Chapter Page

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 56

CHAPTER - I

INTRODUCTION

1.1 Background of the Study


Inflation means a persistent and appreciable rise in the general price level in the
economy over time. A modest level of inflation is considered to be desirable because
it creates positive effect on investment, production and employment. Maintaining low
and sustainable inflation brings stability to financial systems and encourages
sustainable economic growth over the longer run (Fergusson, 2005). However, High
and variable Inflation is a worldwide macroeconomic problem that leads to
unpredictability in income and expenditure decisions of the different groups of the
society; deforms economic growth; reduces savings and investments; and rises cost of
capital and exacerbates the income inequality in society (NRB, 2007). High inflation
adversely impacts the overall growth of the economy, generating motivations for
households and firms to curtail their horizons and to spend resources in handling
inflation risk rather than directing on the most productive activities (Iqbal, Nadim &
Akbar, 2022). One of the main objectives of both developed and developing
economies is, therefore, to attain a moderate level of inflation (Tufail & Batool,
2013). The major factors that determine inflation in the economy are broad money
supply, budget deficit, imported prices from international trade, gross domestic
product and exchange rate of country’s currency.

Money supply has a direct and proportional relation with inflation assuming the level
of real output is constant and the velocity of money is constant (Fishers, 1911). This is
because when the money supply increases, it puts more money into the hands of both
consumers and producers, consequently generates consumption and investment
(Amassoma et al., 2018). Furthermore, as the money supply keeps expanding, prices
of goods and services tend to rise, particularly when the growth of output reaches full
employment. Monetarists, believe that the money supply is the main determinant of
economic growth in the short run and the price level over longer periods. Inflation is
always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon and it occurs in the economy when
the rate of growth of the money supply exceeds the growth rate of the real aggregate
output in the economy (Friedman, 1963). Because of the inflationary consequences
associated with excessive expansion of money supply, Friedman (1963) asserted that
1
monetary policy should be done by targeting the growth rate of the money supply to
maintain economic and price stability.

Inflation occurs through money supply if the government adopts deficit budget. If the
government finances a deficit budget either by printing of money by the contra bank
or through the open market operations, both of the measures change the nominal
money supply in an economy and therefore change the price level (Duodu et al.,
2022). Higher deficit policies may lead to higher inflation even in the absence of
monetization by Central banks due to following two reasons (Ackay et al., 1996).
First, the government's need to borrow typically raises the overall demand for credit in
the economy, causing interest rates to rise and crowding out private investment. As a
consequence, the economy's growth rate is likely to decrease, leading to a reduction in
the quantity of goods available at a given level of cash holdings and consequently
causing an uptick in the price level. Such actions alter the nominal money supply
within an economy, consequently leading to changes in the overall price level. The
other channel through which deficits can lead to higher inflation when Central Banks
do not monetize the debt is the private monetization of deficits. This occurs when the
high interest rates induce the financial sector to develop new interest-bearing assets
that are almost as liquid as money and are risk free. Thus, the government debt not
monetized by the Central Bank is monetized by the private sector and the inflationary
effects of higher deficit policies prevail.

Keynes believes that excessive demand causes inflation in an economy. He also


further adds that money supply may create inflation but true inflation starts only after
full-employment. Moreover, the Keynesians argue also that organized labor pressures
on government pushes wages up, and when not matched with output levels creates
inflationary pressures. On the other hand, the Structuralists claim that inflation in
underdeveloped and developing countries occurs due to structural characteristics of an
economy such as structural rigidities, unproductive government interventions, and
political interferences in these economies. The fiscal theory of the price level (FTPL),
alternatively referred to as the quantity theory of government debt, examines how
budget deficits impact the overall price level through mechanisms distinct from those
in the monetarist perspective (Duodu et al., 2022).

The attention of researchers and policy makers in different economies have been
captured to conduct empirical examinations of the dynamics outlined by these

2
theories due to the diverse views among these school of thoughts. This is done to
ensure that suitable measures or policies are implemented to control inflation
effectively. The conflicting propositions made by these theories have consequently
motivated numerous researchers to conduct empirical investigations into the causal
relationships among money supply, budget deficits, and inflation in both developing
and developed countries. Considering this, numerous scholars have conducted
comprehensive examinations of the connection between money supply, budget
deficits, and inflation in both developing and developed nations, yielding varied
outcomes (Neupane, 1992; Khatiwada, 1994; Mathema,1998; Chaudhary and Xiumin,
2018; Kovanen, 2011; Adu & Marbuah, 2011; Nasir et al., 2020; Nguyen, 2015;
Duodu et al., 2022 Byanjankar (2020; Pandey, 2005; Poudyal, 2014; IMF, 2014;
NRB, 2007).

Statistical data from the Ministry of Finance of Nepal shows that Nepal has
persistently faced budget deficits since 1974.The average ratio of budget deficits to
GDP from FY 1974/ 75 to 2021/22 remains 6.97 percent. One of the fundamental
reasons why budget deficits have increased in recent years is that the Nepalese
government wanted to boost the economy by raising expenditures. The highest ratio
of budget ratio to GDP was recorded in FY 1982/83 which was 12.25 percent.
Adoption of such budget deficit has contributed to rise inflation. The statistical data
shows that the average inflation rate of Nepal from FY 1974/75 to 2021/22 has
remained 8.11 percent. The lowest rate of inflation was recorded in FY 1975/76
which was -0.69 percentage while the largest rate of inflation was recorded in FY
1991/92 which was 21.05 percent. Moreover, carefully examining at the dynamics of
money supply, it can be observed that money supply has continuously increased since
FY 1974/75. On an average, the growth rate of money supply has been approximately
18.39 percent since 1974.

The statistical data of Nepal shows that inflation has not been stable since 1974.
Inflation may occur in the economy due to various factors. Therefore, the study tests
the validity of classical theory, monetarist theory and the fiscal theory of the price
level in the context of Nepal. This study analyzes the impact of money supply and
deficit budget on inflation in Nepal in both short-run and long-run. The reason for
focusing primarily on the long run relationship is because the short run relationship
may not be sufficient (though necessary) for effective policy discourse and therefore

3
could render policies unsuccessful in an economy. This study also finds out the
current status of money supply, budget deficit and inflation in Nepal. Autoregressive
Distributed Lag Model is used to examine short-run and long-run relationship
between money supply, budget deficit and inflation.

1.2 Statement of the Problem


The issue of inflation has consistently captured the attention of numerous researchers
in the field of economics as it influences major decisions such as investment,
consumption and savings among others (Duodu et al., 2022). Additionally, inflation
can lead to the failure of important policies or projects because it disrupts budget
allocation, ultimately hindering the economic progress. Considering the adverse
consequences of inflation is likely to have on economies as well as the livelihood and
welfare of citizens, the dynamics of inflation, money supply and budget deficit have
continuously received attention from both theoretically and empirical perspectives
(Adom et al., 2018).
In the context of Nepal, successive governments have made efforts to maintain a
single digit as well as stable inflation rate with the aim of improving the wellbeing of
citizens and boosting savings and investment decisions in the economy. However,
these efforts have proven unsuccessful, as the inflation rate in the economy continues
to fluctuate and remains near to double digits. The inflation rate of Nepal was 12.6
percent in 2008/09. This rate had decreased and reached to 8.3 percent in 2011/12.
This rate had again increased and reached to 9.9 in 2012/13. Again, this rate had
decreased to 7.2 percent in 2014/15 and increased to 9.9 in 2015/16. This rate had fall
drastically to 4.2 percent in 2016/17 and remained stable until 2018/19. Again, this
rate increased to 6.1 percent in 2019/20. In 2021/22, it has remained at 6.3 percent.
This clearly shows that inflation has not been stable and hence could badly affect
major economic decisions.

Different scholars employ different methods to describe the phenomenon of inflation.


Due to the complexity and uncertainty of inflation, different theories have been
formed according to the influential factors of inflation (Wang, Wang, & Skare 2022).
Price stability is the prime objective of monetary policy. Inflation may occur as a
result of increasing budget deficit and money supply in the economy. It is not possible
to carry out effective policy without understanding the relationship between inflation,
money supply and budget deficit. Therefore, it is necessary to study the relationships

4
between these variables in order to formulate correct policies regarding in Nepal. In
this context, there are some pertinent questions regarding rational of analyzing the
relationship between broad money supply, budget deficit and inflation.
a) What is the current status of broad money supply, budget deficit and inflation
in Nepal?
b) Is there short-run and long-long significant relationship between money
supply and budget deficit with inflation in Nepal?

1.3 Objectives of the Study


The main objective of the study is to analyze the relationship between broad money
supply, budget deficit and inflation in Nepal. However, the specific objectives of the
study are as follows:
a) To analyze the current status of inflation in Nepal, broad money supply, budget
deficit, Real GDP, nominal effective exchange rate, and Indian inflation.
b) To examine the short-run and long-run relationship between broad money
supply and budget deficit with inflation in Nepal.

1.4 Hypothesis of the Study


Null Hypothesis (Ho): There is no short-run and long-run significant relationship
between money supply and budget deficit with inflation.
Alternative Hypothesis (H1): There is a short-run and long-run significant relationship
between money supply and budget deficit with inflation.

1.5 Significance of the Study


Money supply and budget deficit are the important determinants of inflation. Increase
in both money supply and budget deficit increases the general price level in an
economy. The economist who follows the monetarist school of thought contends that
the money supply plays a more significant role in driving inflation. Likewise, budget
deficit is the cause of inflation in an economy through money supply. Inflation is a
pressing concern in the field of economics due to its potential to significantly impact
the overall economy. It poses detrimental effects on both developing and developed
economies, and several nations have experienced collapse as a result of
hyperinflation. Inflation disrupts the smooth functioning of the economy. This
research aims to investigate the connection between the money supply, budget deficit
and inflation within the context of Nepal.

5
This study can contribute to the existing economic literature in the context where
theories and existing literatures have given mixed and conflicting results about the
relationship between inflation, money supply and budget deficit. Furthermore, from a
practical standpoint, the contribution and findings of this study would be supportive to
the government and policy makers in terms of helping them to understand the
influence of money supply on inflation as well as building policies that will make
ensure stability and sustainable development in the country.

1.6 Limitations of the Study


a. The outcome of the study depends upon the validity of secondary data.
b. Only data of 48 years from the fiscal year1974/75 to 2021/22 will be used in
the study.
c. Although there are many methods of examining co-integration between
variables, this study will only be employed ARDL Bounds test approach to co-
integration. Therefore, the conclusions drawn by this study may not be
matched with the conclusions drawn by the study which used another
methodology.
d. Due to non-availability of monthly and quarterly data, this study uses only
annual data which may lead fewer dynamic results than other studies.

1.7 Outline of the Study


The study is divided into five chapters. The first chapter is introductory. This chapter
includes background of the study, statement of the problem, objectives of the study,
significance of the study and the limitations of the study. The second chapter is
review of the literature that includes theoretical, empirical review and research gap.
The third chapter is research methodology. It including research design, conceptual
framework, nature and sources of data, study period covered, tools and methods of
data collection, data organization and processing, tools and methods of data analysis,
model specification, description of variables and model and econometric test. The
fourth chapter is the body part of the study. This chapter analyzes the trend and
empirical analysis of money supply, budget deficit and inflation in Nepal. Moreover,
this chapter is divided in to trend analysis and descriptive statistics as well as
empirical analysis. Finally, the fifth chapter gives a glimpse of summary of findings,
conclusion and recommendations of research findings.

6
CHAPTER - II
REVIEW OF LITERATURE

This section presents a brief review of theories as well as earlier studies on money
supply, budget deficit and inflation nexus. This section is divided into three parts viz.
theoretical literature review, empirical literature review and research gap.

2.1 Theoretical Review


Several theories related to the effects of money supply and budget deficit on inflation
have emerged in monetary economics. This section has reviewed some of the notable
theories of inflation.
2.1.1 Classical Theory
The quantity theory of money developed by Classical and neoclassical economists
believe that if money supply is increased in full employment situation where money
plays as a means of transaction only, it only increases price level in the economy. The
quantity theory of money can be explained by the following equation:
MV = PT
Where, M is money supply; V is the velocity of money, which is the measure
of number of times one unit of money crosses the hands from one transaction to
another; P is the general price level; and T represents the real volume of transactions.
In classical system, both V and T are assumed to be constant in the short run and
hence the above equation of exchange can be rewritten to yield a price equation for
the economy as follows:
MV
P=
T
This equation shows that price level is directly proportional to the money supply.

2.1.2 Monetarist Hypothesis


The monetarist theory, akin to the classical theory, relies on the quantity theory of
money, which claims that the price level is influenced by the nominal money supply.
The monetarists argue that the equality between desired level of real balances and the
purchasing power of the money supply at any given level of nominal money supply
determines the general price level. Inflation occurs due to the deviation of nominal
money supply from the desired real balances at given any price level. The monetarists

7
further argue that deficit budget is the cause of inflation through money supply. This
is because the deficit budget is financed either through printing of money by the
central bank or through the open market operations. Both of them changes the money
supply in an economy and hence changes in the price level. According to the
monetarists, the QTM implies that inflation is always, everywhere a monetary and
demand side phenomenon. Inflation is, therefore, always and everywhere a monetary
phenomenon (Friedman, 1963).

2.1.3 Fiscal Theory of the Price Level


The fiscal theory of the price level (FTPL) also known as the quantity theory of
government debt analyzes how fiscal (budget) deficit feeds through general price
level in different mechanism other than that of the monetarist approach. The FTPL
considers the government’s inter-temporal budget constraint (GBC) as an instrument
that links both fiscal and monetary policies. According to the FTPL, the GBC is at
equilibrium when the discounted value of the government’s future primary surplus
(which includes seignior age as a revenue source) is greater than (equal to) the current
nominal value of the government (public) debt, which considers the monetary base.
The proponents opine that the discount rate is measured by the ratio of real interest
rate to the growth rate of the economy. The FTPL assumes that the future path of
revenues and primary expenditures is determined exogenously by fiscal authority. The
theory further argues that, at a given discount rate, the price level will rise to
equilibrate the GBC condition anytime the discounted value of primary surplus is
lower than the value of nominal public debt. Therefore, price is the only adjustment
variable to maintain equilibrium condition in the GBC.

To understand how the price level is affected by fiscal policy, Woodford (1995)
suggests that a positive and exogenous price shock reduces the value of government
debt (liabilities) owed to private individuals who have purchased or invested in
government securities which in turn lowers their wealth as well as demand for goods.
The FTPL theory postulates that, when this happens, the individual’s expectations
with respect to the sustainability of fiscal policy will generate similar wealth-effect. If
the market recognizes a negative perception about the sustainability of public finances
(when discounted value of government primary surplus deviate from the nominal
value of government liabilities), such negative perception will trigger an increase in
the level of price to a higher level required to equalize the GBC. This higher price

8
lowers the value of private assets, which generates the abovementioned wealth-effect.
Therefore, higher government debt (liabilities) generates higher distortion, and hence,
higher prices are required to restore the GBC. The implication is that budget deficit
causing long run inflation with money supply playing no role may establish a strong
backing for the FTPL as indicated by Lozano-Espitia and Lozano-Espitia (2008).

2.1.4 Keynesian Approach


The Keynesian approach to determination of inflation is subjected to excessive
demand dominations, which assumes that the economy is at full employment. Keynes
argues that firms generate more profit at a fixed nominal wages when there exists
excess demand at full employment level. As result, firms demand for labour increases
with the aim of meeting the growing demand in the economy, which in turn leads to
higher wages paid by firms. As documented by Kotwal (1987) and Frisch (1989)), the
higher wages increase the general price level as cost of production increases and
hence inflation arise.

2.1.5 Demand-pull Theory of Inflation


According to this theory, when aggregate demand increases the available supply
cannot meet the increased demand. So, the price of goods and services will rise and
demand-pull inflation occurs. According to this theory, inflation is generated by
pressure of excess demand of goods and services for the available supply in the
economy, especially when the economy approaches to the full employment level. If
aggregate demand rises, the multiplier effect of the increase in aggregate demand
becomes disabled due to supply constraint and hence the only way to clear the goods
market is through raising the money prices of the goods.
The main causes of increase in aggregate demand are the following - some are related
with Keynesians and others with Monetarists:
 Depreciation or devaluation of the exchange rate: This increases the price of imports
and reduces the foreign price of economy's exports. If consumers buy fewer imports
while foreigners buy more exports; or if export is more elastic than imports, the
aggregate demand in the economy will rise. If the economy is already at full
employment or there is supply bottleneck, it is hard to increase output and so prices
are pulled upwards.

9
 Reduction in taxation: If taxes are reduced (either by lowering the rate or by escaping
the people from tax-net), consumers will have more disposable income causing
demand to rise. A reduction in indirect taxes (taxes on goods and services such as
VAT) will mean that a given amount of income will now buy a greater real volume of
goods and services than it would be before its reduction.
 Deficit financing of the government: It results increase in money supply and then
aggregate demand of the economy, whatever be the sources of financing.
 Faster economic growth in other countries - It may accelerate the exports of goods
and services of the economy. Since exports are counted as an injection of aggregate
demand, it causes demand-pull inflation in the economy.

2.1.6 Cost-push Theories of Inflation


 It occurs when aggregate supply falls either from the increase in cost of production,
fall in production or monopoly powers. It is also known as supply side inflation. Due
to increase in costs of production, the aggregate supply decreases and ultimately price
level rises. Cost-push inflation can be shown using the aggregate demand and
aggregate supply curves. In this case, it is not the aggregate demand that increases; it
is the aggregate supply curve that shifts to the left as a result of the increase in the cost
of production. The cost of production can be increased if there is wage rate increment
from the trade union power in greater proportion compared to the increase in the marginal
productivity of the labour.
 Profits: Firms having more power and ability to raise prices, independently to
demand, can make more profit and result cost-push inflation. This is most likely to
occur, when markets become more concentrated and move towards monopoly or
perhaps oligopoly.
 Wages: The trade unions may be able to push wages up without increasing the
productivity of labors. Firms, then, are forced to increase their prices to pay the higher
claims and maintain their profitability.
 Imported inflation: In a global economy, firms import a significant proportion of their
raw materials or semi-finished products. If the cost of these imports increases for
reasons out of domestic control, then once again firms will be forced to increase
prices to pay the higher raw material costs.
 Exchange rate changes - If there is depreciation in the exchange rate, then exports will
become cheaper abroad, but imports will appear to be more expensive. Firms will be

10
paying more for their overseas raw materials leading to increase prices of domestic
economy.
 Commodity price changes - If there are price increases on world commodity markets,
firms will be faced with higher costs if they use these as raw materials. Important
markets would include the oil market and metals markets.
 External shocks - This could be either for natural reasons or because a particular
group or country will gain more economic power. An example of the first was the
Kobe earthquake in Japan, which disrupted world production of semi-conductors for a
while. An example of the second was the case of OPEC which forced up the price of
oil four-fold in the early 1970s.
 Exhaustion of natural resources: As resources run out, their price will inevitably
gradually rise. This will increase firms' costs and may push up prices until they find
an alternative source of raw materials (if they can). For example, in many countries
such problem has been caused by erosion of land when forests have been cleared. The
land quickly became useless for agriculture.
 Taxes: Increase in indirect taxes (taxes on expenditure) increases the cost of living
and push up the prices of products in the shops.

2.1.7 Real Business Theory of Inflation


This theory has been formulated by John Muth and is supported by new classical
economists such as Robert E. Lucas, Thomas J. Sargent, Neil Wallac etc. This theory
states that individuals and companies, acting with complete access to the relevant
information, forecast inflation in the future without bias. Errors on their forecasts are
assumed to result from random components.

Unlike in adaptive expectation principle, people do not consistently make the same
prospect. Economic agents form their macroeconomic expectations “rationally” based
on all past and current relevant information available, and not only on past
information. The expectations are, however, totally random, or independent of each
other. The RE approach to the business cycle and prices generated a vertical PC both
for the short- and the long run. If the monetary authority announces a monetary
stimulus in advance, people expect that prices rise.

Fully anticipated monetary policy cannot have any real effects even in the short-run.
Thus, the central bank can affect the real output and employment only if it can find a

11
way to create a price surprise. Otherwise, forward-looking expectation adjustments of
economic agents will fail the pre-announced policy. Likewise, if a disinflation policy
is announced in advance, it cannot reduce prices if people do not believe that the
government will really carry it out. That is price expectations are closely related to the
policy credibility and reputation for successful implementation.

2.1.8 Structuralist Theory


The structuralist approach to inflation is one of the major versions of the cost-push
theories of inflation. The structuralist inflation models (developed in the 1960s)
explain inflation with the productivity differences between the industrial and
agricultural sectors. In general, the traditional sector responds to monetary (or
aggregate-demand) shocks with a lag. This lag is accompanied by a partial increase in
industrial output and employment in the short run, which in turn increases wages and
hence the demand for agricultural products. This increase implicates a change in
relative prices in favor of foodstuffs. Higher agricultural prices lead to higher wage
demands in this sector. Increasing wages increase the demand for industrial products,
and the mechanism continues to work. In this model, aggregate supply chronically
lags behind aggregate demand as a result of the temporary output rigidities in one of
the sectors. Therefore, the structuralist model is accepted as a cost-push theory. The
structuralist argues that by the very nature of their economies, LDCs are prone to
inflation as most of them are characterized by structural rigidities, unproductive
government interventions, and political interferences in these economies. While the
Keynesians argue also that organized labor pressures on government pushes wages
up, and when not matched with output levels creates inflationary pressures; and most
of these LDCs are net importers of energy and most industrial imputes and other basic
necessities of life.

2.1.9 New Political Economy Theory of Inflation


The theories as mentioned above mainly focus on macroeconomic determinants of
inflation (e.g., monetary and real shocks, and inertia in inflation) and simply ignore
the role of non- economic factors such as institutions, political process and culture in
process of inflation. They also overlook the possibility that sustained government
deficits may be partially or fully endogenized by considering the effects of the
political process and possible lobbying activities on government budgets, and thus, on
inflation. Political forces, not the social planner, choose economic policy in the real

12
world. Economic policy is the result of a decision process that balances conflicting
interests so that a collective choice may emerge (Drazen, 2000). It, therefore, provides
fresh perspectives on the relations between timing of elections, policymaker
performance, political instability, policy credibility and reputation, central bank
independence and the inflation process itself.

2.2 Empirical Review


Various studies have been carried out for many countries using various sample
periods and econometric approaches and methods. This section is devoted to
exploring some key studies that have been carried out over the past decades. This
section is divided into two pats. The first part is related to the international context
whereas the second part presents national context.

2.2.1 International Context


Sowa (1994) examined the relationship between fiscal deficits, output growth and
inflation targets for the period 1965 to 1991 using the error correction model (ECM)
as estimation technique. The results revealed that nominal money (M0) and real
income have a significant positive impact on inflation, whereas exchange rate tend to
have a positive significant impact on inflation. The study further indicated that, for
periods with consistent fiscal deficit or policy (inconsistent fiscal deficit), inflation
tends to be within target (above target).

Ghartey (2001) investigated macroeconomic instability and inflationary financing


nexus using quarterly time series data covering the period 1970 to 1992. Employing
the pair-wise Granger causality test and vector error correction model (VECM) for the
analysis, the study showed that monetary base and currency ratio cause inflation and
real output growth and inflation also cause exchange rate growth. Real output growth
is revealed to have a bi- directional causal relationship with money supply growth,
monetary base, currency ratio, budget deficit as a percentage of GDP, and inflation.
Similarly, using annual time series data spanning 1983 to 1999, Bawumia and

Abradu-Otoo (2003) explored the relationship between monetary growth, exchange


rates and inflation. The results from the error correction model showed that money
supply (M2+) and exchange rate have a significant positive relationship with inflation,

13
whereas the effect of real income on inflation is revealed to be negative and
significant.

Using the ordinary least squares and generalized method of moments estimation
techniques, Kovanen (2011) investigated whether money matter for inflation using
quarterly time series data spanning 1990 to 2009. The study revealed that inflation
gap and real output gap have a positive and significant effect on inflation. Real money
gap and nominal money gap are also found to have insignificant negative effect on
inflation in both estimation techniques. Currency depreciation is also found to have
significant negative (significant positive) effect on inflation in four quarters (eight
quarters) in both the OLS and GMM estimators.

Eita et al., (2021) examined the impact of fiscal deficit on inflation in Namibia. The
paper employed Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model (ARDL) and Granger
causality approach using quarterly data for the period 2002 - 2017. Empirical results
showed evidence of a long run positive effect of fiscal deficit on inflation in Namibia.
This suggests that fiscal deficit has a direct effect on inflation in Namibia. The study
also found a unidirectional causality running from fiscal deficit to inflation in
Namibia. The study confirmed that South Africa’s prices have positive effect on
inflation in Namibia.

Ssebulime & Edward (2019) investigated the relationship between budget deficit and
inflation in Uganda for the period 1980 – 2016. The results revealed that the
relationship between the two variables is positive. The results suggest that budget
deficit is a driver of inflation in Uganda.

Duodu et al, (2022) investigated the long run dynamics of money supply, budget
deficit and inflation in Ghana using quarterly data from 1999Q1 to 2019Q4 and
employing Granger causality test and the vector error correction model (VECM) for
the analysis. The study found that budget deficit has a significant positive effect on
inflation whereas money supply affects inflation negatively.

Nasir et al. (2020a) examined inflation expectations in the face of oil shocks for New
Zealand and United Kingdom from the period January 1984 to June 2018. The results
from the non-linear autoregressive distributed lag (NARDL) model indicated that real
effective exchange rate has a significant negative relationship with inflation
expectations in both the short- and long-run for both countries. The results further

14
revealed that inflation, real effective exchange rate, money supply, output growth,
unemployment and fiscal deficit/ surplus have significant implications for inflation
expectations for the two countries. Nasir et al. (2020b) investigated the exchange rate
pass-through and management of inflation expectations for Czech Republic using the
NARDL. The outcome of the study showed that real effective exchange rate has a
significant negative relationship with inflation expectations in both the short- and
long-run. However, the relationship between inflation expectations and oil price
shocks is positive but insignificant in both periods. Fiscal stance and money supply
are also revealed to have insignificant negative relationship with inflation
expectations in both periods.

Alam et al, (2022) investigated the impact of selected macro-economic variables like
real effective exchange rate (REER), GDP, inflation (INF), the volume of trade (TR)
and money supply (M2) on-budget deficit (BD) in Bangladesh over the period of
1980–2018. By using secondary data, the paper uses the Vector Error Correction
Model (VECM) and Granger Causality test. Johansen’s cointegration test is used to
examine the long-run relationship among the variables under study. Johansen’s
cointegration test result shows that there exists a positive long-run relationship of
selected macroeconomic variables (real effective exchange rate, inflation, the volume
of trade and money supply) with the budget deficit, whereas GDP has a negative one.
The short-run results from the VECM show that GDP, inflation and money supply
have a negative relationship with the budget deficit. The Granger Causality test results
reveal unidirectional causal relationships running from BD to REER; TR to BD; M2
to BD; GDP to REER; M2 to REER; INF to GDP; GDP to TR; M2 to GDP and
bidirectional causal relationship between GDP and BD; TR and REER; M2 and TR.
Nguyen (2015) studied the effect of fiscal deficit and money supply (M2) on inflation
in selected economies (Bangladesh, Cambodia, Indonesia, Malaysia, Pakistan,
Philippines, Sri Lanka, Thailand and Vietnam) of Asia using time series data from the
period 1985 to 2012 and applying the pooled mean group (PMG) estimation-based
error correction model and the panel differenced GMM estimation techniques. The
result of the study showed that fiscal deficit and money supply (M2) have a
significant positive effect on inflation in long run whereas, in short run, money supply
has significant negative effect on inflation, and the effect of fiscal deficit is
insignificant.

15
Using annual time series data from 1960 to 2009 and employing the autoregressive
distributed lag (ARDL) model, Adu and Marbuah (2011) examined the determinants
of inflation. The study showed that money supply has a significant positive influence
on inflation in both the long and short run. The relationship between fiscal deficit and
inflation is revealed to be insignificant in the long run but positive and significant in
the short run. Exchange rate is found to exert significant negative effect in the long
run. The study further showed that, while interest rate impacted positively on
inflation, real output is found to have a significant negative effect on inflation in both
the long- and short-run.

Lakshmanasamy (2022) examined the causal relationship between inflation and


macroeconomic variables - interest rate, exchange rate, money supply, GDP and fiscal
deficit - in India over the period 1986 to 2020 applying the vector correction (VECM)
estimation method. The macro variables are stationary at first difference and a
cointegrating and causal relationship exists between the wholesale price index and
interest rate, exchange rate, GDP, broad money and gross fiscal deficit. The VECM
estimates reveal that money supply and GDP are the most important macro variables
in explaining the variation in inflation. The estimated error correction term shows that
the short-run disequilibrium is corrected by about 20% every period towards the long-
run equilibrium. The impulse response results show that inflation responds positively
to money supply from the start to the 9th period.

Istiqomah & Mafruhah (2022) analyzed the relationship between budget deficits and
economic growth based on Keynesian, Neoclassical, and Ricardian Equivalent
theories, and to explain the relationship between inflation, poverty, world crude oil
prices, and government consumption on economic growth. Time-series data in
Indonesia from 1981 to 2019 were analyzed using the Domowitz-El Badawi ECM and
VAR methods. The results show that the Ricardian Equivalence is proven to have
occured in the short-term in Indonesia, while in the long-term, budget deficit shows a
positive impact on economic growth in Indonesia and supports the Keynesian
perspective. In the short term, only inflation and government consumption show an
impact on economic development: while inflation has a negative effect. In the long
run, budget deficit, inflation, poverty, and world oil prices all affect economic growth,
while government consumption does not.

16
Kaur (2021) examined the important macroeconomic determinants of inflation in
India and investigated whether the proposition of a positive effect of fiscal deficits on
inflation can be verified in the particular case of the Indian economy using quarterly
data from Q1: 1996–1997 to Q1: 2016-2017 and employing ARDL Bounds approach
to cointegration. The study found that gross fiscal deficit and money supply had
negative impact on inflation in India. Moreover, the study also found that crude oil
prices and exchange rate were important determinants of inflation in India.

2.2.2 National Context


Using OLS technique Neupane (1992) examined both monetarist (closed economy)
and structuralist approaches to the inflation process in Nepal over the period 1965 to
1988. Percentage change in CPI was used as the dependent variable and percentage
change in current money supply, money supply lagged by one and two years,
percentage change in GDP, and the expected cost of holding money, percentage
change in output in commodity producing sectors lagged by one year, percentage
change in the import price index lagged by one year and percentage change in
government budget deficit were taken as the explanatory variables. The study found that
monetary policy is an important instrument to control inflation. the study also found that an
increase in money supply in line with the growth of per capita GDP could help to control
inflation.

(ISD, 1994) used an eclectic approach of the monetarist and structuralist views to
identify major determinants of inflation in Nepal. money supply and real output,
Indian wholesale price exchange rate, lagged effect of money supply and government
expenditure were taken as additional explanatory variable. The study found that
money supply, international prices (particularly Indian prices), exchange rate, real
output, government expenditure and expectation factors as major sources of inflation
in Nepal. Similarly, infrastructural bottlenecks, imperfect market condition and
market oriented economic policies are also instrumental for inflation escalation. ISD
(1994) found that Nepalese inflation increases by more than 8 percent if Indian
inflation increase by 10 percent.

Khatiwada (1994) examined the inflation process in Nepal utilizing basis the quantity
theory of money. Initially, results showed low explanatory power and suggested that
there were other missing variables in the equation. When open economy variables,

17
such as Indian inflation and the exchange rate, were included this showed significant
increase in the explanatory power of the equation. The study had also included
structural variables such as per-capita output and government expenditures, but those
did not have a significant effect being "swamped" by the monetary variables. The
study finds that IPI is consistently significant and suggests that inflation in Nepal is
influenced by open economy forces.

Mathema (1998) has used an expectation augmented Phillips Curve approach to


examine whether the nominal wage increases are the most significant sources of cost
push inflation. Annual CPI inflation (P), real GDP growth (GDPR), change in money
supply (narrowly defined; M), change in wages (W), change in imported price (PI)
and change in price expectation (PE)11 are the variables where excess demand
proxies for unemployment. The data for the study period is 1978/79 and 1995/96.
OLS and unit root tests are performed for stationarity test of the variables chosen. The
author finds the importance of several wage variables for influencing domestic
inflation but surprisingly does not find significant effect of imported prices. The
author attributes this to "absorption of the effect of WPII (whole sale prices of India)
by the money wages of laborers in the homeland" (Mathema, 1998, p. 16). Granger
Bivariate Causality Test finds unilateral causation from the rate of inflation to wages
of agricultural and masonry labour while industrial wages cause inflation in Nepal.

Pandey (2005) utilized an excess demand model of inflation and has applied OLS,
stationarity test, co-integration technique and error correction modeling to study the
determinants of inflation in Nepal. The study has identified money supply (both
narrow and broad), real GDP, government expenditure, Indian inflation and exchange
rate as explanatory variables influencing inflation, over the period 1973 to 2004.
Although bivariate regression between price and the average money revealed
significant relationship, the low explanatory power of the equation suggested
inclusion of more variables. The author could not find any change in the explanatory
power of the model while including public expenditure as well as real GDP, a supply
side variable. In an open economy monetarist model, Indian prices and exchange rate
with Indian rupees and US dollar are included; however, the explanatory power of the
model is limited to 47 percent only. The study had then used the ECM to avoid the
problem of loosing long-run information on data to reveal both short-term relationship
and adjustment toward long run equilibrium.

18
Chaudhary and Xiumin (2018) examine the impacts of macroeconomic variables on
the inflation in Nepal during 1975-2016. The variables considered for the study are
limited to the use of real broad money supply, real GDP, Indian prices. The results
suggest that all variables considered are significant in the long-run implying that these
variables are the determinants of inflation in Nepal. The results are consistent with the
monetary theory. The results concluded that the money supply (0.197) and Indian
prices (1.074) cause inflation in the long-run based on an Ordinary Least Squares
regression model.

Poudyal (2014) examined short term and long-term effects of the macroeconomic
variables on the inflation in Nepal during 1975-2011. The variables considered are
budget deficits, Indian prices, real broad money supply, exchange rate, and real GDP.
The regression results from the Wickens-Breusch Single Equation Error Correction
model suggest that all variables considered are significant in the long run implying
that these variables are the determinants of inflation in Nepal. However, only budget
deficit, money supply, and Indian prices cause inflation in the short run.

IMF (2014) estimated the determinants of Nepalese inflation on the monthly series of
Nepal's CPI, broad money, a nominal effective exchange rate (NEER), and Indian CPI
using OLS. The coefficient of broad money supply and Indian inflation was 0.12 and
0.45 percent respectively; indicating a 1 percent increase in broad money supply will
cause Nepalese inflation to rise by 0.12 percent whereas such an increase in Indian
CPI will increase Nepalese inflation by 0.45 percent.

NRB (2007) estimated the impact of narrow money supply and Indian inflation in
Nepal’s inflation applying cointegration and error correction model on annual data
from 1978 to 2006. The result revealed a significant short-run impact of M1 but did
not find a long-run impact on inflation. Further, the findings suggest that a one
percent increase in Indian price level changes Nepal’s inflation by 1.09 percent in the
short-run.

Byanjankar (2020) Examine the relationship between money supply and inflation by
using time series data from 1975 to 2018. The study use CPI as dependent variable
and money supply, Indian CPI, government deficit, crude oil price, RGDP and
nominal effective exchange rate as independent variable. By using ARDL model
study find out the insignificant relation between money supply and inflation in both

19
short run and long run. The result shows that in long run Indian inflation rate, real
income and exchange rate are major determinant of inflation in Nepal.
2.3 Research Gap
The conflicting propositions by the aforementioned theories and evidence from past
studies by authors and policy makers on Nepal and other parts of the world have
revealed mixed and conflicting results regarding the impact of budget deficit and
money supply on inflation. Therefore, it is crucial to conduct further research on the
topic to ensure the validity of previous results. Indeed, the motivation behind this
research stems from the desire to contribute to the existing pool of knowledge by
empirically reevaluating how the money supply and budget deficit impacts inflation in
Nepal. Its goal is to enhance my understanding of the various interpretations found in
the literature, which have examined the relationship between money supply, budget
deficit and inflation in Nepal from both practical and theoretical perspectives.

20
CHAPTER - III
RESEARCH METHODOLOGY

This section is divided into nine parts. The first part presents research design used in
the study. Similarly, the second, third, fourth and fifth pars presents sample period
covered in the study, sources of data, conceptual framework and specifications of
variables respectively. Tools and methods of data collection, data organization and
processing, model specification and methods of analysis are presented in sixth,
seventh, eighth and ninth chapters respectively.

3.1 Research Design


The study is based on time series data and quantitative in nature. Therefore,
descriptive and inferential research designs have been used in order to address the
objective of the study. The descriptive research design was used in order to find out
the trends of money supply, budget deficit and inflation in Nepal whereas, inferential
research design was employed to examine the short-run and long-run relationship
between the variables used in the study.

3.2 Conceptual Framework


Inflation can be defined as the persistent and appreciable rise in the price level of
goods and services in an economy. It is measured as the percentage change in the
general price level of goods and services. The quantity theory of money states that
inflation in the economy entirely depends on money supply. Inflation can be set in
motion when budget deficits are financed by the monetary authority, like the Central
Bank. This can happen through means such as seigniorage, which involves the central
bank creating money, or by supporting government expenditures through open market
operations, which involve acquiring interest-bearing government securities. The
conceptual framework has been shown in the following figure.

21
Figure 3.1: Conceptual Framework

Independent variables Dependent variable

Broad Money
supply

Budget deficit

Inflation
Real GDP

Nominal Effective
Exchange rate

Indian inflation

Source: Researcher’s Creation

This study has taken inflation as a dependent variable whereas money supply and
budget deficit as independent variables. Real GDP, Indian inflation and exchange rate
are also considered as control variables in the model.

3.3 Nature and Sources of Data


Since this study is based on secondary data, this study uses quantitative data. Data
were obtained from the following sources:
 Various current macroeconomic and financial situation published by NRB
 Various economic surveys published by Ministry of Finance of Nepal
 World development indicators (WDI, 2022)

3.4 Study Period Covered


Annual time series data on money supply, budget deficit and inflation from 1974/75
to 2021/22 have been used to address the objective of the study. This is because of the
non-availability data before 1974/75.

3.5 Tools and Method of Data Collection


Secondary data have been used to address the objectives of this study. Due to non-
availability of data before 1974/75, this study has taken the data since 1974. The web
sites of Nepal Rastra Bank, Ministry of Finance of Nepal and World Bank have been
22
used as the tools and methods of data collection. Additionally, the published articles
and unpublished thesis were also used to collect the required data for the study.

3.6 Data Organization and Processing


After collecting raw data from various sources, these data are arranged in a table
using Microsoft excel for applying different statistical tests and methods. Real GDP,
consumer price index of Nepal, consumer price index of India and nominal effective
exchange rate are expressed at base year 2010/11. All these variables are converted
into natural logarithm form using Microsoft excel. The following formula is used to calculate
nominal effective exchange rate:
NEER = ∑𝑛𝑖=1 𝑇𝑊𝑖 𝑋 𝑁𝐸𝑅𝑖

Where,

TWi= Trade weight of country i

NEERi = Nominal effective exchange rate of country i

3.7 Tools and Methods of Data Analysis


3.7.1 Trend and Descriptive Analysis
To find out the trend of money supply, budget deficit and inflation in Nepal, simply
figures have been drawn in rupees and percent using Microsoft excel. Mean, median,
maximum, minimum, standard deviation, skewness, kurtosis and pair-wise correlation
have been calculated using EViews 12 version.

3.7.2 Empirical Analysis


To examine the long-run and short-run relationship between money supply, budget
deficit and inflation in Nepal, autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) model has been
used. EViews 12 version software has been employed to run ARDL model.

3.8 Model Specification


Based on Duodu et al. (2022), the study has specified the following functional form:
LnNCPIt = f (LnM2t, LnBDt, LnRGDPt, LnNEERt, LnICPIt) ………… (1)
Where, NCPIt, M2t, BDt, RGDPt, NEERt, and ICPIt represents Nepalese consumer
price index, broad money supply, budget deficit, real gross domestic product, nominal
effective exchange rate, Indian consumer price index and t denotes time trend. Ln
denotes natural log form (See: Appendix – II).

23
The econometric models of equation (1) can be written as:

LnNCPIt = α0 + β1 LnM2t, + β2LnBDt + β3LnRGDPt + β4LnNEERt + β5LnCPIt + εt


….… (2)

α0 and εt are the constant and the stochastic error terms, respectively, such that the
error term is normally distributed with a mean of zero and a constant variance [εt ~ N
(0, σ2]. Again, the β’s (1, 2, 3, . . ., 5) are the respective coefficients of the variables to
be estimated, and ln denotes the natural logarithm.

3.9 Description of Variables


a) Inflation: The proxy of national consumer price inflation is consumer price index of
Nepal and it is denoted by NCPI. It is expressed at 2010/11 prices and transformed
into natural logarithm form. Data on NCPI is taken from various current macroeconomic
and financial situation published by NRB
b) Broad Money Supply: The broad money supply is denoted by M2 and natural
logarithm form M2 is taken for the purpose of this study. The value of M2 is taken in
Rs. Million. Data on money supply was taken from various current macroeconomic
and financial situation published by NRB. It is expected that money supply is
positively related to inflation.
c) Budget Deficit: Budget deficit is defined as total tax revenue minus total expenditure.
Budget deficit is denoted by BD and natural logarithm form BD is taken for the purpose
of this study. The value of BD is taken in Rs. Million. Data on BD is taken from
various economic surveys published by Ministry of Finance of Nepal. It is expected
that BD and inflation are positively related.
d) Real GDP: It is expressed at 2010/11 prices and transformed into natural logarithm
form. Data on RGDP is taken from various economic surveys published by Ministry
of Finance of Nepal.
e) Nominal Effective Exchange Rate: the proxy of exchange rate is nominal effective
exchange rate which is denoted by NEER. It is expressed at 2010/11 prices and
transformed into natural logarithm form. Data on NEER is taken from various current
macroeconomic and financial situation published by NRB
f) Indian Inflation: The proxy of Indian inflation is consumer price index of India and
it is denoted by ICPI. It is expressed at 2010/11 prices and transformed into natural
logarithm form. Data on ICPI was taken world development indictors.

24
Is short, the description of variables can also be shown with the help of given Table 3.1.
Table 3.1: Descriptions of Variables
Variables Measureme Notation Source Unit Expected
nt / sign
Proxy
Inflation Nepalese NCPI Nepal Rastra Bank natural logarithm -
(Dependent Variable) consumer form, base year
price index 2010/11
Money supply (First Broad money M2 Nepal Rastra Bank natural logarithm Positive
Core Independent Supply form (Rs. million)
Variable)
Budget deficit (Second Total tax BD Economic survey natural logarithm Positive
Core Dependent revenue of Nepal form (Rs. million)
Variable) minus total
expenditure
Gross domestic product Real gross RGDP Economic survey natural logarithm Positive
(First Control domestic of Nepal form, base year
dependent Variable) product 2010/11 (Rs. million)
Exchange rate (Second Nominal NEER Nepal Rastra Bank natural logarithm Positive /
Control dependent effective form, base year Negative
Variable) exchange rate 2010/11
Indian inflation (Third Indian ICPI Word natural logarithm Positive
Control dependent consumer Development form, base year
Variable) price index 2010/11
Source: Various Publications

3.10 Model and Econometric Test


This section presents stationarity test of variables used in the study, autoregressive
distributed lag (ARDL) to co-integration analysis, error correction model, diagnostic
test and stability test of the model.

3.10.1 Stationary Test (Unit Root Test)


ADF and P-P unit root tests have been used to test stationarity of variables used in the
study although there are many method of testing stationarity of variables

3.10.2 Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) to Co-integration


Analysis
There are three techniques that have been used to examine the co-integration among
the variables. First one is an Engle and Granger (E-G) Test. This is a bivariate
technique implying that multivariate analysis is excluded under this co-integration
test. This means this technique is used to examine the cointigration between only one
independent variable and one dependent variable. Second one is Johansen
Cointegration Test which is a system-based approach to co-integration. This is more
25
efficient than the E-G approach, as it offers multiple cointegrating vectors. Unlike E-
G, the Johansen approach reduces omitted lagged variables bias by including the lag
in the estimation. However, this approach is also criticized, as it is highly sensitive to
the number of lags selected Gonzalo. Moreover, interpretation often becomes difficult
when more than one co-integrating vector exists in the model. In the case of mixed
orders of integration in the regressors, the validity of both the E-G and Johansen
techniques have been challenged. Thus, these techniques are only valid in cases with
the same order of integration. Third one is an Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL)
Bound Test. According to this test; it does not need all the variables under study to be
integrated of the same orders and can be applied even if underlying variables are
integrated of order zero or one or fractionally integrated in comparison with
traditional co-integration methods (Pesaran et al., 2001). Furthermore, ARDL test is
relatively efficient in the case of small sample data size and gives unbiased estimates
of the long model (Harris and Sollis, 2003).

This study employed the ARDL technique proposed by Pesaran at al. (2001).The first
step of autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) bound test is to examine the stationarity
of variables to see the order of co-integration. The main assumption of ARDL bounds
test is that the variables should be I(0) or I(1). If there is I(2), the ARDL bound test is
not suitable because the result so obtained can be spurious (Pesaran and shine,
1999).Therefore, before applying this test, Augmented Dickey Fuller test (ADF) by
Dickey and Fuller (1979) has been used to determine the order of integration of all
variables.

After testing the stationarity of variables, the ARDL bounds test of co-integration
developed by Pesaran and Shine (1999) and Pesaran et al., (2000) was employed to
examine the cointegration for long-run relationships among the variables of interest.
Following the ARDL approach proposed by Pesaran and Shin (1999), the ARDL
model used in this study is the following:
𝑝 𝑞
∆LNCPIt = α + ∑𝑖=0(Υ1𝑖 ∆LnN𝐶𝑃𝐼𝑡−𝑖 ) + ∑𝑖=0(Υ2𝑖 ∆LnM2𝑡−𝑖 ) +
𝑟
𝑡
∑ (Υ3𝑖 ∆Ln𝐵𝐷𝑡−𝑖 ) + ∑𝑠𝑖=0(Υ4𝑖 ∆Ln𝑅𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑡−𝑖 ) + ∑𝑖=0(Υ5𝑖 ∆Ln𝑁𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑡−𝑖 ) +
𝑖=0

∑𝑢𝑖=0(Υ6𝑖 ∆Ln𝐵𝐷𝑡−𝑖 )) + β1Ln CPIt-1+ β2LnM2t-1 + β3LnBDt-1 ++ β4LnRGDPt-1 +

β5LnNEERt-1 + β6LnICPIt-1 + εt …………...….3

26
Where, β1, β2, β3, β4, β5, and β6 are long-term coefficients and Υ1𝑖 , Υ2𝑖 , Υ3𝑖 Υ4𝑖 ,
Υ5𝑖 𝑎𝑛𝑑 Υ6𝑖 represents short-run dynamics and εt = represents a random disturbance
term.
H0: β1= β2 = β3 = β4 = β5 = β6 =0 (there is no cointegration)

H1: β1 ≠ β2 ≠ β3 ≠ β4 ≠ β5 ≠ β6 ≠ 0 (there is cointegration)

The F-test will be employed to test co-integration among the variables. If the
computed F-value was less than the F-value for the lower bound, then the null
hypothesis cannot be rejected. If the computed F-value exceeded the F-value for the
upper bound, then the null hypothesis of no co-integration was rejected, otherwise the
test was inconclusive. (Pesaran et al. 2001). To select the lag values p, q and r in
Equation (1), model selection criteria, such as AIC, SIC, Hannan-Quinn information
criteria, Adjusted R-squared will be used (See: E Views analysis in Appendix – IV).

3.10.3 Error Correction Model


There must have an error correction representation wherein an error correction term
(ECT) is incorporated in the model, if a set of variables is co-integrated (Engle and
Granger 1987). The short-run dynamics of the variables was described by employing
the Error Correction Model (ECM). The ECM representation was specified as
follows:
𝑝 𝑞
∆CPIt = α + ∑𝑖=0(µ1𝑖 ∆In𝐶𝑃𝐼𝑡−𝑖 ) + ∑𝑖=0(µ2𝑖 ∆InM2𝑡−𝑖 ) + ∑𝑟𝑖=0(µ3𝑖 ∆In𝐵𝐷𝑡−𝑖 )
+∑𝑠𝑖=0(µ4𝑖 ∆LnRGDP𝑡−𝑖 ) + ∑𝑡𝑖=0(µ5𝑖 ∆LnNEER 𝑡−𝑖 )+ ∑𝑢𝑖=0(µ6𝑖 ∆LnICPI𝑡−𝑖 ) +µ7ECTt-1
+νt ……………. (4)

Where µ1i, µ2i …. µ6i are the short-run dynamic coefficients of the model’s
convergence to the equilibrium and µ7 is the speed of adjustment parameter,
indicating how quickly the series can come back to its long-run equilibrium. The sign
of the coefficient must be negative and significant.

3.10.4 Diagnostic Tests


This study has employed three diagnostic tests after ARDL bound in order to identify
whether the models were correctly specified or not.

a. Breusch- Godfrey Serial Correlation Test


This test has been carried out whether the model has serial correlation or not.

27
Null Hypothesis (H0): There is no serial correlation in the model

Alternative hypothesis (H1): There is serial correlation in the model

In this condition, null hypothesis is desirable. Therefore, P-value should be greater


than 5 percent in order to accept the null hypothesis of no serial correlation in the
model.

b. Breusch-Pagan –Godfrey Test


This test will be employed in order to test whether the model has heteroskedasticity
or not.

Null Hypothesis (H0): There is no heteroskedasticity in the model

Alternative hypothesis (H1): There is heteroskedasticity in the model

In this condition, null hypothesis is desirable. Therefore, P-value should be greater


than 5 percent in order to accept the null hypothesis of no heteroskedasticity in the
model.

c. Jarque- Bera Test

This test has been employed in order to test whether the model has normality or not.

Null Hypothesis (H0): There is normality in the model

Alternative hypothesis (H1): There is no normality in the model

In this condition, null hypothesis is desirable. Therefore, P-value should be greater


than 5 percent in order to accept the null hypothesis of normality in the model.

3.10.5 Stability Test


The stability test of the model as well as coefficients has carried using two tests as
follows:

a. Cumulative Sum of Recursive Residuals (CUSUM)


The stability test of the model will be carried out by plotting cumulative sum of
recursive residuals (CUSUM). According to this test, the residuals should lie within
the critical bounds at the 5 percent significance level.

28
b. Cumulative Sum of Squares of Residuals (CUSUMQ)
The stability test of the individual parameter will be carried out by plotting the
cumulative sum of squares of residuals (CUSUMQ). According to this test, the
residuals should lie within the critical bounds at the 5% significance level.

29
CHAPTER - IV
DATA PRESENTATION AND ANALYSIS

This section has discussed the trend analysis, descriptive statistics and empirical
results of the study. This section is divided into two parts. The first part of this section
presents the trend analysis and descriptive statistics of the variable used in the study
while the second part presents the results of empirical analysis.

4.1 Trend Analysis


This section has divided into four parts. The first, second and third parts present the
trend of inflation, budget deficit and money supply respectively while the fourth part
is the comparison between the broad money supply, budget deficit with inflation in
Nepal.

4.1.1 Trend Analysis of Inflation in Nepal


Inflation means a persistent and appreciable rise in general price level. when the
annual rate of inflation is up to 3 percent, it is said to be creeping inflation. It has no
negative impact on the economy. It creates positive effect on investment, production
and employment. when the annual rate of inflation is in -he range of 3 to 10 percent, it
is said to be walking inflation. It is the warning signal for the government to control
before turns into running inflation. when the annual rate of inflation is in the range of
10 to 50 percent, it is said to be running inflation. It affects poor and middle classes
group adversely. When price level rises more than more than 50 percent, it is called
hyperinflation. Hyperinflation reduces purchasing power, discourages of saving and
investment, rises of cost of borrowing, encourages speculative investment, raises the
cost of development projects and reduces competitiveness in the economy. The trend
analysis of percentage change in inflation in Nepal can be shown in the Figure 4.1.

30
Figure 4.1: Trend Analysis of Inflation in Nepal

25

20

15

10

-5
INF

Source: Appendix II

The Figure 4.1 shows that trend of inflation in Nepal from 1974/75 to 2021/22 has
been shown in appendix II. As shown in the figure, the inflation rate of Nepal was -
0.69 percent in 1974/75. The highest inflation rate was recorded in 1991/92 which
was 21.05 precent. The average rate of inflation from 1974 to 2021 is around 8
percent. The inflation rate of Nepal has not been stable and this rate is near to two
digits. Although the Nepal Rastra Bank has formulated monetary policy every year
with prime objective of controlling inflation, there are many other factors besides
monetary factors such as infrastructure bottlenecks, market imperfections, supply side
shocks international regions which are fueling inflation in Nepal.

4.1.2 Trend Analysis of Broad Money Supply in Nepal


Money supply refers to the total stock of money at a point of time in an economy
(total quantity of money held by public in spendable form at a point of time). Money
supply consists of notes and currency held by the public, demand deposits maintained
at the banks by the public. Narrow Money Supply (M1) consists of currency held by
public (non-banking public) and demand deposit held by the commercial banking
system. In case of Nepal, DD consists of the current account deposits maintained at
class A, B, & C banks. Similarly, Broad Money Supply (M2) consists of narrow
money supply and time deposits consists of the deposits maintained at saving account,
call account and margin account and fixed deposit accounts. Time deposits are less
31
liquid as they have restrictions for withdrawal before the maturity. The trend analysis
of percentage change in money supply can be shown in the Figure 4.2.
Figure 4.2: Trend Analysis of Broad Money Supply in Nepal

30

25

20

15

10

Percentage change in M2

Source: Appendix II.

The Figure 4.2 shows that the highest percentage change in money supply was
recorded in fiscal years in 1976, 1992 and 2010/11 which was around 28 percent
while the lowest wad recorded in 2001 which was 4 percent followed by 2021/22
which was 7 percent. The average growth rate of money supply from 1974/75 to
2021/22 is around 16 percent. The trend of money supply growth has not been stable.
It ranges from four percent to 28 percent rate of broad money supply.

4.1.3 Trend Analysis of Budget Deficit in Nepal


A budget is a financial document of the government that consists of estimated
expenditures and proposed revenues for a coming fiscal year. When government
keeps its total expenditure equals to its total revenue, then it is called balanced
budgetary policy whereas when government keeps its total expenditure less than its
total revenue, then it is called surplus budget policy similarly, when government
spends more than its total revenue, then it is called deficit budget policy. The trend
analysis of percentage change in budget deficit can be shown in the Figure 4.3.

32
Figure 4.3: Trend Analysis of Budget Deficit in Nepal

300.0

250.0

200.0

150.0

100.0

50.0

0.0
1986/87

2006/07
1974/75
1976/77
1978/79
1980/81
1982/83
1984/85

1988/89
1990/91
1992/93
1994/95
1996/97
1998/99
2000/01
2002/03
2004/05

2008/09
2010/11
2012/13
2014/15
2016/17
2018/19
2020/21
-50.0

-100.0

BD

Source: Appendix II

The Figure 4.3 shows that the percentage change in money supply was 58 percent in
1974/75. The highest level of percentage change in budget deficit was recorded in
fiscal year 2016/17. It was due to the fact that Nepal had experienced devastating
earthquake in 2015/16 and had to spend large amount of money for reconstruction of
physical infrastructures taking loan externally. On the other hand, the lowest level of
percentage change in budget deficit was realized in fiscal year 2019/20. This is
because all economic activities were slow down due to Covid pandemic and
government couldn’t collect revenue for its spending. The figure also shows that
Nepal has adopted budget deficit over study period. This is due to the fact that Nepal
is a poor developing country and the revenue collected from tax and non-tax is not
enough to spent on infrastructures. Nepal is, therefore, pursuing deficit budget every
year as a tool to refinancing development projects.

4.1.4 Trend Analysis of Real GDP in Nepal


Economic growth refers to the change in real output in an economy over time. It is
measured as a change in real GDP in the economy over time. The trend analysis of
economic growth in Nepal has been shown in figure 4.4. As shown in figure, the
highest level of economic growth rate was realized in fiscal year 1980/80 which was
10 percent. Nepal had realized negative growth rate in fiscal years 1979/80 and

33
2019/20. Nepal has realized negative growth of 2.4 percent due to covid pandemic
outbreak. This is because all economic activities were stopped due to lock-down. As a
result, negative growth rate was recorded in Nepal. The figure 4.4 also shows that
after 2019 when effect of Covid decrease, economic growth rate of Nepal had
increased slowly and reached 5.6 in fiscal year 2021/22.

Figure 4.4: Trend Analysis of Percentage change in Real GDP in Nepal


12.0

10.0

8.0

6.0

4.0

2.0

0.0

-2.0

-4.0

Economic Growth

Source: Appendix II

Looking at the Figure 4.4, it can be seen that the average growth rate of Nepal for the
sample period is only 4.3 percent. This shows that the economic growth rate of Nepal
is very low. The figure 4.4 also shows that the economic growth rate has not been
stable over the sample period.

4.1.5 Trend Analysis of Nominal Effective Exchange Rate in Nepal


Exchange rate is defined as the price of one country’s currency in term of another
country’s currency. Exchange rate is also an important determinant of inflation.

34
Figure 4.5: Trend Analysis of NEER

30.0

20.0

10.0

0.0
1984/85

2006/07
1974/75
1976/77
1978/79
1980/81
1982/83

1986/87
1988/89
1990/91
1992/93
1994/95
1996/97
1998/99
2000/01
2002/03
2004/05

2008/09
2010/11
2012/13
2014/15
2016/17
2018/19
2020/21
-10.0

-20.0

-30.0

-40.0
NEER

Source: Appendix II

The trend of nominal effective exchange is shown in figure 4.5. Aa shown in figure,
the nominal effective exchange rate of Nepal is not stable for the sample period.

4.1.6 Trend Analysis of Nepalese inflation and Indian Inflation


Nepal is a land-locked country located between India to the east, south, and west and
the China to the north. Nepal has around two third trade with India. Nepal mostly
exports low-value agricultural products to India and imports high-value manufactured
products from India. Moreover, Nepalese currency is pegged to the Indian rupee and
hence Nepalese currency becomes weak as Indian currency becomes weak.
Furthermore, Nepal and India share an open boarder. Due to aforementioned reasons,
if inflation occurs in India, it is easily transmitted in Nepal through trade.

35
Figure 4.6: Trend Analysis of Nepalese inflation and Indian Inflation
25.0

20.0

15.0

10.0

5.0

0.0
1974/75
1976/77

2016/17
2018/19
2020/21
1978/79
1980/81
1982/83
1984/85
1986/87
1988/89
1990/91
1992/93
1994/95
1996/97
1998/99
2000/01
2002/03
2004/05
2006/07
2008/09
2010/11
2012/13
2014/15
-5.0

-10.0

Nepalses Inflation Indian Inflation

Source: Appendix II

The trend analysis of Nepalese inflation and Indian inflation have been shown in
figure 4.6. It can be seen from figure 4.4 that inflation of Nepal and India have been
moving in same direction for the sample period which indicates that Nepalese
inflation and Indian inflation are positively correlated i.e., Indian inflation is main
determinant of Nepalese inflation. For example, the highest rate of inflation was
recorded in Nepal in 1991 which was 21.05 percent. In the same year, the inflation
rate of India was also highest which was 13. 87 percent. The figure also shows that
Indian inflation and Nepalese inflation have not been stable over the years.

36
4.1.7 Comparison between Broad Money Supply, Budget Deficit,
Real GDP, Nominal Effective Exchange Rate and Indian Inflation
with Inflation in Nepal

The trends of money supply inflation (NCPI) , (M2), budget deficit (BD), RGDP,
NEER and ICPI over the study period are shown in the figure 4.7.

Figure 4.7: Comparison between NCPI, M2, BD, RGDP, NEER & ICPI

30.00

25.00

20.00

15.00

10.00

5.00

0.00

LnRGDP LnGD LnNCPI LnICPI LnNEER LnM2

Source: Appendix II

It is observed that RGDP, BD & M2 have a steady upward trend over the study
period. However, ICPI, NCPI & NEER, have been fluctuating over the years, but
shows an upward trend.

4.2 Empirical Analysis


This section presents descriptive statistics, stationary test, bound test result, estimated
long run coefficients, estimated short-run coefficients and diagnostic test and stability
test.

4.2.1 Descriptive Statistics


The summary of the descriptive statistics in terms of mean, standard deviation,
skewness, kurtosis, Jarque-Bera and linear correlation are reported in Table 4.1

37
Table 4.1: Summary of Descriptive Statistics
Variables LnNCPI LnM2 LnBD LnRGDP LnNEER LnICPI
Mean 3.36 11.69 9.85 13.47 4.35 3.86
Median 3.8 11.84 10.03 13.45 4.52 3.84
Maximum 5.31 15.52 12.79 14.45 4.9 5.2
Minimum 1.57 7.6 6.2 12.63 3.67 2.00
Std. Dev. 1.11 2.23 1.71 0.54 0.33 1.03
Skewness -0.21 -0.05 -0.26 0.11 -0.68 -0.14
Kurtosis 1.84 1.86 2.27 1.79 2.23 1.76
J-B 3.02 2.60 1.62 3.02 4.92 3.20
Probability 0.22 0.27 0.44 0.22 0.08 0.20
Pair-Wise Correlation
LnNCPI 1 - - - - -
LnM2 0.99 1 - - - -
LnBD 0.98 0.98 1 - - -
LnRGDP 0.79 0.77 0.77 1 - -
LnNEER 0.06 0.11 0.01 0.02 1 -
LnICPI 0.99 0.99 0.98 0.79 0.10 1
Source: Author’s own calculation using E Views 12.
From Table 4.1, it is observed that money supply (M2), budget deficit (BD) and
inflation (NCPI) have mean (standard deviation) values of 11.6 (2.23), 9.85 (1.71) and
3.36 (1.11) respectively. The maximum (minimum) values for money supply (M2),
budget deficit (BD) and inflation (NCPI) are 15.79 (7.6), 12.79 (6.2) and 5.31 (1.57),
respectively. In all, it is observed that the sample variables do not deviate much from
their respective mean values as indicated by the standard deviation values.
Furthermore, the values for the Skewness, Kurtosis and the Jarque-Bera show that the
data is normally distributed. Turning to the linear correlation, it is observed that
money supply (M2) and budget deficit (BD) have a strong positive correlation with
inflation.

38
4.2.2 Stationary Test (Unit Root Test)
The results from the ADF and P-P unit root tests are reported in table 4.2

Table 4.2: Stationary Test (Unit Root Test)


Variables ADF Test P-P Test
I(0) I(1) I(0) I(1)
LnNCPI -1.19 -5.38* -1.04 -5.36*
LnM2 -2.08 -4.87* -2.12 -4.92*
LnBD -3.43*** -5.06* -3.14*** -8.14*
LnRGDP -0.92 -6.81* -0.97 -6.89*
LnNEER -2.07 -6.13* -2.19 -6.24*
LnICPI -1.54 -4.69* -1.17 -4.73*
Source: Author’s Calculation using EViews 12.
Note: (*), (**) & (***) show 1%, 5% and 10% level of significance respectively.

From the results, both tests confirm budget deficit is stationary at its level data [I(0)]
and first difference [I(1)]. However, money supply (M2), NCPI, NEER and ICPI are
all stationary at the first difference [I (1)]. This implies that some series are stationary
at I(0) and some are at I(1). Due to the presence of mixed orders of integration (I(0),
I(1)), an appropriate method of analyzing the long run relationship between variables
is Autoregressive Distributed Lagged (ARDL) bounds test (Pesaran et al., 2000).
Therefore, this study used ARDL bound test approach to examine the cointegrating
relationship among variables under study. Following the confirmation of stationarity
properties of the variables, the study proceeds with the Autoregressive Distributive
Lag model of cointegration.

4.2.3 Bound Test Results


The calculated F- statistics, the lower bound critical value I(0) and upper bound
critical value I(1) are presented in the Table 4.3. Calculated F-statistics is compared
with the Pesaran et al. (2001) critical value.

39
Table 4.3: Bound Test Results
Variables F-Statistics Co-integration Lag Optimal
F (LnNCPI , 11.42* Co-integration (1, 0, 1, 0, 0, 1)
LnM2, Critical value Lower bound I(0) Upper bound I(1)
LnBD,
1% 3.5 4.8
LnRGDP,
5% 2.6 3.7
LnNEER,
LnICPI) 10% 2.2 3.2
Source: Author’s Calculation using EViews 12.
Note: (*), (**) & (***) show 1%, 5% and 10% level of significance respectively.

The calculated F-statistic is 11.42 which is greater than upper bound critical values at
1, 5 and 10 percent level of significance. This implies that the null hypothesis of no
co-integration among the variables is rejected. Therefore, there is cointegration
between inflation, money supply and budget deficit in long-run i.e., these variables
move in the same direction in long-run.

4.2.4 Estimated Long-run Coefficients


The estimated long-run coefficients are presented in table 4.4. The coefficients of
money supply (M2), real gross domestic product (RGDP), Indian inflation (ICPT) and
exchange rate (NEER) are positive and statistically significant as expected.
Table 4.4: Estimated long-run coefficients
Dependent Variable: LnNCPI
Variable Coefficient Standard Error T- Statistics
LnM2 0.22* 0.05 3.81
LnBD 0.004 0.02 0.20
LnRGDP 0.05* 0.01 2.77
LnNEER 0.14* 0.02 7.04
LnICPI 0.54* 0.12 4.49
C -1.15* 0.34 -3.39
Source: Author’s Calculation using EViews 12.
Note: (*), (**) & (***) show 1%, 5% and 10% level of significance respectively.

The long-run elasticity of M2 is 0.22 which indicates that money supply is positively
related to inflation and inflation increases by 0.22 percent as money supply increases
by 1 percent. Similarly, long-run elasticity of RGDP is 0.05 percent which implies

40
that an increase in RGDP by one precent increases inflation by 0.05 percent.
Moreover, the long-run coefficient of Indian inflation (ICPI) is 0.54 which shows that
Nepalese inflation increases by 0.54 percent as Indian inflation (ICPI) increases by 1
percent. The positive and statistically significant long-run coefficient of exchange rate
(NEER) suggests that the devaluation of currency by 1 percent increases inflation by
0.14 percent. However, budget deficit is positive as expected but statistically
insignificant.

4.2.5 Estimated Short-run Coefficients and Diagnostic Tests


Table 4.5 reports the short-run coefficient estimates obtained from the ECM version
of the ARDL model.
Table 4.5: Estimated Short-run Coefficients and Diagnostic Tests
Dependent variable: LnNCPI
Variables Coefficients Standard Error T- Statistics
D(LnBD) 0.18 0.01 1.49
D(LnICPI) 0.63* 0.05 11.72
ECM (-1) -0.77 0.08 9.6
Diagnostic Tests
Serial Correlation F(2, 36) = 2.27 [0.11]
Normality 0.45[0.79]
Heteroscedasticity F(8, 38) = 1.12[0.31]
R2 0.99
Adj. R2 0.99
F- Stat. 1594*
DW- Stat. 1.77
Source: Author’s Calculation using EViews 12.
Note: (*), (**) & (***) show 1%, 5% and 10% level of significance respectively.

As expected, Indian CPI has a positive impact on Nepalese CPI in the short run. The
short-run elasticity of Indian CPI is 0.63 and is significant 1 percent. This shows that
a 1 percent increase in Indian CPI results in a 0.63 percent increase in Nepalese CPI.
However, as in the long-run, budget deficit (BD) is positive but statistically
insignificant. The ECM coefficient is - 0.77 and is statistically significant at a 1
percent level of significance. This shows that short-run disequilibrium on the system
converges to equilibrium at a speed of 77 percent per annum.

41
The study also carried out all diagnostic tests such as Breusch-Godfrey serial
correlation test for serial correlation, Breusch-Pagan – Godfrey test for
heteroskedasticity test and Jarque-Berra test for normality. The result of Breusch-
Godfrey serial correlation test showed that there is no serial correlation because p
value is greater than 5 percent and this accepts the null hypothesis of no serial
correlation. The result of Breusch-Pagan –Godfrey test of heteroskedasticity showed
that there is no heteroskedasticity because p value is greater than 5 percent and this
accepts the null hypothesis of no heteroskedasticity. The result of Jarque –Bera test of
normality showed that there is normality in residuals because p value Jarque –Bera
test is greater than 5 percent which accepted the null hypothesis of there is normality
in residuals. The results of diagnostic tests indicated that the model was correctly
specified. The results of diagnostic tests show that there is no serial correlation, no
heterscedasticity and there is normality in residuals. The results of R squares and F-
statistics showed that the model is well fitted.

4.2.5 Stability Test


The stability test of the model as well as individual parameters were carried out by
plotting cumulative sum of recursive residuals (CUSUM) and the cumulative sum of
squares of residuals (CUSUMQ). The results of CUSM and CUSUMQ for model 1
and 2 are shown in Figures 4.8.

In both models, the residuals are within the critical bounds at the 5 percent
significance level which indicated that the model was correctly specified and stable.

42
Figure 4.8: Plot of CUSUM and CUSUMQ
1.4
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
-0.2
-0.4
15 20 25 30 35 40 45

CUSUM of Squares 5% Significance

20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
15 20 25 30 35 40 45

CUSUM 5% Significance

Source: Author’s Calculation


Note: The straight line represents critical bounds at 5 percent level of significance.

In both models, the residuals are within the critical bounds at the percent significance
level which indicated that the model was correctly specified and stable.

43
REFERENCES

Adom, P. K., Agradi, M. P., & Quaidoo, C. (2018). The transition probabilities for
inflation episodes in Ghana. International Journal of Emerging
Markets, 13(6), 2028-2046.

Akcay, O. C., Alper, C. E., & Ozmucur, S. (1996). Budget deficit, money supply and
inflation: Evidence from low and high frequency data for Turkey. Bogazici
University Research Papers, 12.

Alam, M. M., Sadekin, M. N., & Saha, S. K. (2022). The impact of macroeconomic
variables on the budget deficit in Bangladesh: an econometric analysis. South
Asian Journal of Business Studies, 11(2), 216-234.

Amassoma, D., Sunday, K., & Onyedikachi, E. E. (2018). The influence of money
supply on inflation in Nigeria. Journal of Economics and Management, (31),
5-23.

Adu, G., & Marbuah, G. (2011). Determinants of inflation in Ghana: An empirical


investigation. South African Journal of Economics, 79(3), 251–
269. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1813-6982.2011.01273.

Byanjankar, R. (2020). Determinants of inflation in Nepal: An application of ARDL


bounds testing approach to cointegration (Vol. 48). NRB Working Paper.

Chaudhary, S. K., & Xiumin, L. (2018). Analysis of the determinants of inflation in


Nepal. American Journal of Economics, 8(5), 209-212.

Duodu, E., Baidoo, S. T., Yusif, H., & Frimpong, P. B. (2022). Money supply, budget
deficit and inflation dynamics in Ghana: An empirical investigation. Cogent
Business & Management, 9(1), 2043810.

Eita, J. H., Manuel, V., Naimhwaka, E., & Nakusera, F. (2021). The impact of fiscal
deficit on inflation in Namibia. Journal of central banking theory and
practice, 10(1), 141-164.

Ferguson, R. W. (2005). Speech delivered at the Cato Institute, 23rd Annual Monetary
Conference on Monetary Institutions and Economic Development.

Friedman, M. (1963). Inflation: Causes and consequences. Asia Publishing House.

44
Friedman, M. (1977). Nobel lecture: Inflation and unemployment. Journal of political
economy, 85(3), 451-472.

Frisch, H. (1989). Inflation Theories. Elif Printing Limited, Istanbul, Turkey.

Ghartey, E. E. (2001). Macroeconomic instability and inflationary financing in


Ghana. Economic Modelling, 18(3), 415-433.

Institute for Sustainable Development (1994). Inflation in Nepal. Economic Review


Kathmandu: Nepal Rastra Bank Occasional Paper No.7 pp. 99 – 108

Istiqomah, N., & Mafruhah, I. (2022). The effect of budget deficit in Indonesia: A
comparative study. Economics Development Analysis Journal, 11(1), 110-119.

IMF (2014). IMF Country Report No. 14/336. Denmark, Financial System Stability
Assessment, IMF Publication Services, Washington, December, 1-48.

Iqbal, M. A., Nadim, N., & Akbar, Z. (2022). Determinants of recent inflation in
Pakistan and its relation with economic growth: An Econometric
Analysis. Pakistan Journal of Humanities and Social Sciences, 10(1), 345-
353.

Fisher, I. (1911). The purchasing power of money. New York: MacMillan.

Kaur, G. (2021). Inflation and fiscal deficit in India: An ARDL approach. Global
Business Review, 22(6), 1553-1573.

Khatiwada, Y. R. (1994). Some aspects of monetary policy in Nepal. New Delhi:


South Asian Publishers.

Kotwal, O. P. (1987). Theories of Inflation: A Critical Survey. The McGraw-Hill


Publishing Companies.

Kovanen, A. (2011). IMF Working Papers. London. United Kingdom: Palgrave


Macmillan, 1–23.

Lakshmanasamy, T. (2022). Inflation and macroeconomic performance in India:


Vector Error Correction Model Estimation of the Causal Effects. JQFE, 4, 17-
37.

Lozano-Espitia, I. (2008). Budget deficit, money growth and inflation: evidence from
the Colombian case. Borradores de Economía; No. 537.
45
Mathema, S. R. (1998). Determinants of Inflation with special reference to wages in
Nepal. NRB Economic Review, 10, 1-18.

Nasir, M. A., Balsalobre-Lorente, D., & Huynh, T. L. D. (2020). Anchoring inflation


expectations in the face of oil shocks & in the proximity of ZLB: A tale of two
targeters. Energy Economics, 86, 104662.

Neupane, G. P. (1992). Causes of inflation in Nepal: A quantitative analysis. NRB


Economic review, 6, 33-49.

Nguyen, B. (2015). Effects of fiscal deficit and money M2 supply on inflation: Evidence
from selected economies of Asia. Journal of Economics, Finance and
Administrative Science, 20(1), 49–
53. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jefas.2015.01.002

NRB. 2007. Inflation in Nepal. NRB Special Publication, Nepal Rastra Bank.
Kathmandu.

Pandey, R. P. (2005). Inflation, 50 years of Nepal Rastra Bank. Nepal Rastra Bank,
Kathmandu, Nepal.

Paudyal, S. B. (2014). Determinants of inflation in Nepal: An empirical


assessment. NRB Economic Review, 26(2), 61-82.

Philips, A. W. (1958). The Relationship between Unemployment and the Rate of


Change of Money in the UK 1861-1957. Economica, 25, 283-99.

Sowa, N. K. (1994). Fiscal deficits, output growth and inflation targets in


Ghana. World Development, 22(8), 1105-1117.

Sebulime, K. & Edward, B. (2019). Budget deficit and inflation nexus in Uganda
1980 – 2016: A co-integration and error correction modelling approach.
Journal of Economic Structures, 8(3): 1-14.

Tufail, S. & Batool, S. (2013). An analysis of the relationship between inflation and
gold prices: Evidence from Pakistan. The Lahore journal of economics, 18(2),
1-35.

46
Wang, X., Xu, Z., Wang, X., & Skare, M. (2022). A review of inflation from 1906 to
2022: A comprehensive analysis of inflation studies from a global
perspective. Oeconomia Copernicana, 13(3), 595-631.

Woodford, M. (1995, December). Price-level determinacy without control of a


monetary aggregate. In Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public
policy (Vol. 43, pp. 1-46). North-Holland.

47
Appendices
Appendix I: Nominal Variables Used in the Table (Rs. in million)
Fiscal NCPI M2 BD RGDP at NEER ICPI
Years 2010 price
1974/75 5.81 2064.4 507 348744.4 144.94 8
1975/76 5.77 2524 801 360839.8 121.48 8
1976/77 5.92 3223 999 364485.3 120.96 7
1977/78 6.58 3772.1 1122 375885.4 107.62 8
1978/79 6.81 4511.4 1223 383892.8 97.09 8
1979/80 7.48 5285.3 1614 378119.0 91.98 9
1980/81 8.48 6307.7 1692 416048.9 95.17 10
1981/82 9.36 7458 2685 434402.8 92.29 11
1982/83 10.69 9222.4 4144 436172.9 82.09 12
1983/84 11.35 10455.2 4031 474545.3 90.93 13
1984/85 11.82 12296.6 4478 500084.8 91.98 14
1985/86 13.70 15159 5153 522917.4 65.21 15
1986/87 15.51 17498.2 5538 531805.7 63.38 17
1987/88 17.19 21422.6 6815 572736.9 55.60 18
1988/89 18.62 26605.1 10228 597523.2 44.66 20
1989/90 20.42 31552.4 10381 625218.7 39.62 21
1990/91 22.43 37712.5 12819 665022.8 47.78 23
1991/92 27.15 45670.5 12906 692342.5 45.61 26
1992/93 29.56 58322.5 15749 718975.2 40.43 29
1993/94 32.20 69777.1 14017 778069.4 44.69 31
1994/95 34.67 80984.7 14485 805056.4 45.22 34
1995/96 37.49 92652.2 18649 848027.2 47.45 38
1996/97 40.52 103721 20350 892641.6 41.72 41
1997/98 43.89 126463 23180 918903.8 48.90 44
1998/99 48.89 152800 22328 960104.9 56.30 50
1999/00 50.55 186121 23383 1018820.2 59.48 52
2000/01 51.78 214454 30942 1076163.8 71.99 54
2001/02 53.27 223988 18339 1077456.9 83.14 56
2002/03 55.80 245911 12577 1119963.7 84.67 59

48
2003/04 58.01 277306 12663 1172407.2 87.28 61
2004/05 60.65 300440 14295 1213196.4 92.70 63
2005/06 65.48 346824 16428 1254015.0 95.47 66
2006/07 69.34 395518 18763 1296797.8 93.82 70
2007/08 73.99 495377 22476 1375962.0 97.28 74
2008/09 83.30 630521 34356 1438336.2 87.48 81
2009/10 91.27 719599 40732 1507612.3 89.43 89
2010/11 100.00 921320 50506 1559200.0 100.00 100
2011/12 108.32 1130302 28905 1632040.5 98.16 109
2012/13 118.97 1315376 36672 1689572.4 99.33 119
2013/14 129.78 1565967 18170 1791140.8 100.25 131
2014/15 139.14 1877802 68307 1862357.5 95.84 140
2015/16 152.97 2244579 56682 1870423.6 92.22 147
2016/17 159.77 2591702 188695 2038336.7 95.71 154
2017/18 166.41 3094467 305499 2193706.4 96.88 159
2018/19 174.12 3582138 180505 2339742.7 97.17 165
2019/20 184.83 4230970 267450 2284299.7 93.58 172
2020/21 191.48 5154853 262690 2394800.0 96.39 183
2021/22 203.59 5505401 263666 2529200.0 96.05 192
Source: Various publications.

49
Appendix II: Percentage Change in the Variables Used in the Study (Rs. in million)
Fiscal Years NCPI M2 BD RGDP NEER ICPI
1974/75 - - - - - -
1975/76 -0.7 22.3 58.1 3.5 -16.2 5.75
1976/77 2.7 27.7 24.6 1.0 -0.4 -7.63
1977/78 11.2 17.0 12.3 3.1 -11.0 8.31
1978/79 3.4 19.6 9.0 2.1 -9.8 2.52
1979/80 9.8 17.2 32.0 -1.5 -5.3 6.28
1980/81 13.4 19.3 4.9 10.0 3.5 11.35
1981/82 10.4 18.2 58.7 4.4 -3.0 13.11
1982/83 14.2 23.7 54.3 0.4 -11.0 7.89
1983/84 6.2 13.4 -2.7 8.8 10.8 11.87
1984/85 4.1 17.6 11.1 5.4 1.2 8.32
1985/86 15.8 23.3 15.1 4.6 -29.1 5.56
1986/87 13.3 15.4 7.5 1.7 -2.8 8.73
1987/88 10.8 22.4 23.0 7.7 -12.3 8.80
1988/89 8.3 24.2 50.1 4.3 -19.7 9.38
1989/90 9.7 18.6 1.5 4.6 -11.3 7.07
1990/91 9.8 19.5 23.5 6.4 20.6 8.97
1991/92 21.1 21.1 0.7 4.1 -4.5 13.87
1992/93 8.9 27.7 22.0 3.8 -11.4 11.79
1993/94 8.9 19.6 -11.0 8.2 10.5 6.33
1994/95 7.7 16.1 3.3 3.5 1.2 10.25
1995/96 8.1 14.4 28.8 5.3 4.9 10.22
1996/97 8.1 11.9 9.1 5.3 -12.1 8.98
1997/98 8.3 21.9 13.9 2.9 17.2 7.16
1998/99 11.4 20.8 -3.7 4.5 15.1 13.23
1999/00 3.4 21.8 4.7 6.1 5.7 4.67
2000/01 2.4 15.2 32.3 5.6 21.0 4.01
2001/02 2.9 4.4 -40.7 0.1 15.5 3.78
2002/03 4.7 9.8 -31.4 3.9 1.8 4.30
2003/04 4.0 12.8 0.7 4.7 3.1 3.81
2004/05 4.5 8.3 12.9 3.5 6.2 3.77
2005/06 8.0 15.4 14.9 3.4 3.0 4.25
2006/07 5.9 14.0 14.2 3.4 -1.7 5.80

50
2007/08 6.7 25.2 19.8 6.1 3.7 6.37
2008/09 12.6 27.3 52.9 4.5 -10.1 8.35
2009/10 9.6 14.1 18.6 4.8 2.2 10.88
2010/11 9.6 28.0 24.0 3.4 11.8 11.99
2011/12 8.3 22.7 -42.8 4.7 -1.8 8.91
2012/13 9.8 16.4 26.9 3.5 1.2 9.48
2013/14 9.1 19.1 -50.5 6.0 0.9 10.02
2014/15 7.2 19.9 275.9 4.0 -4.4 6.67
2015/16 9.9 19.5 -17.0 0.4 -3.8 4.91
2016/17 4.4 15.5 232.9 9.0 3.8 4.95
2017/18 4.2 19.4 61.9 7.6 1.2 3.33
2018/19 4.6 15.8 -40.9 6.7 0.3 3.94
2019/20 6.2 18.1 48.2 -2.4 -3.7 3.73
2020/21 3.6 21.8 -1.8 4.8 3.0 6.62
2021/22 6.3 6.8 0.4 5.6 -0.3 5.13
Source: Author’s calculation from the Appendix I

51
Appendix III: Log form of Variables used in the Study / Model
Fiscal LnNCPI LnM2 LnBD LnRGDP LnNEER LnICPI
Years
1974/75 0.76 3.31 2.70 5.54 2.16 0.88
1975/76 0.76 3.40 2.90 5.56 2.08 0.90
1976/77 0.77 3.51 3.00 5.56 2.08 0.87
1977/78 0.82 3.58 3.05 5.58 2.03 0.90
1978/79 0.83 3.65 3.09 5.58 1.99 0.92
1979/80 0.87 3.72 3.21 5.58 1.96 0.94
1980/81 0.93 3.80 3.23 5.62 1.98 0.99
1981/82 0.97 3.87 3.43 5.64 1.97 1.04
1982/83 1.03 3.96 3.62 5.64 1.91 1.07
1983/84 1.06 4.02 3.61 5.68 1.96 1.12
1984/85 1.07 4.09 3.65 5.70 1.96 1.16
1985/86 1.14 4.18 3.71 5.72 1.81 1.18
1986/87 1.19 4.24 3.74 5.73 1.80 1.22
1987/88 1.24 4.33 3.83 5.76 1.75 1.25
1988/89 1.27 4.42 4.01 5.78 1.65 1.29
1989/90 1.31 4.50 4.02 5.80 1.60 1.32
1990/91 1.35 4.58 4.11 5.82 1.68 1.36
1991/92 1.43 4.66 4.11 5.84 1.66 1.42
1992/93 1.47 4.77 4.20 5.86 1.61 1.47
1993/94 1.51 4.84 4.15 5.89 1.65 1.49
1994/95 1.54 4.91 4.16 5.91 1.66 1.53
1995/96 1.57 4.97 4.27 5.93 1.68 1.58
1996/97 1.61 5.02 4.31 5.95 1.62 1.61
1997/98 1.64 5.10 4.37 5.96 1.69 1.64
1998/99 1.69 5.18 4.35 5.98 1.75 1.70
1999/00 1.70 5.27 4.37 6.01 1.77 1.72
2000/01 1.71 5.33 4.49 6.03 1.86 1.74
2001/02 1.73 5.35 4.26 6.03 1.92 1.75
2002/03 1.75 5.39 4.10 6.05 1.93 1.77

52
2003/04 1.76 5.44 4.10 6.07 1.94 1.79
2004/05 1.78 5.48 4.16 6.08 1.97 1.80
2005/06 1.82 5.54 4.22 6.10 1.98 1.82
2006/07 1.84 5.60 4.27 6.11 1.97 1.84
2007/08 1.87 5.69 4.35 6.14 1.99 1.87
2008/09 1.92 5.80 4.54 6.16 1.94 1.91
2009/10 1.96 5.86 4.61 6.18 1.95 1.95
2010/11 2.00 5.96 4.70 6.19 2.00 2.00
2011/12 2.03 6.05 4.46 6.21 1.99 2.04
2012/13 2.08 6.12 4.56 6.23 2.00 2.08
2013/14 2.11 6.19 4.26 6.25 2.00 2.12
2014/15 2.14 6.27 4.83 6.27 1.98 2.15
2015/16 2.18 6.35 4.75 6.27 1.96 2.17
2016/17 2.20 6.41 5.28 6.31 1.98 2.19
2017/18 2.22 6.49 5.49 6.34 1.99 2.20
2018/19 2.24 6.55 5.26 6.37 1.99 2.22
2019/20 2.27 6.63 5.43 6.36 1.97 2.23
2020/21 2.28 6.71 5.42 6.38 1.98 2.26
2021/22 2.31 6.74 5.42 6.40 1.98 2.28

53
10
11
12
13

6
7
8
9

10
11
12
13
14
15
16

7
8
9
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5

1974/75 1974/75 1974/75


1977/78 1977/78 1977/78
1980/81 1980/81 1980/81
1983/84 1983/84 1983/84
1986/87 1986/87 1986/87
1989/90 1989/90 1989/90
1992/93 1992/93 1992/93
1995/96

InM2
1995/96 1995/96
Fiscal Year
1998/99

Fiscal Year
1998/99 1998/99

54
2001/02 2001/02 2001/02

2004/05 2004/05 2004/05

InBD
InNCPI

Fiscal Year
2007/08 2007/08 2007/08

2010/11 2010/11 2010/11


2013/14
Appendix IV: Graph of M2, BD & NCPI

2013/14 2013/14
2016/17 2016/17
2016/17
2019/20 2019/20
2019/20
Appendix V: F-bound Test Result and Estimated Long-run Coefficients
ARDL Long Run Form and Bounds Test
Dependent Variable: D(INNCPI)
Selected Model: ARDL(1, 0, 1, 0, 0, 1)
Case 2: Restricted Constant and No Trend
Date: 09/20/23 Time: 15:41
Sample: 1 48
Included observations: 47

Conditional Error Correction Regression

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C -0.892053 0.217621 -4.099116 0.0002


INNCPI(-1)* -0.770144 0.150060 -5.132227 0.0000
INM2** 0.173465 0.035915 4.829825 0.0000
INBD(-1) 0.003706 0.018125 0.204453 0.8391
INRGDP** 0.041684 0.012448 3.348640 0.0018
INNEER** -0.109232 0.020296 -5.381904 0.0000
INICPI(-1) 0.418949 0.160383 2.612173 0.0128
D(INBD) -0.018112 0.017175 -1.054568 0.2983
D(INICPI) 0.631853 0.136748 4.620570 0.0000

* p-value incompatible with t-Bounds distribution.


** Variable interpreted as Z = Z(-1) + D(Z).

Levels Equation
Case 2: Restricted Constant and No Trend

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

INM2 0.225237 0.059041 3.814948 0.0005


INBD 0.004812 0.023381 0.205790 0.8381
INRGDP 0.054124 0.019495 2.776265 0.0085
INNEER 0.141833 0.020138 7.043010 0.0000
INICPI 0.543987 0.120935 4.498188 0.0001
C -1.158293 0.341495 -3.391829 0.0016

EC = INNCPI - (0.2252*INM2 + 0.0048*INBD + 0.0541*INRGDP + 0.1418


*INNEER + 0.5440*INICPI - 1.1583)

F-Bounds Test Null Hypothesis: No levels relationship

Test Statistic Value Signif. I(0) I(1)

Asymptotic: n=1000
F-statistic 11.42780 10% 2.08 3
k 5 5% 2.39 3.38
2.5% 2.7 3.73
1% 3.06 4.15

Actual Sample Size 47 Finite Sample: n=50


10% 2.259 3.264
5% 2.67 3.781
1% 3.593 4.981

Finite Sample: n=45


10% 2.276 3.297
5% 2.694 3.829
1% 3.674 5.019

55
Appendix VI: Estimated Short-run Coefficients

ARDL Error Correction Regression


Dependent Variable: D(INNCPI)
Selected Model: ARDL(1, 0, 1, 0, 0, 1)
Case 2: Restricted Constant and No Trend
Date: 09/20/23 Time: 16:11
Sample: 1 48
Included observations: 47

ECM Regression
Case 2: Restricted Constant and No Trend

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

D(INBD) -0.018112 0.012082 -1.499026 0.1421


D(INICPI) 0.631853 0.053894 11.72402 0.0000
CointEq(-1)* -0.770144 0.080022 -9.624207 0.0000

R-squared 0.738803 Mean dependent var 0.075683


Adjusted R-squared 0.726931 S.D. dependent var 0.036753
S.E. of regression 0.019206 Akaike info criterion -5.005514
Sum squared resid 0.016230 Schwarz criterion -4.887420
Log likelihood 120.6296 Hannan-Quinn criter. -4.961074
Durbin-Watson stat 1.775727

* p-value incompatible with t-Bounds distribution.

F-Bounds Test Null Hypothesis: No levels relationship

Test Statistic Value Signif. I(0) I(1)

F-statistic 11.42780 10% 2.08 3


k 5 5% 2.39 3.38
2.5% 2.7 3.73
1% 3.06 4.15

56

You might also like