Capital Theory and Investment Behavior : Dale W. Jorgenson
Capital Theory and Investment Behavior : Dale W. Jorgenson
Capital Theory and Investment Behavior : Dale W. Jorgenson
By DALE W. JORGENSON
Universityof California,Berkeley
Introduction
There is no greater gap between economic theory and econometric
practice than that which characterizes the literature on business in-
vestment in fixed capital. According to the neoclassical theory of capi-
tal, as expounded for example by Irving Fisher, a production plan for
the firm is chosen so as to maximize utility over time. Under certain
well-known conditions this leads to maximization of the net worth of
the enterprise as the criterion for optimal capital accumulation. Capi-
tal is accumulated to provide capital services, which are inputs to the
productive process. For convenience the relationship between inputs,
including the input of capital services, and output is summarized in a
production function. Although this theory has been known for at least
fifty years, it is currently undergoing a great revival in interest. The
theory appears to be gaining increasing currency and more widespread
understanding.
By contrast, the econometric literature on business investment con-
sists of ad hoc descriptive generalizations such as the "capacity prin-
ciple," the "profit principle," and the like. Given sufficientimprecision,
one can rationalize any generalization of this type by an appeal to
"theory." However, even with the aid of much ambiguity, it is im-
possible to reconcile the theory of the econometric literature on in-
vestment with the neoclassical theory of optimal capital accumula-
tion. The central feature of the neoclassical theory is the response of
the demand for capital to changes in relative factor prices or the ratio
of factor prices to the price of output. This feature is entirely absent
from the econometricliterature on investment.
It is difficult to reconcile the steady advance in the acceptance of
the neoclassical theory of capital with the steady march of the econo-
metric literature in a direction which appears to be diametrically op-
posite. It is true that there have been attempts to validate the theory.
Both profits and capacity theorists have tried a rate of interest here
or a price of investment goods there. By and large these efforts have
been unsuccessful; the naive positivist can only conclude, so much the
worse for the theory. I believe that a case can be made that previous
attempts to "test" the neoclassical theory of capital have fallen so far
* The researchfor this paper was completedwhile the author was Ford FoundationRe-
searchProfessorof Economicsat the Universityof Chicago.The researchwas supportedby
the NationalScienceFoundation.
247
248 AMERICAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION
w= e-rt[R(t) - D(t)]dt.
Second, we assume that output and employment on the one hand and
capital stock on the other are determined by a kind of iterative process.
In each period, production and employment are set at the levels given
by the first marginal productivity condition and the production func-
tion with capital stock fixed at its current level; demand for capital is
set at the level given by the second marginal productivity condition,
given output and employment. With stationary market conditions, such
a process is easily seen to converge to the desired maximum of net
worth. Let K* represent the desired amount of capital stock, if the
production function is Cobb-Douglas with elasticity of output with
respect to capital, y,
pQ
K*-PQ
E 00N
It = w(L)It
r=O
It -E Voit-2 =vo(L)I ,
r.0
0
S2E S E S1E
It = E = vi(L)It
,=O
It EVI2si-
a 2(L)It2
T=0
where vo(L), v1(L), and v2(L) are power series in the lag operator.
Up to this point we have discussed investment generated by an
increase in desired capital stock. Total investment, say It, is the sum of
investment for expansion and investment for replacement, say IR:
E It
It = It + It
We assume that replacement investment is proportional to capital
TOPICS IN ECONOMIC THEORY 251
stock. The justification for this assumption is that the appropriate
model for replacement is not the distribution of replacements for a
single investment over time but rather the infinite stream of replace-
ments generated by a single investment; in the language of probability
theory, replacement is a recurrent event. It is a fundamental result of
renewal theory that replacements for such an infinite stream approach
a constant proportion of capital stock for (almost) any distribution
of replacementsfor a single investment and for any initial age distribu-
tion of capital stock. This is true for both constant and growing capital
stocks. Representing the replacement proportion by 6, as before,
R
It = Wt;
combining this relationship with the correspondingrelationship for in-
vestment in new projects, we have:
Empirical Results
To test the theory of investment behavior summarizedin the preced-
ing section, the correspondingstochastic equations have been fitted to
quarterly data for U. S. manufacturing for the period 1948-60. The
data on investment are taken from the OBE-SEC Survey; first and
second anticipations of investment expenditureas reported in that Sur-
vey are taken as intermediate stages.' With two intermediate stages,
six possible relationships may be fitted. First, for actual investment
and both intermediate stages, the level of investment is determined by
past changes in desired capital stock. Second, investment is determined
by past values at each intermediate stage and the second anticipation
is determined by past values of the first anticipation. The first test of
the theory is the internal consistency of direct and derived estimates
of the coefficients of each of the underlying power series in the lag
operator.
The results of the fitting are given in Table 1. For each of the fitted
relationships coefficients of the polynomials s(L) and t(L) in the ex-
1 Data on capital stock were obtained by interpolating the capital stock series for total
manufacturing given in the U.S. national accounts between 1949 and 1959, using the formula
Kt+1 = It + (1 -)Kt.
Given an investment series, a unique value of a may be determined from the initial and
terminal values of capital stock. Investment data from the OBE-SEC Survey were used for
the interpolation. For desired capital stock, the quantity pQ was taken to be sales plus changes
in inventories, both from the Survey of Current Business. User cost depends on a number of
separate pieces of data. The quantity q is an investment deflator, a is, of course, a fixed pa-
rameter (taken to be equal to .025), r is the U.S. government long-term bond rate. The tax
functions vary with time; as an example, the tax rate u is the ratio between corporate income
tax payments and corporate profits before taxes as reported in the U.S. national accounts.
A detailed description of the data underlying this study will be reported elsewhere.
2 To derive the form of the functions used in the actual fitting, we take v2(L)v1(L) Vo(L)
as an example. First:
w0
T P0
TOPICS IN ECONOMIC THEORY 2 53
TABLE 1
REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS AND GoODNESS OF FIT STATISTICS, UNRESTRICTEDESTIMATES
Regres- t2 R2 s
'SO y yS2 1 A2/s2
pression for each power series as a rational function are given.2 For
example, the power series v2(L)v1(L)vo(L) is expressed as:
.00106L2
V2(L)vj(L)vo(L) = -2
1 - 1.52387L + .63100L2
It = It-1,
S2 S2
I t = It-II
Si S1
I t= It-i.
Simple as these models may be, they are quite stringent standards for
comparison for seasonally adjusted quarterly data, much more strin-
gent, for example, than the correspondingmodels for annual data. The
appropriatestatistics for comparisonare the standard errorsof estimate
and the VonNeumann ratios. Results of this comparison are given
separately for the periods 1948-60 and second quarter 1955 to 1960 in
Table 2.3 For the period as a whole, each of the regressionmodels has a
standard error well below that for the correspondingnaive model. For
the later subperiod the advantage of the regression models is even
greater. Turning to the VonNeumann ratios, there is practically no
evidence of autocorrelated errors for the fitted models and very clear
evidence of autocorrelation for the naive models. Of course, this test is
biased in favor of the fitted regressions. Even with this qualification,
the fitted regressions are clearly superior in every respect to the cor-
respondingnaive models.
As a standard of comparison for the second three regressions, we
take the forecasts actually used by the Department of Commerce in
presenting the results of the OBE-SEC Survey. These alternative
models take the form:
ItI _
It =It-2, 8
2
59 S
1t It-l.
t
if i't 2 Ig
t2I i't2= =
t I,=12It=I't'
NOTE:I =I't'lit-I Iu_i
=1(Ir1)
Ig=f(I')
t2:f(I8l)
) It=f(AKg)Model
It2=f(AKs
=f(AKt)
Total t t 1
R2
.93380 .83673 .95121
.93504 .92729 .83854
.96234 .86193 .87128
.84966 .88986
.94156
percentages
may
S
not .11983 .17391 .10597
.10969 .11955 .20282
.08604 .18058 .16087
.15950 .18848 .10830
add 19481-1960IV
to
GOODNESS
A2/S2
.99342
100%01.45737 .69933 1.70179 1.162941.31901.66900 2.53442
1.47693 2.00549
2.10778 OF
FIT
..04366
because R2
of .92833 .95931
.77138 .96477
.91854 .92169 .81161 .81929 .91921
.81297 .94757
.94298
STATISTICS:
rounding s
821036.93
.12031 .20707 .09045
.12359 .19435
.12996 .19947
.09368 .18410 .14372
.09368
.11378 FITTED,
1955II-1960IV
TABLE
error.
2
NAIVE,
A2/S2
1.25062 .46505 2.26525
.91146 1.65030 .94465
1.09855.83580 .52078 2.25394
1.84699
1.95800 AND
20 14 25 16 14 16 35 24 22 39 29 TP
29%o Error
FORECASTING
49 51 47 45 45 43 25 37 39 33 43
Over-
47%/o estimate
MODELS
1948I-1960IV
31 35 27 39 41 41 39 39 39 27 27
Under-
estimate
24%|
18 18 27 23 18 23 32 32 23 41 41 TP
Error
23%|
45 50 50 41 45 41 27 27 32 27 32
Over-
41% estimate
1955II-1960IV
136 32 23 36 36 36 41 41 45 32 27
36%o estimate
Under-
TOPICS IN ECONOMIC THEORY 25 7
"forecasts" to the turning points of the actual data is presented. In
general, the first set of fitted regressions is slightly inferior to the naive
models and the second set slightly superior to the forecasting models on
the basis of this criterion. A final comparison is between the fitted re-
gression of investment on changes in desired capital stock and the fore-
cast of investment from its second anticipation. The comparison favors
the fitted regression; however, the anticipations data used in a fitted
relationship between investment and second anticipation provide a
model which is superior to the simple forecasting model and to the
fitted regression of investment on changes in desired capital stock.
Structure of the Investment Process
In the preceding sections, only those aspects of the theory of invest-
ment behavior relevant to testing the theory were presented. In this
section certain further implications of the theory are developed. Specifi-
cally, we will characterize the long-term response of investment to
changes in the underlying market conditions and the tax structure and
the time pattern of response of investment to changes in demand for
capital.
First, using the facts that gross investment is determined by the rela-
tionship:
It = [1 - (1 - 8)L]w(L)K*,
= y(L)Kt,
where y(L) is a power series in the lag operator. XVedefine the r-period
response of investment to a change in market conditions or tax struc-
ture as the change in gross investment resulting from a change in the
underlying conditions which persists for r periods. More precisely, sup-
pose that desired capital remains at a fixed level for r periods to the
present; then,
Kt = Kt-, (v = 1, 2 ),
and
00
It = E yvKt-p)
co
+
=zKt E yvKt-',
P-7+ 1
258 AMERICAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION
RESPONSE ELASTICITY
Average End of Period Average End of Period
Market Conditions
Price of output .......... .35830 .35299 1.00000 1.00000
Price of capital goods .... -.35273 -.32106 -1.00000 -1.00000
Rate of interest ......... -14.23653 -15.17789 -.29143 -.37866
Tax Structure
Income tax rate ......... -.37487 -.33016 -.50959 -.42064
Proportion of replacement .18729 .20502 .39181 .48565
Proportion of interest.... .55656 .79840 .19428 .32659
TOPICS IN ECONOMIC THEORY 2 59
TABLE 4
TImE FORM OF LAGGEDRESPONSE
average lag between change in demand for capital stock and the cor-
responding net investment is, roughly, 6.5 quarters or about a year and
a half. Of course, this estimate is affected by the essentially arbitrary
decision to set the proportion of the change invested in the same period
and period immediately following the change at zero. The coefficients
of the power series z(L) are of interest for computation of short-period
responses of investment to changes in the demand for capital stock.
For example, the 2-period response of manufacturing gross investment
to a change in the rate of interest of 1 per cent is:
AK* .11277
Z7 Or = . .15178 = .68465 billions/quarter.
ar .02500