Newtonian Microeconomics PDF
Newtonian Microeconomics PDF
Newtonian Microeconomics PDF
MICROECONOMICS
A Dynamic Extension to
Neoclassical Micro Theory
Matti Estola
Newtonian Microeconomics
Matti Estola
Newtonian
Microeconomics
A Dynamic Extension to Neoclassical
Micro Theory
Matti Estola
University of Eastern Finland
Joensuu, Finland
Cover illustration: © Carol Dembinsky / Dembinsky Photo Associates / Alamy Stock Photo
v
vi Preface
Acknowledgements
The main results presented in the book were developed in my PhD
Dissertation Thesis in 1995, where Docent Veli-Matti Hokkanen had an
essential role in supervising the work. I am also grateful to the contributing
suggestions by Professor Jouni Suhonen during that work. In studying
these matters and writing this book, various colleagues and students
have made contributing comments to the work. Kaija Häkkinen wrote
a mathematical appendix for the Finnish version of the book in 1996, and
in this book I have translated it into English and added some extra minor
details. Parts of the Finnish version of the book has been reviewed by Tapio
Ruokolainen, Jaakko Pehkonen, Kari Heimonen and Kari Kinnunen. I
give my deepest thanks to these people for their contributions in that
work.
This new English version of the book has received input by Kalle
Määttä, Heinz Eckart Klingelhöfer, Thomas Hering, Michael Olbrich,
Kristiaan Kerstens, and Alia Dannenberg. I give my warmest thanks to all
of them for their contributing comments. Naturally, I am also grateful to
the several other students, whose names are not mentioned here, but who
have contributed to this work during my 20 years of teaching experience
at the University of Jyväskylä and the University of Eastern Finland.
Needless to say, I take full responsibility for all remaining errors and
inconsistencies existing in the book. Finally, I give my deepest thanks
to editor Laura Pacey for accepting this book in the Palgrave Macmillan
series.
References
Estola, M. (2001). A dynamic theory of a firm: An application of economic
forces. Advances in Complex Systems, 4(1), 163–176.
Estola, M. (2011). Measuring the growth and the structural change in a
multi-sector economy. Hyperion International Journal of Econophysics & New
Economy, 4(1).
x Preface
1 Economics as a Science 1
1.1 Classification of Economics 3
1.2 The Axioms of Economics 5
1.2.1 Regular Needs of Human Beings 5
1.2.2 Business Competition and
Rational Behavior 6
1.2.3 The Birth of Organizations 9
1.2.4 The Principle of Modeling in Economics 12
1.3 Forecasting Human Behavior 14
1.3.1 Predictability of Economic Events 15
1.4 Frameworks of Economic Modeling 16
1.4.1 The Neoclassical Framework and
Its Critique 16
1.4.2 Econophysics 19
1.4.3 A Dynamic Extension to
Neoclassical Economics 24
1.4.4 Decision-Making Steelyard 26
1.5 A Summary of the Methodological Basis of
Economics 30
References 30
xi
xii Contents
2 Measuring in Economics 35
2.1 Principles of Dimensional Analysis 36
2.2 A Measurement System for Economics 41
2.2.1 Measurement of Volume of Goods 41
2.2.2 Measurement of Time 42
2.2.3 Measurement of Monetary Values 43
2.2.4 Measurement of Satisfaction 47
2.2.5 Primary Dimensions in Economics 49
2.3 Nominal and Real Quantities 52
2.3.1 How Do We Use Real Quantities? 54
2.3.2 Internal and External Value of a Currency 56
2.4 Discrete and Continuous Quantities 57
2.5 Measuring Changes in Scalars 59
2.6 Measuring Changes in Values 61
2.6.1 Changes in Values in Discrete Time 61
2.6.2 Changes in Values in Continuous Time 64
2.6.3 Interest Rate 65
2.7 Economic Kinematics 68
2.7.1 Average Velocity of Production 69
2.7.2 Instantaneous Velocity of Production 73
2.7.3 Velocity and Accumulated Production 74
2.7.4 Average Acceleration of Production 80
2.7.5 Instantaneous Acceleration of Production 81
2.7.6 Kinematics of a Two-Good
Production System 82
2.8 Index Numbers 88
2.8.1 Index Numbers as Average Quantities 89
2.9 The Production Function 91
References 96
3 Consumer Behavior 97
3.1 The Axioms of Consumer Behavior 99
3.2 A Consumer’s Budget Equation 100
3.3 A Consumer’s Preferences 103
3.4 A Consumer’s Optimal Choice 108
Contents xiii
Economics is a social science that analyzes the conflict between the almost
unlimited needs of human beings, and the limited amount of goods
available for the satisfaction of people’s needs. For example, the following
questions are studied in economics: (1) Why are certain goods produced in
different economies? (2) Whose needs does the production aim to satisfy?
(3) Which methods are applied in the production of different goods, and
what is the reason for this? (4) How are the prices of goods determined? (5)
What kind of institutions and economic units exist in societies, and how
they operate? (6) What are the factors that affect the welfare of a society,
and how are these factors measured? (7) Which factors cause economic
growth? and (8) How have the relations between economic units been
developed over time?
In the following we denote a definition by the symbol §.
§: By an economy we understand a society from the point of view of
its economic structure. ˘
§: A good is the term applied to material and non-material products. ˘
A good is thus a shirt, a radio set, a meal in a restaurant, a bottle of
wine, a haircut, a soccer game, etc.
The DNA -structure in the genes of the human being is so stable that
no essential change has taken place within it during the last 10,000 years,
(Hawking 1993, p. 119). The change in human beings during the near his-
tory has thus taken place due to cultural factors, and not because of genetic
changes. According to Charles Darwin, cultural factors strengthen certain
genetic features. For example, in modern societies, people’s need for phys-
ical power has been replaced by the need for mental ability; being able to
build a machine or use one is more important than being able to work with
the hands. Cultural evolution thus somewhat changes human beings.
point out what we ought to do, as well as to determine what we shall do.
: : : They govern us in all we do, in all we say, in all we think.” However,
according to Becker (1976), “Although Bentham explicitly states that
the pleasure-pain calculus is applicable to what we ‘shall’ do as well as
to what we ‘ought’ to do, he was primarily interested in ‘ought’ and
did not develop a theory of actual human behavior with many testable
implications” (Becker 1976, p. 8). “I am saying that the economic
approach provides a valuable unified framework for understanding all
human behavior. : : : If this argument is correct, the economic approach
provides a unified framework for understanding behavior that has long
been sought by and eluded Bentham, Comte, Marx, and others” (ibid.,
p. 14). “Only after long reflection on this work and the rapidly growing
body of related work by others did I conclude that the economic approach
was applicable to all human behavior” (ibid., p. 8).
We continue the efforts of Bentham and Becker in seeking a unified
framework to model economic phenomena. Our definition of rationality,
however, deviates from that of Becker (1976) who understands by rational
behavior that an individual maximizes a well-defined function, such as
utility or profit. We do not insist that a rational economic unit is
maximizing a function; only that he (she/it) has goals he is willing to
reach, and makes decisions consistent with these goals. The connection
between decisions and goals may be too complicated to be expressed by
a smooth function. Some decisions require strategic thinking in a game-
theoretic way (consider a chess player), while others are simple ‘pickings
of the best alternative from a set of options’ without considering other
people’s reactions.
On this basis, irrational behavior either means decisions that do not
support the goals of the economic unit, random decision-making without
any goals, or such behavior that is generally considered foolish. An exam-
ple of the first kind of irrationality is where a candidate for a professorship
announces that if he is appointed, he will stop his research and concentrate
on family life; or where an entrepreneur announces that his/her com-
petitors’ products are not only cheaper but also of better quality. This
behavior conflicts with success in these competitions. The second type of
irrationality turns up in a sequence of choices where in the first case an
economic unit prefers choice A to B, and in the second case choice B to A,
8 Newtonian Microeconomics
without any change in the situation. This economic unit will lose money
in a sequence of bargains. An example of the last kind of irrationality is a
person who likes to pay more for a used, broken car without any intrinsic
value, rather than an identical new one. When this becomes known by
his/her neighbors, they most probably start to consider him stupid. These
kinds of controls over other people force those of us who like to manage,
and be respected by, others to behave in a ‘rational’ way.
A necessary condition for a private firm to survive in a market economy
is profitability, because non-profitable firms run out of financial resources
and have to close down. This forces firms to behave rationally. An
individual interested in his material well-being must also make rational
consumption and education decisions. We can thus believe that the
average behavior of economic units is rational, even though irrational
people exist, and people make errors every now and then due to uncer-
tainties in the decision-making situations they face. As a result of this, we
can state the second axiom of economics:
those who have made bad choices will lose their money. In the long run,
only those investors who make good decisions will survive. Thus, people’s
unwillingness to throw away money leads, in a market economy, to the
situation where only a profitable business, able to pay returns to its
investors, survives.
The factors described here can be considered as regularities that charac-
terize the market system. These regularities are caused by free competition
and people’s willingness ‘not to throw away money’. Because people and
organizations are similar in their needs, the willingness of people and
organizations to reach their goals creates certain regularities in economic
behavior. These regularities are observed, modeled, and explained in
economics. The regularities in economic behavior that arise from the
competition between firms and people for economic success are in many
ways similar to those occurring in biology between plants and animals, in
the battle for survival. The difference between regularities in economies
and in biological Nature is: Economic units make conscious decisions
to reach their goals while plants and animals mainly act based on their
instincts.
The opinions of Adam Smith, Leon Walras, and William Stanley Jevons
of a human being as a creature interested in its own wealth is quite
an accurate description of human beings (see Sect. 1.4.1). This claim
is supported by the observation that humans have won against ‘other
animals’ in the battle for existence. This has required selfish behavior
on the part of humans in respect to ‘other animals’. Humans must also
have behaved relatively rationally during the history of mankind, because
otherwise Darwinian evolution would have guaranteed the defeat of
humans by ‘other animals’. One factor that has helped human beings in
this battle is the social character of humans that allows us to cooperate.
These days we have evidence that socialist economies that were built on
the assumption of a non-egoistic human being have not functioned well.
If competition does not exist, and people do not receive compensation for
their efforts, it is difficult to motivate people to work effectively. Behind
10 Newtonian Microeconomics
products of a firm, this firm will eventually collapse. We have been able
to observe examples of this kind of boycott.
Predicting a consumer’s decisions on a certain day is difficult. This is
not needed, however, because shopkeepers are not interested in forecasting
the purchases of every customer on every day. Rather, they are interested
in forecasting the sales of different goods at certain time units. The
situation resembles statistical mechanics. It is much easier to forecast the
average or aggregate behavior of consumers (molecules) than that of a
single consumer (molecule). The ability to predict an economic event
thus depends on whether we can forecast the decision-making of an
average economic unit in the situation. Compare, for example, an average
customer, in forecasting the sales of a hamburger bar and that of an opera.
This illustrates the problems in forecasting stock market behavior where
we should be able to forecast the buying and selling decisions of an average
investor. The interactions between investors complicate this forecasting,
see Sect. 1.4.2.
1.4.2 Econophysics
models could explain the complex behavior in stock and exchange rate
markets. This analog has a reasonable foundation, because asset prices are
determined according to the buying and selling behavior of thousands
of investors. If investors are identified as particles, asset prices can be
modeled as the result of ‘collisions’ of these particles. The methodological
tools in this research are computer-based simulation models where
the behavior of every ‘particle’ is modeled in a system of thousands of
particles. These programs are let to run over numerous time units, after
which the macro-level quantities characterizing the state of the system
at every time unit are reported. In econophysics, this methodology is
called agent-based modeling where the investors are the agents. This
multidisciplinary subject was given the name ‘econophysics’ because the
object of the research is economics and not physics.
Of course, throughout history there have been several pieces of research
where the methods of physics have been applied in economic problems.
Examples of this can be seen in (1) The book by astronomer Adolphe
Quatelet in 1842: Physics of Social Phenomena: An Essay on Human
Development;(2) Mathematician Louis Bachelier developed in his PhD
thesis in 1900 the ‘theory of speculation’, where he applied Brownian
motion in financial markets. Brownian motion gets its name according to
botanist Robert Brown from his studies of microscopic particles in 1827,
and Albert Einstein applied Brownian motion in his celebrated paper in
1905; (3) Mathematician Benoit Mandelbrot (1963) observed power-law
scaling in commodity markets. Thus, econophysics had its pioneers over
the course of scientific history, but these works were almost completely
neglected by neoclassical economists until the rise of econophysics in the
1990s gave them renewed interest.
Chen and Li (2012) state, however, that the standard models of
neoclassical economics have, in any event, been borrowed from physics.
Thus the connection between the two sciences is not a new phenomenon.
According to Mirowski (1989a), the pioneers of neoclassical economics
like Jevons and Walras consistently imitated classical mechanics in trying
to develop similar concepts for economics as physics has invented in the
development of Newtonian and Lagrangian mechanics. The forces acting
upon economic quantities as well as the kinetic and potential energy
1 Economics as a Science 21
used as a measure of risk. Thus Lévy and power law distributions cause
a conflict between these two groups of researchers, and other areas of
financial economics, for instance, portfolio selection, capital asset pricing,
and the Black-Scholes model are also in conflict with these distributions.
This conflict is so serious that one of the leading econophysicists, Joseph
McCauley, states that “econophysicists are safer to ignore the lessons
taught in standard economics texts”, McCauley (2006, p. 602).
This conflict between economists and physicists has been considered
insolvable, but Jovanovic and Schinckus (2013) have proposed a solution.
If the Gaussian distribution applied in economics is changed to truncated
stable Lévy distribution, that distribution has a finite standard error. This
distribution can be accepted by both camps, and it has been shown to give
consistent results with observed behavior; see, for example Mariani and
Liu (2007), Mantegna (1991), and Lux (1996).
Needless to say, there still exists a deep gulf between people studying
financial markets with background in economics and in physics. Nat-
urally, some economists—that ‘have been there longer’—feel that the
newcomers from physics with new research tools are not welcome because
they threaten the position of economists as authorities in these matters.
However, scientific competition should be open for new ideas, and
thus economists should compete about superiority of research methods
rather than keep their own seminars of financial research. The new
concepts econophysicists have brought to financial markets research are
universality and scaling, power law distribution, and network theory
in modeling; see Ausloos (2013). There exists also examples of applying
thermodynamic framework in economic modeling; see, for example
Drăgulescu and Yakovenko (2000) and Kusmartsev (2011). Thus the
research in econophysics is very broad and applies almost all principles
of modeling invented in physics. An extension of econophysics to social
sciences has been made by Serge Galam (2004), called Sociophysics.
Sociophysics applies similar tools as econophysics in modeling the group
behavior of people, and it has been used in explaining the voting and con-
sumer behavior of a group of persons. Sociophysics, however, is beyond
the scope of this book, and thus it is not treated here in a detailed way.
As this section reveals, the neoclassical framework of economics is
lacking a consistent framework for modeling dynamic events. The gap
24 Newtonian Microeconomics
decision maker from his decision, and the equilibrium state (the zero-
force condition) corresponds to the optimal situation. This framework
can be applied in the decision-making of every economic unit concerning
any quantity, as Becker (1976) and Bentham (1963) proposed.
According to the above, we change the assumption in the neoclassical
framework to the following: Economic units have goals they like to
reach and make decisions to obtain these goals. Assuming this, we can
explain the observed evolution of economic quantities as well as possible
equilibrium states that may change with time. This is in accordance with
the principle of modeling in economics given in Sect. 1.2.4, and also in
agent-based models applied in econophysics.
From the point of view of scientific thinking, the proposed framework
deviates from the neoclassical framework in that an economy is not
assumed to be in an equilibrium state. Rather, an economy consists of
various evolutionary processes driven by different factors. These factors
consist of the quantities economic units compare in their decision-
making. In an evolutionary economy, nothing stays fixed for long. New
products and technologies are created, the qualities of existing products
evolve with time, and people’s preferences change with time and wealth.
These elements complicate the forecasting of economic events.
We can think that dynamic economic events are caused by conflicting
‘economic forces’. In an equilibrium state, the forces acting upon opposite
directions cancel each other out. For example, we can think that employers
direct a negative, and employees a positive, force component upon wage
level, and the wage level changes according to the net or resultant force
acting upon it. An equilibrium wage balances these two force components.
The definition of economic forces is important because economic
forces are the reasons behind observed changes in economic quantities.
If, however, a control variable exists in the resultant force acting upon
an economic quantity, that an outside controller (an economic policy-
maker, a legislator, the manager of a firm, etc.) can adjust, the force is
controllable. In these cases, we can apply control theory in modeling
economic policy-making. Various kinds of inertial factors resist changes
in economic quantities. The easier it is to change an economic quantity,
the more it will fluctuate with time. This is consistent with observations
of the variability of economic quantities. Exchange rates, interest rates,
26 Newtonian Microeconomics
stock prices, goods prices, and growth rates of production of goods vary
with different daily and weekly rates.
In economics, we cannot hope to be able to reach the same degree of
predictability as can be obtained in certain physical processes by applying
Newtonian laws. The reason for this is that economic forces change
over time. The innovation of a new technology may change consumers’
preferences or firms’ costs so that some goods become more popular and
others become worthless. The longer the time unit, the more difficult it
is to accurately forecast economic events due to these reasons.
As a summary, we can state the foundation for modeling economic
phenomena as follows:
s(t)
m1
m2
References
Ausloos, M. (2013, July). Econophysics: Comments on a few applica-
tions, successes, methods, & models. Society & Management Review, 2(2),
101–115.
1 Economics as a Science 31
Using the first form of Eq. (2.1) we can add 3000 meters to 5 miles as:
1
Measurement units are in brackets after the numbers of measurement.
38 Newtonian Microeconomics
Using the second form of Eq. (2.1) we can add the two lengths in miles as:
2
In dimensional analysis, a dimension is denoted by brackets.
40 Newtonian Microeconomics
x3 x5 x7 x2 x3
Sin(x) D x C C ; ex D 1 C x C C C ;
3Š 5Š 7Š 2Š 3Š
(x 1)2 (x 1)3 (x 1)4
ln(x) D (x 1) C C ;
2 3 4
History has shown that it is practical to use a specific good called ‘money’
in measuring the values of traded goods, see Sect. 8.1. The good to be
used as money can be any good that is accepted by all. Independent of
the good used as the reference good (money), it is not possible to obtain
generally accepted values for goods. This is due to personal differences in
(1) the valuation of goods, and in (2) the valuation of the reference good
we use in measuring. Some people pay to listen to classical music, and
some to heavy metal music. Some pay to see a boxing match while others
wouldn’t go there even if they were paid. These examples demonstrate
the first claim. The second claim can be understood by realizing that in
all trading we use one good in valuing the other goods. When we are
trading two goods A and B without a third good giving the prices, we
value good A in units of good B or vice versa. Let us study some examples
to demonstrate the second claim.
Suppose you are planning to buy a consumer good. If you are rational,
you buy the good if you can afford it, and you value the good higher than
or equal to its price. To be able to do the comparing, you have to transform
your valuations into monetary units, or vice versa. A rational person must,
44 Newtonian Microeconomics
Rule 1. Value one unit of money according to the trouble you expect to have in
acquiring it. Use this valuation to transform the prices of goods to the amount
of trouble it causes you to pay their prices. Then buy a good if it is worth the
trouble; that is, if the pleasure you get from consuming the good exceeds or
equals the trouble of acquiring the money to pay its price. ˘
Rule 2. Buying a good involves a loss of pleasure in the form of losing the
best alternative use of the money: buying another good or saving it. Find the
alternative cost of acquiring a good by estimating the loss of pleasure due to
giving up the best alternative use of the money. Then buy a good if the pleasure
you get from consuming it exceeds the pleasure you could get from the best
alternative use of the money. ˘
Rule 3. Define your marginal willingness to pay for a good by dividing your
marginal utility of the good by your marginal utility of money. Then buy the
good if your marginal willingness to pay of the good exceeds its price.˘
consumers may buy a good and the other may not, even though they both
enjoy consuming the good and can afford it. Suppose we use squirrel furs
in valuing goods. A skillful hunter probably values one squirrel fur less
than an unqualified hunter because of the less trouble he has in catching
it. A skillful hunter may, then, be more ready to go shopping due to his
lower valuation of ‘money’. These examples demonstrate the second claim
stated earlier.
In physics, it is required of a measurement unit that it does not change
with time, with location, or with the person who is doing the measuring.
Now, we have seen that we need at least one good in valuing the other
goods—any commonly accepted one will do—and a historical process
has led to money being used as the reference good, see Sect. 8.1. Above
we demonstrated that the personal valuation of one unit of money differs
from one person to another, and we know that the purchasing power of
money varies with time, see Sect. 2.3. We can thus conclude that a good
with an equal value for all people and a constant value with time—that
could be used in measuring the values of goods—does not exist. We thus
have to give up any hope of exact measuring of values because valuation
is based on personal judgments.
A practical way to value a good is to let the market do it. This is what
people do in real life. The market value of a good measured by any other
good—squirrel fur, gold, money, and so on—increases with its necessity,
popularity, and scarcity. Due to these reasons, the market value of a good
depends on the market in which the good is offered for sale. The market
value of winter clothes, for example, depends on whether they are offered
for sale in Kenya or in Finland. Therefore, we cannot determine whether
an increase in the value of a good is caused by its increased necessity or
popularity, or by a decrease in the purchasing power of the measuring good
(money). This demonstrates the difficulties we have in explaining changes
in values of goods. Independently of these problems, we can always get a
measure—possibly zero or negative—for the market value of a good. The
market value of a good is thus a measurable quantity, and we can state the
following definition:
§: The market value of a good is the maximum monetary offer made
for it when it is offered for sale. ˘
46 Newtonian Microeconomics
This definition can be applied for negative values too; that is, for
garbage goods. The owner of garbage likes to pay the minimum amount of
money to get rid of the garbage. This corresponds to the highest (nearest
to zero) of all negative offers people require for taking care of the garbage.
Following on from the above, we suggest the euro as the basic unit of
the dimension of monetary values (or money for short). The arguments
for this choice are that any commonly accepted good will do, and money
is used for this purpose in everyday life. With respect to measurement
units, the most widely used currencies are denoted by their common
abbreviations, euro by e, US dollar by $, Great Britain pound by £,
and so on. However, these types of abbreviations do not exist for some
currencies, and we therefore denote these by their official abbreviations,
such as Swedish crown by SEK, and so forth. With regard to the exchange
rates of currencies, we apply the official abbreviations: USD for US dollar,
GBP for Great Britain pound, and so on.
Now, all monetary quantities measured in units euro, US dollar,
Swedish crown, and so on, belong in the dimension of money and are
thus additive. Different currencies have transformation rules like those
in adding quantities belonging in the dimension of length measured in
different units, and in adding the amounts of a good measured in different
units. Suppose the exchange rate between US. dollar and Great Britain
pound is 1 (GBP) D 2:5 (USD). We can write this transformation
equation as
1 GBP
1 D 2:5 (USD=GBP) , 1D :
2:5 USD
With these two forms of the transformation equation, we can add 2 (GBP)
to 5 (USD) in US dollars as3
3
See the transformation equation between two units of length in (2.1).
2 Measuring in Economics 47
these choices the ‘level of utility’ becomes a measurable entity, that is, a
‘quantity’. After this de Jong gives the following definition:
§: The set of all conceivable levels of satisfaction is called the dimension
of satisfaction symbolized by ŒS. ˘
This definition assumes that the satisfaction consumers receive from the
consumption of different goods is of a homogeneous type. All consumer
goods do not satisfy the same need, however. The needs of human beings
can be roughly classified into physiological, social, and mental categories.
Satisfying the need of hunger by eating does not decrease the need of
social relations, and the satisfaction of social relations does not decrease
the need of sleeping, and so on. The level of satisfaction of a consumer
is thus a holistic feeling that depends on his/her satisfaction of various
kinds of needs.
One solution to the comparability problem of various types of needs
is the following: consumers classify their needs in different categories.
One category of need, for example hunger, can be satisfied by eating
different kinds of food; another, such as social relations, can be satisfied
by meeting people in various ways, for example at home, in a restaurant,
or via the Internet. To be able to make a rational choice, a consumer must
be aware of his/her needs, and be able to classify the satisfaction he gets
from the consumption of every available good in one of his categories
of needs. Consumers may have several categories of needs depending on
how sophisticated they are with the types of satisfaction they recognize.
The satisfaction a consumer gets from his consumption of all goods that
belong in one of his categories of needs are directly comparable (goods are
close substitutes), and the satisfaction from goods belonging in different
categories is not directly comparable; they are either distant substitutes or
complements.
If a consumer can directly compare the satisfaction he receives from the
consumption of all goods belonging in one of his categories of needs, and
the unit prices of these goods are known, then the consumer can make a
rational choice between these goods. When consumers allocate funds for
their consumption, they first budget funds for their different categories of
needs for a time unit: housing, food, hobbies, and so on. Exact decisions
are made between the goods in these categories within the limits of
budgeted funds. If a consumer can estimate the satisfaction he gets from
2 Measuring in Economics 49
Note. The difference between the monetary value of a good and its price
is that monetary values belong in the primary dimension ŒM and prices
in the secondary dimension ŒM=R. For example, the market value of a
computer, say, 1000 (e), is the highest monetary amount that someone is
ready to pay for it. The price of the computer can be solved as 1000 (e)
D 1 (unit) ) 1000 (e/unit) = 1, where number 1 in the latter form of
the equation represents the equality of the numerator and denominator
in the price on the left hand side. This equation expresses the relationship
between the price and the monetary value of the good. The value of the
computer can be obtained from its price as: 1000 (e) = 1000 (e/unit)
1 (unit). ˘
Example 1
Suppose 10 tons of paper has been produced in a paper factory in two days.
The dimension of this flow of production, ŒR=T D ŒRT 1 , is the product of
the powers of basic dimensions ŒR and ŒT. The flow of production is then
measured as: 10 (tn)/2 (d) = 5 (tn=d). ˘
Example 2
The production in Example 1 has been sold at unit price 1 ($=kg) to a
newspaper corporation. The dimension of the unit price, ŒM=R D ŒMR1 ,
is the product of the powers of basic dimensions ŒM and ŒR. ˘
Example 3
The value of production of the paper factory in Example 1 (or the value
flow of production) can be calculated asa : 5 (tn=d) 1 ($=kg) = 5 (1000kg=d)
1 ($=kg) = 5000 (kg=d)($=kg) = 5000 ($=d). The dimension of the value of the
flow of production, ŒM=T D ŒMT 1 , is the product of powers of primary
dimensions ŒM and ŒT. ˘
a
Note that the number of measurement and the unit of measurement are
multiplied together, and so we can multiply the number of measurement
by the number in the measurement unit.
52 Newtonian Microeconomics
Proof. Suppose the country is USA and the amount of every good in
the economy is measured in units kg. Assuming this, we can express
the price of every good in units $=kg. Let us, for instance, calculate the
kilogram price of a computer. The physical weight of the computer is
mC (kg=unit). Dividing the price of the computer pC ($=unit) by its
mass, we get its kilogram price as pC =mC ($=kg). The average
P kilogram
price of all goods in the economy is then pN D (1=n) njD1 pj , where
pj is the kilogram price of good j and n is the number of goods in the
economy. With one US dollar you can then, on average buy the amount
1=(Np ($=kg)) = 1=Np (kg=$) of goods in the economy; quantity 1=Np thus
measures the purchasing power of one US dollar. If the average price level
in the economy increases, that is 1=Np decreases, the purchasing power
of US dollar decreases. By one dollar you can then on average buy less
goods. ˘
If the average price level increases in an economy, that is, the purchasing
power of the home currency decreases, this raises the nominal values of
most goods. Real quantities, such as the number of goods or the amount of
production of a good in a time unit, may then stay constant even though
their (nominal) values increase. This is the topic in this section.
2 Measuring in Economics 53
Example 1
Let the price of ice cream be 10 ($=l) and the average price level of goods in
the economy be 100 ($=kg). The exchange rates between goods and money
54 Newtonian Microeconomics
are then: 10 ($) D 1 (l) and 100 ($) D 1 (kg). The transformation equation
between ice cream and other goods in the economy is obtained by dividing
these equations: 1 (kg) D 10 (l). The last equation defines the real price of
ice cream as 1/10 (kg=l) D 1. Thus, on average, one liter of ice cream can be
exchanged to 1=10 (kg) of other goods. If, however, the average price level is
expressed as ‘liter price’, then the ‘real price of ice cream’ is a dimensionless
quantity that measures the exchange rate between liters of other goods
and one liter of ice cream in the economy. ˘
Example 2
Let a nominal wage be W ($=h) and the price of milk p ($=l). The corre-
sponding transformation equations between goods and money are then:
W ($) D 1 (h) and p ($) D 1 (l). The ‘real wage’ W=p (l=h) D 1 is obtained
by dividing these equations, and it measures the exchange rate between
liters of milk and one hour of work. The corresponding transformation
equation is (1=W) (h) D (1=p) (l). The higher the nominal wage W, the less
work time is required in exchange for one liter of milk. If, however, the
nominal wage is divided by the average kilogram price of goods in the
economy p ($=kg), then ‘real wage’ W=p (kg=h) measures the exchange rate
between the amount of goods in the economy and one hour of work. This
corresponds to the purchasing power of wage W. ˘
be defined for various forms of wealth. Real values inform whether these
forms of wealth have kept their exchange rates with respect to other forms
of wealth.
Suppose the value of the flow of production of good k, Vk (e=mn) and
its price pk (e=kg) are known from one month. Then we can calculate
the amount of production of the good during that month. The value of
production consists of the flow of production qk (kg=mn) multiplied by
the price pk (e=kg). The value of the production can then be expressed
as Vk (e=mn) D pk (e=kg) qk (kg=mn) from which we get qk D
Vk =pk (kg=mn).
The flow of production can then be calculated by dividing the value of
the flow of production by the price. We call this ‘deflation of the value
flow of production by the price of the good’. If, however, the deflation is
made by an average kilogram price of goods in the economy, p (e=kg), we
get Vk =p = pk qk (e=mn)=(p (e=kg)). Quantity Vk =p (kg=mn) measures
the amount of other goods the monthly production of good k can be
exchanged for in the economy. ‘The real value of monthly production’
of good k thus either measures the flow of production of the good (if
deflated by the price of the good), or the average amount of goods the
monthly production can be exchanged for in the economy (if deflated by
an average price level in the economy).
We can, similarly, approximate the flow of production of a group of
goods on the basis of their aggregate value in a time unit and their prices.
This is based on the idea that the amount of production of these goods
can be transformed to be measured in equal units; for example, in mass
units. We operate as follows. Define the kilogram price for all goods,
as described earlier for a computer. Then define a weighted average of
kilogram prices of the goods where the weights can be; for example, the
shares of the goods from the aggregate value flow. This way the defined
average kilogram price is denoted by p. Divide the value of the aggregate
flow of production V (e=mn) into price and volume flow components
as: V D p (e=kg) q (kg=mn). If we then divide V by p, we get an
estimate for the aggregate flow of production q (kg=mn) of the goods.
This approximation is required if we have aggregated value data from the
production of many goods, and we like to approximate the aggregate flow
of production of these goods.
56 Newtonian Microeconomics
Let the average kg-prices of all goods in USA and Sweden be denoted
as pu and ps . The internal value or the purchasing power of money
in the two countries is then 1=(pu (USD=kg)) D 1=pu (kg=USD), and
1=(ps (SEK=kg)) = 1=ps (kg=SEK), respectively.
Next, we denote certain amounts of goods in USA as xu (kg) and
in Sweden as xs (kg). Suppose that the values of these amounts are,
respectively, pu (USD=kg)xu (kg) and ps (SEK=kg)xs (kg), where pu ; ps
are average price levels of the two amounts of goods. Next we choose the
amounts xu ; xs so that with current nominal exchange rate S (SEK=USD),
the values of the amounts of the goods are equal. Then we get
2 Measuring in Economics 57
xs Spu
Spu xu (SEK) D ps xs (SEK) ) D : (2.2)
xu ps
The left hand side of the last form of the equation expresses the exchange
rate between the amounts of the goods, and the right hand side shows that
this depends on the ratio of average unit prices multiplied by the nominal
exchange rate. Ratio xs =xu is called the real exchange rate. In contrast
with the nominal exchange rate—which expresses the exchange rate
between two currencies—the real exchange rate expresses the exchange
rate between amounts of goods of equal value in the two countries.
Equation (2.2) shows that the higher the US prices on average, the
smaller the Swedish prices, and the more valuable one US dollar is in
terms of Swedish crowns, the higher the real exchange rate; that is, the
more Swedish goods are needed on average in exchange for one kilogram
of US goods.
●
●
●
t0 t1 t t0 t1 t2 t t0 t1 t2 t
Fig. 2.1 One continuous and two discrete quantities with time
Example
Suppose the production of a firm is measured by the number of finished
products: 1; 2; 3; : : : . Let the daily production of the firm be 3 goods. The
velocity (flow) of production of the firm is thus 3 (unit=d). This discrete
velocity of production can be expressed as
3 3
3 (unit=d) D 3 (unit=24h) D (unit=h) D (unit=60min)
24 24
1 1 1
D (unit=min) D (unit=60sec) D (unit=sec) etc.;
480 480 28800
first and third, and the second and fourth quantities are equal but their
measurement units differ. The common assumption t = 1 (time unit)
in economics is the reason that, for example, an interest rate is often
erroneously identified as relative change, and not as the growth rate of a
monetary quantity, which is the correct identification. Knowing the exact
measurement units of economic quantities is a necessity for well-defined
mathematical expressions with these quantities, as we will see later.
The continuous time correspondents for the above discrete time quan-
tities are obtained as their limits with t ! 0, see Table 2.2.
In mathematics, the instantaneous absolute change of x, dx, is called
the differential of x, and the instantaneous velocity of x with respect to
time, dx=dt D x0 (t), is called the time derivative of x; see Sect. 10.7.
Mathematics differs from ‘real sciences’ in that mathematics does not
operate with dimensional quantities or with measurement units.
Note 3. Growth rates can also be expressed in per cent. Growth rates in
per cent deviate from growth rates in that the former measures the strength
of change as ‘parts of a hundred in a time unit’, and the latter as ‘parts
of a unity in a time unit’. The former equals the latter multiplied by 100.
Growth rate in per cent ‘10 parts of a hundred in a year’ equals the growth
rate ‘0.1 parts of unity in a year’: 10 (%=y) = 10 ((1=100)=y) = 0.1 (1=y).
Formula (2.3) is known as Fisher equation (Fisher 1930), and from the
equation we can solve one of the three quantities x=x, x D V; p; q when
the other two are known.
V1 p1 q1
D ; (2.4)
V0 p0 q0
2 Measuring in Economics 63
x 1 ln .x/
and if, for example, t D 1 (mn), the numerical values of relative changes
and growth rates are equal, even though their measurement units differ.
Equation (2.7) shows that the growth rate of the value of production
approximately equals the growth rate of the flow of production plus the
growth rate of price.
§: The growth rate of price level is called price inflation. ˘
is not required; relative changes and growth rates are more clear measures
for changes in quantities than logarithms of their ratios. We have to
remember that the value of a logarithmic function is a pure number,
and the argument of a logarithmic function must be a pure number for
the function to be dimensionally well-defined. This holds in Eq. (2.5)
because x(t)=x(t0 ) is always a pure number independent of the unit of x,
x D V; q; p. ˘
where the measurement units of p0 (t)q(t) and p(t)q0 (t) are e=mn2 . If we
divide Eq. (2.8) by V(t), we get the growth rate of the value flow as:
where price inflation p0 (t)=p(t) is subtracted from the growth rate of the
value flow of production. This is a general method of estimating the
growth rate of the flow of production from the growth rate of the value
flow of production; that is, the growth rate of the real flow from the
nominal one.
2 Measuring in Economics 65
Example 1
Let the annual interest rate the bank pays on its deposits be 4 (%=y). The
annual interest revenues for capitals 100 (e) and 1000 (e) are then 4 (e/y)
and 40 (e=y), respectively. ˘
Example 2
The interest earnings in Example 1 are 4 (e=y) and 40 (e=y). Dividing these
by the corresponding capitals, we get the growth rates of the capitals as: 4
(e=y)/100 (e) = 0.04 (1=y) and 40 (e/y)/1000 (e) = 0.04 (1=y). Thus the growth
rates are equal: 0.04 (1=y) or 4 (%=y). ˘
Example 3
Let W (e=h) be a nominal wage and p (e=kg) an average price level in an
economy. The real wage W(t)=p(t) (kg=h) then measures the exchange rate
between one hour of work and the amount of goods in the economy. The
growth rate of the real wage during time unit t1 t0 is:
W(t1 )
W(t0 )
=(t1 t0 )
p(t1 ) p(t0 ) 1 W(t1 )p(t0 )
D 1
W(t0 )
p(t0 )
t1 t0 W(t0 )p(t1 )
1 W(t1 )p(t0 ) W(t0 )p(t1 )
D : (2.10)
t1 t0 W(t0 )p(t1 )
If, on the other hand, we calculate the growth rate of the nominal wage
during the time unit and subtract from this the growth rate of the average
price level, we get almost the same result:
This example shows that the development of the real wage can be approx-
imated by subtracting price inflation from the growth rate of the nominal
wage, when these two are measured from the same time unit. This result
also holds for other real quantities that are obtained from nominal ones
by dividing them by an average price level; this result holds particularly for
interest rates. ˘
Let the average price level in the economy be p(t) (e/kg) at time moment
t. The growth rate of the average price level, namely the inflation i with
unit 1=t at time unit t1 t0 , is then:
p(t1 )p(t0 )
t1 t0 1 p(t1 ) p(t0 )
iD D :
p(t0 ) t1 t0 p(t0 )
The real interest rate rR with unit 1=t measures the growth rate of the
x(t)
purchasing power p(t) (kg) of money x(t) (e) as follows:
x(t1 ) x(t0 )
p(t1 ) p(t0 )
t1 t0 1 p(t0 )x(t1 ) p(t1 )x(t0 )
rR D D : (2.12)
x(t0 )
p(t0 )
t1 t0 p(t1 )x(t0 )
The deviation between the accurate measure rR and its approximation ri
is in the denominator; the smaller the difference p(t1 ) p(t0 ) the more
accurate is the approximation. As in the case of the real wage, the reader
can check that this approximation becomes exact in continuous time.
Nominal lending and saving interest rates are positive because the
lender (saver) requires a compensation for his lending (saving). In an
inflationary economy, the purchasing power of the domestic currency
decreases with time. For the purchasing power of the lent (saved) money
68 Newtonian Microeconomics
not to decrease with time, the nominal interest rate must be at least as
great as inflation. If this does not hold, lenders (savers) are not interested
in lending (saving) money.
• • •
Qk (t0 ) Qk (t1 ) Qk (t 2 ) S
● ●
Qk (t ) ●
●
●
t0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 t (mn)
Example 1
Suppose 10 cars were produced in a factory in one day. The velocity
of production of the factory is then: 10 (unit=d) = 10 (unit=24h) = 10/24
(unit=60min) = 1/144 (unit=60sec) = 1/8640 (unit=sec), if the factory operates 24
hours per day. This average velocity of production can also be expressed as
10 (unit=(1=30)mn) D 300(unit=mn) assuming 1(mn) D 30(d) and transforming
by time units in the opposite direction. ˘
Qk (t )
Qk (t 2 )
ΔQ k
Qk (t1 )
Δt
t1 t2 t
In Fig. 2.4, a line is drawn through points .t1 ; Qk (t1 )/ and .t2 ; Qk (t2 )/.
Expression (2.14) then corresponds to the slope of this line, see Sect. 10.2.
The graphical interpretation of the average velocity of production of good
k is the slope of the line in Fig. 2.4. The steeper the line, the greater the
average velocity of production and vice versa.
Example 2
A factory produces 500 (kg) cement in 7 hours. The average velocity of
production is then: 500 (kg)/(7(h)) = 500=7 (kg=h) = 500/7 (kg=((1=24)d)) =
24 500=7 (kg=d), if 24 hours in a day are worked. ˘
Example 3
Suppose 50 cars have been produced in a factory in two weeks by working
8 hours a day and 5 days in a week. The average velocity of production
of the factory was then: 50 (unit)/(2(week)) = 25 (unit=week) = 25 (unit=(5d)) =
25=5 (unit=d) = 5 (unit=(8h)) = 5=8 (unit=h). ˘
2 Measuring in Economics 73
Qk (t )
S1
Qk (t 2 )
S2
Qk (t1 )
t1 t2 t
vk (t n − Δt )
vk (t n − 2Δt)
vk (t n )
vk (t0 + 2Δt)
vk (t0 + Δt)
t0 t 0 + Δt t0 + 2Δt t n − 2Δt t n − Δt tn t
Example 1
Suppose the average velocity of production is 40 (kg=d). The amount of
production during 10 days can then be approximated as: 40 (kg=d) 10 (d)
= 400 (kg). ˘
shaded area in Fig. 2.6. If then the length of the time unit is decreased
as t ! 0, the amount of production during time period (t0 ; tn ) can be
expressed as the following definite integral (see Sect. 10.14.2)
X
n Z Z
Qk (t0 C it) tn
dQk tn
Qk (t0 ; tn ) D lim t D dt D Q0k (t)dt
t!0
iD1
t t0 dt t0
This definite integral measures the area between the curve of instanta-
neous velocities of production and the horizontal axis during time unit
(t0 ; tn ). With t ! 0, time units t turn to time moments, and average
velocities turn to instantaneous velocities at these moments.
We can measure the accumulated amount of production by using
formula (2.16) for any time interval. For example, setting Qk (t0 ) D 0
and Qk (t) 0 with t > t0 , formula (2.16) measures the accumulated
production that was started at time moment t0 . We can thus call the
definite integral in Eq. (2.16) the accumulation function of production
of good k.
In Eq. (2.16), the upper limit of the integral is fixed. However, because
tn is a fixed moment of time, we can define it as a measure for the flowing
time that increases without limit. The integral can thus be analyzed as a
continuous function of its upper limit. Denoting tn D t and using the
principles of differential and integral calculus (see Sect. 10.14.2), we can
write:
dQk (t0 ; t)
D Q0k (t):
dt
The instantaneous velocity of production at time moment t thus corre-
sponds to the time derivative of the accumulation function of production.
By the notation t we underline that t is a continuous variable that measures
time, while tn is a fixed time moment.
According to the principles of differential and integral calculus
(Sect. 10.14.2), the accumulation function of production of good k
corresponds to the time integral of the instantaneous velocity of
production
2 Measuring in Economics 77
Z t
Qk (t) D Qk (t0 ) C Q0k (s)ds; (2.17)
t0
Example 2
Let the velocity of production of a firm be 6 (unit=d). How much does the
firm produce in 14 days?
where the running time with unit d is denoted by s. The same result is
obtained by adding the daily amounts of production:
X14
Q
Q(t1 ; t14 ) D t D 6 (unit=d) 1 (d) C C 6 (unit=d) 1 (d)
iD1
t
Example 3
Let the velocity of production of a firm be 10 (kg=h) when all workers are
working. How much does the firm produce in a week, if every worker does
8 hours per day and the firm operates 5 days a week?
Answer. Let us denote the initial moment by 0 (we could also denote it by
t0 ). The production of the firm in one day is then
Z ˇ8
8 ˇ
10 ds D ˇˇ 10 s D 10 (8 0) D 80 (kg);
0 0
Notice that the unit of running time s is h in the first integral and d in the
second. The measurement unit of both integrals is kg, even though in the
first is calculated on the daily, and in the second the weekly, production.
In these calculations, we have to remember in which units the velocity of
production and time are measured. According to the measurement units,
the calculated daily and weekly amounts of production are stock quantities,
even though they are measured from fixed time units.
The above result can also be obtained by calculating first the amount
of working hours in a week 40 (h) and then integrating as:
Z ˇ40
40 ˇ
10 ds D ˇˇ 10 s D 10 (40 0) D 400 (kg);
0 0
Example 4
Suppose the average velocity of production of a firm is constant q (kg=week).
How much does the firm produce in a year?
Example 5
Let the velocity of production qk (kg=week) of a firm producing good k be
constant. The accumulation function of production of the firm is then
Z
Qk (t) D qk dt D qk t C bk (kg);
Example 6
Let the instantaneous velocity of production of a firm producing good k
be constant 100 (kg=week), and let the accumulated amount of production
of the firm from the beginning of the year be 1500 (kg). What is the
accumulated amount of production of the firm in this year, in five weeks
from this moment?
Example 7
Let the loan capital of a person be 10;000 (e) at time moment t0 , and suppose
he pays back the loan with constant velocity 500 (e=mn). (a) What is the loan
capital in six months from now, if no interest is paid on the loan? (b) When
is the loan completely paid off?
Answer. (a) We denote the initial moment by t0 , the loan capital by A(t),
and running time by s with unit mn. The solution is then:
Z t0 C6
A(t0 C 6) D 10000 500 ds D 10000 500 (t0 C 6 t0 ) D 7000 (e):
t0
(b) The length of the time period is denoted by x (mn). Then we get
Z t0 Cx
0 D 10000 500 ds , 0 D 10000 500x , x D 20 (mn):
t0
The reader can check that the measurement units of x (mn) and dimen-
sional constants 10,000 (e) and 500 (e=mn) make the equations well
defined with respect to dimensions; notice that ds has unit mn. ˘
Example 1
Let the velocity of production of a firm be 17 (kg=d) at time moment t0 and
22 (kg=d) at moment t0 C 10, where time is measured in units d. What is the
average acceleration of production of the firm?
Answer. The length of the time unit is t0 C 10 (d) t0 D 10 (d), and the
average acceleration of production is:
v 22(kg=d) 17(kg=d) 5 kg 1 kg
D D D :˘
t 10(d) 10 d2 2 d2
Example 2
Let the instantaneous velocity of production of a firm producing good k be
6 (unit=h) at moment t0 , and 4 (unit=h) after six hours from moment t0 . What
is the average acceleration of production of the firm?
Example
Let the instantaneous acceleration of production of good k be constant ak
(kg=week2 ). The velocity of production of good k is then
Z
vk D ak dt D ak t C bk ;
where the constant of integration bk has unit kg=week, and time t is mea-
sured in units week. The velocity of production thus increases (decreases)
with constant positive (negative) velocity ak with time. The accumulation
function of the production with unit kg is then
Z
ak 2
Qk D (ak t C bk )dt D t C bk t C ck ;
2
where the horizontal axis is on the level of the earth. The horizontal
axis is pointing in the direction the ball is moving, and the vertical axis
measures the height of the ball from the earth. A generalization to a
production system with three, four, five, or more goods is straightforward.
It only requires the definition of the corresponding vector function and
to be operating analogously, see Estola (2011). In this book, however, we
restrict the analysis in the two-dimensional case that can be demonstrated
graphically.
In physics, the free motion of a rigid body can be demonstrated by
the motion of its mass point. The particle may be in a rotational motion
around its mass point (for example the motion path of a thrown hammer),
but the path of its motion can be described roughly by the motion of its
mass point. In the gravitational force field, if we forget the resistance of the
air, the time path of the mass point of a moving particle is a continuous
curve with the shape of a parabola. If we are only interested in the time
path of a particle—and not its rotational motion around its mass point—
the motion path of the particle can be characterized according to that of
its mass point which is identified as a point particle with a mass.
Also in economic kinematics, we can apply the motion of a point
particle with a ‘mass’. An economy with many industries, or a firm with
many products, can be identified at one time moment as a point in the
coordinate system of accumulated production values of all its products.
Here we describe the motion of this point in the space of accumulated
production values in order to define the velocity vector and speed for an
economy and for a multi-product firm.
The accumulated production values of goods 1 and 2 are denoted
as V1 (t) D p1 (t)Q1 (t) and V2 (t) D p2 (t)Q2 (t) at time moment t,
where Q1 ; Q2 with units kg; unit, respectively, are the accumulated
amounts of production of the two goods, and p1 ; p2 with units e=kg,
e=unit, respectively, the corresponding prices. The accumulated values
are thus measured in units e. The corresponding vector function for the
accumulated production values is
where V1 (t) and V2 (t) are the coordinate functions and the vector
function is denoted by a bold letter, see Sect. 10.5.1. This vector function
describes the state of a two-good production system at time moment
t. The function maps the state of the production system at every
time moment as a point (vector) in the two-dimensional space of the
accumulated production values of the two goods. The position vector
changes when the accumulated value of production of either of the goods
increases (accumulated values of production cannot decrease). Vector
function (2.18) can be presented as
Z t Z t
0 0
V(t) D V1 (t0 ) C V1 (s)ds; V2 (t0 ) C V2 (s)ds
t0 t0
Z t Z t
D .V1 (t0 ); V2 (t0 )/ C V10 (s)ds; V20 (s)ds
t0 t0
D V(t0 ) C .V1 (t0 ; t); V2 (t0 ; t)/ D V(t0 ) C V(t0 ; t); (2.19)
The reader can check this by giving function f (t) a specific form (for
example x(t) D 5t), and making the graphs of both functions in the
coordinate system (t; x). The graph of a one variable real-valued function
can thus be identified as that of a vector function, the coordinate functions
of which are the argument of the real function and the real function
itself.
A two-dimensional vector function is a generalization of a two-
dimensional vector that can be described either as a point in a
two-dimensional space, or as an arrow drawn from the origin to the
point. A vector function deviates from a vector so that the value of the
vector function is not a fixed point in the vector space, but the value point
of a vector function moves when the values of the coordinate functions
change.
Because the coordinate functions V1 and V2 of vector function (2.18)
are both functions of time t, the value point of vector function (2.18)
changes with time. If time is assumed continuous, the value set of
the vector function (2.18) defines a continuous curve in the coordinate
system, see Fig. 2.7. If, however, the coordinate functions depend on
a discrete variable (for example discrete time), the graph of the vector
function is a set of separate points in the coordinate system.
In Fig. 2.7 is shown the graph of the vector function
norms are the Euclidean norm—that exactly measures the length of the
arrow—and the absolute value norm. These norms taken from function
V(t) are
q
kV(t)k D V12 (t) C V22 (t) and kV(t)k1 D jV1 (t)j C jV2 (t)j:
The norms of a velocity vector are scalars that measure the velocity (speed)
of the point the vector function describes. The speed of the value of
production in a two-good production system can thus be measured by the
norms of the corresponding vector function. As an example, the Euclidean
norms of the vector function F0 (t) in Eq. (2.21) at moments t D 1 and
t D 2 are:
p p p p
kF0 (1)k D 9 C 9 D 18 D 4:24 and kF0 (2)k D 9 C 25 D 34 D 5:83:
The increase in the velocity of the latter coordinate function makes the
length of the arrow corresponding to the velocity vector increase with
time; that is, the speed of the point increases with time. An analogous
result is obtained by using the absolute value norm. The absolute value
norm of vector function F0 (t) in Eq. (2.21) at time moments t D 1 and
t D 2 is:
kF0 (1)k1 D 3 C 3 D 6 and kF0 (2)k1 D 3 C 5 D 8:
If the velocities of production values Vi0 (t) in Eq. (2.22) are replaced by
annual value added of industries in the economy, this norm corresponds
to the annual gross domestic product (GDP) of the economy. The GDP
of an economy thus measures the speed of a point in the space of
accumulated value added of industries of the economy, see Estola (2011).
Example
Suppose a player tosses a fair die once and wins the amount of euros the
die expresses. What is the expected win in this game?
Answer. Every possible value 1; : : : ; 6 of the die has probability 1=6. The
expected win in the game (E comes from ‘Expected’ and W from ‘Win’) is:
1 1 1
E(W) D 1 (e) C 2 (e) C C 6 (e)
6 6 6
1 21 1
D (1 C 2 C C 6) (e) D (e) D 3 (e): (2.23)
6 6 2
and milk with 1/3, etc.) and calculate a weighted average of the two index
values every month. This is a weighted price index of the two goods.
The most commonly used weighted price index is the consumer price
index (CPI) that measures the average living costs of households. The CPI
is a weighted average of price indexes of consumption goods. The weights
are the shares of the goods in the aggregate expenditures of households.
These weights sum up to unity as they should, and they are determined by
interviewing consumers after fixed time units. For example, if on average
consumers spend 10% of their monthly expenditures on milk, the price
index of milk has weight 0.1 in CPI.
The CPI is not the only commonly used weighted price index. The
average price development in export and import goods are calculated on a
similar basis. For example, the prices of export goods of a country are
transformed to the corresponding price indexes, and an average price
index of export goods is calculated by weighting the individual price
indexes by the value shares of the goods of the total exports of the country
at a time unit. This type of calculated average price index is called an
export price index.
Besides price indexes, volume indexes of amounts of goods are defined
because the amounts of different goods are not additive. For example,
the annual production of sugar may be measured in units kg=y, that of
milk in units l=y, and so forth. Thus this addition has the same problem
with measurement units as prices have. Volume indexes are dimensionless
numbers as price indexes. By weighting the volume indexes of production
flows of individual goods with a certain principle, we get average volume
indexes that measure the development of the flow of production of a group
of goods. Commonly used average volume indexes are the volume index
of domestic production, and export and import volume indexes.
Example 1
The labor input of a worker is changed in a certain production by the share
1=100 of his weekly work time (he does mostly other works but changes
this work this much). Labor input in working hours can also be changed,
for example by 3=8 hours in a day, the use of computer time in production
can be changed by 3 minutes in a week, and so on. ˘
Example 2
If the use of labor of a firm is analyzed as a function of time t denoted
by L(t), the following connection exists between average and marginal
productivity of labor, and ‘instantaneous velocity of productivity of labor’
(see Sect. 10.7.3):
q.L(t)/
d L(t)
L0 (t) 0 q.L(t)/
D q .L(t)/ : (2.25)
dt L(t) L(t)
Formula(2.25) implies that the instantaneous velocity of productivity of
q.L(t)/
labor, d L(t) =dt, is positive, if the instantaneous growth rate of use of
labor L (t)=L(t) is positive, and the marginal productivity of labor q0 .L(t)/ D
0
dq=dL
is greater than the average productivity q .L(t)/ =L(t). However,
d L(t) =dt is also positive if L0 (t)=L(t) < 0 and q0 .L(t)/ < q .L(t)/ =L(t). We
q.L(t)/
Example 3
One worker working with a computer does a certain amount of production
in one month. Adding another worker to work with the same computer
increases the monthly production with that computer, but hardly as much
as the first worker increased from zero production. Adding a third worker
working with the same computer still increases the monthly production
with this computer, but the fifth worker working with the same computer
hardly increases the monthly production at all. ˘
Let the measurement unit of labor input be h=mn and suppose that
the labor input in the production of good k is increased by one hour per
month at a time. The law of non-increasing marginal productivity can
then be expressed as:
ˇ ˇ ˇ
qk ˇˇ qk ˇˇ qk ˇˇ
;
Lk ˇLk D0 (h=mn) Lk ˇLk D1 (h=mn) Lk ˇLk D2 (h=mn)
Δqk
ΔLk
Δq k
ΔLk Lk = 100
Δq k
ΔLk Lk = 300
Example 4
Suppose the production function of a firm is of the form q(L) D aL bL2 ,
where the measurement units of q; L are kg=week and h=week, respectively,
and a; b are positive constants with units kg=h and (kgweek)=h2 , respectively.
The marginal productivity of labor is then
a
q0 (L) D a 2bL 0 ) L ;
2b
where q0 (L) has unit kg=h. Suppose a D 100; b D 1=2. Then non-increasing
marginal productivity of labor holds with this function (L < a=2b D 100):
References
Allen, R. G. D. (1938). Mathematical analysis for economists. London: MacMillan.
Allen, R. G. D. (1956). Mathematical economics. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
de Jong, F. (1967). Dimensional analysis for economists. Amsterdam: North-
Holland.
Estola, M. (2011). Measuring the growth and the structural change of a
multi-sector economy. Hyperion International Journal of Econophysics & New
Economy, 4(1), 23–44.
Fisher, I. (1930). The theory of interest. New York: Macmillan.
Ohanian, H. C. (1989). Physics. Second Edition Expanded. New York: W.W.
Norton & Company.
3
Consumer Behavior
Example
Let the average daily flow of meat consumption of a consumer be 0.1 (kg=d);
this corresponds to the weekly flow 0.7 (kg=week). Weekly consumption is
thus obtained as an average of daily decisions. ˘
E D p1 q1 C p2 q2 C C pn qn ;
where qi are the flows of consumption of the n goods and pi their prices,
i D 1; : : : ; n. The measurement units of the quantities could be, for
example, q1 (kg=week), q2 (unit=week), q3 (l=week), : : : , and p1 (e/kg),
p2 (e=unit), p3 (e=l), and so on.
In this chapter, we assume a consumer’s decision-making situation as
simple as possible. The consumer can choose his weekly consumption of
only two goods the consumer consumes every week. For clarity, let good
1 be ‘food’ and good 2 ‘playing video games’ according to the traditional
choice between ’food or fun’. This simplification is made because choices
between two goods can be demonstrated in a two-dimensional space. A
generalization to n goods (n > 2) is analogous, but it requires functions
of several variables and it cannot be demonstrated graphically if n 4.
3 Consumer Behavior 101
where the consumption flows of the two goods are denoted by qf and qv .
In the following we do not present the measurement units of the quantities
in equations as above to simplify the notation; units are treated separately
when necessary. The combinations of consumption flows the consumer
can afford with his budgeted funds are shown in Fig. 3.1, where on the
coordinate axes are the consumption flows of the two goods. Only the
positive quadrant of the space is presented—negative consumption flows
are impossible—and on the horizontal axis qv D 0 and on the vertical
axis qf D 0.
The line in Fig. 3.1 is called the budget line or the frontier of the
set of consumption possibilities of the consumer. The points on the
line represent the combinations of consumption flows of the two goods
qv (h / week )
T / pv
T= p q + pq
f f v v
T/p f
q f (kg / week )
where the budget holds as an equality. Thus the line is the graphical
presentation of the weekly budget of the consumer. Axiom 1 implies
that the graphical presentation of the weekly budget of a consumer is
unique. If the consumer does not play video games at all, he operates
on the horizontal axis in Fig. 3.1 and can at most consume food qfmax D
T=pf (kg=week). If the consumer does not eat at all during the week, he
operates on the vertical axis and can at most play video games qvmax D
T=pv (h=week). These cases are obtained from Eq. (3.1) by setting first
qv D 0 and then qf D 0, and solving the other quantity from the
equation. In the combinations of consumption flows of the two goods
inside the area restricted by the budget line and the two coordinate axes,
the consumer does not use all the money T (e=week).
The slope of the budget line in Fig. 3.1 is derived as follows. Suppose
two combinations of consumption flows of the two goods are located on
the budget line; let these be (qf0 ; qv0 ) and (qf1 ; qv1 ). Then
qv pf
D :
qf pv
This slope of the budget line can also be obtained by solving Eq. (3.1)
with respect to qv and taking the derivative with respect to qr because
limqf !0 q
qf
v
D dq
dqf
v
, see Sect. 10.7.
3 Consumer Behavior 103
The slope of the budget line is the ratio of the prices of the two goods
with a minus sign. The measurement unit of the slope h=kg shows that
it expresses the exchange rate between hours of video games and one
kilogram of food. The negativity of the slope shows that if the consumer
operates on his budget line, he must decrease his food consumption
(qf < 0) if he wants to increase his playing of video games (qv > 0),
and vice versa. These are the alternative costs of increases in consumption
of the two goods, because on the points of the budget line, all money T
(e=week) is used.
Example
Suppose a consumer has budgeted himself T D 400 (e=week) for consump-
tion, and the prices of the two goods are: pf D 2 (e=kg) and pv D 4 (e=h),
respectively. The budget equation is then
400 D 2 qf C 4 qv :
p
The slope of the budget equation is pvf D 24 D 12 , and the maximal
consumption flows are: qfmax D 200 (kg=week) and qvmax D 100 (h=week). ˘
qv (h / week )
q vC
●C
D ● I II
q vA
B ● ●A
IV III
q fB
q fA q f (kg / week )
Note. Note that denotes the preference relation and not the ‘at least
as great as’ relation, that is denoted by . Thus we cannot operate
mathematically with relation A B as we can with A B. ˘
D D aB C (1 a)C; 0 a 1: (3.3)
3 Consumer Behavior 105
Example
Let us identify the combinations of consumption flows in Fig. 3.2 as points
in a two-dimensional vector space. Let B D (qfB ; qvB ) D (4; 8) and C D
(qfC ; qvC ) D (12; 16), where we have omitted measurement units for short-
ness. Then A D (qfA ; qvA ) D (12; 8). The rules for multiplication a vector by
a scalar and adding two vectors are given in Sect. 10.4.1. With these rules,
the following results can be derived:
(1) a D 1=2 ) D1 D 1=2 (4; 8) C 1=2 (12; 16) D (2; 4) C (6; 8) D (8; 12).
(2) a D 1=4 ) D2 D 1=4 (4; 8) C 3=4 (12; 16) D (1; 2) C (9; 12) D (10; 14).
The reader can check that points D1 , D2 are on the line segment BC. ˘
qv (h / week )
I II
q vA
●A C●
IV ● D III
●B
q fA q f (kg / week )
vertical lines going through point A so that for every cutting point on the
vertical line, a unique cutting point exists on the horizontal line.
Let one such pair of cutting points be B, C in Fig. 3.3, where the
segment of line OS combining points B and C belongs in area III. Now,
Axiom 3 implies that a unique point exists on line segment BC that the
consumer considers equally good as point A. Because the same holds for
every pair of cutting points B, C defined by line OS when it turns over the
consumption space, the twisting of the OS line over the space defines a
unique set of points (a curve) that represents equal weekly satisfaction
as point A. This curve can be proved continuous, that is, the points
formulate a continuous curve in the space. The proof of this would require
an exact set-theoretic description of the situation, which is the reason we
omit it; see Debreu (1959, pp. 55–58). This way derived curve is called an
indifference curve of the consumer.
§: An indifference curve represents points of equal satisfaction (later
utility) for a consumer. ˘
One continuous indifference curve going through point A divides the
consumption space of a consumer into two subspaces; points closer to
the origin than the curve and points further away. The first subspace
represents smaller and the latter higher weekly utility than point A.
The uniqueness of an indifference curve proved above implies that the
consumer can rank every point in the consumption space with respect
to point A. Points further away from origin than the indifference curve
going through point A represent higher, those on the curve equal, and
those closer to the origin smaller weekly utility than at point A. Because
point A was chosen randomly, any other point could have been chosen as
the reference point, and a curve could have been defined that represents
points of equal weekly utility as that point. Axioms 2 and 3 thus guarantee
that every point in the space can be ranked in preference relation with
respect to other points. Thus the consumer can say of any two points in
the consumption space whether he prefers one to another, or considers
them equally good.
The indifference curves representing different levels of weekly utility
of a consumer construct a family of curves that covers the whole
consumption space. Every point in the space represents certain weekly
108 Newtonian Microeconomics
utility, and equally good points define an indifference curve. Thus the
space is covered with indifference curves lying next to each other. The
further away from origin a curve lies, the higher weekly utility it repre-
sents.
The diagram of a family of indifference curves is analogous to the
contour curves of hills in large-scale topographical maps. The third
dimension, that measures the level of weekly utility, is assumed to be
rising upward from the two dimensional plane of the page of the book.
Indifference curves are the contour curves of the ‘hill of weekly utility’.
Indifference curves are obtained by cutting the ‘weekly utility hill’ with
horizontal planes at various heights, and dropping these ‘cutting point
curves’ on the ground plane. The method is exactly the same as how
contour curves of hills are presented in large-scale topographical maps, as
track-finding runners know. The lowest point of the ‘weekly utility hill’ is
in the origin (qf ; qv ) D (0; 0), and the hill rises when moving away from
the origin.
In Fig. 3.4 is graphed two-variable function u D A(aqf )c (bqv )1c ,
where the units of the positive constants A; a; b are ut=week, week=kg,
and week=h, respectively, and 0 < c < 1 is dimensionless. The numerical
values of the constants are: A D 10; a D 2; b D 2; c D 0:5. Utility u
is thus measured in units ut=week, and the values of the function create
a surface in the three-dimensional space. The arguments of the function
are measured on the horizontal axes, and the values of the function on
the vertical axis (Sect. 10.5.2). The contour curves corresponding to the
surface in Fig. 3.4 are presented in Fig. 3.5. This example demonstrates
the indifference curves corresponding to this utility function.
the week, the satisfaction he gains from his consumption takes place
in that week. For this reason, the values of utility function u(qf ; qv )
are measured in units ut=week. Utility u is thus a flow quantity that
measures the average level of satisfaction of the consumer in a week. Utility
function itself is a useful theoretical term in formulating quantities—such
as a consumer’s marginal willingness-to-pay for goods—that are helpful
in modeling consumer behavior.
§: The Average utility of a good for a consumer is measured by
dividing the utility of the consumer at a time unit by his flow of
consumption of the good at the time unit. ˘
The average utility of food and playing video games in a week are thus
u(qf ; qv ) u(qf ; qv )
and
qf qv
the function value and a marginal change in one argument of the function.
A change in the argument may be positive or negative (Sect. 10.9), and
the value of the function either changes or stays constant due to this
change. If an increase in the argument increases the value of a function,
and thus a decrease in the value of the argument decreases the value of
the function, the partial derivative like an ordinary derivative is positive,
and vice versa. Consumption flows qr0 ; qh0 are shown as arguments of the
utility function to demonstrate that marginal utilities depend on current
flows of consumption. Later, we do not usually show them in order to
simplify the notation.
The measurement unit of the marginal utility of a good is the same as
that of average utility. According to Axiom 2, for a rational consumer
the marginal utilities of goods are positive; that is, an increase in the
weekly flow of consumption of a good increases the weekly utility of the
consumer, and vice versa. If qf > qf0 , then u(qf ; qv0 ) > u(qf0 ; qv0 ) and
vice versa, namely, both the denominator and numerator in Eq. (3.4) are
simultaneously positive or negative, and the same holds for playing video
games.
§: Law of non-increasing marginal utility. Non-increasing marginal
utility means that an increase in the flow of consumption of a good
increases the consumer’s utility (satisfaction) flow at a non-increasing
rate. ˘
Example
Eating one orange increases the daily utility of a consumer. Eating another
orange during the same day further increases the daily utility, but at most
by as much as the first did. Eating a fifth orange during the same day,
however, does not increase the daily utility as much as the first did, and
eating the twentieth orange during one day hardly increases the daily
utility at all. The twenty-fifth orange may even make the consumer feel
bad, but a rational consumer never reaches that level of consumption
(Axiom 2). ˘
unit, the less we enjoy increasing the consumption of the good in the
time unit. In the case of a differentiable utility function, the law of non-
increasing marginal utility can be expressed mathematically as:
@2 u(qf ; qv ) @2 u(qf ; qv )
0; 0;
@q2f @q2v
that is, the second order partial derivatives of the utility function with
respect to same quantity are non-positive. According to the law of non-
increasing marginal utility, the weekly utility of a consumer increases
with the consumption flows of goods, but a fixed increase in the flow
of consumption causes at most an equal utility increase as the previous
identical increase in the argument.
From the point of view of the consumer, finding the optimal combina-
tion of consumption flows can be thought of as moving along the budget
line starting from either of the coordinate axes. Suppose a consumer is
consuming at point qfmax and he considers whether to move along the
budget line towards playing more video games, see Fig. 3.1. The consumer
considers whether to change x (e=week) from food consumption to
playing video games. The consumer is assumed to do this change if it
increases his weekly utility. With x (e=week) the consumer can buy the
amount (u=qv ) (x=pv ) (ut=week) of utility from playing video
games. Analogously, with x (e=week) the consumer can buy (u=qf )
(x=pf ) (ut=week) of utility using this money on food.
In the optimal situation, the consumer cannot increase his weekly
utility by changing his combination of consumption flows. In the optimal
situation, the amount of weekly utility to be obtained with a fixed amount
of money is the same for all goods. This situation corresponds to
u x u x u 1 u 1
D , D ; (3.6)
qf pf qv pv qf pf qv pv
If Eq. (3.6) does not hold, the consumer can increase his weekly utility by
changing his bundle of consumption flows. The ratios
u 1 u 1
and
qf pf qv pv
with unit ut=e are called the efficiency ratios of consumption of the
goods, because they measure the amount of utility to be obtained from
these goods by one euro at the prevailing flows of consumption.
The above means that the consumer chooses that point on his budget
line where he ‘most efficiently buys utility’. If the prices, budgeted funds,
and goods stay the same during several weeks, we can believe that with
time the consumer ends up consuming so that his weekly utility gets
maximized. The optimal situation can thus be considered as the point
where the consumer ends up if the decision-making situation stays the
same long enough.
The condition for efficient consumption in Eq. (3.6) can be generalized
to a situation where the consumer is choosing between n goods,
u 1 u 1 u 1
D D D ; (3.7)
q1 p1 q2 p2 qn pn
when the consumer changes his weekly playing of video games from qv0 to
qv1 , that is qv D qv1 qv0 . The weekly utility of the consumer is in the
beginning u D u(qf0 ; qv0 ), and we analyze how it changes with qv ¤ 0.
The marginal utility of playing video games u=qv measures in units
ut=h the change in weekly utility due to a change in playing video games.
Because qv is a certain amount of playing video games in a week, its
u
effect on the weekly utility can be expressed as: u D q v
qv (ut=week).
When the consumer changes his playing of video games by qv ¤ 0,
his weekly utility changes due to the positive marginal utility. For the
weekly utility to stay constant after this change, the consumer must
simultaneously change his food consumption in the opposite direction.
Let us denote the change in the flow of food consumption as qf D
u
qf1 qf0 . The effect of this on utility is u D q f
qf (ut=week). For
the weekly utility to stay constant when the composition of consumption
changes from (qf0 ; qv0 ) to (qf1 ; qv1 ), the following condition must hold
(qf ; qv ¤ 0):
u u qv u u
qf C qv D 0 , D = : (3.8)
qf qv qf qf qv
On the left hand side of the latter form of the equation is the ratio
of changes in consumption flows, and on the right hand side the ratio
of marginal utilities with minus sign. This ratio expresses the exchange
rate between the two consumption flows that keeps the weekly utility
of the consumer constant. Because marginal utilities are positive at all
consumption flows, the right hand side of the latter equation in Eq. (3.8)
is negative. Then, the left hand side is also negative, that is, if qf is
positive then qv is negative and vice versa.
The consumer is assumed to be able to estimate the numerical values
of his marginal utilities at all levels of his consumption flows. From
Eq. (3.8) we can solve how much the consumer is ready to decrease his
food consumption (qf < 0) to increase his playing of video games
by qv > 0 for his weekly utility to stay constant. The exchange
rate between the two consumption flows, which keeps the consumer’s
weekly utility constant, is determined by marginal utilities. The greater
the marginal utility of food, and the smaller that of playing video games,
3 Consumer Behavior 117
qv (h / week )
I II
q vA
●A
IV III
q fA q f (kg / week )
Fig. 3.6 An indifference curve of a consumer
the greater the absolute value of the exchange rate; that is, the more
playing of video games the consumer is ready to exchange for a certain
consumption of food, and vice versa.
We analyze the situation by using Fig. 3.6, where a certain combination
of consumption flows is denoted by A. The bundles of consumption flows
the consumer considers equally good as point A are in areas I and III.
Only in these areas the consumption flow of one good increases and that
of the other decreases as compared with A. Earlier on we showed that
all bundles of consumption flows equally good as point A formulate a
continuous curve in the plane. Next we show the connection between
an indifference curve and the analysis in this section. The smaller
. the
qv u u
changes qf , qv are, the more exactly ratio qf D qf qv
corresponds to the slope of the tangent of an indifference curve at a point.
By the limiting process we get the following exact correspondence (see
Sects. 10.7.1 and 10.10.2):
.
dqv @u @u
D : (3.9)
dqf @qf @qv
118 Newtonian Microeconomics
Result (3.9) can be derived also by using differential calculus. The change
in the value of a two variable function u D u(qf ; qv ) (the total differential
of u) is defined in differential calculus as (see Sect. 10.10.2):
@u @u
du D dqf C dqv :
@qf @qf
qv (h / week )
T/p v
q *
v
u 2
u 1
u 0
q *
f
T/p f
q f (kg / week )
The consumer can now affect his weekly utility only by quantity qf ,
because other quantities in the function are constants and qv is substituted
by the budget equation. Differentiating the utility function with respect
to time by using the chain rule (Sect. 10.9.4), we get:
du 0 @u pf @u
u0 (t) D q (t) D q0f (t); (3.13)
dqf f @qf pv @qv
@u @u p
where the two quantities subtracted in @q f
pvf @q v
both have unit ut=kg.
In Eq. (3.13), the unit of u (t) is ut=week and that of q0f (t) is kg=week2 ;
0 2
u0 (t) and q0f (t) are thus the instantaneous acceleration of utility and food
consumption, while u and qf are the corresponding velocities.
122 Newtonian Microeconomics
du @u @u pf @u 1 @u 1
D0 , D0 , D : (3.14)
dqf @qf @qv pv @qf pf @qv pv
pv @u
q0f (t) > 0 if pf > 0;
@u @qf
@qv
pv @u
q0f (t) < 0 if pf < 0;
@u @qf
@qv
pv @u
q0f (t) D 0 if pf D 0:
@u @qf
@qv
Analogous adjustment rules can be derived for playing video games. This
is done as follows. Solve the budget equation with respect to qf (t), use this
to substitute qf (t) in the utility function, and differentiate it with respect
to time. Then, define the adjustment rules as we did above. Quantities
@u @u @u @u
hf D = pv ; hv D = pf
@qf @qv @qv @qf
@u @u 1
D :
@T @qv pv
utility of food and the price of playing video games, and negatively on his
marginal utility of playing video games.
In Sect. 3.8 we show that quantity Ff ,
@u @u
Ff D hf pf D = pv pf
@qf @qv
can be interpreted as the force this consumer directs upon his food
consumption. The explanation for this interpretation is that the greater
this quantity, the higher the acceleration of food consumption of this
consumer. The force acting upon the food consumption of this consumer
consists of the pleasures and pains a marginal increase in the flow of
food consumption causes for him. The consumer compares his marginal
willingness-to-pay and the price of food and changes his flow of food
consumption on this basis. The acceleration of food consumption of this
consumer is positive, if the above-defined force is positive, and vice versa.
Thus we use the concept of force in this modeling analogously as it is used
in Newtonian mechanics.
In Sect. 10.12.2 we show that a consumer’s marginal willingness-to-
pay for a good is independent on the chosen utility function: any
continuous function expressing the same preference order defines an
equal marginal willingness-to-pay for a good in the neighborhood of
a consumer’s optimum. The ambiguity in measuring utility thus does
not affect our modeling of consumer behavior, because different values
for marginal utilities by different utility functions divided by marginal
utilities of budgeted funds by the same utility function give equal marginal
willingness-to-pay values.
@u 0 @u 0
L0 (t) D q (t) zpf q0f (t) C q (t) zpv q0v (t)
@qf f @qv v
@u 0 @u
D zpf qf (t) C zpv q0v (t);
@qf @qv
where time t is left out of the consumption flows to simplify the nota-
tion, is a multivariable function. In Sect. 10.5 is given the mathematical
principles of two-variable functions. The above multivariable function
can always be simplified to a one or a two-variable function by assuming
that other variables in the analysis stay constant. This way we can operate
with only one or two variables at a time, even though we know that a
consumer’s marginal willingness-to-pay for any good depends on various
quantities.
Next we study how a consumer’s marginal willingness-to-pay for food
depends on the quantities included in the model. We study this by
differentiating hf with respect to qf ; T; pv :
!
@2 u @2 u pf @u @u @2 u @2 u pf
2
@hf @q2f @qf @qv pv @qv @qf @qv @qf @qv pv
D pv ; (3.17)
@qf @u 2
@qv
@2 u @u @u @2 u
@hf @qv @qf @qv @qf @q2v
D ; (3.18)
@T @u 2
@qv
2
@ u @u @2 u @u T pf qf @u
@hf @qv @qf
2 @qv @qf @qv pv @qf
D 2 C : (3.19)
@pv @u @u
@qv @qv
@2 u @2 u
0; 0;
@q2f @q2v
make @hf =@qf < 0 and @hf =@T > 0. In @hf =@qf , the first term in
parentheses in the numerator is negative, the latter term in parentheses is
positive, and the denominator is positive. The condition for @hf =@qf <
0; @hf =@T > 0 is thus the same as that the equilibrium point of the
consumer is a maximum. A unique negative relation thus exists between
the consumer’s marginal willingness-to-pay for food and his flow of food
consumption. In @hf =@pv , the first additive term is negative and the latter
is positive; thus the sign is ambiguous.
The following equation corresponds to the consumer’s optimum,
@u(qf ; qv ) @u(qf ; qv )
pf D hf , pf D = pv : (3.20)
@qf @qv
Equation (3.20) is called the demand relation for food of this consumer.
The demand relation is similar to that of the marginal willingness-to-
pay, but their slopes in coordinate system (qf ,e=kg) differ. We prove this
next. By totally differentiating Eq. (3.20) and using the utility function in
Eq. (3.12), we get:
0 1
@2 u @u @2 u @u
B 2 qf C
B @qv @qf @qv @qv @qf C
B1 C C dpf
@ @u 2 A
@qv
0 ! 2 1
@2 u @2 u pf @u @u @2 u pf @u
B C
B @q2f @qv @qf pv @qv @qf @qv @q2v pv @qf C
DB
B pv C
C dqf
@ @u 2 A
@qv
0 1
@2 u @u @2 u @u
B @q @q @q @q2 @q C
B v f v v f C
CB C dT
@ @u 2 A
@qv
3 Consumer Behavior 129
0 1
@2 u @u @2 u @u T pf qf @u
B @q2 @q @q @q @q @qf C
B v f v f v pv C
CB C C dpv ; (3.21)
@ @u 2 @u A
@qv @qv
where the sign of the last partial is ambiguous. Because pf , hf both have
unit e=kg, they can be measured on the same coordinate axis. The slope
@pf
@qf
D aa21 < 0 of the demand relation in Eq. (3.20) in coordinate system
@h
(qf ;e=kg) deviates from that of the marginal willingness-to-pay: @qff D
a2 < 0. Because a1 > 1, the latter of the curves is steeper. The reason for
this is the income effect a change in price has on the marginal willingness-
to-pay. If the price of food decreases, a consumer’s utility maximizing flow
of food consumption increases. However, a price decrease increases the real
budgeted funds of the consumer, and this moves his marginal willingness-
to-pay relation away from the origin. A price increase, analogously, moves
the marginal willingness-to-pay relation towards the origin.
Equations (3.16), (3.20) give similar results concerning how quantities
qf ; T; pv affect the optimal flow of food consumption, and both are
useful. The demand relation is estimable from the real world by statistical
methods with observed prices and flows of consumption of a consumer,
and the marginal willingness-to-pay relation can be quantified by creating
a questionnaire.
130 Newtonian Microeconomics
Example 1
Let the weekly utility function of a consumer be u D aqf qv , where a with
unit (ut week)=(kg h) is a positive constant and the budget equation is as
earlier. With this utility function, the marginal utilities are
@u @u
D aqv > 0; D aqf > 0;
@qf @qv
@2 u @2 u @2 u @2 u
2 D D 0; D D a > 0:
@qf @qv2 @qf @qv @qv @qf
Solving qv from the budget equation and setting in the utility function
gives:
aqf
uD T pf qf :
pv
du a T T
D0 , T 2pf qf D 0 ) q
f D , pf D ; (3.23)
dqf pv 2pf 2qf
and the sufficient condition for maximum holds: d2 u=dq2f D 2apf =pv < 0.
The utility maximizing flow of food consumption q f in Eq. (3.23) positively
depends on T and negatively on pf . We call function q f this consumer’s
demand function for food, and the last form of the equation his inverse
demand function for food. Price pv does not affect q f in this case, which
result is caused by the assumed form for the utility function. The consumer’s
marginal willingness-to-pay for food is
@u
@qf @u @u
hf D pv ; where D aqv and D aqf :
@u @qf @qv
@qv
Thus
pv qv T
hf D D pf ; (3.24)
qf qf
@u @u
the marginal willingness-to-pay is to divide @qf
D aqv by @T D aqf =pv . In
the consumer’s optimum, his marginal willingness-to-pay equals with price
pf . ˘
Example 2
Let a consumer’s weekly utility function be
where the quantities are as earlier, constants A; a; b > 0 have units ut=week,
week=kg, week=h, respectively, and 0 < c < 1 is a pure number. Utility is thus
measured in units ut=week and the terms in parentheses are dimensionless
as they should be for dimensional consistency. Marginal utilities of the two
goods with units ut=kg, ut=h, respectively, are then:
@u
D Aac(aqf )c1 (bqv )1c > 0; (3.26)
@qf
@u
D Ab(1 c)(aqf )c (bqv )c > 0; (3.27)
@qv
@2 u
D Aa2 c(c 1)(aqf )c2 (bqv )1c < 0;
@q2f
@2 u
D Ab2 c(1 c)(aqf )c (bqv )c1 < 0;
@q2v
@2 u
D Aabc(1 c)(aqf )c1 (bqv )c > 0:
@qv @qf
Marginal utilities are thus decreasing and the unique second order cross
partial is positive; sufficient conditions for utility maximization thus hold.
Substituting the earlier assumed budget equation in the utility function
gives:
bŒT pf qf 1c
u D A(aqf )c :
pv
132 Newtonian Microeconomics
From Eq. (3.28) we can solve this consumer’s demand and inverse demand
functions for food as:
cT cT
q
f D , pf D : (3.29)
pf qf
we get
c T
pf pf D 0;
1c qf
where hf D 1c
c T
qf
pf is the consumer’s marginal willingness-to-pay for
food. Notice that we could also have derived the marginal willingness-to-
pay as
@u
@qf cpv qv
hf D pv D ;
@u (1 c)qf
@qv
@u @u
where @q f
, @qv
are as in Eqs. (3.26), (3.27), respectively, and substituting there
the budget equation in the form pv qv D T pf qf .
Solving the budget equation with respect to qf , substituting this in the
utility function and optimizing with respect to qv , we can solve the optimal
playing of video games as: q v D (1 c)T=pv (h=week). Another way to get
this result is to substitute q f in the budget equation and solve it for qv . The
condition for efficient consumption holds with q
f ; qv :
3 Consumer Behavior 133
c 1c
@u 1 ac b(1 c) @u 1
DA D ;
@qf pf pf pv @qv pv
(week=e)1c . Thus their product has unit week=e, and multiplying this unit
by that of A, ut=week, we get ut=e. ˘
€
kg
40
30
20
10
0 qf
0 2 4 6 8 10
du
q0f (t) D f (Ff ); f 0 (Ff ) > 0; f (0) D 0; Ff D ; (3.30)
dqf
3 Consumer Behavior 135
where f is a function with the above characteristics. The first order Taylor
series approximation (Sect. 10.10.1) of function f in the neighborhood of
@u @u pf
the optimum point Ff D @q f
@q v pv
D 0 is:
where f 0 (0) > 0 is a constant. The unit of q0f (t) is kg=week2 , that of
@u @u pf
@qf
@q v pv
is ut=kg, and the unit of f 0 (0) equals with that of f 0 (Ff ) D
dq0f (t)=dFf , which is (kg=week)2 =ut. Equation (3.31) is therefore dimen-
sionally homogeneous.
Now, q0f (t) is the instantaneous acceleration of food consumption of
the consumer. If the reason for the acceleration of food consumption,
@u @u pf
@qf
@q v pv
, is named as the force acting upon the food consumption
of this consumer, we can denote f 0 (0) D 1=mfd (subindex d refers to
demand) and name positive constant mfd as the inertial ‘mass’ of food
consumption of this consumer. Equation (3.31) is then of the same form
as Newton’s equation in physics, a D (1=m) F , F D ma, where a
is acceleration, F force, and m the mass of the moving particle.
Constant mfd is the ratio between force and acceleration, and it
measures the sensitivity of the flow of food consumption of this consumer
with respect to the force. The factors affecting mfd are those that retard
changes in the flow of food consumption of this consumer, like limited
knowledge of compensating goods, time to find such goods, and so on.
The inertial ‘mass’ of food consumption can be measured via the force and
@u @u pf
acceleration as mfd D @qf @qv pv =q0f (t), if these quantities are known
and deviate from zero. This corresponds to the definition of inertial mass
in physics.
136 Newtonian Microeconomics
q f ' (t )
∂q f ' (t )
q f ' (t ) = f ( F f ), <0
∂q f
q f ' (t ) > 0
q f ' (t ) = 0 •
q f 1(t )
*
q f (t ) q f 2 (t ) q f (t )
q f ' (t ) < 0
Fig. 3.9 The relation between flow and acceleration of food consumption
and according to Eq. (3.15), d2 u=dq2f < 0. Equation (3.30) can thus
be graphed as a decreasing relation in coordinate system (qf ; q0f (t)), see
Fig. 3.9.
In the points of the decreasing relation in Fig. 3.9, q0f (t) > 0 (qf
is increasing with time) if qf < qf , (for example qf D qf 1 ), and
q0f (t) < 0 if qf > qf (e.g. qf D qf 2 ). Situation q0f (t) D 0 (qf constant)
corresponds to qf D qf . The arrows show the direction the consumer
changes his flow of food consumption when he is at some other point on
the decreasing relation than in the equilibrium point on the horizontal
axis, where q0f (t) D 0. In Fig. 3.9, point qf is one point on the inverse
demand function of the consumer. Outside the equilibrium point qf , the
consumer adjusts his flow of food consumption toward the equilibrium.
.
@u @u
Because every point in the inverse demand function pf D @q f @qv
pv
is the equilibrium state of the consumer at a certain price, the stability
demonstrated in Fig. 3.9 holds for every point on the inverse demand
3 Consumer Behavior 137
@u @u pf
mfd q0f (t) D C FSf I (3.32)
@qf @qv pv
them with unit ut=kg. This measuring is, however, omitted in this book
and static friction is treated as an unknown quantity, the numerical value
of which can be estimated by using Eq. (3.32).
@u @u pf
According to Eq. (3.32), q0f (t) > 0 if @q f
@q v pv
C FSf > 0,
@u @u pf
and vice versa. Further, FSf < 0 if @qf
@qv pv
> 0, vice versa, and
@u @u pf
jFSf j j @q f
j.
Thus the consumer changes his flow of food
@qv pv
consumption only if the net benefit from this exceeds his static friction.
Static friction does not affect the dynamics of food consumption of this
consumer after the adjustment has begun, that is, after the active force
component has exceeded the static friction. Static friction only explains
that the flow of food consumption may not always be changed when the
active force component deviates from zero.
Example
Let the utility function of a consumer be u D aqf qv , where a with unit (ut
week)=(kg h) is a positive constant. The budget equation is assumed as in
Example 1 in Sect. 3.7.2. This functional form is assumed for utility because
it gives a simple form for the Newtonian equation of food consumption.
The reader should realize that if we applied, for example, function (3.25)
for utility, a very complicated model would result.
Solving the budget equation with respect to qv and substituting this in
the utility function, we get:
aqf
uD T pf qf :
pv
du a
D T 2pf qf ;
dqf pv
and the Newtonian equation of food consumption with this force is:
du a
mfd q0f (t) D , mfd q0f (t) D .T 2pf qf (t)/: (3.33)
dqf pv
We first study qualitatively the content of Eq. (3.33) without solving it.
Because a; pv > 0, the right hand side (rhs) of the equation is positive if
3 Consumer Behavior 139
T
T 2pf qf (t) > 0 , qf (t) < ;
2pf
and vice versa. If the rhs of Eq. (3.33) is positive, then also its lhs is positive,
that is, q0f (t) > 0. Because qf D T=(2pf ) is the utility maximizing flow of
consumption derived earlier, Eq. (3.33) implies that the consumer increases
qf if qf < q
f , and decreases qf if qf > qf . Thus the system is stable and will
converge with time into the optimal state.
The solution of differential equation Eq. (3.33) (Sect. 10.15) confirms
these qualitative results:
2apf
T t
qf (t) D C C0 e pv mfd ; (3.34)
2pf
T
pf ;
2qf
T
pf D mfd q0f (t) , T 2pf qf D 2mfd qf q0f (t);
2qf
a T
(T 2pf qf ) and pf ;
pv 2qf
T pf 2apf t
qv (t) D C0 e pv mfd :
2pv pv
The ‘free body’ diagram of the forces acting upon food consumption
of the consumer is shown in Fig. 3.10, where the static friction force
is omitted for simplicity. The direction of motion on ‘right’ is defined
positive, and on ‘left’ negative. The positive force component acting upon
the food consumption of the consumer is hf , and the negative force
component is pf . Quantity qf (t) with unit kg=week on the horizontal axis
measures the flow of food consumption of the consumer (the velocity of
the ‘particle’), and quantity mfd with unit eweek2 =kg2 resists changes
in this movement. The shape of the ‘particle’ has no economic meaning,
and actually the particle should be drawn as a point on coordinate axis qf .
However, the ‘box-shape’ for the variable the flow of food consumption of
the consumer visualizes better the analogy we make here with Newtonian
mechanics.
The dynamic consumer behavior presented in this section has still one
advantage as compared with the static utility maximization assumed in
the neoclassical framework. Because in the neoclassical analysis time is
omitted, in that framework we cannot study how a consumer’s increasing
wealth with time affects his consumption. In the proposed framework
this can be done. Suppose a consumer gains wealth so that he can steadily
ℎ
( )
Fig. 3.10 Free body diagram of the forces acting upon consumption
3 Consumer Behavior 141
increase funds for his consumption. The budgeted funds for his weekly
consumption are then a function of time, and we assume a linear form for
the function: T(t) D T0 C bt, where T0 > 0; b are constants with units
e=week and e=week2 , respectively, and time t has unit week. Assuming
the utility function as in the previous example, the following Newtonian
equation results:
a a
mfd q0f (t) D .T(t)2pf qf (t)/ , mfd q0f (t) D .T0 Cbt 2pf qf (t)/:
pv pv
qf
qf 49.995
50.020
50.018
50.016 49.990
50.014
Newtonian Microeconomics
50.012
49.985
50.010
50.008
50.006
time time
6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20
Fig. 3.11 The graph of Eq. (3.35) with b D 0:01 and b D 0:01
3 Consumer Behavior 143
cTj
qfj D :
pf
cTA cTA
qfA D , pf D : (3.37)
pf qfA
a 1 a 1
qfA D pf , pf D abqfA ; D b0 ; D b1 > 0; (3.40)
b b b b
of the residuals of the model we see that the errors are positively correlated,
and thus the model is not statistically well defined. It is presented here
only to demonstrate that aggregate consumption can be explained highly
accurately by aggregate income.
In the earlier sections, the consumption flows of consumers were
derived by assuming that every consumer behaves in the optimal way from
their points of view. In Sect. 3.8, on the other hand, the behavior of a
consumer was presented in a dynamic form consistent with the optimal
behavior. There we assumed that a consumer may not always behave in an
optimal way, but he will adjust his consumption flows of goods with time
to increase his weekly utility. This explains how consumers find a new
equilibrium when changes in prices and budgeted funds take place. Thus
we can think that consumers actively react to changes in their decision-
making situation, and they adjust their consumption flows of goods with
time to reach their optimum.
The relatively complicated modeling in this section was made because it
is needed in the next chapter in modeling firms’ behavior. For simplicity,
in modeling firms’ behavior we assume that consumers choose between
good k and other goods that are treated as a basket good. This basket good
is constructed as was described in Sect. 2.3.1 by assuming that the amounts
of these goods are measured in units kg, and their prices in units e=kg.
The average price of these goods is denoted by pG (e=kg) and the flow
of consumption of the basket good of consumer j by qGj (kg=week). In
this chapter when we modeled food consumption, and quantities qvj ; pv
correspond to qGj ; pG , respectively.
@uj
@qfj
pf D p ; j D 1; : : : ; m; (3.41)
@uj v
@qvj
148 Newtonian Microeconomics
where symbol D refers to ‘demand’. Next, we take the first order Taylor
series approximation (Sect. 10.10.3) of the demand function of consumer
j in the neighborhood of his equilibrium point zj0 D (pf 0 , pv0 ; Tj0 ) as
@Dfj @Dfj
qfj D Dfj (zj0 ) C zj0 .pf pf 0 / C zj0 (pv pv0 )
@pf @pv
@Dfj
C zj0 (Tj Tj0 ) C j ; (3.43)
@Tj
€
kg
∂u ∂u
pf = pv
∂qf ∂qv
pf 1
pf 2
qf 1 qf 2 qf
X
m
@Dfj X
m
@Dfj X
m
@Dfj
Cpf (zj0 ) C pv (zj0 ) C (zj0 )Tj
jD1
@pf jD1
@pv jD1
@Tj
b3
b0 C b1 pf C b2 pv C TA ; (3.44)
m
where1
Xm h i
@Dfj @Dfj @Dfj
b0 D Dfj (zj0 ) (zj0 )pf 0 (zj0 )pv0 (zj0 )Tj0 ;
jD1
@pf @pv @Tj
X
m
@Dfj X
m
@Dfj X
m
@Dfj
b1 D (zj0 ); b2 D (zj0 ); b3 D (zj0 )
jD1
@pf jD1
@pv jD1
@Tj
Pm Pm Pm Pm
1
Because jD1 cj Tj D c jD1 Tj C jD1 (cj c)Tj where c D (1=m) jD1 cj , the approximation
is the more accurate the less cj D @Dfj =@Tj vary, j D 1; : : : ; m.
150 Newtonian Microeconomics
1 b0
qfA D Df (pf ) b0 C b1 pf , pf D Df 1 (qfA ) D Bf (qfA ) qfA ;
b1 b1
(3.45)
where the general forms of the demand and inverse demand functions are
denoted by Df and Bf D D1 0 0
f , respectively. Because Df (pf ) D 1=Bf (qfA ),
then D0f (pf ) < 0 implies B0f (qfA ) < 0 and vice versa. ˘
References
Apostol, T. M. (1969). Calculus (Vol. II, 2nd ed.). New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Debreu, G. (1959). Theory of value. An axiomatic analysis of economic equilibrium.
A Cowles foundation monograph 17. New Haven: Yale University Press.
4
The Behavior of Firms
A private firm has to compete for its existence with other firms; it must
be profitable and not run out of financial resources, so that banks and
investors would be interested in investing in the firm and giving loans to
it. If the owners and managers of a firm know how its profitability can
be increased, it would be irrational not to use these means. That would
correspond to ‘throwing money away’ as was described in Sect. 1.2.2. It has
also been claimed that firms have some social goals they aim to achieve.
These kinds of activities can, however, in most cases be explained as a part
of their marketing strategy.
Competition between firms, if there are no rules, can easily cause
harm to society; for example, polluting of the environment, causing
dangerous working conditions for workers and other people, misuse of
monopoly power of a firm, and so on. Due to these reasons, the market
system requires business laws that define the limits within which firms
are allowed to operate, and how they must report to officials of their
operation. Such laws include environmental laws, laws of working time
and working conditions, tax laws, and the laws of accounting principles
of firms. The task of political leaders is to state the necessary laws and
make sure that firms follow them. The lack of clear business laws has been
one obstacle in the transformation of former socialist countries to market
economies.
To understand the role of business laws for business competition we can
use an analogy between the rules of sporting games and sporting competi-
tion, and between business laws and business competition. Competition
in business and sport is similar in many ways. We can think of the firms
in one industry as teams playing in the same series. The rules of sporting
games are clear, and if one team does not follow them, it can be ruled
out of the series or punished in some other way. For example, in 2006
the Italian soccer team, Juventus, was transferred to a lower series as a
punishment for arranging the results of games by bribery. Similarly, the
rules for competition between firms are stated in the laws of societies, of
which many are international.
If all teams obey the rules of a sporting game, the teams can be ranked
according to their playing against each other, and we can consider this
ranking fair. Similarly, if firms compete for customers according to the
existing laws, the most effective firms gain most customers and we can
4 The Behavior of Firms 153
may change. In this book, firms’ planning is divided into two categories:
short- and long-term planning. In management, these are called tactical
and strategic planning, which terminology is borrowed from military
language. These terms are also common in sport. It depends on the type of
the product and the industry as to the length of time tactical and strategic
planning covers; a hamburger bar and a nuclear power plant naturally
operate with different timescales.
According to the above, the length of the time period for tactical and
strategic planning depends on the firm. In this book, we assume that
the tactical time horizon of a firm is one week and strategic planning
covers a few years. The time horizon for tactical planning could just as
well be one month, a quarter of a year or any other suitable time unit,
but in this book we assume it to be one week. In economics, short- and
long-term analyses have traditionally been separated as follows.
§: In economics, we call long-term a time period during which all
economic units have completely adjusted their behavior to a change in
circumstances. On the other hand, we call short-term a time period
during which all economic units have not completely adjusted their
behavior. ˘
The payments for raw materials and machines, as well as the revenues
from sales, are not always obtained at the same fiscal period the real
158 Newtonian Microeconomics
Example
A firm buys two computers at a value of 1000 (e) in the same fiscal period.
At the end of the period, both computers can be sold at 600 (e). The
depreciation of the computers during this fiscal period is then 2 400
(e=t) D 800 (e=t), where t is the length of the fiscal period. The firm
can thus book these costs at this fiscal period, and the rest of the investment
is depreciated during the following two or three fiscal periods. ˘
If some products are not sold in the fiscal period they were produced,
their production costs cannot be subtracted from the revenues of the
firm at that period because the corresponding revenues have not been
obtained. This increase in inventory value of a firm is called inventory
investment from which the revenues are obtained in the following fiscal
periods. Inventory investments may be intentional or not, because firms
can stock their products and raw materials if they believe that their price
will rise in the future.
The Income Statement or Profit-and-Loss Account of a firm shows
the difference in revenues and costs of the firm in its fiscal period; that is,
the net amount of money that flowed into the firm in the time unit. The
Balance Sheet, on the other hand, describes the net wealth of a firm as the
difference between its assets and liabilities. The Balance Sheet measures
the accumulated profitability of a firm during its existence, because the
share of the firm’s profit, that is not distributed to the owners of the firm,
is booked in the assets of the firm. The losses of a firm at one fiscal period
can be covered by its assets. Because outstanding bills are booked in the
Balance Sheet, the Balance Sheet shows the net wealth position of a firm
after its fiscal period.
An example of a hairdresser’s Income Statement is shown in Table 4.1,
and an example of its Balance Sheet is shown in Table 4.2. Net worth—
also called own capital—is the difference between the assets and liabilities
of the firm. Net worth balances the two sides of the Balance Sheet.
where Qk (t1 ) is the accumulated production of the firm from its foun-
dation until moment t1 , Q0k (t) D qk (t)(unit=week) the momentous
velocity of production, and Q00k (t) D q0k (t)(unit=week2 ) the momen-
tous acceleration of production at time moment t (see Sect. 10.14). The
reason for a separate symbol for the flow of production, qk , is that in
economics the flow of production is a basic quantity, while in physics,
162 Newtonian Microeconomics
C(q k)
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
qk
1 2 3 4 5
where g(qk )qk (e=week) are the variable costs. Then we get
Ck C0 C g(qk )qk C0
Average unit costs: D D C g(qk );
qk qk qk
Ck dCk
Marginal costs: lim D D Ck0 (qk ) D g0 (qk )qk C g(qk ):
qk !0 qk dqk
Now, C0 =qk are average fixed unit costs, g(qk ) average variable unit
costs, and function g(qk ) is assumed differentiable; if this does not hold,
marginal costs are measured by C qk
k
. Marginal costs and all different
unit costs are measured in units e=unit. The shape of the marginal cost
function depends on the function
Ck00 (qk ) D g00 (qk )qk C 2g0 (qk ); where g00 (qk ) > 0:
Marginal costs are constant (C00 (qk ) D 0) if qk D 2g0 (qk )=g00 (qk ), and
decreasing (Ck00 (qk ) < 0) if qk < 2g0 (qk )=g00 (qk ), and vice versa. Thus
with small (large) values of qk , marginal costs are decreasing (increasing).
164 Newtonian Microeconomics
Example
Suppose g(qk ) is of the form of second order polynomial
g(qk ) D c1 c2 qk C c3 q2k ;
Thus with values qk < c2 =(3c3 ), marginal costs are decreasing and with
larger values increasing. The assumed functional forms for the cost concepts
demonstrate how an increase in the flow of production decreases units
costs in the beginning, but after a certain flow of production, unit costs
start to increase. These cost curves demonstrate in a simple mathematical
form how an increase in the flow of production affects the costs of a firm.
The weekly, average unit, and marginal cost functions are then:
From Fig. 4.2 we see that the only constantly decreasing (the thinnest
one) cost curve with increasing qk is C0 =qk . The marginal cost curve (the
thickest one) is first decreasing and then increasing with qk , and it cuts
the average unit cost curve as well as the average variable unit costs curve
(the latter of these is below the former) in their minimum points. We
4 The Behavior of Firms 165
prove this next (the rules of derivation are in Sect. 10.7.2; zero derivative
corresponds to the horizontal tangent line of a function):
d Ck (qk ) Ck0 (qk )qk Ck (qk ) Ck (qk )
D0 , 2
D 0 , Ck0 (qk ) D
dqk qk qk qk
and g0 (qk ) D 0 ) Ck0 (qk ) D g0 (q)qk C g(qk ) D g(qk ):
When the derivatives of both average unit cost curves with respect to the
flow of production are zero, marginal costs equal with both unit costs.
Because marginal costs are calculated by taking the derivative of the
cost function, the shape of the marginal cost function was explained in
connection with the cost function. Thus if the flow of production is
increased, marginal costs decrease when the flow of production is small
with respect to full capacity level. Marginal costs may be constant or
decreasing as long as free production capacity is available. However, near
the full-capacity level, overtime work and other such factors increase
marginal costs.
166 Newtonian Microeconomics
a 1
qkdA D pk , pk D a bqkdA a; b > 0; (4.3)
b b
We assume here that the firm cannot charge its customers different
prices. Consumers decide on their weekly consumption flow of good k
at the existing price, and the firm must sell its products to all customers
at the price it has chosen. The firm has an estimate of its sales at various
prices, and it uses this to plan its weekly flow of production. This estimate
may be based on market research or on the experience of the firm of its
sales at different prices.
§: The sales function of a firm expresses the sales of the product of the
firm during a time unit at different prices. These sales correspond to the
equilibrium states of all consumers consuming the good. ˘
Because the demand relation of good k is derived on the basis of all
consumers interested in consuming this good, and good k is produced
only by one firm, the demand relation of good k equals the sales
function of the firm producing good k. On this basis, the maximal
weekly revenues of the firm from its sales of good k can be approximated
as:
a 1
Rk D pk qkdA D (a bqkdA )qkdA D pk pk ; (4.4)
b b
Rk pk qkdA
D D pk D Bk (qkdA ) a bqkdA :
qkdA qkdA
Thus the demand relation expresses average revenues from one sold good.
The firm plans its flow of production and the price of good k so that
its weekly profit gets maximized. Now, demand relation pk D a bqkdA
expresses the highest price at which the flow of consumption qkdA takes
place. If the firm sets a lower price than that expressed by the demand
relation at a certain flow of production, the whole weekly production gets
sold, but a higher price could have been obtained for each unit. Thus, if a
firm aims to sell its whole production at the highest possible price, it prices
its product according to its sales (demand) function. A firm behaving in
this way can either decide the price of its product or its flow of production,
4 The Behavior of Firms 169
but not both. If the firm sets a certain price, consumers decide how much
they will consume at that price in a week. If the firm want’s to sell a certain
flow of production, consumers decide at which price they will buy the
whole weekly production of the firm.
In the following we assume that the firm knows its sales function
and decides its flow of production according to it. This assumption is
made to simplify the modeling. In the real world, a difference between
estimated and the true sales function makes this situation uncertain. The
assumption, that a firm prices its product according to its sales function,
allows us to set the flows of production and consumption equal qk D qkdA ,
because behaving in this way the whole production of the firm gets sold.
The revenues of a firm from producing a good can then be expressed as
a function of the price of the good, or as a function of the firm’s flow
of production. In Chap. 5 we will analyze the behavior of a perfectly
competed industry where firms cannot affect the price of their product.
Because firms can always decide their flow of production, but not always
the price of their product, in the following we analyze the revenues of a
firm as a function of its flow of production. A deviation from this is made
in Sect. 4.7 where we study firms’ pricing.
§: The ratio between a change in the revenues and a marginal change in
the flow of production of a one-good firm is called the marginal revenues
of the firm. Marginal revenues measure average revenues from a marginal
increase in the firm’s flow of production. ˘
The marginal revenues of a firm producing good k are:
Example
Let the sales function of a firm producing good k be as in Eq. (4.3). Then
constant a (e=unit) shows the price at which the first produced unit can be
sold (qkdA D 0). Constant b with unit (eweek)=unit2 measures the strength of
the relationship between pk and qkdA . Suppose the firm is the only producer
of good k and the firm prices its product according to its sales function. The
weekly revenues of the firm, which correspond to the equilibrium states of
all consumers, are then Rk D pk qk D aqk bq2k , where the consumption and
production flows are set equal (qk D qkdA ). The revenues of the firm are thus
a parabolic function of qk , and marginal revenues dR k
dqk
D a 2bqk decrease
linearly with increasing qk . ˘
= −
= −2
⁄(2 ) ⁄
2
= −
⁄(2 ) ⁄
The flow of production that maximizes the weekly revenues of the firm is
found at the highest point of the parabola. We can solve it as
dRk a
D0 , a 2bqk D 0 , qk D :
dqk 2b
172 Newtonian Microeconomics
From Figs. 4.4 and 4.5 we see that marginal revenues are zero at the flow
of production a=2b that maximizes the weekly revenues.
Example
We analyze the finding of the optimal flow of production of a firm by
a numerical example. The planning time horizon is assumed to be one
week, and the weekly sales and costs estimated by the firm are shown in
Table 4.3. The measurement units are: flow of production: unit=week, price:
1000 e=unit, revenues, costs, and profit: 1000 e=week.
In Table 4.3 in column (1) are the firm’s estimate of its weekly sales at the
prices in column (2); together they construct the sales function of the firm.
Column (3) is formulated by multiplying the numbers in columns (1) and (2)
so that the numbers in the same row are multiplied, and the product is set
in column (3). In column (4) are the firm’s estimate of its weekly costs at the
flows of production in column (1). Columns (1) and (4) formulate the cost
function of the firm. The weekly profit of the firm in column (5) is obtained
by subtracting column (4) from column (3) so that the numbers in every row
are subtracted and the result is set in column (5). From Table 4.3 we see that
the profit is maximized at the flow of production 6 (unit=week), and weekly
revenues are maximized at the flow of production 11 (unit=week). ˘
…k D Rk (qk ) Ck (qk ) D Bk (qk )qk Ck (qk ); B0k (qk ) < 0; Ck0 (qk ) > 0;
(4.6)
where the weekly revenues and costs are denoted by Rk (qk ) and Ck (qk ),
respectively, and Bk (qk ) is the sales function of the firm, see the Appendix
in Chap. 3. In Eq. (4.6) we assumed that the firm can estimate its
weekly sales at various prices and costs, and that the firm prices its
product according to its sales function. The necessary condition for profit
maximization is
d…k
D 0 , R0k (qk ) Ck0 (qk ) D 0 , B0k (qk )qk C Bk (qk ) D Ck0 (qk );
dqk
(4.7)
where R0k (qk ) D B0k (qk )qk C Bk (qk ) are marginal revenues and Ck0 (qk )
marginal costs of the firm. The sufficient condition for maximum is
d 2 …k
D B00k (qk )qk C 2B0k (qk ) Ck00 (qk ) < 0:
dq2k
Because B0k (qk ) < 0, the above condition holds if Ck00 (qk ) 0 and
B00k (qk ) 0. Thus marginal costs should be non-decreasing and the sales
function non-increasing with qk ; we return to these matters with specific
cost and sales functions. At the profit maximizing flow of production,
marginal revenues and costs are equal. This corresponds to the situation
in the previous section where the slopes of the tangents of the weekly
revenue and cost functions are equal. If the forms of functions Bk (qk ) and
Ck (qk ) are known, we can solve the profit maximizing flow of production
qk from Eq. (4.7).
4 The Behavior of Firms 175
€
unit
Ck ' (qk )
p k*
C k (qk* ) Ck (qk )
qk* qk
q k* a /(2b) a/b qk
Example 1
Suppose the weekly sales function of a firm is of the form pk D a bqk as
in Sect. 4.3.3, where the units of qk and pk are as earlier. The weekly cost
function of the firm is Ck (qk ) D C0 C c1 qk , where C0 and c1 are positive
176 Newtonian Microeconomics
d…k a c1
D0 , a 2bqk D c1 ) q
k D ; (4.9)
dqk 2b
d 2 …k
D 2b < 0:
dq2k
In Eq. (4.9), marginal revenues are a 2bqk and marginal costs are c1 ;
the condition for optimality thus holds. For the profit maximizing flow
of production to be positive, a > c1 must hold. Thus the price at which
the first produced good can be sold must exceed variable unit costs.
Equation (4.9) implies that the optimal flow of production increases when
the sales function moves away from origin (a increases), and decreases
when c1 increases or the sales function gets ‘steeper’ (b increases). The price
corresponding to qk is:
a c1 2a a C c1 a C c1
p
k D a bqk D a b D D > 0: (4.10)
2b 2 2
a C c1 a c1 a c1
…k jqk Dqk D p
k qk Ck (qk ) D C 0 c1
2 2b 2b
a c1 a C c1 2c1 (a c1 )2
D C0 D C0 :
2b 2 4b
(a c1 )2 (a c1 )2
C0 0 , C0 ; (4.11)
4b 4b
which shows the upper limit for fixed costs C0 for the profit to be positive.
Next we show how we can use measurement units in checking our
calculations. We defined the units of the constants as: C0 (e=week), a (e=unit),
4 The Behavior of Firms 177
d…k a 2pk c1 a C c1
D0 , C D0 ) p
k D ;
dpk b b 2
which result we got earlier. The optimal flow of production with price p
k is
obtained by using the sales function:
a C c1 a c1
p
k D D a bqk ) q
k D :
2 2b
d 2 …k 2
D < 0:
dp2k b
This example shows that if a firm operates with the (qk ; pk ) combinations
of its sales function, the firm has actually only one quantity by which it
can affect its profit. If the firm changes the price of its product, consumers
react to this by changing their flows of consumption according to the
sales function. On the other hand, if the firm reduces its weekly flow of
production from that which was previously completely sold, the firm can
sell its whole production at a higher price as is shown by the sales function.
It is a matter of taste which quantity—the price or the flow of production—
is considered as the policy variable of the firm, because a firm that aims to
sell its whole production has to accept that consumers decide at which price
they will buy it.
178 Newtonian Microeconomics
1
Ck (qk)
C0 C c1 ac 2bC0 C c1 a c21
D ac1
2b
D : (4.12)
qk 2b
a c1
The non-negativity condition for profit in Eq. (4.11) can now be derived by
using Eqs. (4.10) and (4.12) and demanding that p k must exceed average
unit costs at q
k :
The checking of this is left to the reader as well as that the mathematical
expressions in this example are dimensionally well-defined. ˘
Example 2
We continue the numerical example in Sect. 4.4.1. Suppose the flow of
production is 3 (unit=week) and the firm is considering whether to increase
its flow of production by one unit in a week. We assume that the firm
has estimated its weekly sales and cost functions correctly. Increasing the
weekly flow of production by one unit causes extra costs 51 44 D 7(1000
e=week), and revenues increase by 72 57 D 15 (1000 e=week). Thus profit
increases by 8 (1000 e=week) and the change should be done.
By comparing the marginal revenues (MR) and marginal costs (MC)
we see that condition MR D MC holds at the profit maximizing flow of
production 6 (unit=week). If MR > MC, the firm should increase its flow of
production, and if MR < MC, decrease. The flow of production should thus
be increased as long as 6 (unit=week) is obtained (see Table 4.4).
Note 1. The increase in the flow of production in Table 4.4 takes place
in units 1 (unit=week). In marginal revenues and costs, the denominator
is thus constant 1 (unit=week). This does not hold in general, however,
because in the real world the effects on the revenues and costs of a
firm can be measured with varying amounts of changes in the flow of
production. ˘
at the flow of production where marginal revenues and costs are equal.
The reason for this is that in marginal analysis fixed costs are eliminated.
For example, in Table 4.4 fixed costs 10 (1000 e=week) at the flow of
production 0 (unit=week) are not seen in the marginal analysis. Also with
differentiable functions, a constant representing fixed costs vanishes from
the necessary condition for optimum because the derivative of a constant
is zero. ˘
where we have assumed that the firm knows its sales and cost functions,
and the flow of production is set to depend on time t. Now qk (t) is
the only quantity by which the firm can affect its profit, because we
have substituted price by the sales function pk (t) D Bk .qk (t)/. The time
derivative of the profit function is (Sect. 10.7.3):
d…k 0
…0k (t) D qk (t) D B0k .qk (t)/qk (t) C Bk .qk (t)/ Ck0 .qk (t)/ q0k (t):
dqk
180 Newtonian Microeconomics
d…k
q0k (t) D f (Fk ); f 0 (Fk ) > 0; f (0) D 0; Fk D ; (4.13)
dqk
d…k
q0k (t) D f 0 (0) ,
dqk
q0k (t) D f 0 (0) B0k .qk (t)/qk (t) C Bk .qk (t)/ Ck0 .qk (t)/ ; (4.14)
where f 0 (0) > 0 is a constant with unit (unit=week)2 =e; this unit
comes from f 0 (Fk ) D dq0k (t)=dFk , where Fk D d… dqk
k
(e=unit) and
0 2
qk (t)(unit=week ).
Next we denote f 0 (0) D m1ks and name mks (> 0) the ‘inertial "mass"
of production of good k’ because in the above formulation, mks has the
same role as inertial mass has in Newtonian mechanics. Subscript s refers
to ‘supply’. With these definitions, Eq. (4.14) exactly corresponds to the
Newtonian equation of motion a D F=m, where a is acceleration, F
force, and m the mass of the moving particle. Factor mks (e/(unit=week)2 )
contains the factors resisting changes in the flow of production, like time
required to find new workers and teach them, the laws restricting the firing
of employees, and so on.
If the force and acceleration of production of good k are known, factor
mks can be calculated as: mks D d… dqk
k
=q0k (t). The smaller the mks , the
faster the flow of production adjusts with a fixed force, and vice versa.
According to Eq. (4.14), the flow of production increases (q0k (t) > 0)
182 Newtonian Microeconomics
if B0k .qk (t)/qk (t) C Bk .qk (t)/ Ck0 .qk (t)/ > 0, and vice versa. The
flow of production continuously adjusts with force B0k .qk (t)/qk (t) C
Bk .qk (t)/Ck0 .qk (t)/, and the profit maximizing flow of production—that
corresponds to the neoclassical theory—can be solved from the zero-force
situation: B0k .qk (t)/qk (t) C Bk .qk (t)/ D Ck0 .qk (t)/. The characteristics of
the cost and sales functions guarantee that the force is positive at small
and negative at high flows of production, which makes the equilibrium
state stable.
Factor mks explains that the adjustment of the flow of production
takes time. We can also add static friction to the situation to explain
that a firm may not always change its flow of production when the
defined force deviates from zero. Economics textbooks usually talk about
adjustment costs instead of static friction. Static friction is, however, a
more general concept that covers all factors resisting changes in firms’
flows of production not included in sales and cost functions. Such factors
are: the building costs of new capacity and the time it takes, the hiring
and firing costs of labor, the costs of changing production methods,
uncertainties in the sales and cost functions, and so forth. Adding static
friction into the model we get
d…k
mks q0k (t) D C FSk ; (4.15)
dqk
where the static friction force is denoted by FSk (e=unit). The direction
of static friction force is opposite to that of d…
dqk
k
, and jFSk j j d…
dqk
k
j. Static
friction keeps the resultant force zero as long as j dqk j does not exceed the
d…k
qk(t)
Example
Let the weekly sales and cost functions of a firm producing good k be
…k (t) D pk (t)qk (t) Ck .qk (t)/ D aqk (t) bq2k (t) C0 c1 qk (t): (4.17)
d…k
D mks q0k (t) , a 2bqk (t) c1 D mks q0k (t); (4.18)
dqk
where mks is the inertial ‘mass’, q0k (t) the instantaneous acceleration, and
d…k
dqk
the force acting upon production. The equation of motion in Eq. (4.18)
shows that the firm increases its flow of production (q0k (t) > 0) if qk (t) <
(a c1 )=2b D q
k , and decreases its flow of production if qk (t) > qk , where qk
is the profit maximizing flow of production. This can be interpreted and
compared with physics, in that in this situation, together with constant
184 Newtonian Microeconomics
a c1 2b t
qk (t) D C A0 e mks ; (4.19)
2b
y(t) D ay(t 1) C b;
Fig. 4.9 The graph of function (4.21) with c2 D 0:01 and c2 D 0:01
4 The Behavior of Firms 187
with constant b. Our results in Estola (2015) were that the AR1 model
outperformed the neoclassical one in explaining the flows of production
in every tested industry in both countries, and the Newtonian theory
outperformed the AR1 in 10 out of 13 cases in Finnish industries,
and in 14 out of 18 cases in Swedish industries. Finally, in Estola and
Dannenberg (2012) and in Estola (2015) the Newtonian theory was shown
to outperform the neoclassical one in every tested industry. Figure 4.10
shows examples of these results from industries C20C21: Chemicals and
chemical products, and C31 C32: Furniture and other manufacturing
in Sweden. The graphs of the estimated models show that the Newtonian
model follows the real data more accurately than the neoclassical one in
all cases. Thus we have empirical evidence that the Newtonian theory
performs better than the neoclassical one in empirical tests.
188 Newtonian Microeconomics
…k (t) D pk (t)qk (t) Ck .qk (t)/; qk (t) D Dk .pk (t)/; Ck0 (qk ) > 0; D0k (pk ) < 0;
where dpk =dt D p0k (t) ((e=unit)=week) is the velocity of the price. A
profit-seeking firm changes the price of its product to increase its weekly
profit. The adjustment rules, that increase the firm’s profit, are:
p0k (t) > 0 if Dk (pk ) C D0k (pk )Œpk Ck0 (qk ) > 0;
p0k (t) < 0 if Dk (pk ) C D0k (pk )Œpk Ck0 (qk ) < 0;
p0k (t) D 0 if Dk (pk ) C D0k (pk )Œpk Ck0 (qk ) D 0:
4 The Behavior of Firms 189
The quantity
with unit unit=week can then be named as the force acting upon the
price of good k. In this decision-making, the firm compares changes in
its weekly revenues dRk =dpk and costs dCk =dpk due to a price change.
Term qk D Dk (pk ) measures the increase in the firm’s revenues from sold
goods due to a price raise, and term pk D0k (pk ) < 0 measures the decrease
in revenues due to reduced sales after a price increase. These factors define
the force component dRk =dpk that measures demand-based price effects,
and factor Ck0 (qk )D0k (pk ) > 0 measures cost-based price effects.
The demand-based force component acting upon the price may be
positive or negative. In the latter case, the revenues of the firm can be
increased by decreasing the price (remember that the revenues of a firm
are measured by the area of a rectangle as shown in Fig. 4.3). Also, the
costs-based force component acting upon the price may be positive or
negative. According to it, all factors that increase marginal costs Ck0 (qk )
positively affect the price, and vice versa.
Because D0k (pk ) < 0, the force Dk (pk ) C (pk Ck0 (qk ))D0k (pk ) is positive
if pk Ck0 (qk ). Thus if price is below marginal costs, the firm always
benefits by a price increase. In situations pk > Ck0 (qk ), however, we cannot
say for sure in which direction the price should be changed to increase
profit. The zero force situation Dk (pk ) C pk D0k (pk ) D Ck0 (qk )D0k (pk )
defines the price that maximizes the weekly profit of the firm.
Example
Let the weekly sales and cost functions of a firm be qk (t) D b1 b2 pk (t) and
Ck D C0 Cc1 qk (t), respectively, where qk (unit=week) is the flow of consumption
(= flow of production), pk (e=unit) the price of the product of the firm, and
positive constants b1 ; b2 ; C0 ; c1 have units unit=week, unit2 =(eweek), e=week
and e=unit, respectively. The weekly profit of the firm is then:
The force acting upon the price of the product of the firm is
d…k
D b1 C b2 c1 2b2 pk (t):
dpk
The constant force component b1 Cb2 c1 > 0 consists of demand and cost
factors; the greater b1 and c1 are, the greater is the force. The negative force
component 2b2 pk (t) depends on the price; the greater the price the greater
the absolute value of this factor. The equilibrium price, that maximizes the
profit of the firm, is pk (t) D (b1 C b2 c1 )=2b2 , and the sufficient condition for
maximum holds too:
d 2 …k
D 2b2 < 0: ˘
dp2k
We continue the analysis from the previous section. The modified Newto-
nian equation of motion for the price is formulated analogously as earlier:
mkp p0k (t) D Dk .pk (t)/ C D0k .pk (t)/Œpk (t) Ck0 .Dk (pk (t))/; (4.22)
where constant mkp > 0 with unit unit2 =e is the inertial ‘mass’ of
price pk . Notice that p0k (t) is the flow, and not the acceleration, of
price pk . Thus Eq. (4.22) does not exactly correspond to the Newtonian
4 The Behavior of Firms 191
Fig. 4.12 Free body diagram of the forces acting upon price pk
Example
We continue the analysis in the example in the previous section, and we
assume, for simplicity, that the price has no static friction. The modified
Newtonian equation of motion for the price is then:
d…k
D mkp p0k (t) , b1 C c1 b2 2b2 pk (t) D mkp p0k (t); (4.23)
dpk
where mkp with unit unit2 =e is the ‘inertial mass’ resisting changes in the
price. The solution of this differential equation is
b1 C c1 b2 2b
2t
pk (t) D C Ae mkp ; (4.24)
2b2
4 The Behavior of Firms 193
are divided by a fixed price series p(0)q(t). Prices are still multiplied by
1000 to get their numerical values close to those of production flows
so that they can be graphed in the same figure. Figure 4.13 shows that
industrialized prices may have positive and negative time trends, or prices
may fluctuate around a relative constant value like in industry DF. In
some industries production flows follow the price development and in
others not.
References
Estola, M. (2001). A dynamic theory of a firm: An application of economic
forces. Advances in Complex Systems, 4(1), 163–176.
Estola, M. (2014). The neoclassical theory of a firm; corrections for its errors.
Hyperion International Journal of Econophysics and New Economy, 7 (1), 7–25.
Estola, M. (2015). Neoclassical and Newtonian theory of production: An empiri-
cal test. Hyperion International Journal of Econophysics and New Economy, 8(1),
7–22.
Estola, M., & Dannenberg, A. (2012). Testing the neoclassical and the Newto-
nian theory of production. Physica A, 391(24), 6519–6527.
Vihriälä, V. (1999). Banks and the Finnish credit cycle 1986–1995. Bank of Finland,
BOF Series E (Vol. 7). Helsinki: Suomen Pankki.
5
Goods Markets
Example 1
Perfect substitutes could be electricity and oil in heating houses, loans
issued by different banks, and same kinds of insurances from insurance
companies. Imperfect substitutes could be, for example, coffee and tea,
Edam cheeses from different producers, and traveling by car or bus. ˘
Example 2
The carrots of different producers can be considered as almost perfect
substitutes. On the other hand, for the need to eat, which a carrot satisfies,
various imperfect substitute goods exist. These are, for example, turnips,
Swedish turnips, and other vegetables from which consumers get the same
vitamins and almost the same taste experience. ˘
price increase raises the status value of a good, and this may increase
some people’s willingness to pay for them. A price increase may also
be perceived as a sign of an improved quality of the good, which may
increase its demand. Giffen goods are, however, exceptional and in the
text that follows, therefore, we assume the studied goods to be normal
unless otherwise indicated.
In Sect. 3.9 we defined the demand for good k as a relation between
its price and the aggregate flow of consumption that corresponds to the
equilibrium states of all consumers consuming the good. We define supply
analogously.
§: By the market supply relation of a good we understand the
(aggregate flow of production, price) combinations that correspond to
the equilibrium states of all firms producing the good. ˘
It is a matter of preference whether we present the supply function
in a form where the aggregate flow of production of the good depends
on its price, or in its inverse function, where the dependence of the
price is on the aggregate flow of production. The former expresses the
aggregate flow of production that corresponds to the equilibrium states of
all firms producing the good at a certain price, and the latter expresses the
minimum possible price at which a certain aggregate flow of production
takes place. The former is traditionally called the supply function and
the latter the inverse supply function. In the inverse supply function,
the idea that price depends on the aggregate flow of production of a good
can be understood so that every aggregate flow of production defines a
unique price at which this flow takes place.
In Sect. 5.2 we will define a relation between the price and the flow of
production of a firm corresponding to the equilibrium states of the firm at
different prices in a perfectly competed industry. The supply relation of an
industry is aggregated from those of all firms in the industry. In imperfect
competition, firms operate as price setters and not as price takers like
firms in a perfectly competed industry. The supply relation of a good can
be defined only when the price of the good is determined ‘in the market’,
and firms adjust their production on this basis. Usually, no such place like
the ‘market of a good’ exists. The term ‘market’ is used to underline that
price is determined ‘outside firms’ according to the aggregate demand and
supply of the corresponding good.
5 Goods Markets 199
customers exist that none of them can affect the price. For this reason, we
assume in the following that numerous consumers exist for the goods we
are studying.
All market situations that are not perfect competition are called imper-
fect competition. In imperfect competition, either individual sellers
(producers) or consumers can affect the prices of the products. Three
forms of imperfect competition, which can be separated from the rest,
are: monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly.
goods have been produced, every inhabitant can enjoy their services and
access cannot be denied from any individuals. For this reason, consumers
are not willing to buy pure public goods, and private firms are not
interested in producing such goods because no person likes to buy them
for himself. The only way to finance the production of pure public goods
is to use tax money.
Some goods can be partly public and partly market goods. For example,
most parks and sport fields in cities are public goods. Even though every
citizen can freely use these goods, people are in different position with
respect to the services produced by them. Those living at the opposite
side of the city must travel to enjoy these services, and in this way they
have to pay for these services. Similar examples are public entertainment
areas that benefit most those people living next to them.
Increasing returns to scale in production may define a minimum scale
of production after which unit costs do not remarkably decrease any
further. This together with a relatively small market may lead to an
oligopoly situation.
§: Oligopoly is a market situation where a few relatively large firms
produce a roughly homogeneous good with increasing returns to scale in
production (see Sect. 5.5). ˘
In oligopoly, small firms cannot manage in cost competition, and the
size of the market does not allow profitable operation of many medium-
size firms. The high costs of small firms prevent their entry into the
market, which explains how the market situation stays constant. In an
oligopoly, the products of firms are similar. The difference between
oligopoly and perfect competition (Sect. 5.2) is that in the former a
smaller number of firms exist with a greater size. Increasing returns to
scale explains this difference.
The difference between perfect and monopolistic competition is in the
heterogeneity of the goods. In monopolistic competition, firms compete
with product differentiation and quality rather than price (see Sect. 5.4).
The quality difference may be real—for example cars and television
sets—or fictitious—for example candies and beverages. In monopolis-
tic competition, increasing returns to scale are not so remarkable that
this would restrict the entry of small firms. In this way, monopolistic
202 Newtonian Microeconomics
@…k 0 @…k 0
…0k (t) D pk (t) C qk (t) D qk (t)p0k (t) C pk (t) Ck0 .qk (t)/ q0k (t);
@pk @qk
where marginal revenues equal with pk and by Ck0 .qk (t)/ is denoted
marginal costs. Because a firm in a perfectly competed industry cannot
affect the price of its product, the only variable by which the firm can
204 Newtonian Microeconomics
The relationship between the flow of production and price in Eq. (5.1)
defines those flows of production at different prices that correspond to
the equilibrium states of the firm. A profit-seeking firm changes its flow
of production with time so that eventually Eq. (5.1) holds.
If the form of the cost function Ck is known, the optimal flow of
production of the firm at moment t can be solved from Eq. (5.1) as
1
qk (t) D Ck0 .pk (t)/; (5.2)
5 Goods Markets 205
where Ck0 1 is the inverse function of Ck0 . To be able to find this solution,
function Ck0 must be at least partially monotonic so that it has a unique
inverse at every flow of production (see Sect. 10.5.4).
In a perfectly competed industry, every firm decides its flow of produc-
tion with the aim to sell this production at the price determined in the
market. Firms know the price when they make their production decision,
but they do not know the production decisions of other firms. If, then,
the aggregate flow of production is greater than was sold in the previous
time unit, consumers may not buy the increased production at current
price. Some firms then have unsold goods, and they can decrease their
production to diminish the aggregate flow of production towards the level
that gets sold at current price. On the other hand, if price is greater than
marginal costs of these firms, these firms can decrease their product price
to get their production sold.
Now, a price decrease by one firm forces other firms to follow this,
because otherwise their products would not get sold. In this way the price
determination in perfect competition leads to marginal cost pricing with
time. At a higher price than that—assuming that firms’ marginal costs are
higher than their unit costs—firms can increase their profit by decreasing
their price and producing and selling more. This would increase the
aggregate flow of production in the industry. If one firm decreases the
price of its product lower than that of other firms, the firm knows that
other firms will follow this. This decreases firms’ interest to lower their
product price to increase their profit and market share. However, a higher
price than marginal costs of firms may attract new firms in the industry.
Thus in a perfectly competed industry, the aggregate flow of production
will increase with time if price is higher than firms’ marginal costs. An
increase in supply decreases the price, and thus price adjusts with time at
the level that equals with the marginal costs of firms.
In several textbooks on economics, it is claimed that competition
between firms forces the equilibrium price in perfect competition at the
level where marginal costs of firms equal their unit costs. This occurs
because those firms, for which this condition does not hold, may adjust
their production so that they can decrease their product price at that
level. This way they gain customers from other firms, which forces other
206 Newtonian Microeconomics
firms to follow the price decrease and produce at the flow of production
that creates the minimum possible unit costs. If a firm produces at its
minimum unit costs, the firm can sell its products at the lowest possible
price (see Fig. 5.1).
The supply relation of a firm in a perfectly competed industry can be
derived as is shown in Fig. 5.1. The unit and marginal costs of the firm
are described as in Sect. 4.3.2. Suppose that price is pk0 in Fig. 5.1. Then
every produced kilogram until the flow of production qk0 increases the
weekly profit of the firm, and the firm is motivated to increase its flow of
production until qk0 . However, the firm knows that its production affects
the aggregate supply in the industry, and this way the market price of
good k. For this reason, the production decision of the firm cannot be
analyzed separately from the price adjustment mechanism, and the market
mechanism must be analyzed as a complete system in Sects. 5.2.3–5.2.7.
Figure 5.1 shows that the force by which the firm affects the aggregate
production of the industry is positive at price pk0 if qk < qk0 , and negative
if qk > qk0 . An increase in the flow of production of the firm from qk0
5 Goods Markets 207
creates more costs than revenues at price pk0 , which would decrease the
profit of the firm. At price pk0 , the weekly profit of the firm is maximized
at the flow of production qk0 , and this corresponds to the zero-force
situation.
If price increases from pk0 to pk1 in Fig. 5.1, every sold kilogram until
the flow of production qk1 increases the profit of the firm. If the whole
production of the firm gets sold, the optimal flow of production at price
pk1 is qk1 . We can thus think that the optimal flow of production of the
firm is derived by its marginal costs. By the uniqueness of the marginal
cost function above the unit cost function, the marginal cost function
uniquely defines the flow of production the firm is willing to produce at
every price in the case its production gets sold. Thus it is profitable for the
firm to adjusts its flow of production with time at the level its marginal
costs equals with the price.
The supply relation of a firm shows the flows of production at different
prices that correspond to the optimal states of the firm. If the price
decreases, the optimal flow of production of a firm decreases according to
its marginal cost function. However, if price pk decreases below the unit
costs of a firm, the firm starts making losses. In that situation, the firm
can either stop its operation permanently or temporarily, or continue by
making losses. The last option is rational if the firm can cover its variable
costs and the firms’ managers believe that the firm can reduce its costs, or
that the price will increase in the future. On this basis, we can define the
marginal cost function as the supply relation of a firm in a perfectly
competed industry. Marginal costs show the optimal flow of production
at every price greater than unit costs of the firm.
Example
Let the cost function of a firm in perfect competition be Ck (qk ) D C0 C
g(qk )qk , where the flow of production qk has unit kg=week, g(qk ) D c1 C c2 qk
with unit e=kg is the variable unit cost function, and C0 ; c1 ; c2 are positive
constants with units e=week, e=kg and (e week)=kg2 , respectively. The
weekly profit of the firm is then
d…k pk c1
D0 , pk D c1 C 2c2 qk , q
k D : (5.4)
dqk 2c2
The marginal revenues of the firm equal with price pk , and marginal
costs c1 C 2c2 qk linearly increase with the flow of production. The supply
relation of the firm is the last form of Eq. (5.4). The optimal flow of
production increases with price and decreases if constants c1 ; c2 increase.
If pk < c1 , the firm makes losses and it is optimal to decrease or stop the
production. ˘
…ki D pk qki Cki (qki ) D pk qki C0i c1i qki c2i q2ki ;
Next we assume n firms in the industry and derive the optimal aggregate
flow of production of these firms. For simplicity, the cost functions are
assumed of identical form for every firm, but the constants in them may
vary. The optimal aggregate flow of production is then
X
n X
n
pk c1i
qkA D qk1 C qk2 C C qkn D qki D
iD1 iD1
2c2i
Xn
1 X
n
c1i
D pk D pk A B; (5.6)
iD1
2c2i iD1 2c2i
5 Goods Markets 209
Pn Pn c1i
where A D iD1 2c2i , B D
1
iD1 2c2i are positive constants. The
aggregate supply function thus positively depends on price pk ,
Note. The assumption that firms cost functions are of identical form, was
made to simplify the aggregation. In the real world, varying cost functions
of firms make the aggregation more complicated. In the next section
we show that in the case of varying cost functions, we can approximate
the supply relations of firms by linear ones in the neighborhood of
their equilibrium states, and in this way we can solve the aggregation
problem. ˘
Adding the n and m equations in Eq. (5.8), separately, and dividing the
results by n and m, respectively, we get
1X 0 1X
n m
pD Ci (qsi ) D hj .qdj ; Tj ; p; pG /I (5.9)
n iD1 m jD1
1X 0 X
n n
0 a0 a1
C .qs / Ci .qsi / C 2 qs ; qs D qsi ; (5.10)
n iD1 n n iD1
1X
m
b0 b1 b2 b3 b4
h(qd ; p; T; pG ) hj C 2 qd C p C 2 T C pG ; (5.11)
m jD1 m m m m m
1X
m
b0 b1 b2
h(qd ; p) hj (qdj ; p) C 2 qd C p: (5.12)
m jD1 m m m
na0 n2
qs D C p; (5.15)
a1 a1
2
mb0 m b2
qd D C p; (5.16)
b1 b1
Note. The aggregate demand relation in Eq. (5.16) equals with that
derived in Sect. 3.10 with a D mb0 =(m2 b2 ) > 0, b D b1 =(b2 m2 )
> 0. ˘
The reader can check the measurement units of the constants to see
that the given solutions are dimensionally well defined. The condition
for qd D qs > 0 is that p1 D a0 =n < b0 m=(m2 b2 ) D p2 , where p1
is the price at which the aggregate supply, and p2 the price at which the
aggregate demand, is zero. The equilibrium state is displayed in Fig. 5.2.
Note. In Fig. 5.2, on the horizontal axis are the aggregate flows of pro-
duction and consumption of good k; these are both measured in units
kg=week. On the vertical axis is the price of good k, the average marginal
costs of firms, and the average marginal willingness-to-pay of consumers
for one kilogram of good k; these all are measured in units e=kg. ˘
p0k (t) D fp (qkd qks ); fp0 (qkd qks ) > 0; fp (0) D 0; (5.18)
5 Goods Markets 213
where qkd qks is the excess demand (supply) when it is positive (neg-
ative). This mechanism was suggested by Paul Samuelson (1941, 1942).
Assuming the demand and supply relations as in the previous section,
2
and denoting the constants in them as A0 D na a1
0
> 0, A1 D na1 > 0,
> 0, B1 D m bb
2
B0 D mbb1
0
1
2
> 0, the excess demand becomes the
following:
where fp0 (0) is a positive constant with unit e=kg2 . From Eq. (5.19) we
see that the quantity in brackets is positive if pk < AA01 CB
CB1
0
D pk , and
vice versa. Thus price increases (p0k (t) > 0) if pk < AA01 CB0
CB1
D pk , and
decreases if pk > AA01 CBCB1
0
D pk . The equilibrium is thus stable, and
price adjusts with time toward its equilibrium value pk . According to
Eqs. (5.15), (5.16), a price raise increases supply and decreases demand,
and vice versa. Thus firms and consumers react to price changes, and the
demand and supply relations show how both parties adjust their flows of
production and consumption.
Equation (5.19) can be explained as follows. If the whole production
in the industry gets sold, and even more could have been sold at current
price, the lack of goods forces consumers to compete to buy the scarce
goods. This allows some firms to raise their product price, and other firms
can follow suit because their whole production will also get sold. In the
opposite situation, any firm can assure that its production gets sold by
decreasing its product price, even though the whole production of the
industry does not get sold. The price reduction of one firm forces other
firms to follow its example if they want to sell their whole production.
214 Newtonian Microeconomics
Difference qkd qks is thus the cause that changes price pk , and every
consumer and producer affects this quantity by their decisions.
The differential equation in Eq. (5.19) has solution
A0 C B0 0
pk (t) D C C0 efp (0).A1 CB1 /t ;
A1 C B1
of production. The new equilibrium state (qk1 ; pk1 ) shown in Fig. 5.4 is
obtained at a higher price and higher aggregate flows of production and
consumption than at (qk0 ; pk0 ).
By the presented model we can also analyze the possibilities for the
public sector to promote economic growth. The public sector can affect
firms’ marginal costs by decreasing taxes, giving technological support,
and/or by improving education in society. The public sector may also
promote consumers’ marginal willingness-to-pay for one kilogram of the
good. We do not know, however, which goods consumers buy if they get
216 Newtonian Microeconomics
support. For example, financial support from the state may increase the
consumption of imported goods, which does not contribute to domestic
production. Thus if the public sector wants to support the production of
domestic firms in a perfectly competed industry, the best way to do this
is to try to decrease the marginal costs of the firms.
1X
m
Fd D hkj (qkdj ; pk ; pG ; Tj ) pk ; (5.20)
m jD1
q0kd (t) D fd (Fd ); fd0 (Fd ) > 0; fd (0) D 0; Fd D hk .qkd (t); pk (t); T; pG / pk (t);
(5.21)
where function fd obeys the above characteristics and by hk .qkd ; pk ; T; pG /
is denoted the average marginal willingness-to-pay of consumers for one
kilogram of good k. The equilibrium situation of consumers hk D pk
is asymptotically stable because according to Sect. 5.2.3, @hk =@qkd
b1 =m2 < 0 and thus @q0kd (t)=@qkd fd0 (Fd ) @hk =@qkd < 0. The
graphical analysis of stability of Eq. (5.21) thus exactly corresponds to that
in Fig. 3.9.
The equation of motion for the aggregate flow of production is defined
analogously as for consumption:
q0ks (t) D fs (Fs ); fs0 (Fs ) > 0; fs (0) D 0; Fs D pk (t) Ck0 (qks ); (5.22)
production if it believes that the extra production gets sold. The forces in
Eqs. (5.21), (5.22) are measured in units e=kg and so we can add them.
The resultant force is
p0k (t) D fp (qkd qks ); fp0 (qkd qks ) > 0; fp (0) D 0; (5.24)
Fig. 5.5 The forces acting upon consumption, production, and price
1
The analogue between the price equation and a spring system in physics was suggested by Alia
Dannenberg (Spring 2016, PhD Physics).
220 Newtonian Microeconomics
1 0
p (t) D qkd (t) qks (t): (5.26)
kp k
The ‘free body’ diagram of the forces acting upon the consumption,
production, and price of good k is shown in Fig. 5.5, where the static
friction forces are omitted for simplicity. The direction of motion on
the right-hand side of the diagram—where the accumulated amounts of
consumption and production, Qd ; Qs , with unit kg increase—is defined
positive, and that on the left-hand side is negative. Similarly, positive
forces point to the right and negative to the left. The coordinate axis
was chosen so that the system is in a continuous motion on the right
(negative flows of consumption and production are impossible), and the
difference in velocities of the particles changes the length L of the spring,
L D Qkd Qks .
The length of the spring measures the difference in accumulated
amounts of consumption and production of good k in units kg, because
the unit of the coordinate axis in Fig. 5.5 is kg. The positive force
component acting upon consumption is hk (qkd ; pk ) and the negative one
is pk , and the positive force component acting upon production is pk and
the negative one is Ck0 (qks ).
The spring between the two ‘particles’ reflects the situation that an
equal mutual force pk is acting upon the two particles, and a difference in
velocities of the particles qkd qks changes their distance and, therefore,
also the length of the spring that changes the mutual force component pk .
Analogously with Hooke’s law in physics, price pk is the force by which
the spring acts upon the two particles.
§: In physics, Hooke’s law states that force F by which a spring acts
upon the particles tied in the spring is of form F D kX, where k is a
positive spring constant and X the deviation of the spring from its rest
length. Thus if X D 0, then F D 0. ˘
Force pk depends positively on the length of the spring L D Qkd Qks ,
and we assume the rest length of the spring to be zero. Thus when the
spring stretches, the price increases, which exerts a higher force on the
two particles and vice versa.
Now, from Eq. (5.26) we see that if qkd D qks , then p0k (t) D 0 that is
pk is constant, and if qkd < qks (qkd > qks ), the distance between particles
5 Goods Markets 221
mkd ; mks decreases (increases) in Fig. 5.5. According to Eq. (5.26), qkd <
qks (qkd > qks ) causes p0k (t) < 0 (p0k (t) > 0), and decreasing price increases
qkd and decreases qks and vice versa. Thus price with unit e/kg is a force
component that acts upon aggregate consumption and production, and
these interact back to price by the difference qkd qks . These interactions
keep the system in a relatively stable motion. Because economic units are
not actively changing price pk , here we do not treat price as a ‘particle’ in
the system but a variable that interacts with aggregate consumption and
production. In the equilibrium state, the system moves with equilibrium
speed qkd D qks and constant pk . If, however, hk (qkd ; pk ) < C0 (qks ),
the system stops because then pk ! 0. In this case, the firms producing
good k go into bankruptcy unless they also have other, more profitable,
products.
Let us rewrite Eq. (5.26) as
pk (t) pk (0) D kp .Qkd (t) Qks (t)/ kp .Qkd (0) Qks (0)/ ;
Rt
where Qki (t)Qki (0) D 0 qki (s)ds; i D d; s with unit kg are accumulated
amounts of consumption and production from the initial moment until
current time moment t (see Sect. 2.7.3). We can rewrite this equation as
pk (t) D kp .Qkd (t) Qks (t)/ C C0 ; C0 D pk (0) kp .Qkd (0) Qks (0)/ ;
(5.28)
where C0 is a constant with unit e/kg. At the beginning of the production
of good k, its consumption is zero, but some products have already
been produced and offered for sale at price pk (0). Thus Qd (0) D 0
and Qs (0); pk (0) > 0; these make C0 > 0. Thus in the beginning
of the production, ‘particle’ mks has been for some time on the right-
hand side of ‘particle’ mkd in Fig. 5.5. Once consumption then started,
the first sold goods were already produced and stocked, and no extra
222 Newtonian Microeconomics
production was needed. This explains how consumption could grew faster
than production in the beginning, and particle mkd —that demonstrates
accumulated consumption in Fig. 5.5—bypassed that of accumulated
production mks and consumption started to lead this production system
via the price system.
Equation (5.28) shows that the historical scarcity of the good measured
by its accumulated difference in consumption and production, Qd (t)
Qs (t), defines the current price level of the product, and positive constant
C0 explains that pk (t) 0 even if Qd (t) < Qs (t). As earlier, the shapes
of the ‘particles’ in Fig. 5.5 have no economic meaning, and actually the
particles should be drawn as points on the horizontal axis. However, the
box shapes of the variables better visualizes the analogy we make here with
Newtonian mechanics.
Assuming hk .qkd (t); pk (t)/ and Ck0 .qks (t)/ as in Eqs. (5.13), (5.14),
System (5.25) becomes:
b0 b1 b2
mkd q0kd (t) D C 2 qkd (t) C 2 pk (t) pk (t);
m m m
a0 a1
mks q0ks (t) D pk (t) 2 qks (t); (5.29)
n n
1 0
p (t) D qkd (t) qks (t):
kp k
With certain parameter values, System (5.29) is globally stable and will
converge with time toward its equilibrium state given in Eq. (5.17). We
can thus make the following definition.
§: In the equilibrium state of an industry, the forces acting upon the
aggregate flows of consumption, production, and price, vanish. ˘
The equilibrium state of the industry in Eq. (5.17) can be solved by
setting p0k (t) D q0kd (t) D q0ks (t) D 0 in System (5.29) and solving the
resulting three equations with respect to the three endogenous variables.
The speed of adjustment of the system toward the equilibrium depends on
the two inertial masses, the spring constant, and the values of the param-
eters in the model. An exact mathematical analysis of this adjustment is
given in Estola and Hokkanen (2008), and an interested reader can turn
to this work for more information. In this book we mainly concentrate
5 Goods Markets 223
Table 5.1 The share of five biggest firms in terms of turnover in Finnish industrya
Manufacture of food products, beverages, and tobacco 21.9%
Building of complete constructions or parts thereof and con- 26.5%
struction services
Manufacture of pulp, paper, and paper products 54%
Manufacture of basic metals and fabricated metal products 78.9%
Manufacture of refined petroleum products, coke, and nuclear 98.3%
fuel
a
Source: Statistic Centrum in Finland: ‘Finnish firms’, Helsinki 1994, pp. 40–41
5 Goods Markets 227
between pk and Ck0 (qk ), because in Sect. 5.2.3 we showed that in the
equilibrium state of a perfectly competed industry, price equals the average
of marginal costs of firms.
The weekly profit of the firm in Fig. 5.8 can be named as monopoly
profit the firm gains because it can set the price of the product in the
industry. A monopoly firm is a price-setter while firms in a perfectly
competed industry are price-takers (see Sect. 5.2.1). As a price-setter, a
monopoly firm is assumed to know the sales function of the good. The
flow of production of a monopoly firm equals the aggregate flow of
production in the industry, and the sales function of a monopoly firm
is the market demand relation of the good. The weekly profit of the firm
is then
…k (t) D pk (t)qk (t) Ck .qk (t)/ D Bk .qk (t)/qk (t) Ck .qk (t)/;
where the firm is assumed to know its sales and cost functions: pk D
Bk .qk /, B0k (qk ) < 0, and Ck .qk /, Ck0 (qk ) > 0. The time derivative of the
profit is:
228 Newtonian Microeconomics
d…k 0
…0k (t) D qk (t) D B0k .qk (t)/qk (t) C Bk .qk (t)/ Ck0 .qk (t)/ q0k (t):
dqk
Substituting the sales function pk (t) D Bk .qk (t)/ in the above expression,
the force acting upon the production of the monopoly firm becomes:
Fks D B0k .qk (t)/qk (t) C pk (t) Ck0 .qk (t)/: (5.30)
government can try to change all three factors in the force acting upon
the production in the industry by using its policy variables.
the industry and the number of firms stays fixed. A characteristic feature
in oligopolistic competition is the avoidance of price competition by
direct or indirect price agreements, and competition takes place by other
means.
Avoiding price competition is beneficial for all firms in an industry with
oligopolistic competition, because that would decrease the profitability of
the whole industry. Even though direct price contracts are usually illegal,
it is often difficult to prove their existence. A typical oligopoly situation
prevails, for example, in the gasoline station industry, in banking and
insurance, and in wholesale and retail industries.
analysis, defined for every player (firm) are the goals he/she/it aims to
achieve in the game, and the strategies he/she/it can use in attaining
these goals. After this, the next thing to look for is whether there exists
an aggregate flow of production/price combination in the industry that
is derived by firms’ cooperative or separate behavior, from which none of
the firms likes to deviate if other firms stay in it. This situation is called a
Nash equilibrium in the honor of Nobel laureate John Nash (1950), who
invented the concept. However, a game theoretic analysis of oligopolistic
competition would require the definition of various concepts applied in
game theory, and in this book we omit modeling oligopolistic competition
in game theoretic way. A reader interested in game theory can turn, for
example, to Gibbons (1992).
The less public information there is about prices, the more easy it is for
firms to slip out of a common price agreement. In this kind of situation,
firms base their operation on their assumptions of the strategies of other
firms.
2
Joseph Louis Françis Bertrand (11 March 1822–5 April 1900) was a French mathematician that
worked in the fields of number theory, probability theory, thermodynamics and economics.
3
Antoine Augustin Cournot (28 August 1801–31 March 1877) was a French philosopher and
mathematician who also contributed to the development of economics theory.
234 Newtonian Microeconomics
Both firms wish to maximize their profit, and so in the equilibrium holds
@…1 @…2
D 0; D 0:
@q1 @q2
The equilibrium state in the industry can be solved from the following
system of equations
@…1
D 0 , a 2bq1 bq2 d1 D 0; (5.34)
@q1
5 Goods Markets 235
@…2
D 0 , a 2bq2 bq1 d2 D 0; (5.35)
@q2
as
a C d2 2d1 a C d1 2d2
q1 D ; q2 D : (5.36)
3b 3b
The flows of production q1 ; q2 maximize the firms’ profits. The
equilibrium state is shown in Fig. 5.9 as the crossing point of the lines
representing Eqs. (5.34), (5.35); the former of these is the less steep one.
@…1 0
…01 (t) D q (t) bq1 (t)q02 (t)
@q1 1
D Œa 2bq1 (t) bq2 (t) d1 q01 (t) bq1 (t)q02 (t); (5.37)
@…2 0
…02 (t) D q (t) bq2 (t)q01 (t)
@q2 2
D Œa 2bq2 (t) bq1 (t) d2 q02 (t) bq2 (t)q01 (t): (5.38)
Each firm’s leader aims to maximize the profit of their firm, and so they
change qi (t) towards increasing …i .q1 ; q2 ), i D 1; 2, with time as
@…i
q0i (t) > 0 if > 0;
@qi
@…i
q0i (t) < 0 if < 0; (5.39)
@qi
@…i
q0i (t) D 0 if D 0; i D 1; 2:
@qi
These rules increase the profits of the firms with time, and the last
rule implies that there is no reason to change the flow of produc-
tion if it is expected not to affect the profit. The time derivatives in
Eqs. (5.37), (5.38) show that a change in q2 affects the profit of Firm 1, but
these changes are outside control of the managers of Firm 1. Similarly, q1
affects the profit of Firm 2 but Firm 2 cannot affect it. Thus by adjusting
their flows of production as in Eq. (5.39) the firms increase their profits.
A relation that fulfills the rules in Eq. (5.39), is
@…i
q0i (t) D fi (Fi ); fi0 (Fi ) > 0; fi (0) D 0; Fi D ; i D 1; 2; (5.40)
@qi
@…i 1
mi q0i (t) D ; mi D 0 i D 1; 2: (5.41)
@qi fi (0)
Fig. 5.10 Forces acting upon the production system of two firms
238 Newtonian Microeconomics
In System (5.42), we assume that each firm can identify the flow of
production of the other, and that each firm can forecast its own costs
and the market price. System (5.42) has a unique solution with a fixed
initial condition. However, because this solution is rather complicated, we
simplify the analysis by assuming numerical values for the parameters. Let
a D 100, and b D di D mi D 1, i D 1; 2. The solution of System (5.42)
is then:
1 1
q1 (t) D 33 C (C1 C C2 )e3t C (C1 C2 )et ;
2 2
1 1
q2 (t) D 33 C (C1 C C2 )e3t C (C2 C1 )et ; (5.43)
2 2
Fig. 5.12 The force field and demarcation lines in Cournot’s duopoly
q01 (t) > 0; q02 (t) > 0 (the direction of motion is thus upward and to
the right because q1 increases ‘up’ and q2 increases ‘right’). Above both
demarcation lines holds q01 (t) < 0; q02 (t) < 0, and so on. The defined
force field implies stability, and depending on the initial condition, the
adjustment may be smooth or oscillatory. Assuming time dependencies in
parameters a; b; di ; i D 1; 2, we can model the time path of production
in the industry by using System (5.42). This cannot be done by using
the static model described in Eqs. (5.34), (5.35), which demonstrates the
usefulness of the dynamic framework introduced in this section.
where Ri (e=week) and Ci (e=week) are the weekly revenues and costs of
firm i, pi (e=kg) the price of the product of the firm, qi (kg=week) the
flow of production (= flow of consumption of the products of the firm),
and qi D Di (pi ) the sales function of the firm. The derivative of the sales
function of the firm with respect to the price, dqi =dpi D D0i (pi ), measures
the change in weekly sales of the firm when a marginal change in price
takes place.
242 Newtonian Microeconomics
where p0i (t) with unit (e=kg)=week is the flow of the price of the product
of firm i. Now, p0i (t) is the effect of firm i on the change in the average
price level in the industry, and so also on the economy level price inflation.
According to Sect. 4.7.1, we can name quantity
d…i dRi dCi
Fi D D D Di (pi ) C (pi Ci0 (qi ))D0i (pi )
dpi dpi dpi
with unit kg=week as the force firm i directs upon the average price level
in the industry. A profit-seeking firm changes the price of its product to
increase its weekly profit. The equation of motion for price pi is then
p0i (t) D fi (Fi ); fi0 (Fi ) > 0; fi (0) D 0; Fi D Di (pi ) C (pi Ci0 (qi ))D0i (pi );
(5.44)
where function fi obeys the defined characteristics. Average price level p
(e=kg) in the industry and its flow are then:
1X 1X 0
n n
p(t) D pi (t); p0 (t) D p (t):
n iD1 n iD1 i
X
n X
n
p0i (t) D fi (Fi ): (5.45)
iD1 iD1
5 Goods Markets 243
1X 0 1X
n n
p0 (t) D pi (t) D fi Di (pi ) Ci0 (qi )D0i (pi ) pi D0i (pi ) : (5.46)
n iD1 n iD1
Equation (5.46) shows that the average price level in the industry increases
if the arithmetic average of changes in firms’ profits is positive due to a
price increase, and vice versa. The equilibrium price level in the industry
corresponds to situation Fi D 0; i D 1; : : : ; n. Then the firms cannot
increase their weekly profit by changing their product price. In the next
section we show that assuming fi0 (0) D f 0 (0) > 0 8i, we can make the
following approximation
1X
n z z1
fi Di (pi )Ci0 (qi )D0i (pi )pi D0i (pi ) f 0 (0)
0
C p(t) ; (5.47)
n iD1 n n
where z0 > 0; z1 < 0 are constants with units kg=week, kg2 =(e week),
respectively. The equilibrium price level can then be solved as
z0
p0 (t) D 0 , p(t) D > 0:
z1
The modeling in this section shows how we can model price inflation
in an industry with monopolistic competition. At the roughest level, the
empirical testing of this modeling requires data of average price level in
the industry. However, a more detailed data of the costs of the firms in
the industry would allow a more detailed testing of the theory by using
Eq. (5.44).
where fi0 (0) with unit e/kg2 is a positive constant. Adding the adjustment
equations in Eq. (5.49) of the n firms in the industry, we get:
X
n X
n
p0i (t) D fi0 (0) ŒDi (pi ) C (pi Ci0 (qi ))D0i (pi ): (5.50)
iD1 iD1
1X 0 1X 0
n n
p0 (t) D pi (t) D f (0) ŒDi (pi ) C (pi Ci0 (qi ))D0i (pi ):
n iD1 n iD1 i
(5.51)
X
n X
n
FD Fi D ŒDi (pi ) C pi D0i (pi ) Ci0 (qi )D0i (pi )
iD1 iD1
z1 X
n
F z0 C pi ;
n iD1
where constants z0 ; z1 have units kg=week and kg2 =(e week), respec-
tively. Now, assuming fi0 (0) D f 0 (0) 8i, we can approximate Eq. (5.51) as:
!
z1 X
n
z0
p0 (t) D f 0 (0) C 2 pi (t) :
n n iD1
Term ‘modified’ is used because p0 (t) is the velocity, and not the accel-
eration, of average price level. The force acting upon the average price
level in the industry is the arithmetic average of the firm-specific force
components causing demand and cost inflation. In the profit maximizing
situation of firm i holds: pi D Ci0 (qi ) > 0 and Ci00 (qi ) > 0. Assuming that
the firms operate near their profit maximizing situations, we can sign the
constants as z0 > 0; z1 < 0 because Fi (pi0 ) D 0 and D0i (pi ) < 0. These
246 Newtonian Microeconomics
are sufficient conditions for price stability. The higher the average price
level, the smaller its velocity and vice versa, and the equilibrium price level
corresponds to: p0 (t) D 0 ) p(t) D z0 =z1 > 0. The general solution
of Eq. (5.52) is:
z0 z1
t
p(t) D C H0 e mp n ; (5.53)
z1
X
n X
n
Ci0 .qsi / ŒCi0 (qsi0 ) Ci00 .qsi0 /qsi0 C Ci00 .qsi0 /qsi
iD1 iD1
a1
a0 C qs ;
n
Pn Pn Pn Pn
4
c q D c iD1 qsi C iD1 (ci c)qsi where c D (1=n) iD1 ci . The approximation
Pn iD1 i i Pn 00
iD1 ci qi c iD1 qsi is thus the more accurate the less ci D Ci (qsi ) or qsi vary, i D 1; : : : ; n.
5 Goods Markets 247
Pn
where qs D iD1 qsi and constants
X
n X
n
a0 D ŒCi0 .qsi0 / Ci00 .qsi0 / qsi0 ; a1 D Ci00 .qsi0 / ;
iD1 iD1
@hj @hj
hj (qdj ; p; pG ; Tj ) D hj (zj0 ) C (zj0 )(qdj qdj0 ) C (zj0 )(p p0 )
@qdj @p
@hj @hj
C (zj0 )(Tj Tj0 ) C (zj0 )(pG pG0 ) C j ; j D 1; : : : ; m:
@Tj @pG
(5.55)
X
m Xm
@hj @hj
hj (qdj ; p; pG ; Tj ) D hj (zj0 ) (zj0 )qdj0 (zj0 )p0
jD1 jD1
@qdj @p
X m Xm
@hj @hj @hj @hj
(zj0 )Tj0 (zj0 )pG0 C (zj0 )qdj C (zj0 )p
@Tj @pG jD1
@qdj jD1
@p
Xm
@hj Xm
@hj
C (zj0 )Tj C (zj0 )pG
jD1
@Tj jD1
@pG
b1 b3
b0 C qd C b2 p C T C b4 pG ; (5.56)
m m
5
Similar approximations are made here as in footnote 2.
248 Newtonian Microeconomics
Xm h
@hj @hj @hj
b0 D hj (zj0 ) (zj0 )qdj0 (zj0 )p0 (zj0 )Tj0
jD1
@qdj @p @Tj
@hj i X @hj
m X @hjm
(zj0 )pG0 ; b1 D (zj0 ); b2 D (zj0 );
@pG jD1
@qdj jD1
@p
Xm
@hj Xm
@hj
b3 D (zj0 ); b4 D (zj0 ):
jD1
@Tj jD1
@pG
1X
m
b0 b1 b2
h(qd ; p) hj (qdj ; p) C 2 qd C p; (5.57)
m jD1 m m m
where
m
X Xm
@hj @hj @hj
b0 D hj (zj0 ) (zj0 )qdj0 (zj0 )p0 ; b1 D (zj0 );
jD1
@qdj @p jD1
@qdj
X
m
@hj
b2 D (zj0 ):
jD1
@p
5 Goods Markets 249
References
Estola, M., & Hokkanen, V.-M. (2008). Consumer, firm, and price dynamics:
An econophysics approach. An application of economic forces. Saarbrücken,
Germany: VDM Verlag Dr. Müller.
Gibbons, R. (1992). A primer in game theory. Bodmin: Hartnolls Ltd.
Samuelson, P. (1941). The stability of equilibrium: Comparative statics and
dynamics. Econometrica, 9(2), 97–120.
Samuelson, P. (1942). The stability of equilibrium: Linear and nonlinear systems.
Econometrica, 10(1), 1–25.
6
Labor as a Production Factor
Example
Let the price of the product of a firm be 10 (e=unit), and let the marginal
productivity of labor be 100 (unit=h). What is, then, the value of marginal
productivity of labor from: (a) 1 hour, (b) 10 minutes, (c) 8 hours?
Answer.
The costs of the firm are assumed to consist of labor costs and fixed
costs, and the cost function is then Ck D C0 C (1 C s)wLk . Thus we
can no longer define the firm’s marginal costs as dCk =dqk like in Chap. 4,
because now the flow of production does not exist in the cost function.
On the other hand, we can analyze the dependence of weekly costs on the
firm’s use of labor.
§: By unit labor costs we understand the ratio between the costs of a
firm and its use of labor in a time unit. ˘
§: By marginal costs of labor we understand the ratio between a
change in the costs of a firm and a change in its use of labor in a time
unit. Marginal costs of labor measure unit labor costs from a marginal
increase in use of labor. ˘
254 Newtonian Microeconomics
The unit and the marginal costs of labor of the firm studied in this section
are:
Ck C0 C (1 C s)wLk C0 dCk
D D C (1 C s)w and D (1 C s)w:
Lk Lk Lk dLk
@…k 0
…0k (t) D Lk (t) D pk fk0 (Lk .t)/ (1 C s)w Lk0 (t):
@Lk
6 Labor as a Production Factor 255
The adjustment rules for the use of labor, that make the weekly profit of
the firm increasing with time (…0k (t) > 0), are:
Quantity pk fk0 .Lk (t)/(e=h) measures the value of the marginal pro-
ductivity of labor, and we can interpret such as this firm’s marginal
willingness-to-pay for one hour of labor time of this profession. Wage
and social security payments, on the other hand, are the costs of one
hour of work time for the firm. Similarly as a consumer compares his
marginal willingness-to-pay for a good and its price, a firm compares its
marginal willingness-to-pay for one hour of work time and its costs. A
profit-seeking firm increases its use of labor if its marginal willingness-to-
pay for one hour exceeds the hourly labor costs at the prevailing use of
labor, and vice versa.
Quantity Fd D pk fk0 .Lk (t)/ (1 C s)w (subindex d refers to demand)
can thus be named as the force this firm directs upon the weekly work
time of the profession. The explanation for this is that Fd causes the
acceleration of use of labor of the firm: Lk0 (t)(h=week2 ). Force Fd with unit
e=h consists of the revenues and costs the firm compares in its decision-
making concerning its use of labor. According to the law of non-increasing
marginal productivity, marginal productivity of labor is non-increasing
with increasing use of labor. This makes the force non-negative at small
and non-positive at large uses of labor. In the profit maximizing situation,
the force acting upon the use of labor vanishes:
The term ‘relation’ is used because actually the last form of Eq. (6.4) is the
inverse demand function of labor. The corresponding demand function
would be of form Lk D f (w; s), which would require solving L from
Eq. (6.4) by taking the inverse function of fk (Lk ). This is not necessary. We
can generally call Eq. (6.4) labor demand relation, which term means that
the equation relates quantities Lk ; w together. It shows the firm’s optimal
use of labor at different wage levels: see Fig. 6.1. The slope of the labor
demand function in coordinates (Lk ; w),
dw pk fk00 (Lk )
D 0;
dLk 1Cs
Lk0 (t) D g(Fd ); g0 (Fd ) > 0; g(0) D 0; Fd D pk fk0 .Lk (t)/ (1 C s)w;
(6.5)
where g is a function with the above characteristics. Function g expresses
the relationship between the acceleration of use of labor Lk0 (t)(h=week2 )
and the force acting upon the labor input of the firm. This relationship is
asymptotically stable (Sect. 3.8), if the following inequality holds strictly:
@Lk0 (t) @Fd pk f 00 (Lk )
D g0 (Fd ) D g0 (Fd ) k 0:
@Lk @Lk (1 C s)
where both sides of the equation are measured in units e=y; notice that
possible holiday time payments are omitted from this analysis.
The maximal annual after-tax wage income of the labor supplier is:
T D 1920(1 )w. Annual wage income is zero if L D 0, and then
H D 1920 (h=y). The possible choices of the labor supplier are shown in
Fig. 6.2. In coordinate system (H; T), the slope of the ‘budget line’ of the
labor supplier is dT=dH D (1 )w < 0; the greater the w, the steeper
the line.
A labor supplier enjoys income and leisure time, and the law of non-
increasing marginal utility is assumed to hold for both these ‘goods’. The
utility function of a labor supplier could be derived from a set of axioms
like that of a consumer. This is omitted, however, and we assume that the
utility of a labor supplier is measured by continuous and differentiable
function
where the first order partials are the corresponding marginal utilities,
the non-positivity of the second order partials with respect to the same
260 Newtonian Microeconomics
quantity imply non-increasing marginal utility, and the second order cross
partials are equal due to the assumed continuity of the partial functions
(see Sect. 3.7).
The arguments of the utility function of a labor supplier are annual
after-tax wage income and leisure time. Thus this utility consists of
different factors than that of a consumer who gains utility from the
consumption of goods. The satisfaction from leisure time can, though,
be understood to be gained from the ‘consumption’ of leisure time, but
receiving wage income can hardly be understood as consumption. In this
decision-making, the labor supplier compares the satisfaction from leisure
time and its alternative cost, the lost income due to not working. In this
way the situation resembles that of a consumer. The measurement unit
of utility again does not have an essential role in the modeling. Utility is
an auxiliary quantity needed in defining the marginal willingness-to-pay
of the labor supplier for leisure time. Thus we set measurement unit ut=y
for the utility of a labor supplier.
The preferences of a labor supplier can be described by indifference
curves analogously with those of a consumer. One indifference curve
represents constant utility, and the slope of an indifference curve in
coordinates (H; T) can be derived as in Sect. 3.5:
@u(H;T)
@u @u dT @H
du D 0 , dH C dT D 0 ) D @u(H;T) < 0:
@H @T dH
@T
income and leisure time, and the latter the subjective rate at which the
labor supplier is willing to exchange these two quantities. In the optimal
situation, an indifference curve touches the ‘budget’ line and at this point
the slopes of the curves are equal.
The optimum condition can be expressed as a two equation system:
T D (1 )wL and
@u(H;T) @u(H;T)
@H @H
(1 )w D @u(H;T) , (1 )w D @u(H;T)
;
@T @T
where the ‘budget’ equation that restricts the choices of the labor supplier
is included in the utility function. At fixed wage and tax rates, annual
6 Labor as a Production Factor 263
work time L(t) is the only quantity by which the labor supplier can affect
his utility. The time derivative of the utility function is
@u 0 @u @T @u @H @u @u
u0 (t) D L (t) D C L0 (t) D (1 )w L0 (t);
@L @T @L @H @L @T @H
where @T
@L
D (1 )w and @H @L
D 1 are obtained from the relations
substituted in the utility function. The changes in the annual work time,
that make the acceleration of utility, u0 (t)(ut=y2 ), positive, are:
@u
@u @u
L0 (t) > 0 if (1 )w > 0 , (1 )w @H
@u
> 0;
@T @H @T
@u
@u @u
L0 (t) < 0 if (1 )w < 0 , (1 )w @H
@u
< 0;
@T @H @T
@u
@u @u
L0 (t) D 0 if (1 )w D 0 , (1 )w @H
@u
D 0:
@T @H @T
@u @u
F1 D (@u=@T)(1 )w @u=@H or F2 D (1 )w = ;
@H @T
can be used as the force this labor supplier directs upon the labor
supply of the profession he represents. Either of these forces cause
the acceleration of labor supply of this person: L0 (t)(h=y2 ). The latter
form of the force consists of the alternative cost of one hour of leisure
time, (1 )w(e=h), minus the marginal willingness-to-pay of the labor
@u @u
supplier for one hour of leisure time, @H = @T (e=h). The equilibrium state
@u @u
(1 )w D @H = @T corresponds to zero force. In the equilibrium, the
after-tax wage and the marginal willingness-to-pay of the labor supplier
for one hour of leisure time are equal. This relation is presented in Fig. 6.5
@u @u
in the form of w D (1=(1 )) @H = @T , and it can be interpreted as the
supply relation of labor of this person.
The labor supply relation (inverse supply function) in Fig. 6.5 defines
the optimal annual work time of the person at different wages. The choice
264 Newtonian Microeconomics
of the labor supplier is restricted by the equation that relates the annual
after-tax wage income and leisure time. This constraint may make the
labor supply relation ‘backward bending’ at high wage levels and annual
work time, which is denoted by the dotted part of the relation in Fig. 6.5.
The slope of the labor supply relation (1 )w @u=@T D @u=@H in
coordinate system (L; w) is:
@ u2 @ u 2
2 2@ u 2
dw 2(1 )w @H@T @H 2 (1 ) w @T 2
D @u @2 u @2 u
: (6.8)
dL (1 ) @T (1 )L @H@T C (1 )2 wL @T 2
The result in Eq. (6.8) can be derived by taking the total differential
(Sect. 10.10.2) so that other quantities in equation (1 )w @u=@T D
@u=@H except w and L are treated as constants. Equation (1 )w
@u=@T @u=@H D 0 is then of the general form f (w; L) D 0 from
which we get by totally differentiating:
@f
@f @f dw
dw C dL D 0 , D @L
@f
: (6.9)
@w @L dL
@w
6 Labor as a Production Factor 265
Formula (6.8) deviates from that in Eq. (6.9) so that the partial derivatives
in Eq. (6.9) are written in a complete form in Eq. (6.8). The exact
derivation of the slopes of curves in graphical presentations hopefully
motivates a serious student of economics to learn the mathematical
techniques needed in this (see Sect. 10.13).
From formula (6.8)—the slope of the labor supply function in coordi-
nates (L; w)—we see that its numerator is positive if @2 u=@T@H is positive,
because the law of non-increasing marginal utility makes the two other
additive terms in the numerator non-negative. Quantity @2 u=@T@H can
be assumed to have a small absolute value because an increase in leisure
time may not have a great effect on the marginal utility of income, or an
increase in annual income may not have a great effect on the marginal
utility of leisure time. The sufficient condition for maximal utility is that
@2 u=@T@H > 0. The sign of the numerator is thus ambiguous but the
positive sign is more plausible.
The first additive term in the denominator of Eq. (6.8) is positive, the
second is ambiguous, and the last is non-positive. The greater the annual
income T, the smaller the marginal utility @u=@T. The denominator may
thus be negative; namely, the labor supply relation may be decreasing
in coordinate system (L; w) (the backward bending part of the relation
corresponds to dw=dL < 0). The probability of this is the higher the
greater is T.
In the following we assume that @2 u=@T@H > 0, which guarantees the
existence of an optimum for the labor supplier. The following results are
obtained from the marginal willingness-to-pay
@u @u of the labor supplier for
one hour of leisure time, g(L; w; ) @H = @T :
2 2
@ u @2 u @u @u @ u @2 u
@g @H 2 C @T@H (1 )w @T
@H @T 2
(1 )w @H@T
D @u 2 > 0;
@L
@T
2
@ u @u @u @ u2
@g (1 )L @T@H @T
@H @T 2
D > 0;
@w @u 2
@T
2
@ u @u @u @2 u
@g wL @T@H @T
@H @T 2
D @u 2 < 0:
@ (1 ) @T
266 Newtonian Microeconomics
These results imply that the labor supplier is the more willing-to-pay for
one hour of leisure time the higher are w and L, and the smaller is .
This is the Newtonian equation of motion for the labor supply of this
person. According to Eq. (6.11), the annual labor supply of this person
increases if the after-tax wage income from one work hour is greater than
6 Labor as a Production Factor 267
the value of one hour of leisure time for the person, and vice versa. We
could have also added static friction in Eq. (6.11) to explain that the labor
supply of this person is not always changed when the force acting upon
it deviates from zero. This, however, is omitted as well as the finding of
possible solutions for Eq. (6.11).
The above definitions assume that labor markets work locally; a limited
area exists around firms and homes of labor suppliers which define the
maximum distance for daily working. In the above definitions we talked
generally about labor and wage, because the use of labor can be measured
in different units. For example, if the use of labor is measured by the
number of employees working in a time unit, the unit price of labor is
the salary of one employee in the time unit. However, in the following
we measure firms’ use of labor by worked hours in a time unit; unit labor
costs are then hourly wage plus social security payments per one hour.
Our analysis here exactly corresponds to that in Sect. 5.2.7, and so
the presentation is a little shorter. Let perfect competition prevail in the
product market of every firm employing the studied type of labor as well
as in the labor market. Let there be n firms employing the type of labor we
study and m labor suppliers. The planning time horizon of every firm and
labor supplier is assumed to be one year. The modeling of firms’ behavior
is based on the assumption that firms try to increase their annual profit by
adjusting their use of labor. Labor suppliers are, similarly, assumed to seek
utility by changing their annual work time. A firm is assumed to increase
its annual use of labor if it believes that the revenues from production
during the extra work time exceed the extra labor costs, and vice versa.
Similarly, an individual labor supplier is assumed to increase his annual
work time, if the extra income received from this exceeds its alternative
cost, the decrease in annual leisure time and vice versa.
The profit and utility functions of firms and labor suppliers are
assumed continuous and differentiable, and both parties are assumed to
consider changes in their annual use of labor and work time. With these
assumptions, we can define the forces by which the firms and the labor
suppliers act upon the annual aggregate work time of this profession.
Suppose the flows of production of firms are measured in units kg=y. The
profit of firm i producing a single good is then
where fi is the production function of the firm, pi (e=kg) the price of the
product of the firm, Ci0 (e=y) the annual fixed costs of the firm, w(e=h)
the wage of the employed labor, 0 < s < 1 the dimensionless social
security rate of wage, and Ldi (h=y) the annual use of labor of the firm
(subindex d refers to ‘demand’). We assume that Ldi and w depend on
time t, because later we will analyze their adjustment with time.
The labor costs of the firm consist of the wage costs wLid and social
security payments swLid the firm pays to the state. The force by which
firm i acts upon the annual work time of the studied profession is:
@…i
D pi fi0 .Lid (t)/ (1 C s)w(t):
@Lid
This force measures the firm’s marginal profitability of its use of labor.
The rationale for the force interpretation is as before; the greater the above
quantity, the more profitable it is for the firm to increase its use of this
type of labor. The profit-seeking firm increases its use of this type of labor
if the above force is positive, and vice versa. For simplicity, firms’ use of
labor is assumed not to have a static friction, which assumption does not
hold in the real world.
In the following we analyze the forces directed by all firms using, and
by all labor suppliers supplying. the labor upon the annual work time of
the profession in a region. In practice, this can be assumed to take place
via the employment office in the region, where all labor suppliers and
demanders express their willingness to supply and demand work. The role
of the office is to guide potential workers to the firms interested in hiring
them, in which way employment offices work in real life.
We assume n firms employing the studied type of labor in the region.
At time moment t, the average force acting upon the firms’ use of labor is
1X
n
FdL D pi fi0 .Lid (t)/ (1 C s)w(t) D fd .Ld (t); p/ (1 C s)w(t);
n iD1
(6.12)
P
whereby fd .Ld (t); p/ (1=n) niD1 pi fi0 (Lid (t)) is denoted the average
value of marginal productivity of labor for the firms at their aggregate
270 Newtonian Microeconomics
P
annual use of the labor Ld D niD1 Lid . Suppose the production of every
firm is measured in units kg=y. The prices of the products then have unit
e=kg, and by p we denote the arithmetic average of these prices; see the
Appendix of this chapter.
Firms employing the studied profession adjust the aggregate use of labor as
Ld0 (t) D Gd (FdL ); G0d (FdL ) > 0; Gd (0) D 0; FdL D fd .Ld (t); p/ (1Cs)w(t);
(6.13)
where Gd is a function with the above characteristics. From Eq. (6.13) we
get @Ld0 (t)=@Ld (t) D G0d (FdL ) @fd =@Ld , and according to the Appendix
of this chapter, this partial is non-positive. The adjustment of labor
demand is thus stable if @fd =@Ld < 0, see Fig. 3.9.
where the annual leisure time and wage income P of labor supplier j is
denoted by Hj and Tj , respectively, and Ls D m jD1 Ljs is the aggregate
annual work time of all labor suppliers (subindex s refers to ‘supply’).
By fs (Ls ; w; ) we denote the average marginal willingness-to-pay of the
m labor suppliers for one hour of leisure time; see the Appendix of this
chapter. According to Eq. (6.14), on average the labor suppliers are willing
6 Labor as a Production Factor 271
to increase their annual work time, if the after-tax hourly wage exceeds
their average marginal willingness-to-pay for one hour of leisure time,
and vice versa.
The labor suppliers are assumed to adjust the aggregate labor supply as
where function Gs obeys the above characteristics. From Eq. (6.15) we get
@Ls0 (t)=@Ls (t) D G0s (FsL ) @fs =@Ls , and according to the Appendix of
this chapter, this partial is negative. The adjustment of labor supply is thus
stable, see Fig. 3.9.
The resultant force acting upon the annual work time of a profession is
defined as the sum of the force components created by labor demanders
and suppliers. Both force components in Eq. (6.12) and in Eq. (6.14) are
measured in units e=h, and so we can add them. The resultant force is
then:
The rationale for this resultant force is the same as earlier; the two force
components are caused by independent partners, and they both affect the
annual aggregate work time of the profession.
Let us assume, for a moment, that the wage tax and social security rates
of wage, and s, are zero. Then a positive force is acting upon the annual
work time of the profession, if the average marginal willingness-to-pay
of firms for one hour of annual work time exceeds the average marginal
272 Newtonian Microeconomics
Note. The result that wage tax and social security rate decrease employ-
ment, is based on partial analysis. To find out their total effect on
employment, we should take account as to how public sector uses the
money it collects with these two forms of taxes. ˘
wage, and a labor supplier likes to increase his annual work time, he can
do this by decreasing his wage requirement because a decrease in wage
positively affects firms’ demand of labor.
Equation (6.17) corresponds to the principle of modeling in economics,
because in the excess demand situation of labor, firms can increase their
profit by increasing their use of labor, which takes place only by increasing
their wage offer. In a situation where there is an excess supply of labor,
labor suppliers can increase their utility by increasing their annual work
time, which takes place similarly by decreasing their wage requirement.
Note. The labor demand and supply relations in Fig. 6.6 may not corre-
spond to the annual uses of labor of all firms and the annual amounts
of work time of all labor suppliers at a certain moment of time, but they
describe the aggregate amounts of annual work time in the region when
every firm and labor supplier are in their equilibrium state. The stability
analysis given earlier show, however, that both parties adjust their behavior
with time to reach their equilibrium states. ˘
274 Newtonian Microeconomics
1X 0
n
a0 a1 a2
F(Ld ; p) pi fi (Lid ) C 2 Ld C p;
n iD1 n n n
X
n
1X
n
Ld D Lid ; pD pi ; (6.20)
iD1
n iD1
where constants a0 > 0; a1 < 0; a2 > 0 have units e=h, (e y)=h2 and
kg=h, respectively; see the Appendix of this chapter.
In the Appendix of this chapter, we approximate the labor suppliers’
average marginal willingness-to-pay for one hour of leisure time as
@uj
1X
m
@Hj b0 b1 b2 b3
G(Ls ; w; ) @uj
C 2 Ls C w C ;
m jD1 m m m m
@Tj
a0 b1 n a1 m(b0 C b3 )
w D ;
a1 mŒb2 C ( 1)m C (1 C s)b1 n2
mnfa0 Œ(1 )m b2 (1 C s)(b0 C b3 )ng
Ld D Ls D : (6.23)
a1 mŒb2 C ( 1)m C (1 C s)b1 n2
The units of the constants can be used to check that the solutions are
dimensionally well-defined, namely the units of w , Ld are e=h, h=y,
respectively.
fs(Ls, w, t) w w ¯
fd (Ld ,p)
mks mkd
tw SW
∫ Ld (t)dt, ∫ Ls (t)dt
Fig. 6.7 The forces acting upon wage and demand and supply of labor
The equations of motion for labor demand, supply and wage are then:
Notice that we could have also added static friction for wage in Eq. (6.25)
to explain the rigidities that may prevent wage adjustment in some
cases according to excess demand and supply. However, we assume, for
simplicity, that wages do not have static friction which assumption does
not hold in the real world.
The ‘free body’ diagram of the forces acting upon the demand and
supply of labor is in Fig. 6.7, where the static friction forces are omitted for
simplicity. The direction of motion to the right—where the accumulated
amounts of demanded and supplied labor time increase—is defined
positive, and to the left, negative. In Fig. 6.7, the system cannot move
to left direction, because the flows of demanded and supplied labor time
Ld ; Ls cannot be negative. The positive force component acting upon
the demand of labor is fd (Ld ; p), and the negative force consists of two
components; wage w and social security payments sw for one hour. Both
these cost components are paid by firms, and employees receive the wage
while government receives the social security payments. The positive force
component acting upon the supply of labor is wage w, and the negative
force components consist of average marginal willingness-to-pay of labor
suppliers for one hour of leisure time fs (Ls ; w; ) and income tax from one
hour’s wage, w. As earlier, the shapes of the ‘particles’ in Fig. 6.7 have no
economic meaning, and actually the particles should be drawn as a points
278 Newtonian Microeconomics
on the horizontal axis. However, the box shapes for the variables better
visualizes the analogy we make here with Newtonian mechanics.
In Fig. 6.7, the spring between the two ‘particles’ reflects the matter
that an equal mutual force w is acting upon the two particles, and the
difference in velocities of the particles Ld Ls changes their distance and
so also the length of the spring that changes the mutual force w. This is
seen in wage equation (6.25) that corresponds exactly to the price equation
given in Sect. 5.2.7. Thus wage with unit e/h is a force component that
acts upon the aggregate labor demand and supply, and these interact back
to wage by the difference Ld Ls . The diagram in Fig. 6.7 shows how
government as an outside actor can affect the system by changing its
policy variables s and . In the equilibrium state, the system moves with
the equilibrium velocity Ld D Ls in the direction of accumulated labor
demand and supply with wage w staying constant.
Assuming fd (Ld ; p) and fs (Ls ; w; ) as in Eqs. (6.21), (6.22) and
pi D pi0 8i to eliminate quantity p from System (6.24), we get:
a0 a1
mLd Ld0 (t) D C 2 Ld (t) (1 C s)w(t);
n n
b0 b1 b2 b3
mLs Ls0 (t) D (1 )w(t) Ls (t) w(t) ; (6.26)
m m2 m m
1 0
w (t) D Ld (t) Ls (t):
kw
With certain parameter values, System (6.26) is globally stable and will
converge with time to the equilibrium state given in Eq. (6.23). The
equilibrium state of the labor market in Eq. (6.23) can be solved by
assuming Ld0 (t) D Ls0 (t) D w0 (t) D 0 in System (6.26), and solving the
resulting system of three equations with respect to the three endogenous
variables. The speed of adjustment of the system toward the equilibrium
depends on the two inertial masses, the spring constant, and the values
of the parameters. In this book we concentrate on the equilibrium state,
however, and therefore it is necessary to know that the system is stable and
will converge into the equilibrium state with time.
6 Labor as a Production Factor 279
Fig. 6.8 displays the aggregate annual working hours in the Finnish
economy and an index of earnings level during 1975–2013. The figure
shows that the earnings level has been rising steadily while aggregate
working hours have been slightly decreasing during the time period. Thus
a steady rise in the standard of living of employees has occurred in Finland.
Because the analytic solution of System (6.26) is rather complicated, we
demonstrate the solution by the following numerical values: m D n D 10,
mLd D mLs D 2, kw D 1=2, s D D 0, a0 D 400 C 25:1t; a1 D 8,
and b0 D 10C24:4t; b1 D 10; b2 D 0:2. The time paths of quantities
Ld ; Ls ; w with these parameter values are shown in Fig. 6.9, where on the
horizontal axis is time and on the vertical axis are Ld ; Ls , and w. The
three quantities are presented in the same figure to demonstrate their
connections, even though the measurement units of the quantities differ.
The time path of wage is the increasing one, and that of Ld is the thicker
one of those remaining. The figure shows that wage increases faster if Ld >
Ls , and Ld ; Ls stay relatively constant while wage increases continuously.
The initial condition of the solution is: Ld (0) D 400; Ls (0) D 300 and
w(0) D 5. A positive time trend in labor demand (a0 D 400 C 25:1t)
and a negative time trend in labor supply (b0 D 10C24:4t) is assumed.
These trends cause scarcity of labor that explains the continuous increase
in wage shown in Figs. 6.8 and 6.9.
280 Newtonian Microeconomics
these unions, every firm and labor supplier makes their decision to hire
a person or accept a work offer independently. These matters make the
functioning of the labor market more complicated, because many of the
work contracts are not made at the wage agreed by the unions. It is a
commonly occurrence that contracts of work are agreed at a higher wage
than unions have agreed. The difference between a contract wage and the
actual wage is called a wage slide.
In this section, we analyze the behavior of a unionized labor market
by one simplified model called Monopoly Union model (see Dunlop
(1944)). This model assumes that a trade union makes the choice on
behalf of its members with respect to their work time and wage. Let the
time unit be one year. Analogously with a monopoly firm, a trade union
is supposed to know the demand relation of its ‘product’ (labor), and the
union sets the wage like a monopoly firm sets the price of its product. Like
a monopoly firm, a monopoly union chooses the optimal (annual use of
labor, wage) combination from the annual aggregate demand relation of
its members’ work time.
The demand of the work time of union members is assumed to be a
unique relation between the use of labor time of union members and wage.
The utility of the union is assumed to depend on the after-tax wage and
the aggregate annual work time of union members. The target function
of the monopoly union is then:
@u @u @2 u @2 u
u D u.wN ; L/; > 0; > 0; 0; 0;
@wN @L @wN 2 @L2
@2 u @2 u
D ; wN D (1 )w;
@L@wN @wN @L
where wN (e=h) is the after-tax hourly wage of union members, 0 < <
1 the wage tax rate, w(e=h) the hourly wage, and L(h=y) the annual
aggregate work time of union members. The marginal utilities of after-tax
wage and employment of union members, @u=@wN , @u=@L, are positive,
the second order partials of the utility function with respect to the same
quantity are non-positive due to non-increasing marginal utility, and the
second order cross partials are equal due to the continuity of the partial
functions.
282 Newtonian Microeconomics
Of course, there exists models of trade union behavior where the target
function of the union is defined by aggregating over utility functions of
individual union members; see, for example McDonald and Solow (1981).
In this book we omit these models, however, because this section is only
a minor part of this book.
The slope of an indifference curve of the trade union in coordinates
(L; w) can be derived as follows. The total differential of the utility
function is:
6 Labor as a Production Factor 283
@u @u 1 @u @u
du D dwN C dL D (1 )dw C dL; (6.27)
@wN @L 1 @w @L
@u @u @wN @u @u 1 @u
D D (1 ) , D ;
@w @wN @w @wN @wN (1 ) @w
@u
dw @L
D @u < 0:
dL @w
This condition—together with the demand relation for annual work time
of union members—uniquely defines the optimal wage and annual work
time of union members.
The force the monopoly union directs upon the annual work time of
its members can be derived as follows. We substitute wage from the utility
function of the union by using the labor demand relation as
(1 )
u D u(wN (t); L(t)) D u fd .L(t); p/; L(t) ;
(1 C s)
6 Labor as a Production Factor 285
where the aggregate annual work time of union members is set to depend
on time t. The union can now affect its utility only by the annual work
time L(t). The time derivative of the utility function is:
@u (1 ) @fd .L(t); p/ @u
u0 (t) D C L0 (t):
@wN (1 C s) @L @L
Changes in the aggregate annual work time, that make the acceleration of
utility u0 (t)(ut=y2 ) positive, are:
@u
0 (1 ) @fd .L(t); p/ @L
L (t) > 0 if C @u
> 0;
(1 C s) @L @wN
@u
(1 ) @fd .L(t); p/
L0 (t) < 0 if C @L
@u
< 0;
(1 C s) @L @wN
@u
(1 ) @fd .L(t); p/
L0 (t) D 0 if C @L
@u
D 0:
(1 C s) @L @wN
) @fd .L(t);p/ @u @u
As before, quantity Fu D (1(1Cs) @L
C @L = @wN can be named as the
force the union directs upon the annual work time of the members
of the union in the region. The first negative component in the force
measures the decrease in utility due to a decrease in wage required for an
increase in employment. The second positive component measures the
increase in utility due to an increase in annual work time. The union
compares the gain of extra work time and its cost, the decrease in wage,
and decides the optimal (annual work time, wage) combination on this
basis. The zero force situation corresponds to the optimal state of the
union.
In the above defined force, the measurement unit of utility cancels
out. Thus the force is measurable in units (e=h)=(h=y) D e y=h2 ,
when the benefits and losses for the union from this decision can be
quantified. Another way to model the decision-making of the trade union
is to substitute the aggregate annual employment from the utility function
by using the labor demand relation, and analyze the utility as a function of
286 Newtonian Microeconomics
wage. This way we could define the force the union directs upon the wage
of union members. This, however, is omitted because in solving the labor
demand relation with respect to Ld we should take the inverse function
of fd that would complicate the modeling.
where the union is assumed to know the ‘force’ Fu acting upon the
employment of union members in the region. The union adjusts the
employment according to this force with the aim of increasing its utility
with time. Assuming a specific utility function for the union we could
study the stability of the model. However, for shortness we omit these
analyses.
pi fi0 .Ldi / D pi0 fi0 .Ldi0 / C pi0 fi00 (Ldi0 ).Ldi Ldi0 / C fi0 (Ldi0 ).pi pi0 / C i ;
(6.29)
where i is the residual term. Assuming i D 0 and summing over i, we get
X
n X
n
pi fi0 .Ldi / pi0 fi0 .Ldi0 / pi0 fi00 (Ldi0 )Ldi0 fi0 (Ldi0 )pi0
iD1 iD1
X
n X
n
a1
C pi0 fi00 (Ldi0 )Ldi C fi0 (Ldi0 )pi a0 C Ld C a2 p;
iD1 iD1
n
6 Labor as a Production Factor 287
Pn Pn
where Ld D iD1 Ldi , p D (1=n) iD1 pi and1
X
n
a0 D pi0 fi0 .Ldi0 / pi0 fi00 (Ldi0 )Ldi0 fi0 (Ldi0 )pi0
iD1
X
n X
n X
n
D pi0 fi00 (Ldi0 )Ldi0 ; a1 D pi0 fi00 (Ldi0 ); a2 D fi0 (Ldi0 ):
iD1 iD1 iD1
X
m
gj (Lsj ; w; )
jD1
m
X
@gj (zj0 ) @gj (zj0 ) @gj (zj0 )
D gj (zj0 ) Lsj0 w0 0
jD1
@Lsj @w @
X
m
@gj (zj0 ) X
m
@gj (zj0 ) X
m
@gj (zj0 )
C Lsj C w C
jD1
@Lsj jD1
@w jD1
@
b1
b0 C Ls C b2 w C b3 ;
m
Pn Pn Pn Pn
1
ci xi D c iD1 xi C iD1 (ci c)xi where c D (1=n) iD1 ci . The approximation
PniD1 Pn
iD1 ci xi c iD1 xi is the more accurate the less ci or xi vary, i D 1; : : : ; n.
2
See footnote 1.
288 Newtonian Microeconomics
Pm
where Ls D jD1 Lsj and
Xm
@gj (zj0 ) @gj (zj0 ) @gj (zj0 )
b0 D gj (zj0 ) Lsj0 w0 0 ;
jD1
@Lsj @w @
X
m
@gj (zj0 ) X
m
@gj (zj0 ) X
m
@gj (zj0 )
b1 D ; b2 D ; b3 D :
jD1
@Lsj jD1
@w jD1
@
References
Dunlop, J. T. (1944). Wage determination under trade unionism. New York:
Macmillan.
McDonald, I., & Solow, R. (1981). Wage bargaining and employment. American
Economic Review, 71, 896–908.
7
Capital Goods as Firms’ Inputs
We repeat here the definition given in Sect. 4.3 for firms’ capital goods.
§: The plant, machinery, and equipment owned by a firm, that create
revenues during several fiscal periods, are called the physical capital of
the firm. ˘
The raw materials used by firms are not counted as capital goods
because they wear out in production. The term ’physical capital’ makes a
distinction from the financial or monetary capital of a firm, and name
capital refers to a stock concepts as distinct from flow concepts. The
amounts of different kinds of capital goods are measured, for example,
in units kg, unit, and so on. Flow quantities, on the other hand, are
time-related quantities and their measurement units are, for example,
unit=week, kg=h (see Sect. 2.7.1).
All stocks are accumulated from some kind of a flow process, and
a stock measures the sum of a flow at a certain moment of time (see
Sect. 2.7.3). For example, the inventory of a firm’s produced but unsold
products, the number of production factors acquired and not scrapped
during the history of the firm, the common value of all production factors
of a firm at a certain time moment, are all stocks. Pieces of land measured
exists a unique optimal use of these capital goods, as in the case of labor.
This analysis is carried on here shortly because it exactly corresponds to
that of the use of labor.
Suppose the weekly production of a firm producing good k depends
on its use of one kind of labor Lk (h=week) and one kind of capital
goods Bk (h=week) as qk D f (Lk ; Bk ), where qk (kg=week) is the flow
of production of the firm. Production function f obeys the following
characteristics:
@qk @qk @2 qk @2 qk @2 qk @2 qk
> 0; > 0; 0; 0; and D D 0:
@Lk @Bk @Lk2 @B2k @Lk @Bk @Bk @Lk
…k (t) D pk qk (t) C0 wLk (t) zBk (t); qk (t) D f .Lk (t); Bk (t)/;
where C0 (e=week) are fixed costs, all the three prices are assumed
constant, and the firm’s use of both production factors is set to depend on
time t. The firm is assumed to adjust its use of labor and capital to increase
its weekly profit with time. The time derivative of the profit function is
(Sect. 10.9.4):
@qk @qk
…0k (t) D pk w Lk0 (t) C pk z B0k (t):
@Lk @Bk
The firm can now affect its weekly profit by adjusting its use of labor
and capital independently of each other. In Sect. 6.1 we analyzed a firm’s
adjustment of its use of labor, and thus we can omit it here. The
292 Newtonian Microeconomics
These adjustment rules show that the firm increases its use of capital goods
if the value of marginal productivity of capital from one hour is greater
than hourly rent, and vice versa. In the optimal situation, the value of
marginal productivity of capital from one hour is equal to hourly rent.
@B0k (t) @2 qk
D g0 (F)pk 2 0;
@Bk @Bk
the equation of motion in Eq. (7.1) is stable if @B0k (t)=@Bk < 0. This
analysis exactly corresponds to that of a firm’s use of labor, and we omit
all details here.
7 Capital Goods as Firms’ Inputs 293
1
The term ‘discount’ comes from the reduction in future debt payments a debtor receives if he repays
his debt before the terminal date.
294 Newtonian Microeconomics
The last form of the equation shows that the money on the bank account
at moment t0 C t, x(t0 C t), can be expressed by the interest rate rd .
Assuming rd to be fixed, we can calculate how a monetary capital increases
during n time intervals when interest revenues are added in the capital
at the last moment of every time unit. We call this compound interest
calculation.
§: By compound interest calculation we understand the calculation
of interest returns in the way that interest revenues from one time unit are
added in the invested capital after every time unit. ˘
The money on the bank account at the last moment of every time
interval is shown in Table 7.1. The deposit at moment t0 , x(t0 ), grows
during time unit t so that at the end of the time unit, the money in
the bank account is x(t0 C t) D x(t0 ) C rd tx(t0 ) D (1 C rd t)x(t0 ),
where x(t0 ) is the invested capital and rd tx(t0 ) the interest revenues from
the time unit. The dimensionless term 1 C rd t, where the measurement
units of rd and t cancel each other out, is called the interest factor for
one time unit. At time moment t0 C 2t the capital is, similarly,
x(t0 C2t) D (1Crd t)x(t0 )Crd t(1Crd t)x(t0 ) D (1Crd t)2 x(t0 );
where (1 C rd t)x(t0 ) is the capital at the beginning of the time unit and
rd t(1 C rd t)x(t0 ) the interest revenues from the time unit.
Next we define the amount of money at time moment t0 , x(t0 ), that
corresponds to the money x(t0 C t) at moment t0 C t, as
1
(1 C rd t)x(t0 ) D x(t0 C t) , x(t0 ) D x(t0 C t):
1 C rd t
7 Capital Goods as Firms’ Inputs 295
We call x(t0 ) the present value of x(t0 C t) and 1=(1 C rd t) the
discount factor between time moments t0 and t0 C t. The discount
factor is a dimensionless quantity like the interest factor. In general, the
discount factor between time moments t0 and t0 C nt is 1=(1 C rd t)n .
If the interest rates of time units differ, that is rd1 ¤ rd2 ¤ where rdj
is the interest rate of the jth time unit, the interest and discount factors
between t0 and t0 C nt are:
1
(1 C rd1 t) (1 C rdn t) and : (7.2)
(1 C rd1 t) (1 C rdn t)
The reader can check this by constructing a similar table to Table 7.1
varying the interest rates of the time units.
Example
Let interest rate be 10 (%=y) = 0.1 (1=y) and t D 1 (y). Then, setting x(t0 C
t) D x(t0 C 2t) D x(t0 C 3t) D 1 (e) we get the corresponding present
values as: 1=(1 C 0:1 1) D 0:91 (e), 1=(1 C 0:1 1)2 D 0:83 (e), and 1=(1 C
0:1 1)3 D 0:75 (e). If interest rate is 5 (%=y) and t D 1 (y), the present
values are: 0.95 (e), 0.91 (e), and 0.86 (e), respectively. Thus an increase in
interest rate decreases present values. ˘
Interest and discount calculation can be defined for real values too. Sup-
pose x (e) is deflated by an average price level p (e/kg) of the economy.
The growth rate of the real quantity x(t)=p(t) (kg) then corresponds to
the real interest rate rR :
x(t0 Ct)
p(t0 Ct)
x(t0 )
p(t0 )
=t x(t0 C t) x(t0 )
D rR , D (1 C rR t): (7.3)
x(t0 )
p(t0 )
p(t0 C t) p(t0 )
This can be seen by comparing Eqs. (7.3) and (2.12) and remembering
that t1 D t0 C t or t D t1 t0 . The latter form of Eq. (7.3) defines the
transformation equation between values of real quantity x=p at different
time units. Quantity x(t0 Ct)=p(t0 Ct) measures the purchasing power
of x(t0 C t) at time moment t0 C t, that is, the amount of goods in
the economy that can be obtained by x (e) at time moment t0 C t.
It is a matter of preference as to whether discounting is made in nominal
or in real terms. It is essential that if we operate with nominal (real) terms,
the interest rate to be used in discounting is the nominal (real) one.
Equation (7.5) defines the money on the bank account at time moment
t when x(t0 ) was deposited at moment t0 with continuous time interest
rate r that may vary during (t0 ; t). In a continuous time compound interest
calculation, interest revenues are added in the capital after every instant of
time, which creates the exponential growth. If t D t0 , then x(t) D x(t0 )
in Eq. (7.5).
Using the definition r(s) D x0 (s)=x(s), we get:
Z Z ˇt
t t
x0 (s) ˇ x(t)
r(s)ds D ˇ
ds D ˇ ln(x(s)) D ln :
t0 t0 x(s) t0 x(t0 )
If the interest rate is constant during time interval (t0 ; t), then:
The first form of Eq. (7.6) expresses the present value of x(t) at time
moment t0 , and the latter is the corresponding compound interest for-
mula. The continuous time correspondent for the discrete time discount
298 Newtonian Microeconomics
Note. One essential difference exists between the two discount factors. In
the continuous time discount factor, the length of time interval t t0 is
measured in time units. In the discrete time discount factor, on the other
hand, exponent n is a pure number that represents the order of the time
interval. If time is measured in years in discrete analysis, then n D 3
implies that the discount factor is that between the initial and the third
year, and so forth. ˘
Solving x(tn )=x(t0 ) from both equations and setting them equal, we get:
R tn
r(t)dt
(1 C rd t)n D e t0 : (7.7)
Thus both methods give identical results if the two interest (and discount)
factors are equal. Suppose then that the two interest rates with unit 1=t
are constant. The amount of money on the bank account after time
interval t, calculated by both methods, is then:
Example
We calculate the capital on a bank account by discrete and continuous
time methods when 100 (e) is deposited at moment t0 D 0 for time unit
tn t0 D 20 (y), and rd D r D 0:1 (1=y). The time paths of the capitals are in
Fig. 7.1a. The continuous time capital (the curve) somewhat overestimates
the discrete time one (the dots). However, using rc D ln(1 C rd t)=t D
0:0953 (1=y) in continuous time, the two time paths coincide, see Fig. 7.1b.
Hull (2000, pp. 51–52) shows that even without the adjustment r D rc , the
continuous time interest calculation gives almost identical results as the
daily discrete time analysis with ‘normal’ levels of interest rates. ˘
300 Newtonian Microeconomics
Fig. 7.1 (a) Discrete and continuous time interest rates. (b) Two conformal
interest rates
Another parity can be made between discrete time interest rates of varying
time units. Let us denote the discrete time interest rate for time unit k
by rdk , and that for time unit z by rdz , where s D k=z , k D sz
is the transformation equation between the time units. For example,
1 (y) D 12 (mn) where k D y; z D mn, and s D 12. In both cases,
interest returns are added in the deposited capital at the ending moment
of the corresponding time unit. Let s > 1, which implies k > z; thus
rdz represents a more dense splitting of time, that is, the interest revenues
are added in the capital more frequently. In monthly (annual) compound
interest calculation, interest revenues are added in the capital after every
month (year). The deposited capital x(t0 ) (e) increases in both cases
during time unit k as:
x(tk ) D x(t0 )(1 C rdk k) and x(tsz ) D x(t0 )(1 C rdz z)s :
Fig. 7.2 (a) Capitals with two discrete time interest rates. (b) Capitals with
conformal discrete time interest rates
These transformation rules make any two discrete time interest rates
comparable with each other, because relation k D sz holds for every two
time units k; z. Thus Eq. (7.10) defines two discrete time interest rates
conformal with each other in compound interest calculation.
Example 1
Suppose rdy D 0:1 (1=y), rdm D 0:01 (1=m) and 1 (y) D 12 (m). Using
the rules in Eq. (7.10), the corresponding conformal monthly and annual
interest rates are rdc;m D 0:00797 (1=m) and rdc;y D 0:1268 (1=y), respectively.
These somewhat differ from the approximate ones we get by transforming
simply by using time units: rOdm D 1=12 (y=m) 0:1 (1=y) D 0:0083 (1=m) and
rOdy D 12 (m=y) 0:01 (1=m) D 0:12 (1=y). ˘
Example 2
Figure 7.2a shows the differences in capitals during 20 years when 100 (e)
is deposited at time moment 0 and interest rates rdy D 0:1 (1=y), rOdm D
0:0083 (1=m) are applied (the curve refers to monthly and dots to annual
analysis). This difference disappears when the conformal monthly interest
rate rdc;m D 0:00797 (1=m) is applied in the annual analysis, see Fig. 7.2b. ˘
302 Newtonian Microeconomics
X
n
D N(t0 C jt)t .1 C rd t/j ; (7.11)
jD1
This sum is called a geometric series with positive terms. Let us denote
the sum of the series of n terms Sn as:
X
n
Sn D a1 C a2 C a3 C C an D aj :
jD1
7 Capital Goods as Firms’ Inputs 303
where
a(1 an )
1
1Crd t
1 1
(1Crd t)n
1
Œ1 (1 C rd t)n
1Crd t
D D 1Crd t1
1a 1 1
1Crd t 1Crd t
1 (1 C rd t)n
D :
rd t
A quick test for the correctness of the last form of Eq. (7.13) can be made
by dimensional analysis. The measurement unit of the left hand side is e,
that of N=rd is e, and the term in parenthesis is dimensionless. At least
the measurement units match; hopefully also the form of the equation.
Equation (7.13) is a complicated connection of four quantities: P(t0 ),
N, rd and n. There exists computer programs that solve rd from Eq. (7.13)
in a numerical way to see what is the yield (the internal rate of return
per annum) of an asset with initial price P(t0 ) D 10;000 (e) that pays
Nt D 1300 (e) at the end of every year during n D 10 years. This yield
can be compared with the prevailing risk-free interest rate in the economy
to see whether this asset is competitive in creating revenues. Another way
to use Eq. (7.13) is to calculate the necessary annual payment N related to
an n period fixed flow with initial price P(t0 ) and discount rate rd as:
rd P(t0 )
ND : (7.14)
1 (1 C rd t)n
304 Newtonian Microeconomics
One clear result can still be obtained from Eq. (7.13): the higher the
interest rate rd , the smaller the present value of a fixed payment instru-
ment. Although quantities N, n and P(t0 ) are known at the moment of
the investment decision, interest rate rd during the term to maturity of
the asset is not known, and so there exists an interest rate risk in this
investment decision.
Assuming an infinite time horizon (limn!1 ) in Eq. (7.13), we get
N
P(t0 ) D : (7.15)
rd
Notice that the measurement unit of the interest rate transforms the
measurement unit of the present value as: (e/t)=(1=t) D e.
Next we calculate the present value of a money flow, where one euro is
received at the end of every week in a time unit of four weeks. Notice
that the total of the flow is the same as above: 4 (e=4week). Again,
transforming the interest rate simply by time units the weekly interest
rate is 10 (%=y) = 1=520 (1=week), and the present value is:
7 Capital Goods as Firms’ Inputs 305
Thus the more frequently the payments take place in a fixed flow, the
greater is the present value of a positive money flow. The four week interest
rate rd (1=4week), that gives the same present value as the above when
calculated on the four week basis, can be obtained as follows:
4 (e=4week) (4week)
3:981 (e) D )
1 C rd (1=4week) (4week)
4 3:981 1
rd D D 0:00477 :
3:981 4week
This is clearly smaller than the four-week interest rate we used without
making the compounding correction: 4=520 D 0:00769 (1=4week).
X
t t j
nk
t t
P(t0 ) D N t0 C j 1 C rd t0 C j :
jD1
k k k k
306 Newtonian Microeconomics
00 1 .
jrd t0 Cj t
k /
1 k=t k=t
.
rd t0 Cj t /
t t j B 1 k
C
1 C rd t0 C j D @@1 C k=t
A A ;
k k
rd .t0 Cj t
k /
X
t t j t
nk
t
lim N t0 C j 1 C rd t0 C j
k!1
jD1
k k k k
Z tn
D N(t)er(t)(tt0 ) dt
t0
Thus if rd D r, we get equal present values for the same fixed infinite
money flow by discrete and continuous time discounting.
Next we calculate the present value of flow 4 (e=4week) in continuous
time. Time is first measured in units 4week and then in units week. The
present value of flow 4 (e=4week) is in the first case:
Z ˇtDt0 C1
tDt0 C1 ˇ 4 4
4er(tt0 ) dt D ˇˇ er(tt0 ) D er e0
tDt0 tDt0 r r
4
D 520 1 e 520 D 3:985 (e):
Z ˇtDt0 C4
tDt0 C4 ˇ 1 1
1er(tt0 ) dt D ˇˇ er(tt0 ) D e4r e0
tDt0 tDt0 r r
4
D 520 1 e 520 D 3:985 (e);
where the money flows R(t0 C it) (e=t) are assumed to be received at
the ending moment of every time unit, and the discrete time interest rates
are denoted by ri (1=t), i D 1; : : : ; n. The deviation of the interest rates
at different time units makes the discount factors as products of different
discount factors, and not as powers of factor 1=(1 C rt) (see Sect. 7.3.1).
A firm can finance its investment by its cash reserves, by issuing
equities, or by taking a loan. If a firm finances its investment by a loan, we
assume that the firm pays back the loan with a fixed payment in a time
unit that contains interest cost and part payment. The present value of
costs of one machine from n time units, that contains the possible costs
of a loan too, is
7 Capital Goods as Firms’ Inputs 309
where r (1=t) is the discount rate. In Sect. 7.4.1 we derived the sum of
the above geometric series with positive terms 0 < a D 1=(1Crt) < 1.
In the case of an infinite money flow, the present value Npv is:
a Nt Nt
Nt N
Npv D Nt D 1Crt1 D 1Crt
D D : (7.16)
1a 1 1Crt 1Crt1
1Crt
rt r
Notice that the measurement unit of the interest rate transforms the
measurement unit of the present value as: (e=t)=(1=t) D e.
Next we assume, for simplicity, that the machine lasts forever with its
maintenance costs that are included in user costs. We can then use the
sum of an infinite geometric series in the calculations, which simplifies
the analysis. The condition for profitability of the investment is then:
N
Npv > C0 , > C0 : (7.17)
r
The last form of this inequality shows how interest rate r affects the
investment decision. If N > 0, r ! 0 makes the investment surely
profitable because then the left hand side of the inequality increases
without limit while C0 is limited. If N < 0, the investment is never
profitable. The higher the interest rate, the smaller the left hand side of
the inequality (when N > 0), and thus the smaller the probability that
the investment is profitable.
7 Capital Goods as Firms’ Inputs 311
N
r< or N > rC0 :
C0
The former of these inequalities shows that the interest rate used in
discounting must be smaller than the rate of return of the investment—
the fixed net revenues from one time unit N (e=t) divided by the
invested capital C0 (e). The latter form of the inequality shows that the
net revenues at one time unit from one machine must exceed the interest
revenues that could be obtained for the invested capital C0 . In Sect. 7.4.2
we showed that the present value of a fixed infinite money flow is the same
in continuous and in discrete time discounting; thus these results hold in
continuous time too.
Example
A firm is planning to buy a machine that is estimated to be used 3 years
producing services of net value 4000 (e=y), and that can be sold after
three years at 10,000 (e). Suppose the firm uses interest rate 10 (%=y) in
its discounting. How much should the firm pay for this machine?
Answer. The discount factors for the three years were calculated in
Sect. 7.3.1. Assuming that the revenues are obtained at the ending moment
of every year, the present value of revenues from the machine is
and the present value of reselling the machine is 0:75 10000 D 7500 (e).
The firm should thus pay at most 9960 C 7500 D 17;460 (e) for the machine.
˘
Suppose a firm has two possible ways to increase its use of capital goods
(machines) at time moment t0 : (1) rent the machines at a fixed hourly rent,
or (2) buy the machines. The need of machine hours per time unit t is
assumed to be fixed B (h=t). The firm can rent these machines at z (e=h)
or buy them at price (value) C0 (e). We assume that the firm cannot
operate without these machines, and so renting or buying the machines is
312 Newtonian Microeconomics
compulsory. The reselling price of one machine is assumed zero, and the
user plus maintenance costs of one machine at time unit t are denoted
by a (e=t) (< zB (e=t)). With these costs, the rented and bought
machines can be used forever.
The managers of the firm are assumed to use a fixed interest rate
r (1=t) in their discounting. The renting costs of B (h=t) machine
hours from time unit t are zBt (e). By using the sum of an infinite
geometric series, the present value Vpv (e) of renting costs from an infinite
future is:
zBt zB
Vpv D D :
rt r
The present value of costs from buying one machine that produces the
required machine hours and using it an infinite time, Cpv (e), is similarly:
at a
Cpv D C0 C D C0 C :
rt r
a zB zB a
Cpv < Vpv , C0 C < , C0 < , rC0 < zB a:
r r r
positive, it is profitable for the firm to invest in these capital goods in the
case the firm plans to operate long enough. ˘
The capital stock of a firm is measured by the accumulation function
of investments of the firm, because investments increase the firm’s capital
stock. The accumulation of the capital stock of a firm can be analyzed as a
continuous process, even though in the real world additions in the capital
stock are made in a discrete way. This will be studied in the next section.
Note. Usually firms use their capital goods a finite time. In that case, a
similar analysis of investment decisions can be made as we have made here
by calculating present values of net revenues from a finite time. Examples
of this will be given in Sect. 8.2.6 and here we omit these cases. ˘
X
n
K(t) D I(t0 )t C I(t0 C t)t C C I(t0 C nt)t D I(t0 C it)t;
iD0
is that because these capital goods have been bought and paid for, there
is no reason to compare the past and present money by taking account of
possible interest returns that could have been obtained for the money that
has been used in buying these capital goods. On the other hand, we could
adjust the value of the capital stock of a firm by correcting the values of
old capital goods in terms of their wearing out and aging, or according to
their resale value. However, to simplify the analysis we do not make these
corrections, and we value the capital stock of a firm by the sum of its past
investments.
Next we transform time continuous by letting t ! 0. The value of
the capital stock of the firm at moment t D t0 Cnt can then be expressed
by the following definite integral (Sect. 10.14.2):
X
n Z t
K(t) D lim I(t0 C it)t D I(s)ds; (7.18)
t!0 t0
iD0
where running time ds during the year is measured in units y. The same
result can be obtained by using the weekly flow of investment as:
Z ˇ52
52
3000 ˇ 3000 3000
K(0; 52) D ds D ˇˇ sD (52 0) D 3000 (e):
0 52 0 52 52
X
m Z t
dKi
K(t) D Ki (t); Ki (t) D Ii (s)ds; D Ii (t);
iD1 t0 dt
where Ki (t) is the value of the capital stock of the firm of goods of type i
at moment t, and Ii (t) (e=y) the investment of the firm in type i capital
goods at moment t. If Ii (t) < 0, the firm decreases its capital stock of type
i goods at moment t by selling or scrapping the P machines. Investment
Pm
0
means an increase in capital stock, and K 0 (t) D m K
iD1 i (t) D iD1 Ii (t)
with unit e=y is the flow of the value of the capital stock, or the net
investment flow of the firm at time moment t. The capital stock of the
firm can be modeled as:
Thus the capital stock of the firm increases if the internal rate of return of
investing in capital goods is greater than discount rate r.
We linearize function fi in Eq. (7.19) in the neighborhood of point Fi D
0 by the Taylor series approximation, assume the error term zero, and omit
the subindex for shortness. The investment decision of the firm at time
moment t can then be modeled as
0 0 N 1
K (t) D f (0) r C FKS ; f 0 (0) D > 0; I(t) D K 0 (t); (7.20)
C0 mK
where FKS (1=y) is the static friction force of the capital stock, and
f 0 (0) D 1=mK a positive constant where mK with unit 1/e represents
the ‘inertial "mass" of the capital stock of the firm’. Static friction is
needed in the model to explain that the capital stock of the firm may not
always be changed when a non-zero force is acting upon it. The static
friction force contains all factors resisting changes in the capital stock not
included in the revenues and the costs of the machines. These factors are
added up to constant FKS the numerical value of which can be estimated
on the basis of observations.
The ‘free body’ diagram of the forces acting upon the capital stock
K is in Fig. 7.3, where the static friction force is omitted for simplicity.
The direction of motion on the right is defined positive, and on the left,
negative. The positive force component acting upon the capital stock
is N=C0 , and the negative force component is r. Quantity K(t) on the
horizontal axis measures the capital stock, and quantity mK with unit
y resists changes in the motion of the ‘particle’. Similarly, as described
earlier, the shape of the ‘particle’ has no economic meaning, and the
particle should be drawn as a point on coordinate axis K(t). However,
the box shape for the variable the capital stock of the firm visualizes better
the analogy we make here with Newtonian mechanics.
Fig. 7.3 Free body diagram of the forces acting upon the capital stock
318 Newtonian Microeconomics
The force acting upon the capital stock of the firm, FK D N=C0
r C FKS , has unit 1=y. Notice that Eq. (7.20) does not exactly correspond
to Newton’s equation F D ma, because K 0 (t) is velocity, and not
acceleration, of the capital stock. According to Eq. (7.20), the capital
stock increases (decreases) with time if force FK is positive (negative). An
increase in N positively, and increases in C0 and r negatively affect the
force. This investment behavior corresponds to the principle of modeling
in economics (see Sect. 1.2.4). In the case the active force component
N=C0 r exceeds the static friction force FKS , the following dynamic
equation and its solution result:
0 N 1 N
mK K (t) D r ) K(t) D K0 C r t; (7.21)
C0 mK C0
where K0 with unit e is the constant of integration. Thus the capital stock
increases linearly with time if CN0 > r, and the greater the mK the slower
this adjustment.
In Fig. 7.4 is annual capital formation in current prices of four macro
sectors in Finland: non-financial firms, financial firms, public sector, and
households. Non-financial firms have been the greatest investor of these
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
75
77
79
81
83
85
87
89
91
93
95
97
99
01
03
05
07
09
11
13
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
–5000
sectors in Finland, and financial firms the least. A positive time trend exists
in investment in all other sectors except financial firms, and a relatively
great variability exists in every sector. Thus to get the model for firms’
investment behavior in Eq. (7.21) to correspond more accurately with
observed cyclical behavior as in Fig. 7.4, a more detailed force should be
created acting upon the capital input of a firm. The observed fluctuations
in investments originate either from changes in interest rate or from
changes in expected net revenues from firms’ investments. These elements
can be added in Eq. (7.21) by modeling the expected net revenues in a
more detailed way.
References
Chiang, A. C. (1984). Fundamental methods of mathematical economics (3rd ed.)
Singapore: McGraw-Hill International Editions.
Hull, J. C. (2000). Options, futures, & other derivatives (4th ed.). USA: Prentice-
Hall International, Inc.
8
Money and Financial Markets
Precious metals fulfilled these criteria better than, for instance, furs
and corn, and this explains their gained popularity with time. The
transportation, storing, and division of precious metals was not easy,
however. Gradually people realized that they did not have to carry precious
metals (money) with them. Rather, they could store (deposit) the metals
in the vaults of goldsmiths, for example, who had safe places for their
raw materials. Goldsmiths gave receipts for these deposits, in the form of
documents stating the amount of precious metals a person had stored in
the vault, and people started to use these receipts, which were guaranteed
by the goldsmiths, as means of payments. These were the predecessors of
modern paper money, which gradually started to take over from precious
metals as the medium of exchange.
When the exchanges of goods increased in Europe in the beginning of
seventeenth century, the payment system was centered in trading houses
called Giro banks. Giro banks accepted precious metals as deposits, coins
were struck from these metals, and receipts for these ‘deposits’ were given
to the ‘depositors’. These receipts–the first banknotes– were then used as
means of payments of goods. Giro banks were predecessors of the modern
central banks that have the exclusive right to issue paper money. By the
eighteenth century, in some countries alongside precious metals money,
banknotes were also in circulation with a limited use; they were accepted
only locally. Gradually, public authorities gave itself the uniform right to
issue money, and this way money started to lose its meaning as a good. In
Finland, the Bank of Finland has had the exclusive right to issue money
since 1886.
In a precious metals-based money system, banknotes are so-called
representative money. The issuer of the banknote (has written the receipt
for the depositor of gold or silver), has promised to give the precious metal
to the holder of the receipt (note) at full value. In this way banknotes
represented the amount of gold or silver stored in an organization, which
thereafter began to be called banks. As mentioned earlier, the first such
organizations were goldsmiths who needed the metals as raw material for
their products. Later on some goldsmiths started to concentrate on the
deposit business, and they were the predecessors of modern banks. The
advantage of banknotes as compared with precious metals was that the
8 Money and Financial Markets 323
‘deposited’ gold or silver did not need to be transported from one person
to another; only the owner of the receipt changed in the exchange, and
precious metals stayed safely on the ‘bank account’.
The next innovation in the means of payments came in the form of a
check.
§: A check is a request to pay its holder a written amount of money
from the checking account of the writer of the check. ˘
The advantage of checks as compared with banknotes is that there is less
need to hold cash money. This decreases the risk of losing money or being
robbed. The newest forms of medium of exchange are bank and credit
cards that work like checks. Their advantages as compared with checks are
lower transaction costs and more smooth functioning. The disadvantage
of bank and credit cards is the uncertainty about the payer’s ability to pay.
Various banks have guaranteed the payments by their bank cards up to a
limit because banks can judge the credibility of their clients.
The last innovation in the means of payments is a computer-based
payment system that charges the payer’s bank account by the amount of
the payment, and transfers the money to the receiver’s account. No cash is
needed, and time will tell as to how much cash money will eventually be
needed in the future, after most people begin to use electronic methods
of making payments.
In a gold standard paper money system, the issuer of the paper money
is responsible for holding the required gold reserves that secure the gold
value of the paper money. In the beginning of twentieth century, the
world’s monetary system was secured by the gold reserves of central banks.
The gold reserves in central banks equated to the total value of banknotes
(paper money) in circulation. Gradually, central bankers realized that
they could issue more banknotes than they had gold reserves, because
the probability that all people would simultaneously come to redeem
their gold was low. In this way, the fractional reserve banking principle
was developed, where banks keep only a fraction of their deposits in
reserve.
324 Newtonian Microeconomics
monetary union. The more goods are produced, the more money can be
issued to buy these goods. An excess supply of money over real production
causes excess demand for goods, which causes either price inflation or a
stock market bubble.
We can remark here that before money was invented, goods were
exchanged with each other, and the ‘amount of money in circulation’
was equal to the amount of exchangeable goods. A modern paper money
system more closely resembles the exchange system of goods where every
produced good increases the monetary base (see the next section) than
the gold-based paper money system. This is reasonable because a limited
amount of gold exists in the Earth, and the aggregate flow of production
of goods in the world has no upper limit. Thus, there is no sense in tying
the monetary base of a growing economic system to a fixed quantity.
In the 1870s, William Stanley Jevons (1970) presented three main func-
tions of money as: (1) A means of making payments, (2) A measure of
monetary values of goods, and (3) A liquid form of wealth. By ’liquid
wealth’ we understand such forms of wealth that can easily and quickly be
transformed to cash money. In addition to these functions, Jevons defined
another: A measure for the amount of savings and debts. Later, this fourth
function of money was seen as a part of a measure of values. We can thus
state the second function as: A measure of the values of goods, future
payments, and savings and debts. However, we can still define the fourth
function of money as: (4) The final amortization of a debt. People can
amortize their debts by other debts, but only by paying with cash money
can a loan finally be amortized.
The concepts of money and a monetary economy can be defined on
the basis of the functions of money.
§: We call money, or legal tender, the legal medium of exchange that
every participant in the economy is obligated to accept. ˘
§: Essentially, two forms of legal tender exists: Principal money (notes)
and exchange money (coins). Everyone has to accept principal money as
the medium of exchange, but exchange money needs to be accepted only
8 Money and Financial Markets 327
Example 1
It is common for customers to request shopkeepers’ permission to pay for
their purchases with large amounts of coins, because legally shopkeepers
do not have to accept this. However, those shopkeepers who like to keep
their customers usually agree to this request. ˘
Example 2
Bank and credit cards are not accepted by all shops, and so they have a
limited use in the medium of exchange ˘
DIRECT FINANCE
Financial intermediaries
Funds Funds
-Credit institutions
-Other financial institutions
INDIRECT FINANCE
issuing liabilities in the form of various types of deposits, and earns money
by making loans of these funds or by investing them. For example, a bank
can give loans to firms and households or buy government or corporate
bonds (see Sect. 8.2.3). This way funds are transferred from lenders–
savers to borrower-spenders with the help of a financial intermediary (the
bank). By charging a higher interest rate for its loans than it pays for its
deposits (the interest differential), a financial intermediary earns money.
Financial intermediaries improve the efficiency of financial markets
in the following ways:
1. Small savings can gain a higher interest rate as a part of a large loan.
2. Small firms, for which it would be impossible to get funds in the form
of direct finance, can get relatively large loans from banks.
3. Financial intermediaries reduce information costs. It would be very
expensive for lenders to identify all potential borrowers, and for bor-
rowers to identify all potential lenders.
4. Once a lender finds a potential borrower, he/she/it has to consider the
probability that the borrower will default (see the definition later).
Financial intermediaries, on the other hand, have regular information
on the financial situation of their clients through their bank accounts.
This gives them superior information of the risks of their clients as
compared with other lenders.
5. Financial intermediaries reduce transaction costs as compared with the
situation that every lender and borrower writes a loan contract, or pays
a brokerage commission for the transaction. Smaller transaction costs
related to one large loan as compared with many small loans creates
economies of scale in the lending business (lower unit costs at a larger
scale of operation).
6. Financial intermediaries can create scale and maturity transformations
between financial agreements. For example, from a continuous inflow
of small short-term deposits from various sources with different interest
rates, a bank can issue large long-term loans with a fixed interest rate.
7. The expertise and education of the personnel in banks allows them to
make better investment decisions as compared with many small savers
with less information. Investing large sums of money, though, may
create large losses in a case where banks make bad investment decisions.
332 Newtonian Microeconomics
The distinction between money and capital markets is made on the basis
of the maturity of securities traded in the markets. In practice, specific
market places do not exist for these markets, and the securities traded in
both markets are often sold by the same financial intermediaries.
§: The maturity of a debt instrument is the length of the time (term)
to the instrument’s expiration date. ˘
§: The money market is the financial market where short-term debt
instruments (maturity less than one year) are traded. The capital market
is the market where long-term debt and equity instruments (maturity over
a year) are traded. ˘
§: An equity is a financial instrument that gives its holder a specified
ownership concerning the underlying matter. For example, shares of
common stocks of corporations are equities. ˘
discount, that is, at a lower price than the principal value. T-bills are the
most liquid asset in the money market with the minimum possible risk
of default, because they are issued by governments and actively traded
every weekday.
3. A commercial paper is a short-term debt instrument issued by large
banks and well-known corporations.
4. A banker’s acceptance is a bank draft (a promise of payment) issued
by a firm payable at some future date, and guaranteed by the bank who
stamps it as ‘accepted’. The firm issuing a banker’s acceptance deposits
the required funds in its bank account at the date of maturity to cover
the draft. If the firm fails to do this, the bank’s guarantee obligates
the bank to cover the draft. These ‘accepted’ drafts can be resold in
secondary markets (see the next section) at discount similarly to T-bills.
5. A Repurchase agreement (RP) is an agreement to buy securities on the
understanding that they will be repurchased at some specified time and
price in the future. In this deal, the seller corresponds to the borrower
and the buyer the lender.
6. An Interbank deposit is a loan between banks ranging from one day
to one year. This market is highly sensitive to the credit needs of banks,
and the interest rate on these loans is a closely watched barometer of
the tightness of the credit market. In the euro area, this interest rate is
called the euribor and in the USA the federal funds rate.
Usually, no secondary market (see the next section) exists for loans, and
so they are the least liquid of all capital market instruments. However, in
some countries banks are allowed to securitize the loans they have issued
by grouping them in a pool, and selling equities as shares of ownership of
these pooled loans in secondary markets. Thus bank loans can be resold
in secondary markets after being securitized in similar debt instruments
to bonds.
We studied direct and indirect finance in Sects. 8.2.1 and 8.2.2. In direct
finance, organizations raise funds from financial markets by issuing bonds
or equities that are claims on the net income and assets of the issuers.
If you own one share of the common stock of a corporation that has
issued a hundred shares, you have a claim on 1% of future net income
and assets of the firm. Equities give their holders annual payments called
dividends, while bonds give their holders annual or semi-annual (twice-a-
year) coupon payments and pay back the principal at the date of maturity.
Thus bonds have a fixed maturity while equities have no maturity. Equities
can, though, be resold in secondary markets.
An organization can raise either own (capital with ownership rights) or
foreign capital (debts) from financial markets. For example, equities are
‘own’ and bonds and loans are ‘foreign’ capital. The main disadvantage of
holding a corporation’s equities rather than its debt instruments is that an
equity holder is a residual claimant; that is, the corporation must fulfill its
obligations to its debt holders before its equity holders. On the other hand,
8 Money and Financial Markets 335
the advantage of holding equities is that equity holders benefit from the
increased profitability of a corporation and its asset value, since equities
confer ownership rights to their holders. The debt holders of a firm do not
benefit from firm’s increased profitability, because the payments on loans
are not affected by the firm’s profitability. However, the risks of holding
equities are greater than those of debt instruments issued by a firm. These
questions are studied further in Sect. 8.2.6.
§: The Primary market is the market where the issuing of new
securities, such as bonds and equities, takes place. ˘
§: The Secondary market is the market where previously issued
securities are resold. ˘
The primary markets of securities are not well known to the public
because the issuing of new securities takes place behind closed doors.
The issuing of new securities usually takes place as follows. A financial
firm buys a given amount of new securities (shares, bonds, etc.) from
the issuing organization in the primary market at an agreed price. In this
case, we call the financial company a dealer because just like with playing
cards, someone must deal the cards (securities) to the players before the
game can start. The dealer resells the securities in the secondary market
at the price determined there by the demand and supply of the securities.
Investors buy and sell securities in the secondary market like card players
who try to change ‘bad’ cards to ‘better’ ones in order to win the game. The
dealer must thus estimate the price at which the securities can be resold
in secondary markets, which secondary market will be applied and when
the emission is profitable to be done. If the average price index of a stock
market is decreasing, and no demand exists for new securities, there is no
sense in issuing new securities in that market, and vice versa. Nowadays,
it is common for big corporations to issue their equities and bonds in
secondary markets in various countries, depending on the situation in
these markets.
When someone buys a security in a secondary market, the person who
sells the security receives the money in exchange for the security, but
the corporation that has originally issued the security receives no funds.
The issuing corporation receives funds only when it issues new securities
in a primary market. The New York and Helsinki Stock Exchanges are
336 Newtonian Microeconomics
Consols
The pricing formula for a consol, or its equilibrium price (value), is given
in Eq. (8.1). The price of a consol is determined in the market according
to the fixed flow of payments N (e/t) it offers and the prevailing
interest rate; the greater the former and the lower the latter, the greater the
338 Newtonian Microeconomics
equilibrium price of a consol. Consols were sold for the time by British
Treasury during the Napoleonic Wars, and are still traded today.
Equation (8.1) can also be written as
N
rd D or N D rd P(t0 ):
P(t0 )
The former of these equations shows that the discount rate applied equals
the rate of return of the consol—the fixed money flow N (e=t) divided
by the invested capital P(t0 ) (e). The latter equation shows that the
revenues from a consol are equal to the interest revenues to be obtained
for capital P(t0 ) (e) at time unit t. At the equilibrium price of a consol
P(t0 ) (e), investing in consols is as profitable as investing with a risk-free
interest rate; thus at price P(t0 ), risk-free arbitrage is impossible.
the internal rate of return of a treasury bill that does not explicitly pay
interest returns. Due to this, T-bills are also called zero-coupon bonds.
Now, the present value of payment 110 (e) after one year with interest
rate 10 (%=y) is:
If, however, interest rate increases from 10 (%=y) to 12 (%=y), the present
value of the repayment of the loan decreases to
and if the interest rate decreases to 5 (%=y), the present value increases to
These examples show that the present value of a fixed payment asset
decreases when the interest rate in the economy increases, and vice versa.
Thus an interest rate risk exists in a fixed payment asset although no
risk exists in monetary payments of such assets. This holds for all fixed
payment securities like T-bills, bonds, and consols.
Note. If we know the current price and the future payments of a security,
we can calculate its rate of return. We call this the internal rate of return
of the financial asset. On the other hand, if we know the future payments
of an asset, and we have an estimate of the future interest rate in the
economy, we can calculate the expected present value of this asset. Thus
we call the interest rate that is used in discounting either the expected
future interest rate in the economy—when we calculate present values—
or the internal rate of return of a security—when we solve the unknown
rate of return of a security. ˘
340 Newtonian Microeconomics
N Z
P(t0 ) D Œ1 (1 C rd t)n C : (8.4)
rd (1 C rd t)n
The pricing formula in Eq. (8.4) is obtained from Eq. (8.3) by adding
to it the present value of repayment of the principal denoted by Z (e).
Similarly, as in the previous case, an interest rate risk exists in this asset.
Next we test numerically how the pricing formula in Eq. (8.4) works.
Example 1
Suppose the principal is Z D 100 (e), the bond offers 5 (%/y) coupon rate,
that is, N D 0:05 (1=y) 100 (e) D 5 (e=y), and the interest rate in the
economy is rd D 0:05 (1=y). Then the present value P(t0 ) with different values
of n, n D 0; 1; 2; 3; : : : , is always P(t0 ) D 100 (e). ˘
Example 1 shows that if the coupon rate of a bond equals the prevailing
interest rate in the economy, the price of the bond, that eliminates the
risk-free arbitrage possibility, is equal to its principal value. This result
does not depend on the term to maturity of the bond.
8 Money and Financial Markets 341
Example 2
Suppose Z D 100 (e), N D 0:1 (1=y) 100 (e) D 10 (e=y) and rd D 0:05 (1=y).
Then if n D 1, P(t0 ) D 104:8 (e), and if n D 10, P(t0 ) D 138:6 (e). ˘
Example 3
Suppose Z D 100 (e), N D 5 (e=y) and rd D 0:1 (1=y). Then if n D 1, P(t0 ) D
95:5 (e), and if n D 10, P(t0 ) D 69:3 (e). ˘
The pricing formula for one share of the common stock of a corporation
equals with that in Eq. (8.4), but in this case n denotes the investor’s
investment horizon (the length of time the investor plans to hold the
share), Z the price (value) at which the investor believes he can sell the
share at the ending moment of his investment period, and N the investor’s
estimate of dividends for one share at every time unit t during the time
the investor holds the share. This current value is based on the investor’s
expectation of future share price, dividends, and interest rate. Thus there
exists a risk in quantities N, rd , and Z, but P(t0 ) and n are known by the
investor at the initial moment. The risks in holding an equity then consist
of different factors than those in holding a bond.
An investor makes his decision whether to invest in the shares of a
corporation on the basis of the internal rate of return rd he expects to
342 Newtonian Microeconomics
gain from one share. He can calculate this by putting in formula (8.4)
his expectations of quantities N and Z, the known values of P(t0 ) and n,
and solving the equation numerically with respect to rd . In the decision-
making, the investor must still consider the risks in this decision. This
can be made, for example, by calculating the internal rate of return with
different estimates for the unknown quantities.
N Z
P(t) D Œ1 (1 C rd t)n C : (8.5)
rd (1 C rd t)n
Ni Zi
FiS (t) D Œ1 (1 C rdi t)ni C P(t); (8.6)
rdi (1 C rdi t)ni
Dij (t) D fij (Fij (t)) fij0 (Fij ) > 0; fij0 (0) D 0; j D S; B; C; T: (8.8)
We create here a simple model for the dynamics of an asset price. For this,
all investors are separated in three classes: those who are willing to buy
the studied asset, those who are willing to sell them, and those who are
not interested in this asset. The third class of investors does not affect the
price of the asset, and thus their behavior is not modeled. In this one-
period setting, one investor can belong in only one of the three classes. In
the real life, these one-period settings repeat, and investors may change in
between these classes. We assume that the asset is the share of the common
stock of a corporation, but a similar model can be created for all other
assets too. For all investors i D 1; : : : ; m willing to buy these shares, the
following holds:
N Zi
FiS (t) D Œ1 (1 C rdi t)ni C P(t) > 0:
rdi (1 C rdi t)ni
346 Newtonian Microeconomics
Thus every investor willing to buy these shares must value the share higher
than its current price. Adding the terms FiS over the m investors and
dividing by m, we get
m
1 X Ni ni Zi
Fd (t) D Œ1 (1 C rdi t) C P(t): (8.11)
m iD1 rdi (1 C rdi t)ni
Thus every investor willing to sell these shares must value the shares lower
than their current price. Adding the terms FjS over the n investors and
dividing by n, we get
8 Money and Financial Markets 347
n
1 X Nj nj Zj
Fs (t) D P(t) Œ1 (1 C rdj t) C : (8.14)
n jD1 rdj (1 C rdj t)nj
Price Determination
who really like to sell these assets must accept buying offers at a lower
price, and thus asset price decreases. The equation of motion for the asset
price is then
The ‘free body’ diagram of the forces acting upon the demand and
the supply of the shares is in Fig. 8.2. The direction of motion on the
Fig. 8.2 Forces acting upon the demand, supply, and price of an asset
8 Money and Financial Markets 349
30
25
20
P(t)
15
10
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
time
Solving Eqs. (8.18) and (8.19) with respect to D(t) and S(t), respectively,
and substituting these in Eq. (8.20), we get it in the following form:
1 0 1 1
P (t) D .Hd P(t)/ .P(t) Hs / ; (8.21)
kP md ms
where P0 (t) (e=t)) is the flow of the share price. The equilibrium share
price can be solved from Eq. (8.21) by setting P0 (t) D 0:
ms Hd C md Hs
P D : (8.22)
md C ms
see Fig. 3.9. In the Appendix of this chapter, Hd (Ni ; Zi ; rdi ; ni ) is approx-
imated as:
a0 a1 a2 a3 a4
Hd (N d ; Z d ; rdd ; nd ) C N d C Z d C rdd C nd ; (8.23)
m m m m m
8 Money and Financial Markets 351
b0 b1 b2 b3 b4
Hs (N s ; Z s ; rds ; ns ) C N s C Z s C rds C ns ; (8.24)
n n n n n
3500
3250
3000
2750
2500
2250
2000
1750 © Kauppalehti
7/11 1/12 7/12 1/13 7/13 1/14 7/14 1/15 7/15 1/16
OMX Helsinki 25
Fig. 8.4 presents the OMX Helsinki 25 stock price index that measures
the average stock price of 25 Finnish corporations. The index behaves
like all stock prices; there is sometimes positive and sometimes negative
trend, and the index fluctuates around its trend. Thus to get model
(8.21) accurately mimicking observed stock price behavior, quantities
Hd ; Hs should be modeled more exactly. Model (8.21) explains how the
asset price reaches its equilibrium value with fixed Hd ; Hs . In real life,
however, investors receive every day and every hour new information
about firms’ future revenues and costs, and this information changes their
expectations. These changes in expectations affect the investors’ buying
and selling behavior, as Eqs. (8.18), (8.19) describe.
A commonly used stock price model is the random walk (RW) model,
see, for example, Fama (1965). An example of an RW process is presented
in Fig. 8.5 where the graph is created as
Fig. 8.5 The time path of a random walk process for 150 time units
140
120
100
80
60
0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140
Fig. 8.6 The time path of a random walk process for 150 time units
specific stock price models in a detailed way, but we show that the RW
model can be obtained as a special case of model (8.21).
The complete model in Eq. (8.21) with Hd ; Hs as in Eqs. (8.23), (8.24),
respectively, shows how different factors affect the share price. In order to
show how the RW process is obtained as a special case of Eq. (8.21), we
make the following assumptions. First, the average time unit of investors
is assumed to be very short, because only investors that are active in stock
market actually affect stock prices. Usually corporations pay dividends
annually, and thus short term investors—that plan to hold the shares they
buy for a few days or hours—do not earn dividends. Thus we can set Nk D
0 8k, k D i; j, and we can also omit the discount factor 1=(1 C rdk t)nk ,
k D i; j from Eqs. (8.12) and (8.15) when nk is less than a week. Then we
get from Eqs. (8.12) and (8.15):
1X 1X
m n
Hd Zi D Z d ; Hs Zj D Z s :
m iD1 n jD1
8 Money and Financial Markets 355
Next we assume that investors willing to buy the shares expect the share
price to increase from that of current price, and those willing to sell these
shares expect the share price to decrease from that of current price. Thus
we set Hd D P(t) C d and Hs D P(t) s , where k , k D d; s are
random variables with unit e with positive mean and constant variance.
In the RW process time is discrete, and assuming this we transform the
velocity of share price as
where symbol 1 in the denominator is not pure number but one unit of
time, and P is the change in the price during the time unit. In order
to avoid errors in measurement units of the quantities, we keep in the
following t instead of 1 in denoting the time unit. Then we get the
discrete time version of Eq. (8.21) as follows:
1 P 1 1
D ŒHd P(t) ŒP(t) Hs ,
kP t md ms
1 P(t C 1) P(t) 1 1
D ŒP(t) C d P(t) ŒP(t) (P(t) s ) ,
kP t md ms
1 P(t C 1) P(t) d s
D ,
kP t md ms
d s
P(t C 1) P(t) D tkP ,
md ms
d s
P(t C 1) D P(t) C P ; P D tkP ;
md ms
Ni Zi
Hi (Ni ; Zi ; rdi ; ni ) Œ1 (1 C rdi t)ni C (8.26)
rdi (1 C rdi t)ni
in the neighborhood of point xi0 D (Ni0 ; Zi0 ; rdi0 ; ni0 ) by taking the
Taylor series approximation as:
X
m
Hi (Ni ; Zi ; rdi ; ni ) a0 C a1 N C a2 Z C a3 rd C a4 n; (8.28)
iD1
Pm
where x D (1=m) iD1 xi is the arithmetic average of x D N; Z; rd ; n,
and:
m
X @Hi (xi0 ) @Hi (xi0 ) @Hi (xi0 )
a0 D Hi (xi0 ) Ni0 Zi0 rdi0
iD1
@Ni @Zi @rdi
Xm Xm
@Hi (xi0 ) @Hi (xi0 ) @Hi (xi0 )
ni0 ; a1 D ; a2 D ;
@ni iD1
@Ni iD1
@Zi
X
m
@Hi (xi0 ) X
m
@Hi (xi0 )
a3 D ; a4 D :
iD1
@rdi iD1
@ni
every asset gives some revenues in the future and thus has a positive present
value. Thus a0 > 0 (let Ni ; Zi ; rdi ; ni ; i ! 0 8i in Eq. (8.27)). In
Sect. 8.2.7 we showed that @Hi =@Ni > 0, @Hi =@Zi > 0, and @Hi =@rdi ,
@Hi =@ni are ambiguous; thus a1 > 0, a2 > 0 and the signs of a3 ; a4 are
ambiguous.
Dividing both sides of Eq. (8.28) by m, we get an approximation for
the average value of Hi , i D 1; : : : ; m as:
1X
m
a0 a1 a2 a3 a4
Hi (Ni ; Zi ; rdi ; ni ) C N C Z C rd C n: (8.29)
m iD1 m m m m m
By taking the same steps we can derive the following approximation for
the average value of Hj , j D 1; : : : ; n as:
1X
n
b0 b1 b2 b3 b4
Hj (Nj ; Zj ; rdj ; nj ) C N C Z C rd C n: (8.30)
n jD1 n n n n n
References
Fama, E. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work.
Journal of Finance, 25, 383–417.
Fama, E. F. (1965). Random walks in stock market prices. Financial Analysts
Journal, September–October, pp. 55–59.
Friedman, M. (1968). The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review,
March, pp. 1–17.
Hull, J. C. (2000). Options, futures, and other derivatives (4th ed.). Upper Saddle
River, NJ: Prentice-Hall International, Inc.
Jevons, W. S. (1970). Theory of political economy (2nd ed.), Original publication
at 1879. Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Mishkin, F. S. (2001). The economics of money, banking, and financial markets
(6th ed.) Reading, MA: Addison Wesley.
9
Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates
1
By a household we understand a decision-making unit that may consist of a family with a unique
utility function, or of only one person.
The average price levels are assumed fixed and known by every household
at the first period when they make their consumption/saving decision. At
the first period, households may consume their income exactly, or more or
less, depending on whether they act as borrowers or depositors in the loan
market. Every household belongs in one of the following three groups: net
savers, net borrowers, or those whose net saving is zero. The behavior of
the last group is not modeled, however, because these households do not
affect the interest rate. The saving and borrowing households are grouped
into two groups that are studied separately. In this two-period setting,
one household can belong in only one of these three groups. In the real
life, these two-period settings repeat and households may change between
these groups.
for the two time units. The income and consumption of the household
with units e=t and kg=t, respectively, are denoted by Tic ; Xic at period
c D 0; 1. In the following we assume t D 1 (y), and then the deposit
rate denoted by rs has unit 1=y. On the left-hand side of the first form
of the equation are the present values of income at the two time units
discounted by the savings rate rs , and on the right hand side are the present
values of consumption expenditures at both periods. The explanation for
the discount rate is that a saving household compares present and future
consumption on the basis of the deposit rate that defines the interest
returns from savings. On the left-hand side of the second form of the
equation are the savings from the first period Si D Ti0 p0 Xi0 > 0,
and on the right hand side the present value of excess consumption over
income at the latter period, p1 Xi1 Ti1 > 0. Subindex 0 is omitted from
savings because households can save only in the first period.
9 Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates 361
where on the left-hand side are the savings and interest returns on these
savings from the first period, and on the right-hand side is the excess
consumption expenditures in the latter period. All these three forms of
the equation express the same thing. In a two-period setting with fixed
incomes, prices, and deposit rate, the consumption decision at the first
period Xi0 exactly defines the savings Si and the consumption at the latter
period Xi1 . We can thus define the consumptions at both periods by
savings Si . Defining the savings of household i as we did above, we can
write:
Ti0 Si
Si D Ti0 p0 Xi0 , Xi0 D :
p0
By using the budget equation, the consumption at the latter period can
be expressed in terms of savings as
(1 C rs t)Si C Ti1
(1 C rs t)Si D p1 Xi1 Ti1 , Xi1 D :
p1
The satisfaction household i gains during the two time units is measured
by utility function ui with unit ut=(2y). Function ui is assumed continu-
ous and differentiable:
@ui @ui @2 ui @2 ui
ui D ui .Xi0 ; Xi1 /; > 0; > 0; 0; 0;
@Xi0 @Xi1 @Xi0
2
@Xi1
2
@2 ui @2 ui
D > 0:
@Xi1 @Xi0 @Xi0 @Xi1
consumption p0 Œ(Ti0 =p0 ) Xi0 equals with optimal savings Si . In the
optimum, the slopes of the budget equation and indifference curve are
equal,
@ui
p0 @Xi0
(1 C rs t) D @ui
; (9.4)
p1 @Xi1
where the minus sign is cancelled from both sides of the equation.
If household i is consuming too much at current period, the situation
corresponds to point (Xi0A ; Xi1A ) in Fig. 9.3, where the slope of the budget
equation is steeper than that of the indifference curve. Thus it holds
364 Newtonian Microeconomics
@ui
p0 @Xi0 @ui 1 @ui 1
(1 C rs t) > @ui
, (1 C rs t) >
p1 @Xi1
@Xi1 p1 @Xi0 p0
@ui 1 @ui 1
!
@Xi0 p0 1 @Xi0 p0
, 1 C rs t > @ui
, rs > @ui 1
1 : (9.5)
@Xi1
1
p1
t @X p i1 1
@ui 1 @ui 1
; ;
@Xi0 p0 @Xi1 p1
with unit ut/e measure the household’s marginal utilities from consump-
tion at the two time units by one euro. If the household decides to save
one euro, the gain from this is the interest returns to be obtained for one
euro by which the household can increase its future consumption. The
loss from this is the lost consumption at current period by one euro. Thus
on the left-hand side of the second form of Eq. (9.5) is the received gain
in future utility by increased consumption with one euro plus interest
returns rs t on one euro, and on the right-hand side is the required loss in
current utility due to decreasing current consumption by one euro. Thus
in situation (Xi0A ; Xi1A ), the household would gain from saving more and
changing current consumption to future. The rate of loss in utility due to
passing consumption to future is
!
@ui 1 @ui 1
@Xi0 p0
@Xi1 p1
=t 1
@ui 1
@Xi0 p0
1 @ui
D @ui
1 :
p1 @Xi1
t @Xi1
1
p1
@ ui p1
2
@ ui 2
@ ui 2
dSi @ui p 0 @2 u i @2 u i
p t C S t (1 C r t)
@Xi1 0 i s p1 @Xi1
2 @Xi1 @Xi0
The numerator of this partial is positive and the sign of the denominator is
ambiguous. However, assuming that the savings of household i are small,
that is, Si 0, then the denominator and also the derivative are positive.
Thus with small savings the supply function of savings of household i,
that corresponds to the equilibrium state of the household, is increasing
in the coordinate system (Si ; rs ); see Fig. 9.4. In the dotted part of the
curve, drs =dSi < 0.
In order to model the dynamics of savings of household i, we assume
that savings Si (t) depend on time t with unit y. This makes the household’s
consumption at the two time units time-dependent too, Xi0 (t); Xi1 (t), and
the other defined quantities are assumed fixed. We can then write the
utility function of household i as a function of its savings Si (t) (e=y) as:
Ti0 Si (t) (1 C rs t)Si (t) C Ti1
ui (t) D ui .Xi0 (t); Xi1 (t)/ D ui ; :
p0 p1
(9.6)
366 Newtonian Microeconomics
According to Eq. (9.6), household i has only one variable by which it can
affect its utility, namely Si (t). The time derivative of the utility function,
or the acceleration of utility u0i (t) with unit ut=(4y2 ), is then2 :
@ui 1 @ui (1 C rs t) 0
u0i (t) D C Si (t): (9.7)
@Xi0 p0 @Xi1 p1
For the utility to increase with time, both factors in the product on the
right-hand side of Eq. (9.7) must be of equal sign. Household i likes to
increase its utility with time, namely, to get u0i (t) > 0, and so it changes
its saving to:
2
Unit ut=4y2 D ut=(2y 2y) results from dividing the measurement unit of the flow of utility
ut=2y by time unit 2y.
9 Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates 367
with unit 1=t as the ‘force acting upon saving of household i’, because
it is the cause for the household’s acceleration of saving. Household i
decreases its consumption at first period if rs > zi , and vice versa, and
the utility maximizing situation corresponds to zero force: rs D zi .
368 Newtonian Microeconomics
@2 ui @ui
@X@i0 @X @ui
ui 2
@zi 2 @Xi1
@Xi0 i1 @Xi0
D 2 < 0;
@Ti0 p20 t @ui
p1 @Xi1
@2 ui @ui @2 ui @ui
@zi @Xi1 @Xi0 @Xi1
2 @Xi0
@Xi1
D 2 > 0;
@Ti1 @ui
p0 t @Xi1
2
@ ui @ui @ ui @ui 2
@zi
1
p0 @Xi0 @Xi1 @Xi0
@X 2 @Xi1
D 2
i0
@Si p0 t @ui
p1 @Xi1
(1Crs t) @2 ui @ui @2 ui @ui
p1 @Xi1 @Xi0 @Xi1
2 @Xi0
@Xi1
C 2 > 0;
p0 t @ui
p1 @Xi1
@2 ui @ui @2 ui @ui
@zi @Xi1 @Xi0 @Xi1
2 @Xi0
@Xi1
D 2 > 0;
@rs p0 @ui
Si @Xi1
These results are based on the utility function in Eq. (9.6), and we can
interpret them as follows. An increase in zi means that the household
prefers current consumption more, which decreases its saving. Increases in
p0 ; p1 change the relative prices of current and future consumption, and
their effects on saving are ambiguous. An increase in Ti0 decreases zi and
thus increases the saving of household i, and an increase in Ti1 decreases
the saving of household i. Result @zi =@Si > 0 implies that the adjustment
9 Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates 369
where Fi is the force acting upon the saving of household i. The acceler-
ation of saving Si0 (t) is positive if Fi is positive, and vice versa. Taking the
first order Taylor series approximation of function G in Eq. (9.8) in the
neighborhood of point Fi D 0, and assuming the error term zero, we get:
Now, denoting 1=G0 (0) D mi , we can call Eq. (9.9) the ‘Newtonian
equation of savings of household i’. The name comes from the analo-
gous form of Eq. (9.9) with Newton’s equation ma D F, and constant
mi > 0 with unit y/e represents the inertial factors (‘mass’) in this
adjustment.
The ‘free body’ diagram of the forces acting upon the saving of
household i is in Fig. 9.5. The positive force component acting upon
saving is rs and the negative force component is zi .
where the income and consumption of the household at the two periods
with units e=t and kg=t, respectively, are denoted by Tjc , Xjc , c D
0; 1, and t D 1 (y). On the left-hand side of Eq. (9.10) is the loan the
household takes at the first period Bj D p0 Xj0 Tj0 > 0 and its interest
costs, and this equals with the savings of the household at the latter period
Tj1 p1 Xj1 > 0. Equation (9.10) can also be written as
p1 Xj1 Tj1
p0 Xj0 C D Tj0 C ;
1 C rb t 1 C rb t
Bj C Tj0
Bj D p0 Xj0 Tj0 , Xj0 D ; (9.11)
p0
Tj1 (1 C rb t)Bj
(1 C rb t)Bj D Tj1 p1 Xj1 , Xj1 D : (9.12)
p1
9 Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates 371
@uj @uj @2 uj @2 uj
uj D uj .Xj0 ; Xj1 /; > 0; > 0; 0; 0;
@Xj0 @Xj1 @Xj0
2
@Xj1
2
@2 uj @2 uj
D > 0:
@Xj1 @Xj0 @Xj0 @Xj1
The assumptions of the utility function are equal as for saving households.
The budget equation of household j in Fig. 9.6 shows the consumption
bundles the household can choose at the two periods. An indifference
curve for a borrowing household is defined analogously as for a saving
household. The shape of the indifference curve results from our assump-
tions of the utility function. In the coordinate system (Xj0 ; Xj1 ), the slopes
of the budget line and an indifference curve are:
@uj
dXj1 p0 dXj1 @Xj0
D (1 C rb t) < 0 and D @u < 0:
dXj0 p1 dXj0 j
@Xj1
Thus both are decreasing, and the higher the rb the steeper the budget
line.
kg
y
(1 + rb Dt )T j 0 + T j1
p1
(1 + rb Dt )( p0 X j 0 – T j 0 ) = T j1 – p1 X j1
æ T j1 æ 1
çT j 0 + ç kg y
è 1 + rb Dt è p0
kg
y
(1 + rb Δt )( p 0 X j 0 – T j 0 ) = T j1 – p1 X j1
T j1
p1
X *j1 u j ( X j 0 , X j1 ) = u j 0
T j 0 / p0 X *j 0 kg y
The optimal consumption bundle (Xj0 ; Xj1 ) and optimal borrowing
Bj of household j are shown in Fig. 9.7. At point (Tj0 =p0 ; Tj1 =p1 ), the
household does not save or borrow, and in the optimum the household
consumes by Xj0 (Tj0 =p0 ) > 0 more than it could by its first period
income. The monetary value of this excess consumption p0 Xj0 Tj0 equals
with Bj .
Substituting Eqs. (9.11) and (9.12) in the utility function and assuming
the loans taken to depend on time t, Bj (t)—the consumption of house-
hold j at both periods then depends on time too, Xj0 (t); Xj1 (t)—the utility
function becomes as:
Bj (t) C Tj0 Tj1 (1 C rb t)Bj (t)
uj (t) D uj .Xj0 (t); Xj1 (t)/ D uj ; :
p0 p1
(9.13)
Household j has now only one quantity by which it can affect its utility,
namely Bj (t) (e=y). The acceleration of utility u0j (t) with unit ut=(4y2 ) is:
@uj 1 @uj (1 C rb t)
u0j (t) D B0j (t):
@Xj0 p0 @Xj1 p1
9 Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates 373
The rules to adjust borrowing that make the utility of household j increase
with time, are:
Quantity
0 @uj
1
1
1 @ @Xj0
1A
p0
zj D @uj
t 1
@Xj1 p1
with unit 1=t measures the household’s subjective rate of time preference
between current and future consumption. Using the form in Eq. (9.13) of
the utility function, we can derive the following results from zj :
(Bj CTj0 )p1 @uj @2 uj @2 uj @uj @u @u
@Xj0 @Xj0 @Xj1
2 @Xj1 p1 @Xj0j @Xj1j
@zj p0 @Xj0
D 2 ;
@p0 @uj
tp20 @Xj1
374 Newtonian Microeconomics
ŒTj1 (1Crb t)Bj @uj @2 uj @2 uj @uj @uj @uj
@Xj0 @Xj1
@Xj1 @Xj0 @Xj1
C @Xj0 @Xj1
@zj p1 2
D 2 ;
@p1 @uj
tp0 @Xj1
@uj @2 uj @2 uj @uj
p1 @Xj1 @Xj0
@Xj0 @Xj1 @Xj0
@zj 2
D 2 < 0;
@Tj0 @uj
tp20 @Xj1
@uj @2 uj @2 uj @uj
@zj @Xj1 @Xj1 @Xj0 2 @Xj0
@Xj1
D 2 > 0; (9.14)
@Tj1 @uj
tp0 @Xj1
@uj @2 uj @2 uj @uj
(1 C rb t) @Xj0 @Xj1
@Xj1 @Xj0 @Xj1
@zj 2
D 2
@Bj @uj
tp0 @Xj1
p1 @uj @2 uj @2 uj @uj
p0 @Xj1 @Xj0
2 @Xj0 @Xj1 @Xj0
C 2 < 0;
@uj
tp0 @Xj1
@uj @2 uj @2 uj @uj
Bj @Xj0 @Xj1
@Xj1 @Xj0 @Xj1
@zj 2
D 2 < 0: (9.15)
@rb @uj
p0 @Xj1
p 1 @2 u j p0 @2 u @2 u
drb p0 @Xj02 C p1
(1 C rb t)2 @X 2j 2(1 C rb t) @Xj0 @Xj j1
D < 0:
j1
Because dBj =drb D 1=(drb =dBj ), we can interpret this result so that an
increase in rb decreases the optimal borrowing of household j.
According to the above, we can name quantity Fj ,
Fj D zj rb ;
Now, denoting 1=H 0 (0) D mj we can name Eq. (9.17) as the ‘Newtonian
equation of borrowing of household j’, where constant mj > 0 with
unit y/e represents the inertia (‘mass’) in this adjustment.
The ‘free body’ diagram of the forces acting upon the borrowing of
household j is in Fig. 9.9. The positive force component acting upon
borrowing is zj and the negative component is rb .
The average force saving households direct upon the aggregate saving in
the economy is
@ui
!
1X 1
n 1
@Xi0 p0
FS D rs @ui
1 D rs zs (S; rs ; p0 ; p1 ; Ts0 ; Ts1 );
n iD1 t @Xi1
1
p1
Fres D FS C FB D rs zs rb C zb D zb zs rd ;
that for saving households more than the interest differential, and vice
versa. Thus in the economy borrowing increases if borrowing households
prefer current consumption more than saving households. The aggregate
savings at time unit 0 are
X
n X
n X
n X
n
SD Si D (Ti0 p0 Xi0 ) D Ti0 p0 Xi0 D Ts0 p0 Xs0 ;
iD1 iD1 iD1 iD1
X
m X
m X
m X
m
BD Bj D (p0 Xj0 Tj0 ) D p0 Xj0 Tj0 D p0 Xb0 Tb0 ;
jD1 jD1 jD1 jD1
According to Sects. 9.1.1, 9.4, and the Appendix of this chapter, the
equation of motion for aggregate saving in the economy is
According to Sects. 9.2.1, 9.4, and the Appendix of this chapter, the
equation of motion for aggregate borrowing in the economy is
B0 (t) D Rb (FB ); R0b (FB ) > 0; Rb (0) D 0; FB D rb Czb (B; rb ; p0 ; p1 ; Tb0 ; Tb1 );
(9.20)
380 Newtonian Microeconomics
In the case of a fixed interest rate differential, either of the two interest
rates rs , rb can be considered as the adjusting quantity in the loan market,
and the other is determined by equation rb D rs C rd . Here we choose
lending rate rb to be the adjusting quantity. The lending rate is assumed
to be determined according to the excess demand of loans as:
The velocity of lending rate rb0 (t) with unit 1=y2 depends positively on
net borrowing at time unit 0, because p0 (Xs0 C Xb0 ) (e=y) is the value
of aggregate consumption and Ts0 C Tb0 the aggregate income in the
economy at time unit 0.
where constant a0 > 0 has unit 1=y, a2 > 0 is dimensionless, the signs
of a3 ; a4 with unit kg/(ye) are ambiguous, and a1 > 0; a5 < 0; a6 > 0
all have unit 1/e. In the Appendix of this chapter, the average rate of time
preference of borrowing households is approximated as
9 Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates 381
0 @u 1
1 X 1 @ @Xj0 p0
m j 1
b0 b1 b2 b3 b4 b5 b6
C 2 B C rb C p0 C p1 C Tb0 C Tb1 ; (9.23)
m m m m m m m
where constant b0 > 0 has unit 1=y, b2 < 0 is dimensionless, the signs
of b3 ; b4 with unit kg/(ye) are ambiguous, and b1 < 0; b5 < 0; b6 > 0
all have unit 1/e.
Assuming pc D pc0 and Thc D Th0c0 , h D s; b and c D 1; 2, we can
eliminate these quantities from Eqs. (9.22), (9.23); see the Appendix of
this chapter. Substituting rs from Eq. (9.22) by equation rs D rb rd , we
can approximate the equilibrium state in the loan market as:
a0 a1 a2
Supply function of savings: rb rd D C 2 S C (rb rd ); (9.24)
n n n
b0 b1 b2
Demand function of loans: rb D C 2 B C rb : (9.25)
m m m
The units of the constants can be used to check that the solutions in
Eq. (9.26) are dimensionally well-defined, that is, the units of rb , S are
1=y and e=y, respectively.
The equilibrium state in the loan market, where the forces acting upon
saving, borrowing, and interest rate vanish, is shown in Fig. 9.10, and
where the demand and supply functions are presented in reduced forms
of Eqs. (9.24), (9.25), with n > a2 . This assumption holds when there
are enough saving households, i.e. n is large. On the horizontal axis are
382 Newtonian Microeconomics
the aggregate saving and borrowing at time unit 0, and on the vertical axis
is the lending rate. In the equilibrium, aggregate saving equals aggregate
borrowing S D B and this takes place at lending rate rb D rs C rd .
Fig. 9.11 The forces acting upon saving, borrowing, and interest rate
The ‘free body’ diagram of the forces acting upon saving, borrowing,
and interest rate is in Fig. 9.11. The positive force component acting upon
saving is rb and the negative components are zs and rd . The positive force
component acting upon borrowing is zb and the negative one is rb . Notice
that interest differential rd affects negatively the motion of the system.
The horizontal coordinate axis is chosen so that in the equilibrium state
of the system, it moves with constant velocity B D S in the coordinate
system of accumulated saving and borrowing with interest rate staying
constant. A difference in velocities of the particles changes the interest
rate, which balances the difference. The connection between accumulated
and velocity of saving is:
Z Z
d
S(t)dt D S(t); where S(t)dt has unit e and that of S(t) is e=y;
dt
and the same holds for borrowing. As earlier, the box shapes of the
‘particles’ in Fig. 9.11 have no economic meaning, and they are assumed
only to improve Rthe clarityRof the figure. The length of the spring Lr in
Fig. 9.11 is Lr D B(t)dt S(t)dt, and the force by which the spring acts
upon the two particles is rb D kr Lr . By taking the time derivative of this
384 Newtonian Microeconomics
equation we get Eq. (9.28). The spring between the two particles reflects
the matter that an equal mutual force rb is acting upon the two particles,
and the difference in velocities of the particles B(t) S(t) stretches the
spring that increases the mutual force rb .
Assuming functions zs ; zb as in Eqs. (9.24), (9.25), we can write System
(9.27) as:
a2 a a0 a1
ms S0 (t) D 1
2
rb (t) C 1 rd 2 S(t);
n n n n
b0 b1 b2
mb B0 (t) D C 2 B(t) C 1 rb (t); (9.29)
m m m
1 0
r (t) D B(t) S(t);
kr b
the deposits they have received during the whole time period, banks have
also acquired funds by issuing certificates of deposits to their clients.
Because Finnish financial markets are a relatively small part of European
financial markets, Finnish bank loans and deposits do not much affect
the EONIA rate. On the other hand, changes in the EONIA rate do
affect Finnish saving and borrowing, but because the changes have been
relatively modest during time period 2006–2013 these effects have been
minor.
Because the general solution of System (9.29) is rather complicated, we
demonstrate it by using the following values for the parameters: rm D 0:5,
mc D 1, c D s; b, kr D 1=5, a0 D 100; a1 D 2000; a2 D 0:02,
b0 D 200 C 0:4t; b1 D 5; b2 D 2, m D 100; n D 200. The interest
rate is expressed in percent and the loans and savings are expressed in
units 109 e. A positive time trend is assumed in zb , b0 D 200 C 0:4t,
to get model (9.29) to resemble the observed behavior in Fig. 9.12. With
these parameter values, the time paths of variables S; B; rb are presented
in Fig. 9.13 where on the horizontal axis is time and on the vertical axis
are S; B, and rb . The three quantities are presented in the same figure
to demonstrate their connections, even though their measurement units
Fig. 9.12 Deposits and bank loans in Finland together with Eonia rate
386 Newtonian Microeconomics
Fig. 9.13 Time paths of aggregate saving, borrowing and interest rate
differ. The time path of rb is the one below those of S; B, and that of S is
the thicker one. The figure shows that rb increases if B > S, and vice versa.
As compared with the static neoclassical analysis, by System (9.27) we
can study the reasons for the dynamics of a perfectly competed loan mar-
ket by assuming time dependencies in zs (S(t); rb (t); rd ; p0 ; p1 ; Ts0 ; Ts1 )
and in zb (B(t); rb (t); p0 ; p1 ; Tb0 ; Tb1 ). On the other hand, the adjustment
process in the loan market can be studied by solving System (9.29) with
different numerical values for the parameters in the model. Concerning
the speed of adjustment, the neoclassical framework is a special case of
System (9.27) with an infinite speed of adjustment, that is, mc D 0,
c D s; b and 1=kr D 0.
other hand, we do not model firms’ depositing their cash reserves in banks
because we assume that firms mainly act as borrowers in the loan market.
The equation of motion for a firm’s investment was given in Sect. 7.5.3.
For simplicity, we assume that every firm applies loan financing in only
one kind of capital goods, and we denote by Npvi (e) the present value of
net revenues (or cost savings) one capital good (machine) causes for firm
i, and by Ci (e) the price (value) of one machine. These net revenues also
include the costs of loans.
We assume v firms in the economy and denote by Ii (t) (e=t) the
loan financed investments of firm i during time unit t D y. According
to Sect. 7.5.3, the following model describes the investments of firm i:
Npvi
mi Ii (t) D Fi ; Fi D rb ; Ii (t) D Ki0 (t); (9.30)
Ci
where Ni (e=y) is the net revenues (or cost savings) one capital good
causes for firm i during time unit y, and rb (1=y) is the interest rate on
loans. A firm financing its investments by a loan applies the loan rate in its
discounting due to the same reason as borrowing households. Constant
mi > 0 with unit 1/e represents the inertial factors in the adjustment of
the capital stock of firm i.
In the Appendix of this chapter, we show that we can approximate
P the
dynamics of loan financed investments of all firms, I(t) D viD1 Ii (t), in
the neighborhood of point xi0 D (Ni0 ; rb0 ; Ci0 ), i D 1; : : : ; v, as:
z0 z1 z2
mI I(t) D C 2 N C 2 C rb ;
v v v
P
where N D viD1 Ni is the aggregate netPrevenues one machine causes for
all firms during time unit y, and C D viD1 Ci is the aggregate of prices
(values) of the investment goods. Denoting the aggregate investment loans
by I(t), System (9.29) becomes the following:
a a0 a1 a2
ms S0 (t) D
2
1 rd 2 S(t) 1 rb (t);
n n n n
b0 b1 b2
mb B0 (t) D C 2 B(t) C 1 rb (t);
m m m
388 Newtonian Microeconomics
z0 z1 z2
mI I(t) D C 2 N C 2 C rb (t);
v v v
1 0
r (t) D B(t) C I(t) S(t): (9.31)
kr b
Then, comparing Systems (9.29) and (9.31) we see that now the equilib-
rium state in the loan market, S0 (t) D B0 (t) D rb0 (t) D 0, is:
b1 mI n .a0 C (n a2 )rd / v 2 C a1 b1 (vz0 C Nz1 C Cz2 ) b0 mmI v 2
rb D ;
.a1 .b1 C (b2 m)mmI / C b1 mI (a2 n)n/ v 2
The equilibrium state in the loan market thus changes somewhat. Notice
that I ¤ 0, that is, in the equilibrium the aggregate loan-financed
investments change the equilibrium aggregate saving, borrowing, and
interest rate in the economy. If we had assumed that in the equilibrium
state holds I(t) D K 0 (t) D 0, this would mean that the capital stock
remains constant, and then investments would not affect the loan market.
We could compare the solutions in Eqs. (9.26) and (9.32) by assuming
numerical values for the exogenous variables and the parameters in the
model. For shortness, however, we omit this.
9 Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates 389
in the neighborhood of point xi0 D (Si0 ; rs0 ; p00 ; p10 ; Ti00 ; Ti10 ) as
@zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 )
zsi D zsi (xi0 ) C (Si Si0 ) C (rs rs0 )
@Si @rs
@zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 )
C (p0 p00 ) C (p1 p10 ) C (Ti0 Ti00 )
@p0 @p1 @Ti0
@zsi (xi0 )
C (Ti1 Ti10 ) C i : (9.33)
@Ti1
Xn
@zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 )
D zsi (xi0 ) Si0 rs0
iD1
@Si @rs
@zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 )
p00 p10 Ti00 Ti10
@p0 @p1 @Ti0 @Ti1
X
n
@zsi (xi0 ) X
n
@zsi (xi0 ) X
n
@zsi (xi0 ) X
n
@zsi (xi0 )
C Si C rs C p0 C p1
iD1
@Si iD1
@rs iD1
@p0 iD1
@p1
X
n
@zsi (xi0 ) X
n
@zsi (xi0 )
C Ti0 C Ti1
iD1
@Ti0 iD1
@Ti1
a1 a5 a6
a0 C S C a2 rs C a3 p0 C a4 p1 C Ts0 C Ts1 ;
n n n
Pn Pn Pn Pn
3
Because iD1 ci xi D c iD1 xi C iD1 (ci c)xi where c D (1=n) iD1 ci , the approximation
is the more accurate the less ci and xi vary, i D 1; : : : ; n.
390 Newtonian Microeconomics
Pn Pn Pn
where S D iD1 Si , Ts0 D iD1 Ti0 , Ts1 D iD1 Ti1 , and
n
X @zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 )
a0 D zsi (xi0 ) Si0 rs0 p00
iD1
@Si @rs @p0
@zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 ) @zsi (xi0 )
p10 Ti00 Ti10 ;
@p1 @Ti0 @Ti1
X
n
@zsi (xi0 ) X
n
@zsi (xi0 ) X
n
@zsi (xi0 )
a1 D ; a2 D ; a3 D ;
iD1
@Si iD1
@rs iD1
@p0
X
n
@zsi (xi0 ) X
n
@zsi (xi0 ) X
n
@zsi (xi0 )
a4 D ; a5 D ; a6 D :
iD1
@p1 iD1
@Ti0 iD1
@Ti1
in the neighborhood of point xj0 D (Bj0 ; rb0 ; p00 ; p10 ; Tj00 ; Tj10 ) as
X
m Xm
@zbj (xj0 )
zbj (Bj ; rb ; p0 ; p1 ; Tj0 ; Tj1 ) D zbj (xj0 ) Bj0
jD1 jD1
@Bj
X
m
@zbj (xj0 ) X
m
@zbj (xj0 ) X
m
@zbj (xj0 )
Cp0 C p1 C Tj0
jD1
@p0 jD1
@p1 jD1
@Tj0
X
m
@zbj (xj0 ) b1 b5 b6
C Tj1 b0 C B C b2 rb C b3 p0 C b4 p1 C Tb0 C Tb1 ;
jD1
@Tj1 m m m
where
m
X @zbj (xj0 ) @zbj (xj0 ) @zbj (xj0 )
b0 D zbj (xj0 ) Bj0 rb0 p00
jD1
@Bj @rb @p0
@zbj (xj0 ) @zbj (xj0 ) @zbj (xj0 )
p10 Tj00 Tj10 ;
@p1 @Tj0 @Tj1
X
m
@zbj (xj0 ) X
m
@zbj (xj0 ) X
m
@zbj (xj0 )
b1 D ; b2 D ; b3 D ;
jD1
@Bj jD1
@rb jD1
@p0
X
m
@zbj (xj0 ) X
m
@zbj (xj0 ) X
m
@zbj (xj0 )
b4 D ; b5 D ; b6 D :
jD1
@p1 jD1
@Tj0 jD1
@Tj1
4
See footnote 3.
392 Newtonian Microeconomics
Xv
@Fi (xi0 ) @Fi (xi0 ) @Fi (xi0 )
z0 D Fi (xi0 ) Ni0 Ci0 rb0
iD1
@Ni @Ci @rb
v
X v
X v
X
@Fi (xi0 ) @Fi (xi0 ) @Fi (xi0 )
z1 D ; z2 D ; z3 D D 1 v:
iD1
@Ni iD1
@Ci iD1
@rb
5
See footnote 3.
9 Saving, Borrowing, and Interest Rates 393
10.1 Introduction
In this chapter we present the mathematical concepts and rules of calcu-
lation necessary to understand the main parts of the book.
In general, quantities can be divided into scalar and vector quantities.
Scalars have a certain magnitude and vectors have, besides magnitude,
also a direction, which means that vectors have several dimensions (see
Section 10.4). All real numbers and dimensional quantities are scalars,
and vectors may have real numbers or scalars as their components. In this
book, complex numbers or vectors with complex number components are
not treated.
where the slope k has been defined earlier; see Fig. 10.1. The latter form
of the equation shows that this equation can be presented analogously as
in the solved form by denoting the constant as: b D y1 kx1 .
Example
Suppose it is known that the costs of production of a firm from a good
depend linearly on the amount of production. It is also known that when 12
products were produced, the costs were 2520 (e), and 22 products created
costs 3620 (e). With this knowledge, we can formulate the equation that
describes the relationship between costs and amount of production.
We denote by x (unit) the amount of production and by y (e) the
costs of production. The line goes through points (12 (unit); 2520 (e)) and
(22 (unit); 3620 (e)). The equation of the line is then:
e D A unit C B; (10.2)
e B D A unit
we see that B D e must hold that the adding on left-hand side of the
equation is dimensionally well-defined. On the other hand, the unit of
the right-hand side of the equation A unit must be e for both sides to
have equal unit. Thus we can write equation
e
e D A unit , A D
unit
from which we solved the unknown measurement unit A for constant 110.
10 Mathematical Appendix 399
Example
The circular disc of a plane, B((x0 ; y0 )I r), is not a closed set because it does
not contain its border points. On the other hand, a set that contains points
with distance from (x0 ; y0 ) less than or equal with r, is a closed set. This set
contains its border points the distance of which from point (x0 ; y0 ) is exactly
r, too. ˘
10.4 Vectors
Quantities that have an exactly defined direction in addition to magnitude
are called vectors. Vectors are usually denoted by small letters with a little
arrow above the variable like vE, uE, or by bold small letters like v, u. We
use the latter notation.
400 Newtonian Microeconomics
We can graph vector v 2 R2 with the starting point in the origin (0; 0)
and ending point at (x0 ; y0 ). The coordinates of the end pointq
define the
direction of vector v exactly, and the length of vector v is jvj D x02 C y20 ;
see Fig. 10.2.
a C b D (x1 C x2 ; y1 C y2 );
a b D (x1 x2 ; y1 y2 ):
10 Mathematical Appendix 401
ra D (rx; ry):
jraj D jrjjaj;
10.5 Functions
10.5.1 The Definition of a Function
Example 1
Function
f W RC ! R; f (x) D 214x C 515;
Example 2
Function
f W R2 ! R; f (x; y) D 24xy;
Example 3
Function
f W R2 ! R2 ; f (x; y) D (x2 ; xy)
Fig. 10.4 (a) The surface of z D f (x; y): (b) The level curves of z D f (x; y)
surface above the point; see Fig. 10.4a. The values of the function are
constant at constant height, which is demonstrated in the figure by
horizontal plane at z D c, c constant. The cutting curve of plane z D c
and the surface of function values is a curve in the plane, where the value
of the function is constant, z D c.
The surface of function z D f (x; y) in Fig. 10.4a can be described
in a two-dimensional plane, similar to a two-dimensional topographical
map being used to describe the three-dimensional shape of the Earth; see
Fig. 10.4b. In a topographical map, the points at the same height from
the level of sea are connected by a level curve. These level or indifference
curves are drawn on the horizontal ‘bottom’ plane of the map. The level or
contour curves of function f (x; y) similarly consist of points (x; y) 2 R2
in which the value of the function has constant value: f (x; y) D c,
c 2 R, constant. In Fig. 10.4b is shown two contour curves of function
z D f (x; y); the further away from origin the level curve is, the smaller
function value it represents.
Example
Suppose the daily costs of production of a good C (e/day) follow the
function
C(x) D a0 x2 C a1 x C 900;
e day e
a0 W and a1 W :
unit2 unit
The unit of a0 x2 and a1 x is then e/day, which is also the unit of constant 900.
Suppose the flow of production at a normal day is 25 (unit=h), and we
want to express the costs of production as a function of daily work time
L (h=day). This is
unit h unit
x(L) D 25 L D 25L :
h day day
Note. Not all functions have an inverse function. An inverse function can
be defined only for functions f W A ! B for which for every element
in the range b 2 B corresponds to one and only one element in the
domain a 2 A. This kind of function is called a bijection. Function
f W A ! B is a bijection, if it obeys the following characteristics:
• f gets its all values only once, that is f (x1 ) D f (x2 ) , x1 D x2 , and
• f gets all values in its range. ˘
406 Newtonian Microeconomics
Example
Let the weekly cost function of a firm C Œ0; 1Œ! Œ45; 1Œ be C(x) D 15x C 45,
where constants 15 and 45 have units e/unit and e=week, respectively. The
inverse function of C expresses the flow of production that can be produced
at costs y (e/week). Function C is strictly increasing and its range is Œ45; 1Œ.
Thus C is a bijection and it has an inverse function. The inverse function is
obtained as follows:
C(x) D y; y 45
e unit
e
e
15 x C 45 Dy ; x0
unit week week week
e e
unit y week 45 week
x D e
week 15 ( unit )
unit y unit unit
x D 3 :
week 15 week week
y
Thus by costs y (e/week) the firm can produce x D 15 3 (unit=week). The
inverse function of C is C1 W Œ45; 1Œ! Œ0; 1Œ, C1 (y) D 15 3. ˘
y
10 Mathematical Appendix 407
lim f (x) D a;
x!x0
if f (x) approaches a when the values of x are close enough to x0 . The limit
value can also be denoted as: f (x) ! a when x ! x0 . ˘
The limit value of a two-variable real-valued function is defined as:
§: The limit value of a two-variable real-valued function f W A ! R,
A
R2 at point (x0 ; y0 ) 2 A, is
lim f (x; y) D a;
(x;y)!(x0 ;y0 )
Note. If function f W A ! R, A
R2 has limit value a at point (x0 ; y0 ),
the values of the function must approach a independently of the direction
from where (x; y) ! (x0 ; y0 ). ˘
10.7 Derivative
10.7.1 The Definition of Derivative
f (x1 ) f (x0 ) f
D ;
x1 x0 x
f (x1 ) f (x0 ) f
lim D lim :˘
x1 !x0 x1 x0 x!0 x
f (x1 ) f (x0 ) f
kD D :
x1 x0 x
f (x1 ) f (x0 )
f 0 (x0 ) D lim :˘
x1 !x0 x1 x0
10 Mathematical Appendix 409
Derivative of a Product
Let f (x) D g(x) h(x). The derivative of a product of two functions is:
Derivative of a Quotient
g(x)
Let f (x) D h(x)
. Then f is differentiable if h(x) ¤ 0, and its derivative is:
g0 (x)h(x) h0 (x)g(x)
f 0 (x) D ; h(x) ¤ 0:
(h(x))2
Thus in solving variable x from the first equation in Eq. (10.3) we apply
the exponential function on both sides of Eq. (10.3) as
ey D eln(x) D x: (10.4)
10 Mathematical Appendix 411
d 1 d x
ln(x) D ; e D ex :
dx x dx
dy f 0 (x) dz
D and D g0 (x)eg(x) :
dx f (x) dx
Example 1
Let y D 2 ln(x). Dividing by 2 and applying the exponential function on both
sides of the equation, we get the inverse function as:
y
D ln(x) , ey=2 D eln(x) , ey=2 D x:
2
dy 2 dx 1
D and D ey=2 :
dx x dy 2
dy 2
D D 2ey=2 :
dx x
Comparing this and the formula for dx=dy we see that dy=dx D 1=(dx=dy). ˘
412 Newtonian Microeconomics
Example 2
Let L(t) describe the labor input of a firm as a function of time, and let q(L(t))
be the production function of the firm. The instantaneous rate of change
q(L(t))
of productivity of labor of the firm, L(t) , with respect to time, is then:
q(L(t))
d( L(t)
) q0 (L(t)) L0 (t) L(t) L0 (t) q(L(t))
D
dt ŒL(t)2
L0 (t) 0 L0 (t) q(L(t))
D q (L(t))
L(t) L(t) L(t)
0
L (t) 0 q(L(t))
D q (L(t)) :˘
L(t) L(t)
Example 3
Let the weekly profit …k of a firm be
where qk (t) is the flow of production of good k at time moment t, Bk (qk (t))
the inverse demand function of the good, and Ck (qk (t)) the weekly cost func-
tion of the firm. Then, according to the rule of derivation of a composite
function, the time derivative of the profit function is:
…0k (t) D B0k (qk (t)) q0k (t) qk (t) C q0k (t) Bk (qk (t)) Ck0 (qk (t)) q0k (t)
D B0k (qk (t)) qk (t) C Bk (qk (t)) Ck0 (qk (t)) q0k (t): ˘
f 0 (x0 ) D 0:
Fig. 10.8 (a) Two local extremums. (b) Two local extremums
414 Newtonian Microeconomics
Fig. 10.9 (a) Local minimum, (b) maximum, and (c) turning point of f (x)
Second derivative f 00 (x) measures the rate of change of f 0 (x). In the case
of local minimum, f 0 (x) increases when x increases in the neighborhood
of x0 , that is, f 00 (x) > 0; x 2 Œx1 < x0 < x2 , see Fig. 10.9a. Similarly,
in the case of local maximum, f 0 (x) decreases when x increases in the
neighborhood of x0 , that is, f 00 (x) < 0; x 2 Œx1 < x0 < x2 , see Fig. 10.9b.
Point x0 is a turning point of function f , if f 0 (x0 ) D 0 and f 00 (x) changes
its sign at point x0 . In Fig. 10.9c, f 00 (x) 0; x x0 and f 00 (x) > 0; x > x0 .
Example
Let the flow of production of a firm be q (unit=week), q > 0, and its product
price p (e/unit). The sales function of the firm is p D 4000 33q, where the
units of constants 4000 and 33 are e=unit and eweek=unit2 , respectively. The
revenues of the firm R (e=week) are then
Next we calculate the flow of production that maximizes the weekly profit
of the firm. The weekly profit function of the firm, …, is the following:
Let us continue to study the type of the extremum at the zero point of the
derivative, q D 20 (unit=week). The second order derivative of function … is
Now …00 (20) D 12 20 60 D 300 < 0, and thus function … has a local
maximum at q D 20. Because this is the only possible (positive) extremum
point, the profit of the firm is maximized at the flow of production 20
(unit=week). The maximal value of weekly profit is:
e
…(20) D 2 203 30 202 C 3600 20 5000 D 39;000 :
week
Next we show that the derivative of the profit function is well-defined with
respect to measurement units. The unit of derivative d…=dq is the same as
that of …=q,
e
… e
unit D
W week :
q week
unit
Partial functions ˆ(x) and ‰(y) describe the behavior of function f when
one of its arguments changes and the other stays fixed.
The geometrical interpretation of the graph of function ˆ(x) is the
cutting curve of the surface of function f and plane y D y0 ; see Fig. 10.10.
The geometrical interpretation of function ‰(y) is the cutting curve of the
surface of f and plane x D x0 . However, plane x D x0 is not presented in
Fig. 10.10 to keep the figure clear.
Fig. 10.10 The surface of z D f (x; y) and partial functions ˆ(x); ‰(y)
10 Mathematical Appendix 417
@f @f
D fx D Dx f and D fy D Dy f :
@x @y
@y @x
D @y@x , @x @y
D @x@y , and @y @y
D @y 2.
@f @g(x; y) @h(x; y)
D h(x; y) C g(x; y);
@x @x @x
@f @g(x; y) @h(x; y)
D h(x; y) C g(x; y):
@y @y @y
dz @f dx @f dy
D C :
dt @x dt @y dt
Example 1
Suppose a firm producing good k has the following profit function:
where qk (t) is the flow of production of the firm, pk (t) the price of good k,
and Ck .qk (t)/ the cost function of the firm. The time derivative of the profit
function is
where
@…k @…k
D qk (t) and D pk (t) Ck0 (qk (t)): ˘
@pk @qk
Example 2
Let
z D f .x(t); y(t)/ D x(t) y(t):
dz @f dx @f dy dx dy
D C D y(t) C x(t) D x0 (t) y(t) C y0 (t) x(t):
dt @x dt @y dt dt dt
Example 3
Let z D f .x(t); y(t)/ D x(t)
y(t)
, y(t) ¤ 0. The partial derivatives of this function
are:
@f 1 @f x(t)
D and D :
@x y(t) @y (y(t))2
dz @f dx @f dy 1 dx x(t) dy
D C D
dt @x dt @y dt y(t) dt (y(t))2 dt
x0 (t) y0 (t)x(t) x0 (t) y(t) y0 (t) x(t)
D 2
D :
y(t) (y(t)) (y(t))2
10.10 Approximation
The tangent line of function f W A ! R, A
R at point (x0 ; f (x0 ))
approximates the curve of the function near this point. We can thus use
the tangent line in approximating changes in the function value with small
changes in the argument close to x0 ; see Fig. 10.12.
Change x D x x0 causes the change in function value
y
lim D f 0 (x0 );
x!0 x
y
D f 0 (x0 ) C (x0 ; x); where (x0 ; x) ! 0 with x ! 0:
x
y D f 0 (x0 )x;
Example
Let us have function y D f (x) D 2ln(x), where ln is the natural logarithmic
function. We approximate this function by the second order Taylor polyno-
mial P2 (x) in the neighborhood of point x D 1:
2 2
P2 (x) D 2 ln(1) C (x 1) (x 1)2
1 21
D 2 C 2x (x 1)2 D 3 C 4x x2 ;
where ln(1) D 0. From P2 (x) we get the first order polynomial as: P1 (x) D
2 C 2x. We can then use the first and the second order Taylor polynomials,
P1 (x), P2 (x), in approximating the function values near point x D 1. The
corresponding values of the function and the polynomials at points x D
1; 1:2; 1:5; 2 are the following:
424 Newtonian Microeconomics
The above table shows that both polynomials are more accurate the
closer to the fixed point the approximation is made, and the second order
polynomial is more accurate if the distance is increased.
@f @f
z x C y;
@x @y
10 Mathematical Appendix 425
Example 1
Let f (x; y) D c, c 2 R constant, be the level curve of a two-variable function.
We like to define the slope of the tangent of this level curve dy=dx in
coordinate system (x; y). Suppose function f is differentiable. On a level
curve, the change in the function value is zero, that is, dc D 0, and so
@f @f
dx C dy D dc; dc D 0:
@x @y
@f
@f @f dy
dy D dx; which can be solved as D @x
@f
: (10.7)
@y @x dx
@y
Notice that in solving Eq. (10.7), we can multiply and divide by real-valued
quantities dx; dy; @f =@x; @f =@y ¤ 0 like with real numbers, if they deviate from
zero. The expression we solved for dy=dx is the slope of the tangent of level
curve f (x; y) D c in coordinate system (x; y). ˘
Example 2
We define the slope of the tangent of a level curve of a two-variable
function in two ways. Let y 3x2 C 4x D 5 be the equation of the level
curve. The slope of the tangent of the curve is then:
426 Newtonian Microeconomics
@f
dy 6x C 4
D @x
@f
D D 6x 4:
dx 1
@y
In this case, we can solve y from the equation of the level curve as: y D
3x2 4x C 5. The slope of the tangent of the curve can then be obtained as:
dy
D 6x 4: ˘
dx
Let f (x; y) W A ! R, A
R2 be a differentiable function, and g(x; y) D
k, k constant, a condition that restricts variables x and y. The following
so called Lagrange’s function can then be defined:
@F
D 0;
@x
@F
D 0;
@y
@F
D 0: (10.8)
@z
Note. Because @F=@z D k g(x; y), Eq. (10.8) guarantees that the
constraint holds in the possible extremum point. ˘
see Sect. 3.7. Substituting q2 from the utility function by the budget
equation, we get:
1
u D u q1 ; (T p1 q1 ) :
p2
F D u(q1 ; q2 ) C z1 (T p1 q1 p2 q2 ):
@F @u
D z1 p1 D 0;
@q1 @q1
@F @u
D z1 p2 D 0;
@q2 @q2
@F
D T p1 q1 p2 q2 D 0:
@z1
1 @u
z1 D ;
p1 @q1
This is the same result as in Eq. (10.9) and it holds in the optimum
together with the budget equation in Eq. (10.10).
Next we transform the utility function by function f (u), f 0 (u) > 0.
The new Lagrange’s function is F D f (u(q1 ; q2 )) C z2 (T p1 q1 p2 q2 ),
and in the optimum holds:
@F @u
D f 0 (u) z2 p1 D 0;
@q1 @q1
@F @u
D f 0 (u) z2 p2 D 0;
@q2 @q2
@F
D T p1 q1 p2 q2 D 0:
@z2
This equation together with Eq. (10.11) corresponds to that in Eq. (10.9).
Because p1 , p2 are the same in both cases, in the optimum holds:
f 0 (u) @u 1 @u f 0 (u) @u 1 @u
D and D :
z2 @q1 z1 @q1 z2 @q2 z1 @q2
@u
z p1 D 0;
@q1
@u
z p2 D 0;
@q2
T p1 q1 p2 q2 D 0;
dF du
z D D :
dT dT
z D f (x; y):
10 Mathematical Appendix 435
F(x; y; z) D 0;
Example 1
Let 2z D 4x C 6xy. We can solve this equation with respect to z to get the
explicit form of the function as
z D 2x C 3xy: (10.12)
@z @z
D 2 C 3y; D 3x:
@x @y
@z @z
2 D 4 C 6y ) D 2 C 3y:
@x @x
Example 2
Let us study the labor supply of a person. We denote hourly wage by w (e/h),
income tax rate by , and annual working hours by L (h=y). The annual after-
tax wage income T (e/y) of the person is then
T D (1 )wL: (10.13)
Let us denote the annual leisure time by H (h=y). We can then write
H D 1920 L; (10.14)
where 1920 (h=y) is the maximum annual work time; see Sect. 6.3. Let
u D u(H; T) with unit ut=y be the utility function of the labor supplier. Then
equation
@u @u
(1 )w D
@T @H
dw @w dT @w dH
D C : (10.15)
dL @T dL @H dL
Next we define this derivative by solving the partial derivatives, @w=@T and
@w=@H, in it by implicit differentiation. The partial derivative of equation
@u @u
(1 )w D (10.16)
@T @H
with respect to T is
@w @u @2 u @2 u
(1 ) Cw 2 D :
@T @T @T @T@H
@2 u @2 u
@w
1
1 @T@H
w @T 2
D @u
:
@T @T
10 Mathematical Appendix 437
1 @2 u @2 u
@w 1 @H 2
w @H@T
D @u
:
@H @T
dw @w dT @w dH
D C
dL @T dL @H dL
@2 u @2 u
1
1 @T@H
w @T 2 dw
D @u
(1 ) LCw
@T
dL
@2 u @2 u
1
@H 2
w @H@T
C 1 @u
(1); (10.17)
@T
@ u2 @ u2
2 2@ u2
dw 2(1 )w @T@H @H 2 (1 ) w @T 2
D @u @ u
2 @2 u
:˘
dL (1 ) @T (1 )L @T@H C (1 )2 w L @T 2
F 0 (x) D f (x)
The symbol x after the d-letter is the variable with respect to which the
integration is made, and function f is called the integrand. ˘
Note. If a function has one integral function, it has several other integral
functions. For example, one of the integral functions of function f (x) D
3x2 is F(x) D x3 , because F 0 (x) D 3x2 . However, all functions G(x) D
x3 CC, where C 2 R is a constant, are also integral functions of f , because
G0 (x) D 3x2 D f (x). Constant C is called the constant of integration.
10 Mathematical Appendix 439
X
n
In D f (x1 )x1 C f (x2 )x2 C C f (xn )xn D f (xj )xj I
jD1
see Fig. 10.16. Now, if n ! 1, the number of the division points increases
without limit, and xj ! 0 8 j D 1; 2; : : : ; n. Then In approaches a
limit value which we call the definite integral of function f from a to b;
see Fig. 10.16.
§: The definite integral of function f from a to b is the limit value
Z b X
n
f (x)dx D lim f (xj )xj
a n!1
jD1
Rb
Fig. 10.16 The principle of calculation of definite integral a f (x)dx
440 Newtonian Microeconomics
when this limit value exists. Numbers a and b are called the lower and
the upper limit of the integration, respectively. ˘
Rb
The geometric interpretation of the absolute value of a f (x) dx is the
area between the graph of y D f (x) and x-axis on interval Œa; b. We can
understand this as follows. If function f is continuous and positive on
interval Œa; b, f (xj )xj measures the area of the rectangle having xj as
the basis and f (xj ) as the height. Then the sum
X
n
In D f (x1 )x1 C f (x2 )x2 C C f (xn )xn D f (xj )xj
jD1
is an approximation for the area between the graph of function f and the
x-axis on the interval Œa; b; see Fig. 10.16. If n ! 1, then xj ! 0 8 j D
1; 2; : : : ; n, and the approximation becomes more accurate. The limit
value of In —given in the definition of the definite integral—measures
the area between y D f (x) and the x-axis on interval Œa; b.
In the graphical demonstration in Fig. 10.16, we assumed that f (x) >
Rb
0 8 x 2 Œa; b. However, if f (x) < 0 8 x 2 Œa; b, then a f (x)dx < 0,
and this definite integral has an equal absolute value as the area limited
by function f (x) > 0, the x-axis, and the lines x D a, x D b.
The first fundamental theorem of calculus: Let function f be contin-
uous on interval Œa; b and x 2 a; bŒ. Then function
Z x
F(x) D f (t)dt
a
Example 1
Suppose the velocity of the price of a product p0 (t) is linearly related to the
difference between its demand D(p(t)) and supply S(p(t)) that both depend
on price p(t). This relationship can be expressed as:
Example 2
We show here that function
2apf
T t
qf (t) D C C 0 e pv m f (10.20)
2pf
a
mf q0f (t) D (T 2pf qf (t))I (10.21)
pv
2apf
2apf t
mf q0f (t) D C 0 e pv m f : (10.23)
pv
a a T
2apf
t
(T 2pf qf (t)) D T 2pf C C 0 e pv m f
pv pv 2pf
a 2pf T
2apf
t
D T 2pf C0 e pv mf
pv 2pf
2apf
2apf t
D C 0 e pv m f : (10.24)
pv
From Eqs. (10.23) and (10.24) we see that both sides of the differential
equation in Eq. (10.21) are equal, and so function qf (t) in Eq. (10.20) fulfills
the differential equation and is thus its solution. Dimensional constant C0
in the solution of qf (t) is the constant of integration with unit kg=week.
Function qf (t) in Eq. (10.20) is called the general solution of the differential
equation in Eq. (10.21), and all solutions of Eq. (10.21) with different values
of C0 are its special solutions. ˘
1
This section is based on Stevens (1946).
10 Mathematical Appendix 445
ai ,x aj :
• Reflexivity: ai ,x ai 8 ai 2 E.
• Symmetry: If ai ,x aj then aj ,x ai .
• Transitivity: If ai ,x aj and aj ,x ak , then ai ,x ak .
ai ,x aj
Example 1
For the set E of all inhabitants in a city, we can construct the following
indicator function f1x :
8
ˆ
ˆ 0; if ai is unmarried
ˆ
ˆ
<1; if ai is married
f1x (ai ) D
ˆ2;
ˆ if ai is divorced
ˆ
:̂
3; if ai is widow:
Let function f be: f W f0; 1; 2; 3g ! f27; 8; 1; 0g, f (x) D x3 . Then the
composite function f2x D f (f1x ) is an indicator function on the classification
scale (f is a bijection), and its values are:
8
ˆ
ˆ 0; if ai is unmarried
ˆ
ˆ
<1; if ai is married
f2x (ai ) D
ˆ8;
ˆ if ai is divorced
ˆ
:̂
27; if ai is widow: ˘
10 Mathematical Appendix 447
• ai x ai 8 ai 2 E,
• if ai x aj and aj x ak , then ai x ak ,
• if ai x aj and aj x ai , then ai ,x aj .
Example 2
An example of an indicator function fx on ordinal scale in the set E of
military staff in the USA is:
8
ˆ
ˆ 1; if ai is Private
ˆ
ˆ
ˆ
ˆ
ˆ
ˆ 2; if ai is Corporal
<
fx (ai ) D 3; if ai is Sergeant
ˆ
ˆ
ˆ
ˆ 4; if ai is Staff Sergeant
ˆ
ˆ
ˆ: ::
:̂:
: : ˘
f2x D f (f1x )
fx (ai ) D xi :
10 Mathematical Appendix 449
An interval scale is the first scale of measurement where adding and sub-
tracting the numbers of measurement can be interpreted in a meaningful
way. The difference in numbers of measurement, xj xi (xi xj ),
measures the change in characteristic x between statistical units ai and aj .
We denote the increment in characteristic x from statistical unit ai to unit
aj (ai x aj ) by (ai ; aj ), whereby x is denoted relation ‘smaller or equal
than’ with respect to characteristic x. If we measure characteristic x on the
interval scale, increments (ai ; aj ) and (am ; an ) can be compared, that
is, we can determine which of the following alternatives holds:
(ai ; aj ) ,x (am ; an ):
f2x D f (f1x )
f (x) D ax C b;
where a and b are dimensional constants; a > 0 and b may take any value.
450 Newtonian Microeconomics
The connection between indicator functions f1x and f2x on the interval
scales 1 and 2 is then:
f2x D af1x C b:
f2x D af1x :
Now, if f1x D 1 then f2x D a, that is, one unit change in scale 1
corresponds to a units change in scale 2. If f1x D 0, then f2x D b, that is,
the zero point in scale 1 corresponds to number b in scale 2.
For example, when measuring temperature, we use two indicator
functions with different scales: Celsius and Fahrenheit scales. If we denote
the values of the indicator function on the Celsius scale by f1x and at
Fahrenheit scale by f2x , the following relation holds between the measured
values:
f2x D f (f1x )
f (x) D ax;
The term ‘ratio scale’ reflects that at this scale of measurement, the ratio
of numbers of measurement xi and xj of statistical units ai and aj , xi =xj , is
independent of the indicator function. Most of the traditional measures
for quantities, like length, weight, income, time interval, and so on, are
measurable on a ratio scale.
References
Apostol, T. M. (1967). Calculus (2nd ed., Vol. I). New York: Wiley International
Edition.
Apostol, T. M. (1969). Calculus (2nd ed., Vol. II). New York: Wiley International
Edition.
Chiang, A. C. (1984). Fundamental methods of mathematical economics (3rd ed.).
New York: McGraw-Hill International Editions.
Stevens, S. S. (1946). On the theory of scales of measurement. Science, 103(2684),
677–680.
Author Index
A D
Allen, Roy George Douglas, 36, 47 Dannenberg, Alia, 14, 219n1
Apostol, Tom, 122, 443 Darwin, Charles, 6
Ausloos, Marcel, 22 Debreu, Gérard, 100, 107, 110
de Jong, Fritz, 41, 47, 48
Drãgulescu, Adrian, 23
B Dunlop, John, T., 281
Bachelier, Louis, 20
Becker, Gary S., 7, 25
Bentham, Jeremy, 7, 14, 25 E
Bridgman, Percy Williams, 39–40 Einstein, Albert, 20
Brown, Robert, 20 Estola, Matti, 14, 19, 24, 83, 88,
185, 222
C
Canard, Nicolas-Francois, 19 F
Chen, Shu-Heng, 20 Fama, Eugene, 337, 352
Chiang, Alpha Chung-i, 428, 430 Fisher, Irving, 21, 62
Comte, Auguste, 7 Friedman, Milton, 18, 325
L Q
Leibniz, Gottfried Wilhelm, 68 Quatelet, Adolphe, 20
Lenin, Vladimir Iljits, 17
Li, Sai-Ping, 20
Liu, Y., 23 S
Lucas, Robert, 24 Samuelson, Paul, 213
Lux, Thomas, 23 Schinckus, Cristophe, 22
Smith, Adam, 9, 19
Solow, Robert, 282
M Sornette, Didier, 22
Mandelbrot, Benoit, 20 Stanley, Eugene, 19, 22
Mantegna, Rosario, 23 Stevens, Stanley Smith, 444
Author Index 455
T W
Takayasu, Hideki, 22 Walras, Leon, 9, 16, 20
V
Vihriälä, Vesa, 151 Y
von Wright, Georg Henrik, 12 Yakovenko, Viktor M., 23
Subject Index
A approximation, 421–6
absolute change, 59 average acceleration of production,
absolute scale, 451–2 80–1
acceleration of borrowing, 376 average fixed unit costs, 160, 163
acceleration of consumption, 135 average marginal costs of firms, 217
acceleration of labor supply, 266 average marginal willingness-to-pay,
acceleration of production, 28, 204 217
acceleration of savings, 367, 369 average productivity, 92
acceleration of use of labor, 255 average revenues from a product, 168
acceleration of utility, 121, 263, average unit costs, 160, 163, 164
366, 372 average utility, 112
accumulated amount of production, average variable unit costs, 160, 163,
69, 161 164
accumulation function of production, average velocity, 60
76, 82 average velocity of production, 71,
agent-base modeling, 20 75, 161
aggregate demand relation, 145–7, axioms of consumer behaviour,
166 99–100
alternative cost, 44, 103 axioms of economics, 5–14
inertial mass of price, 190, 245 Lagrangian coefficient, 126, 430, 433
inertial mass of production, 181, 183, Lagrangian function, 125, 361
219, 237 law of large numbers, 14
inertial mass of saving, 382 law of non-increasing marginal
inferior good, 149 productivity, 94
inflation, 54, 63 law of non-increasing marginal utility,
instantaneous acceleration of 113
production, 81–2, 180, 183 legal tender, 326
instantaneous acceleration of liability, 329
utility, 121 limit value, 407
instantaneous velocity of production, linear approximation of nonlinear
73–4, 76 relation, 148
instantaneous velocity vector, 86 logarithmic function, 410–11
integral calculus, 438–41
integral function, 438–9
interbank deposit, 333 M
interest differential, 331, 376 macroeconomic thinking, 18
interest factor, 294, 295 marginal costs, 160, 163, 174, 176,
interest rate, 65–8 207
interest rate risk, 304, 339 marginal costs of labor, 253
internal rate of return, 303, 339 marginal productivity, 92, 275
interval scale, 40, 109, 448–50 marginal productivity of capital, 292
inventory, 158 marginal productivity of labor, 252,
inverse demand function, 144, 150 269, 286
inverse function, 405–6 marginal revenue, 169, 171, 172,
inverse supply function, 198 174, 175
investment, 158, 313 marginal utility, 112, 116, 131
irrational behaviour, 15 marginal utility of budgeted funds,
124, 126
marginal willingness-to-pay, 44, 111,
K 124, 126–9, 248, 255, 261, 265,
kinematics, 68 275, 343, 346, 350, 430–3
kinematics of production, 162 market supply relation, 198
market value of a good, 45
marxian political economics, 5
L maturity, 332
labor, 2 maturity transformation, 331
labor demand relation, 273, 283 maximum, 413
labor supply relation, 273 measurement, 444
462 Subject Index
U
unit costs, 160 Z
unit labor costs, 253 zero-coupon bond, 339