Elec 9714
Elec 9714
Elec 9714
AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS
ELEC9714
Electricity Industry Planning &
Economics
by
2 World Energy 14
2.1 2015 Energy Trilemma Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
2.1.1 Australia’s Index Ranking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
2.1.2 Switzerland . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
2.2 World Energy Issues Monitor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
2.2.1 What keeps energy leaders awake at night? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
2.2.2 What keeps energy leaders most busy? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
2.2.3 New Issues of 2015 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
i
3 Generation Costs 21
3.1 Costs - now and in the future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
3.2 Levelised Cost of Energy (LCOE) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
3.3 Location of Generation plants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
3.4 Summary of each type of Generation plants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
3.4.1 Coal Fire Generation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
3.4.2 Gas-fired Generation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
3.4.3 Hydro Generation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
3.4.4 Wind Farm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
3.4.5 Solar Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
3.4.6 Biomass Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
3.4.7 Cogeneration Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
3.4.8 Nuclear Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
3.4.9 Geothermal Energy - Radioactive Rock . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
3.4.10 Tidal Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
3.4.11 Wave Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
3.4.12 Capturing CO2 from Power Station . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
3.4.13 Geosequestration Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
3.5 NEM in Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
3.6 Recent asset and investment estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
3.7 Distributed Energy Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
ii
5.6 Electricity Market Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
5.6.1 Gross Pool . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
5.6.2 Net Pool . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
5.7 Electricity Pricing Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
5.7.1 Motivation for trading in electricity derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
5.8 Longer-Term: Key role for derivatives (CFD) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
5.8.1 Key Parameters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
5.8.2 Two sided CFD or swap is a piece of paper stating . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
5.8.3 Trader’s view of CFD trading . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
5.8.4 Generator using CFD as a PPA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
5.8.5 Summary of CFD properties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
5.9 Call and Put Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
5.9.1 Features . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
5.9.2 High Operating Cost . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
5.9.3 End-user Hedge . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
5.10 Market power issues in spot and derivative markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
5.11 Risk Positions and Strategies for market participants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
5.12 Toolbox for Restructuring . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
5.13 “Energy only or + capacity” Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
5.13.1 Market Design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
5.13.2 Conclusions on electricity market design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
Bibliography 60
Appendix A 61
iii
List of Figures
2.1 Top 10 Energy Trilemma Index performers overall and per dimension . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
2.2 Energy Trilemma Balance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
2.3 Energy Trilemma Index Rankings and Balance Score . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
2.4 Diversity of Electricity Generation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
2.5 Fossil Fuel Reserves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
2.6 Fossil Fuel Reserves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
2.7 Energy Trilemma Balance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
2.8 Energy Trilemma Index Rankings and Balance Score . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
2.9 Diversity of Electricity Generation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
2.10 Nuclear Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
2.11 Fossil Fuel Reserves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
2.12 Fossil Fuel Reserves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
2.13 WEC’s Global Energy Issues Monitor 2015 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
iv
5.1 Current Load Duration Curve in 2014 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
5.2 Market Suppliers and Consumers Selling Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
5.3 Single Node Spot Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
5.4 CFD and Electricity Trading . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
5.5 CFD and Electricity Trading cashflow . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
5.6 Call and Spot Generator Surplus . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
5.7 Call and Cap End-users . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
v
List of Tables
vi
Chapter 1
• Substation - consist of transformers that converts high voltage electricity to low voltage for
distribution
• Consumption - Customers use electricity for lightning, heating and to power appliances
• High voltage transmission lines are “undersea” for exporting between countries.
• All houses in VIC are connected to the grid with “Smart Meters” (1/2 hr reading interval)
• Change in generation, 30-40 coal fire generators are most likely to retire soon.
Function perspective focus on the electricity grid as a function of useful delivered energy in an
efficient median to the consumer. From Figure. 1.1, energy losses occurs in every stage of the electricity
conversion from primary to end-use energy form. To reduce these energy losses, each states in Australia
are implementing different kind of energy generating technologies, such as:
1
• TAS: hydro power plants
Some experts argue that direct fuel and heat, in a refined fuel system will transition into the electrical
system. Due to the reduction in gas and coal fire plants and an increasing demand for clean energy,
renewable source technologies such as solar, wind and hydro are transiting into the electricity system.
The electricity demands in NSW are falling due to deindustrialisation. However, unlike QLD electricity
demands, it gives an increase to wind and solar PV generation, while their largest consumer of electricity
are the coal fire plants. Similarly in SA, where coal fire plants activity are decreasing with wind power
system increasing to about 35%.
From Figure. 1.3, typically the electricity energy flow ends at the meter of the consumer. However,
from an electricity economical point of view, the energy flow ends at the appliances of the consumer. For
2
example, the light bulb useful energy is 10% of the 100% of the light bulb consumed. Therefore, if the
consumed energy is 30Watt, only 3 Watt of energy is useful energy, while the 23 Watt of energy is wasted
as heat.
1.3.1 Economics
“The study of choices as they are affected by incentives and resources” Our analysis framework is built
around decision making: who makes them, what are their options and how are their decisions actually
made. Key issues include the mix of centralised and decentralised decision making most appropriate for
particular questions, cooperative and competitive motivations, information and knowledge.
1.3.2 Planning
“long term goals and create future strategies by forward looking decision making”
1.3.3 Investment
Investment is the production per unit time goods which are consumed but are to be used for future
production. Examples include tangibles (such as building a railroad or factory) and intangibles (such as a
year of schooling or on-the-job training)
A decision is the commitment to irrevocably allocate valuable resources with consequences. Decision
making is the cognitive process of selecting a course of action from among multiple alternatives.
Framework:
3
• What decisions (available choices)
A continuum (continuing sequence) between centralised (government and social norms) and decentralised
(commercial) frameworks.
1.3.5 Words
Deregulation the process of removing or reducing state regulations, typically in the economic sphere. It
is the undoing or repeal of governmental regulation of the economy
Liberalisation refers to a relaxation of government restrictions, usually in such areas of social, political
and economic policy.
Privatisation means the transfer of assets from the public (government) sector to the private sector.
Restructuring a reorganisation of a company with a view to achieving greater efficiency and profit, or
to adapt to a changing market.
Ambiguity a lack of decisiveness or commitment resulting from a failure to make a choice between
alternatives.
Decentralised move departments of (a large organization) away from a single administrative center to
other locations, usually granting them some degree of autonomy
In a decision making, the industry must decide on a wide range of objectives such that it will benefit
the industry in the upcoming future. The decisions that the industry can make are:
4
These decisions can be taken as:
4. Transparency: make it clear on what basis, with, what information, decisions are taken
5. Processes
The characteristics of a “Risk Infused Industry” within an electricity Industry structure are:
1. Physical Characteristics: A commodity which can not be stored and which requires a
dedicated transmission ’network’ with complex network dynamics
3. Flat cost curve of generation where marginal cost is only 15% - 25% of total long run cost
4. Commodity nature of product inhibits value based competition resulting in limited degrees of
freedom for competition at the end user level
5. High asset intensity of the industry requiring long time frame investment decisions, where cost is
capital cost driven not opex driven
6. High political interest in the industry driving slow ’interest based’ decisions
The key elements of sustainability developments and interconnections that the electricity industry must
focus are: Economic, Social and Environmental
5
Figure 1.4: Key Elements
A market is a form of coordinated decentralised decision making where participants aim to maximise
their commercial outcomes which requires well-specified tradeable goods and services thus can cause
participants to “reveal their preferences”. The EI needs formal market design since it is difficult to define
tradeable goods and services due to special characteristics of electricity and hence difficult to achieve clear
contractual obligations. It is also difficult to achieve adequate levels of competition due to potential for
market power in primary energy and generation yet little to achieve on the end-user participation.
Traditional industry structure are centralised which are supply-side. Centralised decisions are
unavoidable due to
Industries worldwide have undertaken restructuring to provide greater role for market-based competition
which requires designer markets as special characteristics of electrical flows not amenable to traditional
commodity market.
6
1.5 Greatest Global Electricity Industry investment challenge
The number of people gaining access to electricityLikewise for investment for both grid and off-grid
in:
2010-2015 Gird: 100 Million
2010-2015 Urban: 150 Million
Off-grid: 100 Million
Rural: 250 Million
2016-2030 Gird: 150 Million
2016-2030 Urban: 50 Million
Off-grid: 320 Million
Rural: 780 Million
In 2009, the addition finance require for additional investment is $700 billion which is divided into
Mini-Grid 43%
Isolated off-grid 20%
Grid Connected 37%
• provides accessible, reliable and competitively priced energy for all Australians
On a broader scale
• Energy Information
• International engagement
• Sustainable development
7
1.5.2 Australian (current) energy policy objectives
To set out a cohesive policy to secure long-term domestic energy needs, maintain international
competitiveness and grow our export base.
• give the community confidence that the energy industry is operating in an efficient and sustainable
manner.
• All externality costs and benefits associated with operation of all these options
• All their technical parameters, operating constraints, operation and capital costs and derived energy
service benefits of demand
• An inventory of all existing and potential future generation, network and demand-side
electrical equipment
• All externality costs and benefits associated with operation and investment of all these options
• All their technical parameters, operating constraints, operation and capital costs and derived energy
service benefits of demand
• The ability to control all generation. network and end-use equipment and undertake all investment
decision making.
8
1.6 IEA Energy Atlas (not lecture material)
1.6.1 Electricity
Two countries, namely the People’s Republic of China (23%) and the United States (18%) dominate
the electricity production in the world. They are followed by India, the Russian Federation, Japan,
Canada, Germany, France, Brazil and Korea. The top ten countries account for more than two thirds of
global electricity production.
However when looking at the electricity consumption per capita the ranking is quite different because
electrification rates, penetration of appliances, market saturation, electrical heating or cooling have a
major impact on the level of consumption per capita. For instance, while India is number 3 in terms of
production of electricity, India only appears at the 107th place in terms of electricity consumption per
capita. The consumption per capita map available on the IEA Energy Atlas is very informative on this
respect. Other maps are available for electricity; they include electricity production, share of fossil fuels
in electricity production, share of renewables in electricity production and share of nuclear in electricity
production.
Two thirds of world electricity production come more or less from fossil fuel followed by hydroelectric
plants 16.5%, nuclear plants 10.6%, biofuels and waste 2.0%, and geothermal, solar, wind and other
sources make up the remaining 3.3%.
9
Figure 1.6: Electricity Consumption per Capita
Over the last 40 years, the contribution of renewables to world Total Primary Energy Supply (TPES)
had more or less been stable around 12.5%. Although solid biofuels (mainly fuel wood) are by far the
largest renewable energy source, representing three quarters of global renewables supply, recent dramatic
developments in solar and wind due to supporting policies have started to change the energy renewables
mix, especially for electricity production.
The steep growth of solar and wind compensated the decline in share of hydroelectricity, and therefore
renewables have kept their rank of third largest contributor to global electricity production. They
accounted for 21.6% of world generation in 2013, after coal (41.2%) and slightly behind gas (21.8%), but
ahead of nuclear (10.6%) and oil (4.4%). However, for some countries the share can be much higher,
and in fact equal or close to 100%. This is the case for instance for Iceland with 100% of its electricity
produced by renewables (geothermal and hydro) and Paraguay and Norway, with respectively 100% and
98% of their electricity produced by hydro. The map on the share of electricity produced from renewables
available in the electricity section of the IEA Energy Atlas clearly shows the large share of these countries
and several others. The maps contained in the renewables section of the IEA Energy Atlas represent total
production of renewables, the share of renewables in total energy production, the share of solid biofuels
in total renewables production, the share or renewables in total primary energy supply and the share of
renewables used for electricity production.
The map on the share of renewables in total energy production is especially informative because it
shows that some countries like Ethiopia are over 95% dependent on renewables, in fact in the case of
Ethiopia on solid biofuels not to say on fuel wood for cooking and heating.
The IEA Energy Atlas also allows you to look at the evolution of one indicator for one country or to
make a comparison between several countries. To do so, please go to the bottom of this text and play with
the pre-built graphs to make the comparisons you like for total production of renewables, the share of
renewables in total energy production, the share of solid biofuels in total renewables production, the share
or renewables in total primary energy supply and the share of renewables used for electricity production.
10
Figure 1.7: Energy Production from Renewables (Mtoe)
Data from energy balances complemented or not by various socio-economic information are the basis
for useful indicators to go beyond pure energy flows. For instance, dividing the total primary energy supply
of a country by its energy production gives an indication on the level of self-sufficiency (or dependency)
of a country. Other indicators mix TPES and socio-economic data such as GDP and population: this
is the case for instance for the energy intensity of a country, a ratio between TPES and GDP, which is
often incorrectly used as a proxy for measuring energy efficiency in a country. Energy intensity is not an
indicator of energy efficiency; to build meaningful indicators to assess energy efficiency there is a need for
more detailed energy consumption and activities data (heating consumption and total floor heated floor
area, for instance for the residential sector).
The IEA Energy Atlas provides the user with five selected indicator maps: Total energy production,
energy self-sufficiency, overall energy intensity (based on GDP and GDP PPP) and energy consumption
(TPES) per capita. A quick look at the production map shows that the People’s Republic of China
(dominated by coal), the United States (coal, oil, gas and nuclear) and Russia (coal, oil, gas) are by far
the largest energy producers, followed by Saudi Arabia (oil) and India (coal), accounting together for half
of global production.
It is interesting to look for a little while at the energy intensity map. The fact that Iceland is #4 for
energy intensity perfectly illustrates the importance of dissociating energy intensity and energy efficiency.
If Iceland has a high energy intensity, it is not because the country is not energy efficient; on the contrary,
Iceland is a leader in several energy savings programmes especially for building because of cold winters.
If Iceland has a high energy intensity, it is because a large part of its electricity production comes from
geothermal and because the convention in international statistics for the efficiency of geothermal power
plants is around 10%.
The IEA Energy Atlas also allows you to look at the evolution of one indicator for one country or to
make a comparison between several countries. To do so, please go to the bottom of this text and play with
the pre-built graphs to make the comparisons you like for total energy production, energy self-sufficiency,
energy intensity (based on GDP and GDP PPP) and energy consumption per capita.
11
Figure 1.8: Overall Energy Self-sufficiency (%)
The IEA defines energy security as the “uninterrupted availability of energy sources at an affordable
price”. Energy security has many dimensions: long term energy security which mainly deals with timely
investments to supply energy in line of economic developments and sustainable environmental needs.
Short-term energy security focuses on the ability of the energy system to react promptly to sudden changes
within the supply-demand balance.
Lack of energy security is thus linked to the negative economic and social impacts of either physical
unavailability of energy or prices that are not competitive or the lack of cost-effective storage or electrical
energy. The key measurements of “good energy security” of an electrical flowing industry are the availability
and unavailability as well as the quality of supply the point of end-use.
12
1.8 Economic Efficiency
Today. the energy market is global, fast moving and facing increasingly complex challenges. One of
its biggest challenges is to balance the need for cleaner energy to slow down climate change, while at the
same time satisfy the demand for affordable energy from the emerging markets. Efficiency challenges are
narrowed down into three categories: Allocative, technical or productive and Dynamic efficiency.
• Allocative challenges: relates to the appropriate choice between goods and services, for example,
electricity versus gas
• Productive efficiency: choosing the cheapest method to produce a good or service such as picking
the best technology or work practices
• Dynamic efficiency: supporting innovation and response to change such as Research and Development
(R&D) technological change or environmental impacts or social expectations.
13
Chapter 2
World Energy
The World Energy Trilemma Index registers overall improvements across the three trilemma goals
(Energy security, Environmental Sustainability & Energy Equity). The Index provides a comparative
ranking of a total of 130 countries and awards countries with a balance score. The balance score highlights
how well countries manage the trade-offs between the three energy trilemma dimensions and identities top
performing countries with a AAA score.
In 2015, Switzerland. Sweden and Norway takes the top ranking in the Index. Figure. 2.1 shows the
Top 10 countries for each indexes.
Figure 2.1: Top 10 Energy Trilemma Index performers overall and per dimension
Managing trade-offs between the three dimensions continues to be a challenge for most countries,
as only Switzerland and Sweden obtain ’AAA’ balance score. Despite the evident challenges faced by
14
each country, Index results for the past five years show signs of progress for all dimensions of the energy
trilemma, proving that the transition towards sustainable, balanced energy systems is slowly occurring.
• Global electrification rate risen to 85%, with an additional 222 million people gaining access to
electricity.
From the 21st Conference of the Parties (COP21), discussion about varies regions in relation to emissions
production.
• Asia is almost 50% of global emissions, but the use of renewable energy is increasing, with half of
global investment in renewable energy made is Asia in 2014.
• Europe with ambitious GHG reduction targets set out, with a combination of continued deindustrialisation,
greater energy efficiency and the use of more renewable energy has allowed countries of the European
Union to decouple economic growth and GHG emissions.
• Responsible of 9% of the GHG emissions is countries in Latin America, face with an increasing
challenge driven by changing weather patterns and concerns related to the energy-water-food nexus,
which require the implementation of soft and hard resilience to adapt to potential ’new normal’.
• In the Middle East and North Africa, policies related to energy efficiency and diversification of
the energy mix are given a growing focus.
• Emissions in North America, accounting for 14% of the global total are expected to peak by
2030 and then decrease back to 2010 levels or even lower.Efforts to reduce GHG emissions from
the energy sector will likely focus on energy-efficiency improvements and the development of lower
carbon energy solutions, such as carbon capture and storage technologies.
• Sub-Saharan African countries, located in the lower Index half, registered low emissions from
the energy sector. These countries are expected to experience significant economic growth with
emissions increasing between 30% to 140% by 2050.
15
Figure 2.2: Energy Trilemma Balance
16
2.1.2 Switzerland
17
Table 2.4: Key Metrics
GDP / capita (PPP,
Rate of industrialisation 26.7% $56,839 (US$ per capita) (Group
USD); GPD Group
I)
TPEP : TPEC (net Energy intensity (million
0.47 0.08 quadrillion BTU per US$
energy exporter) BTU per USD)
Emission intensity (CO2 / CO2 emissions (metric
0.12 Mt per US$ 4.93
GDP) tons CO2 per capita)
Energy affordability (US$ Population Access to
0.21 100.00
per kWh) Electricity (%)
The monitor provides a snapshot of what keeps energy leaders awake at night. It helps to define the
world energy agenda and its evolution over time. It provides a high level perception of what constitute
issues of critical uncertainty, in contrast to those that require immediate action or act as developing signals
for the future. Thus, it has developed into an essential tools to understand the complex and uncertainty
environment within which energy leaders must operate.
The World Energy Issues Monitor is comprised of 40 issues across four categories: macroeconomic
risks, geopolitics, business environment and energy vision and technology. The WEC’s Monitor is set in a
context of high uncertainty.
18
2.2.1 What keeps energy leaders awake at night?
Energy prices/volatility has been a critical uncertainty since 2009, which highlights the issue’s
long-lasting importance to energy leaders. In 2015, price volatility remains a key concern, demonstrated
by the more than 50% drop in price over seven months where a barrel of crude oil was priced $108 in
January 2014, reaching its peak price of $112 in June before falling below the $50 benchmark in early
2015.
Commodity price and price volatility are consistently perceived to have a high impact across the
word, which highlights the link between both energy and non energy commodities (e.g. oil and gas) and
the issues of pricing.
The costs of non-energy commodities are failing in line with plunging energy prices, reflecting the
weaker demand from China and the trend of oversupply found with regards to a number of energy markets.
This is perhaps seen most notably for those countries and industries with the strongest links to this
relative slowing demand for example in Australia the price of iron ore fell by more than 49% during phases
of 2014 and in South Africa where commodity price are the second highest uncertainty issue.
Climate framework relates to the uncertainty on the outcome and time-horizon of global climate
negotiations (i.e questions of whether there will be global or regional price on CO2 and if so, what what
price)
The US-China ’climate deal’ makers a change in the positions of two of the largest greenhouse gas
emitters, increasingly putting pressure on other large emitters not bound by targets, such as India. The
extend of the situation will transform into actions, with meaningful effect for national policy and industry
implications.
The role of electric storage to secure the supply of electricity becomes even more important in
combination with the recent commitments towards energy security (G&) and access to energy (UN goal).
At the same time, incentives to deliver required storage and back-up capacity are not strong enough with
traditional market designs, which is a driving factor of uncertainty.
There is however a strong regional split with regards to the extend the issue is perceived to have an
impact on the sector. While Africa perceives climate to have a low impact on the sector, North America
and other OECD countries perceive the impact to be large on the sector, which reflects the expected
degree of commitment to legally binding climate target.
Electric storage is a top critical uncertainty and high chance issue having increased in impact
and uncertainty compared to 2014. The increasing shares of intermittent energy sources is expected to
quadruple by 2035 which further driving the need to storage facilities to secure the supply of energy.
Energy Subsidies, the International Monetary Fund estimates that in 2012 alone, $2 trillion of
government spending/lost revenue was allocated to subsidies fossil fuels globally.
Renewable energies and energy efficiency have consistently been need for action issues in 2013
and 2014. They play an important role towards fulfilling climate targets and commitments towards energy
energy security and access to energy. This is important in view of rising long term energy demand due to
increasing wealth and population growth.
Capital Markets is a high change issue, having moved from a top uncertainty in 2014 to a key
need for action issue in 2015. The WEC World Monitor report 2014 estimates that energy efficiency
investments of $1.7 trillion will be necessary in order to achieve a sustainable energy supply.
19
China/India is an issue with last perceived impact across the world. Key factors that determines
the position of the issue is; for Africa the investment and trade relations as well as technology transfer
with China are a key driver for the perceived impact. In 2012, the Chinese foreign direct investment (FDI)
stock in South Africa, Nigeria and Sudan amounted to approximately $19.8 billion, making half of Chinese
FDL stock in Africa. In North America and other OECD countries, China’s economic development, energy
demand and its effects on energy prices plays a crucial role in the perceived impact associated with the
issue.
Coal, in Asia and North America coal is a key need for action issue, which reflects the regions coal
demand, where Asia is the world’s largest consumer with a 14% share of total use, including the export
basis for the latter as we continue to see the displacement of cheap coal from the US to Europe.
20
Chapter 3
Generation Costs
The distinct ways to generating electricity incur significantly different costs. Generations costs only
focus on the overall expenditure of the plant.
Investment costs are costs incurred that offer potential for future production. Operation costs are
costs incurred for production using past investment. Questions asked is whether to invest now or later, or
how to operation your investment?
21
3.2 Levelised Cost of Energy (LCOE)
Most commonly used tool for measuring and comparing electric power generation costs. It reflects
the minimum cost of energy at which a generator must sell the produced electricity in order to breakeven.
The calculation of LCOD requires a significant of inputs and assumptions. The formula for calculating
LCOE:
Pn I t + M t + Ft
t=1
(1 + r)t
LCOE = Pn (3.1)
Et
t=1
(1 + r)t
Mt = Operations and maintenance expenditure in the year t (carbon price and other costs may be
added)
r = Discount rate
Resource Type
Plant Type
1. Tidal Energy - Upper coastal line of Western Australia and Northern Territory
2. Wave Energy - Bottom Coastal line of WA, SA, VIC and TAS
NSW has Black Coal, Wave Energy in Gunnedah Basin and Wind, Solar Energy
22
3.4 Summary of each type of Generation plants
Figure 3.1: Open Cycle Gas Turbine (OCGT) Figure 3.2: Closed Cycle Gas Turbine (CCGT)
• First stage is identity, a gas turbine generations energy by consuming natural Gas.
• In OCGT, the second stage, the excess heat is wasted while in a CCGT, the heat is transferred to a
Stack which travels through a stream line to operate a stream turbine which runs a different set of
generator.
Hydro uses the flow the water usually from damp to operate the generator.
Capital cost are very high: because of plumbing hot water and stream (PV is quarter of the capital
cost)
Trudge - 2D curved mirrors Linear fresnel: segmented mirrors used to mimic parabola shape
Tower(most popular): an array of helix stack, focusing the heat into one tower which can be connected
to storage tanks at low additional costs. Levelised cost of electricity with storage in the spreadsheet is on
par or lower that those without. 12hrs generator, and don’t store it, the generator must be rated for its
output rate. With storage, the plant can run on a lower rate hence, saving money (investment).
Storage is the most valuable thing. Operation cost: cleaning, plumbing and maintenance
23
3.4.6 Biomass Energy
A stream cycle power plant with heat provided by controlled ongoing nuclear fission.
Capital Costs for nuclear plants are much greater than coal plants due to its complexity build and
research that must be invest into nuclear plants. Also, nuclear plants has the highest construction fail
rate due to over budget or under scheduled plans.
Australia has plentiful of radioactive rock at 3,000m covered by insulated layers. Trials is underway
in SA (Copper Basin).
Relies on high level of volcanic, Australia has radioactive rock aka Nuclear Hard rock deep into the
Earth’s crust. Relocation of people and equipments - geographic location is difficult. Oil and gas dig
deep down however they are very valuable, while geo thermal company only sees hot stream. People still
doesn’t understand the Earths crust which introduces a high level of uncertainties with this technology.
Low-head hydro with two directional flow, less cost-effective than hydro. Usually place in fresh water
due to the corrosive effect of sea water on equipment. Hydro plant, driven by tidal wave, created by the
moon. 20MW plant O&M are high due to salty water & marine life can damage equipments
Wave energy is similar to wind energy, energy density varies dramatically. Need strength to survive
storms yet cheap and sensitive enough to produce energy from small waves. Australia is in the lead with
a couple of pilot technology Blow hole like function where the wave energy is derives from wind energy
Post combustion: capture CO2 and stick it underground or varies chemical process that sucks CO2
and blow it out. CO2 is around 14% of exhaust gas, mainly is nitrogen. 1tonne of coal -> 3tonnes of CO2
IGCC Gasified gas and pre combustion: run hydrogen in a convert gas fire plant and capture the CO2
OxyFuel: handle lots of nitrogen to capture the C02, So burn all the nitrogen and capture the CO2
at the end. Trading cost of operating the plant versus cost for capturing CO2 gas
24
Good news there are 3 options. Bad news, no obvious winner, therefore high uncertainty 600MWatt
coal fire plant ~> to a 400MW coal fire plant due to CO2 capturing and storage. Therefore most of the
money are spend upfront or capturing and storage of energy and CO2.
If lots of money and risk upfront with lots of risk in future operation=bad. Captured CO2 is used for
soft drinks
Extensive experience with injecting CO2 to enhance recovery from depleting oil reservoirs. CO2 used
to enhanced oil recovery plant to produce more oil .
Coal plants runs harder typical higher than gas and hydro plants. It indicating that coal pant is the
cheapest. Installed capacity is 55000MW now With ~330 installed generators
The UK is constructing additional transmissions faculties to bring power plants away from the urban
regions. Investment rate is lower than networks. The network is mono-policy connect and investment is
market driven hence major disconnection between them.
25
Australian electricity demand + supply Australia doesn’t have heavy industry close to people.
Electricity Consumption
• Agriculture 6.7
• Mining 70.5
• Chemical 15.6
• Construction 0.3
• Residential 223
Distributed Generation
• Renewable energy sources including solar thermal, photovoltaics (PV), smaller-scale wind or biomass.
• small-scale fossil fueled generation. combined heat and power (CHP) plants powered with engines,
gas turbines or fuel cells
• Direct energy storage, chemical battery technologies, super-conducting magnetic systems, fly wheels
• Electrical end-user that actively respond to changing conditions; e.g.. “smart” buildings that control
heating and cooling to exploit their inherent thermal energy storage
Energy Efficiency
The big modeling tools are the big stuff well however, terrible in the small smart decision planning
Peak demand is the highest demand. Its more jagged than the average consumption of energy
26
• Energy efficiency
• Residential PV system
• Introduction of new load in the region. (i.e. LNG export in QLD 1GW of energy)
AEMO graphs doesn’t see PV, it sees as reduced demand When the demand starts falling, question ask
when will demand starts rising, which makes investment decision very very hard. AEMO wants more
investments.
27
Chapter 4
Australia is the world leading residential PV penetration with majority of the PV systems located in
SA and QLD.
The average Australian electrical bill have increased about 200% due to the introduction of carbon
tax, 130% increase in network price and a 33% increase in energy price
28
4.1 Capital Recovery Factor
A Capital Recovery Factor (CRF) converts a present value into a stream of equal annual payments
over a specified time, at a specified discount rate (interest). The generation cost consists of annualised
fixed and variable costs, The annualised fixed cost is calaculated from the overnight capital cost of each
generation technology using the CRF, Eqn. 4.1, where m is plant life and i is the discount rate.
i(1 + i)m
CRF = (4.1)
(1 + i)m 1
4.2 Externalities
NEM environment externality costs are likely outweigh direct costs. However, social and economic
benefits of delivered energy services which outweigh both direct and environment costs.
This table will give a better perspective of each characteristics of generation plants against other
technologies.
29
4.4 Commercial Perspectives
This table illustrates the characteristics of each functions in the energy network from the investors
point of view and the potential features for competition.
• Natural monopoly
Distribution No competition
• Large sunk costs
Each technologies are associated with a level of uncertainty which can ranges from economic to legal
risks.
30
Category Types Examples
Market Risk Inadequate price and demand to cover investment
and production cost
Economic Risk
Construction Risk
• Cost overruns
• Projection completion delays
Operation Risk
• Insufficient reserves
31
4.7 Centralised decision making Model
1. the physical electricity industry takes the highest priority which contains equipment, collective and
existing infrastructures (ramp rate, minimal operating level and emissions).
2. Engineering models, which consist of abstract plan of the generation plant (efficiency).
3. Economic models, taking consideration of humans and collectives (costs associated with operation).
Two main charts used to aid decision making is the Operating Cost Estimates (SRMC) and Economic
Dispatch.
It is obvious that the most cheap energy generating plant will dominate other technologies that are
costly to operate. However, this charts gives a good indication of where each technology are position in
term of their operation cost.
32
Figure 4.5: Economic Dispatch
The economic dispatch curve indicates the energy demand for each hour intervals. Most cheap
generation plant will operate at its maximum capacity regardless of the day. However, costly generation
plants such as Gas Turbine and Hydro supplies the peak demands only.
The above two charts only considers variable operating costs. We need to consider capital, fixed and
variable O&M for any possible mix of future generation technologies. The Optimal Resource Mix does the
key comparison between generations.
• Direct Costs
where
CF is capacity factor which is equivalent to percentage of time, indicating how hard the plant operates
33
Figure 4.6: Optimal Resource Mix Chart
The optimal resource mix is the cheapest available options of generation plants for any capacity
factor. This is represented by the enveloped curve. The intersection of the total annual cost for each
technologies in the envelope curve represents the breakeven points.
The load duration curve is a representation of the load demand usually over one year period. The
breakeven points are then projected down to the load duration curve to determine the regions that the
optimal generation plants will operate in.
The Optimal Resource Mix method assumes that all plants are dispatchable across their entire
output range. However, this is not the case for renewable plants due to their non-changing total annual
cost over all output range. Renewables is a strategy to reduce uncertainty risk in gas, coal and carbon
emissions.
34
One approach is to use Residual (net) load duration curve
Integrate resource planning -planning methodology that minimises cost- least cost service delivery, not
least cost of electricity (differences involved due to network issues, security, efficiency cost)
Integrated resource planning looks at the loads and efficiency between the plant to the supply. Around
the full supply chain from resources to the deliver service. Integrate resource planning needs to consider
the chain.
This method is implemented when their is no competition between generation plants. In most
situation, the market determines the prices through negotiation or auction trading where uncertainty
comes from the market design or industry structure (supply-demand balance, degree of market power)
35
Chapter 5
• Risk
– Low efficiency
– low innovation (lack of completion)
– stakeholder capture (politicians, contractors, the public, employees of the organisation)
– economically efficient signaling to the demand side
• Process issues
– transparency (vertically integrated utilises can be ether very high or very low)
– stakeholder consultation processes
– separation of powers between those who make the rules, put them into operation and judge
them.
In Australia, all generation planning, investment and operation are all undertaken by Electricity
Commission of NSW. NSW electricity consumption +9%/year in 1960-70s, +6%/year up to the early
1980s, then 3%/year.
36
Commission Findings
Currently, the Electricity Commission generation plan is that they can defer a new base-load investment
proposed since they are:
• more gas turbines rather than base-load coal which will save money (~300MW of peaking per
600MW of base)
NSW generation planning suffers from procedural problems due to the lack of consultation with the public
in industry which is funded by consumers. Generation are large project which make the lead time difficult
to exercise adequate political control. Such organisation can inefficiently allocate societal wealth for excess
capacity which can cost NSW several $billions.
The issue is that existing NSW plant mix is biased towards base-load generations which are are
adequate for present demand despite no significant new base-load plants since Mt Piper in the early 1990s.
A planning methodology which seeks the least cost option for meeting customers’ needs for energy
products. Least cost is determined from the perspective of the community as a whole and strictly should
include all costs borne by the community. The IRP methodology specifically compares both supplyside1
options with demandside2 options on a equal basis on determining the least cost option.
1 such as building power stations
2 such as promoting energy efficiency
37
5.2 Role of Markets in EL Decision Making
A market is a form of coordinated decentralised decision making where the participants aim
to maximise their commercial outcomes. The electricity industries need formal market design because of
difficulty defining tradable goods/services due to special characteristics of electricity. Hence difficult to
achieve clear contractual obligations.
• require well-specified tradeable goods or services and cause participants to reveal their preferences.
A single owner of an electricity industry could maximise Industry benefits of trade (IBOT)
• if all supply costs and all demand side benefits were known
• that set of prices that achieves the same IBOT incremental cost or loss of benefit of delivering
additional flow of energy at any particular location at any particular time similar to usual SRMC
definition.
38
5.3.2 An economic optimisation problem
• In each energy flow meets QOS criteria at local spot price in successive short spot market intervals
Ancillary Services
• resources that maintain availability and quality of supply (systemic or location specific)
If the supplier is selling at $10 and a buying at $12, it is not beneficial for the seller, since there are
other buyers willing to pay more. Want to maximise the area between the supply to demand The clearing
price and quantity is the maximise demand & supply. i.e., never trade on the right of the clearing line.
With all buyers and sellers negotiated as a group, an efficient auction leads to bid to buy, offers to sell
as well as price and quantity while maximising the benefits of trade (consumers’s surplus + supplier’
surplus, surplus = [benefit - purchase cost] or [income - operating cost])
Double auction can accept offers to sell, starting from the lowest price. it can also accept bids to buy,
but starting from the highest. The auction stops when offer price equals to the bid price.
39
5.4 How does an end-user know what to bid to buy electricity?
For example, an aluminium smelter which needs 15MWh to make 1 tonnes of Aluminium which
sells for $1800/t. Non-electricity variable costs are $1100/t. What is the value ($/MWh) of consumed
electricity for this smelter?
Therefore, if the
Consider a simple power system with a hospital that values electricity supply at $1000/MWh and a
generator that has electricity generating costs of $30/MWh.
Any value between $30/MWh to $1000/MWh. The economic solution does not care who profits and
market does not care bout decision of profit.
Consider a simple power system with a hospital that values electricity supply at $1000/MWh and
wishes to expand and hence would require an additional continuous MW of demand. Unfortunately the
generator is already operating at its maximum output and the construction of a new power plant would
cost $175,000/MW/yr with operating costs of $30/MWh.
$175, 000
+ $30/MWh = $59.98/MWh
365 ⇥ 24
Consider a simple power system with a hospital that values electricity supply at $1000/MWh and
wishes to expand and hence would require an additional continuous MW of demand. Ample generation
is available at a wholesale price of $50/MWh. Unfortunately the network supplying the hospital is
constrained and the construction of augmenting the network is $437,000/MW/yr with operating costs of
$1/MWh.
$437, 000
+ $1/MWh + $50/MWh = $100.89/MWh
365 ⇥ 24
40
Therefore the economically efficient price $100.89/MWh to $1000/MWh for the new augmented
network and electricity.
• Unbid decisions is forecast and the assumes that end-users are willing to pay spot market at ceiling
price
NEM uses a gross pool market in which all generators sell all of their electricity through the
market which supply to demand instantaneously. From the generator’s offer, the market determines the
combination of generation to meet demand in the most cost-efficient way.
The market determines the spot price every 5 to 30 minutes for each of the five region of the NEM.
The short term 5 minute refresh sets the operation levels for dispatchable resources.
The gross pool is also temporal and location risk managed collectively: spot market, PASA4 and
SOO.
All generator and load pool must sell to the pool and buyers must buy from the pool.
41
5.6.2 Net Pool
Used by UK NETA as a system based on ’bilateral5 contracts’, which measures the imbalances as the
difference between:
the difference between contract and physical positions is recorded a an imbalance to be settled at a price
that is determined not by the market but by rules set out in the compulsory balancing and settlement
agreement. Therefore, the network is not modelled in the trading agreement.
System operator are given only one day of notice of bilateral trades - dispatches resources consistently.
A single owner of an electricity industry could maximise Industry Benefits of Trade (IBOT), if all
supply costs and all demand side benefits were known.
Optimal prices in a decentralised industry, that set of prices to achieves the same IBOT,
• Otherwise a set of prices that reflect future decisions options is based on best available model of
future price behaviour, including impacts of a specific decision on future prices.
42
5.7.1 Motivation for trading in electricity derivatives
Generators that have fixed costs but face variable spot price
Retailers that buy at variable spot price and sell on pre-determined retail price. Retailers are usually
short life investments but prepare to sign long term contract.
Large end-users that buy at variable spot price and sell in competitive product market
Its only relationship to the physical product is through the future spot price. It creates a financial
obligation related to a future spot market price outcome.
The spot market purely uses derivatives, buying future prices of electricity.
2. Contract quantity = xc
3. A future spot time at which contract will be reverse traded (or closed out) at spot price ps
Trade in CFDs is only related to trade in the physical commodity by the spot price at which the reverse
trade is carried out which determines the financial value.
43
5.8.3 Trader’s view of CFD trading
CFD buyer
CFD seller
Direct end-user using CFD as a hedge against price risk when investing.
End-user wanting to build 15MW factory buying from spot market with expected future price of
$50/MWh (spot market price), with a assume product contract value is $150/MWh.
pc = $150/MWh
xc = 15MW
44
At spot price time, consider two cases:
or Shut down factory and earn a profit from the CFD transaction alone:
profit from CFD = xc (ps pc ) = 15(200 50) = 2250$/h
Company wanting to build a baseload generator (100MW) & required to sell directly into spot market:
– Assume that capital cost of plant is $175.2k/MW/yr ($20/MWh) and can run at 100% capacity factor,
SRMC = $20/MWh
At contract time, generator sells: 100 MW CFD @ 50 $/MWh starting in year x= 5000 $/h
Assuming plant gets built in time and on budget ‘Locked in’ operating profit = 100(50-20) = 3000
$/h from year x
What of overall profitability?
Profitability to the company is $2000/h or $17,520,000/h
At spot time in year x, consider two cases:
1. Spot price = 100 $/MWh With generation of 100 MW, spot + CFD trading
electricity revenue = $8000/h = 100MW(100-20) (price is above contract price) CFD revenue =-$5000
= 100(50-100) Profit = $1000/h ($8000+-$5000-$2000)
2. Spot price = 10 $/MWh
electricity revenue = $1000/h CFD revenue =$4000/h Profit = $0/h ($1000+$4000-$3000-$2000) or
shut down = $2000 (No O&M cost)
45
5.8.5 Summary of CFD properties
CFD protects against future price risk and hence supports longer term operating decisions but also
investment in both load and generation
Thus CFD market predicts future spot market in both price and volume (hedge volume)
Even when fully hedged, there is still an incentive to respond to spot price
The seller must compensate the buyer if the spot price is above the strike price
• unreliable base load generator, to replace when the plant breaks down when spot market is really
high
5.9.1 Features
Unlike CFDs, the option layer must pay a fee to purchase the option
The option fee is based on an estimate of the close out value of the option at spot time:
• a call option will have non zero close out value if the spot price exceeds the option strike price
• a put option will have non zero close out value if the post price is lower than the option strike price
Can create composite derivatives such a collar combines a call option at a higher strike price with a put
option at a lower strike price.
46
5.9.2 High Operating Cost
Generator would like to assured operating surplus will earn return on investment.
• But if operating cost > expected spot price, they cannot benefit from a CFD contract
• Then option fee provides return on investment with size of fee depends on likelihood of spot price
> strike price
If the plant doesn’t even operate, it will get pay regardless of operation. If the spot price increase over
generation price, the profit goes up. Therefore, the revenue price never increase. Profit is absolutely
independent from the spot price.
47
End-user with 100MW inflexible load in market with high price volatility.
Developer can build peaking plant generator with 60 $/MWh operating cost
End-user buys call option from generator which then gets built prior to period T:
– Generator pays end-user the option ‘close out’ value: 100x(200-60) = 14,000 $/h
– End-user buys 100 MW electricity at spot price, receives option ‘close out’ value from generator:
price
20 30 200
($/M W h)
probability 0.35 0.5 0.15
• Cost with option, you only pay $60/MWh for the $200/MWh because of the call.
= (0.35 x 20 + 0.5 x 30 + 0.15 x 60) x 100 = $3100/h
This will save $2100/h average peaking plant will get.
Profit can increase if the spot price increases due to call.
48
5.10 Market power issues in spot and derivative markets
• Regulatory Risk: impact on derivative value due to regulatory decisions (such like Carbon Tax)
49
• Horizontal Restructuring - create competing generators and suppliers
• Access to transmission network - efficient location and interconnection of new generation facilities
Energy only markets intended to incentives generators to offer at their operating costs
• Ability to pay off capital, other fixed costs depends on how much and often market price above
operating cost.
• Some generators and market circumstances prices to low to cover fixed cost.
• Can only price to delivery energy. Use ’energy’ market + ’capacity’ market that provides revenue to
generators on their ability to provide capacity if and as required.
1. Energy-only market
6. Energy markets with forward reserve requirement and centralised capacity markets
A ’designer’ process
50
Restructuring:
51
Chapter 6
Mitigating local and global environmental impacts, notably greenhouse impacts of energy production,
transformation, supply and use.
• Establishing a transparent, wholesale spot market for electricity to enable competition among
generators and retailers
Federal Government
State Governments
52
Council of Australian Government (COAG)
• Cooperative national policy including energy industry restructuring and environmental regulation
• A multi-region gross wholesale electricity spot market with dynamic inter regional loss
• 8 Frequency Control Ancillary Services markets for maintaining supply/demand balance over time
periods < 5 min
• No capacity market or equivalent; participants determine unit commitment through energy spot
market bidding strategy
Networks
Retailers - buy energy from the wholesale market and sell it to end users or onsellers
Onsellers - buy energy from retailers and sell it to customers in embedded networks
Power purchase agreement providers - install generation at a customer’s premises and sell the
generation output to the customer.
53
AEMO Forecasts of ( Power System reliability ) AEMO Operation:
supply and demand and security standards
) Spot Market (
• 10 years (annual) • Network Data
l
Derivative market
• Bilateral trading
• Over-the-counter instruments
Inter-regional hedges
54
Instruments Description
Forward contracts Agreement to exchange the NEM spot
price in the future for an agreed fixed
• swaps (OTC market)
price. Settlement is based on the
• futures (SFE) difference between the future spot price
and the agreed fixed price. Forwards
are called swaps in the OTC markets
and future on the SFE
Options A right - without obligation - to enter
into a transaction at an agreed price in
the future
cap A contract that places a ceiling on the
effective price the buyer will pay for
electricity in the future
floor A contract that sets a minimum
effective price the buyer will pay for
electricity in the future
swaptions/future options An option to enter into a swap/futures
contract at an agreed price and time in
the future
Asian options An option in which the payoff is linked
to the average value of an underlying
asset during a defined period
profiled volume and options for A volumetric option that gives the
sculpted loads holder the right to purchase a flexible
volume in the future at a fixed price
NEL contains NEM rules and access regime which both address network issues.
Network access and pricing, revenue cap for regulated network service providers.
55
Figure 6.1: Regulated Network Services Model
The settlement residue is the difference in the spot market price on both region of the distribution.
Settlement profit usually goes to the retailer. Hence, there are laws to prevent retailers to have full control
of the network.
Each network service provider (NSP) takes own network investment decisions
56
Required to consider distributed resource options
AEMO merges the role of the national electricity market operator with gas market operations in
Victoria. AEMO undertakes new functions:
The National Transmission Planner (NTP) attempts to move the planning focus away from individual
jurisdiction to national grid.
57
6.8 Key Environmental Issues for EI
• Land-use impacts
• water consumption
• pollutants
• Climate change
• Tax
Key focus on electricity industry emission reduction opportunities in policy to date because of low/zero
carbon emission supply options. Options that are particularly interested are:
• energy efficiency
• Nuclear power
• technical status
58
6.9.2 Key Drivers for Renewable Energy
• energy security
6.9.3 Extras
Iceland and Norway are the two largest renewable energy consumer
Table 6.1: A$b/yr AETA high and low technology cost scenarios
59
Bibliography
60
Appendix A
61