Apple Supreme Court Ruling
Apple Supreme Court Ruling
Apple Supreme Court Ruling
Syllabus
Syllabus
Syllabus
Syllabus
No. 17–204
_________________
fee, even if ” the iPhone owners wish “to buy apps else-
where or pay less.” Id., at 45a. According to the com-
plaint, that 30 percent commission is “pure profit” for
Apple and, in a competitive environment with other retail-
ers, “Apple would be under considerable pressure to sub-
stantially lower its 30% profit margin.” Id., at 54a–55a.
The plaintiffs allege that in a competitive market, they
would be able to “choose between Apple’s high-priced App
Store and less costly alternatives.” Id., at 55a. And they
allege that they have “paid more for their iPhone apps
than they would have paid in a competitive market.” Id.,
at 53a.
Apple moved to dismiss the complaint, arguing that the
iPhone owners were not direct purchasers from Apple and
therefore may not sue. In Illinois Brick, this Court held
that direct purchasers may sue antitrust violators, but
also ruled that indirect purchasers may not sue. The
District Court agreed with Apple and dismissed the com-
plaint. According to the District Court, the iPhone owners
were not direct purchasers from Apple because the app
developers, not Apple, set the consumers’ purchase price.
The Ninth Circuit reversed. The Ninth Circuit concluded
that the iPhone owners were direct purchasers under
Illinois Brick because the iPhone owners purchased apps
directly from Apple. According to the Ninth Circuit, Illi-
nois Brick means that a consumer may not sue an alleged
monopolist who is two or more steps removed from the
consumer in a vertical distribution chain. See In re Apple
iPhone Antitrust Litig., 846 F. 3d 313, 323 (2017). Here,
however, the consumers purchased directly from Apple,
the alleged monopolist. Therefore, the Ninth Circuit held
that the iPhone owners could sue Apple for allegedly
monopolizing the sale of iPhone apps and charging higher-
than-competitive prices. Id., at 324. We granted certiorari.
585 U. S. ___ (2018).
4 APPLE INC. v. PEPPER
II
A
The plaintiffs’ allegations boil down to one straightfor-
ward claim: that Apple exercises monopoly power in the
retail market for the sale of apps and has unlawfully used
its monopoly power to force iPhone owners to pay Apple
higher-than-competitive prices for apps. According to the
plaintiffs, when iPhone owners want to purchase an app,
they have only two options: (1) buy the app from Apple’s
App Store at a higher-than-competitive price or (2) do not
buy the app at all. Any iPhone owners who are dissatis-
fied with the selection of apps available in the App Store
or with the price of the apps available in the App Store are
out of luck, or so the plaintiffs allege.
The sole question presented at this early stage of the
case is whether these consumers are proper plaintiffs for
this kind of antitrust suit—in particular, our precedents
ask, whether the consumers were “direct purchasers” from
Apple. Illinois Brick, 431 U. S., at 745–746. It is undis-
puted that the iPhone owners bought the apps directly
from Apple. Therefore, under Illinois Brick, the iPhone
owners were direct purchasers who may sue Apple for
alleged monopolization.
That straightforward conclusion follows from the text of
the antitrust laws and from our precedents.
First is text: Section 2 of the Sherman Act makes it
unlawful for any person to “monopolize, or attempt to
monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person
or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or com-
merce among the several States, or with foreign nations.”
26 Stat. 209, 15 U. S. C. §2. Section 4 of the Clayton Act
in turn provides that “any person who shall be injured in
his business or property by reason of anything forbidden in
the antitrust laws may sue . . . the defendant . . . and shall
recover threefold the damages by him sustained, and the
cost of suit, including a reasonable attorney’s fee.” 38
Cite as: 587 U. S. ____ (2019) 5
claims for damages. Illinois Brick did not address injunctive relief, and
we likewise do not address injunctive relief in this case.
6 APPLE INC. v. PEPPER
supporting the plaintiffs, and they argue that C should be able to sue A
in that hypothetical. They ask us to overrule Illinois Brick to allow
such suits. In light of our ruling in favor of the plaintiffs in this case,
we have no occasion to consider that argument for overruling Illinois
Brick.
Cite as: 587 U. S. ____ (2019) 7
No. 17–204
_________________
nois Brick may not apply to claims for injunctive relief, ante, at 5, n. 1.
Under our normal rule of construction, a plaintiff who’s not proximately
harmed by a defendant’s unlawful conduct has no cause of action to sue
the defendant for any type of relief. Lexmark Int’l, Inc. v. Static Control
Components, Inc., 572 U. S. 118, 135 (2014) (although a plaintiff that
“cannot quantify its losses with sufficient certainty to recover damages
. . . may still be entitled to injunctive relief,” the requirement of proxi-
mate causation “must be met in every case”).
Cite as: 587 U. S. ____ (2019) 5
——————
3 The Court denies that allowing both consumers and developers to
sue over the same allegedly unlawful commission will “result in ‘con-
flicting claims to a common fund’ ” as Illinois Brick feared. Ante, at 12.
But Apple charged only one commission on each sale. So even assum-
ing for argument’s sake that the 30% commission was entirely illegal,
Apple can only be required to pay out in damages, at most, the full
amount it received in commissions. To their credit, even plaintiffs have
conceded as much, acknowledging that because “there is only one 30%
markup,” any claim by the developers against Apple would necessarily
be seeking “a piece of the same 30% pie.” Brief in Opposition 12. It’s a
mystery why the Court refuses to accept that sensible concession.
8 APPLE INC. v. PEPPER
III
The United States and its antitrust regulators agree
with all of this, so how does the Court reach such a differ-
ent conclusion? Seizing on Illinois Brick’s use of the
shorthand phrase “direct purchasers” to describe the
parties immediately injured by the monopoly overcharge
in that case, the Court (re)characterizes Illinois Brick as a
rule that anyone who purchases goods directly from an
alleged antitrust violator can sue, while anyone who
doesn’t, can’t. Under this revisionist version of Illinois
Brick, the dispositive question becomes whether an “in-
termediary in the distribution chain” stands between the
plaintiff and the defendant. Ante, at 6. And because the
plaintiff app purchasers in this case happen to have pur-
chased apps directly from Apple, the Court reasons, they
may sue.
This exalts form over substance. Instead of focusing on
the traditional proximate cause question where the al-
leged overcharge is first (and thus surely) felt, the Court’s
test turns on who happens to be in privity of contract with
whom. But we’ve long recognized that antitrust law
should look at “the economic reality of the relevant trans-
actions” rather than “formal conceptions of contract law.”
United States v. Concentrated Phosphate Export Assn.,
Inc., 393 U. S. 199, 208 (1968). And this case illustrates
why. To evade the Court’s test, all Apple must do is
amend its contracts. Instead of collecting payments for
apps sold in the App Store and remitting the balance (less
its commission) to developers, Apple can simply specify
that consumers’ payments will flow the other way: directly
to the developers, who will then remit commissions to
Apple. No antitrust reason exists to treat these contrac-
tual arrangements differently, and doing so will only
induce firms to abandon their preferred—and presumably
more efficient—distribution arrangements in favor of less
efficient ones, all so they might avoid an arbitrary legal
Cite as: 587 U. S. ____ (2019) 9