Adam Smith Selections From The Wealth of Nations, 1776 Book I, Chapter 1. of The Division of Labor: THE Greatest
Adam Smith Selections From The Wealth of Nations, 1776 Book I, Chapter 1. of The Division of Labor: THE Greatest
Adam Smith Selections From The Wealth of Nations, 1776 Book I, Chapter 1. of The Division of Labor: THE Greatest
I have seen a small manufactory of this kind where ten men only were employed, and
where some of them consequently performed two or three distinct operations. But
though they were very poor, and therefore but indifferently accommodated with the
necessary machinery, they could, when they exerted themselves, make among them
about twelve pounds of pins in a day. There are in a pound upwards of four thousand
pins of a middling size. Those ten persons, therefore, could make among them upwards
of forty-eight thousand pins in a day. Each person, therefore, making a tenth part of
forty-eight thousand pins, might be considered as making four thousand eight hundred
pins in a day. But if they had all wrought separately and independently, and without any
of them having been educated to this peculiar business, they certainly could not each of
them have made twenty, perhaps not one pin in a day.
Book I, Chapter 2. Of the Principle which gives occasion to the Division of Labor:
THIS division of labor, from which so many advantages are derived, is not originally the
effect of any human wisdom, which foresees and intends that universal opulence to
which it gives occasion. It is the necessary, though very slow and gradual consequence
of a certain propensity in human nature which has in view no such extensive utility; the
propensity to truck, barter, and exchange one thing for another... Man has almost
constant occasion for the help of his brethren, and it is in vain for him to expect it from
their benevolence only. He will be more likely to prevail if he can interest their self-love
in his favor, and show them that it is for their own advantage to do for him what he
requires of them. Whoever offers to another a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this.
Give me that which I want, and you shall have this which you want, is the meaning of
Adam Smith, excerpts from The Wealth of Nations
every such offer; and it is in this manner that we obtain from one another the far greater
art of those good offices which we stand in need of. It is not from the benevolence of
the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to
their own interest.
As it is by treaty, by barter, and by purchase that we obtain from one another the
greater part of those mutual good offices which we stand in need of, so it is this same
trucking disposition which originally gives occasion to the division of labor. In a tribe of
hunters or shepherds a particular person makes bows and arrows, for example, with
more readiness and dexterity than any other. He frequently exchanges them for cattle or
for venison with his companions; and he finds at last that he can in this manner get
more cattle and venison than if he himself went to the field to catch them. From a
regard to his own interest, therefore, the making of bows and arrows grows to be his
chief business, and he becomes a sort of armorer, etc...
Book I, Chapter 5. Of the Real and Nominal Price of Commodities, or their Price in
Labor, and their Price in Money: EVERY man is rich or poor according to the degree in
which he can afford to enjoy the necessaries, conveniences, and amusements of human
life. But after the division of labor has once thoroughly taken place, it is but a very small
part of these with which a man's own labor can supply him. The far greater part of them
he must derive from the labor of other people, and he must be rich or poor according to
the quantity of that labor which he can command, or which he can afford to purchase.
The value of any commodity, therefore, to the person who possesses it, and who means
not to use or consume it himself, but to exchange it for other commodities, is equal to
the quantity of labor which it enables him to purchase or command. Labor, therefore, is
the real measure of the exchangeable value of all commodities...
Book I, Chapter 8. Of the Wages of Labor: THE produce of labor constitutes the
natural recompense or wages of labor. In that original state of things, which precedes
both the appropriation of land and the accumulation of stock, the whole produce of
labor belongs to the laborer. He has neither landlord nor master to share with him. …
But this original state of things, in which the laborer enjoyed the whole produce of his
own labor, could not last beyond the first introduction of the appropriation of land and
the accumulation of stock. … As soon as land becomes private property, the landlord
demands a share of almost all the produce which the laborer can either raise, or collect
from it. His rent makes the first deduction from the produce of the labor which is
employed upon land. Masters are always and everywhere in a sort of tacit, but constant
and uniform combination, not to raise the wages of labor above their actual rate.…
A man must always live by his work, and his wages must at least be sufficient to
maintain him. They must even upon most occasions be somewhat more; otherwise it
would be impossible for him to bring up a family, and the race of such workmen could
not last beyond the first generation.... No society can surely be flourishing and happy, of
which the far greater part of the members are poor and miserable. It is but equity,
besides, that they who feed, clothe, and lodge the whole body of the people, should
SUSAN E. GALLAGHER, HISTORY OF POLITICAL THOUGHT, POLITICAL SCIENCE DEPT, UMASS LOWELL 2
Adam Smith, excerpts from The Wealth of Nations
have such a share of the produce of their own labor as to be themselves tolerably well
fed, clothed, and lodged.
SUSAN E. GALLAGHER, HISTORY OF POLITICAL THOUGHT, POLITICAL SCIENCE DEPT, UMASS LOWELL 3