Macro Assignment
Macro Assignment
Macro Assignment
An Overview
Lemi Taye
2 Literature Review
1
elastic, and an increase in the rate of interest will have stronger effects of increasing the
marginal propensity to save than discouraging investment (Johnson, 2015; Tiriongo, 2005).
In this theory, the level of investment is constrained by the volume of savings available.
This theory assumes full employment in the economy and therefore the level of income is
exogenous. It also assumes full employment in the economy and therefore the level of income
is exogenous (Tiriongo, 2005).
According to the Keynesian savings framework, savings is a stable and increasing function
of the level of income (Ting, 2013; Tiriongo, 2005). Keynes envisaged the marginal propensity
to save to be governed by what he called objective and subjective factors, and included such
factors as the rate of interest, social and institutional changes, and subjective motives for
savings (Tiriongo, 2005). Keynes (1936) postulated that the average propensity to consume
falls as income rises. This suggests that the average propensity to save, also known as
the saving rate, which is the ratio of saving to disposable income, should rise with income
(Mishkin, 2014). However, this was later challenged by an empirical anomaly which came to
be known as the Kuznets paradox (Parker, 2011; Mankiw, 2015). Keynes (1936) also argued
that saving is not so responsive to interest (Johnson, 2015).
The relative-income hypothesis, described by James Duesenberry (1949), was an attempt
to address the Kuznets paradox. He argued that a households consumption would depend not
just on its own current level of income, but on its income relative to those in the subgroup
of the population with which it identifies itself. The household will attempt to align its
consumption expenditures with those of other members of its group. Thus, households with
lower income within the group will consume a larger share of their income to keep up, while
households with high incomes relative to the group will save more and consume less (Parker,
2011).
The life cycle hypothesis, mainly due to Modigliani and Ando (1957, 1963), posits that
consumption and saving reflect an individual’s stage in the life cycle, which is generally
proxied by age. Since retirement, for most people, is the most substantial and enduring
income fluctuation, this model emphasizes saving for retirement as a primary motivation for
deferred consumption (Beverly and Sherraden, 1999; Mishkin, 2014). The prediction of this
model is that there should be a relation between aggregate saving and the rates of population
growth and income growth. If saving is accumulated during the working years to finance
retirement, as the hypothesis suggests, then population growth provides more savers than
dissevers, and positive aggregate saving (Deaton, 1989).
Friedman (1957) proposed the permanent income hypothesis which originates from the
basic intuition that individuals would wish to smooth consumption and not let it fluctuate
with short run fluctuations in income. This suggests that an individual’s consumption in
a given period is determined not by income in that period, but by permanent or lifetime
income (Meghir, 2004; Romer, 2011). According to this hypothesis observed differences in
household saving and consumption are believed to reflect, in part, differences in the relative
shares of transitory and permanent income. In other words, when an individual experiences
an increase in income that she perceives as temporary, she is expected to save, rather than
consume, this money (Beverly and Sherraden, 1999). Another implication of this hypothesis
for saving is that people save because they rationally expect their labor income to decline
2
and thus saving can be a predictor of declines in labor income (Campbell, 1986).
3
a substantial fluctuation in aggregate savings to GDP ratio was observed. Economic and
demographic factors, and measures of financial sector development were considered in the
study. The results showed that aggregate savings is significantly determined by the current
account deficit, the ratio of M2 money1 to gross domestic product, real per capita income
growth, deposit rate and the old age dependency ratio.
Nwachukwu and Odigie (2011) employed an error correction model to examine the deter-
minants of private saving in Nigeria for the period between 1970 and 2007. The framework
of their analysis involves the estimation of a saving rate function derived from the life cycle
hypothesis while recognizing the structural characteristics of a developing economy. The
result shows that the saving rate rises with both the growth rate of disposable income and
the real interest rate on bank deposits. They also found that public saving does not seem to
crowd out private saving with the implication that government policies aimed at improving
the fiscal balance have the potential of bringing about a substantial increase in the national
saving rate in Nigeria.
1
The M2 monetary aggregate includes currency and demand deposits (together called M1), plus savings
deposits and several less liquid asset types, such as money market deposit accounts and money market
mutual fund shares with check-writing features.
4
3 Data and Discussion
In the world we live in today, significant differences in saving rates can be found between
countries. One can observe differences even in broad classifications of countries according to
their income status. Figure 1 shows the gross saving rates of low income, middle income and
high income countries. Although the data for low income countries is not complete (data is
missing for the years before 1990), it can be seen that their saving rate is fairly low, while
middle and high income countries tend to save more. It also shows that the gap in saving
rates between middle and high income countries has widened since the early 2000s.
Figure 1: Gross Domestic Saving Rates in high, middle and low income countries
So this begs the question: what caused such huge gap in saving rates among countries?
One factor that has been proposed is the rate of per capita income growth. Figure 2 illustrates
the relationship between saving and growth of real GDP per capita for a sample of 84
countries.2 It implies a positive correlation between growth and saving. However, correlation
does not imply causation, meaning we cannot infer whether high saving drives growth or
high income growth leads to high rates of saving.
In the neoclassical growth models (Solow (1956) and Swan (1956)) saving is an important
determinant of growth. That is countries with high rates of saving (and investment) will have
high incomes and vice versa. But recent literature has focused on the simultaneity between
growth and saving, that is, the level of growth may itself affect the saving rate. The primary
2
See Adema (2015), Section 3.2.
5
studies to support the proposition that the rate of growth of per capita income affects the
saving rate were Left (1969) and Modigliani (1970) (cited in Gersovitz, 1988). Ram (1982)
provides the strongest evidence that per capita income has a significant effect on the saving
rate. A relatively recent study by Carroll and Weill (1994) indicates that economic growth
causes domestic saving, but not vice versa.
6
Figure 3: Rate of Gross Domestic Savings and Growth of GDP in Ethiopia
In parallel with the increase in domestic savings, the rate of gross national savings also
reached 32.4 percent in 2015/16. The difference between the two rates was mostly covered
by net current transfer from the rest of the world. In GTP II, resource mobilization from the
domestic private savings and government revenue have been identified as a core component
of financing the development goal. In the last five years, savings have been mobilized mainly
through the government housing scheme and the Grand Renaissance Dam Bond (EEA, 2017).
Other than these forced saving mechanisms policy instruments such as the interest rate were
found to have an insignificant impact on aggregate domestic saving (Getnet, 2017; Haile,
2013).
7
4 Conclusions and Policy Implications
Saving is an important instrument to enhance economic growth by providing sufficient funds
for investment. The importance of saving for growth has been emphasized by neoclassical and
new growth theories. Given the crucial role saving plays to bring about growth in income,
many theories have been proposed to explain what determines saving. The important ones
include the absolute income hypothesis of Keynes (1936), Modigliani’s (1950s) life cycle
hypothesis, and Friedman’s (1957) permanent income hypothesis.
Empirical evidences on the determinants saving in developing countries have identified
many variables that affect aggregate domestic saving. Many studies suggest that growth in
income has a positive and significant effect on saving. In addition, demographic factors such
as the dependency ratio, developments in the financial sector, fiscal policy and budget deficit
were found to affect saving. However, the results for inflation and interest rates are mixed.
Interest rates do not seem to have a significant impact on saving in developing countries.
Several policy implications can be drawn from these analyses. As growth in income is
the primary determinant of saving, efforts has to be made to raise the level of income in
a sustainable manner. Moreover, the budget deficit has to be kept at fairly manageable
levels since it adversely affects growth of saving. There is also a role for prudent fiscal and
monetary policy to encourage private saving. Finally there is a need to urgently develop
the financial sector of the country by further expanding bank branches and services and by
creating a very competitive environment in the financial sector.
8
References
Balassa, B. (1989). The effect of interest rate on savings in developing countries. World
Bank Working Paper No. 56.
Carroll, C. D., and Weil, D. N. (1994). Saving and growth: a reinterpretation. In Carnegie-
Rochester conference series on public policy (Vol. 40, pp. 133-192). North-Holland.
Deaton, A. (1989). Saving in developing countries: Theory and review. The World Bank
Economic Review, 3(suppl 1), 61-96.
EEA (2017). Report on the Ethiopian economy: Challenges of sustaining Ethiopias for-
eign exchange earnings from exports and remittances. Addis Ababa, Ethiopian Economics
Association.
Getnet G. (2017). Trends and Determinants of Gross Domestic Saving in Ethiopia. Journal
of Economics and Sustainable Development, 8(5), 72-81.
Loayza, N., Schmidt-Hebbel, K., and Servn, L. (2000a). What drives private saving across
the world? The Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(2), 165-181.
Loayza, N., Schmidt-Hebbel, K., and Servn, L. (2000b). Saving in developing countries:
an overview. The World Bank Economic Review, 14(3), 393-414.
9
Masson, P. R., Bayoumi, T., and Samiei, H. (1998). International evidence on the de-
terminants of private saving. The World Bank Economic Review, 12(3), 483-501.
Mishkin, F. S. (2014). Macroeconomics: Policy and Practice, 2nd Edition (Pearson Se-
ries in Economics). Prentice Hall.
Nwachukwu, T. E., and Odigie, P. (2011). What drives private saving in Nigeria? African
Economic Research Consortium, Nairobi.
Perkins, D. H., Radelet, S., Lindauer, D. L., and Steven, A. Block. (2013). Economics
of Development. W. W. Norton & Co.
Ram, R. (1982). Dependency rates and aggregate savings: a new international cross-section
study. The American Economic Review, 72(3), 537-544.
Romer, D. (2011). Advanced Macroeconomics, 4th Edition. McGrew Hill Higher Educa-
tion.
Swan, T. W. (1956). Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic record, 32(2),
334-361.
Ting, L. (2013). Savings and Poverty: Is there really a link? (First working draft for
submission to the ESSA conference). University of Johannesburg.
10