Bauer. Rural Workers in Spanish America
Bauer. Rural Workers in Spanish America
Bauer. Rural Workers in Spanish America
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/2514135?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Duke University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
The Hispanic American Historical Review
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Hispanic American Historical Review
59(1), 1979, 34-63
Copyright i 1979 by Duke University Press
ARNOLD J. BAUER
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
BURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 35
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
36 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
Europe. All of the authors emphasized the extremely tentative and
even speculative nature of their views and the ambiguity of scanty
evidence.
A picture of generalized peonage nevertheless became standard in
textbooks. A generation of students and the general public were taught
by the forceful prose of L. B. Simpson's enormously popular Many
A'exicos that peonage was universally employed "to secure a cheap
and constant supply of labor" throughout Mexico in the nineteenth
century. Charles Cumberland also found debt peonage all pervasive,
but he believed that the practice reached a peak in the eighteenth cen-
tury.4 Enrique Semo's recent book repeats the earlier view that peon-
age became a general practice in nineteenth century Mexico. In the
absence of research most studies agree that the Mexican example is ap-
plicable to South America. Rodolfo Stavenhagen finds that peonage
grew with the development of capitalist agriculture everywhere in
Latin America.5
But have we been given a correct picture of debt bondage? We
must be very careful, first of all, to distinguish between the two terms,
for there can be bondage without debt and more commonly, debt with-
out bondage. In places where landowners wield effective police con-
trol themselves or through local political leaders, no excuse, not even
the legal fiction of debt is needed to bind workers. But where land-
owners do not have such power, what has been called debt may also
been seen as credit; that is, as advances of cash or goods against the
promise of future work. It is not enough merely to find cash, or more
commonly rations from the hacienda store, marked against the work-
er's account to assume that the advance carried coercive power. To
establish the presence of a functioning peonage, there must be evi-
dence of the landowner's ability to restrict workers' mobility.
About Yucata'n and the southeast Mexican lowlands there is no dis-
agreement: labor conditions were harsh; workers were imported by
force; debt was systematically used to provide a legal basis for coer-
cion; and plantation owners, aided by local police or the army were
able to restrict workers' movement and tie them to the estates. There
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 37
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
38 HAM I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
The older reports insist that it was harsh and tyrannical. The pre-
dominately urban observers found a six A.M. to six P.M. work day
"bleak" and "oppressive;" the wage advanced in the sierra was de-
scribed as a "lure" to entrap the innocent. Most writers who reported
on the enganche system assumed that workers could be held for their
debt and that once "hooked" into the system they were bent to their
task and mercilessly and effectively hunted down if they tried to
sC ,,"8
escape.
It is true that the onset of capitalist agriculture attracted a score
of outraged critics and also produced outbursts of labor troubles
around Trujillo, especially in the years 1910-1920, but a clear under-
standing of the system itself has been distorted by more than the or-
dinary volume of ideological fervor and charged language. Recent re-
search carried out in the Archivo del Fuero Agrario is beginning to
change the older picture and raise a series of new questions. Where
most of the prior studies implied that workers drawn from the families
of smallholders and villagers were incapable of learning and each year
seemed to stumble drunkenly into the recruiter's grasp, it now seems
likely that they freely and knowingly chose to work on the coast, took
advantage of competition for labor, and knew how to drive up the
amount of wages that plantation agents had to advance. Solomon Vil-
ler found another motive in sierra to coast migration: several men left
"expressly for the purpose of changing wives." The point here is that
the closer the new sources enable us to get to social reality, the more
there emerges a world of mutual adjustment and accommodation.
Labor recruiters, for example, undoubtedly had to deal fairly with po-
tential workers in order to establish a reputation which insured con-
tinuing success over the years. Klaren's new research shows that re-
cruiters got repeat business as their peons signed up year after year and
then often asked for additional wage advances to be paid to families
left behind in the sierra. Instead of being passive victims, it seems
more likely that workers saw their chance and took it's
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 39
199-200, shows that the Cayalti administrators scolded a contratista for ill-treat-
ment of peons since such a reputation "does the hacienda much harm." Mr. Mi-
chael Gonzalez is now finishing a dissertation on Peruvian labor systems at the Uni-
versity of California, Berkeley.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
40 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
reinforce their original way of life. Favre argues that these particular
peasants were responsive because a breakdown in their system of in-
terdependent, vertical agricultural niches forced them to seek work
on the coast; consequently their experience may not be applicable to
other zones.10
The degree of competition for workers among plantations, ha-
ciendas, mines, and cities is another serious omission in most studies
of labor systems. The older reports drew a picture of sierra haciendas
in which workers were immobilized by debt. At the same time, we are
asked to believe that plantation agents recruited masses of these same
people with no apparent objection from the hacendados. Is it reason-
able to assume that haciendas and plantations would collude and not
compete for scarce labor? Or, if workers were not scarce in the sierra,
why would debt peonage have been necessary to hold them? There are
local, national, and even international political questions involved here
which with few exceptions are ignored. In the case of the Mexican
north, Friedrich Katz shows that because of competition from Mex-
ican mines and U.S. industry, hacendados were forced to increase peon
wages and offer more generous sharecropping arrangements. In a re-
cent study of another sugar economy in northern Argentina in the
1930s, Ian Rutledge argues that plantation owners bought or rented
haciendas in the Jujuy highlands solely in order to extract labor ser-
vices from the service tenantry or subrenters whom they then forced
"with brutal methods" into plantation labor during the zafra.'1 Apart
from the fact that this seems like an exceedingly expensive way of find-
ing workers-one highland hacienda cost 41,000 pesos-Mr. Rutledge
acknowledges that the Indian tenants were in fact free to leave the
hacienda had they wanted to avoid plantation labor. A possible alter-
native to the Draconian interpretation of debt and violence presented
by Mr. Rutledge is that given their possibilities, Indian tenants chose
to work for wages on plantations and that the parcels of land guaran-
teed them by the hacienda were actually an incentive offered by the
landowners to keep them from migrating out of the region during the
dead season.'2
10. Henri Favre, "La crise de la society paysanne et la migration vers les
plantations cotiers dans le Perou Central," translated and reprinted in Kenneth
Duncan and Ian Rutledge, eds., Land and Labour in Latin America (Cambridge,
1977), pp. 253-267.
11. Katz, "Labor Conditions," p. 34; Rutledge, "Plantations and Peasants in
Northern Argentina: The Sugar Cane Industry of Salta and Jujuy, 1930-1943" in
David Rock, ed., Argentina in the Twentieth Century (London, 1975), p. 99.
12. A recent article by Donna Guy, "The Rural Working Class in Nineteenth-
Century Argentina: Forced Plantation Labor in Tucuman," Latin American Re-
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AM1E.RICA 41
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
42 HAHR j FEBRUARY j ARNOLD J. BAUER
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 43
the way things must be done." There are many times, Herrera con-
tinues, when one must "tolerate any number of demands [from the ser-
vice tenantry] because on this hacienda there are so many places where
a worker can go to live ... one fires an inquilino and he says 'Well, I'm
not going' and when he sees there is no hope of staying, what he does
is move to another place or some settlement or along the road and
there he mocks the sentence. One complains again to the owner [of
the neighboring estate] on whose land he now lives and the man moves
again and now besides mocking, he declares himself an enemy ... this
is why one must put up with impertinences of the workers and before
firing one, try to arrange things with prudence."'7
Finally, let us return to Mexico where the study of peonage began
and where the debate over its function is most developed. The tropical
lowlands were notorious for harsh working conditions, but the center
and north of Mexico were very different and one must be careful not
to confuse these regions with the special circumstances found in Yuca-
tan or Chiapas. There is no better guide to the Mexican material than
Friedrich Katz whose recent work provides an overview and pre-
liminary analysis. As he is careful to point out, however, few studies
of the nineteenth century are based on hacienda records.'8 Since Katz'
1974 article, several new works have appeared. Two of these deal with
years preceding the 1870-1930 period emphasized in this paper, but
since they both present useful correctives to conventional views, I brief-
ly note them here.
David Brading's study of the Bajlo (1700-1850), which is based on
estate and notarial records, shows how population increase enabled
landowners to diminish tenant perquisites in the eighteenth century
and move gradually to a system of money rents and wage payments.
But Brading inverts the older notions of debt to show that in fact the
estates were more indebted to the workers than the other way around.
Those workers who did have debts apparently left work with im-
punity.19 John Tutino's research in the Riva Palacio papers deals with
the mixed grain and livestock haciendas in the heart of dense Indian
settlement near Chalco, where in the early nineteenth century perhaps
seventy percent of the population lived in communities. A small num-
17. Rafael Herrera, "Memoria sobre la hacienda 'Las Condes' en 1895," ed.
by Gonzalo Izquierdo, Boletin de la Academia Chilena de la Historia, no. 79
(1968), pp. 202-203.
18. Katz, "Labor Conditions," pp. 1-47; see also his Servidumbres agrarias en
Mexico del porfiriato (Mexico, 1977).
19. David Brading, "Estructura de la production agricola en el Bajio, 1700-
1850," in Enrique Florescano, ed., Haciendas, latifundias y plantaciones en America
Latina (Mexico, 1975), pp. 112, 114.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
44 HIAAR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
ber of specialized workers-shepherds, gardeners, stable keepers-were
attracted to the haciendas through wage advances and by the "um-
brella of security" which the haciendas provided in the form of ra-
tions and rudimentary medical care during famine and epidemics. The
hacienda books record credit extended, but there is no evidence of debt
bondage. Ordinary fieldworkers were recruited by the day or week
in nearby villages with the help of local priests and through payment
to labor bosses or contractors. These peons were organized into work
teams andl paid a cash wage which varied with age and experience.
These workers, however, often chose to attend the numerous village
fiestas or market days instead of working on the hacienda, and in any
case they always gave their first priority to their own village plots. The
haciendas' harvesting was consequently delayed, but even though the
owners or managers handed out cash advances, paid for and had ra-
tions prepared for the workers, cajoled and complained, there was little
the hacendados were able to do.20
Ward Barrett's study of the Atlacomnulco sugar plantation in More-
los at about the same time gives a similar picture of the problems in
labor recruitment. In the early nineteenth century, hacendados had
either to beseech in a "smooth and persuasive tone" to attract Indian
workers or else hand out fairly large cash advances. In one case, 2,000
pesos were distributed, but most of the expected workers simply took
the advance and never showed up for work.2' The research of both
Tutino and Barrett undoubtedly reflects the immediate post-indepen-
dence reversal of a trend toward greater landowner control of produc-
tion which began in the later eighteenth century and then picked up
again in the 1870s.
Some of the most elaborate and richly detailed research on ha-
ciendas was published in 1975 by Jan Bazant who had access to a
number of private archives in the San Luis Potosi region. His study
covers precisely the years-the last half of the nineteenth century-
20. John Tutino, "Hacienda Social Relations in Mexico: The Chalco Region
in the Era of Independence," HAHR, 55 (Aug. 1975), 496-528. See also his more
recent, "Life and Labor on North Mexican Haciendas: The Queretaro-San Luis
Potosi Region, 1775-1810" (Paper presented at the Fifth Reunion of Mexican and
North American Historians, Patzcuaro, 1977), in which resident workers are
advanced money and goods not as a pretext for debt bondage but as the only
way to keep them from seeking employment elsewhere.
21. Ward Barrett, The Sugar Hacienda of the Marqueses del Valle (Minne-
apolis, 1970), p. 88. Jan Bazant, "El trabajo y los trabajadores en la hacienda de
Atlacomulco" (Paper presented at the Fifth Reunion of Mexican and North Amer-
ican Historians in Patzcuaro, 1977), shows that many workers left owing money
and the hacienda simply wrote them off as bed debts.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 45
22. Bazant, Cinco haciendas mexicanas: Tres siglos de vida rural en San Luis
Potosi (Mexico, 1975), pp. 163-167; and two articles: "Peones, arrendatarios y
aparceros en Mexico: 1851-1853," Historia Mexicana, 23 (Apr.-June 1973), 330-
355; and "Peones, arrendatarios y aparceros: 1868-1904," Historia Mexicana, 24
(Jan.-Mar. 1974), 94-121. In San Luis Potosi as elsewhere, the best land usually
was in the demesne, the less fertile or unirrigated, let to sharecroppers.
23. Chevalier, "The North Mexican Hacienda: Eighteenth and Nineteenth
Centuries" in A. R. Lewis and Thomas McGann, eds., The New World Looks at
its History (Austin, 1963), pp. 95-107; Katz, "Labor Conditions," pp. 32-35.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
46 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
age, in the north because of different circumstances it led to free labor
and higher wages. Harry Cross' recent dissertation based on hacienda
account books and letter files from Zacatecas brings into question the
conventional notions about peonage in this region. The main variables
in the north seem to have been competition, differences in workers'
mentalities, and the absence of control sufficient to restrict mobility.24
To this merging picture, however, there is a recent exception.
Charles Harris' 1975 book is the most detailed examination ever
made of a single latifundium. In contrast to most of the new work,
Harris makes a strong case for an extremely oppressive debt peonage in
Coahuila throughout the century of his investigation from 1765-1867.
Working in the iich Sanchez-Navarro papers, Harris leaves no doubt
that permanent workers often owed money to the hacienda as a re-
sult of salary advances, charges against their account in the hacienda
store, charges for lost animals, fees for clerical services performed by
the resident priest, and so on. He is equally detailed and emphatic in
his contention that the Sanchez-Navarros were able to bring force
against defaulting debtors and make them return to the hacienda to
work off their obligations. The lack of quantitative control over the
vivid stories of ill-treatment and the clear sympathies of the author
make the argument on this point less convincing. As David Brading
recently pointed out, one does have the impression that when it comes
to peonage and oppression, Mr. Harris "may have encountered what
he set out to find."25
If debt is one thing and bondage often another, how can we under-
stand the common practice of advancing cash or goods to workers,
especially when the amount advanced often far exceeds that needed to
provide a pretext for coercion? In the case of enganche labor in Peru
and Argentina, I have tried to show that plantations were forced to
advance as much as six months' salary in order to attract workers to
field labor. The fact that workers could insist on so large an advance
24. Harry Cross, "The Mining Economy of Zacatecas in the Nineteenth Cen-
tury" (Ph.D. Diss., University of California, Berkeley, 1976), and his more recent
work based on hacienda records in Zacatecas and San Luis Potosi.
25: Charles Harris III, A Mexican Family Empire: The Latifundio of the
Sanchez-Navarros, 1765-1867 (Austin, 1975), pp. 58, 59, 216-217, 222. When,
for example, one hacienda continues to provide food and supplies from its store
even when the workers are idle-often for as long as ten months of the year-
Harris indicts the hacienda for hooking workers into debt. He complains that
workers' pay is docked for days not worked and believes it unjust when a shep-
herd is charged for having "lost" a mule when, in the case at hand, he had traded
the mule, an animal belonging to the hacienda, to a passing American for a
double-barreled shotgun. The Brading review is in Journal of Latin American
Studies, 9 (May 1977), 158.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 47
suggests that there was competition for their labor and that they
had certain cards to play in bargaining with plantations. In place of
force and coercion, wage advances more likely testify to the landown-
ers' lack of extraeconomnic power and their need to play by the rules of
a new and as yet imperfectly functioning labor market.26 The same
thing can be said of the coffee and cacao planters discussed by Deas
and Kaerger or of Herrera, the frustrated Chilean mnayordomo.27
In the case of tenant or permanent workers' debt in the more tradi-
tional haciendas, Herbert Nickel presents a closely reasoned and cau-
tiously interpreted analysis of hacienda and notarial records in the
Tlaxcala-Puebla region during the Porfiriato. Mr. Nickel finds that
calpaneros (permanent residents) were given wage advances or credit
at the hacienda store. At the same time, semaneros (seasonal workers)
were given short-term salary advances as incentive for an agreed upon
task (not to hold them). Toward the end of the Porfiriato there was
a tendency toward standard work contracts, that is, payment for work
done, for all workers. Nickel shows that salary advances or credit to
the service tenantry was only one element in a concerted strategy
which aimed at the systematic blocking of alternatives in order to ob-
tain a constant and reliable work force. The strategy took into ac-
count population size, political strength of the Indian community,
capital investment on the estate, and tenure patterns and ran the gamut
from usurpation of village lands through religious intimidation to ma-
nipulation of bookkeeping. The strategy also included the sale of maize
to permanent workers at rates well below the going market price, im-
proved workers' quarters, and occasional medical care in order to en-
courage the service tenantry to stay on the hacienda.
Mr. Nickel interprets the extension of credit beyond a certain
amount, that is, an amount too great to be assumed by a neighboring
hacendado who might wish to hire the worker, as an "indirect wage
increase." In Tlaxcala-Puebla, the daily wage had been kept constant
at around two reales since the seventeenth century; but in the later
nineteenth, with prices rising, hacendados advanced more credit to
loyal workers. This advance could be withdrawn at any time and pay-
ment in such a form protected landowners because it did not generate
26. Cristobal Kay makes these points in the Bulletin of the Society for Latin
American Studies (Glasgow), no. 25 (Nov. 1976), 81-88. Several writers point
out that debt does not necessarily mean bondage, including Katz in "Labor Condi-
tions," p. 7. William Taylor raises many questions about the conventional view
of peonage in "Haciendas coloniales en el Valle de Oaxaca," in Florescano, ed.,
Haciendas, latifundios, plantaciones, pp. 91-93.
27. Karl Kaerger, Landwirtschaft und Kolonisation im Spanischen Arnerika,
2 vols. (Leipzig, 1901), II, 448-449.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
48 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
a claim for general wage increases. Workers did want more credit
(that is, debt) and in fact, high debt was equated with high status and
conferred prestige. Nickel's research shows that debts were rarely in-
herited; they were often waived upon the worker's death, and many
tenants were reluctant to leave an hacienda for fear of losing their
source of credit in lean times. Service tenants frequently left an ha-
cienda for all the normal reasons: disagreements with foremen, man-
agers, or other workers, or simply for a better opportunity. Although
landowners talked about not hiring a tenant who had left another
estate, in practice they often did. If the worker who left had a debt
against him, the competing hacendado usually reimbursed the previous
employer.28
Arturo Warman's brilliant new book on Morelos fills out the picture
of the privileged position of resident workers, the hijos de la hacienda,
in convincing detail. Usurpation of village lands by the hacienda to-
gether with population growth in the late nineteenth century meant
that men lined up to obtain permanent work on the estates. They were
then eligible for tiny salary advances which were always presented as
a favor, an act of kindness and generosity, on the part of the land-
owner in order to cement ties of authority and dependence. Along with
favors came the implicitly and sometimes brusquely demonstrated
threat of expulsion for sloth or disobedience. The resident workers
were in any case a small minority of the total work force. Most labor
was carried out by village peons hired by the week or task. Here the
landowner did not need to advance credit nor bother with an hacienda
store. The landless peon stood in line and took what he could get in
the form of a money wage: "he was a free worker in the liberal sense
of the word."29
How can the new archival findings be reconciled with the older,
still widely accepted picture of peonage? The role of debt can probably
best be understood by placing it within the larger pattern of labor use
and, especially, by considering the interplay between the landowners'
attempts to gain better control over production on one hand and the
changing values and attitudes of rural people on the other. In figure 1,
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 49
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
50 HAHR I FEBRUARY ARNOLD J. BAUER
asked to pay more and in money; often, however, on account and not
in cash. Finally, where markets were strongest in their influence,
where profitability and calculability were greatest, and where capital
was most easily available, landowners usually attempted, not always
successfully, to transform labor types toward the wage labor pole of the
continuum. Often although not necessarily, a phase was undergone in
which intermediaries such as renters or labor contractors and recruiters
were needed. This latter phase is especially apparent in the years after
1870 and the still incomplete transition to wage labor has come only in
the past few decades.
From approximately 1870 on, a much stronger market was the main
force for change in the internal organization of the hacienda system. As
demand rises for commodities and then for land and labor, the estates
become economically unstable and evolve into different forms, usually
through some sort of family-size rental scheme (including sharecrop-
ping) and toward wage labor.32 In a broad global survey of rural class
relations, Arthur Stinchcombe concluded that family-size rentals and
sharecropping are most likely where: (a) land productivity and market
prices are high; (b) the crop is highly labor intensive and little mech-
anized; (c) labor is cheap; (d) no economies of scale other than in
labor exist; and (e) the period of crop production is less than one
year.33 To these economic features social and historical explanation
may be added. Landowners, for several reasons, may resist the hard
work involved in demesne management or in cases of especially un-
certain crops or weather, they may prefer to let subentrepreneurs share
the risk of farming. And, as mentioned above, landowners may under-
stand that rentals or sharecropping are profitable and consequently see
no point in moving to wage labor.
The effect of market penetration can be seen in the new research on
Spanish America. Malcolm Deas' study of the correspondence files of a
coffee finca shows that this estate let its land to a dozen renters who
put out the coffee trees, weeded and pruned them, grew their own food
on estate land, and then were expected to work for the estate itself for
two weeks of each month for cash. These renters in turn hired dav
32. It is important to notice that this trend is not necessarily sequential, in-
exorable, or the most rational. Recent work suggests the economic efficiency of
self-employed over hired labor under certain conditions. Steven N. S. Cheung,
The Theory of Share Tenancy (Chicago, 1969); see also Martmiez-Alier, Ha-
ciendas, Plantations, pp. 9-10, and Bertram, "New Thinking," pp. 96-102.
33. Arthur Stinchcombe, "Agricultural Enterprises and Rural Class Relations,"
The American Journal of Sociology, 67 (Sept. 1961), 165-176.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 51
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
52 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
A strong market for agricultural commodities in the Guanajuato
mining region and Peruvian demand for Chilean wheat in the eigh-
teenth century also led to systems of rentals and sharecropping similar
to those produced by international demand after 1870. Renters farmed
three-quarters of the fertile Bajlo, and about the same time arrenda-
tario was still the proper term in Chile for fairly well-off tenants who
had not yet been reduced to mere service tenantry or inquilinaje.
What we have in all of these cases is an early stage of response to
modern markets. The turn to sharecroppers and rental tenants makes
sense when we recall that most of the rural people still lived in com-
munities of smallholders, on the move seeking occasional daily work,
or in loose squatter settlements in the interstices of various kinds of
private property. Most of the rural people could not yet be brought
easily into the orbit of the large estate. In the mid-nineteenth century
less than one-third of all Bolivian peasants were attached to the haci-
endas; some seventy percent in Chalco (Valley of Mexico) still lived in
communities in the early nineteenth century; and for all of central
Mexico the figure is probably roughly the same at this time.38 In Peru,
coastal plantation owners must have believed it easier to reach 7,000
miles across the Pacific for laborers rather than attempt to pry them
loose from their own sierra communities.3"
As demand for more labor began to grow, everyone complained of
escasez de brazos (shortage of hands) and not without reason, for both
the villagers and the marginal squatter were disinclined to work for
the remuneration offered especially if, as in the case of villagers, ac-
cess to their own land provided an acceptable way of life. If rental
tenants and sharecroppers provided the haciendas with more income
than before, it was not enough given the enormous possibilities now
apparent as world demand grew, rail and steam lowered freight rates,
and capital became more easily available. The next step taken by
landowners was to apply pressure on the tenants by reducing their
perquisites and pressing for greater labor service while at the same time
negotiating for a larger part of sharecropping arrangements. Follow-
ing this, landowners attempted to gain more direct control over pro-
duction by moving toward wage labor systems.
38. Pearse, "Peasants and Revolution: The Case of Bolivia," part one,
Economy and Society, 1 (Aug. 1972), 257; Tutino, "Hacienda Social Relations,"
pp. 497, 499-500.
39. Jonathan Levin, The Export Economies (Cambridge, Mass., 1960), pp.
85-90. Macera, Las plantaciones azucareras en el Per', 1821-1875 (Lima, 1974),
pp. xc-xcii, examines the choice of Chinese versus peon labor in some detail and
concludes that formally coerced Chinese could be held more closely to the task
than could the hard but irregularly working peon.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 53
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
54 HAHR FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BATER
in the crudest way by the market.41 The purpose of wage-fixing policy
was to fix the maximum, not minimum, rates, and Hobsbawm writes
that not until the last half of the nineteenth century were the laissez
faire rules of the game thoroughly learned.42 Before then, wages were
fixed by customary standard; skilled workers got roughly double that
of unskilled, for example. Employers aimed to hire at the lowest
wage-to pay the lowest total wage bill for a given mass of workers-
on the assumption that more pay would not lead to incentive for greater
output. J. H. Plumb makes the point that it was among the Quaker
industrialists in mid-eighteenth century that this attitude first began
to change, and it is this growing notion that "free" workers, if treated
well, if given incentives and needs, would produce more, that underlies
the innovations of such men as Josiah Wedgwood and Robert Owen
and the abolition of black slavery.43
Given this understanding of the most advanced capitalist economy
in the world, we should not be surprised to find similar ideas expressed
among the eighteenth and nineteenth-century peninsular and creole
elite. The Bishop of Quito was entirely representative of current opin-
ion when he argued in 1797 that the best way "to get esa gente [that
is, the common Ecuadorian peasants] to work, to eliminate their sloth,
reduce their drunkenness and erase the memory of their Yncas," was
to insist on taxation.44 Innumerable examples of this outlook can be
found into the nineteenth century, and although there is no systematic
study of either worker or entrepreneurial mentality, it seems to me
that it is not until the last third of the nineteenth century-that is, a
century after a similar shift had occurred in Western Europe-that
there emerges gradually a new attitude toward the common worker.
Given the prevailing notion that men would work only out of nec-
essity, it naturally followed that needs should be created; and this, in
the later eighteenth and in the nineteenth century, takes two general
forms. In the first place, the colonial devices of tax, clerical fees, and
forced distribution of merchandise were increasingly employed in the
later eighteenth century. The tribute was the most convenient form
of creating obligations and the standard practice was for the entre-
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 55
preneur, hacendado or obrajero, to pay the cash tribute for his workers
while extracting labor service from those liable for the tax.45 All of
these expedients-tribute, fees, forced purchase of merchandise-were
designed to bring the ordinary person into the economy at a time when
the subtle hard-sell consumerism of modern capitalism was unknown,
the wares of city life had not yet penetrated into the hinterland, and
the modern lust for possession had not yet become general. Everyone
complained that workers had exceedingly minimal needs and con-
sequently would not work beyond the point where their bare neces-
sities were satisfied.
The other principal element in the precapitalist strategy was to
deprive potential workers of alternatives to estate labor, or, to put it
another way, to remove restraints in the formation of a free labor mar-
ket. An early feature of the new strategy was the Bourbon assault on
charity or on the kind of welfare which was believed to encourage idle-
ness and sloth. Thus we see in the later eighteenth century an effort
to confine the incorrigible, sweep the streets of mendicant indigents,
put them into workhouses, and limit welfare and alms to the truly de-
serving poor. Some pressure was brought to bear on both the Church
and individuals to reduce the indiscriminate handing out of alms. This
is all standard eighteenth-century fare and its application in America
would make an interesting study, but as yet there is no good recent
work on Spanish America comparable to Callahan's on Spain.46 It
would be easy to overstate the effect of these reforms but we may al-
ready detect here some pressure, whatever the magnitude, directed at
undercutting the floor of self-sufficiency by blocking the alternatives
of workers in order to encourage them to enter the labor market. A
much more effective measure was the nineteenth-century liberal chal-
lenge to the Church which inadvertently weakened charitable and wel-
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
56 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
fare functions in addition to diminishing its economic and political
role. The impact of the liberal reform on welfare has not been mea-
s-ured, but both liberals and Marxists coincide in seeing the reform as
progressive. However the social cost, especially its impact on the
lower classes who had depended on the Church and on the widespread
practice of almsgiving, may have been important. Paradoxically
enough, the hacienda itself may have provided a certain measure of
social welfare by its tolerance of underemployed residents and their
often unproductive dependents.
Much more important in the process of threatening the foundations
of independent peasant existence was the absorption of village lands
by private haciendas. In Mexico beginning in the 1870s, in Guatemala
where the reduction of Indian lands was accompanied by anti-vagrancy
laws, in Bolivia where two-thirds of the rural population became de-
pendent upon haciendas, and in fact throughout the Andean spine, the
resources and means of independent livelihood of a great many rural
people were reduced.47 All of this is a familiar story. The process of
separating peasants from their independent livelihood, which included
access to hacienda land, village lands, or artisanal production, was
rarely carried to the point of complete destitution. Peasant resistance
was a factor in some cases and, where the state was unable or unwill-
ing to put itself squarely on the landowner's side, the costs of expul-
sion or appropriation were too high for individual landowners. Again,
there is also a question of social welfare. The pre-1870 hacienda had
undoubtedly sheltered, fed, and underemployed far more people than
required for production, and because the patron-client relationship
"implied the obligation of the patron to assist his dependents . . . the
hacienda probably had a beneficent r6le."48 The more cost-conscious
landowners understood that village communities and their extended
family networks provided important services for the wage-earning poor
Day laborers on the estates could return to the subsistence sector which
fulfilled functions of social security which the hacienda was less and.
less willing to undertake.49
47. For recent research on Mexico, see Katz, "Labor Conditions," p. 1; John
Coatsworth, "Railroads, Landholding, and Agrarian Protest in the Early Porfiriato,"
HAHR, 54 (Feb. 1974), 55 and passim; David J. McCreery, "Coffee and Class:
The Structure of Development in Liberal Guatemala," HAHR, 56 (Aug. 1976),
456-457; Jean Piel, "The Place of the Peasantry in the National Life of Peru in the
Nineteenth Century," Past and Present, 46 (Feb. 1970), 117-118. Pearse, "Peas-
ants and Revolution," p. 260.
48. Borah, "Social Welfare," p. 51.
49. Claude Meillassoux, "From Reproduction to Production," Economy and
Society, 1 (Feb. 1972), 102, makes this point about South African society, and
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 57
In any case, the more common practice in Spanish America was not
the complete destruction of communities-they still survive every-
where-but the reduction of them to the point where diminished re-
sources forced villagers or their dependents into the labor market.
And of course it was not just the reduction of village lands, but this
combined with population growth which propelled rural people into
the labor market. After the 1940s, the scramble for any kind of job
by millions of landless rural people eliminated labor shortage and
made the previous forms of compulsion unnecessary.
The other side of the question, that is, the change in condition and
attitude of rural people, is more difficult to gauge, and the new
research on individual estates does not help very much. What people
thought or felt about working for others or even for themselves is not
recorded, and so far the scholar with an interest in this kind of men-
tality has not come forward. Workers' attitudes and emotions still must
be inferred either from a careful reading of their employers' opinions
of them or from their own actions.
The change from the natural or seasonal rhythms of ordinary agri-
culture to the more disciplined and timed labor required in industry or
in industrial agriculture has been noticed by students of other societies,
and we may begin, to obtain a frame of reference, with the work of
E. P. Thompson and others around the journal Past and Present.
Thompson describes the natural rhythms of "task oriented" work in
agriculture. Nature demands that the grain be harvested before the
thunderstorms set in, seafaring people must "integrate their lives with
the tides," sheep must be attended to at lambing time and so on.
Thompson then makes three observations: first, that task orientation is
more "humanly comprehensible than timed labor" because the "peas-
ant or laborer appears to attend upon what is an observed necessity."
Second, he notes that "social intercourse and labor are intermingled"
and consequently there is no great sense of conflict between labor and
"passing the time of day." Third, "to men accustomed to labor timed
by the clock, this attitude to labour appears to be wasteful and lack-
ing in energy."50 The innumerable Spanish American travel accounts,
Martinez-Alier points out its relevance for Peru: Haciendas, Plantations, p. 13.
Both the California grower and the state benefit in this sense from migratory labor
across a national frontier: Michoacan peasants work for rock-bottom wages in
California fields and then return to Mexico for whatever social services that country
might supply.
50. E. P. Thompson, "Time, Work-Discipline and Industrial Capitalism," Past
and Present, 38 (Dec. 1967), 56-97, reprinted in M. W. Flinn and T. C. Smout,
eds., Essays in Social History (Oxford, 1974). See also A. W. Coats, "Changing
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
58 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD j. BAUER
written in large part by Anglo-Americans with little rural experience
scornfully decrying sloth, are familiar to us all; and in more recent
times, other features of this impression appear as a new post-industrial
urban generation of young scholars is shocked by the ordinary scene
in any farming society of dawn-to-dusk labor. The distortion and mis-
understanding work both ways: the peasants are "incurably lazy"
when seen in the off-season or on rainy days; and "crushingly ex-
ploited" while only working an ordinary farming day.
Thompson's ideas are not, of course, based on Spanish American
experience but much of what he says is applicable to rural or village
life everywhere. Robson Tyrer's study of the Quito farming and obraje
economy in the seventeenth century, long considered to be one of the
most exploitative and harsh systems in Spanish America, shows that
people probably worked no more than half the days of each year in the
obrajes and during the rest of the time tended their flocks and farmed.5'
Charles Harris writes that many workers in eighteenth-century Coa-
huila worked only two months of the year (although the hacienda fed
them over a full twelve months) .52
Actually, little attention has been paid to the length of the work-
ing day, week or year, either by contemporaries or modern academics.
But as labor demands were stepped up in the 1870s, reproaches against
'St. Monday' (the common practice of taking Monday off) became
more frequent; there were more complaints about absenteeism. In
the 1880s in Chile, a time of strong market demand, workers even dur-
ing the harvest season rarely worked more than twenty days of the
month. In Malcolm Deas' 1900 coffee finca, where the modern de-
vices of fines for tardiness and prizes for production were clearly pres-
ent, the administrator still lamented the lack of discipline or the de-
sire for gain. "I don't understand these people," he confessed, "they're
really 'Indios'; even with a good wage one has to drag them to work."53
Karl Kaerger, with experience in the agriculture of Prussia and Ger-
many, was scornful of the casual and indefinite modes of labor (Un-
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 59
Let us now bring the various elements of our problem into sharper
focus. The scheme below arranges the two principal features in the
argument along vertical and horizontal continua.56 Along the left side
is the range of workers' attitudes, the varying degree of their incentive
toward gain. Implicit here is their changing perception of need and
the acceptance and internalization of discipline. Along the top, rang-
ing from much to little, is the degree of direct control over production
on the part of the large landowners or rural entrepreneurs. Implicit
here are change in capital investment with consequent division and
specialization of labor, the landowners' power to limit or block alterna-
tive ways of life for other rural inhabitants, and the landowners' in-
creasingly rational or profit-maximizing attitude. At one extreme pole
in this scheme, where there is little incentive for gain on the part of
the workers and little control over production by a rural elite, the
historical record generally shows a subsistence economy with little
linkage to the market; the rhythm of work turns around seasonal de-
mand. At the other pole where workers are keen to earn ever more
and landowners have control (the case say, of California agribusiness,
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
60 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
Much Little
. . . t~iLargandowners'd ir control over production,
Much
Little
Tucuman sugar, and the Peruvian coast in the 1950s and 1960s), one
finds a nearly pure wage labor system with overtime pay and bonus
for extra output.
Between these poles are areas of ambiguity and conflict. Where
workers emerge with strong incentive toward gain while landowners
have but little control, smallholders or villagers may hold on to their
land and there are usually varieties of rentals for cash or crop or
sharecropping on the estate. The system of yanaconaje which came
into existence on the Peruvian coast in the late nineteenth century and
endured until heavy capital investment in the late 1940s; the coffee
workers described by Deas; Brading's late eighteenth-century Bajio;
and Bazant's nineteenth century acasillados are all illustrative ex-
amples. As landowners increase their control through expropriation
of village lands or when they benefit from a shift in the labor-to-land
ratio, there is a tendency to reduce renters' perquisites, increase labor
requirements, and eventually move to a wage labor system. Obviously,
local or national political support is important in this process; without
either, the transition to wage labor remains only a goal. Martinez-
Alier's studies show how unsuccessful the attempt was in a number
of highland Peruvian haciendas where neither the Cerro de Pasco
corporation nor the Fernandini corporation had sufficient control to
expel tenants.
The greatest conflict in our scheme comes when the market rather
quickly opens enormous opportunities for landowners-through, for
example, overseas demand, new domestic markets, the introduction of
rail or new roads, or new sources of capital-while there is still a gen-
eral resistance to wage labor and where precapitalist attitudes are still
the rule. As landowners' control increases, they first, as we have seen,
put the screws to the service tenantry and sharecroppers. Increasing-
ly however, others, including villagers and the rootless or casual work-
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 61
er. must also be brought into the production process. How is the land-
owner to make the wage mechanism work? Advertisements al-e put
in papers, but the word is slowly and imperfectly spread and only a
few workers appear at the gates of the new sugar central or sisal
plantation. Or, if they do appear, they work only to cover their own
needs (defined by them very modestly) and then disappear, or they
return for village fiestas or to work their own fields. One measure
of how unresponsive or inconstant rural people were to wage offers
can be seen in the price paid for Chinese laborers. In Cuba and Peru
between 1847-1874, over a quarter of a million Chinese were employed
at a cost of $340 to $500 each. 57 It is at this point-in the interstices be-
tween subsistence and rental arrangements at one pole and wage labor
at the other-where other devices and mechanisms are employed by the
landowners to obtain a work force. The power of landowners to block
alternatives and their reluctant but eventual willingness to pay suf-
ficiently high wages for higher quality labor (the United Fruit Com-
pany early initiated this practice) did bring workers into the wage
labor market.58 But where the demand for labor was especially strong
and potential workers dragged their heels, more direct measures were
used. Landowners hired labor contractors or enganchadores whom
they paid as much as twenty percent of the wage bill for recruitment,
transportation, and labor management. The contractors often found it
necessary to give part of the total salary in advance to potential work-
ers; in other cases landowners extended credit during slack times or
charged corn rations, merchandise or even clerical services against
a tenant's or worker's account.
Until recent years, most students and observers have assumed that
debt meant bondage. Because of this assumption and because the
sources then available did not reveal the inner workings of rural
estates, we have by and large an unreal and one-dimensional picture
of rural society. New research based on sources closer to social reality
now provides a basis for reevaluation. An explanatory context of course
is still fundamental. To help with this, I have suggested the possibility
of examining the change in values which occurred in the transition from
noncapitalist to capitalist forms of agriculture.
From about 1870 onward, because of capital investment and tech-
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
62 HAHR I FEBRUARY I ARNOLD J. BAUER
nological change there was in many regions of Spanish America a
fundamental change in the way men made their living. Alongside
the quickening pace of economic life, the majority of rural people still
lived a quiet existence, their attitudes toward work shaped by the
rhythms of ordinary agriculture and the limited economic horizons of
village life. The consequent disjunction between the demand and sup-
ply of labor brought about conflict and accommodation. A great many
rural people were wrenched out of one social and mental world and
ended up in another.
The years 1870-1930 represented a transition which in many ways
is analogous to the period a century earlier in Great Britain and West-
ern Europe. During these sixty years, landowners and rural entre-
preneurs managed, gradually and incompletely, to tighten their con-
trol over production. This was done only rarely with the kind of
Draconian measures described in Barbarous Mexico, or by the Ameri-
can envoy in Veracruz, or the novels of Ciro Alegria or Jorge Icaza.59
More commonly labor contractors, enganchadores, paternalistic mea-
sures, wage increases, wage advances, and in rare cases debt bondage
were used to obtain the kind of labor needed by new types of planta-
tions and haciendas.6? Reliable and productive workers were de-
manded at a time when rural people were not yet fully responsive to
wage incentive; when, in other words, a free labor market did not yet
exist. All of the landowners' devices were accompanied by only par-
tially successful efforts to block alternatives to wage labor. Most of
the new research is consistent in its rejection of debt as a controlling
feature of labor. The closer we get to social reality, to the everyday
workings of society, the better we understand that rural people are
not merely passive victims; rather, they make choices, work out of self-
interest. They and landowners alike make compromises and strike
accommodations which are often mutually beneficial. To be sure,
the world within which the relatively powerless make choices is nar-
rowly limited and, in some cases, the indirect limitation of choice
comes dangerously close to direct coercion.
By the 1940s, new labor habits were formed, men were alienated
from their work, and the values appropriate to a smoothly working
wage labor system became more common. This process is not yet
59. John Kenneth Turner, Barbarous Mexico (Austin, 1969); John Lind's re-
port of virtual slavery is quoted in Katz, "Labor Conditions," p. 16.
60. The strategy of pressure and persuasion undertaken by Tucumaln planta-
tions is discussed by Jorge Balan in a valuable article, "Migraciones, mano de obra
y formacion de un proletariado rural en Tucuman, Argentina, 1870-1914," Demo-
grafla y Economia, 10:2 (1976), 201-235, especially 217-228.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
RURAL WORKERS IN SPANISH AMERICA 63
complete. In those areas where labor was not needed, where markets
were weak, where capital was not attracted, pockets of rural people
were by-passed. But everywhere else we can see the breakdown of
community, the creation of a rootless and alienated mass, and the
triumph of the consumer society. For having accelerated this integra-
tion of rural people into modern economic life, we may thank the mod-
ernizing landowner, the effective contratista, and the rural workers'
own capacity for spiritual self-destruction.
This content downloaded from 164.77.114.99 on Fri, 12 Jul 2019 14:23:29 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms