S(p, w) Is NEGATIVE SEMIDEFINITE ⇒ function e(p, U ) is concave S(p, w) = ∇p h(p, U )
if S(p, w) Is NEGATIVE DEFINITE function e(p, U ) is strictly concave
determinant test: (−1)k ∆k > 0, det = 0
S · p = 0 (price vector)
" wp2 [2p2 +p1 ] w
# " p2
#
− [p2 +p1 p2 ]2 (p1 +p2 )2 p1 (p1 +p2 )
h
wp2 wp1
i
Dp x(p, w) = 2
w wp1 [p1 +2p2 ] + p1 · (p1 +p2 )p1 (p1 +p2 )p2
(p1 +p2 )2 − [p2 +p1 p2 ]2 p2 (p1 +p2 )
2
12
5 Slutsky substitution matrix (Based on MWG 3.G.14)
The matrix below records the demand substitution effects for a consumer endowed with rational prefer-
ences and consuming three goods at the prices p1 = 1, p2 = 2 and p3 = 6:
−10 ? ?
S= ? −4 ?
3 ? ?
Supply the missing numbers using the properties of the Slutsky matrix. Check whether it is negative
semidefinite.
−10 ? ?
S= ? −4 ? where p1 = 1, p2 = 2, p2 = 6, with S:symmetric, S:NSD, S · p = 0:
3 ? ?
−10 α 3
S= α −4 b
3 b c
−10 α 3 1 0
S·p= α −4 b · 2 = 0
3 b c 6 0
−10 + 2α + 18 = 0
2α = −8
α = −4
α − 8 + 6b = 0
−4 − 8 + 6b = 0
b=2
3 + 2b + 6c = 0
3 + 4 + 6c = 0
c = −7/6
−10 −4 3
S = −4 −4 2
3 2 − 67
(−1)k ∆k > 0
(-1)3 10 · + 28
28
6 − 4 − 4 · + 6 − 6 − 3[−8 − 12] = ...... = 0
13