Effective Regulation Part 5
Effective Regulation Part 5
Effective Regulation Part 5
Institute
Systemic regulation and a new resolution authority are two proposed solutions to these problems. Systemic
regulation might reduce the frequency and severity of crises, but it is unlikely that crises can be eliminated
entirely. In fact, systemic regulation might actually increase the risk of another crisis by encouraging risky
behavior. Similarly, even a well-designed resolution authority could lead to more “bailouts” by making the
resolution process easier and less expensive. Ultimately, reform must effectively eliminate the concept of “too
big to fail” if it is to succeed.
One of the most promising proposals for substantially eliminating “too big to fail” is contingent capital.
Structured as debt that converts into common equity when a firm is in financial distress, contingent capital is a
form of self-insurance for systemically important firms. Correctly structured, it would force firms to recapitalize
early and quickly, before localized problems could spiral into a systemic crisis.
How might this kind of capital work? A firm is deemed to be systemically important because it provides
fundamental services, services so important and so intertwined with the basic structure of the financial system
that stopping or even interrupting them could disrupt the economy. While these services must be maintained,
the shareholders and bondholders of systemically important firms do not need special protection. Contingent
capital allows a firm to continue to provide these essential services, even as that firm is recapitalized at the
expense of its shareholders and contingent bondholders.
Back-tests indicate that contingent capital triggered by a process modeled after the U.S. “stress test” would have
allowed the firms that were included in the stress test to recapitalize without taxpayer funds. The keys to making
continent capital effective are: (1) converting before the firm is insolvent; (2) using a broad definition of risk,
including all off-balance-sheet items; and (3) applying a consistent, stress-based assessment of likely loan losses.
Further, making conversion highly dilutive to existing shareholders has the effect of incentivizing both
shareholders and the firm’s management to raise capital well before the firm reaches the mandatory conversion
point. The back-tests also indicate that contingent capital could be more effective in improving financial firm
incentives than a simple increase in regulatory capital requirements would be.
However, contingent capital could also be structured in ways that would make it ineffective or even dangerous.
Standard regulatory capital ratios have proved to provide an inadequate early warning system for financial firms
facing trouble. They would, therefore, be ineffective if used as part of a contingent capital regime. Additionally,
conversion triggers that are based on market prices (rather than on comprehensive capital ratios) might actually
exacerbate bank runs, rather than prevent them. So while the promise of contingent capital is great, it must be
structured with tremendous care.
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
Table of contents
2
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
The greater the emergency and the faster the unraveling of confidence, the more dramatic
such rescues need to be. In fact, overreaction on the part of policymakers is crucial to
breaking the momentum of a crisis. And it is why, in crisis after crisis, there comes a time
when key policymakers demand and receive overwhelming resources, whether in the form
of extended authority or funds.
An equally inevitable problem, particularly after a crisis in which otherwise unviable firms
are rescued, is the post-crisis review of fairness, moral hazard, the misuse of authority and
the need to prevent similar occurrences in the future. This review speaks to the political
and economic consequences of intervention.
The recent crisis raises two particularly challenging issues for reform of the financial
system. First is the tremendous expansion in the scope of institutions deemed to be “too
big to fail.” Second is the resulting increase in the size and scope of the government-
sponsored safety net needed to break the chain of failure that naturally arises during times
of crisis.
This is why some policymakers and academics are suggesting that a third-leg of reform is
needed: large financial firms should be required to hold contingent capital. 1 The idea is
quite simple: shareholders and contingent capital holders (a new type of bondholder) of a
systemically important firm agree ahead of time that contingent bonds will convert to
common equity if the firm’s capital falls below a specific threshold or some other identified
“trigger” is breached.
1
See U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke’s remarks to the U.S. House Financial Services
Committee, October 2009; see New York Federal Reserve President and Chief Executive Officer William
Dudley’s speech entitled “Some Lessons Learned from the Crisis,” October 2009; see Federal Reserve
Governor Daniel Tarullo’s speech entitled “Confronting Too Big to Fail,” October 2009; see the Gordon
S. Rentschler Memorial Professor of Economics and Public Policy at Princeton University Alan Blinder’s
speech entitled “It’s Broke, Let’s Fix it: Rethinking Financial Regulation,” October 2009; see Goldman
Sachs Managing Director Gerald E. Corrigan’s speech entitled “Containing Too Big to Fail,” November
2009; see the Bank of England’s Deputy Governor for Financial Stability Paul Tucker’s comments,
November 2009; and see the U.K. Treasury’s piece entitled “Risk, Reward and Responsibility: The
Financial Sector and Society,” December 2009.
3
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
Why might this kind of capital be effective? The reason a firm is deemed to be systemically
important is because it provides fundamental services, services so important and so
intertwined with the basic structure of the financial system that stopping or even
interrupting them could disrupt the economy. While these services must be maintained,
the shareholders and bondholders of systemically important firms do not need special
protection. Contingent capital, if correctly structured, could allow the firm to continue to
provide these essential services, keeping the economy safe, even as it is recapitalized at the
expense of its shareholders and contingent bondholders.
This is not to say that the “too big to fail” problem can be eliminated entirely. While
contingent capital could clearly allow troubled firms to recapitalize in periods of extreme
financial stress, such as during the recent financial crisis, it is not possible to rule out all
contingencies. Further, solving “too big to fail” only addresses the problem of how to
recapitalize a failed firm in a functioning financial market. Regulators and central banks will
continue to need to provide market liquidity in emergencies, and as needed, serve as a
lender of last resort. This need will not go away simply because individual firms can
recapitalize in periods of stress. No financial firm, regardless of how well capitalized it is,
can survive if the financial markets themselves fail.
As contingent capital is considered as a means to reduce the “too big to fail” problem, it is
important to understand that its effectiveness will depend on how it is structured, as well
as a few other critical issues. First, the conversion “trigger” must operate quickly, so that
recapitalization occurs promptly, preventing the firm’s management from further
endangering the firm’s capital or the broader economy. Second, this trigger must be
transparent, so investors can properly assess their risk exposure. Third, the quantity of
contingent capital must be large enough to deal with a crisis, but not so large as to reduce
the availability of credit and raise the cost of borrowing for bank customers to excessively
high levels. Additionally, the terms of conversion must incentivize systemically important
firms to be well-run and to act rapidly to correct problems, rather than encourage them to
take excessive risk using their “too big to fail” status as a shield against market discipline.
In this paper, we discuss how to get a contingent capital regime right. Then we provide a
“what if” analysis: how a well-structured contingent capital requirement, if it had existed,
might well have averted the need for financial institutions to turn to government funds
during the recent crisis. We end with an explanation of how contingent capital could be
ineffective or even dangerous, if is not structured with care.
As we discuss in this paper, the details matter, and a significantly different structure might
not have been as successful. In the same vein, changes to financial supervision, including
4
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
increases in tier one common capital requirements, would almost certainly affect the ideal
structure of a contingent capital regime.
A well-designed trigger for the conversion of contingent capital can correct for these bad
incentives, but only if a number of conditions are met. First, the trigger needs to operate
before the firm is insolvent, so that shareholders are incentivized to protect the value of the
remaining entity. Second, to ensure that the firm really is still solvent, the trigger must be
based on an accurate and comprehensive assessment of capital (or another similar test of
solvency) that measures the true health of the firm. This is one of the key lessons learned
from the crisis: reported balance sheets proved to be entirely inadequate to assess the
health of many financial firms. The full extent of capital shortfalls often did not become
visible until all off-balance-sheet liabilities were accounted for and likely losses were
recognized.
While other triggers should also be considered, the U.S. stress test provides a clear and
reasonable blueprint for how to address this problem. The stress test forced all risks onto
balance sheets; removed regulatory and accounting arbitrages; forced consistent loss
expectations for all assets for the following two years; offset some of these losses by
estimating conservative possible forward earnings; and, finally, calculated a two-year
forward capital ratio for the firm. Because the stress test was run in this manner, it created
a credible and comprehensive assessment of the true health of each institution in a
stressful environment.
Such a stress test would provide a known process to the markets, which would make
raising contingent capital much easier. Further, because much of the data from the stress
test was made public, it provides enough information to test what might have happened
had contingent capital with a stress-test-based trigger been in place during the crisis.
5
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
A contingent capital shield is comprised of interest-paying debt that, when converted, turns
into non-interest-paying equity. The structure of contingent capital could give triggered
firms a window of perhaps 30 days, in which they could recapitalize in public markets. If
they could not, or if they chose not to, then the contingent capital would automatically
convert to equity. Once contingent capital converts, the firm has fewer liabilities. Further,
because the firm stays solvent, its business counterparties are reassured that the firm will
remain a going concern (assuming that the trigger is fast and the contingent capital shield
is sufficiently large), meaning that there is far less incentive for the bank runs that often
create crises.
The terms of conversion can also be used to enhance the stability of the financial system. If,
for example, the conversion of contingent capital is sufficiently dilutive to current
shareholders, then firms will raise new capital even in times of high stress, in order to
avoid hitting the trigger. For example, even using very conservative assumptions, if the
firms that were subject to the U.S. stress test had been required to hold a contingent
capital shield sized at 6% of RWA from 2007 to 2009, a back-test indicates that every firm
would likely have recapitalized voluntarily, so that contingent capital would not have been
converted. Shareholders would have voluntarily suffered an average of about 50% dilution,
but no government funds or government-assisted mergers would have been needed, and
business would have likely been able to proceed without interruption.
The terms of conversion and size of the shield can also affect the cost of contingent capital.
A highly dilutive conversion for existing shareholders can help make the cost of contingent
capital more reasonable for financial firms. This is because contingent capital holders
would likely demand a lower rater of return in exchange for a greater share of the firm in
the event that contingent capital is converted. A prompt and comprehensive trigger can
also reduce the cost of contingent capital, because the value of the firm is likely to be
higher when contingent capital is converted. If, on the other hand, contingent capital is
structured poorly, it may prove to be unreasonably expensive.
The ideal size of the contingent capital shield will depend in part on changes to financial
supervisory regimes and capital requirements in the future. The back-test assumes a 6% of
RWA tier one common capital requirement, as is currently the case. But it is entirely
possible that financial regulators will require a higher level of base capital in the future. If
so, and if firms accordingly have a stronger tier one capital cushion, then the ideal size of
the contingent capital shield would likely be lower than 6% of RWA. The analysis also
strongly suggests that the addition of a contingent capital layer may be more effective in
improving financial firm incentives than increasing core minimum regulatory capital
requirements.
Of course many other factors must be considered, including who will buy contingent debt
and how regulators could roll-out a contingent capital plan. The devil will likely be in the
details, and many of the answers to these questions will depend on changes to existing
rules. That said, if the goal is to substantially eliminate the “too big to fail” problem,
contingent capital does so by allowing systemically important firms to recapitalize at the
expense of their shareholders and contingent bondholders – and not at the expense of the
public.
6
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
To answer these questions, a few key assumptions must be made. First, public capital must
be assumed to be available at all times. We know all too well that this may not always be
the case and that, in reality, some of these firms may have no choice but to convert
contingent capital if public markets are unwilling or unable to provide the funding they
require.
Second, it must be assumed that these firms would have had access to the various forms
of liquidity that were provided to keep overall markets functioning. As we have noted, no
financial firm, regardless of how well-capitalized it is, can survive if financial markets
themselves fail. To that end, some proposals in circulation today would restrict the Federal
Reserve’s ability to lend in times of stress, and this would undoubtedly intensify the
problems that arise in times of stress. If the Federal Reserve’s power is sharply constrained
in this way, then specific provisions for emergency liquidity or a minimum liquidity ratio
would be needed in addition to contingent capital. (Regulators are clearly considering
liquidity requirements, but this issue is outside of the scope of this paper.)
Third, it is assumed that these firms only raise enough capital to meet their minimum
regulatory requirements. In reality, they are more likely to attempt to raise a larger capital
cushion, which would reduce the need for successive capital raises. The firms included in
the U.S. stress test, for example, raised 50% more capital than mandated.
Fourth, the back-test does not account for the fact that the discipline imposed by a stress
test, as well as early capital raises, should have made these firms more likely to quickly
curtail the activities that allowed losses to mount.
Lastly, the U.S. stress test is used in the back-test as a blueprint for how contingent capital
could be designed: it is incorporated into the conversion trigger, capital adequacy
thresholds, the treatment of off-balance-sheet risks and forward operating assumptions.
The back-test includes firms that suffered substantial losses: Citigroup, Merrill Lynch, Bank
of America, Washington Mutual and Countrywide. It also examines firms that fared
relatively well during the crisis: J.P. Morgan and Morgan Stanley. Each firm is considered
on a stand-alone basis, as if no acquisitions had been made, so that we can better
understand if and how they would have survived on their own if contingent capital had
been in place. Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers are not included in the study, because
data are too limited.
The first step in the analysis is to determine how much capital might have been destroyed
at each firm over the course of the crisis. To do so, we must take account of actual and
estimated losses net of pre-provision earnings.
Let’s consider Citigroup as an example. The company generated nearly $120bn in losses,
including write-downs and provisions, from 1Q2007 through 4Q2008. The 2009 stress test,
which used data from the end of 2008 as a reference point, projected incremental losses for
Citigroup of $105bn over the following two years. This means that, in aggregate,
Citigroup’s losses could be about $225bn from the start of the crisis through the end of
7
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
2010. Some of these losses could be offset by income. For example, the stress test
projected that Citigroup could offset about half of its losses with income generated from
2009 through 2011. A tax shield would be applied to some of these losses as well.
When all of these factors are taken into account, Citigroup could generate net cumulative
losses of just under $115bn. As we noted earlier, if a stress test had been conducted
throughout the economic cycle, Citigroup would have been more likely to raise capital
early. This would have left it better capitalized, and should have made it more likely to
quickly curtail the activities that caused these losses to build.
For companies that did not survive the crisis as independent entities, this analysis is a bit
more complicated. For Washington Mutual, for example, we have to estimate potential
losses and potential income based on the company’s loan portfolio. For Merrill Lynch, for
example, we know that the company generated nearly $60bn in losses from 1Q2007
through 4Q2008, but we have to estimate the losses and income a stress test would have
projected, using other investment banks as a model.
Once net losses have been determined, their effect on capital can be calculated. The
process here is simple: net losses are subtracted from capital while net gains are added to
capital. Remember that tier one capital consists largely of shareholders’ equity, which is
simply the market value of equity at issuance, plus any retained earnings, less any losses
or dividends paid.
Next, it is determined if and when these systemically important firms would have breached
specific tier one common capital thresholds. If such a threshold is breached, contingent
capital would be triggered to convert to common equity. It is also assumed that the
company could, as an alternative, have issued equity in the public markets at a 15%
discount to its share price at that time. (We think this 15% discount is a conservative
assumption, particularly given the prices at which these firms were able to raise capital
after the stress test results were released, but we would also note that markets could have
shut entirely, in which case the conversion would have been forced.) Where a share price is
not available because a company was acquired, that price is estimated based on the
performance of the U.S. Banks Index. A haircut is then applied to this estimate due to the
likelihood that business would have continued to deteriorate after the acquisition was
completed.
Each time a firm breaches its tier one common capital threshold, the back-test asks
whether the firm would prefer to raise capital in the public markets or convert its
contingent capital. Again, this decision will depend on which option is less dilutive to
existing shareholders, and whether capital can actually be raised.
As we have already noted, the back-test considers a firm to have breached its tier one
common capital requirement if this ratio dips below the current minimum requirement of
6% of RWA in the current quarter or below 4% of RWA based on a two-year forward stress
test. Citigroup, for example, would have breached this 6% threshold in 4Q2007. At that time,
it would have been less dilutive to raise capital in public markets to fill the capital gap.
Citigroup would again have breached this 4% threshold in 1Q2008, 2Q2008 and 4Q2008. At
each of these times, it would also have been less dilutive to raise capital than to convert
contingent capital.
We provide some key conclusions for each of these firms in Exhibits 1 through 6, and walk
through a specific example (Washington Mutual) in detail in Appendix A. If you would like
greater detail for each of the companies included in the back-test, please contact us.
8
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
Exhibit 1: Net cumulative losses and capital levels Exhibit 2: Cumulative losses as a % of total assets
USD bn
$200 14%
$177
$180
$161 12%
$160 $153
$140 10%
$120 $113
8%
$100
6%
$80 $74
$63 $60
$60 $55
4%
$45 $43 $44 $45
$40 $32
$23 $26 2%
$22 $19 $20
$20 $16
$11 $12
$0 0%
C BAC MER JPM MS WaMu CFC WaMu BAC C CFC MER JPM MS
After-tax cumulative losses net of pre-provision
Capital (4Q2007; common, preferreds, TruPS & sub. debt) Cumulative losses as a percentage of assets
Tangible common equity (4Q2007)
* Cumulative losses are taken as percentage of 3Q2007 assets. * We use 35% tax rate in all of our analysis.
* Estimated losses include write-downs and provisions reported.
* Cumulative losses are taken as percentage of 3Q2007 assets.
* WaMu actuals used from 1Q2007 to 2Q2008. After that based on JPM deal marks.
* Countrywide actuals used from 1Q2007 to 2Q2008. After that based on BAC deal
marks.
* For Fed stress test pre-provision earnings, we use $75bn for BAC. We estimate split
between legacy BAC, MER and CFC.
Source: Goldman Sachs Research estimates. Source: Goldman Sachs Research estimates.
Exhibit 3: Additional capital needed to meet minimum Exhibit 4: Cumulative dilution from raising public capital
tier one common capital thresholds in the back-test in lieu of converting contingent capital
USD bn
90%
$70 83%
$66
79%
80%
$60
70% 67%
61%
$50 $47 60%
$40 50%
40%
$30
$26
$22 30%
$20
20%
15%
$9 10%
$10 10%
$5
0%
$0 0%
$0
WaMu CFC ML C BAC MSDW JPM
C ML BAC WaMu CFC MSDW JPM
Capital required to meet our minimum tier one common capital thresholds Cumulative dilution from public capital raises
* How much capital each firm would have to raise to meet our 4% stress test or 6% * The numbers above represent the cumulative dilution existing shareholders would
current quarter minimum tier one common capital ratio threshold. have faced at the start of the financial crisis, if each of these firms had opted to raise
* Remember that we examine each company on a stand-alone basis, as if it had never capital in public markets rather than allow contingent capital to convert. They would
been acquired or made any acquisitions. have elected to raise capital in public markets, assuming capital is available, because
at any given point in time, it would be less dilutive than the 60% fixed dilution that
occurs when contingent capital converts.
* Recall that we examine each company on a stand-alone basis, as if it had never been
acquired or made any acquisitions.
Source: Goldman Sachs Research estimates. Source: Goldman Sachs Research estimates.
9
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
Exhibit 5: The size of a contingent capital shield Exhibit 6: How many tranches of contingent capital
USD bn might each firm have had to convert during the crisis?
$160 2 2
$151 2
$137
$140
$120
$100
$80 1 1 1 1
1
$62
$60
$49
$40
$30 $29
$20 $14
$0
0
ML WaMu C BAC MSDW CFC JPM 0
ML WaMu C BAC MSDW CFC JPM
The size of a contingent capital shield (6% of risk weighted assets)
If contingent capital were converted, how many tranches might be needed?
* Above we show the total amount of contingent capital each of these firms would * Although we do not think that any firm would have elected to convert contingent
have held if they had a 6% of RWA contingent capital requirements. Remember, capital during the crisis, we would note that if they had, a 6% total contingent capital
however, that we should suggest that this 6% shield be held in two tranches, each shield would have been sufficient to recapitalize even the most troubled firms.
equal to 3% of risk weighted assets. The estimates above are based on risk-weighted
assets as of 4Q2007.
Source: Goldman Sachs Research estimates. Source: Goldman Sachs Research estimates.
The first important feature is a stress-test trigger. Some have recommended using
regulatory capital-based triggers, but had such a trigger been used in the 2007 to 2009
period, it clearly would have failed. Publicly available data did not accurately convey the
true reality of bank balance sheets: too much risk could be hidden off balance sheets; too
much discretion was left to the reporting firms; and too little discipline in assessing
forward losses was evident in the public numbers.
Market triggers are also being considered. They are technically very interesting, but they
suffer from two critical flaws. First, they reflect no better information than do public
accounting statements. Thus they may create incentives for managements to try to conceal
problems from the market, hoping to earn their way out of trouble but potentially just
exacerbating problems instead. Second, market-based triggers can easily create or
intensify instability because of the way they are heeded in the market. For example,
experience with similar “barrier options” (an option whose intrinsic value changes
dramatically upon breaching a specific price level) suggests that the hedging associated
with holding such options is likely to force a market trigger to be breached. Clearly a
trigger should be pulled because a firm is at serious financial risk, not because of the
hedging needs of its continent capital holders.
One advantage of a capital-adequacy-based trigger is that it would provide these firms with
a window in which they would have the opportunity to recapitalize in public markets; a
market trigger is unlikely to be able to provide this kind of leeway.
10
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
The stress-test design is also attractive because it can be adapted to incorporate various
other risks. One could imagine a battery of stress scenarios where firms are required to
pass the 4% of RWA test all-in. The stress test also addresses the desire for a less pro-
cyclical approach to bank capital standards. If the parameters of the test were held largely
constant, losses would not be determined relative to current conditions but instead relative
to the same stress levels, which would cause the firm to build up capital even in good
times. Thus, while the original stress test represented a fairly substantial burden on both
regulators and banks, repeating such a test quarterly in conjunction with regular reporting,
based on constant parameters, could increase transparency, reduce the pro-cyclicality of
capital and not represent an unreasonable burden on either regulators or financial firms.
The stress test could also be updated as warranted to incorporate new products or risks.
While a single tranche sized at 6% of RWA would have worked in the back-test, there are
advantages to having two tranches. Consider what would happen if firms were required to
hold their contingent capital shield in two tranches, each equal to 3% of RWA. Even if one
tranche were converted, the second tranche would still provide a capital cushion. Moreover,
even though converting the first tranche would massively dilute existing shareholders, the
continued existence of the second tranche (which would also be highly dilutive if
converted) would maintain the pressure on (old and new) shareholders to address
problems promptly. The second tranche would also likely price more favorably than the
first, keeping the cost of contingent capital somewhat lower.
Additionally, it is worth noting that the conversion of even one tranche of contingent
capital would immediately subject a firm to more stringent regulatory oversight. This is
because the conversion itself would deplete the firm’s capital below the regulatory
minimum (although the conversion would add more tier one capital, in the form of equity,
it would deplete tier two capital). This breach of regulatory requirements would give
regulators the ability to take prompt corrective action and intervene as appropriate. It could
also lead to the termination of existing management, if regulators feel that is the most
appropriate course of action.
The back-test shows that a contingent capital shield of 6% of RWA would have been
sufficient even in the worst banking crisis since the 1930s. Small changes to this structure
clearly would not matter, but a significantly higher or lower number could be problematic.
If the shield were much smaller than 6% of RWA, it might not be large enough to
recapitalize firms in real distress. In that case, it would not offer real and credible protection,
and it would raise the risk that government funds might ultimately be needed in any case.
Alternatively, if the shield were much more than 6% of RWA, it could be too expensive for
the issuing firm. This could lead to higher borrowing costs for bank customers and lower
availability of credit.
Lastly, the analysis indicates that making the conversion highly dilutive to existing
shareholders would add substantially to the stability of the overall financial system in
times of stress. The much increased likelihood that firms would recapitalize without direct
government capital injections, and voluntarily choose to hold excess capital instead, is a
clear and unambiguous positive. If shareholders knew that the mandatory dilution would
be much smaller, they might be more inclined to allow conversion. This would lead to a
greater government role (because regulators would be more deeply involved) and likely to
greater government expense. The threat of losing control of the company should compel
existing shareholders to seek capital in public markets as the better alternative.
11
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
Severe dilution has other advantages, beginning with a cost advantage. The higher the
incentive to recapitalize in public markets, the lower the cost of the contingent capital to
the issuing firm, as the likelihood of conversion is lower and the residual value of the firm
upon conversion is considerably higher.
We would also note in passing that it would be quite natural to tie the voluntary decision to
hold contingent capital to either the size of a firm, or the range of activities in which a firm
engages, by allowing smaller firms to avoid the need to hold contingent capital by staying
small, and not engaging in activities beyond narrow banking-related ones.
Conclusions
In summary, it is clear that correctly structured contingent capital could solve many of the
problems associated with “too big to fail.” As regulators and policymakers seek to enhance
the safety and soundness of the global financial system, it is important to consider that
well-structured contingent capital could provide better incentives for financial firms to be
well-managed than a simple increase in minimum regulatory capital requirements.
However, it is also possible that contingent capital can be structured in ways that might
make it ineffective or even dangerous, and so it must be designed and implemented with
care.
12
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
First, the back-test estimates that WaMu could generate net losses of $19bn from 1Q2007
through 4Q2010. This includes $38bn in cumulative losses, which are estimated by
assuming that 15% of the company’s $250bn loan book is lost (this compares to the 12.5%
loss estimate used by JPM).
Pre-provision income in 2007 and 2008, and an estimate of pre-provision income for 2009
and 2010 of $8bn, are netted from cumulative losses. 2009 and 2010 pre-provision
estimates are derived by taking a one-third haircut to the $6bn average pre-provision
income WaMu generated in the four quarters prior to its acquisition. A tax shield is applied
to losses, but deferred tax assets are limited to 10% of tier one common capital.
In 4Q2007, WaMu had consolidated capital of $32bn. Net losses from 2007 through 2010
would therefore have wiped out 60% of the firm’s capital (as of 4Q2007). See Exhibit 7.
If tier one common capital had to be above 6% of RWA in the current quarter, and above
4% of RWA based on the application of a “stress test,” WaMu would need to add $22bn in
capital from 2007 through 2010 to meet minimum capital requirements (see Exhibit 8).
The firm must determine if it will convert its contingent capital to fill this minimum capital
gap, or if instead it should raise capital in the public markets. For the purposes of the back-
test, it is assumed that public capital can always be raised.
In order to determine if WaMu would have elected to raise capital in the public markets, the
company’s share price is estimated. For 1Q2007 through 2Q2008, actual share prices can
be used. But for 3Q2008 through 4Q2009, the company’s stock price must be estimated
because its shares were retired after it was acquired. The firm’s share price is estimated by
applying the performance of the U.S. Banks Index. Then a 20% haircut is taken to that price,
as it is assumed that business conditions at WaMu would have worsened more than they
did at the other firms included in the Index. Another 15% discount is then applied to this
price.
The company would likely have elected to raise public capital (see Exhibit 9), as dilution at
any single point in time from a public capital raise would have been less than the 60% fixed
dilution associated with converting one tranche, or the 90% fixed dilution associated with
converting both tranches of contingent capital. That said, cumulative dilution from public
capital raises would reach more than 80%.
13
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
Exhibit 7: Legacy WaMu losses and capital positioning Exhibit 8: Legacy WaMu contingent capital scenario
USD bn analysis
USD bn; % of risk-weighted assets
Tier 1 common:
$35 bn Simulated net Tier 1 common: Contingent
Contingent capital
income "Do nothing" scenario capital required
scenario
4Q07 -$1.9 bn 8.5% $0.0 bn 8.5%
$30 bn
$7.7 bn 1Q08 -$1.1 bn 7.6% $1.4 bn 8.2%
Sub debt Contingent
$7.6 bn capital 2Q08 -$3.3 bn 5.4% $7.3 bn 9.0%
$25 bn (tranche 2)
$0.8 bn TruPS 3Q08 -$3.3 bn 3.2% $0.0 bn 6.9%
$0 bn
Capital requirement / losses Consolidated capital Hypothetical capital
(4Q2007) contingent plan (4Q2007)
*Including $4bn of preferred stock at WMPF LLC, which is considered tier 1 capital.
Source: Global Investment Research estimates. Source: Goldman Sachs Global Investment Research.
14
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
Acknowledgements
We would like to acknowledge the significant contributions in putting together
this piece of the following members of Goldman Sachs:
15
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
16
December 15, 2009 Global Markets Institute
Disclosures
This report has been prepared by the Global Markets Institute, the public policy research unit of the Global Investment Research Division of The
Goldman Sachs Group, Inc. (“Goldman Sachs”). As public policy research, this report, while in preparation, may have been discussed with or
reviewed by persons outside of the Global Investment Research Division, both within and outside Goldman Sachs, and all or a portion of this report
may have been written by policy experts not employed by Goldman Sachs.
While this report may discuss implications of legislative, regulatory and economic policy developments for industry sectors, it does not attempt to
distinguish among the prospects or performance of, or provide analysis of, individual companies and does not recommend any individual security or
an investment in any individual company and should not be relied upon in making investment decisions with respect to individual companies or
securities.
Distributing entities
This research is disseminated in Australia by Goldman Sachs JBWere Pty Ltd (ABN 21 006 797 897) on behalf of Goldman Sachs; in Canada by
Goldman Sachs Canada Inc. regarding Canadian equities and by Goldman Sachs & Co. (all other research); in Germany by Goldman Sachs & Co.
oHG; in Hong Kong by Goldman Sachs (Asia) L.L.C.; in India by Goldman Sachs (India) Securities Private Ltd.; in Japan by Goldman Sachs Japan Co.,
Ltd.; in the Republic of Korea by Goldman Sachs (Asia) L.L.C., Seoul Branch; in New Zealand by Goldman Sachs JBWere (NZ) Limited on behalf of
Goldman Sachs; in Singapore by Goldman Sachs (Singapore) Pte. (Company Number: 198602165W); and in the United States of America by
Goldman, Sachs & Co. Goldman Sachs International has approved this research in connection with its distribution in the United Kingdom and
European Union.
European Union: Goldman Sachs International, authorised and regulated by the Financial Services Authority, has approved this research in
connection with its distribution in the European Union and United Kingdom; Goldman, Sachs & Co. oHG, regulated by the Bundesanstalt für
Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht, may also be distributing research in Germany.
No part of this material may be (i) copied, photocopied or duplicated in any form by any means or (ii) redistributed without the prior
written consent of The Goldman Sachs Group, Inc.
17