Coca Cola in China
Coca Cola in China
Coca Cola in China
39-58
ABSTRACT
In the presence of high transaction costs due to market imperfections, it is normally less
new markets through their internal corporate structures rather than by relying on the
markets. Based on a case study of Coca-Cola’s entry into the Chinese market, this paper
tests the applicability of internalization theory to explaining the entry mode choices of
MNCs in developing countries. Internalization theory reveals the economic rationale that
was behind the changes in Coca-Cola’s modes of entry as it moved from franchising to
joint ventures (JVs) with selected local partners, and more recently to the combination of
INTRODUCTION
When a multinational corporation (MNC) enters into new markets, it is rather costly for it
to conduct business activities in imperfect markets due to high transaction costs. These
costs include those accruing from the problems of opportunism, small numbers of market
argued that the transaction costs of writing, executing, and enforcing contracts via the
market are greater than the costs of internalizing the market. The situation is further
2
such, it appears that an MNC will prefer to establish wholly owned subsidiaries (WOSs)
to deal with market imperfections. Apart from the choice of WOSs, there are also other
commonly used modes, such as joint ventures (JVs). Based on a case study of Coca-Cola
in China, this paper tests the applicability of the internalization theory to explain the entry
Coca-Cola in China has been chosen as a case study for a number of reasons.
First, Coca-Cola is the world’s largest cola producer and one of the biggest MNCs.
Second, Coca-Cola has a relatively long history of investment in China since 1979, when
economic reform was implemented under the de facto leadership of Deng Xiaoping.1
Third, faced with keen competition from its close competitor, Pepsi-Cola, and an
unfamiliar and highly versatile local market environment, Coca-Cola’s ability, experience
and success in capturing a large market share in China seem to constitute an interesting
case, upon which implications may be drawn for the understanding of MNCs’ market
entry into developing countries via establishing equity joint ventures (EJVs). Fourth,
there are only two previous studies on the operation of Coca-Cola in China: Nolan (1995)
and PU-TU-USC (2000). Based on a case study of the Coca-Cola bottling plant in
Tianjin, Nolan (1995) conducted the first in-depth analysis of the micro-economic impact
of a single Coca-Cola plant in China. He found that the Coca-Cola business system in
general has positive impacts on the development of labour, capital and product markets in
China. The findings of Nolan (1995) are in-line with the conclusion of the large-scale
they estimate that the economic multiplier effects of Coca-Cola’s capital investment and
business linkages in the Coca-Cola business system] in China generated a total of about
414,000 jobs, 21.7 billion yuan of output and 1.2 billion yuan of tax payment in 1998
Despite the valuable information provided by the above meticulous studies, there
is no specific literature providing the theoretical foundation for the entry mode choice of
Coca-Cola in China. To fill this gap, this paper tests the applicability of the
internalization theory in explaining the entry mode choice of Coca-Cola in China since
1979. The contributions of our paper not only produce implications for the applicability
of the internalization theory, but also provide an insight into the market expansion
strategy of a global soft drink manufacturer in China. It must be emphasized that other
relevant impacts of the Coca-Cola businesses, such as the economic impacts of the Coca-
Cola business system in China, are not the focus and thus will not be discussed in this
paper.
METHODOLOGY
modes of entry into the Chinese market. The framework helps to explain why JVs are the
complemented by empirical research that was conducted in China. The principal author
made two research trips to China between November 1999 and March 2000. In addition
to general data collection, face-to-face interviews were carried out with high-level
Operations, and the Director of Marketing of Coca-Cola’s head office in Beijing were
interviewed in November 1999, and the Deputy General Manager of Coca-Cola’s bottling
plant in Tianjin was interviewed in March 2000.2 Prior to the field visits, questions were
sent to interviewees at Coca-Cola’s head office in Beijing. For further details of the
questions that were posed and other related information, see Appendix A.
Apart from discussing Coca-Cola’s expansion in China since 1979, the interviews
focused on the qualitative aspects of the company’s business operations, in particular its
relationship with local partners. Only rarely was this type of information obtainable from
all of the interviews were conducted in a semi-structured and informal manner. Chinese
government officials were not present. Whilst each interview had a specific focus, open-
ended questions were posed, and the interviewees were encouraged to guide the
close personal contact with Coca-Cola’s regional office in Hong Kong, which was a
reliable source of general and up-to-date information about the company’s presence,
In the following sections we discuss the key arguments that concern the entry
mode choices of MNCs, and examine the economic rationale and conditions that allow
JVs to be more efficient than WOSs. The discussion then extends to a brief review of the
development of foreign direct investment (FDI) in China since the late 1970s, which is a
process that is relevant to Coca-Cola’s entry into the Chinese market. This is followed by
1979. Finally, implications are drawn about Coca-Cola’s experiences with reference to
Transaction costs are increasingly important for MNCs in the selection of host countries
for FDI (Sara and Newhouse, 1995). According to Buckley and Casson (1976, 1985) and
Hennart (1982, 1991), internalization theory proposes that in the event of high transaction
costs which are caused by market imperfections, it is normally less expensive for an
MNC to use its internal corporate structure to conduct business transactions rather than
by relying on the market (McManus, 1972; Dunning, 1981). Imperfections may be the
result of uncertainty in the market, the small number of agents that are available,
MNC would tend to establish a WOS, either in the form of greenfield investment or the
acquisition of another firm in the host country. However, there are other modes that
MNCs can adopt to deal with market imperfections, viz. joint ventures.4 It is crucial to
identify the economic rationale behind the theory that the establishment of JVs may
generate more efficiency gains than the establishment of WOSs for MNCs in the host
According to Teece (1983), the basic argument for the attractiveness of JVs over
WOSs is the potential for reaping revenue-enhancing and cost-reducing benefits. Lacking
nation-specific knowledge of the host country, such as the nature of the local market
(including its culture, business practices, contacts, etc.) and the local government, it could
6
and enforcing complex contracts with market intermediaries (Beamish, 1988; Meyer,
1998: 87-113). However, the usual attractiveness of an MNC is its possession of a rent-
yielding asset. When an MNC’s rent-yielding asset is combined with the assets of its
local partners, the synergistic effect may produce more rents to offset the costs of
forming JVs. The revenue-enhancing and cost-reducing potential in JVs may outweigh
mind: why and under what conditions are JVs a better solution than WOSs to the
rationality? Some of the literature has touched upon this question, e.g. Buckley and
Opportunism: Williamson (1975) argues that the problems of opportunism while not
uncommon, are not necessarily inevitable. Beamish (1988: 98) suggests that JVs can
mitigate the problem of opportunism via mutual trust and forbearance. Based on mutual
trust, both an MNC and its local partners would be more willing to tolerate their
relationship in order to ensure the long-term viability of their JV. Relying on the
managerial talent of the JV that may accrue from mutual trust may be a more efficient
way of dealing with opportunism than relying on explicit legal efforts to complete all
contingencies. Moreover, Casson (1990) explains that a high degree of trust between
agents could promote economic performance. Berg and Friedman (1980) suggest that
when there are reasonable mechanisms for profit division, joint decision-making and
monitoring, both the MNC and its local partners would have less incentive to behave
7
manner and is accepted by all parties of the JV, they may be willing to aim for the same
be mitigated.
Small numbers of market agents: Small numbers of market agents can be an acute
problem when an MNC wishes to seek a new venture partner in the host country. Since
the initial local partner has cost advantage over other local market agents, it is thus not
always optimal for the MNC to switch its partners. If the above-mentioned mechanisms
for profit division, joint decision-making and monitoring are well-developed enough to
will be less incentive for both parties of the JV to switch partners (Contractor, 1985).
requirements for FDI (Mutinelli and Piscitello, 1998: 491-506). This objective can be
achieved by pooling the resources of the MNC and its local partners (Caves, 1982). The
technology, management and capital markets. The competitive advantages of its local
partners are mainly their location-specific knowledge about the local market, such as its
culture, business practices, contacts and the local government. The synergistic effects of
combining the resources of all parties of the JV could possibly result in a lower long-term
Bounded rationality: In his study of human behaviour, Simon (1957) used the term
‘bounded rationality’ to indicate that human beings have limited knowledge. In the
8
process of making a decision, the information and knowledge that are acquired by
economic agents are limited. This in itself is one source of market imperfections. Despite
uncertainty in the market environment (Hayek, 1945). When entering foreign markets, it
is essential for MNCs to devise economic structures that lessen the costs of bounded
rationality and minimize the losses from other sources of market imperfections (Sara and
Newhouse, 1995). Beamish (1988) argues that the problem of bounded rationality also
exists in JVs and WOSs. In fact, there is no substantial evidence to support the argument
that this problem can be less severe in JVs than in WOSs. As an alternative mode of
foreign market entry, JVs incur lower costs that are associated with the problems of
opportunism, small numbers of agents and uncertainty under the conditions that are
specified above.
Apart from discussing entry mode choices with reference to the transaction cost
paradigm, some studies (e.g. Erramilli, 1996) suggest that the national culture of MNCs
explains, to a degree, the variation in ownership levels of their FDI. However, the effect
of the national culture on the level of equity ownership is not the focus of this paper.
China has been considerably successful in attracting FDI since the implementation of
economic reform in 1979. According to the Ministry of Foreign Trade and Economic Co-
operation (MOFTEC), the total utilized value of FDI reached US$385 billion till October
2001 (Table 1). EJV has been the most popular mode for MNCs to enter the Chinese
market during this period. The total number of EJVs reached 213,780 in October 2001,
9
accounting for 56 per cent of the total number of FDI firms in China. Together with other
types of JVs [e.g. contractual joint ventures and joint R&D ventures], JVs owned and/or
operated by Chinese and foreign firms accounted for 69 per cent of all firms with FDI. In
comparison, there were 119,589 WOSs of foreign firms, which accounted for 31 per cent
In terms of the share in the total utilized value of FDI, EJVs accounted for 45 per
cent, amounting to US$172 billion, during the period 1979-October 2001 (Table 1). In
comparison, WOSs accounted for 34 per cent of total utilized value of FDI at the same
time. This suggests that the mode of EJVs was popular in China among foreign direct
investors. During the two decades of economic reform, the Chinese market remained a
relatively new territory for foreign firms. In other words, China was a typical ‘imperfect
market’ for foreign MNCs – the result of, among others, uncertainty, small numbers of
agents, opportunism, bounded rationality and a lack of knowledge about the local market.
To reduce the risks associated with the ‘imperfect market’, JVs in many cases could be a
growth opportunities that are available. That Coca-Cola considered different market entry
models is indicative of the company’s efforts to produce a strategy that was capable of
coping with the potential problems of a new and ‘imperfect’ market. The choice of entry
Given China’s enormous population and relatively high growth rate of real GDP (about
nine per cent on average since 1979), the country has long been viewed as an important
market with great potential for many of the world’s giant MNCs, including the
accessibility, Coca-Cola utilized different modes of market entry over three different
stages of operation after 1979. A brief outline of these three stages is as follows.5
• During the first stage (1979-84), Coca-Cola sold concentrate to its franchised
Chinese-owned bottlers. Its local market agents were fully responsible for production
and distribution. Market agents were opportunistic in running the bottling business
because they wanted to focus on their bottom lines. This limited the expansion of
• During the second stage (1985-92), Coca-Cola bought equity shares in the bottling
• During the third stage (1993-present), Coca-Cola teamed up with two foreign bottlers,
the Kerry group and the Swire group, under a franchise agreement. Apart from
transactions and the labour section of its bottling business by localizing its
management team and upstream suppliers. The synergistic effect appeared to be high,
In 1992, there were about ten Coca-Cola bottling plants in the form of JVs, in
which Coca-Cola only had minority shares. In eight years, eighteen new JVs were
bottling plants (Table 2). Among these only three plants located in Hainan, Tianjin and
Shanghai are under the direct control of Coca-Cola. The Kerry Group and the Swire
Group share the management of the other 25 plants. After investments of more than
US$1 billion by the Coca-Cola system (including investments by the anchor and key
bottlers) during the last two decades, Coca-Cola products are now available to about 80
per cent of the Chinese population via a comprehensive network of production and
wholesale) all over the country (PU-TU-USC, 2000: 24). In 2000, the share of Coca-Cola
brands (including Sprite and Fanta) in China’s carbonated soft drinks market was 40 per
cent, while that of Pepsi-Cola was only 15 per cent (Table 3) (Field survey, 1999 and
2000; hereinafter see Appendix A for further details about the field survey).6
Franchise was Coca-Cola’s entry mode during this period. The bottling plants were
launched its open door policy in 1979, Coca-Cola began a lengthy process of negotiation
with the Chinese Government on accessing the Chinese market. The outcome of the
negotiation was the permission for the sale of imported Coca-Cola soft drinks to
foreigners only in China’s three ‘economic cities’, viz. Beijing, Shanghai, and
Guangzhou. Between 1980 and1984, Coca-Cola built three bottling plants in Beijing
(1981), Guangzhou (1983) and Xiamen (1984) and then transferred all its ownership
government policy on the beverage sector. Foreign firms, such as Coca-Cola, were not
12
allowed to own bottling plants in China.7 In return, the Chinese-owned bottling plants
Coca-Cola, the bottling plants added syrup, water, sugar and gas (CO2) into the
concentrate and the carbonated soft drinks were then ready for sale. Under this type of
arrangement, Coca-Cola worked like a wholesaler, while the bottling plants were market
agents, performing the functions of production and distribution. Furthermore, the only
return for Coca-Cola’s investment in China during the first stage was the sale of
concentrate to the bottling plants. The profit from this type of business activity was
As all bottling plants were wholly owned by local Chinese enterprises, Coca-Cola
had neither management rights in the operation of the plants, nor control over the volume
penetration into the vast Chinese market. Being a de facto wholesaler of concentrate and
facing uncertainty on the long-term accessibility in the Chinese market, Coca-Cola lacked
market information or the permission by the Chinese government to expand its business
in China. Besides, Coca-Cola faced problems of opportunism. Its market agents were
invariably passive and merely focused on their own bottom lines (Field survey, 1999 and
2000; Business China, 19 February 1996: 1-2). They did not have the same goal as Coca-
Cola to pursue a long-term marketing strategy for the soft drink business in China. This
can largely be explained by the typical problem of a socialist regime in which the
ownership rights of enterprises were not clearly defined. Claims on the residuals of
enterprises were vague. On the operation side of the bottling business, Coca-Cola did not
have any say on the output level. Although the local partners held the management and
13
control rights, their production behaviour was highly influenced by the operational policy
of ‘promoting’ sales which was in turn subjected to the constraints of production targets
(yichan dingxiao) (Field survey, 2000).8 Under this policy, production units produced a
level of output that was based on readily available raw materials, energy supply and
production ability. Related distributors were expected to handle and market the output.
The distributors provided the market information to the production units, but the
producers decided the output level according to their readily available resources. In fact,
the producers did not necessarily adjust their production outputs according to the market
information. Consequently, there was often a disparity between output and market
demand.9
Apart from the opportunistic behaviour of its market agents in China, Coca-Cola
transport system and national wholesale networks. The transport system was at best
primitive and antiquated, and at that time no wholesale network existed. In cities, large
fleets of peddle-wheeled tricycles were still used to distribute soft drinks from one
location to another. The distribution network was highly cost-ineffective and time-
consuming (Field survey, 1999; Clifford, 1993). Thus, during the first stage of its entry
into the market, Coca-Cola targeted bottling and concentrate plants in China’s coastal
cities, where a greater degree of economic liberalization had enhanced the consumption
there were only three bottling plants in China (Table 2), and by 1985 the company’s
14
market share was less than two per cent (Advertising Age, 9 June 1986: 56). Such
In order to penetrate the Chinese market, Coca-Cola prepared to internalize its market
transactions by acquiring the management rights to the bottling plants through the
establishment of JVs.10 With its liberalization policy to attract FDI in the mid-1980s,
China permitted Coca-Cola’s bottling partner in Macau and a local enterprise in Zhuhai
to form the first JV bottling plant in 1985. In order to handle the uncertainty on market
its local partners, Coca-Cola started to actively involve in the operation of the bottling
plants by entering into JV arrangements with local partners. This marked the beginning of
form of WOS. To keep concentrate plants in the form of WOSs was, and still is, Coca-
Cola’s strategy to safeguard the formula of producing its concentrate.11 In return for the
permission to run the concentrate plant on sole-proprietorship, Coca-Cola let its Chinese
partners hold the ownership of the bottling plant, which was jointly built near the
concentrate plant in Shanghai. Coca-Cola entered a 50-50 JV with the former Ministry of
Light Industry (now called the State Light Industry Bureau, reporting to the State
Economic and Trade Commission) and the Shanghai Investment and Trust Company to
establish the Shanghai Shenmei Beverage Co. Ltd. in 1986 (Field survey, 2000). The
15
business relationship between Coca-Cola’s concentrate plants in Shanghai and its local
Meantime, the Chinese Government actually still maintained tight control over
the development of soft drink industry in China with an aim to nurture local Chinese
brands. This was mostly due to the shortage of fund for local soft drink makers to catch
up with foreign soft drink makers, notably as Coca-Cola and Pepsi-Cola (South China
Morning Post (SCMP), 8 June 1996: 6). Coca-Cola might have had limited knowledge
about the paternalistic attitude of the Chinese Government to protect its local brands. This
was a problem of bounded rationality faced by foreign firms (Field survey, 2000).
However, with its liberalization policy to attract FDI and partly due to the opening up of
the beverage market in China since the mid-1980s, foreign soft drink makers such as
Coca-Cola were allowed to jointly own bottling plants with local partners but at minority
shares (Table 4). The number of Coca-Cola’s bottling plants had increased rapidly from
four in 1985 to ten in 1992 (Table 2). A decade after re-entering the Chinese market,
15). Coca-Cola’s strategy was to acquire management rights of its JVs regardless of the
amount of its shares in the plants. The main objective was to exert control over the
bottling operations, otherwise, the opportunistic behaviour of the market agents would
seriously hamper the growth of Coca-Cola business in China. For example, Coca-Cola
only acquired 25 per cent of shares in its JV bottling plant in Hainan, yet its local partners
rights to their Western partners, the local partners could earn decent profits by off-loading
16
part of their shares in bottling plants. In addition, the local partners hoped to learn the
had the authority to appoint general managers to consolidate the production and
During the second stage, when the entry mode was JVs, Coca-Cola faced several
constraints to further expand its business in China. Some of them were basically the same
as those in the first stage. The behaviour of its local partners was opportunistic, in that
they still wanted to focus on their own bottom lines rather than the maximization of
Coca-Cola’s market share in China. More importantly, the local partners did not have a
strong grasp of the concept of marketing and market share. The operational policy of
yichan dingxiao highly constrained the growth potential of the JVs in the carbonated soft
drinks market. Another serious difficulty faced by Coca-Cola was its limited knowledge
(i.e. bounded rationality) to fully appreciate the financial difficulties that were faced by
its local partners for a long-term expansion strategy of their JV businesses. This was
various ministries. They were too poor to finance the JV expansion (Field survey, 1999
and 2000).12 Furthermore, any major decisions about additional investment from the JV
transaction costs that were involved in cutting through local government red tape were
very high. Besides, Coca-Cola was constrained by the rigidities in the labour market and
the lack of experienced managerial staff with whom to oversee new plants. As a result,
the company’s market share increased only slightly during the second stage of its entry.
17
Between 1992 and 1993, when local soft drink producers controlled up to 70 per cent of
the market, Coca-Cola’s market share stagnated at 12 per cent (Table 3).
To reduce the impact of the above problems, Coca-Cola internalized the market
transactions through its strategy of long-term investments combined with its control of
production and the domestic distribution channel. In addition, the company also
internalized the procurement transactions and labour market of its bottling business by
localising its management team and upstream suppliers. During the 1980s, most of the
inputs, such as glass bottles, aluminium cans, polyethylene terephthalate bottles, were
imported because the locally produced ones failed to meet the standard established by
Coca-Cola. With technical assistance from Coca-Cola, a number of Chinese suppliers are
able to produce the quality products demanded by Coca-Cola. Since the mid-1990s, more
than 98 per cent of the supplies were sourced in the local Chinese market (AWSJ, 5
For the market expansion in China, Coca-Cola’s strategy was to ensure that the
way to reduce risk and to overcome the problem of shortage of human resources was to
foreign partners.13 As such, Coca-Cola teamed up with two foreign bottlers, namely
Malaysia’s Kerry Group and Hong Kong’s Swire Group. The Swire Group mainly
produces and distributes Coca-Cola products in southern and central China, while the
Kerry Group focuses on northern and interior China. These foreign partners were able to
bring in capital and human resources. The Coca-Cola bottling business was undertaken in
18
the form of a JV between Coca-Cola and its local partners.14 The involvement of the
Kerry Group and the Swire Group was in the form of a franchise agreement with Coca-
Cola. This arrangement has shaped the basic features of the third stage of Coca-Cola’s
arrangements with foreign partners (i.e., the Kerry and Swire Groups) and its JVs with
Chinese partners constitute the main elements of the company’s internalization strategy.
which the franchiser customarily grants the franchisee the right, or privilege, to operate
the business in a prescribed manner over a period limited by the term of the franchise
agreement. A large element of the franchise represents the market alternative to the
internalized transfer of managerial and marketing skills (Buckley and Casson, 1985: 45-
49). In the case of Coca-Cola in China, the transfer includes manufacturing technology
(Field survey, 2000). Mendelsohn and Bynoe (1995: 7) noted that “the investment in and
ownership by the franchisee of the franchised business is a key feature (of franchising)
since the franchisee is committed by his investment and expected, as owner, to be better
motivated than would be a manager. Although there are references to the business being
owned by the franchisee, there are two factors that make that ownership different from
that enjoyed by a non-franchised businessman. The franchisee must operate under the
franchiser’s name, using his system and within the terms of the franchise agreement.”
They added that the ability of a franchised business to achieve growth is by linking the
franchiser with his franchisees, who possess the capital and manpower to operate the
business. This type of agreement fundamentally addresses the shortages of capital and
human resources faced by Coca-Cola in its strategy of expanding market share in China.
19
Cola. Coca-Cola possesses rent-yielding assets, viz. the technology of producing Coca-
Cola and marketing expertise. Its local partners have the advantages of strong distribution
arms and knowledge of local beverage markets (the nation-specific knowledge mentioned
by Beamish (1988: 106)). The Kerry and Swire Groups are rich in cash, share the goal of
long-term profit and market share maximization of Coca-Cola, and have strong political
connections to the Chinese Government. The synergistic effect of combining the assets of
beverage market share in China. For instance, Coca-Cola was able to capture a market
share of 40 per cent in 2000, almost three times that of Peps-Cola, its close international
outweighed the advantages of WOSs. One way to guarantee these benefits was to make
sure that the Kerry and Swire Groups obtained management rights in overseeing the
bottling plants and assuming direct control of distribution via the acquisition of majority
shares in the JV bottling business in China. The Kerry Group has in fact obtained about
50-60 per cent equity shares of all its bottling plants, while the Swire Group was able to
keep a controlling block of shares at 51 per cent in the bottling plants under its
It has been argued that ownership is often used to control residual rights in
international operations. An MNC’s ownership share in its foreign operation reflects the
importance of the assets used in its operation and more importantly the bargaining power
relative to its local partners (Nakamura and Xie, 1998: 571-99). Coca-Cola started to
20
negotiate with the Chinese Government in the early 1990s to buy-out the majority shares
of all existing and newly planned bottling plants. The negotiation process was lengthy
and difficult. The local partners were demanding high prices for the buy-outs, based on
unreasonably high levels of projected future earnings.16 How to resolve the problem often
relates to the art of ‘give and take’. The prime wish of the Chinese Government was for
to its local partners to develop local branded beverages (SCMP, 27 January 1994: 14).
This arrangement could be worked out in the form of a JV. For example, through the set-
up of a new 50-50 JV in Tianjin with China’s Ministry of Light Industries, Tianjin Jinmei
Beverage Co. Ltd., Coca-Cola has been helping its local partners in Tianjin to develop
some local branded drinks, e.g. Xingmu (“Smart”) soft drinks, TianYuDi (“Heaven and
Earth”) fruit juice drinks, tea and bottled mineral water (Wang, 1998).
A review of Coca-Cola’s business development in China during the first two stages of its
market entry (1979-1992) highlights four major challenges to the company’s long-term
development strategy:
• Initially, the Chinese market was highly fragmented, and the wholesale and
distributional systems were outdated. This was further complicated because Coca-
Cola was the de facto wholesaler of concentrate, and did not have access to the
operation of the bottling plants. To add to this problem, the company’s local market
agents were fully responsible for production and distribution during the initial stages
of market entry.
21
• Coca-Cola’s local partners played a passive role in the company’s market entry.
Market agents acted out of self-interest and were opportunistic in running the bottling
business. They had neither a strong incentive to acquire market share nor a long-term
development strategy.
• The Chinese government exerted tight control over the development of the soft drink
industry and was careful to nurture domestic brands. Coca-Cola was not permitted to
enter into a JV bottling business with its local partners until 1985, and even then it
• The local partners were too poor to finance further business expansion. As they were
decisions that were made by the JV partners had to gain official approval. These
experiences explain why Coca-Cola’s market share increased but slightly before the
early 1990s.
The first two challenges can be regarded as the high transaction costs that were
bounded rationality. Coca-Cola might have had limited knowledge about the
makers. It was certainly difficult for Coca-Cola to fully appreciate the financial
difficulties that were faced by some of its local partners in expanding business operations.
These challenges were further intensified by opportunism and uncertainty in the market
through a strategy of long-term investment and, with the approval of the Ministry of
Light Industry, was able to co-ordinate this with an increased control of production and
essential. This meant that the acquisition of majority stakes in the bottling plants is
almost a prerequisite for gaining the control over management. However, gaining this
control was costly. To reduce the high risk of direct investment, Coca-Cola teamed up
with two foreign bottlers under a franchise agreement. The synergistic effect of pooling
the resources of Coca-Cola, its local partners and its foreign bottlers was high, and it
CONCLUSIONS
This paper applies the internalization theory to explain the entry mode choice of Coca-
Cola in China since 1979. The findings not only have implications for the applicability of
the internalization theory, but also provide an insight into the market expansion strategy
mode of market entry from franchises to JVs, and then to the current combination of
franchises and JVs, we have employed internalization theory to address the issue of how
and to what extent shifts in various investment modes can reduce the effects of market
imperfections. Furthermore, the empirical data that we have presented suggest that
e.g. Nolan (1995) and PU-TU-USC (2000), and argues that internalization theory is a
useful conceptual framework for the analysis of its modes of investment in China.
However, the application of any theoretical approach to firm-level study may be affected
culture at the macro-level is also influential. Hence, any generalizations that are drawn
from the present study of Coca-Cola’s experiences in China must be treated with care.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The authors would like to express their gratitude to the editors and anonymous reviewers
for their helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. They also thank those who
facilitated the field surveys that were conducted by the principal author in 1999 and 2000.
This paper could not have been completed without the financial support of the Hong
Kong Polytechnic University (Research Grant A/C no. HZJ61).
NOTES
1. Coca-Cola soft drinks first appeared on the Chinese market in 1923. The first bottling plant
was built in Shanghai in 1927. Soon afterwards, Coca-Cola was bottled in other cities,
including Tianjin in 1927 and Qingdao in 1930. The company left China after the socialist
regime came to power in 1949 (Wang, 1998: 36).
2. Each of the two interviews in Beijing lasted for approximately one and a half hours. The
interview in Tianjin lasted for almost two hours, and was followed by a working lunch for
another one and a half hours.
3. Similar research methods have been used by many academics. Among others, see Yeung
(2001: 8-12). Besides, in the context of the global economy, Nolan (2001) presents detailed
case studies of the interaction between China’s big enterprises system and the global
business revolution.
4. There are two major types of JVs, viz. equity joint ventures (EJVs) and contractual joint
ventures (CJVs). The former is characterized by a long-term relationship among the partners
that manage the JV. The latter, in contrast, has the basic feature that the partnership will
dissolve after a specified period (Yeung, 2001: 3-6).
5. The three different stages were suggested by the interviewees (Field survey, 1999, see
Sections [I] and [II] in Appendix A for further details).
24
6. The interviewees were reluctant to disclose Coca-Cola’s sales value in China, which was
regarded as a commercial secret.
7. The Chinese Government exerted tight control over the development of the soft drink
industry to nurture domestic brands (Field survey, 2000; Asian Wall Street Journal (AWSJ),
15 February 1994: 1).
8. Literally, ‘yichan dingxiao’ means that the output level (rather than the market demand)
determines sales and distribution (Yu, 1991: 380). In a report on the branding revolution in
China, Schlevogt (2000) explains the evolving behaviour of Chinese managers in production
and marketing, as well as their attitudes towards branding, from the central planning era to
the current competitive period. He shows that during the central planning era, production
depended on resource availability but not on market demand.
9. Quite often, producers were not concerned about product quality because they were not
responsible for marketing. Consequently, products went unsold and had to be stockpiled in
warehouses. This was a common production problem in the pre-reform era in China. See
Dong, 1987:52-53.
10. However, Coca-Cola was restricted to minority stakes in the plants.
11. In the late 1970s, the Indian Government requested Coca-Cola to publicize the ingredients of
its concentrate. The company preferred to abandon the market rather than comply
(Economist, 15 July 1989: 67).
12. For example, when the Chinese government selected one local enterprise to form a JV with
Pepsi-Cola, it was found to be bankrupt (Business China, 19 February 1996: 2).
13. Approval from the former Ministry of Light Industry and the State Economic and Trade
Commission to build an additional ten bottling plants in 1993 made it necessary for Coca-
Cola to expand its operations in a more cost-effective manner (PU-TU-USC, 2000: 16).
14. Coca-Cola has been very selective in choosing its Chinese JV partners. Partners have been
confined to the China International Trust and Investment Corporation, the China National
Cereals, Oils, and Foodstuffs Import and Export Corporations and affiliates of the former
Ministry of Light Industry (PU-TU-USC, 2000: 19-21).
15. For example, in Xiamen, the bottling plant was 51 per cent owned by the Swire Group. A
local partner, Xiamen Luquan Industrial General Company, held the remaining 49 per cent.
The plant had an annual production capacity of 30 million unit cases (AWSJ, 11 May 1998:
4).
16. The Deputy General Manager of the Tianjin bottling plant was quite assertive on this point.
However, he was not willing to release information on monetary figures in the bargaining
process. He informed us that Coca-Cola promised to help its local partners to develop local
branded beverages, among other terms, to arrive at an agreement for the Coca-Cola buy-out
of the majority of shares of all existing and planned bottling plants (Field survey, 2000).
REFERENCES
Nolan, P. (2001), China and the Global Economy: National Champions, Industrial Policy
and the Big Business Revolution. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Peking University, Tsinghua University and University of South Carolina (PU-TU-USC)
(2000), Economic Impact of the Coca-Cola System on China, August.
(http://research.badm.sc.edu/research/studies/China/)
Sara, T. and Newhouse, B. (1995), ‘Transaction Costs and Foreign Direct Investment in
Developing Countries’, International Advances in Economic Research, Vol.1, No.4,
pp.317-25.
Schlevogt, K.-A. (2000), ‘The Branding Revolution in China’, The China Business
Review, Vol. 27, No.3, pp.52-57.
Simon, H.A. (1957), Models of Man: Social and Rational Mathematical Essays on
Rational Human Behavior in Social Setting, New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Stuckey, J. (1983), Vertical Integration and Joint Ventures in the Aluminium Industry.
Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.
Teece, D. (1983), ‘Multinational Enterprises, Internal Governance and Industrial
Organisation’, The American Economic Review, Vol.75, No.2, pp.232-8.
Wang, Z. (1998), ‘The Investment and Development of Coca-Cola Business in China’,
Zhongguo Waizi, Vol.10, pp.35-40.
Williamson, O. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implication.
New York: Free Press.
Yeung, G. (2001), Foreign Investment and Socio-Economic Development in China: The
Case of Dongguan. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Yu, K.Y. (ed.) (1991), Economics Dictionary (Jingji Dachidian). Shanghai Dictionary
Publishing House.
(1) How many subsidiaries do you have in China in 1999? Can you give me a breakdown
by nature of ownership/relationship? Among these, what are the involvement of Kerry
Group and Swire Group?
(2) Please tell me about the changes in the number of Coca-Cola subsidiaries, in
particular the number of joint ventures during the period after Coca-Cola has re-entered
China. (e.g. early 1980s, mid-1980s, early 1990s, and mid-1990s).
27
(3) What is the total number of employees in Coca-Cola China Ltd? How many of them
are managerial staff? Among them, how many are Chinese nationals recruited from the
local market in China? How many are expatriates from overseas, including US/HK etc.?
(4) Coke has bought the majority equity of bottling plants and distribution channel in
mid-1990s. Why has the strategy of Coke changed in such a direction? Was this change
attributed to the behaviour of hold-up and opportunism of Coke's partners in China when
Coke wanted to expand its market in China during that period?
(5) In relation to point (4), we have an initial suspicion. Whilst equity joint ventures
(EJVs) were an important mode (and absolutely necessary by host-country law) for Coke
to re-enter the Chinese market in early 1980s, was the costs of doing so might be too high
to Coke.
(C) Uncertainty and specific advantages in the execution of contracts / business operation
(6) On the issue of uncertainty in the business environment in China, over the period of
the last two decades, did Coke suffer/benefit from changes in China’s policy regarding
foreign direct investment as far as carbonated soft drinks sector is concerned?
(7) In terms of asset specificity endowed in the Coke’s product, what were the bargaining
chips of Coke in the negotiation processes with its partners in China?
(8) What sort of “specific” advantages did the Chinese partners have? “Specific”
advantages mean those advantages that were not easily provided by other firms in China.
It being so, what were the bargaining chips of Chinese partners in the negotiation
processes with Coke? Did those bargaining chips bring in some favourable terms to the
Chinese partners?
(9) On the issue of small number of agents in the operation of bottling plants in China,
did Coke face difficulties in writing, executing and enforcing complex contracts with the
Chinese partners? Any examples of damages/add extra costs to Coke?
(10) Is there any government requirement for technology transfer? How do you cope with
this requirement?
(11) Have you identified any damage/risk caused by your previous Chinese partners (in
terms of trade secrets, technology, etc.)?
(12) What are the main incentives for local partners to collaborate with Coca-Cola?
(13) After weighing over all sorts of benefits and costs to Coke’s investment in China, do
you see the collaboration with local partners in the form of joint ventures an advantage or
a risk to the company? In what aspects?
(1) Please provide me with the figures of market shares and sales volume (in bottles) of
Coke in the last three years in China. (and Pepsi as well, if available)
(2) Coke has been bottled in 13 sites in China in 1994. It has majority equity in all 16
bottling plants in 1996. In 1998 and 1999, how many bottling plants does Coke have?
Among them, how many are state-owned plants?
Why to allow state-owned plants to produce bottled Coke?
What are the other forms of co-operation with Chinese partners?
Among them, how many are under equity joint venture and the corresponding percentage
of equity?
(3) What are the major factors contributing to the success of Coke in terms of its
marketing strategy? Can we say that Coke’s achievement reflects its status of success as
marketer and a franchiser, but not as a manufacturer or a distributor?
(4) Before 1996, the distribution was handled by state-owned third party wholesalers.
They were criticised being invariably passive. Why? Opportunism? Incentives?
(5) In 1996, Coke adopted a hybrid distribution system consisting of direct distribution &
third party wholesalers. Why Coke adopts the hybrid distribution system? Is it due to cost
reducing or else? Any hold-up behaviour of third party wholesalers?
(6) In relation to point (5), implementing direct distribution requires direct management
controls. Was gaining this control expensive? How long was the period of calculating the
projected future earnings? How much did this increase Coke’s costs to acquire the buy-
out? Do you think this is a hold-up/opportunistic behaviour?
29
(8) In relation to points (3) & (5), what are the roles of Robert Kuok’s Kerry Group &
Swire Group?
(9) Pepsi is lagging behind Coke in the Chinese market. This is partly due to the fact that
Coke has successfully explored the ‘first-mover advantage’. Are there other reasons?
(10) What kind of competition do you have from the domestic soft drink manufacturers?
(11) How important are the JV arrangements for Coke to initially get into the Chinese
market?
(12) Can you provide an overview on the Coke's operation in China since 1979 with
particular reference to their joint venture (JV) arrangements
(13) What is your experience in dealing with policymakers and regulators in China? Is
the bureaucratic process less efficient that that of many other developing countries?
(14) How important is guanxi to the successful operation of Coke in the Chinese market?
(15) What are the ‘grey areas’ (semi-legitimate areas) in Chinese regulations and
government policy regarding foreign investment in the soft drinks industry? Do these
‘grey areas’ add costs or provide opportunities for Coke?
Questions asked in the interview: We did not fax questions to the Deputy General
Managers before the visit. The principal author conducted the interview in a semi-
structured mode. Questions were selected from the above list.
30
TABLE 1
MODES AND STRUCTURE OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN CHINA
(1979 – OCTOBER 2001)
Actual Percentage of
Number of Percentage of Utilization of Total
Mode of FDI
Firms Total Firms FDI (US$100 Utilization of
million) FDI
Equity Joint 213,780 55.59 1,717.64 44.64
Ventures
Co-operative 51,046 13.27 761.69 19.79
Joint Ventures
Joint R&D 180 0.05 70.78 1.84
Ventures
Wholly-Owned 119,589 31.09 1,297.73 33.73
Subsidiaries
Total 384,595 100 3,847.84 100
TABLE 2
NUMBERS OF COCA-COLA’S BOTTLING PLANTS IN CHINA, 1982-2000
1982 1
1984 3
1985 4
1992 10
1993 11
1996 16a
1999 24b
2000 28
Note: The numbers of Coca-Cola bottling plants in China do not correspond directly to
Table 4 because some JV bottling plants have been re-named since Coca-Cola bought the
majority shares.
Sources:
a
: Asian Wall Street Journal (AWSJ), 31 May 1996: 12.
b
: AWSJ, 26 November 1999: 11.
Others: Field survey, 1999 and 2000.
32
TABLE 3
MARKET SHARES OF COCA-COLA AND PEPSI-COLA IN CHINA
(PER CENT)
Sources:
a
: AWSJ, 15 February 1994: 1.
b
: AWSJ, 27 Jan 1994: 1.
c
: South China Morning Post (SCMP), 27 January 1994: 14.
d
: SCMP, 22 July 1995: 3
e
: AWSJ, 31 May 1996: 12.
f
: SCMP, 3 March 1998: 4.
g
: China Daily, 19 September 1999: 7.
h
: Field survey, 2000.
33
TABLE 4
LOCATION AND NAME OF COCA-COLA’S JOINT VENTURE BOTTLING
PLANTS IN CHINA, 2000
Sources: Field survey, 1999 and 2000; PU-TU-USC, 2000:17-18; Wang, 1998: 36.
34
FIGURE 1
THE OPERATIONAL MODE OF COCA-COLA BUSINESS IN SHANGHAI
DURING THE 1980s
Notes:
* This was wholly-owned by a state-owned enterprise. Coca-Cola had no involvement in
production, distribution, or profit-division of the company.
** This was (and still is) wholly-owned by Coca-Cola.
Source: Field survey, 1999 and 2000.