Park (2007)
Park (2007)
Park (2007)
Scott H. Irwin
Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics,
University of Illinois
Abstract. The purpose of this paper is to review the evidence on the profitability
of technical analysis. The empirical literature is categorized into two groups,
‘early’ and ‘modern’ studies, according to the characteristics of testing procedures.
Early studies indicate that technical trading strategies are profitable in foreign
exchange markets and futures markets, but not in stock markets. Modern studies
indicate that technical trading strategies consistently generate economic profits
in a variety of speculative markets at least until the early 1990s. Among a total
of 95 modern studies, 56 studies find positive results regarding technical trading
strategies, 20 studies obtain negative results, and 19 studies indicate mixed results.
Despite the positive evidence on the profitability of technical trading strategies,
most empirical studies are subject to various problems in their testing procedures,
e.g. data snooping, ex post selection of trading rules or search technologies,
and difficulties in estimation of risk and transaction costs. Future research must
address these deficiencies in testing in order to provide conclusive evidence on
the profitability of technical trading strategies.
Keywords. Market efficiency; Technical analysis; Speculative markets; Trading
systems
1. Introduction
Technical analysis is a method of forecasting price movements using past prices,
volume and/or open interest.1 Pring (2002, p. 2), a leading technical analyst, provides
a more specific definition:
The technical approach to investment is essentially a reflection of the idea that
prices move in trends that are determined by the changing attitudes of investors
toward a variety of economic, monetary, political, and psychological forces. The
art of technical analysis, for it is an art, is to identify a trend reversal at a relatively
early stage and ride on that trend until the weight of the evidence shows or proves
that the trend has reversed.
Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
THE PROFITABILITY OF TECHNICAL ANALYSIS 787
Foreign
Stock exchange Futures Relative
Year markets markets markets Total frequency (%)
1960–1964 3 0 3 6 4.4
1965–1969 6 1 1 8 5.8
1970–1974 4 0 3 7 5.1
1975–1979 2 3 2 7 5.1
1980–1984 2 1 6 9 6.6
1985–1989 4 3 7 14 10.2
1990–1994 5 3 2 10 7.3
1995–1999 18 13 1 32 23.4
2000–2004b 22 20 2 44 32.1
Total 66 44 27 137 100.0
a
Studies on equity (index) futures and options and foreign exchange futures are categorized into
‘stock markets’ and ‘foreign exchange markets’ studies, respectively. ‘Futures markets’ studies
include studies on other individual futures markets or various groups of futures markets.
b
Through August 2004.
and discuss the consistency and reliability of evidence on technical trading profits
across markets and over time. Previous empirical studies are categorized into two
groups, ‘early’ studies and ‘modern’ studies, based on an overall evaluation of each
study in terms of the number of technical trading systems considered, treatment
of transaction costs, risk, data snooping problems, parameter optimization, out-
of-sample verification, and statistical tests adopted. Empirical studies surveyed
include those that test technical trading systems, trading rules formulated by genetic
algorithms or some statistical models (e.g. ARIMA), and chart patterns that can
be represented algebraically. Special attention is paid to testing procedures used in
empirical studies and identification of their salient features and weaknesses. This
will improve understanding of the profitability of technical trading strategies and
suggest directions for future research.
after deducting transaction costs, Jensen’s definition implies that market efficiency
may be tested by considering the net profits and risk of trading strategies based on
information set θt .
Jensen also subdivided the efficient markets hypothesis into three types based on
definitions of the information set θt :
1. weak form efficiency, where the information set θt is limited to the information
contained in the past price history of the market as of time t;
2. semi-strong form efficiency, where the information set θt is all information
that is publicly available at time t (this includes, of course, the past history of
prices so the weak form is just a restricted version of the semi-strong form);
3. strong form efficiency, where the information set θt is all public and private
information available at time t (this includes the past history of prices and all
other public information, so weak and semi-strong forms are simply restricted
versions of the strong form).
Timmermann and Granger (2004, p. 25) extended Jensen’s definition by specifying
how the information variables in θt are used to generate forecasts. In their definition,
a market is efficient with respect to information set θt , search technologies St and
forecasting models Mt if it is impossible to make economic profits by trading on the
basis of signals produced from a forecasting model in Mt , defined over predictor
variables in the information set θt and selected using a search technology in St .5
A key implication of the efficient market hypothesis is that any attempt to make
profits by exploiting currently available information is futile. The market price
already reflects all that can be known from available information. Therefore, the
expected return for technical trading rules based only on the public record of past
prices is zero. This logic was stated in colourful terms by Samuelson (1965, p. 44):
. . . there is no way of making an expected profit by extrapolating past changes in
the futures price, by chart or any other esoteric devices of magic or mathematics.
The market quotation already contains in itself all that can be known about the
future and in that sense has discounted future contingencies as much as is humanly
possible.
3. Empirical Studies
The earliest empirical study included in this review is Donchian (1960). Although the
boundary between early and modern studies is blurred, Lukac et al.’s (1988) work is
regarded here as the first modern study because it is among the first to substantially
improve upon early studies in several important ways. This study considers 12
technical trading systems, conducts out-of-sample verification for optimized trading
rules with a statistical significance test, and measures the performance of trading
rules after adjusting for transaction costs and risk. Thus, early studies are assumed to
commence with Donchian’s study (1960) and include studies through 1987, while
modern studies begin with Lukac et al.’s (1988) study and cover studies through
August 2004.
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
790 PARK AND IRWIN
Along the same lines, Jensen and Benington (1970, p. 470) state that:
. . . given enough computer time, we are sure that we can find a mechanical trading
rule which works on a table of random numbers – provided of course that we are
allowed to test the rule on the same table of numbers which we used to discover
the rule. We realize of course that the rule would prove useless on any other table
of random numbers. . .
Indeed, when typical technical trading rules such as filters and moving averages
are applied to randomly generated price series, it turns out that the rules generate net
profits for some of the random series by chance (Dooley and Shafer, 1983; Tomek
and Querin, 1984).
To deal with data snooping problems, Jensen (1967) proposes a validation
procedure where the best-performing trading model or models are identified in the
first half of the sample period, and then are validated on the rest of the sample
period. Optimizing trading rules is important because actual traders are likely to
choose the best-performing rules in advance. Only Jensen and Benington (1970)
follow an optimization and out-of-sample validation procedure, and moreover, only
a few early studies (Irwin and Uhrig, 1984; Taylor, 1986) optimize trading rules.
Criteria
Trading Out-of- Data
Number of Representative Transaction Risk rule sample Statistical snooping Distinctive
Category studiesa study costs adjustment optimization tests tests addressed features
√ √ √ √ √
Standard 24 Lukac et al. Conduct parameter optimization
(1988) √ √ and out-of-sample tests
Model-based 21 Brock et al. Use model-based bootstrap
on these calculations. However, if the serial dependence of the actual return series
is mis-specified in the null models or is highly complex, the model-based bootstrap
method may provide inconsistent estimates (Maddala and Li, 1996; Ruiz and Pascual,
2002).
Brock et al. (1992) apply two technical trading systems, a moving average
oscillator and a trading range break-out (resistance and support levels), to the DJIA
over 1897–1986. They recognize the potential for data snooping bias in technical
trading studies and attempt to mitigate the problem by selecting technical trading
rules that were popular over a long time period, reporting results from all trading
strategies, utilizing a long data series, and emphasizing the robustness of results
across various non-overlapping sub-periods.
Results indicate that buy (sell) signals from the technical trading rules generate
positive (negative) returns across all 26 rules and four sub-periods tested. Thus, all
the buy–sell differences are positive and outperform the buy-and-hold strategy. For
example, buy (sell) returns are all positive (negative) for the variable-length moving
average rules, with an annual return of 12% (−7%). As a result, all the buy–sell
spreads are positive with an annual return of 19%, which compares favourably with
a buy-and-hold return of 5%. Moreover, buy signals that generate higher average
returns than sell signals have a lower standard deviation than sell signals. This
implies that technical trading returns cannot be explained by risk. Hence, Brock
et al. (1992, p. 1758) conclude their study by writing, ‘. . . the returns-generating
process of stocks is probably more complicated than suggested by the various studies
using linear models. It is quite possible that technical rules pick up some of the
hidden patterns.’ Brock et al., however, report only gross returns of each trading
rule without adjustment for transaction costs, so their results are not sufficient to
prove that technical trading rules generate economic profits.
Bessembinder and Chan (1998) test the same trading rules as in Brock et al.
(1992) on dividend-adjusted DJIA data over 1926–1991. Incorporating dividends
tends to reduce returns on short sales and, in turn, may decrease technical trading
returns (Fama and Blume, 1966). In an attempt to avoid data snooping problems,
Bessembinder and Chan evaluate the profitability and statistical significance of
returns on portfolios of the trading rules as well as returns on individual trading
rules. For the full sample period, the average buy–sell difference across all rules
is 4.4% per year (break-even one-way transaction costs of 0.39% per transaction)
with a bootstrap p-value of zero. Non-synchronous trading with a 1-day lag
reduces the difference to 3.2% (break-even one-way transaction costs of 0.29%
per transaction) with a significant bootstrap p-value of 0.002. However, break-even
one-way transaction costs decline over time, and for the most recent sub-period
(1976–1991) total 0.22% (without trade lag), less than estimated one-way transaction
costs of 0.24%–0.26%. Thus, it is unlikely that traders could have used Brock et
al.’s trading rules to earn net profits after transaction costs.
The results of the model-based bootstrap studies vary across markets and sample
periods. In general, technical trading rules are profitable even after transaction
costs for stock indices (spot or futures) in emerging markets (Bessembinder and
Chan, 1995; Raj and Thurston, 1996; Ito, 1999; Ratner and Leal, 1999; Coutts
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
THE PROFITABILITY OF TECHNICAL ANALYSIS 797
and Cheung, 2000; Gunasekarage and Power, 2001), while profits for stock indices
in developed markets are negligible after transaction costs or have declined over
time (Hudson et al., 1996; Mills, 1997; Bessembinder and Chan, 1998; Ito, 1999;
Day and Wang, 2002). For example, Ratner and Leal (1999) document that Brock
et al.’s moving average rules generate statistically significant net returns in four
equity markets (Mexico, Taiwan, Thailand and the Philippines) over the 1982–
1995 period. Mills (1997) shows that mean daily returns from moving average rules
applied to British equity markets are insignificantly different from a buy-and-hold
return over 1975–1994. Returns are much higher than buy-and-hold returns for the
1935–1954 and 1955–1974 periods. Levich and Thomas (1993), LeBaron (1999),
Neely (2002) and Saacke (2002) all report substantial profits of moving average
rules in foreign exchange markets. For example, LeBaron (1999) finds that a 150-
day moving average rule generates Sharpe ratios of 0.60–0.98 after transaction costs
of 0.1% per round-trip in mark and yen markets during 1979–1992. The reported
Sharpe ratios are much greater than those for buy-and-hold strategies on aggregate
US stock portfolios (0.3–0.4).
and a bootstrap reality check p-value of zero, suggesting their findings are robust
to data snooping biases. Out-of-sample results are disappointing by comparison.
Over the 10-year out-of-sample period (1987–1996), the best rule (a 5-day moving
average rule) from the full universe over 1897–1986 generates a mean return of
only 2.8% per year with a nominal p-value of 0.32, indicating that the best rule does
not continue to generate an economically and statistically significant return in the
subsequent period.9 The best rule for the S&P 500 futures index over 1984–1996
generates a mean return of 9.4% per year and a bootstrap reality check p-value of
0.91, suggesting that the return is a result of data snooping. The poor out-of-sample
performance of technical trading rules relative to in-sample performance led Sullivan
et al. to conclude that the efficiency of stock markets had improved in recent years.
Sullivan et al. (2003) enlarge the full set of trading rules by combining their earlier
set of technical trading rules with calendar frequency trading rules first tested by
Sullivan et al. (2001). The calendar frequency rules are designed to exploit calendar
effects (e.g. the Monday effect, the holiday effect and the January effect) documented
in the finance literature. For DJIA data, the best of the augmented universe of trading
rules (a 2-day-on-balance volume rule) generates an annual mean return of 17.1%
over the full sample period, 1897–1998. The bootstrap reality check p-value is zero
for the best trading rule and it outperforms a buy-and-hold strategy (annual mean
return of 4.8%). However, over a recent period, 1987–1996, the best rule (a week-
of-the-month strategy) generates only slightly higher mean returns (17.3% per year)
than a buy-and-hold return (13.6%). Moreover, the return is statistically insignificant
with a bootstrap reality check p-value of 0.98. Similar results are found for the
S&P 500 futures data. Hence, Sullivan et al. (2003) argue that it may be premature
to conclude that both technical trading rules and calendar rules outperform a buy-
and-hold benchmark in the stock market. Qi and Wu (2002) also apply White’s
(2000) methodology to seven foreign exchange rates during 1973–1998 and find
that technical trading rules generate substantial profits (7.2%–12.2%) in five of the
seven markets even after adjustment for transaction costs and systematic risk.
One issue with White’s bootstrap methodology is the difficulty of constructing the
full ‘universe’ of technical trading rules required by the methodology. Sullivan et al.
(1999) assume that rules from five technical trading systems represent the full set of
technical trading rules. However, there may be numerous different technical trading
systems not included in their full set of technical trading rules. If a set of trading
rules tested is a subset of an even larger universe of rules, White’s bootstrap reality
check methodology delivers a p-value biased toward zero under the assumption that
included rules in the universe performed relatively well during the historical sample
period.
Another issue is that the null hypothesis in White’s bootstrap methodology consists
of multiple inequalities, which leads to a composite null hypothesis. One of the
complications of testing a composite hypothesis is that the asymptotic distribution of
the test statistic is not unique under the null hypothesis. White solves this ambiguity
in the null distribution by applying the least favourable configuration (LFC), also
known as the points least favourable to the alternative hypothesis. However, Hansen
(2003) shows that such a LFC-based test has limitations because it does not ordinarily
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
THE PROFITABILITY OF TECHNICAL ANALYSIS 799
in 1936, 1941 and so on, up to 1981. For example, the first training period is from
1929 to 1933, the selection period from 1934 to 1935, and the test period from 1936
to 1995. For each of the 10 training periods, 10 trials are executed.
Out-of-sample results indicate that trading rules optimized by genetic program-
ming fail to generate consistent excess returns over a simple buy-and-hold strategy
after adjustment for transaction costs. After considering transaction costs of 0.25%,
average excess returns are negative for nine of the 10 periods. Even after lowering
transaction costs to 0.10%, average excess returns are negative for six out of the
10 periods. For most test periods, only a few trading rules generate positive excess
returns. However, in most of the training periods, the optimal trading rules show
some forecasting ability because the difference between average daily returns during
in- and out-of-the-market days is positive, and the volatility during ‘in’ days is
generally lower than during ‘out’ days. Allen and Karjalainen (1999) conclude that
the results are generally consistent with market efficiency.
Ready (2002) compares the performance of technical trading rules formed by
genetic programming to Brock et al.’s (1992) moving average rules for dividend-
adjusted DJIA data. Brock et al.’s best trading rule (1/150 moving average without
a band) for the 1963–1986 period generates substantially higher excess returns than
the average of trading rules identified by genetic programming after transaction
costs. However, the moving average rule underperforms genetically optimized rules
over 1957–1962. Thus, it seems unlikely that Brock et al.’s moving average rules
would have been chosen by a hypothetical trader at the end of 1962. Moreover,
the genetically optimized rules perform poorly for each out-of-sample period, i.e.
1963–1986 and 1987–2000. Ready (2002, p. 43) concludes that ‘. . . the apparent
success (after transaction costs) of the Brock et al.’s (1992) moving average rules is
a spurious result of data snooping’.
The results of other genetic programming studies are mixed. Wang (2000) and
Neely (2003) report that genetically optimized trading rules fail to outperform a buy-
and-hold strategy in both S&P 500 spot and futures markets. Neely (2003) shows
that genetic trading rules produce negative mean excess returns over a buy-and-hold
strategy during the entire out-of-sample period, 1936–1995. In contrast, Neely et
al. (1997) and Neely and Weller (1999, 2001) report successful performance of
genetic trading rules in foreign exchange markets, although trading profits appear
to gradually decline over time. Neely and Weller’s (2001) findings indicate that
technical trading profits net of transaction costs for four major foreign exchange
rates (i.e. mark, yen, pound, Swiss franc) range from 1.7%–8.3% per year over
1981–1992, but are near zero or negative, except for the yen, over 1993–1998.
Using intra-day data for 1996 and realistic trading hours and transaction costs,
Neely and Weller (2003) generate break-even transaction costs of less than 0.02%
for most major foreign exchange rates using genetic trading rules. Roberts (2003)
finds that genetic trading rules generate a statistically significant mean net return
(a daily mean return of $1.07 per contract) in comparison to a buy-and-hold return
(−$3.30) in wheat futures over 1978–1998. For corn and soybean futures markets,
however, genetic trading rules produce both negative mean returns and negative
ratios of profit to maximum drawdown. In sum, technical trading rules formulated
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
THE PROFITABILITY OF TECHNICAL ANALYSIS 801
neural network model as an additional regressor. For the same DJIA data as used
in Gençay (1998a), the non-linear model produces a 12% forecast gain over the
benchmark (an OLS model with lagged returns as regressors) and provides much
higher correct sign predictions (an average of 62%) than other linear and non-linear
models.
Fernández-Rodrı́guez et al. (2000) apply a feed-forward neural network to the
Madrid Stock index, finding that a technical trading rule based on the feed-forward
network outperforms a buy-and-hold strategy before transaction costs. Sosvilla-
Rivero et al. (2002) also show that technical trading rules based on a nearest
neighbour regression earn net returns during 1982–1996 of 35% and 28% for the
mark and yen, respectively. They also demonstrate that eliminating US intervention
days decreases net returns substantially, to −10% and −28% for the mark and yen,
respectively. Fernández-Rodrı́guez et al. (2003) find that trading rules based on the
nearest neighbour model are superior to moving average rules in European exchange
markets for 1978–1994. The non-linear trading rules generate statistically significant
annual net returns of 1.5%–20.1% for the Danish krona, French franc, Dutch guilder
and Italian lira. However, Hamm and Brorsen (2000) develop a neural network
trading model for hard red winter wheat and mark futures and find unfavourable
results. With lagged prices as inputs to the neural network, they cannot reject the
null hypothesis that gross or net trading returns are less than or equal to zero.
Non-linear studies generally provide positive evidence about the usefulness of
technical trading rules in stock and foreign exchange markets. However, non-linear
studies have a similar problem to that of genetic programming studies. That is, as
suggested by Timmermann and Granger (2004), it may be inappropriate to apply a
non-linear approach developed in recent years to reveal the profitability of technical
trading rules in the 1970s or 1980s. Gençay and Stengos (1997) also show that
simple methods such as the one-step-ahead nearest neighbour estimator provide
better forecasts than more complex neural network models. Finally, neural network
solutions are not unique, which makes it difficult to replicate the results of previous
studies.
described as a sequence of three peaks with the highest in the middle. The centre peak
is referred to as ‘head’, the left and right peaks around the head as ‘shoulders’, and a
straight line connecting the troughs separating the head from right and left shoulders
is ‘the neckline’. Head-and-shoulders can occur both at peaks and at troughs, where
they are called ‘tops’ and ‘bottoms’, respectively. Chang and Osler (1999) formulate
an algorithm for head-and-shoulders identification and then establish a strategy for
entering and exiting positions based on such recognition. The entry position is taken
when price breaks the neckline, while the timing of exit is determined by stop-loss,
bounce possibility, or particular holding periods.
Chang and Osler find that head-and-shoulders rules generate statistically signifi-
cant returns of about 13% and 19% per year for the mark and yen, respectively, but
not for other exchange rates. The trading returns are substantially higher than either
the annual buy-and-hold returns or the annual average return (6.8%) on the S&P 500
index over the sample period. Returns for the mark and yen also are significantly
greater than those derived from 10,000 simulated random walk bootstrap samples
and remain substantial even after subtracting transaction costs of 0.05% per round-
trip, incorporating interest differentials, and adjustment for risk. Trading returns for
the mark and yen also appear robust to changes in the parameters of the head-and-
shoulders recognition algorithm, changes in the sample period, and the assumption
that exchange rates follow a GARCH(1, 1) process rather than a random walk.
However, the observed performance of head-and-shoulders rules appears to be easily
dominated by the performance of moving average and momentum rules in terms of
total (accumulated) profits and Sharpe ratios. The simple technical trading rules
generate statistically significant and substantially larger returns than the head-and-
shoulders rules for all six foreign exchange rates.
Lo et al. (2000) evaluate the usefulness of 10 chart patterns in predicting stock
prices: the head-and-shoulders and inverse head-and-shoulders, broadening tops and
bottoms, triangle tops and bottoms, rectangle tops and bottoms, and double tops
and bottoms. For NYSE/AMEX stocks, goodness-of-fitness test results indicate
that relative frequencies of returns conditional on signals from five of the 10 chart
patterns are significantly different from relative frequencies of unconditional returns.
In contrast, all 10 patterns are statistically significant for Nasdaq stocks. Volume
trends provide little incremental information for both stock markets. Lo et al. (2000,
p. 1753) conclude, ‘Although this does not necessarily imply that technical analysis
can be used to generate excess trading profits, it does raise the possibility that
technical analysis can add value to the investment process’. Dawson and Steeley
(2003) apply Lo et al.’s approach to UK stock data and show that ‘informativeness’
of chart patterns does not necessarily lead to trading profits. They find that average
market-adjusted returns are negative for the technical patterns, even though return
distributions conditional on chart pattern signals are significantly different from
unconditional distributions.
Caginalp and Laurent (1998) report that ‘candlestick’ reversal patterns generate
substantial profits in stock markets compared to a buy-and-hold strategy. Specifically,
down-to-up reversal patterns produce an average return of 0.9% during a 2-day
holding period for S&P 500 stocks over 1992–1996. Leigh et al. (2002a, 2002b)
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
804 PARK AND IRWIN
find that bull flag patterns generate positive excess returns (before transaction costs)
for the NYSE Composite Index over a buy-and-hold strategy. However, Curcio et
al. (1997), Guillaume (2000) and Lucke (2003) all show limited evidence of the
profitability of technical patterns in foreign exchange markets, with trading profits
from the patterns declining over time (Guillaume, 2000). Overall, the results of chart
pattern studies vary depending on patterns, markets and sample periods tested, but
suggest that some chart patterns might be profitable in stock and foreign exchange
markets. Nevertheless, all studies in this category, except for Leigh et al. (2002a),
do not conduct parameter optimization and out-of-sample tests and do not address
data snooping problems.
Number of studies
Studies Positive Mixed Negative Profit range Comments
A. Stock markets
Standard 2 2 2 4%–17%b • For the DJIA, which is the most frequently tested series
Model-based bootstrap 7 4 3 (1897–1998) in the literature, results vary considerably depending on
Number of studies
Studies Positive Mixed Negative Profit range Comments
c
Net of transactions costs.
807
808 PARK AND IRWIN
Grossman and Stiglitz (1976, 1980) represent the most influential work on noisy
rational expectations equilibrium models. They demonstrate that no agent in a
competitive market has an incentive to collect and analyse costly information if
current price reflects all available information, and as a result the competitive
market breaks down. However, Grossman and Stiglitz’s model supports weak-
form market efficiency in which no profits are made based on price history (i.e.
technical analysis) because it is assumed that uninformed traders have rational
expectations. In contrast, models developed by Hellwig (1982), Brown and Jennings
(1989), Grundy and McNichols (1989) and Blume et al. (1994) allow past
prices to carry useful information for achieving positive profits in a speculative
market.
Brown and Jennings (1989) propose a two-period noisy rational expectations
model in which the current price is dominated as an information source by a weighted
average of past and current prices. More specifically, if the current price depends on
noise (i.e. unobserved current supply of a risky asset) as well as private information
of market participants, it cannot be a sufficient statistic for private information. Noise
in the current equilibrium price does not allow full revelation of all publicly available
information available in price histories. Therefore, past prices together with current
prices enable investors to make more accurate inferences about past and present
signals than do current prices alone.
As another example, Blume et al. (1994) propose an equilibrium model that
emphasizes the informational role of volume. Unlike previous equilibrium models
that consider the aggregate supply of a risky asset as the source of noise, their
model assumes the source of noise is the quality of information. Blume et al.
show that volume provides information about the quality of traders’ information
that cannot be conveyed by prices, and thus observing the price and the volume
statistics together can be more informative than observing the price statistic alone.
Technical analysis is valuable because current market statistics may be insufficient
to reveal all information.
Noise traders buy when prices rise and sell when prices fall, like technical
traders or ‘trend chasers’. For example, when noise traders follow positive feedback
strategies (buy when prices rise), this increases aggregate demand for an asset and
results in a further price increase. Arbitrageurs may conclude that the asset is mis-
priced and above its fundamental value, and therefore sell it short. According to
De Long et al. (1990a), however, this form of arbitrage is limited because it is
always possible that the market will perform very well (fundamental risk) and
that the asset will be even more overpriced by noise traders in the near future
because they will become even more optimistic. As long as such risks are created by
the unpredictability of noise traders’ opinions, arbitrage by sophisticated investors
will be reduced even in the absence of fundamental risk. A consequence is that
sophisticated or rational investors do not fully counter the effects of the noise traders.
Rather, it may be optimal for arbitrageurs to jump on the ‘bandwagon’ themselves.
Arbitrageurs optimally buy the asset that noise traders have purchased and sell much
later when price rises even higher. Therefore, although arbitrageurs ultimately force
prices to return to fundamental levels, in the short run they amplify the effect of
noise traders (De Long et al., 1990b).11
In feedback models, noise traders may be more aggressive than arbitrageurs
due to overly optimistic (or overly pessimistic) views on markets, and thus bear
more risk with associated higher expected returns. Despite excessive risk taking and
consumption, noise traders may survive as a group in the long run and dominate the
market in terms of wealth (De Long et al., 1991; Slezak, 2003). Hence, feedback
models suggest that technical trading profits may be available even in the long run if
technical trading strategies (buy when prices rise and sell when prices fall) are based
on noise or ‘popular models’ and not on information such as news or fundamental
factors (Shleifer and Summers, 1990).
traders and ‘technical’ traders. Price moves linearly with excess demand, which in
turn is proportional to the excess number of buyers drawn from both regular and
technical traders. In the absence of technical traders, price dynamics form slowly
decaying oscillations around an asymptotic value. However, inclusion of technical
traders in the model increases the amplitude of price oscillations. The rationale
behind this result is as follows. If technical traders believe price will fall, they sell,
and thus excess demand decreases. As a result, price decreases and the chartist
component forces regular traders to sell. This leads price to decrease further until
the fundamentalist priorities of regular traders become dominant again. The opposite
situation occurs if technical traders make a buy decision based on their analysis.
Osler (2003) finds two critical asymmetries in the data that support the predictions
of technical analysis. The first is that executed take-profit orders cluster more
strongly at numbers ending in 00 than executed stop-loss orders. The second is that
executed stop-loss buy (sell) orders are more strongly clustered just above (below)
round numbers. According to Osler, clustering of order flows at round numbers is
possible because (1) the use of round numbers reduces the time and errors incurred
in the transaction process, (2) round numbers may be easier to remember and to
manipulate mentally and (3) people may simply prefer round numbers without any
reasoning.
Kavajecz and Odders-White (2004) provide a similar explanation for support and
resistance levels by estimating limit order books in the stock market (i.e. NYSE) and
analysing the relation to support and resistance. Regression results show that support
and resistance levels are positively and statistically significantly correlated with
high cumulative depth, even after controlling for other current market conditions. In
particular, technical indicator levels are statistically significant for 42% to 73% of
the stocks when measures of cumulative depth in the limit order book such as mode
and near depth ratio are used as the dependent variable. Furthermore, the results
of Granger causality tests and analyses on the flow of newly placed limit orders
suggest that support and resistance levels tend to identify clusters of orders (high
depth) already in place on the limit order book.
Kavajecz and Odders-White also show that sell (buy) signals of moving average
rules, generated when the short moving average penetrates the long moving average
from above (below), correspond to a shift in quoted prices toward sell-side (buy-side)
liquidity levels and away from buy-side (sell-side) levels. That is, moving average
signals appear to uncover information about the ‘skewness’ of liquidity between
the two sides of the limit order book. Hence, Kavajecz and Odders-White (2004,
p. 1066) conclude that ‘. . . the connection between technical analysis and limit order
book depth is driven by technical analysis being able to identify prices with high
cumulative depth already in place on the limit order book’. The explanation of
technical trading profits by order flows is corroborated in recent years by the fact
that order flow analysis has gained in popularity among foreign exchange traders
(Gehrig and Menkhoff, 2003, 2004).
Marquering et al., 2006) demonstrate that many of the well-known market anomalies
in the stock market attenuate, disappear or reverse after they are documented in the
academic literature. In the literature on technical trading rules, several prominent
studies (e.g. Sweeney, 1986; Taylor, 1986; Lukac et al., 1988; Brock et al., 1992),
all of which document substantial technical trading profits, were published during the
mid-1980s and the early 1990s. In this context, an increase in the use of technical
trading rules among investors and traders over the 1990s may have lowered or
even eliminated profitable technical trading opportunities. The massive increase in
hedge fund and CTA investment during the 1990s is consistent with this argument.
Investment in CTAs (and other ‘managed’ futures accounts) alone increased from
about $7 billion at the beginning of the decade to over $40 billion at the end.12
The second possible explanation of temporary inefficiencies is structural change
in markets. At a basic level, all technical trading rules depend on some form of
sluggish reaction to new information as it enters the market. Structural changes in
markets have the potential to alter the speed with which prices react to information
and reach a new equilibrium. For example, cheaper computing power, the rise of
electronic trading and the advent of discount brokerage firms has probably lowered
transaction costs and increased liquidity in many markets (Sullivan et al., 1999).
These changes may have increased the speed of market price movements, and in
turn, reduced the profitability of technical trading rules. Kidd and Brorsen (2004) also
argue that economy-wide changes, such as freer trade, better economic predictions
and fewer major shocks to the economy, lower price volatility and the corresponding
demand for technical speculators to move markets to equilibrium. In order to test
this hypothesis, Kidd and Brorsen compute sample statistics for 17 futures markets
across 1975–1990 and 1991–2001. Price volatility generally decreases across the
two periods and kurtosis (extremeness) of price changes increases while markets are
closed. The authors argue that both changes are consistent with a reduction in the
profitability of technical analysis due to economy-wide structural changes.
1986; Lukac et al., 1988; Taylor, 1992; Levich and Thomas, 1993; Neely et al.,
1997). Results for time-varying premiums are mixed. Taylor (1992) investigated
whether returns on a portfolio of optimal technical trading rules in foreign exchange
futures markets are compensation for bearing time-varying risk premiums. Through
preliminary tests based on McCurdy and Morgan’s (1992) work, he finds that time-
varying risk premiums cannot explain excess returns of technical trading rules.
Okunev and White (2003) report a similar result in which trading profits for their
return-based relative strength rules (also called a momentum strategy) are not a
reward for bearing time-varying risk. In contrast, Kho (1996) and Sapp (2004) show
that a large part of technical trading returns on foreign exchange markets can be
explained by time-varying risk premiums estimated from versions of the conditional
CAPM. These seemingly contradictory results may be caused by different data
frequencies (daily, weekly or monthly), asset pricing model specifications, market
proxies, technical trading systems, and other testing procedures.
It should be noted that the above risk measures have several limitations. For
example, the Sharpe ratio penalizes the variability of profitable returns exactly the
same as the variability of losses, despite the fact that investors are more concerned
about downside volatility in returns rather than total volatility, i.e. the standard
deviation. The CAPM is also known to have a joint hypothesis problem. Namely,
when abnormal returns (positive intercept) are found, researchers cannot differentiate
whether markets are truly inefficient or the CAPM is mis-specified. It is well known
that the CAPM and other multifactor asset pricing models, such as the Fama–French
three-factor model, are subject to mis-specification problems (Fama, 1998).
about $40 per trade, much larger than costs estimates based on statistical bid–ask
estimators. In lieu of obtaining appropriate data sources regarding bid–ask spreads,
plausible alternatives include the use of transaction costs greater than the actual
historical commissions (Schwager, 1996) or assuming several possible scenarios for
transaction costs.
Other market microstructure factors that may affect technical trading returns are
non-synchronous trading and daily price limits. Technical trading studies typically
assume that trades can be executed at closing prices on the day when trading signals
are generated. However, Day and Wang (2002, p. 433) investigate the impact of non-
synchronous trading on technical trading returns for the DJIA and argue that ‘. . . if
buy signals tend to occur when the closing level of the DJIA is less than the true index
level, estimated profits will be overstated by the convergence of closing prices to their
true values at the market open’. This problem may be mitigated by using either the
estimated ‘true’ closing levels for asset prices (e.g. Day and Wang, 2002) or the next
day’s closing prices (e.g. Brock et al., 1992; Taylor, 1992; Bessembinder and Chan,
1998). In addition, price movements are occasionally locked at the daily allowable
limits, particularly in futures markets. Since trend-following trading rules typically
generate buy (sell) signals in up (down) trends, the daily price limits generally imply
that buy (sell) trades will be actually executed at higher (lower) prices than those at
which trading signals were generated. This may result in seriously overstated trading
returns if trades are assumed to be executed at the ‘locked’ limit price levels.
and trace the out-of-sample performance of optimal rules, a researcher may obtain a
successful result by deliberately investigating a number of combinations of in- and
out-of-sample optimization periods and selecting the combination that provides the
most favourable result. Prior selection of only one combination of in- and out-of-
sample periods may be a safeguard, but this selection is also likely to be strongly
affected by similar previous research.
A different form of data snooping occurs when researchers consider only popular
trading rules, as in Brock et al. (1992). Since Brock et al.’s moving average and
trading range break-out rules have obtained their popularity over a long history they
are likely to be subject to ‘survivorship’ bias. In other words, if a large number of
trading rules have been investigated over time some rules may produce abnormal
returns by chance even though they do not possess genuine forecasting power.
Statistical inference based only on the surviving trading rules may cause a form
of data snooping bias because it does not account for the full set of initial trading
rules, most of which are likely to have performed poorly (Bessembinder and Chan,
1998; Sullivan et al., 1999, 2003).
As noted in earlier sections, still another form of data snooping is the application
of a new search procedure, such as genetic programming or nearest neighbour neural
networks, to sample periods before the development of the procedure (Cooper
and Gulen, 2004; Timmermann and Granger, 2004). Cooper and Gulen (2004,
p. 7) argue that ‘. . . it would be inappropriate to use a computer intensive genetic
algorithm to uncover evidence of predictability before the algorithm or computer
was available’. Most genetic programming studies and non-linear studies are subject
to this problem.
genetic programming; (v) non-linear; (vi) chart patterns and (vii) other. Among a
total of 95 modern studies, 56 studies find positive results regarding technical trading
strategies, 20 studies obtain negative results, and 19 studies indicate mixed results.
Modern studies also indicate that technical trading rules yielded economic profits in
US stock markets until the late 1980s, but not thereafter. In foreign exchange markets,
technical trading rules were profitable at least until the early 1990s. Technical trading
rules applied to futures markets were profitable until the mid-1980s.
Technical trading profits in the 1970s and 1980s can be explained by several
theoretical models and/or empirical regularities. Noisy rational expectations equi-
librium models, feedback models and herding models postulate that price adjusts
sluggishly to new information due to noise in the market, traders’ sentiments or
herding behaviour. Under chaos theory, technical analysis may be equivalent to a
method for non-linear prediction in a high dimension (or chaotic) system. Various
empirical factors, such as central bank interventions, clustering of order flows,
temporary market inefficiencies, time-varying risk premiums, market microstructure
deficiencies, and data snooping biases, have also been proposed as the source or
explanation for technical trading profits.
Notwithstanding the positive evidence about profitability, improved procedures
for testing technical trading strategies, and plausible theoretical explanations, many
academics still appear to be sceptical about technical trading rules. For example,
in a recent textbook on asset pricing, Cochrane (2001, p. 25) argues that, ‘Despite
decades of dredging the data, and the popularity of media reports that purport to
explain where markets are going, trading rules that reliably survive transactions
costs and do not implicitly expose the investor to risk have not yet been reliably
demonstrated’. This statement suggests the scepticism is based on data snooping
problems and potentially insignificant economic profits after appropriate adjustment
for transaction costs and risk.
There are two basic approaches to addressing the problem of data snooping. The
first is to simply replicate a previous study on a new set of data (e.g. Lo and
MacKinlay, 1990; Schwert, 2003). This approach is borrowed from the classical
experimental approach to generating scientific evidence. That is, if similar results
are found using new data and the same procedures as in the original study, more
confidence can be placed in the original results.13 To date, only one previous study
replicates earlier technical trading results on new data (Sullivan et al., 1999). For
purposes of replication, the following three conditions should be satisfied: (1) the
markets and trading systems tested in the original study should be comprehensive,
in the sense that results can be considered broadly representative of the actual
use of technical systems, (2) testing procedures must be carefully documented,
so they can be ‘written in stone’ at the point in time the study was published,
and (3) the publication date of the original work should be sufficiently far in
the past that a follow-up study can have a reasonable sample size. The second
approach for dealing with data snooping is White’s (2000) bootstrap reality check
methodology, which has been applied in only three studies to date (Sullivan
et al., 1999, 2003; Qi and Wu, 2002). White’s methodology provides ‘data-snooping-
adjusted’ p-values for the best trading rule out of the full universe considered.
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
818 PARK AND IRWIN
Further research is needed using both the replication and reality check approaches
in order to provide more conclusive evidence on the profitability of technical trading
rules.
Treatment of risk and market microstructure issues also needs to be addressed
in future studies. Risk is difficult to assess because each risk measure has its
own limitations and all are subject to a joint hypothesis problem. Cochrane (2001,
p. 465) suggests consideration of some version of a consumption-based model,
such as Constantinides and Duffie’s (1996) model with uninsured idiosyncratic
risks or Campbell and Cochrane’s (1999) habit persistence model. The market
microstructure issues of bid–ask spreads and non-synchronous trading need careful
attention as well. The advent of large and detailed transactions databases should
allow considerable progress to be made in addressing these problems. Researchers
should also incorporate accurate histories of daily price limits into technical trading
models.
Finally, there remains a large and persistent gap between the views of many
market participants and large numbers of academics about technical analysis.14 In
their recent survey study, Gehrig and Menkhoff (2003, p. 3) state that, ‘According
to our results, technical analysis dominates foreign exchange and most foreign
exchange traders seem to be chartists now’. Shiller (1990, p. 55) also recognized
the gap in his early questionnaire survey work on the stock market crash of 1987,
pointing out that, ‘Obviously, the popular models (the models that are used by
the broad masses of economic actors to form their expectations) are not the same
as those held by economists’. He asserts that, ‘Once one accepts the difference,
economic modelling cannot proceed without collecting data on the popular models
themselves’. While similar efforts have been made in several studies on the use
of technical analysis in the foreign exchange market (e.g. Taylor and Allen, 1992;
Lui and Mole, 1998; Cheung and Chinn, 2001), few studies have directly surveyed
technical traders in other speculative markets (e.g. Smidt, 1965b; Brorsen and Irwin,
1987). Moreover, popular models like technical analysis may differ across markets
and through time. Therefore, researchers are strongly encouraged to directly elicit
and analyse the views and practices of technical traders in a broad cross-section of
speculative markets. This would provide a much richer understanding of the actual
use of technical trading strategies in real-world markets.
Acknowledgements
The authors thank Wade Brorsen, two anonymous reviewers and the editor for helpful
comments. Funding support from the Aurene T. Norton Trust is gratefully acknowledged.
Notes
1. In futures markets, open interest is defined as ‘the total number of open transactions’
(Leuthold et al., 1989).
2. The history of technical analysis dates back to at least the eighteenth century when
the Japanese developed a form of technical analysis known as candlestick charting.
This technique was not introduced to the West until the 1970s (Nison, 1991).
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
THE PROFITABILITY OF TECHNICAL ANALYSIS 819
3. In Smidt’s survey an amateur trader is defined as ‘. . . a trader who was not a hedger,
who did not earn most of his income from commodity trading, and who did not
spend most of his time in commodity trading’ (p. 7).
4. According to Dimand and Ben-El-Mechaiekh (2005), a French researcher, Regnault,
developed the first formal statement of the theory of efficient markets in 1863.
Bachelier (1900) and Working (1949) also developed early versions of the theory.
5. Timmermann and Granger used t as a symbol for the information set. The symbol
t has been changed to θt for consistency.
6. A stop-loss order generates a sell signal whenever current price falls a fixed
percentage below the initial price. A moving average rule generates a buy (sell)
signal when a short moving average rises above (or falls below) a long moving
average. A channel rule generates a buy (sell) signal anytime today’s closing price
is greater (lower) than the highest (lowest) price in a channel length. Momentum
oscillator rules are various. The rule tested by Smidt (1965a) uses the average daily
increase (decrease) in closing prices during the previous n days. If the value is
greater (lower) than a given threshold value, a buy (sell) signal is generated. A
relative strength rule measures price performance by comparing current price to an
average of previous prices in relative terms.
7. These returns are based on the total investment method in which total investment is
composed of a 30% initial investment in margins plus a 70% reserve for potential
margin calls. The percentage returns can be converted into simple annual returns
(about 3.8%–5.6%) by a straightforward arithmetic manipulation.
8. Break-even one-way transaction cost is defined as the percentage one-way trading
cost that eliminates the additional return from technical trading (Bessembinder and
Chan, 1995, p. 277). It can be calculated by dividing the difference between portfolio
buy and sell means by twice the average number of portfolio trades.
9. The nominal p-value is obtained by applying the bootstrap reality check methodology
only to the best rule, thereby ignoring the effect of data snooping. Thus, it is a simple
bootstrap p-value from the stationary bootstrap.
10. Note that in Table 3 studies on equity (index) futures and options and foreign
exchange futures are categorized into ‘stock markets’ and ‘foreign exchange markets’
studies, respectively. ‘Futures markets’ studies include studies on other individual
futures markets or various groups of futures markets.
11. By analysing data on stock holdings of hedge fund managers, one of the most
sophisticated investor groups, Brunnermeier and Nagel (2004) find that hedge funds
‘rode’ the technology bubble over the 1998–2000 period and reduced their holdings
of technology stocks before prices collapsed. These findings are consistent with
feedback models.
12. The source for the data on CTA investment is The Barclay Group (http://www.
barclaygrp.com/indices/cta/Money Under Management.html).
13. This statement strictly applies only to studies that replicate ‘old’ results on ‘new’
data for the same market(s). Numerous studies provide a form of replication by
applying successful technical trading rules from one market to different markets
over similar time periods. The independence of such results across studies is open
to question because of the positive correlation of returns across many markets, i.e.
US and non-US stock markets.
14. The different views on technical analysis may stem partly from a reverse ‘publication
bias’, which occurs when ‘. . . a researcher who genuinely believes he or she has
identified a method for predicting the market has little incentive to publish the
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
820 PARK AND IRWIN
References
Alexander, S.S. (1961) Price movements in speculative markets: trends or random walks.
Industrial Management Review 2: 7–26.
Alexander, S.S. (1964) Price movements in speculative markets: trends or random walks
No. 2. Industrial Management Review 5: 25–46.
Allen, F. and Karjalainen, R. (1999) Using genetic algorithms to find technical trading
rules. Journal of Financial Economics 51: 245–271.
Bachelier, L. (1900) Theorie de la speculation, Paris: Gauthier-Villars, and in Annales de
l’Ecole Normale Superieure, 3e serie, 17: 21–86, trans. A.J. Boness in P. Cootner (ed.),
The Random Character of Stock Market Prices, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1964.
Bessembinder, H. and Chan, K. (1995) The profitability of technical trading rules in the
Asian stock markets. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 3: 257–284.
Bessembinder, H. and Chan, K. (1998) Market efficiency and the returns to technical
analysis. Financial Management 27: 5–17.
Billingsley, R.S. and Chance, D.M. (1996) Benefits and limitations of diversification among
commodity trading advisors. Journal of Portfolio Management 23: 65–80.
Bird, P.J.W.N. (1985) The weak form efficiency of the London Metal Exchange. Applied
Economics 17: 571–587.
Black, F. (1986) Noise. Journal of Finance 41: 529–543.
Blume, L., Easley, D. and O’Hara, M. (1994) Market statistics and technical analysis: the
role of volume. Journal of Finance 49: 153–181.
Brock, W., Lakonishock, J. and LeBaron, B. (1992) Simple technical trading rules and the
stochastic properties of stock returns. Journal of Finance 47: 1731–1764.
Brorsen, B.W. and Irwin, S.H. (1987) Futures funds and price volatility. Review of Futures
Markets 6: 118–135.
Brown, D.P. and Jennings, R.H. (1989) On technical analysis. Review of Financial Studies
2: 527–551.
Brunnermeier, M.K. and Nagel, S. (2004) Hedge funds and the technology bubble. Journal
of Finance 59: 2013–2040.
Caginalp, G. and Laurent, H. (1998) The predictive power of price patterns. Applied
Mathematical Finance 5: 181–205.
Campbell, J.Y. and Cochrane, J.H. (1999) By force of habit: a consumption-based
explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. Journal of Political Economy 107:
205–251.
Chang, P.H.K. and Osler, C.L. (1999) Methodical madness: technical analysis and the
irrationality of exchange-rate forecasts. Economic Journal 109: 636–661.
Cheung, Y.W. and Chinn, M.D. (2001) Currency traders and exchange rate dynamics: a
survey of the US market. Journal of International Money and Finance 20: 439–471.
Clyde, W.C. and Osler, C.L. (1997) Charting: chaos theory in disguise? Journal of Futures
Markets 17: 489–514.
Cochrane, J.H. (2001) Asset Pricing. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Constantinides, G.M. and Duffie, D. (1996) Asset pricing with heterogeneous consumers.
Journal of Political Economy 104: 219–240.
Cooper, M. and Gulen, H. (2004) Is time-series based predictability evident in real-time?
Working paper, Purdue University.
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
THE PROFITABILITY OF TECHNICAL ANALYSIS 821
Cootner, P.H. (1962) Stock prices: random vs. systematic changes. Industrial Management
Review 3: 24–45.
Cornell, W.B. and Dietrich, J.K. (1978) The efficiency of the market for foreign exchange
under floating exchange rates. Review of Economics and Statistics 60: 111–120.
Corrado, C.J. and Lee, S.H. (1992) Filter rule tests of the economic significance of serial
dependencies in daily stock returns. Journal of Financial Research 15: 369–387.
Coutts, J.A. and Cheung, K. (2000) Trading rules and stock returns: some preliminary
short run evidence from the Hang Seng 1985–1997. Applied Financial Economics 10:
579–586.
Curcio, R., Goodhart, C., Guillaume, D. and Payne, R. (1997) Do technical trading
rules generate profits? Conclusions from the intra-day foreign exchange market.
International Journal of Finance and Economics 2: 267–280.
Dale, C. and Workman, R. (1980) The arc sine law and the treasury bill futures market.
Financial Analysts Journal 36: 71–74.
Davutyan, N. and Pippenger, J. (1989) Excess returns and official intervention: Canada
1952–1960. Economic Inquiry 27: 489–500.
Dawson, E.R. and Steeley, J. (2003) On the existence of visual technical patterns in the
UK stock market. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 30: 263–293.
Day, T.E. and Wang, P. (2002) Dividends, nonsynchronous prices, and the returns from
trading the Dow Jones Industrial Average. Journal of Empirical Finance 9: 431–454.
De Long, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H. and Waldmann, R.J. (1990a) Noise trader risk
in financial markets. Journal of Political Economy 98: 703–738.
De Long, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H. and Waldmann, R.J. (1990b) Positive feedback
investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation. Journal of Finance 45:
379–395.
De Long, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H. and Waldmann, R.J. (1991) The survival of
noise traders in financial markets. Journal of Business 64: 1–19.
Denton, F.T. (1985) Data mining as an industry. Review of Economics and Statistics 67:
124–127.
Dimand, R.W. and Ben-El-Mechaiekh, H. (2005) Louis Bachelier. Working paper, Brock
University.
Dimson, E. and Marsh, P. (1999) Murphy’s law and market anomalies. Journal of Portfolio
Management 26: 53–69.
Donchian, R.D. (1960) High finance in copper. Financial Analysts Journal November–
December, 133–142.
Dooley, M.P. and Shafer, J.R. (1983) Analysis of short-run exchange rate behavior:
March 1973 to November 1981. In D. Bigman and T. Taya (eds) Exchange Rate
and Trade Instability: Causes, Consequences, and Remedies (pp. 43–69). Cambridge,
MA: Ballinger.
Edwards, R.D. and Magee, J. (1996) Technical Analysis of Stock Trends. Boston, MA: John
Magee.
Fama, E.F. (1970) Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work. Journal
of Finance 25: 383–417.
Fama, E.F. (1998) Market efficiency, long-term returns, and behavioral finance. Journal of
Financial Economics 49: 283–306.
Fama, E.F. and Blume, M.E. (1966) Filter rules and stock market trading. Journal of
Business 39: 226–241.
Fernández-Rodrı́guez, F., González-Martel, C. and Sosvilla-Rivero, S. (2000) On the
profitability of technical trading rules based on artificial neural networks: evidence
from the Madrid stock market. Economic Letters 69: 89–94.
Fernández-Rodrı́guez, F., Sosvilla-Rivero, S. and Andrada-Félix, J. (2003) Technical
analysis in foreign exchange markets: evidence from the EMS. Applied Financial
Economics 13: 113–122.
Fleming, J., Ostdiek, B. and Whaley, R.E. (1996) Trading costs and the relative rates of
price discovery in stock, futures, and option markets. Journal of Futures Markets 16:
353–387.
Froot, K.A., Scharfstein, D.S. and Stein, J.C. (1992) Herd on the street: informational
inefficiencies in a market with short-term speculation. Journal of Finance 47: 1461–
1484.
Fung, W. and Hsieh, D.A. (1997) The information content of performance track records:
investment style and survivorship bias in the historical returns of commodity trading
advisors. Journal of Portfolio Management 24: 30–41.
Gehrig, T. and Menkhoff, L. (2003) Technical analysis in foreign exchange – the workhorse
gains further ground. Discussion paper, University of Hannover.
Gehrig, T. and Menkhoff, L. (2004) The use of flow analysis in foreign exchange:
exploratory evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance 23: 573–
594.
Gençay, R. (1998a) Optimization of technical trading strategies and the profitability in
security markets. Economic Letters 59: 249–254.
Gençay, R. (1998b) The predictability of security returns with simple technical trading
rules. Journal of Empirical Finance 5: 347–359.
Gençay, R. (1999) Linear, non-linear and essential foreign exchange rate prediction with
simple technical trading rules. Journal of International Economics 47: 91–107.
Gençay, R. and Stengos, T. (1997) Technical trading and the size of the risk premium in
security returns. Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 2: 23–34.
Gençay, R. and Stengos, T. (1998) Moving average rules, volume and the predictability
of security returns with feedforward networks. Journal of Forecasting 17: 401–
414.
Gray, R.W. and Nielsen, S.T. (1963) Rediscovery of some fundamental price behavior
characteristics. Paper presented at the meeting of the Econometric Society held in
Cleveland, Ohio.
Greer, T.V., Brorsen, B.W. and Liu, S.M. (1992) Slippage costs in order execution for a
public futures fund. Review of Agricultural Economics 14: 281–288.
Grossman, S.J. and Stiglitz, J.E. (1976) Information and competitive price systems.
American Economic Review 66: 246–253.
Grossman, S.J. and Stiglitz, J.E. (1980) On the impossibility of informationally efficient
markets. American Economic Review 70: 393–408.
Grundy, B.D. and McNichols, M. (1989) Trade and the revelation of information through
prices and direct disclosure. Review of Financial Studies 2: 495–526.
Guillaume, D.M. (2000) Intradaily Exchange Rate Movements. Boston, MA: Kluwer
Academic.
Gunasekarage, A. and Power, D.M. (2001) The profitability of moving average trading
rules in South Asian stock markets. Emerging Markets Review 2: 17–33.
Hamm, L. and Brorsen, B.W. (2000) Trading futures markets based on signals from a
neural network. Applied Economics Letters 7: 137–140.
Hansen, P.R. (2003) Asymptotic tests of composite hypotheses. Working paper, Brown
University.
Hansen, P.R. (2005) A test for superior predictive ability. Journal of Business and Economic
Statistics 23: 365–380.
Hellwig, M. (1982) Rational expectations equilibrium with conditioning on past prices: a
mean–variance example. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 279–312.
Houthakker, H. (1961) Systematic and random elements in short-term price movements.
American Economic Review 51: 164–172.
Hudson, R., Dempsey, M. and Keasey, K. (1996) A note on the weak form efficiency of
capital markets: the application of simple technical trading rules to UK stock prices
– 1935 to 1964. Journal of Banking and Finance 20: 1121–1132.
Irwin, S.H. and Uhrig, J.W. (1984) Do technical analysts have holes in their shoes? Review
of Research in Futures Markets 3: 264–277.
Irwin, S.H., Zulauf, C.R., Gerlow, M.E. and Tinker, J.N. (1997) A performance comparison
of a technical trading system with ARIMA models for soybean complex prices.
Advances in Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management 4: 193–203.
Ito, A. (1999) Profits on technical trading rules and time-varying expected returns: evidence
from Pacific-Basin equity markets. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 7: 283–330.
James, F.E. (1968) Monthly moving averages – an effective investment tool? Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis September, 315–326.
Jensen, M.C. (1967) Random walks: reality or myth – comment. Financial Analysts Journal
23: 77–85.
Jensen, M.C. (1978) Some anomalous evidence regarding market efficiency. Journal of
Financial Economics 6: 95–101.
Jensen, M.C. and Benington, G.A. (1970) Random walks and technical theories: some
additional evidence. Journal of Finance 25: 469–482.
Kavajecz, K.A. and Odders-White, E.R. (2004) Technical analysis and liquidity provision.
Review of Financial Studies 17: 1043–1071.
Kho, B. (1996) Time-varying risk premia, volatility, and technical trading rule profits:
evidence from foreign currency futures markets. Journal of Financial Economics 41:
249–290.
Kidd, W.V. and Brorsen, B.W. (2004) Why have the returns to technical analysis decreased?
Journal of Economics and Business 56: 159–176.
Koza, J. (1992) Genetic Programming: On the Programming of Computers by Means of
Natural Selection. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
LeBaron, B. (1999) Technical trading rule profitability and foreign exchange intervention.
Journal of International Economics 49: 125–143.
Lee, C.I. and Mathur, I. (1996a) Trading rule profits in European currency spot cross-rates.
Journal of Banking and Finance 20: 949–962.
Lee, C.I. and Mathur, I. (1996b) A comprehensive look at the efficiency of technical trading
rules applied to cross-rates. European Journal of Finance 2: 389–411.
Lee, C.I., Gleason, K.C. and Mathur, I. (2001) Trading rule profits in Latin American
currency spot rates. International Review of Financial Analysis 10: 135–156.
Leigh, W., Paz, N. and Purvis, R. (2002a) Market timing: a test of a charting heuristic.
Economic Letters 77: 55–63.
Leigh, W., Modani, N., Purvis, R. and Roberts, T. (2002b) Stock market trading rule
discovery using technical charting heuristics. Expert Systems with Applications 23:
155–159.
Leuthold, R.M. (1972) Random walk and price trends: the live cattle futures market. Journal
of Finance 27: 879–889.
Leuthold, R.M., Junkus, J.C. and Cordier, J.E. (1989) The Theory and Practice of Futures
Markets. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Levich, R.M. and Thomas, L.R. III (1993) The significance of technical trading rule profits
in the foreign exchange market: a bootstrap approach. Journal of International Money
and Finance 12: 451–474.
Levy, R.A. (1967a) Random walks: reality or myth. Financial Analysts Journal 23: 69–77.
Levy, R.A. (1967b) Relative strength as a criterion for investment selection. Journal of
Finance 22: 595–610.
Levy, R.A. (1971) The predictive significance of five-point chart patterns. Journal of
Business 44: 316–323.
Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A.C. (1990) Data snooping biases in tests of financial asset pricing
models. Review of Financial Studies 3: 431–467.
Lo, A., Mamaysky, H. and Wang, J. (2000) Foundations of technical analysis: compu-
tational algorithms, statistical inference, and empirical implementation. Journal of
Finance 55: 1705–1765.
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
824 PARK AND IRWIN
Locke, P.R. and Venkatesh, P.C. (1997) Futures market transaction costs. Journal of Futures
Markets 17: 229–245.
Lovell, M.C. (1983) Data mining. Review of Economics and Statistics 65: 1–12.
Lucke, B. (2003) Are technical trading rules profitable? Evidence for head-and-shoulder
rules. Applied Economics 35: 33–40.
Lui, Y.H. and Mole, D. (1998) The use of fundamental and technical analyses by foreign
exchange dealers: Hong Kong evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance
17: 535–545.
Lukac, L.P. and Brorsen, B.W. (1990) A comprehensive test of futures market disequilib-
rium. Financial Review 25: 593–622.
Lukac, L.P., Brorsen, B.W. and Irwin, S.H. (1988) A test of futures market disequilibrium
using twelve different technical trading systems. Applied Economics 20: 623–639.
Maddala, G.S. and Li, H. (1996) Bootstrap based tests in financial models. In G.S.
Maddala and C.R. Rao (eds), Handbook of Statistics 14: Statistical Methods in Finance
(pp. 463–488). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.
Maillet, B. and Michel, T. (2000) Further insights on the puzzle of technical analysis
profitability. European Journal of Finance 6: 196–224.
Marquering, W., Nisser, J. and Valla, T. (2006) Disappearing anomalies: a dynamic analysis
of the persistence of anomalies. Applied Financial Economics 16: 291–302.
Marsh, I.W. (2000) High-frequency Markov switching models in the foreign exchange
market. Journal of Forecasting 19: 123–134.
Martin, A.D. (2001) Technical trading rules in the spot foreign exchange markets of
developing countries. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 11: 59–68.
McCurdy, T.H. and Morgan, I.G. (1992) Single beta models and currency futures prices.
Economic Record 68: 117–129.
Menkhoff, L. (1997) Examining the use of technical currency analysis. International
Journal of Finance and Economics 2: 307–318.
Menkhoff, L. and Schlumberger, M. (1995) Persistent profitability of technical analysis
on foreign exchange markets? Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review 193:
189–216.
Mills, T.C. (1997) Technical analysis and the London Stock Exchange: testing trading rules
using the FT30. International Journal of Finance and Economics 2: 319–331.
Neely, C.J. (1997) Technical analysis in the foreign exchange market: a layman’s guide.
Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis September/October, 23–38.
Neely, C.J. (2002) The temporal pattern of trading rule returns and exchange rate
intervention: intervention does not generate technical trading profits. Journal of
International Economics 58: 211–232.
Neely, C.J. (2003) Risk-adjusted, ex ante, optimal technical trading rules in equity markets.
International Review of Economics and Finance 12: 69–87.
Neely, C.J. and Weller, P.A. (1999) Technical trading rules in the European Monetary
System. Journal of International Money and Finance 18: 429–458.
Neely, C.J. and Weller, P.A. (2001) Technical analysis and central bank intervention.
Journal of International Money and Finance 20: 949–970.
Neely, C.J. and Weller, P.A. (2003) Intraday technical trading in the foreign exchange
market. Journal of International Money and Finance 22: 223–237.
Neely, C.J., Weller, P.A. and Dittmar, R. (1997) Is technical analysis profitable in the
foreign exchange market? A genetic programming approach. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 32: 405–426.
Nison, S. (1991) Japanese Candlestick Charting Techniques. New York: New York Institute
of Finance.
Okunev, J. and White, D. (2003) Do momentum-based strategies still work in foreign
exchange markets? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38: 425–447.
Olson, D. (2004) Have trading rule profits in the currency markets declined over time?
Journal of Banking and Finance 28: 85–105.
Journal of Economic Surveys (2007) Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 786–826
C 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation C 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
THE PROFITABILITY OF TECHNICAL ANALYSIS 825
Osler, C.L. (2003) Currency orders and exchange rate dynamics: an explanation for the
predictive success of technical analysis. Journal of Finance 58: 1791–1819.
Park, C. and Irwin, S.H. (2004) The profitability of technical analysis: a review. AgMAS
Project Research Report No. 2004-04, http://ssrn.com/abstract=603481.
Peterson, P.E. and Leuthold, R.M. (1982) Using mechanical trading systems to evaluate the
weak form efficiency of futures markets. Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics
14: 147–152.
Pring, M.J. (2002) Technical Analysis Explained. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Pruitt, S.W. and White, R.E. (1988) The CRISMA trading system: who says technical
analysis can’t beat the market? Journal of Portfolio Management 15: 55–58.
Pruitt, S.W., Tse, M.K.S. and White, R.E. (1992) The CRISMA trading system: the next
five years. Journal of Portfolio Management 19: 22–25.
Qi, M. and Wu, Y. (2002) Technical trading-rule profitability, data snooping, and reality
check: evidence from the foreign exchange market. Working paper, Kent State
University.
Raj, M. and Thurston, D. (1996) Effectiveness of simple technical trading rules in the
Hong Kong futures markets. Applied Economics Letters 3: 33–36.
Ratner, M. and Leal, R.P.C. (1999) Tests of technical trading strategies in the emerging
equity markets of Latin America and Asia. Journal of Banking and Finance 23: 1887–
1905.
Ready, M.J. (2002) Profits from technical trading rules. Financial Management 31: 43–61.
Roberts, M.C. (2003) Technical analysis in commodity markets: risk, returns, and value.
Paper presented at the NCR-134 conference, St Louis, Missouri.
Roll, R. (1984) A simple implicit measure of the effective bid–ask spread in an efficient
market. Journal of Finance 39: 1127–1139.
Ruiz, E. and Pascual, L. (2002) Bootstrapping financial time series. Journal of Economic
Surveys 16: 271–300.
Saacke, P. (2002) Technical analysis and the effectiveness of central bank intervention.
Journal of International Money and Finance 21: 459–479.
Samuelson, P.A. (1965) Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Industrial
Management Review 6: 41–49.
Sapp, S. (2004) Are all central bank interventions created equal? An empirical investigation.
Journal of Banking and Finance 28: 443–474.
Schmidt, A.B. (2002) Why technical trading may be successful? A lesson from the agent-
based modeling. Physica A 303: 185–188.
Schwager, J.D. (1996) Schwager on Futures: Technical Analysis. New York: Wiley.
Schwert, G.W. (2003) Anomalies and market efficiency. In G.M. Constantinides, M. Harris
and R.M. Stulz (eds), Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Vol. 1B: Financial
Markets and Asset Pricing (pp. 937– 972). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.
Shiller, R.J. (1990) Speculative prices and popular models. Journal of Economic Perspec-
tives 4: 55–65.
Shiller, R.J. (2003) From efficient markets theory to behavioral finance. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 17: 83–104.
Shleifer, A. and Summers, L.H. (1990) The noise trader approach to finance. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 4: 19–33.
Silber, W.L. (1994) Technical trading: when it works and when it doesn’t. Journal of
Derivatives 1: 39–44.
Slezak, S.L. (2003) On the impossibility of weak-form efficient markets. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38: 523–554.
Smidt, S. (1965a) A test of serial independence of price changes in soybean futures. Food
Research Institute Studies 5: 117–136.
Smidt, S. (1965b) Amateur Speculators. Ithaca, NY: Graduate School of Business and
Public Administration, Cornell University.
Smith, T. and Whaley, R.E. (1994) Estimating the effective bid/ask spread from time and
sales data. Journal of Futures Markets 14: 437–455.
Sosvilla-Rivero, S., Andrada-Félix, J. and Fernández-Rodrı́guez, F. (2002) Further evidence
on technical trade profitability and foreign exchange intervention. Applied Economics
Letters 9: 827–832.
Stein, J.L. (1987) The Economics of Futures Markets. New York: Basil Blackwell.
Stengos, T. (1996) Nonparametric forecasts of gold rates of return. In W.A. Barnett, A.P.
Kirman and M. Salmon (eds), Nonlinear Dynamics and Economics: Proceedings of the
Tenth International Symposium on Economic Theory and Econometrics (pp. 393–406).
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stevenson, R.A. and Bear, R.M. (1970) Commodity futures: trends or random walks?
Journal of Finance 25: 65–81.
Sullivan, R., Timmermann, A. and White, H. (1999) Data snooping, technical trading rule
performance, and the bootstrap. Journal of Finance 54: 1647–1691.
Sullivan, R., Timmermann, A. and White, H. (2001) Dangers of data mining: the case of
calendar effects in stock returns. Journal of Econometrics 105: 249–286.
Sullivan, R., Timmermann, A. and White, H. (2003) Forecast evaluation with shared data
sets. International Journal of Forecasting 19: 217–227.
Sweeny, R.J. (1986) Beating the foreign exchange market. Journal of Finance 41: 163–182.
Sweeny, R.J. (1988) Some new filter rule tests: methods and results. Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Analysis 23: 285–300.
Szakmary, A.C. and Mathur, I. (1997) Central bank intervention and trading rule profits in
foreign exchange markets. Journal of International Money and Finance 16: 513–535.
Taylor, M.P. and Allen, H. (1992) The use of technical analysis in the foreign exchange
market. Journal of International Money and Finance 11: 304–314.
Taylor, S.J. (1985) The behaviour of futures prices over time. Applied Economics 17:
713–734.
Taylor, S.J. (1986) Modelling Financial Time Series. Chichester: Wiley.
Taylor, S.J. (1992) Rewards available to currency futures speculators: compensation for
risk or evidence of inefficient pricing? Economic Record 68: 105–116.
Taylor, S.J. (1994) Trading futures using a channel rule: a study of the predictive power of
technical analysis with currency examples. Journal of Futures Markets 14: 215–235.
Taylor, S.J. (2000) Stock index and price dynamics in the UK and the US: new evidence
from a trading rule and statistical analysis. European Journal of Finance 6: 39–69.
Taylor, S.J. and Tari, A. (1989) Further evidence against the efficiency of futures markets.
In R.M.C. Guimaraes, B.G. Kingsman and S.J. Taylor (eds), A Reappraisal of the
Efficiency of Financial Markets (pp. 577–601). Berlin: Springer.
Thompson, S.R. and Waller, M.L. (1987) The execution cost of trading in commodity
futures markets. Food Research Institute Studies 20: 141–163.
Timmermann, A. and Granger, C.W.J. (2004) Efficient market hypothesis and forecasting.
International Journal of Forecasting 20: 15–27.
Tomek, W.G. and Querin, S.F. (1984) Random processes in prices and technical analysis.
Journal of Futures Markets 4: 15–23.
Van Horne, J.C. and Parker, G.G.C. (1967) The random-walk theory: an empirical test.
Financial Analysts Journal 23: 87–92.
Van Horne, J.C. and Parker, G.G.C. (1968) Technical trading rules: a comment. Financial
Analysts Journal 24: 128–132.
Wang, J. (2000) Trading and hedging in S&P 500 spot and futures markets using genetic
programming. Journal of Futures Markets 20: 911–942.
White, H. (2000) A reality check for data snooping. Econometrica 68: 1097–1126.
Working, H. (1949) The investigation of economic expectations. American Economic
Review 39: 150–166.