Stakeholder Analysis Crosby PDF

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 7

Stakeholder Analysis

Source: Managing Policy Reform: Concept and Tools for Decision-Makers


in Developing and Transitioning Countries

By: Benjamin Crosby and Derick Brinkerhoff

The recognition of the key role played by stakeholders in the determination of a policy, its
implementation, and outcomes has mad stakeholders analysis a vital tool for policy managers.
Stakeholder analysis is designed to assist policy managers in identifying those interests that
should be taken into account when making a decision. To that end, stakeholder analysis is
directed at assessing the nature of a policy’s constituents, their interests, their expectations, the
strength or intensity of their interest in the issue, and the resources that they can bring to bear on
the outcomes of a policy change. Stakeholder analysis is useful both when policies are being
formulated and when they are being implemented. At the formulation stage it helps to ensure that
policies are shaped in ways that improve their prospects for adoption and implementation. And
during the implementation stage the tool helps build an appreciation of the relative importance of
different groups and the role each might play in the implementation process. This chapter
presents a simple methodology to assess the array of stakeholders that may be encountered in
any policy implementation effort.

1 What is a Stakeholder?
A stakeholder is defined as an individual or group that makes a difference, or that can affect or be
affected by the achievement of the organization’s objectives (see Freeman 1984, Mitroff 1983,
Mitchell et al. 1997). Clearly these are broad criteria, capable of including nearly any group
touched in even the most minor way. Certain approaches to stakeholder analysis argue that all
those affected by a policy, even potentially, should be included in a stakeholder analysis. While
perhaps desirable, such inclusive approaches are not very practical. To be useful, stakeholder
analysis must indicate why interests should be taken into account. How do we know when an
actor’s interests should be given serious consideration?

There are at least three criteria that can be used to determine the relative importance of a
stakeholder. First, if an actor or group is in a position to damage or weaken the authority or
political support for decision-makers or their organizations, it needs to be considered. For
instance, industrial producers in many developing countries are frequently opposed to reforms to
facilitate a more export-driven economy. Since these stakeholders are often the most powerful
economically, they are generally in a position to weaken political authority should they actively
oppose the policy reform (see, for example, Haggard and Webb 1994, Alesina and Drazen 1991).

Second, if the group’s presence and/or provides a net benefit, strengthens implementing
agencies, and enhances decision-makers’ authority (and capacity to secure compliance with
decisions), then it should be given close consideration. For example, if a group can bring new
resources or provide entry into a new market, such as associations of non-traditional exporters, it
should be taken into account.

Third, if a group is capable of influencing the direction or mix of implementing organizations’


activities, it needs to be counted as a stakeholder. Service users and consumers are important
stakeholders of organizations charged with the delivery of public services. In industrialized
nations, consumer interests are protected by laws, and these stakeholders can be mobilized
through advocacy and consumer protection groups. Failure to take into account their interests
can put policy managers in a precarious position.

Generally, stakeholder analysis focuses on two key elements. Groups or actors are analyzed in
terms of (1) the interest they have in a particular issue, and (2) the quantity and types of
resources they can mobilize to affect outcomes regarding that issue. The degree to which each
of these elements is analyzed and weighted varies considerably depending upon the level of
detail in the analysis. As a rule of thumb, only those groups with resources that they can mobilize
and apply directly for or against an issue should be included. They are the groups with the
potential to affect decisions or implementation outcomes. However, for poverty-focused reforms,
gender policies, and policies such as those related to HIV/AIDS, it is important to recognize that
critical stakeholders may be those without voice or resources to make their views and desires
heard, for example, the poor, women, children, ethnic minorities, and so forth. Sometimes policy
managers will need to make extra efforts to assure that their interests are accounted for.

2 When to Carry Out a Stakeholder Analysis


When should policy managers undertake stakeholder analysis? There are two points at which
stakeholder analysis is critical. First, when the policy is being formulated---at the point when
decisions are made that will influence who will be a winner and who will be a loser. The second
point is in the formulation of a strategy for implementation. It is at this point that decisions
become critical in terms of assuring alliances and support. A solid analysis of stakeholder
expectations and a keen appreciation of the relative importance of different stakeholder groups
can be key input for the design of strategies to handle certain groups, knowing what elements of
the policy should be emphasized, what kind of policy communication will work with which
audiences, and how best to craft policy messages to assure future support.

Finally, managers need to pay attention to the balance between the level of effort devoted to the
analysis and the utility the information. It can be tempting to devote too much time or too much
credence to the analysis. Stakeholder analysis is only a tool, one that helps to understand better
the field upon which policy change and the implementation of those changes will be played. It is
not an end in itself.

3 Conducting a Stakeholder Analysis


The approach to stakeholder analysis presented here employs a simple matrix in which
information for each group is arrayed according to the group’s interests, the type and level of
resources is possesses, its capacity for mobilization or resources, and the group’s position on the
issue in question. The matrix provides a means for estimating the importance or potential impact
of the various stakeholders’ interest in a given issue or policy and thereby assists decision-
makers or policy managers in their determination of which of those groups ought to be taken into
account in the decision-making calculus (see Table 6.1).

As with other approaches, Table 6.1 summarizes stakeholders’ interests and their positions on
the issues (see Honadle and Cooper 1989, Brinkerhoff 1991). The first column (Group) of Table
6.1 presents a list of relevant stakeholders. Although a full listing of stakeholders would include
any person or group affected by, or able to affect, a given policy, for purposes of this analysis
stakeholders are considered relevant if and only if the group or actor has significant resources
that can be applied for or against the implementation of the policy. Another way to set priorities
among stakeholders is in terms of their power (ability to command compliance), legitimacy (extent
to which the stakeholder’s claims are seen as appropriate and proper), and urgency (the degree
to which the stakeholder’s claims call for immediate action) (Mitchell et al. 1997). The best way to
develop a first draft of this list is usually in a brainstorming session with six to ten knowledgeable
practitioners. It is not unusual for such brainstorming sessions to identify twenty or thirty
significant stakeholders.

This preliminary list is then evaluated and used as a point of departure for the analysis.

Stakeholder Analysis Matrix


Group’s interest in Resource mobilization
Group Resources available Position on issue
issue capacity
Name of Group Estimate of the level of Summary of resources Estimate of which and Estimate of the
interest of the group in held by group or to how easily group can group’s position on
the issue (e.g. high to which it has access. mobilize resources in the issue.
low) (These may include pursuit of objectives.
financial, information, (E.g., pro or con,
It is also useful to status, legitimacy, (May be defined as high or positive to
indicate exactly what coercion.) to low or may use more negative, or
those interests are. quantitative indicators nominal
Include specifics. such as +5 to -5.) quantitative
measures such as
+3 to -3.)

The second column (Group’s interest in the issue) lists, for each stakeholder, those interests that
will be affected by the policy or decision to be taken. What are the group’s specific interests in
the policy? The analyst should be careful to select only those two or three interests and/or
expectations that are most important. The relative level or intensity of interest in each issue
should also be noted to signal the relative priority of the issue in the group. Relative importance
or priority has implications for what the group is willing to invest with respect to support or
opposition to the issue. Although sophisticated means of specifying intensity of interest may be
used, a simple indication of high, medium, or low intensity will usually suffice.

In the third column (Resources available) are noted those resources that the group possesses
that could be brought to bear in the policy implementation process. Generally, the greater the
level of resources a particular stakeholder can mobilize, the greater its relative influence will be
on policy processes and outcomes. Close and systematic attention to the estimation of resources
and the capacity of the group to bring these resources to bear on a particular policy or issue will
allow policy managers to separate the important from the less critical stakeholders.

Resources may be classed into five types: financial or material resources, access to or control
over vital or important information, status or social position, legitimacy, and coercion. In trying to
determine economic or material resources, managers might ask if the group has the financial
resources to mount a lobbying or advocacy program in favor of or against the policy. Does the
group have influence over some prominent sector of the economy, and would its efforts either in
favor of, or opposed to, the policy make a difference in implementation progress? Can the group
offer some special knowledge or information? Does it have information critical to the formulation
or implementation of policy decisions? Expertise in a new policy area can be a highly valuable
commodity.

The prestige or status that a particular stakeholder can offer may be critical to assure that the
policy or decision receives adequate support. Would a stakeholder’s status and presence on one
side of the policy issue be the key to its implementation? For instance, the position of physicians
on health sector reform is critical because of the high status and respect accorded them in most
countries. At the same time, low social status can offset the value of other resources. For
example, many poverty-focused policies are supported by the poor, but their marginalized and
politically weak status means that they may not be able to serve as effective advocates for
change within a country’s political system (see Robb 1999). Legitimacy is a stakeholder resource
that can provide policy implementers with important support to move ahead with reform (see
Chapter 2 and the discussion of the implementation task framework). Conversely, lack of
legitimacy can be harmful. In a parliamentary democracy, for example, if the prime minister loses
the legitimacy accorded by his party (through a no-confidence vote), the government will be
obliged to resign.

Finally, coercive action is a resource that, if controlled and directed, can be an important asset to
a stakeholder. A labor union will typically use the threat of a strike to achieve its demands,
coercing the employer by shutting down operations of the organization. Marginalized urban
dwellers can use similar tactics by blocking streets and disrupting services to achieve certain
demands. Urban transport owners may halt their services to force authorization of a fare hike or
to protest increases in gasoline prices. However, when violence is spontaneous or cannot be
controlled and directed, it is not a resource.

In the fourth column (Resource mobilization capacity), analysts should note the ease and speed
with which the group can mobilize and deploy its resources. Just having resources is not enough.
It is important to be able to mobilize or use those resources opportunely. Resources that can be
mobilized quickly are advantageous if the issue has immediacy, but less so if the impact is further
in the future. If the group cannot mobilize or make effective use of its resources, then they are
not resources in any meaningful sense. If a group cannot produce a study that will sway
decision-makers to its point of view, its informational resource is thereby limited. For example, if
a business association is unable to raise funds for a media campaign to promote its interests, the
fact that the association represents some of the country’s most powerful economic interests
means little. Analysts should note the group’s capacity to mobilize, but also note limitations on
the use of the resources at the group’s disposal.

Finally, in column 5 (Position on issue), the group’s position on the issue should be examined and
noted. Judgment should be more discrete than a simple for or against. It should give an
indication of the relative strength of the group’s support or opposition to the issue. If a group is
barely in favor of an issue, a convincing argument by an opposition viewpoint could be enough to
change its position. A simple nominal scale of -3 to +3 can often suffice to show relative support
or opposition.

While stakeholder analysts is certainly helpful to gain a better understanding of the interests and
resources of the important players in policy decision-making and implementation, it is even more
valuable when used in conjunction with other analytic tools such as political mapping or force-field
analysts (see Chapter 8). With political mapping, stakeholder analysis helps to define the degree
and relative position of support as well as comparative importance or salience of a political group
on a particular issue. In the case of force-field analysts, it helps clarify a group’s position on the
policy at hand.

4 Data Gathering for Stakeholder Analysis


Depending on policy manager’s needs and the importance of the issue, simple to very
sophisticated (and expensive) strategies can be employed for collecting information on
stakeholders. As with any analytic tool, the value of a stakeholder analysis lies in the quality of
the data that feed into its preparation. The place to start is with written sources on the country’s
political, economic, and institutional situation. These sources can provide a significant amount of
background information that will help to guide the search for key informants and will orient
analysts to the basic sociopolitical dynamics. This information can be complemented by experts
at local universities and think tanks or embassy staff. Initial data gathering should allow analysts
to formulate some tentative hypotheses regarding the array of stakeholders and their relative
importance for the policy issue in question.

Once the field analysts should seek out key informants from as wide a range as feasible, since
many informants will have particular agendas they wish to promote. Key informants can include
journalists and other members of the media, church leaders, business groups, legislators, staff of
executive agencies, members of political parties, donor agency staff, labor leaders, academics,
consultants, NGOs and civil society groups, labor leaders, military officials, and so on. The wide
range of informants will allow analysts to cross-check data and identify common perceptions,
which increase confidence in the accuracy of the information collected.

Although personal interviews are standard method of obtaining information, other techniques can
be used. We have used informal focus groups and workshops both to collect information and to
use as sounding boards for testing hypotheses. Assembling stakeholder analysis teams that pair
outside experts with knowledgeable locals can work well.

Another critical data gathering issue concerns framing the interview questions. Unless the policy
issue is presented in sufficiency precise terms to allow informants to identify where their interests
lie, the analysis risks being too general and therefore less useful for designing and implementing
policy reforms. In common with all forms of social research, how the questions are formed has
an impact on the answers received (see, for example, Miles and Huberman 1994).

5 Stakeholder Analysis for Central Bank Reform


in Honduras
To illustrate how the process works, the following section presents an example of a stakeholder
analysis carried out by an IPC team in Honduras in 1992 to assess the environment for increased
financial and political independence for the central bank (BHC). The purpose of the exercise was
to gauge the level and strength of support and opposition to proposed reforms in the financial
system to develop a strategy for their initiation and implementation.

Greater independence and autonomy for the BCH was considered quite sensitive, because it had
the potential to shift the balance of influence and power in economic policymaking. Compared to
most central banks in Latin America, the BCH were appointed and removed at the disposition of
the president. Private sector members of the BCH board of directors represented interests of the
commercial banking sector and therefore presented potential for conflicts of interest. A principal
concern was the removal of “politics” from the BCH through overlapping terms for board directors
and the bank’s president.

Banking sector opinion was divided on increased autonomy. Larger or distressed commercial
banks were not anxious to alter the status quo, given the strong influence they exercised on the
BCH board of directors.

Conversely, new entrants (mostly foreign banks) were interested in changing the “rules of the
game” to give them a more competitive position---and thus favored a more independent BCH.
Medium-sized and smaller banks lacking the influence of the larger banks also stood to gain from
a more independent BCH. Actors not allied with the larger banking groups had the potential to
benefit from a more level playing field and independence of the central bank. Stakeholders such
as finance and credit card companies operating at the margin of the formal banking sector had
little to gain by a stronger and more independent BCH.

Apart from the private banking sector there were several actors with a positive interest in a more
independent central bank. The president of the bank favored more autonomy, since it would
energize the modernization process. The superintendent of banks also favored greater
independence to strengthen his own authority. Since the BCH board would be restructured and
less subject to political influence, the opinions of its members were mixed. Public sector
members were more supportive than private sector members. Some BCH staff viewed any
change reluctance, believing that change would alter the current balance of resources and
benefits. However, there were those in management and staff who saw opportunities to be
provided by more political and financial independence. The finance ministry was opposed, since
it viewed the BCH as too powerful and uncontrollable. There were apprehensions that greater
independence might mean less access to resources and less interest on the part of the bank in
maintaining a constructive role in solving the government’s financial problems. Consumers
generally favored a stronger and more independent BCH that could provide a more level playing
field in the banking system and thereby assure greater access to credit. They also felt that a
more independent BCH world be better positioned to break concentrations of credit access and
limit the problem of restricted circulation of money. Private organizations, such as chambers of
commerce and industry and the banking association, supported greater independence, but the
strength of this support was tempered by the mixed interests represented in each organization.
These saw greater independence as a means of limiting the influences on the BCH and of
providing a more level playing field. Opposition to the reform was centered mainly in those
favored by the status quo.

The stakeholder matrix (Table 6.2) presents a summary of the stakeholders just described.
Although support and opposition were divided, a brief review of the table shows that the forces for
more independence for the BCH had a numerical majority. In politics, however, more numerical
strength is often insufficient. What counts is the quality of support: What dies the stakeholder
have to offer the policymaker? Does the stakeholder have certain resources that will make the
group a valuable ally or more powerful opponent? By looking at the data in Table 6.2, it can be
seen clearly that factors other than the stakeholder’s position (interests, resources, capacity to
mobilize resources) can be more determinant.

Table 6.2 indicates that opposition actors, though numerically fewer, were more powerful and
influential in terms of resources and the capacity to mobilize those resources that those
supporting greater independence. The quality of support, for the most part, was not high. The
president of the BCH, while supportive, was reluctant to play an active role in advancing the issue
of greater independence. Management of the bank, while supportive, was only lukewarm. The
finance minister was opposed to increasing BCH independence. The table also reveals that other
groups, particularly those in support, were ill-equipped to influence policy outcomes effectively.
Faced with a well-mobilized opposition such as the large banks, the level of support for the
measure in question dropped away quickly. The table shows that one of the most powerful actors
(large banks and the most resource-endowed actors outside government) were solidly opposed
to expansion of independence of the BCH, since it enjoyed considerable influence under the
status quo. At the same time, several other prominent actors (the BCH board, the finance
minister, and the congress) were either opposed or indifferent. Since they figured prominently in
policy regarding the BCH, their support was vital. Its absence condemned the initiative to failure.

6 Conclusion
Stakeholder analysis should not be viewed as a “one-shot” tool to be applied at the outset of
policy implementation and then not used again. As noted throughout this book, policy
implementation is a long-term process. Even in a relatively stable society, stakeholder coalitions
will shift over time; support and opposition will wax and wane as a function of changing interests,
relatively shifts in power among social groups, increases in capacity, perception of policy
success, and so on. It would be imprudent for policy managers to check the financial health of
their agencies only every three or four years. It would be equally unwise to cheek on the views of
key supporters and opponents of policy change on a similar schedule. In much the same way
that accounting tools are designed to allow managers to track financial status, the iterative
application of stakeholder analysis will help managers to track shifting stakeholder interests and
coalitions and adapt their policy implementation strategies to increase the chances of building
support for reform.

Stakeholder Analysis: Financial and Political Independence for the Honduras Central Bank
Capacity to Position on
Group Interest in issue Resources available mobilize issue (+3 to -
resources 3)
Large banks Maintain influence in central Economic power, high political Very high -3
bank board decisions. influence. Intelligence access.
Foreign banks Level playing field. Objective Linkages with outside banks. Very low +2
central bank decisions. Donor access.
Other banks Avoid greater control by central Moderate economic strength. Low +1
bank. Loose compliance. Low political influence.
Finance companies Flexibility in system. Maintain Those associated with large Very Low -2
status quo to keep market banks have political influence,
niche. other few resources.
Bank association Level playing field. Focus on Weak organization, Low +1
central bank functions. studies/information capacity.
Internal conflict.
Pension funds Maximum assurance of level Major economic resources. High +3
playing field. Competition. Political influence. Growing
awareness of power.
Credit cards “Flexibility” in system. Status Economic resources Very Low -1
quo. information?
President central bank More authority and High status, political influence. Medium to +3
independence, focus on central Economic policy coordinator. low
bank tasks. Losing interest in
issues.
Management central More authority and power to Knowledge of financial system, Low +2
bank enforce. Maintain influence. bureaucratic strength.
Board central bank Maintain political influence, Political influence limited by Medium -1
power. mixed organization. Final
authority on central bank policy.
Superintendent of More independence and power Dependent on central bank, Low -1
Banks to enforce banking rules. subject to board decision-
making.
Minister of Finance Maintain access to cheap Strong political influence with High +3
funding for fiscal deficit. president and donors. Analysis
unit.
Congress Maintain political control in Legislative authority. Weakening High -1
defining rules. government party discipline.
Chamber of Commerce Level playing field but political Moderate influence studies Low 0
influence on board. capacity. Problem of
management internal conflict.
Chamber of Industry Level playing field but maintain Major consumer of credit. Low +2
influence on board of central Moderate political influence.
bank.
Donors Level playing field. Greater Resources “carrot,” Low +2
independence for central bank disbursement “stick.”
to implement policy changes.

You might also like