Rough Draft
Rough Draft
Rough Draft
The MIT Faculty has made this article openly available. Please share
how this access benefits you. Your story matters.
May 2013
Eric T. Anderson
Northwestern University
Duncan Simester
MIT Sloan School of Management
Standard models of competition predict that firms will sell less when competitors target their customers with
advertising. This is particularly true in mature markets with many competitors selling relatively
undifferentiated products. We present findings from a large-scale randomized field experiment that contrast
sharply with this prediction. The field experiment measures the impact of competitors’ advertising on sales
at a private label retailer of apparel, home furnishings and sporting goods. Surprisingly, for a substantial
segment of customers the competitors’ advertisements increased sales at this retailer. This is a robust effect,
obtained through experimental manipulation and measuring actual purchases by large samples of randomly
assigned customers. The effect is also large with customers ordering over 4% more items in some categories
in the Treatment condition (compared to the control). We compare how these positive spillovers vary across
product categories to illustrate the importance of product standards, customer learning, and switching costs.
The findings have the potential to change our understanding of competition in mature markets.
*
We thank our research assistant Hojin Jung for his contribution to this work. This paper has benefitted from
seminar participants at the 2010 Yale Customer Insights Conference, and the 2011 Yale Marketing Industrial
Organization Conference, together with audiences at the following universities: Alberta, Berkeley, Carnegie-
Mellon, MIT, and Wisconsin.
1. Introduction
We report the findings from a large scale field experiment to investigate the impact of advertising in a
competitive market. The field experiment was conducted with the cooperation of a large national
retailer that sells private label apparel, home furnishings and sporting goods. Although we cannot
reveal the identity of the retailer, for ease of exposition we will label it “Retail World”. In the field
experiment approximately 370,000 of Retail World’s past customers were randomly assigned to two
experimental conditions. The 185,000 customers in the Treatment condition received over 1.1 million
targeted direct mail advertisements from Retail World’s close competitors. Most of these
advertisements consisted of competing catalogs containing product information, prices and images for
hundreds of products. Customers in the Control condition did not receive these advertisements.
The field experiment takes advantage of a common direct-mail practice: sharing of customer
information between competing retailers. Sharing is often done on a reciprocal basis, so that firms
exchange information for an equivalent number of customers. Firms use this information to identify
where to send direct mail advertising, and this provides a unique opportunity to design a field
experiment to measure the impact of competitors’ advertising on a firm’s sales. We measure this
impact by comparing purchases at Retail World between the two experimental conditions using 20-
months of transactions. This period encompasses the twelve month treatment period and eight
subsequent months, and includes over one million orders and almost $100 million in Retail World
revenue.
Surprisingly, we find that for a substantial segment of customers the competitors’ advertisements
increased sales at Retail World. This effect is large and it is obtained through comparison of actual
purchases by large samples of randomly assigned customers. What makes the outcome particularly
surprising is that the apparel, home furnishings and sporting goods categories are mature and
comprised of many retailers selling relatively undifferentiated products. 1 The maturity of the markets
ensures that all customers are aware of the product categories. Customers can easily search and
purchase products at competing firms, customers do not have to learn how to use the products, and
compatibility between products is generally not specific to a firm. These are product categories in which
we might expect the threat from competition to be particularly strong. Yet, we find positive spillovers
from the competitors’ advertising.
The size of the positive spillovers varied across customers. The largest increase in Retail World sales was
from customers who had not made a recent Retail World purchase. The effect also varied across product
categories. To explain these positive spillovers and the variation across both categories and customers
1
The US retail apparel market contributes almost 3% of the US gross domestic product. In 2007 customers in the
US purchased approximately 20.1 billion garments and 2.4 billion pairs of shoes, representing approximately $371
billion in revenue (AAFA 2008). Sales of apparel and shoes are particularly strong in catalog and Internet channels.
The Direct Marketing Association (DMA 2006) reports that the apparel category has a higher volume of Internet
and catalog orders than any other product category. In 2006 approximately 32% of US adults ordered an item of
apparel from a direct retailer (including 23% of males and 40% of females). Moreover, fully 24% of the 100 largest
catalog retailers sell apparel. Not surprisingly, almost all major apparel retailers now use direct mail advertising
and catalog and Internet channels to complement their traditional retail stores.
1|Page
we will distinguish between the decision to make a purchase in a category, and the selection of which
retailer to purchase from. Competitors’ advertising may influence the first decision by priming
customers to think about the category. However, even though the need to purchase may have been
primed by competitors’ advertising, some customers returned to Retail World to satisfy this need.
The focus of the paper is on the choice of which retailer to purchase from. In preliminary interviews for
this research some customers described examples of products that they only buy from the Retail World
because they have learned which sizes fit. One customer described how he had mailed an outline of his
foot to Retail World, which the company used to determine his appropriate size. When he orders Retail
World footwear he believes it will fit. However, he also knows that sizing differs across brands and so he
avoids buying footwear elsewhere. A key feature of this example is the standardization of product sizes.
While footwear sizes are standardized within Retail World’s (private label) brand, they are different
from sizes at competing brands. 2 If sizes were standardized across all brands, this customer could use
Retail World’s size information to also order from other retailers.
Standardization in sizes does not extend to all categories. For example, swimwear sizes are not
standardized even within Retail World’s brand. Customers may need a size 8 when purchasing one style
of Retail World swimwear and a size 10 when purchasing another style. As a result the fit of past
swimwear purchases may not help predict the fit of a new swimsuit. We will show that variation in how
much customers learn about sizes from past purchases helps to explain where the impact from the
competitors’ advertising was largest.
While the customer interviews yielded useful initial insights, formally documenting these effects
required that we construct measures of how much customers learn from past purchases. Fortunately
this market provides an ideal measure of customer learning: changes in customer return rates. The
main reason that customers return items is due to concerns about product fit. We compare the
response to the competitors’ advertising with the change in return rates between customers’ first and
last orders in the category. We find a clear relationship: categories with the larger decreases in return
rates due to poor fit are the categories with the most positive treatment effects in the competitive
advertising experiment. Across the 35 largest categories, the pair-wise correlation between the Change
in Return Rates and the response to the competitors’ advertising is -0.41 (the rank-order correlation is
0.50). We interpret this as evidence that learning about product sizes created switching costs in favor
of Retail World. These switching costs led customers to purchase from Retail World, even though their
need to purchase was primed by the competitors.
Related Literature
Spillover effects have often been studied using Feldman and Lynch’s (1988) accessibility-diagnosticity
framework. This theory predicts that “an earlier response will be used as a basis for another subsequent
response if the former is accessible and if it is perceived to be more diagnostic than other accessible
inputs” (at page 421). In our application, products are associated through a network that includes both
retail brands and categories. A retail advertisement may activate the retail brand, a category need and
in-turn competing retail brands. This model has been used to explain both positive and negative
spillovers among competing brands. For example, Janakiraman, Sismeiro and Dutta (2009) develop an
2
Discrepancies in footwear and apparel sizes across brands are well-documented (see references on page 5).
2|Page
empirical framework to investigate positive spillovers between competing brands in the pharmaceutical
industry. They find that customers’ quality beliefs about the first entrant can influence customers’ prior
beliefs about the quality of later entrants, but only if the products are similar. They do not find any
evidence of positive spillovers through advertising. In particular, physicians do not appear to use
detailing activities for one drug to form quality perceptions of competing drugs.
Examples of positive advertising spillovers have been established in the context of umbrella brands
(among non-competing brands). For example, Balachander and Ghose (2003) show that these positive
spillovers may not only project from the parent brand to the brand extension, but that reciprocal
spillovers may also operate in the opposite direction (see also Morrin 1999).
Negative spillovers among competing brands have also been documented. Roehm and Tybout (2006,
2009) demonstrate how a product scandal may spillover from a brand like Vioxx, which was recalled due
to safety concerns, to damage a competing brand like Celebrex. Analogously, Dark and Richie (2007)
illustrate how deceptive advertising can have negative consequences for firms who are unrelated to the
original deception. Our findings contribute to our understanding of spillovers by documenting both the
existence of positive advertising spillovers between competing brands, and highlighting the moderating
role of consumer switching costs.
Our findings also contribute to an extensive literature establishing the existence of state dependencies
(consumer loyalty) in consumer choice (Dubé, Hitsch, Rossi and Vitorino 2008; Erdem 1996; Keane 1997;
and Seetharaman, Ainslie and Chintagunta 1999). Switching costs represent an important potential
source of state dependence. The earliest papers in the switching cost literature assumed that switching
costs were exogenous and common across firms. Under these conditions switching costs tend to reduce
competition and increase profits in equilibrium (Klemperer 1987). More recently it has been recognized
that switching costs may be endogenous. For example, Bergemann and Välimäki (1996) endogenize
switching costs in a multi-armed bandit problem in which buyers learn about product quality through
experience. If firms can control the level of switching costs we might expect that they would prefer to
increase them in order to dampen competition. However, the literature often predicts the opposite
result. Anticipation that high switching costs leads will lead to higher second-period profits induces
firms to compete aggressively in the first period. If the resulting price competition erodes profits, then
firms may reduce switching costs to dampen first-period competition (see for example Caminal and
Matutes 1990, Marinoso 2001, Bouckaert and Hans Degryse 2004, and Cabral and Villas-Boas 2005).
These distinct goals of “investing” to capture sticky customers and “harvesting” the surplus from them
once captured makes it difficult to predict whether the presence of switching costs will increase or
decrease the intensity of competition. This has led to recent empirical research evaluating the
contrasting predictions. Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2009) provide a prominent recent example. They study
the refrigerated orange juice and margarine categories and report that the presence of switching costs
can act to amplify the intensity of competition in these grocery markets. Their study focuses on price
competition among heterogenous firms and they find that intermediate levels of switching costs may
lead to lower prices. When switching costs are much larger, their numerical simulations show that
prices can rise as competition is dampened.
Our findings complement these results by extending our understanding of how switching costs impact
competitive intensity. The standard result in this context is that large switching costs create lock-in that
insulates customers from competitors’ actions. The surprise in our findings is that in the presence of
3|Page
switching costs competitors’ actions can generate positive spillovers that are large enough to outweigh
competitive substitution. Moreover, the extant switching cost literature has largely focused on price
competition in markets for low-involvement fast-moving consumer goods, while we focus on
competitive advertising in markets for higher-priced consumer durables.
Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2009) attribute the state dependence in their study to a “psychological”
switching cost, including cognitive dissonance in which customers change their preferences to
rationalize previous choices. Elsewhere the literature has distinguished between “transaction costs”
and “learning costs.” Examples of transaction costs include the cost of travelling to different gasoline
stations or the time required to evaluate alternative suppliers and establish new account information.
Learning costs describe the time and effort customers incur when learning how to use a new product
(Erdem and Keane 1996, Ackerberg 2003, Crawford and Shum 2005). Nilssen (1992) argues that this
distinction is important. He predicts that because learning costs are only incurred once for each supplier
while transaction costs are incurred every time a customer switches, transaction costs lead to a larger
increase in equilibrium prices and contribute to a greater loss of social welfare.
The switching costs we identify in this paper do not fit neatly into either category. Because customers
must learn about product fit when purchasing from a retailer they exhibit some of the characteristics of
a learning cost. However, the cost to the customer also includes the risk of purchasing the wrong item,
which is not the time and effort typically associated with learning. If customers purchase items that do
not fit they may incur a transaction cost to return an item.
The findings provide support for recent work on the role that the Internet plays in lowering search costs.
The fit of apparel products is a feature that is not easy for customers to search on over the Internet. To
evaluate fit customers must actually try the products on, either by visiting a store or ordering the items.
Lal and Sarvary (1999) study markets in which customers can search for some product features using the
Internet, but other product features require a physical inspection. 3 They show that the presence of non-
digital product features can increase customer loyalty, as customers may not risk physically searching for
products with better non-digital attributes, and instead, remain with the product that they are familiar
with. This is essentially the same intuition that we use in this paper to explain why customers are more
loyal to Retail World in categories in which they must learn about product sizes.
The results in this paper can also be compared with the literature on product standards, which has
demonstrated that competition can result in the adoption or preservation of socially inefficient
standards (see for example Farrell and Saloner 1985 and 1986; Katz and Shapiro 1985 and 1994; and
Bessen and Farrell 1994). While the body of theoretical work is now very extensive, there has been
recent recognition that there is need for more empirical work on this topic (Suarez 2005; Birke 2009).
Much of the literature has focused on the role of network effects in technology markets (see for
example Gupta, Jain and Sawhney 1999; Basu, Mazumdar and Raj 2003; Sun, Xie and Cao 2004; Dubé,
Hitsch and Chintagunta 2010; and Wang and Xie 2011). Our findings can be interpreted as evidence that
competition can lead to the adoption of socially inefficient standards even in non-technology markets
and without the presence of strong network effects. There have been many large-scale studies
3
Related work has attributed higher price sensitivity on the Internet to the lower cost of search. Examples include
evidence that airline demand is more sensitive to price changes in the Internet channel than in the traditional
channel (Granados, Gupta and Kauffman 2012); and that apparel and home furnishing demand is more sensitive to
charging sales tax on the Internet channel than in the catalog channel (Anderson, Fong, Simester and Tucker 2010).
4|Page
documenting the variation in sizes across US apparel brands. For example, Kinley (2005) sent a team of
research assistants into 20 retail stores in a Southwestern city to measure the sizes of 1,011 pairs of
pants. They report large discrepancies across brands at every size level. 4
The variation in apparel sizes survives despite numerous attempts to introduce standard sizes. As early
as 1969 the International Standards Organization proposed a very flexible system of standard apparel
sizes that promised to greatly reduce customer confusion. Other researchers have also proposed
standard sizing systems (see for example Ashdown 1998; Caldwell 1996; Chun-Yoon and Jasper 1996;
and Tamburrino 1992). However, none of these sizing systems have been widely adopted (Kinley 2005).
Even though apparel retailers could in principle standardize the sizes of their products they choose not
to do so. Industry commentators have attributed this reluctance to adopt a common standard to a
desire among retailers to make it more difficult for customers to switch stores: 5
“Retailers and clothing makers thrive on sizing confusion. Consumers who find a brand that
fits are likely to stick with it, and a standard sizing system would encourage them to visit
other stores.”
Barbaro (2006 at page 1)
A similar explanation is offered by Ellison and Ellison (2009) to explain why firms may want to obfuscate,
in order to make it difficult for customers to compare prices. In their setting firms forgo standardization
to obstruct price search by customers, resulting in less competition (see also Bergen, Dutta and Shugan
1996; and Gaudel and Sugden 2012). Our findings provide evidence that in apparel markets the absence
of standardization yields a similar outcome by making it more difficult for customers to switch to
competing retailers.
2. Study Design
The study was conducted with the cooperation of a medium-sized retailer (”Retail World”) that sells
apparel, home furnishings and sporting goods. With few exceptions, all of the products sold by this
retailer are private label products carrying the firm’s own brand. 6 Although many competitors sell
4
Delk and Cassill (1989), Workman (1991), Tamburrino (1992) and Workman and Lentz (2000) report similar
findings.
5
The failure to adopt standard sizing systems is also sometimes attributed to “customer vanity”. Manufacturers of
more expensive clothing reportedly tend to increase the physical dimensions to satisfy customers who want to
believe that they fit a smaller size. There is evidence to support these claims; Kiley (2005) Sieben and Chen-Yu
(1992) both report that more expensive products tend to have larger dimensions at a given size.
6
Private label apparel represents over 40% of all apparel sales (Cohen 2009) and up to 50% of sales in department
stores (Trefis Group 2010). For many large retailers such as The Gap, J Crew, and Abercrombie and Fitch private
label sales represent almost all of their sales. Moreover, direct mail advertising is one of the largest forms of
advertising; in 2010 direct mail advertising spending increased 3.1% to $45.2 billion (Levey 2011). This compares
5|Page
similar products, Retail World’s private label products are exclusively available from its own catalog,
Internet and retail store channels. The products are moderately priced ($48 on average) and past
customers return to purchase relatively frequently (1.2 orders containing on average 2.4 items per year).
Competitive Advertising
Like many retailers in this market, Retail World regularly participates in competitive advertising
programs that facilitate acquisition of prospective customers. Retailers who decide to join one of these
programs agree to provide contact information (name and mailing address) and purchase histories of
past customers. In return for providing data, a participating firm has access to customer information
from other firms that join the program. A third-party acts as a clearinghouse and limits information flow
between the firms. Participating firms do not generally have direct access to the names and purchase
histories of other firms’ customers. Instead, each firm makes a request for customers with a specific
demographic profile and transaction history. Three examples of actual mailing requests from the
competitive advertising event that we study are summarized in Table A1 in the appendix (the examples
are disguised to protect confidentiality).
In the competitive advertising event that we study a total of 64 of the Retail World’s competitors mailed
at least one advertising piece to Retail World customers across a period of approximately 12-months
(May 1, 2006 through May 14, 2007). Many of these competitors mailed multiple advertising pieces,
and so a total of 217 different competitive advertising pieces were sent to the Retail World customers.
Because the companies in some cases requested two different samples for the same advertising piece
(e.g. 10,000 female buyers and 15,000 male buyers), the total number of requests exceeded the number
of mailings. In particular, there were 301 requests spread across the 217 advertising pieces.
To confirm that the allocation of customers to the two conditions was random we compared historical
purchases from Retail World by the two samples. In particular, we compared the average units
purchased and average revenue prior to the start of the competitive advertising event. If the
assignment were truly random, we should not observe any systematic differences in historical sales
with $56 billion spent on television advertising and just $27.7 billion on digital (Internet) advertising. Despite these
expenditure levels, direct mail has received much less attention in the literature than digital advertising.
6|Page
between the two samples. Reassuringly, none of the differences are significant despite the large sample
sizes (we report these historical comparisons in Table 1 in the next section).
Customers in the Treatment and Control conditions both continued to receive catalogs from Retail
World. Retail World used the same mailing policy for all customers irrespective of the experimental
condition they were in. It is also helpful to note that Retail World maintains a single price policy.
Although the price of an item may vary over time, all customers purchasing that item at any point in
time pay the same price. This policy ensures that there were no differences in the prices that customers
paid across the two experimental conditions.
The opportunity to compare exogenously manipulated treatment and control groups is an important
characteristic of the study that overcomes a problem that has plagued many previous studies of
advertising. In general advertising decisions are endogenous, and are often at least partly determined
by expectations about sales levels. As a result, simply measuring the level of association between
advertising sales does not allow us to draw causal inferences about how advertising affects sales
(Bagwell 2007). It is generally even more difficult to identify how sales are affected by competitors’
advertising. In most cases it is not possible to distinguish which customers are targeted by competitors,
or to account for the factors that may have contributed to the targeting decisions.
The Treatment
In total approximately 1.15 million competitive mailing pieces were sent to the 184,455 customers in
our sample, or approximately 6.23 competitive mailing pieces per customer. We do not know which
customers received which competitor’s mailing. However, we do know the criteria that competitors
used to request customers for each mailing. We summarize these criteria in Table A2, which is located
in the appendix. The most common criteria were the recency of customers’ last purchases and the
amount spent on those purchases. Of the 301 requests, 87% included a recency criterion, while 80%
included an “amount spent” criterion. Other common criteria included the type of catalog that
customers had purchased from (50% of requests), the product category (43%), the customer’s gender
(37%) and the zip code they lived in (17%). 7
We can also compare our eligibility estimates with measures describing customers’ actual historical
purchases from Retail World. These results are reported in Table A3 of the Appendix. They reveal a
clear pattern: the competitors tended to request Retail World’s most valuable customers. These include
customers who had ordered more recently, more frequently and had placed larger orders with Retail
World.
We caution that we cannot use the mailing requests to construct probabilities that an individual
customer received a specific competitive mailing. Because many of the requests included a criteria that
previously used customers were excluded (see the examples in Table A1), the actual mailing samples
were not independent across the mailing efforts. In general, this “no previously used customers”
criteria will reduce the heterogeneity in actual mailing frequencies across customers. Because the
eligibility for the competitive mailings varied according to customers’ purchasing histories, we also need
7
The frequency of customers’ purchases was not an available selection criterion.
7|Page
to be careful when evaluating how the results of the experiment varied according to customer
characteristics. If we observe a larger effect among customers who were eligible to receive more
mailings then we cannot easily distinguish whether it was the customer characteristics that amplified
the effect or the increase in the number of competitive mailings that these customers received. 8
3. Initial Results
Retail World did not receive data describing which of its customers made purchases from any of the
competing firms. However, it does maintain complete records of customers’ purchases of its own
products. We compare purchases made by customers in the two experimental conditions. We compare
purchases over a period of approximately 20-months (the “Measurement Period”). This period starts
from the first mailing date in the competitive advertising event (May 1, 2006) through December 28,
2007 (almost eight months after the event finished on May 14, 2007). The average units purchased and
average revenue in the two conditions are reported in Table 1.
One possible interpretation of this null overall result is that customers have self-selected to their
favorite firms, and their demand is not sensitive to the actions of the competing firms. However, we will
demonstrate that we should not conclude from this null overall result that the competitors’ advertising
did not have any effect on Retail World’s sales. Instead we will show that the null result is caused by
aggregating positive effects in some categories with negative effects in others. The remainder of the
8
We also note that because eligibility for the competitive mailings was primarily determined by historical
purchasing history, eligibility changed as customers purchased. For example, consider a mailing that was only sent
to customers who had purchased within the last 3-months. At the start of the event a customer may not have
been eligible for this mailing. However, if this customer purchased from Retail World then the customers would
have become eligible immediately after that purchase.
8|Page
paper explores these interactions by comparing how the outcome varied across different customers and
product categories. We begin by comparing the outcome for different segments of customers.
9|Page
In Segment 3 we do observe slightly (although not significantly) higher sales in the Treatment condition
than in the Control condition. To confirm that customer differences do not explain the differences
during the Measurement Period we can use a multivariate approach to control for any historical
differences between the customers. This also provides an opportunity to investigate other factors that
may have contributed to the results. Our multivariate analysis is conducted in two parts. In the first
part we measure purchases by each customer across all categories, while in the second part we measure
purchases by each customer in each category.
Customer-Level Analysis
The dependent variable in this first part of the analysis measures the number of units that customer i
purchased during the Measurement Period. Because Units Purchasedi is a “count” variable, we estimate
a negative binomial model. To estimate the impact of the timing of a customer’s prior purchase in the
category we calculate Recencyi, which is defined as the number of days (in hundreds) since a customer’s
last purchase (prior to the treatment). We then interact Recencyi with a binary variable identifying
customers in the treatment condition (Treatmenti). We also estimate a separate specification in which
we group customers into Segments 1, 2 and 3 (as defined earlier) and estimate the impact of the
treatment separately for these three segments.
As additional controls we considered what other factors might be correlated with the timing of
customer’s prior purchases. There are two obvious candidates. First, we would expect the time since a
customer’s last purchase in the category to be affected by how frequently the customer purchases. We
measure this by simply counting the number of prior units purchased (Prior Unitsi). Notice that this also
explicitly controls for any differences in the historical units purchased between the Treatment and
Control conditions. Second, we might expect that the timing of customers’ last purchase may be
affected by the seasonality in their purchasing patterns. Recall that the treatment started on May 1 and
so customers who only purchase at Christmas will tend to have a different Recencyi measure than
customers who purchase at other times of this year. 9 To control for the impact of this seasonality we
calculated the percentages of a customer’s (pre-treatment) purchases that are made in each calendar
month (Month 1, …, Month 12).
To ensure that the relationship between the experimental treatment and the timing of customers’ prior
category purchases (Recencyi) is not due to either the frequency with which customers purchase or the
seasonality of their purchases, we include interactions between the treatment and these controls in our
model specification. In particular, we estimate the following model:
+ � φm Treatment i ∗ Month mi + 𝐁𝐗
m=1
9
We thank an anonymous reviewer for this suggestion.
10 | P a g e
The vector X contains a complete set of control variables, including main effects for Recencyi,, Prior
Unitsi,, and the Month mi variables. We also include main effects for the demographic variables. 10 The
coefficient of interest is β2. This measures how the effect of the treatment varies according to the
timing of the customer’s most recent prior purchase. The findings are reported in Table 3 (to
demonstrate robustness we also include a base model without covariates). For ease of exposition we do
not report the coefficients for our monthly control variables (seasonality) or their interaction with the
treatment.
The results confirm that competitive advertising led to a large increase in purchases from Retail World
among customers whose last purchases in the category were less recent. A 100-day increase in the time
since a customer’s last purchase is associated with a 1.61% increase in the impact of the competitive
advertising. Moreover, we now see that the significant impact of the competitive advertising extends
beyond Segment 3. For customers in Segment 1 (who had last purchased within 4-months of the start
of the test) the competitive advertising is associated with a 2.53% increase in unit sales, which is not
statistically significant. For Segments 2 and 3 the estimated increases in unit sales are 3.75% and 7.12%
(respectively). The effects for these last two segments are both statistically significant (p<0.05).
Customer x Category-Level Analysis
Notice that the timing of a customer’s last purchase will generally vary across categories. While a
customer may have purchased a pair of pants recently, they may not have purchased footwear. While
customers may have depleted their demand for one category (pants), they may not have depleted
demand for other product categories (footwear). To investigate these possibilities we re-analyzed sales
at the category level.
A category is defined using two dimensions: product type (e.g. footwear, tops, swimwear, pants) and
customer gender (for items where gender is relevant). We focus on the 35 largest categories, which
represent 81% of all purchases (the remaining purchases are spread across approximately 200 other
categories). We stack the data so that for each customer we obtain 35 observations, one for each
category. The dependent variable measures the number of units that customer i purchased from
category c during the test period. To account for category differences we estimate a quasi-maximum
likelihood (QML) Poisson model with (conditional) category fixed effects (Wooldridge 1999). This
estimator is consistent under very general conditions. For example, in contrast to the regular Poisson
model the estimator is consistent even if there is over-dispersion or under-dispersion in the latent
variable model. Moreover, the robust variance-covariance matrix described by Wooldridge (1999) allows
for deviations from the Poisson distribution together with arbitrary category-level fixed effects.
10
We are missing demographic observations for a small number of customers. For these observations we set the
demographic variables at zero and identify the missing data using binary flags (that we also include as controls).
11 | P a g e
To estimate the impact of the timing of a customer’s prior purchase in a category we calculate Category
Recencyi,c, which is defined as the number of days (in hundreds) since a customer’s last purchase in the
category (prior to the treatment). We then estimate the QML Poisson model including Category
Recency both as a main effect and interacted with the binary Treatment flag. As additional controls we
measure the number of prior units purchased at the category level (Prior Category Unitsi,c). We also
again control for the impact of seasonality and estimate the following system of independent variables:
+ � φm Treatment i ∗ Month mi + 𝐁𝐗
m=2
The vector X again contains a complete set of control variables, including main effects for the
demographic variables. Recall also that the model explicitly controls for arbitrary category-level
differences using (conditional) category fixed effects. The coefficient of interest is β2. This measures
how the effect of the treatment varies according to the timing of the customer’s most recent prior
purchase in that category. In Table 4 we report findings when using Category Recency (Model 1) and
when using a log transformation of Category Recency (Model 2). We also report a model in which we
include both Category Recency and overall Recency both as main effects and interacted with the
Treatment variable (Model 3). The standard errors are clustered by category to account for any
correlation in the errors across customers within the category.
Recall that in our prior analysis every customer had made a prior purchase from the firm, and so
Recencyi is well-defined when we calculate it at the aggregate level. However, not all customers have a
prior purchase in all 35 categories. Because the behavior of these customers does not inform us about
how the timing of prior category purchases influenced the outcome, when estimating the impact of
Category Recency we restrict attention to observations in which customers have made a purchase in the
category. In later analysis (Section 4) we use a different approach that relaxes this restriction.
Table 4 about here
The findings in Table 4 replicate the earlier results. The competitive advertising led to a larger increase
in purchases from Retail World among customers whose last purchases in the category were less recent.
In Model 1 we see that a 100 day increase in the time since a customer’s last purchase in the category is
associated with a 0.33% increase in the response (in that category) to the competitors’ advertising.
Interestingly, in Model 3 where we include Category Recency and overall Recency, both interactions are
significant. This indicates that demand depletion is not completely specific to a category. It appears that
among customer who have purchased recently, it is more difficult to prompt an additional purchase,
even in categories they have not recently purchased. For example, a recent purchase of pants appears
to make it more difficult to prompt an additional purchase of footwear (for at least some customers).
This could be explained by these customers having a budget constraint for apparel generally, rather than
separate constraints for footwear and pants.
12 | P a g e
Our calculation of the time since a customer’s last category purchase does not account for variation in
the inter-purchase intervals between categories. However, there is considerable variation across
categories in the typical interval between purchases, which may also influence whether a customer’s
demand for products in a category is depleted. For example, while pants have an average inter-
purchase interval of approximately eighteen months, the average inter-purchase interval for underwear
is closer to three years. Therefore, if the last purchase occurred two years ago, this may indicate that a
purchase of pants is overdue, but customers are not yet ready to purchase underwear. To investigate
this possibility we calculated the average inter-purchase interval for each category. We then re-
analyzed the time since a customer’s last purchase by re-scaling the time since a customer’s last
category purchase according to the number of inter-purchase intervals. The results are also reported in
Table 4 (Models 4 and 5).
We report two specifications. First, we treat the number of (category) inter-purchase intervals since a
customer’s last purchase in the category as a continuous measure (Intervals Since Last Purchasei,c) and
interact this continuous measure with the treatment (Model 4). For every additional inter-purchase
interval since a customer’s last category purchase the impact of the competitive advertising increased by
an average of 2.01%. Second, in the same way that we grouped customers into segments according to
the timing of their last purchases, we can also group them according to the category inter-purchase
intervals since their last purchase. We compare customers whose purchases were less recent with
benchmark customers whose previous purchases were most recent. 11 In particular, our benchmark
includes customers who made a prior purchase within 1 inter-purchase interval of the start of the
treatment. If a customer’s last category purchase was between 1 and 2 inter-purchase intervals prior to
the start of the treatment, then the impact of the competitive advertising was 2.86% higher than the
benchmark customers. If their last category purchase was over 2 inter-purchase intervals ago, the effect
increased by 5.85% compared to the benchmark customers.
Summary
An initial comparison of purchases during the Measurement Period indicates that there is no significant
difference in the outcomes in the Treatment and Control condition. However, further investigation
reveals that we do observe a significant difference in the outcomes for customers who had not
purchased recently. We illustrate this interaction using a variety of approaches, including both the time
since a customer made any purchase from the firm, and the timing of purchases in specific categories.
Our analysis includes controls for a variety of customer differences, together with arbitrary category-
level effects.
We interpret the interaction between the timing of a customer’s last purchase and the response to the
competitive mailing as evidence of demand depletion. Satiation among customers who had recently
purchased appears to have muted their reaction to the competitors’ advertising, limiting any increase in
primary demand. However, we do not have data describing purchases from competing firms and so we
cannot directly measure the change in primary demand.
11
Notice that the treatment effect for these benchmark customers can be calculated from the Treatment
coefficient (-0.99%), but must also be conditioned on the number of prior category units that the customer has
purchased.
13 | P a g e
Instead, we focus on understanding why customers responded to the competitors’ advertising by
purchasing from Retail World rather than the competitors. We turn to this issue in the next section
where we explore how the impact of the competitive advertising varied across different product
categories.
To evaluate the extent to which customers learn standardized sizes over time we constructed measures
of the change in product return rates over time. In particular, comparing the return rate on a
customer’s first purchase in a category and that customer’s most recent purchase may provide a
measure of learning about product fit. The more learning that occurs the larger the expected reduction
in return rates.
To obtain reliable estimates of the return rates we used the complete purchase histories for a sample of
3,634,695 Retail World customers. 12 Their purchase histories include a total of over 93 million
purchases representing over $3.6 billion in revenue. The historical data for these customers describes
when a customer returns an item and the reason for the return. In particular, the sample includes a
total of over 15.1 million returns. For approximately 78% of these returns we have a variable describing
the reason that the item was returned. 13 In Table 5 we list each of the return reasons and describe the
frequency with which they appear. The most common reason that items are returned is that they are
the wrong size, which contributes approximately half (46.6%) of all reasons for returns. The next most
frequent reason is that the customer did not like the item when it arrived, generally because they did
not like the color, material or styling. Defects contribute only a small portion of the returns.
12
We obtain similar results if we calculate return rates using historical transactions by the 369,080 customers in
the study. However, the additional sample size yields more precise estimates of the return rates.
13
The firm has used the same set of explanations for why items are returned throughout the transaction history.
Approximately half of the returns with missing reasons occur before February 23, 1996, which was the first date
that the firm started recording reasons for returns. After this date they occur with slightly diminishing frequency
over time. To ensure that the Return Trend is not affected by missing return reasons, when calculating the Return
Trend for each reason we omit all observations for a customer in a category if a return on the first or last category
order is not accompanied by a reason.
14 | P a g e
Table 5 about here
There are some items for which we would expect more learning about product sizes than other items.
These categories provide an opportunity to investigate our interpretation that the reduction in return
rates provides a way to measure how much customers learn about product sizes. First, we might expect
that customers will learn less about the size of “Childrens” items versus other items. Because childrens’
sizes change, experiences with the fit of past purchases may not provide as much information as the fit
of future purchases in childrens’ product categories than in other product categories. Second, there are
many items that do not have sizes. This includes non-apparel items (e.g. backpacks) and some apparel
items for which “one size fits all” (e.g. scarves).
In Figures 1 and 2 we report the average difference between a customer’s first purchase in a category
and their last purchase in a category according to whether: (a) the item is in the Childrens’ category or
not and (b) whether the items in the category have sizes or not. The unit of observation is a customer in
a category, and we use all of the observations for which the customer made at least two purchases in
the category (so that we can calculate the change in the return rate). We report the difference in return
rates for each of the four return reasons.
Figures 1 and 2 about here
There are several findings of interest. First, for categories without sizes there is essentially no change
(0.06%) in the return rates due to size between a customer’s first and last category order. Further
investigation confirms that the first and last return rates due to size are essentially zero in these
categories. This is precisely what we would expect and offers reassurance that the return rate for sizes
does not include returns for other reasons. Second, for those categories with sizes we see a large
reduction (-1.45%) in the return rate due to sizes between customers first and last orders. This is
consistent with our interpretation that customers learn about sizes as they place more orders in these
categories. Third, the reduction in the return rate due to sizes is considerably smaller for Childrens’
categories than for other categories (-0.88% versus -1.50%). This is consistent with customers learning
less about sizes from past purchases in Childrens’ categories than in other categories.
The change in return rates for the other three return reasons are also interesting. For these other
return reasons the differences between categories with and without product sizes, and between
Childrens’ and other categories are much smaller than we observe for returns due to size. However, the
sample sizes are very large and so even these smaller differences are statistically significant. It appears
that when a customer returns an item because of poor fit this is generally categorized accurately as a
size-related return. However, the larger reduction in returns on categories with sizes for these other
three return reasons could indicate that some of the size returns spillover to these other return reasons.
These attributions are not necessarily errors. Notice that a customer who finds that an item does not fit
could quite reasonably indicate that they do not like the item, or interpret the poor fit as a defect. Any
measurement errors that result from these spillovers will hinder (not help) validation of our prediction
that the response to the competitive advertising event is associated with the change in the size return
rate.
Return rates due to defects and because customers do not like the items exhibit a slight increase in
categories without sizes. One possible explanation is that Retail World has a generous returns policy
15 | P a g e
and the increase in return rates in these two categories may reflect customers learning about this policy.
If this explanation is correct then, in the absence of learning about sizes, we might expect return rates in
every product category to be higher for the last purchase than for a customer’s first purchase.
The Change in Return Rates and the Response to the Competitors’ Advertising
Our analysis again focuses on the 35 largest product categories. However, in this analysis we add an
additional refinement to our definition of a category. Preliminary investigation revealed that for some
apparel items Retail World uses different “size types”’ within a category. For example, women’s pants
come in 3 different size types:
In Table 6 we report the pair-wise correlation between these two measures and the response to the
competitors’ advertising event measured by the number of units purchased during the twenty month
Measurement Period. We report the pair-wise correlations separately for all four return reasons. The
key finding is that the faster the reduction in the return rate due to sizes between a customers’ first and
last orders, the larger the response to the competitive advertising. This is consistent with the
explanation that customers returned to purchase from Retail World because they had learned about
product sizes from previous purchases. The rank-order correlation between the change in returns due
to size and the response to the competitive advertising is even larger (0.50), indicating that the
relationship cannot be attributed to mere outliers.
14
The demand depletion interpretation that motivated our analysis of the recency of customer’s prior category
purchases is not sensitive to these size types. For example, purchasing a size L pair of pants may deplete demand
for size 10 pants as well as size L pants.
16 | P a g e
In Figure 3 we provide a scatter plot of the response to the competitors’ advertising (in each category)
and the change in return rates due to size. The relationship is clearly observable in this figure. The
figure highlights why we observe a null overall effect; the impact of the competitive advertising is
positive in some categories and negative in others. The figure also illustrates the magnitude of the
interaction effect. In particular, if we group the 35 categories into quintiles (of 7 categories each)
according to the change in returns due to size, the mean response to the competitors’ advertising in
each quintile is monotonically decreasing. The first quintile (the leftmost portion of Figure 3) has the
largest decrease in returns due to size and a mean response of 0.87%. In contrast, this effect declines to
-1.8% and -3.1% in quintiles 4 and 5 (the rightmost portions) which have the smallest decrease in returns
due to size. Importantly, this segmentation of the data clearly highlights the competing positive and
negative effects of competitive advertising. We do observe negative advertising effects, but these are
limited to categories with low consumer loyalty (the reduction in returns is smallest). Positive spillovers
exist, but are limited to categories with high consumer loyalty (the reduction in returns is largest).
While learning about sizes appears to play an important role in explaining the variation in the response
to the competitive advertising, learning about the other return reasons is apparently less important. We
do see a negative correlation between the other three return reasons and the response to the
competitive advertising. However, none of these correlations are statistically significant.
To demonstrate that the relationship between prior purchases and the response to the competitive
advertising (if any) is due to learning about sizes rather than just generic loyalty, we will again rely on a
comparison across categories. In particular, the generic loyalty explanation operates for every category,
while we only expect prior purchases to contribute to learning about sizes in some categories. If we can
show that the relationship between prior purchases and the response to the competitor’s advertising is
stronger in categories in which there is more learning about product sizes, we can claim that the
relationship is attributable to customer learning rather than other sources of loyalty.
We begin by constructing a measure of the rate at which customers learn about product sizes in each
category. In particular, for each category we estimate how the change in returns (between the first and
last order) varies according to the total number of orders a customer has made in the category. The
slope of this relationship provides a measure of how quickly customers learn from previous orders. In
categories in which customers learn more about the firm’s products we would expect this slope to be
more negative, so that greater learning leads to a faster reduction in returns. For ease of exposition we
17 | P a g e
label this slope the “Return Trend”. 15 A large positive Return Trend indicates that customers quickly
increase their rate of returns (across orders), while a large negative trend indicates that the rate of
returns quickly decreases.
We then construct a measure of how much we expect each customer to have learned about sizes in
each category by multiplying this measure of the rate of learning with the number of orders that
customers have placed in each category:
We add this variable to the QML Poisson customer x category-level model used to estimate the recency
interactions in the previous section. In particular, we include both Size Learning as a main effect, and an
interaction between Size Learning and the Treatment variable. It is the coefficient for this Treatment
interaction that is the coefficient of interest. We caution that the interpretation requires care because
this is a 3-way interaction between the Return Trend, the number of Prior Category Orders, and the
Treatment variable. The coefficient measures how an increase in the number of prior customer orders
affects the response to competitors’ advertising in categories in which there is a lot of learning about
product sizes compared to categories without a lot of learning about product sizes.
Recall from our earlier discussion that Category Recency is not well-defined if a customer does not have
a prior purchase in a category. It was for this reason that when we investigated the Treatment *
Category Recency interaction in the previous section we omitted these observations. In order to retain
Category Recency as a control in our Size Learning model we use two different approaches. First, as in
Section 3 we estimate the model when omitting observations for customers with no prior purchases in a
category (Model 1). In the second approach we include these observations and constructed a binary
flag identifying customers with no prior purchases in a category. 16 We include this binary flag as both a
main effect and interacted with the Treatment variable (Model 2). This second approach recognizes that
while these observations do not contribute to our understanding of the Category Recency interaction,
they may provide insight in this model. In particular, customers with no prior category purchases cannot
have learned any size information from past purchases. Our interpretation that learning about sizes
contributes to customer loyalty suggests that the competitors’ advertising should have a smaller effect
on purchases from Retail World for these observations.
The findings are reported in Table 7 (we again cluster the standard errors by category). In both models
the coefficient for the interaction between Treatment and Size Learning is negative and highly
significant. This indicates that the response to the competitive advertising was higher among customers
who had more prior experience in categories where the Return Trend is more negative. It is consistent
15
In each category we use OLS to estimate the Return Trend using the separate sample of 3.6 million customers.
We use all customers who placed at least two orders in the category. The average sample size for these estimates
is approximately 143,000, with a minimum of 10,000 observations in any category.
16
Notice that in Model 1 the sample size is smaller than the sample size for the models reported in Table 4. This
reflects the narrower definitions of a category to focus on a single size type.
18 | P a g e
with the interpretation that prior purchases lead to more loyalty in categories in which customers learn
more quickly about product sizes.
We also observe a negative interaction between the Treatment variable and No Prior Category Purchase.
This is consistent with our prediction that these customers would have a less favorable response to the
competitive advertising. Notice that for these customers both Category Recency and Prior Category
Units equal zero, and so the estimated net impact of the Treatment on category sales for these
customers is -6.62% (adjusting the 3.28% main Treatment coefficient with just the -9.90% No Prior
Category Purchase interaction coefficient). This result highlights the mix of positive and negative
treatment effects. We observe a positive main effect from advertising but a negative effect among
customers who have no history in a category.
5. Conclusions
Standard models of competition predict that firms will sell less when competitors target their customers
with advertising. We have presented findings that contrast with this prediction and demonstrated that
advertising can lead to positive spillovers for other firms even in a competitive market. We investigate
how these positive spillovers vary across product categories. The findings reveal that the product
categories with the largest spillovers are the categories in which customers appear to learn about
product attributes from prior purchases. Detailed data on the reasons that customers return items
allowed us to investigate what customers are learning. We show that the rate that customers learn
about size information is closely related to the response to the competitive advertising.
We also investigated how the response to the competitive advertising varied according to how many
times customers had previously purchased in a category. We find that customers who have made more
prior purchases were more likely to respond to the competitors’ advertising by purchasing at Retail
World. However, this only holds in product categories in which there is evidence that customers learn
about product sizes from prior purchases. This distinction is important; it suggests that the relationship
between past purchasing and the positive spillovers can be attributed to learning about product sizes,
rather than other generic sources of customer loyalty.
Our findings provide unique measures of the impact of advertising in a competitive market, and we
believe that the results have the potential to change our understanding of competition in mature
markets. First, we show that advertising by a competitor may increase another firm’s sales. This result
can be compared with previous studies of competitive advertising, which have generally focused on
negative spillovers. For example extensive research in the tobacco industry has studied whether
tobacco advertising leads to brand switching or an increase in primary demand: does Marlboro
advertising lift Marlboro sales by increasing smoking, or by switching smokers from Rothmans to
Marlboro? Few empirical studies anticipate the possibility of positive spillovers from competitors’
advertising, such as a positive impact of Marlboro advertising on sales of Rothmans.
19 | P a g e
Second, the findings highlight the role of product standards. Our evidence that customers can use past
experience to learn about product sizes does not extend to all categories. Instead it is limited to
categories in which product sizes are standardized within a brand but not across brands. This may help
to explain why firms do not adopt common standards in industries where doing so would offer obvious
customer benefits. The customer benefits are particularly true in the apparel market. It is estimated
that 70% to 80% of apparel products may not meet customers’ size expectations, and this contributes to
50% of women and 62% of men not being able to find products that fit (Abend 1993 and DesMarteau
2000). The outcome is not just lost sales but a large volume of returns. At the apparel retailer that
provided data for this study an average of 10.6% of purchases are returned. This increases to over 20%
for swimwear, imposing a monetary cost in managing logistics and depreciation of the returned items,
and possibly also an intangible cost due to customer dissatisfaction.
Our findings may also extend our understanding of the role of switching costs. Learning about product
fit is relatively easy, returning requires only nominal effort, and this effort is only incurred if the product
does not fit. Yet in a mature market with many close competitors we provide evidence that these
switching costs are sufficient to greatly reduce the threat from competition.
Finally, the findings also offer guidance to retailers. When selecting which customers to make available
in rented mailing lists or cooperative advertising events retailers should focus on (1) customers who
have not purchased recently, and (2) customers who have made repeat purchases in categories where
learning about sizes is important (such as footwear). We caution that this does not imply that these are
also the best types of customers to request when mailing to a competitors’ customers. This answer
obviously depends upon sales at the competing firms (which we do not observe). Because the
competing firms do observe these outcomes, the evidence that they tend to choose customers who
have purchased from Retail World most recently and most frequently, suggests that it is the more
recent and more frequent purchasers that a competitor should request.
Our results also call for future research on the role of advertising with consumer switching costs. We
argue that positive spillovers may arise when competitors’ advertising reminds consumers about a
primary need for a category that is later fulfilled at a preferred retailer. More research is required to
understand this mechanism and the implications for advertising competition.
References
AAFA (2008), Trends: An Annual Statistical Analysis of the U.S. Apparel and Footwear Industries,
American Apparel and Footwear Association, Arlington VA.
Abend, Jules (1993), “Our Fits Over Fit,” Bobbin, 34, 78-79.
Ackerberg, Daniel A. (2003), “Advertising, Learning, and Consumer Choice in Experience Good Markets:
A Structural Empirical Examination,” International Economic Review, 44, 1007–1040.
Anderson, Eric T., Nathan M. Fong, Duncan I. Simester, and Catherine E. Tucker (2010), “How Does An
Obligation To Collect Sales Tax Affect Consumer And Firm Behavior?” Journal of Marketing Research,
47(2), 229-239.
20 | P a g e
Bagwell, Kyle (2007), “The Economic Analysis of Advertising,” Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol.
3, edited by M. Armstrong and R. Porter, Elsevier B.V., 1703-1843.
Balachander, Subramanian and Sanjoy Ghose (2003), “Reciprocal Spillover Effects: A Strategic Benefit of
Brand Extensions,” Journal of Marketing, 67(1), 4-13.
Barbaro, Michael (2006), “Standard Sizing Gives Clothing retailers Fits,” The New York Times, March
31, http://www.nytimes.com/2006/03/31/business/worldbusiness/31iht-size.html.
Bergemann, Dirk and Juuso Välimäki (1996), “Learning with Strategic Pricing,” Econometrica, 64, 1125-
1150.
Bergen, Mark, Shantanu Dutta and Steven M. Shugan (1996), Brand variants: A Retail Perspective,”
Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. XXXIII, 9-19.
Bessen, Stanley M. and Joseph Farrell (1994), “Choosing How to Compete: Strategy and Tactics in
Standardizationî,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 117-131.
Birke, Daniel (2009), “The Economics of Networks: A Survey of the Empirical Literature,” Journal of
Economic Surveys, 23(4), 762-793.
Borenstein, Severin (1991), “Selling Costs and Switching Costs: Explaining Retail Gasoline Margins,”
RAND Journal of Economcis, Vol. 22, 354-369.
Bouckaert, Jan and Hans Degryse (2004), “Softening Competition by Inducing Switching in Credit
Markets,” The Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 52, 27-52.
Braithwaite, Dorothea (1928), “The Economic Effects of Advertisement,” Economic Journal, 38, 16–37.
Cabral, Luis M.B. and Miguel Villas-Boas (2005), “Bertrand Supertraps”, Management Science, (April),
vol. 51 no. 4 599-613.
Caminal, Ramon, and Carmen Matutes. "Endogenous switching costs in a duopoly model." International
Journal of Industrial Organization 8.3 (1990): 353-373.
Chounard, Hayley H. and Jeffrey M. Perloff (2007), “Gasoline Price Differences: Taxes, Pollution
Regulations, Mergers, Market Power, and Market Conditions,” The B. E. Journal of Economic Analysis &
Policy, Vol. 7, Article 8.
Chun-Yoon, Jongsuk, and Cynthia R. Jasper. "Key Dimensions of Women's Ready-to-Wear Apparel:
Developing a Consumer Size-Labeling System." Clothing and Textiles Research Journal 14.1 (1996): 89-
95.
21 | P a g e
Crawford Gregory S. and Matthew Shum (2005), "Uncertainty and Learning in Pharmaceutical Demand,"
Econometrica, 73(4), 1137-1173.
Darke, Peter R., and Robin JB Ritchie. "The defensive consumer: Advertising deception, defensive
processing, and distrust." Journal of Marketing Research (2007): 114-127.
Delk, Ann E., and N. L. Cassill. "Jeans sizing: problems and recommendations." Apparel Manufacturer
1.2 (1989): 18-23.
Deltas, George (2008), “Retail Gasoline Price Dynamics and local Market Power,” The Journal of
Industrial Economics, Vol. 56, 613-628.
DesMarteau, Kathleen (2000), “Let the Fit Revolution begin,” Bobbin, 42(2), 42-56.
DMA (2006), Statistical Fact Book, Direct Marketing Association, New York NY.
Ellison, Glenn and Sara Fisher Ellison (2009), “Search, Obfuscation, and Price Elasticities on the Internet,”
Econometrica, 77(2), 427-452.
Erdem, Tulin and Michael Keane (1996), “Decision-Making Under Uncertainty: Capturing Dynamic Brand
Choice Processes in Turbulent Consumer Goods Markets,” Marketing Science, 15, 1–20.
Farrell, Joseph and Garth Saloner (1985), “Standardization, Compatibility and Innovation,” Rand Journal
of Economics, 16, 70-83.
Farrell, Joseph and Garth Saloner (1986), “Installed Base and Compatibility – Innovation, Product
Preannouncements, and Predation,” American Economic Review, 76(5), 940-955.
Feldman, Jack M. and John G. Lynch Jr. (1988), “Self-Generated Validity and Other Effects of
Measurement on Belief, Attitude, Intention, and Behavior,” Journal of Applied Psychology, 73(3), 421-
435.
Gaudel, Alexia and Robert Sugden (2012), “Spurious Complexity and Common Standards in Markets for
Consumer Goods,” Economica, Vol 79, Issue 314, 209-225.
Granados, Nelson, Alok Gupta and Robert J. Kauffman (2012), “Online and Offline Demand and Price
Elasticities: Evidence from the Travel Industry,” Information Systems Research, Vol. 23(1), 164-181.
Janakiraman, Ramkumar, Catarina Sismeiro, and Shantanu Dutta (2009), “Perception Spillovers Across
Competing Brands: A Disaggregate Model of How and When,” Journal of Marketing Research, XLVI
(August), 467-481.
Katz, Michael L. and Carl Shapiro (1985), “Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility.”
American Economic Review, 424-440.
Katz, Michael L. and Carl Shapiro (1985), “Systems Competition and Network Effects.” Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 8(2), 93-115.
22 | P a g e
Kim, Moshe, Doron Kliger and Bent Vale (2003), “Estimating Switching Costs: the Case of Banking,”
Journal of Financial Intermediation, 12, 25-56.
Kinley, Tammy R. (2005), “Size Variation in Women’s Pants,” Clothing and textiles Research Journal, Vol.
21(1), 19-31.
Klemperer, Paul (1987), “Markets with Consumer Switching Costs,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
102, 375-394.
Klemperer, Paul (1995), “Competition When Consumers Have Switching Costs: An Overview with
Applications to Industrial Organization, Macroeconomics, and International Trade,” Review of Economic
Studies, 62, 515-539.
Knittel, Christopher R. (1997), “Interstate Long Distance Rates: Search Costs, Switching Costs, and
Market Power,” Review of Industrial Organization, Vol. 12, 519-536.
Lal, Rajiv and Miklos Sarvary (1999), “When and How is the Internet Likely to Decrease Price
Competition,” Marketing Science, 18(4), 485-503.
Lee Jongsu, Yeonbae Kim, Jeong-Dong Lee and Yuri Park (2006), “Estimating the Extent of Potential
Competition in the Korean Mobile Telecommunications Market: Switching Costs and Number
Portability,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 24, 107-124.
Levey, Richard H. (2011), “Acquisition Spending, Direct Mail on the Rise: Winterberry Report,” January
26 2011, http://chiefmarketer.com/direct/news/winterberry-biegel-direct-mail-digital-rise-0126/.
Marinoso, Begona Garcia (2001), “Technological Incompatibility, Endogenous Switching Costs and Lock-
In,” The Journal of industrial Economics, Vol. 49, 281-298.
Morrin, Maureen (1999), “The impact of Brand Extensions on Parent Brand Memory Structures and
Retrieval Processes,” Journal of Marketing Research, 36, November, 517-525.
Nilssen, Tore (1992), “Two Kinds of Consumer Switching Costs,” RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 23,
579-589.
Ozga, S. Andrew. "Imperfect markets through lack of knowledge." The Quarterly Journal of Economics
(1960): 29-52.
Robinson, Joan, et al. The economics of imperfect competition. London: Macmillan, 1933.
Roehm, Michelle and Alice Tybout (2006), “When Will a Brand Scandal Spill Over, and How Should
Competitors Respond?” Journal of Marketing Research, 43 (August), 366-373.
Sharpe Stephen A. (1997), “The Effect of Consumer Switching Costs on Prices: A Theory and Application
to the Bank Deposit Market,” Review of Industrial Organization, Vol. 12, 79-94.
Shy, Oz. "A quick-and-easy method for estimating switching costs." International Journal of Industrial
Organization 20.1 (2002): 71-87.
23 | P a g e
Sieben, Wanda A., and Hsiu-I. Jessie Chen-Yu. "The Accuracy of Size Information on Men's Prewashed
Jeans." Clothing and Textiles Research Journal 11.1 (1992): 74-82.
Stigler, George J. (1961), “The Economics of Information,” Journal of Political Economy, 69, 213–225.
Stigler, George J. and Gary S. Becker (1977), “De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum,” American Economic
Review, 67, 76–90.
Suarez, Fernando F. (2005), “Network Effects Revisited: The Role of Strong Ties in Technology Selection,”
Academy of Management Journal, 48(4), 710-720.
Tybout, Alice and Michelle Roehm (2009), “Let the Response Fit the Scandal” Harvard Business Review,
(December), 12, 82-88.
Viard, V. Brian. "Do switching costs make markets more or less competitive? The case of 800 ‐number
portability." The Rand Journal of Economics 38.1 (2007): 146-163.
Workman, Jane E. (1991), “Body Measurement Specifications for Fit Models as a Factor in Clothing Size
Variation,” Clothing and textiles research Journal, 10(1), 31-36.
Workman, Jane E. and Elizabeth S. Lentz (2000), “Measurement Specifications for Manufacturers’
Prototype Bodies,” Clothing and textiles Research Journal, 18, 251-259.
24 | P a g e
Table 1. Average Sales at Retail World: All Customers
Treatment Control
Difference
Condition Condition
Measurement Period
The table reports the averages for each Retail World sales measure in the Treatment and Control
Conditions. The outcomes are calculated using the entire twenty-month Measurement Period.
The Historical Sales measures are calculated using the customers’ entire transaction histories
prior to the start of the treatment. Standard errors are in parentheses. *Significantly different
from zero, p < 0.05, **significantly different from zero, p < 0.01.
25 | P a g e
Table 2. Difference in Sales Between Experimental Conditions
by Timing of Customers’ Prior Purchases
Measurement Period
The table describes the difference in the average sales measures between the Treatment and
Control conditions (as a percentage of sales in the Control condition). Positive (negative) values
indicate customers in the Treatment condition placed more (less) orders on average. The
outcomes are calculated using the entire twenty-month Measurement Period. The Historical
Sales measures are calculated using the customers’ entire transaction histories prior to the start
of the treatment. Standard errors are in parentheses. *Significantly different from zero, p <
0.05, **significantly different from zero, p < 0.01.
26 | P a g e
Table 3. The Recency Interaction Estimated at the Customer Level
The table reports coefficient from a negative binomial model estimated at the customer level, where
the dependent variable measures the number of units purchased in the Measurement Period by
customer i. Estimated coefficients that are omitted from Models 2 and 3 include the controls for
seasonality (and their interactions with the Treatment), and the binary flags identifying missing
demographic data. Standard errors are in parentheses.
27 | P a g e
Table 4. Recency Interaction Estimated at the Customer x Category-Level
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5
**
Treatment -1.64% -2.53% -6.26% -1.55% -0.99%
(1.90%) (1.91%) (2.30%) (1.91%) (0.63%)
** **
Treatment * Category Recency (100s days) 0.33% 0.30%
(0.07%) (0.06%)
** **
Category Recency (100s days) -6.37% -5.86%
(0.49%) (0.41%)
**
Treatment * Log Category Recency 2.72%
(0.43%)
**
Log Category Recency -34.28%
(0.98%)
**
Treatment * Intervals Since Last Purchase 2.01%
(0.43%)
**
Intervals Since Last Purchase -41.24%
(1.77%)
**
Treatment * 1-2 Intervals 2.86%
(1.04%)
**
Treatment * 2 Intervals or more 5.85%
(0.98%)
**
1-2 Intervals -63.54%
(3.71%)
**
2 Intervals or more -127.13%
(6.40%)
**
Treatment * Category Recency (100s days) 4.84%
(0.55%)
**
Recency (100s days) -39.63%
(2.02%)
** ** ** ** **
Treatment * Prior Category Units 0.62% 0.57% 0.59% 0.62% 0.63%
(0.05%) (0.06%) (0.05%) (0.05%) (0.05%)
** ** ** ** **
Prior Category Units 0.46% 0.44% 0.44% 0.46% 0.46%
(0.04%) (0.04%) (0.04%) (0.04%) (0.04%)
** ** ** ** **
Age (years) 0.20% 0.16% 0.18% 0.20% 0.18%
(0.05%) (0.05%) (0.05%) (0.05%) (0.05%)
** ** ** ** **
Estimated Household Income ($10,000s) 0.42% 0.39% 0.39% 0.43% 0.42%
(0.06%) (0.06%) (0.07%) (0.06%) (0.06%)
Female Head of Household 2.72% 2.76% 1.77% 2.37% 2.54%
(10.60%) (10.04%) (11.22%) (10.41%) (10.88%)
* * *
Married Head of Household 3.43% 3.34% 1.93% 3.48% 3.55%
(1.68%) (1.87%) (1.82%) (1.67%) (1.68%)
Number of Kids -2.88% -2.40% -2.85% -2.85% -2.76%
(2.31%) (2.36%) (2.41%) (2.29%) (2.34%)
Log Likelihood -3,089,978 -3,079,526 -3,031,000 -3,080,093 -3,103,969
Sample Size 2,214,658 2,214,658 2,214,658 2,214,658 2,214,658
The table reports coefficients from quasi-maximum likelihood Poisson models with (conditional) fixed product category
effects. The dependent variable measures the number of units of category c purchased in the Measurement Period by
customer i. Estimated coefficients that are omitted from Models 2 through 5 include the controls for seasonality (and
their interactions with the Treatment), and the binary flags identifying missing demographic data. The standard errors
are clustered by category and reported in parentheses.
28 | P a g e
Table 5. Return Reasons: Summary Statistics
Table 6. Change in the Return Rate and the Response to the Competitive Advertising
Pearson Correlation
Coefficients
The table reports the pair-wise correlation between the response to the competitive advertising and
both the Change in Return Rate. The Change in Return Rate is estimated using the separate sample
of 3.6 million customers. The response to the competitive advertising measures the % difference in
units purchased in each category by customers in the Treatment and Control conditions. The sample
size for each correlation is 35 (categories). *Significantly different from zero, p < 0.05, **significantly
different from zero, p < 0.01.
29 | P a g e
Table 7. Size Learning Interactions
Estimated at the Customer x Category-Level
Model 1 Model 2
* **
Treatment -4.54% 3.28%
(1.91%) (1.10%)
** **
Treatment * Size Learning -5.60% -5.29%
(1.53%) (1.38%)
** **
Size Learning -5.14% -5.10%
(0.67%) (0.68%)
**
Treatment * No Prior Category Purchase -9.90%
(1.25%)
**
No Prior Category Purchase 243.70%
(11.15%)
** **
Treatment * Category Recency (100s days) 0.39% 0.38%
(0.05%) (0.06%)
** **
Category Recency (100s days) -6.08% -5.95%
(0.49%) (0.49%)
** **
Treatment * Prior Category Units 0.39% 0.41%
(0.05%) (0.05%)
** **
Prior Category Units 0.38% 0.38%
(0.04%) (0.04%)
**
Age (00s years) 0.18% 0.06%
(0.05%) (0.09%)
** **
Estimated Household Income ($10,000s) 0.45% 0.56%
(0.05%) (0.05%)
Female Head of Household 3.28% 7.00%
(10.67%) (10.13%)
**
Married Head of Household 3.46% 5.94%
(1.78%) (1.87%)
Number of Kids -2.68% -0.34%
(2.52%) (2.89%)
Log Likelihood -2,798,281 -5,175,369
The table reports coefficients from a quasi-maximum likelihood Poisson model with
(conditional) fixed product category effects. The dependent variable measures the
number of units of category c purchased in the Measurement Period by customer i.
Estimated coefficients that are omitted from the table include the controls for
seasonality (and their interactions with the Treatment), and the binary flags
identifying missing demographic data. The standard errors are clustered by
category and reported in parentheses.
30 | P a g e
Figure 1. Change in Return Rates in Categories With / Without Item Sizes
-1.00%
-1.50%
-1.45%
-2.00%
The figure reports the average change in the return rates in categories with / without item sizes. The change in
the return rates is measured as the difference in the return rates on a customer’s first and last order in the
category. The unit of analysis is a category x customer and the sample includes all customers who placed at each
two orders in a category. The sample sizes are 5,160,972 for items with sizes and 1,245,168 for items without
sizes. The differences in the two averages are statistically significant (p<0.01) for all four return reasons.
-1.00% -0.88%
-1.50%
-1.50%
-2.00%
The figure reports the average change in the return rates in Childrens’ categories vs. Other categories. The
change in the return rates is measured as the difference in the return rates on a customer’s first and last order in
the category. The unit of analysis is a category x customer and the sample includes all customers who placed at
each two orders in a category. The sample sizes are 429,128 for the Childrens’ categories and 4,731,844 for the
other categories. The differences in the two averages are statistically significant (p<0.01) for all four return
reasons.
31 | P a g e
Figure 3. The Response to the Competitive Advertising by Category
and the Change in the Rate of Size Returns
6%
4%
Advertising (by category)
Response to Competitive
2%
0%
-3% -2% -1% 0% 1%
-2%
-4%
-6%
-8%
Change in Return Rate
The y-axis measures the percentage difference in the average number of units purchased in each
category by customers in the Treatment and Control conditions. Positive (negative) values indicate
customers in the Treatment condition ordered more (less) units on average. The x-axis measures the
change in return rates between customers first and last orders in the category. The measure for each
category is averaged across customers who had placed at least 2 orders in the category using the
separate sample of 3.6 million customers. The figure includes a linear trend line.
32 | P a g e
Appendix Table A1. Examples of Mailing Requests
Request 20 Request 21 Request 22
Company K P AJ
Request Date 2/20/06 2/9/06 3/13/06
Mail Date 3/25/06 3/28/06 4/2/06
Mailing Piece Spring 2006 catalog Spring preview catalog March catalog
Selection Criteria Customers who spent Female customers who Female customers who
$100 or more dollars in spent $75 or more since live in mid-West states
the last 6 months from the November 2005 on and purchased products
childrens’ catalogs. women’s’ apparel other than apparel in the
Exclude previously used products last three months.
customers.
In the first example (Request Number 20), on February 2, 2006 Company K asked for its Spring 2006
catalog to be sent to 28,867 customers who had spent $100 or more in the last six-months on items
from Retail World’s childrens’ catalogs. Company K also specified that any customers included in
previous requests were to be excluded. The third-party is responsible for both identifying the qualifying
customers and fulfilling the mailing request. In this case the third-party firm found 25,905 of Retail
World’s customers that qualified under these criteria and organized for Company K’s Spring 2006
catalog to be mailed to these customers on March 25, 2006. Company K never receives the actual
names of the customers who were mailed. Because the 25,905 customers believe that they were mailed
a catalog directly by Company K, any orders they place are made directly with this company.
33 | P a g e
Appendix Table A2. Competitors’ Mailing Request Criteria
Percentage of
Frequency
Requests
Recency: Time Since Last Purchase
Less than 3 months 96 32%
Less than 6 months 54 18%
Within 7 to 12 months 27 9%
Specific months 68 23%
Any recency criterion 262 87%
Amount Spent
Over $50 36 12%
Over $75 46 15%
Over $100 83 28%
Over $150 62 21%
Any amount spent criterion 240 80%
Other Criteria
Purchasers from a specific catalog-type 150 50%
Purchases from a specific category 128 43%
Customer gender 112 37%
Specific zip codes 50 17%
Sample Size
Total number of mailing requests 301
This table summarizes the criteria used in the 301 mailing requests from competitors.
34 | P a g e
Appendix Table A3. Eligible Mailing Requests
by Customers’ Historical Purchases From the Retail World
Average Number
Sample Size
of Eligible Requests
This table summarizes the estimated number of competitors’ mailing requests (out of a
total of 301) that each customer was eligible for. Customers are grouped according to
their historical purchases from Retail World. We restricted attention to transactions that
occurred prior to the start of the competitive advertising event.
35 | P a g e