EC202 Notes 2 Consumer
EC202 Notes 2 Consumer
EC202 Notes 2 Consumer
Lectures 5 - 8
Quantities Functions
xi consumption of good i U utility function
x = (x1, x2 , …, xn ) consumption vector C cost (expenditure) function
X consumption set Hi compensated demand for good i
Ri resource stock of good i Di ordinary demand for good i
R = (R1,R2 ,…,Rn) resource endowment V indirect utility function
Case 1:
n
•
y/p1
Σ pi xi ≤ y
i=1
x1
x2
Case 2:
n n
Σ pi xi ≤ Σ pi Ri
i=1 i=1
R
x1
Conceptual problems
Can we follow an analogy with the firm?
• inputs – stuff you buy
• constraint – one of the specs of the budget constraint
• output?
Objective of the consumer
• utility?
• subjective wellbeing?
Happiness?
• can we measure happiness? use it to rank situations / states / societies?
Bond & Lang (JPE 2019) “The Sad Truth about Happiness Scales”
x′
x
x1
x
x1
Trying to extend WARP
x2 Take basic idea of revealed preference
Invoke revealed preference again
Invoke revealed preference yet again
Draw the “envelope”
x''
U U*
υ υ
0 x2 x2
0
The greed axiom
Pick any consumption bundle in X
(a) Greed implies that these bundles are preferred to x'
Gives a clear “North-East” direction of preference
(b) What can happen if consumers are not greedy
x2 (a) x2 (b)
Bliss!
x'
x1 x1
Conventionally shaped indifference curves
Slope well-defined everywhere
B
(-) Slope is the Marginal
Rate of Substitution
x1 U1(x) .
—— .
U2 (x) .
Other types of IC: Three cases
x2
A 1: Strictly quasiconcave, but not smooth
2: Smooth but not quasiconcave
Case 1 3: Smooth and quasiconcave, but not strictly
quasiconcave
C
B
x1
x2 x2
Case 2 Case 3
A
C
B
14
The primal problem
The consumer aims to maximise utility…
x2
Subject to budget constraint (green set)
Defines the primal problem
x*: Solution to primal problem
minimise
n
Σ pixi
x*
z* i=1
subject to U(x) ≥ υ
z2 q x2 υ The difference is
only in notation
So their solution
functions and
response functions
must be the same
z* x*
z1 x1
x*
x1
Comparing firm and consumer
Cost-minimisation by the firm…
…and expenditure-minimisation by the consumer
…are effectively identical problems
So the solution and response functions are the same:
Firm Consumer
m n
Problem: min Σ wizi + λ[q – φ (z)] min Σ pixi + λ[υ – U(x)]
z i=1 x i=1
So we can link up
their solution functions
and response functions
x*
Text: Section 4.5.2,
x*
pp 87-89
x1 x1
Utility maximisation
Maximise 𝑈𝑈 𝐱𝐱 + 𝜇𝜇 𝑦𝑦 − ∑𝑛𝑛𝑖𝑖=1 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖 Build Lagrangian from objective
function and budget constraint
Differentiate w.r.t. x1, …, xn , µ
and set equal to 0
Get 𝑛𝑛 + 1 First-Order Conditions
𝑛𝑛
𝑈𝑈1 𝐱𝐱 ∗ = 𝜇𝜇∗ 𝑝𝑝1
𝑈𝑈2 𝐱𝐱 ∗ = 𝜇𝜇∗ 𝑝𝑝2 𝑦𝑦 = � 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖∗ * denotes U-max values
⋯ 𝑖𝑖=1
𝑈𝑈𝑛𝑛 𝐱𝐱 ∗ = 𝜇𝜇∗ 𝑝𝑝𝑛𝑛
Implication of the FOCs
𝑈𝑈𝑖𝑖 𝐱𝐱 ∗ 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖
= “implicit” price = market price
𝑈𝑈𝑗𝑗 𝐱𝐱 ∗ 𝑝𝑝𝑗𝑗
MRS = price ratio
Properties of the solution (1)
• x**
But could the opposite happen?
•
x*
x1
An “inferior” good
Same original budget, different preferences
x2 Again suppose income rises
Equilibrium shifts from x** to x**
x1
Effect of a change in price
Again take the original equilibrium
x2
Allow price of good 1 to fall
Big blue arrow: the effect of the price fall
Small blue arrows: “journey” from x* to x**
broken into two parts
° x**
•
•
x*
x1
A fundamental decomposition
Take the two ways of writing demand:
𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖∗ = 𝐻𝐻𝑖𝑖 p, 𝜐𝜐 = 𝐷𝐷 𝑖𝑖 p, 𝑦𝑦 Two representations of same thing
𝐻𝐻 𝑖𝑖 p, 𝜐𝜐 = 𝐷𝐷 𝑖𝑖 p, 𝐶𝐶 p, 𝜐𝜐 Implicit relation in prices and utility
Substitution effect: “When the Income effect: “I'm better off if the
price of jelly falls and I’m kept on price of jelly falls; so I buy more
the same utility level, I prefer to normal goods, such as ice cream”
switch from ice cream for dessert” The size of the effect depends on
how much jelly I am buying
The Slutsky equation: own-price
Set j = i to get the effect of the price of Important special case
ice-cream on the demand for ice-cream
x*1 x**
1
x1
Consumer equilibrium and the offer curve
x2 Budget constraint, endogenous y
Consumer's equilibrium at x*
Price rises of good 1 yield x**,x***
Connect points on the path
R
x1
Household supply
Flip horizontally , to make
supply clearer
Rescale the vertical axis to
measure price of good 1
Plot p1 against x1
x2 p1
R
x1
Application: labour supply
x2
Endowment: total time & non-labour
income
Slope of budget constraint is wage rate
Consumer's equilibrium
∆C
∆V
x*
x*
x1 x1
37
Marginal changes
W get the value of marginal changes just by re-using results on solutions
The solution function for the primal: 𝑉𝑉 𝐩𝐩, 𝑦𝑦 = 𝑈𝑈 𝐱𝐱 ∗ +𝜇𝜇∗ 𝑦𝑦 − � 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖∗
𝑖𝑖
Differentiate with respect to y and rearrange:
𝑉𝑉𝑦𝑦 𝐩𝐩, 𝑦𝑦 = ∑𝑖𝑖 𝑈𝑈𝑖𝑖 𝐱𝐱 ∗ 𝐷𝐷𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖 𝐩𝐩, 𝑦𝑦 + 𝜇𝜇∗ − ∑𝑖𝑖 𝜇𝜇∗ 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝐷𝐷𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖 𝐩𝐩, 𝑦𝑦
𝑉𝑉𝑦𝑦 𝐩𝐩, 𝑦𝑦 = 𝜇𝜇∗
The solution function for the dual: 𝐶𝐶 𝐩𝐩, 𝜐𝜐 = ∑𝑖𝑖 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖∗ +𝜆𝜆∗ 𝜐𝜐 − 𝑈𝑈 𝐱𝐱 ∗
Differentiate with respect to υ and rearrange:
𝐶𝐶𝜐𝜐 𝐩𝐩, 𝜐𝜐 = ∑𝑖𝑖 𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖 𝐻𝐻𝜐𝜐𝑖𝑖 𝐩𝐩, 𝜐𝜐 + 𝜆𝜆∗ − ∑𝑖𝑖 𝜆𝜆∗ 𝑈𝑈𝑖𝑖 𝐱𝐱 ∗ 𝐻𝐻𝜐𝜐𝑖𝑖 𝐩𝐩, 𝜐𝜐
𝐶𝐶𝜐𝜐 𝐩𝐩, 𝜐𝜐 = 𝜆𝜆∗
1
We also find 𝜆𝜆∗ =
𝜇𝜇 ∗
But what about non-marginal changes?
How to value a price change
Price of good 1 changes
• p: original price vector
• p': vector after price change
This causes utility to change
• υ = V(p, y) original utility level at prices p
x**
•
•
x*
x1
How to value a price change (again)
Price of good 1 changes
• p: original price vector
• p': vector after price change
This causes utility to change
original utility level at prices p
• υ = V(p, y)
• υ' = V(p', y) new utility level at prices p'
x**
•
•
x*
x1
Welfare changes as cost changes
Compensating Variation as –∆(cost): (–) change in cost of hitting utility
level υ. If positive we have a
CV(p→p') = C(p, υ) – C(p', υ) welfare increase
= – EV(p→p')
Application
An index to measure changes in cost of living
What's the change in cost of
𝐶𝐶 𝐩𝐩′ ,𝜐𝜐
If we use a CV-based index: 𝐼𝐼CV = hitting the base utility level υ?
𝐶𝐶 𝐩𝐩,𝜐𝜐
1. but why base utility level rather than final?
2. what if utility fn is not homothetic?
.
Welfare change and consumer demand
Measure impact on welfare of p→p' by cost-diff:
𝐶𝐶 𝐩𝐩, 𝜐𝜐 ∗ − 𝐶𝐶 𝐩𝐩′, 𝜐𝜐 ∗ where 𝜐𝜐 ∗ is reference utility level ( 𝜐𝜐 or 𝜐𝜐 ′ )
Let price of good 1 change from 𝑝𝑝1 to 𝑝𝑝1′ , other prices unchanged
𝑝𝑝1 𝜕𝜕𝐶𝐶 𝐩𝐩,𝜐𝜐∗
Then the cost diff is: ∫𝑝𝑝′ 𝜕𝜕𝑝𝑝 d𝑝𝑝1
1 1
𝑝𝑝1
Further rewrite as: ∫𝑝𝑝′ 𝐻𝐻1 𝐩𝐩, 𝜐𝜐 ∗ d𝑝𝑝1
1
H1(p, υ)
Variation
x*1
x1
Compensated demand and EV
H1(p, υ′)
The EV provides another exact
welfare measure
Based on reference point υ′
Equivalent
price
fall
Variation
x**
1
x1
Ordinary demand and CS
Initial equilibrium at x1*
p1 ordinary (Marshallian) price fall: (welfare increase)
demand curve
Yellow area: an alternative
method of valuing the price fall?
D1(p, y)
CS provides an approximate
welfare measure
Consumer's
price
fall
surplus
x*1 x**
1
x1
The benefits of a price fall: three stories
p1
D1(p, y)
x1* x1**
x1