Poutineau (2015) PDF
Poutineau (2015) PDF
Poutineau (2015) PDF
Economics
and Business
Review
Volume 1 (15)Number
Volume 1 (15) Number 2 2015
2 2015
CONTENTS
ARTICLES
A perspective on leading and managing organizational change
Stanley J. Smits, Dawn E. Bowden
Alternative configurations of firm-level employment systems: evidence from American
companies
Bruce E. Kaufman, Benjamin I. Miller
How team leaders can improve virtual team collaboration through trust and ICT:
A conceptual model proposition
David Kauffmann
International trade in differentiated goods, financial crisis and the gravity equation
Udo Broll, Julia Jauer
Tax revenues and aging in ex-communist EU countries
Mihai Mutascu, Maciej Cieślukowski
The analytics of the New Keynesian 3-equation Model
Jean-Christophe Poutineau, Karolina Sobczak, Gauthier Vermandel
Investments and long-term real interest rate in Poland. Study of investment structure,
current account and their correlation with long-term real interest rates
Jakub Krawczyk, Szymon Filipczak
BOOK REVIEWS
Paweł Marszałek, Systemy pieniężne wolnej bankowości. Koncepcje cechy, zastosowanie
[Free Banking Monetary Systems. Concepts, Characteristics, Application], Wydawnictwo
Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Poznaniu, Poznań 2014 (Bogusław Pietrzak)
Ewa Mińska-Struzik, Od eksportu do innowacji. Uczenie się przez eksport polskich
przedsiębiorców [From Export to Innovation – Learning by Exporting in Polish Enterprises],
Difin, Warszawa 2014 (Jan Rymarczyk)
Thematic Editors
Economics: Ryszard Barczyk, Tadeusz Kowalski, Ida Musiałkowska, Jacek Wallusch, Maciej Żukowski •
Econometrics: Witold Jurek, Jacek Wallusch • Finance: Witold Jurek, Cezary Kochalski • Management and
Marketing: Henryk Mruk, Cezary Kochalski, Ida Musiałkowska, Jerzy Schroeder • Statistics: Elżbieta Gołata,
Krzysztof Szwarc
Language Editor: Owen Easteal • IT Editor: Piotr Stolarski
ISSN 2392-1641
Abstract: This paper aims at providing a self contained presentation of the ideas and
solution procedure of New Keynesian Macroeconomics models. Using the benchmark
“3 equation model”, we introduce the reader to an intuitive, static version of the model
before incorporating more technical aspects associated with the dynamic nature of the
model. We then discuss the relative contribution of supply, demand and policy shocks
to the fluctuations of activity, inflation and interest rate, depending on the key under-
lying parameters of the economy.
Keywords: dynamic IS curve, impulse response analysis, New Keynesian Macro
economics, New Keynesian Phillips Curve, output gap, Taylor rule.
JEL codes: C63, E12, E32, E52.
Introduction
Keynesian ideas returned to the forefront of academic research in the mid 90’s
in new clothes to address questions related to unemployment, economic fluc-
tuations and inflation. This followed a twenty year period that witnessed the
domination of new classical ideas on both monetary and real macroeconom-
ics questions. Before contributing to the building of what is now considered
as the workhouse of modern macroeconomics [Carlin and Soskice 2014], the
New Keynesian School proposed in the 80’s a series of models aimed at provid-
ing microeconomic foundations to price and/or wage rigidity5 and at showing
1
Article received 15 April 2014, accepted 19 February 2015.
2
CREM-CNRS, University of Rennes 1, Faculty of Economics, 7 place Hoche, 35065 Rennes
cedex, France, corresponding author: [email protected].
3
Poznań University of Economics, Department of Mathematical Economy, Poznań, Poland.
4
CREM-CNRS, University of Rennes 1, Faculty of Economics, Rennes, France.
5
On New Keynesianism, its history, development and significance for modern economics,
see for example Bludnik [2009] or Romer [1993].
J.-C. Poutineau, K. Sobczak, G. Vermandel, The analytics of the New Keynesian 111
that this key feature of the real world can be explained in a setting with opti-
mizing agents with market power. An important breakthrough was about 15
years ago, with the papers of Goodfriend and King [1997] and Clarida, Gali,
and Gertler [1999]. These contributions introduced a framework mixing Real
Business Cycle features with nominal rigidities. This setting now forms the ba-
sic analytical structure of contemporaneous macroeconomic models as exem-
plified by Woodford [2003] or Gali [2008].
Besides new ideas and a new modelling strategy this New Keynesian
Synthesis (NKS) has adopted new solution procedures that may appear cum-
bersome to non-specialists. Because of their recursive structure NKS models
do not admit a closed form solution but should be solved by borrowing proce-
dures developed for the analysis of stochastic discrete time dynamics systems.6
The aim of this paper is to provide a compact and self contained presentation of
the structure and of the standard solution procedure of the basic NKS frame-
work known as the “three equation model”. We particularly separate the main
ideas conveyed by this model, using a static version of the reference framework,
from the technical aspects of the solution procedure. In the presentation we
emphasise the qualitative similarities between the simple graphical analysis of
the static model and the Impulse Response Functions (IRFs) of the model fol-
lowing the occurrence of exogenous shocks. We then illustrate the key features
of this model regarding the analysis of business cycles characteristics.
The paper is organized as follows: In the first section we introduce the gen-
eral structure of a benchmark NKS model that combines (the log linear versions
of) a Philips curve, an Euler equation and a monetary policy (Taylor) rule.7 In
the second section we set a simple static version of the model to obtain closed
form solutions for the key macroeconomic variables and to provide the reader
with a graphical analysis of the consequences of demand and supply shocks.
In the third section we introduce the Blanchard-Kahn solution procedure to
get IRFs and dynamic reactions of the model around a stable steady state fol-
lowing exogenous supply demand and policy shocks. This third section is also
devoted to a discussion of business cycles characteristics of the model. Section
four concludes.
6
For an up to date exhaustive introduction to this literature see Miao [2014].
7
In the appendix we provide the micro foundations of the framework used in this paper.
112 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 1(15), No. 2, 2015
shocks and to replicate business cycle statistics. The core representation of this
synthesis has given rise to what is called the “3-equation model” as the basic
NKS setting reduces to a system of three equations corresponding to an AS-
AD model. First, the AS curve is represented by the New Keynesian Phillips
curve that relates inflation to the output gap. Second, the AD component of the
model combines a dynamic IS curve (that relates the evolution of the output
gap to the interest rate) and a MP (Monetary Policy) schedule (that describes
how the nominal interest rate is set by the central bank following fluctuations
in the output gap and in the inflation rate. This model is based on agents‘ mi-
cro founded decision rules where consumers maximize their welfare subject
to an intertemporal budget constraint and where firms maximize their profit,
subject to nominal rigidities, characterising the imperfect adjustment of pric-
es on the goods market. For convenience the micro foundations of this model
and the derivation of the log-linear system are presented in appendix. These
equations in turn determine three main variables of interest in a closed econ-
omy, namely the output gap ( yˆt) which is the gap between the effective output
and potential output, the inflation rate (πˆt) and the nominal interest rate (rˆt).
Formally, the model is defined as follows:
The New Keynesian Philips’ Curve (PC) links current inflation (πˆt) to ex-
pected future inflation (Et {πˆt +1}), to the current output gap ( yˆt) and to an ex-
ogenous supply shock that takes the form of a cost push shock (εtS):8
8
In the paper all parameters are positive.
9
This assumption is commonly adopted in the literature to characterize exogenous shocks
[see for example, Gali 2008 for a discussion].
J.-C. Poutineau, K. Sobczak, G. Vermandel, The analytics of the New Keynesian 113
derived from the Calvo model [1983] which combines staggered price-setting
by imperfectly competitive firms. As presented in the appendix, the Calvo ap-
proach assumes that in each period, only a fraction θ of firms, randomly cho-
sen, can reset their selling prices10. Using this assumption, Clarida, Gali, and
Gertler [1999] show that the Phillips curve then takes a particularly simple
form in which inflation depends on the current gap between actual and equi-
librium output as in the standard Phillips curve but on expected future infla-
tion rather than on past inflation.
The dynamic IS curve is a log linearization of the Euler bond equation that
describes the intertemporal allocation of consumption of agents in the economy:
1
yˆ t = Et { yˆ t +1} − ( rˆ − Et {πˆt +1}) + εtD.
σ t
(2)
This relation plays the same role as the IS curve in the IS-LM model. As
shown in the appendix it comes from the intertemporal optimization of the
welfare index of a representative consumer subject to its budget constraint.
Once aggregated over consumers and log-linearized around the steady state
this relation can be expressed in terms of the output gap ( yˆt). The dynamic IS
curve links the current output gap to the difference between the real interest
rate (rˆt − Et {πˆt +1}), to the expected future output gap (Et { yˆ t +1}) and to an ex-
ogenous preference shock εtD (that represents a demand shock henceforth). The
demand shock is described in a standard way by AR(1) process of the form:
εtD = ρ D εtD−1 + ηtD with ηtD ~ N (0, σ D2 ) and is iid.
The Monetary Policy schedule (MP) is based on the Taylor rule. It links the
nominal interest rate (that is controlled by monetary authorities) to the infla-
tion rate and to the output gap:11
In this equation variable εtR denotes a monetary policy shock that follows
an AR(1) process of the form: εtR = ρ R εtR−1 + ηtR with ηtR ~ N (0, σ R2 ) and iid. This
shock identifies monetary policy decisions which imply deviations from the
standard Taylor rule such as unconventional measures or to reshape the infla-
tion expectations in the medium run. This MP schedule aims at replacing the
standard LM curve commonly found in the standard AS-AD model. It pro-
poses an up-to-date description of the behaviour of central banks that control
a short run nominal interest rate instead of a monetary aggregate [Clarida,
Gali, and Gertler 1999].
10
Baranowski et al. [2013] propose an endogenous mechanism.
11
In appendices, we provide an interest rate smoothing with smoothing parameter ρ. In this
section we neglect these features such that ρ = 0.
114 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 1(15), No. 2, 2015
π = π0 + κy + εS, (4)
y = y0 – σr + εD,(5)
In equilibrium the values of the output gap y*, the inflation rate π* and the in-
terest rate r* solution to the model (4)–(6) are a linear combination of exog-
enous shocks:
y0 σϕ π S σ R 1 D
y* = − ε − ε + ε ,
Ω Ω Ω Ω
κ σκ R κ D Ω − κσϕ π S
12
Dynamic aspects will π −π0 = y0in−Section
be*reintroduced ε +3. ε + ε ,
Ω Ω Ω Ω
r* =
( )
ϕ πκ + ϕ y y0 ϕ πκ + ϕ y D ϕ π S 1 R
+ ε + ε + ε ,
Ω Ω Ω Ω
π
y0 G. Vermandel,
J.-C. Poutineau, K. Sobczak, σϕ S σTheR analytics
1 D of the New Keynesian 115
y* = − ε − ε + ε ,
Ω Ω Ω Ω
κ σκ R κ D Ω − κσϕ π S
π * −π0 = y0 − ε + ε + ε ,
Ω Ω Ω Ω
r* =
( +
)
ϕ πκ + ϕ y y0 ϕ πκ + ϕ y D ϕ π S 1 R
ε + ε + ε ,
Ω Ω Ω Ω
−σϕ π 1 −σ
Output gap ∂y / ∂ε <0 >0 <0
Ω Ω Ω
1 + σϕ y κ −σκ
Inflation ∂π / ∂ε >0 >0 <0
Ω Ω Ω
ϕπ ϕ πκ + ϕ y 1
Interest rate ∂r / ∂ε >0 >0 >0
Ω Ω Ω
To understand more clearly the reaction of the economy to supply and de-
mand shocks we refer the reader to figures 1 and 2. Graphically the model can
be represented as consisting of two panels: in the lower panel of each figure,
the IS-MP block (equations (5) and (6)) presented in the (y, r) space focuses
on demand side aspects and can be treated as a New Keynesian representa-
tion of the IS-LM framework; in the upper panel the AD-PC block presented
in the (y, π) space determines the global equilibrium of the economy and can
be treated as a New Keynesian representation of the AD-AS framework. The
PC curve is given by equation (4) and the AD curve is obtained by combining
equations (5) and (6) and is defined in equation (7),
y0 σϕπ 1
y= − (π − π0 ) + εtD.(7)
1 + σϕ y 1 + σ ϕ y 1 + σϕ y
116 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 1(15), No. 2, 2015
The consequences of the demand shock are presented in Figure 1. The first
panel displays the adjustment of the inflation rate and the output gap. The sec-
ond panel displays the adjustment of the demand side, accounting for the re-
action of the central bank to the shock.
π
PC
πC C
π0
A
AD’
AD
y0 yC yB y
r
MP’
rC C’ MP
B’
IS’
r0
A’
IS
y 0 yC yB y
To understand the main differences between the two panels one has just to
remember that the IS curve (5) moves one for one with a demand shock whilst
the demand curve moves by less than one. Thus, taking point A as the initial
equilibrium of the model a positive demand shock moves the IS curve from
IS to IS’ in the lower panel, which in turn, ignoring the reaction of the central
bank, moves the demand schedule to the dotted line. As the temporarily equi-
librium B implies an increase in the inflation rate the central bank reacts by
increasing the interest rate for any value of the output gap. Thus, the MP curve
in the lower panel moves left from MP to MP’. This, in turn, leads the aggre-
J.-C. Poutineau, K. Sobczak, G. Vermandel, The analytics of the New Keynesian 117
gate demand curve to move to the left from the dotted line to AD’. In the final
equilibrium C, the evolution of aggregate demand from AD to AD’, that com-
bines both the initial demand shock and the monetary reaction, is less than
proportional to the demand shock. Furthermore, with the reaction of the cen-
tral bank the increase of inflation is dampened. Finally the positive demand
shock leads to an increase in the output gap, an increase in inflation and a rise
in interest rate, as summarized in Table 1.
π PC’
PC
πB B
π0 A
AD
yB y0 y
MP’
MP
rB B’
r0 A’
IS
yB y0 y
Figure 2. Supply shock
The consequences of the supply shock are presented in Figure 2. In this ex-
ample the supply shock is a positive inflation shock (that corresponds to a de-
crease in the supply of goods ). Following this supply shock the Phillips curve
moves upwards to the left in the (y, π) space. This shock leads to an increase
in the rate of inflation and the central bank reacts by raising the interest rate.
Graphically the reaction of the central bank means increasing the interest rate
for any value of the output gap so that the MP curve moves left to MP’ in the
118 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 1(15), No. 2, 2015
lower panel of Figure 2. Once all the adjustments have been implemented the
final equilibrium lies at point B which is characterized by a negative output gap
(namely activity falls below its natural value), an increase of the inflation rate
over its targeted value and at point B’ an increase in the interest rate (needed
to dampen part of the inflation consequences of the supply shock).
Finally, the balance between the consequences of the shocks on activity and
inflation depends on the slope of the demand curve which, in turn, is affected by
the reaction of the central bank to inflation rate and output gap developments.
A more conservative central bank (namely a central bank that puts a higher
weight on inflation and a lower weight on the output gap) makes the slope of
the demand curve of the economy flatter in the upper panel of figures 1 and
2, which translates into lower fluctuations in the interest rate but to a higher
variability of the output gap. Conversely if the stance of the central bank reac-
tion is more sensitive to the output gap and less sensitive to inflation then the
MP and AD curves become steeper and shocks have a lower impact on activ-
ity and a higher impact on inflation.
13
In this paper we adopted the Blanchard-Kahn approach for solving the model, given its
anteriority and popularity in literature. However, the reader should be aware of the existence of
other methods introduced by Klein [2000] and Sims [2000]. Miao [2014] offers a nice compari-
son between these three approaches.
J.-C. Poutineau, K. Sobczak, G. Vermandel, The analytics of the New Keynesian 119
This condition reduces to the choice of appropriate values for the parameters
of the model. A sufficiently relevant condition for the previous one to be hold
is that the monetary authorities should respond more than proportionally to
inflation developments (namely, ϕπ > 1) according to the Taylor principle. In
this case a rise in inflation leads to a more than proportional rise in nominal
interest causing an increase in real interest rates that affects agents’ econom-
ic decisions and thus the real macroeconomic equilibrium of the model. The
120 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 1(15), No. 2, 2015
Benchmark regime is: ϕπ = 1.5, ϕ y = 0.5/4, inflation target regime: ϕπ = 1.7, output gap regime:
ϕ y = 0.8/4
crease in activity so that the output gap becomes positive. However, as produc-
tion overshoots its natural value this rise in activity increases the inflation rate.
Since both the output gap and inflation rate increase the central bank should
react by raising the nominal interest rate.
According to the Taylor principle the nominal interest rate increases more
than proportionally to inflation developments to affect real exchange rates. This
policy however is not sufficient to close the positive output gap immediately or
to dampen the inflation rate. The effect of monetary policy should be assessed
over time on the output gap (activity goes back to its natural value as time pass-
es) and on the rate of inflation (that converges towards its natural value). The
adjustment time path is affected by the parameter value of the Taylor rule. As
presented in Figure 3 a higher concern for inflation or output gap reduces the
volatility of both activity and inflation. Thus, stricter monetary policy leads to
more moderate responses of variables to the demand shock.
The supply shock: Figure 4 represents the consequences of a 1% increase
in inflation (i.e. the negative supply shock acts as an increase in the price of
raw materials or energy that increases the real marginal cost of production).
This shock has a direct impact on inflation that rises and overshoots its tar-
geted value. As a consequence monetary authorities should react according to
the Taylor principle by raising the interest rate. Since the increase in the nom-
inal interest rate is higher than the rate of inflation, the real rate rises. This, in
turn, negatively affects output that decreases under its natural value. However,
as time passes, the increase in the interest rate dampens inflation. Finally, the
output gap goes back to its steady state value whilst the inflation rate reaches
its targeted value. As previously for the demand shock, the time path of vari-
ables is affected by the parameter values of the Taylor rule. A higher concern
for output gap (as represented with ‘inflation target’ IRF) leads to weaker re-
sponses of real variables and stronger responses of nominal variables. Inversely
a higher concern for inflation leads to stronger responses of real variables and
weaker responses of inflation and nominal interest rate.
Benchmark regime is: ϕπ = 1.5, ϕ y = 0.5/4, inflation target regime: ϕπ = 1.7, output gap regime:
ϕ y = 0.8/4
Benchmark regime is: ϕπ = 1.5, ϕ y = 0.5/4, inflation target regime: ϕπ = 1.7, output gap regime:
ϕ y = 0.8/4
more sensitive to supply shocks) and reinforces the impact of demand shocks
on inflation (whilst , conversely, it dampens the impact of supply side shocks
on this variable). Finally, this policy has almost no noticeable effect on the rela-
tive contribution of shocks on interest rate developments. In panel 5 an output
oriented monetary policy increases the effect of supply shocks on inflation and
interest rate whilst leaving the relative contribution of shocks on activity almost
unchanged. The results obtained in these last two panels may serve as simple
guideline to determine the nature of monetary policy depending on both its
objective and the origin of shocks. If an economy is mainly affected by price
mark-up shocks monetary policy should be more closely oriented towards out-
put developments. As this policy is able to dampen the effect of supply shocks
on inflation, whilst having no noticeable effect on activity, monetary authori-
ties are able to stabilise prices more easily. In contrast if the economy is affected
by demand shocks the authorities have to use arbitrage because a more aggres-
sive policy against inflation dampens the impact of demand shocks on activity
whilst it increases the impact of demand shocks on inflation.
Conclusions
In this paper we have described in a concise way the main ideas conveyed by
the 3 equation New Keynesian model and the main elements of the solution
procedure required to analyse the dynamics of the model. To introduce the
reader to this class of models we have presented a simple static version of the
model that gives both direct reduced forms and provides the basis for a sim-
ple graphical analysis of the macroeconomic equilibrium. We have then intro-
duced the Blanchard-Kahn solution procedure and report IRFs to describe the
dynamic adjustment of the economy over periods. Finally we have used the
historical variance analysis to evaluate how a modification of values of the key
parameters of the model affect the relative contribution of supply side and de-
mand side shocks. Our aim was not to provide the reader with a comprehen-
sive and up to date catalogue of all the results obtained by this New Keynesian
literature but rather to offer a clear and simple presentation of the basic ideas
and the required technical tools needed to solve this class of models that have
become the conventional workhorse of today’s macroeconomics.
J.-C. Poutineau, K. Sobczak, G. Vermandel, The analytics of the New Keynesian 125
Appendix
A. Micro-foundations
A.1. Households
There is a continuum of households j ∈ [0; 1] with a utility function
C1−σ H 1+φ
U (Ct , H t ) = t − χ t , the representative household maximizes its wel-
1− σ 1+ φ
fare, defined as the expected stream of utilities discounted by β ∈ (0, 1):
+∞
max Et ∑ β τU (Ct +τ ( j ), H t +τ ( j ) ).(A.1)
Ct ( j ), H t ( j ), Bt ( j )
τ =0
where σ > 0 and φ > 0 are shape parameters of the utility function with respect
to consumption and to labour supply whilst χ is a shift parameter which scales
the steady state labour supply to realistic values. As in Smets and Wouters [2005]
we introduce an AR(1) demand shock process in the budget constraint of the
D
representative household denoted by εt .
After replacing the Lagrange multiplier the first order conditions are defined
by the Euler bond condition:
σ
C ( j) β R
Et t +1 = ε D Et t , (A.3)
Ct ( j) e t πt +1
Pt +1
where πt +1 = is the inflation rate and the labour supply equation is deter-
Pt
mined by:
Wt
χCt ( j)σ H t ( j)φ = .(A.4)
Pt
These equations define the optimal paths of labour and consumption and
maximize the welfare index of the representative household.
A.2. Firms
The representative firm i maximizes its profits:
max
H t (i ), Yt (i )
{Pt (i)Yt (i) − Wt H t (i)},(A.5)
126 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 1(15), No. 2, 2015
We suppose that firms solve a two-stage problem. In the first stage, firms choose
labour demand in a perfectly competitive market. The first order condition is:
Wt
MCt (i) = MCt = , (A.7)
Pt
where MCt denotes the nominal marginal cost of producing one unit of goods.
In the second stage problem the firms cannot optimally set prices. There
is a fraction of firms θ that are not allowed to reset prices. Prices then evolve
according to Pt(i) = Pt – 1(i). The remaining share of firms 1 – θ can set their
selling price such that Pt(i) = Pt*(i), where Pt*(i) denotes the optimal price set
by the representative firm given the nominal rigidity. The maximization pro-
gramme is thus defined as:
+∞
λct +τ
max Et ∑ c
(βθ )τ Pt*(i) − MCt +τ (i)Yt +τ (i), (A.8)
τ =0 λt
Pt*(i )
μ
− t +τ
tP* (i ) μt +τ −1
Et {Yt +τ (i)} = Et Yt +τ , τ > 0, (A.9)
P
t +τ
where:
S
μt = e γεt – the time-varying mark-up,
−1
– denotes the imperfect substitutability between different goods
varieties,
εtS – denotes the mark-up shock,
γ – a shift parameter that normalizes the shock to unity in the
log-linear form of the model as in Smets and Wouters [2005].
Since firms are owned by households they discount the expected profits us-
ing the same discount factor as households (βτλt+τ c
/λt c). The first order condi-
tion is thus:
+∞
λct + τ ( βθ )τ
Et ∑ c
Pt*(i) − μt +τ MCt +τ (i) Yt +τ (i) = 0. (A.10)
τ =0 λt μt + τ − 1
J.-C. Poutineau, K. Sobczak, G. Vermandel, The analytics of the New Keynesian 127
A.3. Authorities
To close the model the monetary policy authority sets its interest rate accord-
ing to a standard Taylor Rule:
1− ρ
Rt Rt πt Yt
π y
ρ ϕ ϕ
R
= e εt , (A.11)
R R π Y
where:
Rt – the nominal interest rate,
πt – the inflation rate,
Yt – the level of output,
εRt – an AR(1) monetary policy shock.
Finally, parameters R, π and Y are steady state values for the interest rate,
the inflation rate and GDP16. The central bank reacts to the deviation of the
inflation rate and the GDP from their steady state values in a proportion of
ϕπ and ϕ y, the central bank also smoothes its rate in a proportion of degree ρ.
A.4. Equilibrium conditions
After aggregating all the supplies by firms the resource constraint for the econ-
omy is defined by:
Yt = Ct.(A.12)
B. Linearization
To obtain the steady state of the model, we normalize prices i.e. P = 1 whilst
we assume that households work one third of their time H = 1/3. Then we find:
C = Y = H,
1
W = MC = ,
μ
χ = WC − σ H − φ .
16
Under a credible central bank, π and Y also can be interpreted as the targets of the cen-
tral bank in terms of inflation rate and GDP.
128 Economics and Business Review, Vol. 1(15), No. 2, 2015
First, combining the Euler bond equation (A.3) and the resources constraint
(A.12), i.e. yˆ t = cˆt, we get production determined by:
1
yˆ t = Et yˆ t +1 − ( rˆ − Et πˆt +1 ) + εtD.(A.14)
σ t
wˆ t = σcˆt + φhˆt,(A.15)
where wˆ t denotes the variations of the real wage. Up to a first order approxi-
mation of the firm price optimization solution (A.10) and the aggregate price
equation (A.13), the linearized new Keynesian Phillips curve is:
(1 − θ )(1 − θβ)
πˆt = βEt πˆt +1 + ˆ t + εtS.(A.16)
mc
θ
Thus the real marginal cost is: mc ˆ t = wˆ t and the production function yt = ht,
then from the labour supply equation, the marginal cost can be simplified as:
mcˆ t = (σ + φ) yˆt. Then the Philips curve is:
(1 − θ )(1 − θβ)
πˆt = βEt πˆt +1 + (σ + φ) yˆ t + εtS.(A.17)
θ
( )
rˆt = ρrˆt −1 + (1 − ρ ) ϕ π πˆt + ϕy yˆ t + ε tR.(A.18)
1
yˆ t = Et yˆ t +1 − ( rˆt − Et πˆt +1 ) + εtD ,
σ
(1 − θ )(1 − θβ)
πˆt = βEt πˆt +1 + (σ + φ) yˆ t + εtS ,
θ
( )
rˆt = ρrˆt −1 + (1 − ρ) ϕπ πˆt + ϕy ˆyt + ϕΔy ( ˆyt − ˆyt −1 ) + εtR .
References
Baranowski, P., Gałecka-Burdziak, E., Górajski, M., Malaczewski, M., Szafrański G.,
2013, Inflacja a mechanizmy aktualizacji cen. Studium dla Polski, Łódź, Wydawnictwo
Uniwersytetu Łódzkiego, Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN.
Blanchard, O., Kahn, C.M., 1980, The Solution of Linear Difference Models under Rational
Expectations, Econometrica, vol. 48, no. 5: 1305–1311.
Bludnik, I., 2009, The New Keynesianism – Proclamation of a Consensus?, Poznań Uni
versity of Economics Review, vol. 9, no. 1: 5–24.
Bofinger, P., Mayer, E., Wollmershäuser, T., 2006, The BMW Model: A New Framework
for Teaching Monetary Economics, Journal of Economic Education, vol. 37, no. 1:
98–117.
Carlin, W., Soskice, D., 2014, Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial
System, Oxford University Press.
Clarida, R., Galí, J., Gertler, M., 1999, The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian
Perspective, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 37, no. 4: 1661–1707.
Galí, J., 2008, Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the
New Keynesian Framework, Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Galí, J., Gertler, M., López-Salido D., 2001, European Inflation Dynamics, European
Economic Review, vol. 45, no. 7: 1237–1270.
Goodfriend, M., King, R., 1997, The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary
Policy, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 12: 231–296.
Klein P., 2000, Using the Generalized Schur Form to Solve a Multivariate Linear Rational
Expectations Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 24(10), Septem
ber: 1405–1423.
Miao, J., 2014, Economic Dynamics in Discrete Time, MIT Press.
Poutineau, J.C., Vermandel, G., 2015a, Cross-border Banking Flows Spillovers in the
Eurozone: Evidence from an Estimated DSGE Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics
and Control, no. 2: 378–403.
Poutineau, J.C., Vermandel, G., 2015b, A Primer on Macroprudential Policy, The Journal
of Economic Education, forthcoming.
Romer, D., 1993, The New Keynesian Synthesis, Journal of Economic Perspectives,
vol. 7, no. 1: 5–22.
Sbordone, A.M., 2002, Prices and Unit Labor Costs: Testing Models of Pricing Behavior,
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 45, no. 2: 265–292.
Sims, C., 2000, Solving Linear Rational Expectation Models, Working Paper, Department
of Economics, Princeton University.
Smets, F., Wouters, R., 2005, Comparing Shocks and Frictions in US and Euro Area
Business Cycles: a Bayesian DSGE Approach, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 20(1).
Taylor, J. B., 1999, A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules, in: Taylor, J.B. (ed.),
Monetary Policy Rules, University of Chicago Press , Chicago.
Woodford, M, 2003, Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy,
Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Aims and Scope
Aims and Scope
Economics and Business
EconomicsReview
andisBusiness
the successor
Review toisthe
thePoznań
successor
University
to the Poznań
of Economics
University
Review
of Economics
which wasReview which was
published by the Poznań
published
University
by the Poznań
of Economics
University
Press ofin
Economics
2001–2014. Press
TheinEconomics
2001–2014. and
ThBusiness
e Economics
Review
and Business Review
is a quarterly journal
is a quarterly
focusing on journal
theoretical
focusing
andon applied
theoretical
research
andwork
applied
in the
research
fields work
of economics,
in the fields
man-
of economics, man-
agement and finance.
agement
The Review
and finance.
welcomes
The Review
the submission
welcomes of the
articles
submission
for publication
of articles
dealing
for publication
with micro,dealing with micro,
mezzo and macro mezzo
issues. and
All macro
texts are
issues.
double-blind
All textsassessed
are double-blind
by independent
assessedreviewers
by independent
prior to reviewers
acceptance.prior to acceptance.
More informationMore
and advice
information
on the and
suitability
advice and
on the
formats
suitability
of manuscripts
and formats
canofbe
manuscripts
obtained from:
can be obtained from:
Economics and Business
EconomicsReview
and Business Review
al. Niepodległościal.
10Niepodległości 10
61-875 Poznań 61-875 Poznań
Poland Poland
e-mail: [email protected]
e-mail: [email protected]
www.puereview.ue.poznan.pl
www.puereview.ue.poznan.pl
Subscription
Economics and Business Review (E&BR) is published quarterly and is the successor to the Poznań University of Economics
Review. The E&BR is published by the Poznań University of Economics Press.
E&BR is listed in ProQuest, EBSCO, and BazEkon.
Subscription rates for the print version of the E&BR: institutions: 1 year – €50.00; individuals: 1 year – €25.00. Single copies:
institutions – €15.00; individuals – €10.00. The E&BR on-line edition is free of charge.
Correspondence with regard to subscriptions should be addressed to: Księgarnia Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Poznaniu,
ul. Powstańców Wielkopolskich 16, 61-895 Poznań, Poland, fax: +48 61 8543147; e-mail: [email protected].
Payments for subscriptions or single copies should be made in Euros to Księgarnia Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Poznaniu
by bank transfer to account No.: 96 1090 1476 0000 0000 4703 1245.