SSRN Id3069819
SSRN Id3069819
SSRN Id3069819
Bureau of Economic Research. For helpful comments, the authors thank Alex Albright,
Jordan Barry, Jeremy Bock, Bob Bone, Julie Cohen, Chris Cotropia, Paul Courant, Mechele
Dickerson, Rebecca Eisenberg, Ken Felter, Roger Ford, Mark Gergen, John William Hatfield,
John Eric Humphries, Louis Kaplow, Bill Lee, Mark Lemley, Jonathan Masur, Scott
McCown, Michael Meurer, Martha Minow, Robbie Minton, Linda Mullenix, Justin Nelson,
Randall Rader, Michael Risch, Karen Sandrik, Chester Shiu, Ted Sichelman, Daniel Sokol,
Holger Spamann, Neel Sukhatme, David Taylor, Abe Wickelgren, and participants in
meetings, sessions, or workshops of the American Economics Association, the American Law
and Economics Association, the European Policy for Intellectual Property Association, the
Society for Institutional and Organizational Economics, PatCon 6, the Works in Progress
Intellectual Property Colloquium, the Georgetown University Law Center, the Tel Aviv
University Buchmann Faculty of Law, the Tilburg Law and Economics Center, the University
of Michigan Law School, and the University of Texas School of Law. The authors greatly
appreciate the support of National Science Foundation grants CCF-1216095, SciSIP-
1535813, and SES-1459912, as well as the Harvard Milton Fund and the Ng Fund of the
Harvard Center of Mathematical Sciences and Applications.
Loomer Family Professor, University of Texas School of Law.
INTRODUCTION
Patent litigation reform is coming. Just as in the lead up to the 2011 America
Invents Act (AIA),1 the United States Congress has entertained a host of patent
reform bills over a series of years.2 Many have focused on patent litigation.3 The
House of Representatives passed one of these litigation reform bills by a 325-91
vote in 2013,4 and supermajorities of the House and Senate Judiciary
Committees approved reform bills in 2015.5 Policymakers have promised a
renewed push for reform in 2017.6 Meanwhile, outside pressure for reform has
come not only from the usual suspects among industry stakeholders7 but also
from the popular press. In December 2013, the New York Times editorial board
cheered congressional consideration of sound proposals to restrict abusive
patent litigation.8 In August 2015, the Economist made patent reform its cover
story9 and came close to advocating abolition.10
1 See Joe Matal, A Guide to the Legislative History of the America Invents Act: Part I of
II, 21 FED. CIR. B.J. 435, 438-47 (2012) (chronicling the more than six years of legislative
activity that culminated in the AIA).
2 See infra notes 11-15 and accompanying text (describing recent congressional proposals
American Talent and Entrepreneurship Act (the PATENT Act), S. 1137. Kevin E. Noonan,
Senate Judiciary Committee Passes PATENT Act, JD SUPRA (June 5, 2015),
http://www.jdsupra.com/legalnews/senate-judiciary-committee-passes-85294/
[https://perma.cc/3HNQ-RYL3]. On June 11, 2015, the House Judiciary Committee voted 24-
8 in favor of the Innovation Act, H.R. 9. The Innovation Act, supra note 4.
6 Joseph Marks, Times Too Short for Patent Venue Revamp This Congress, Sponsor Looks
to Next Year, 92 PAT., TRADEMARK & COPYRIGHT J. 1108, 1108 (2016) (reporting that Senator
Jeff Flake had high hopes for [a patent venue reform bills] success in a new Congress, with
a new administration).
7 Cf. Greg Reilly, Linking Patent Reform and Civil Litigation Reform, 47 LOY. U. CHI. L.J.
179, 238 (2015) ([I]t is hard to dispute that procedural reform [of civil litigation] is inevitable
given the political influence of the large corporate interests most burdened . . . . (emphasis
omitted)).
8 Editorial, Congress Takes on Abusive Patent Suits, N.Y. TIMES (Nov. 30, 2013),
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/12/01/opinion/sunday/congress-takes-on-abusive-patent-
suits.html.
9 See ECONOMIST, Aug. 8, 2015 (showcasing a cover with the heading Set innovation
abolish patents altogether . . . .); cf. Intellectual Property: A Question of Utility, ECONOMIST,
Aug. 8, 2015, at 50, 52 ([A]ny lawmaker brave enough to propose doing away with [patents]
altogether . . . would face an onslaught from the intellectual-property lobby.).
1778 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
Reform proposals have tended toward the dramatic. Some proposals have
threatened a revolution in patent litigationfor example, by proposing general
adoption of regular attorney fee shifting along a European loser pays model11
as opposed to the typical U.S. practice of shifting fees only rarely.12 Other
proposals have focused on disempowering so-called patent trolls13a
disparaging moniker for patent-assertion entities (PAEs) that specialize in the
ownership, licensing, and enforcement of patent rights.14 Although the reform
bills endorsed by the House and Senate Judiciary Committees in 2015 were
generally more modest than their predecessors, they were still draconian by the
usual standards of U.S. litigation reform.15
These reform efforts reflect concern that patent assertion activity is
undermining patent laws purpose to promote technological progress
specifically and social welfare more generally.16 A high overall caseload, high
litigation costs, and rampant forum shopping feed these concerns. Even after a
drop in district court filings in 2016, patent-suit filings are proceeding at about
double the rate of the year 2000.17 Moreover, these suits are not cheap. High-
stakes patent litigation tends to cost each side millions of dollars in attorney fees,
and even litigation in which less than $1 million is at stake tends to cost each
11 Adam Smith, Note, Patent TrollsAn Overview of Proposed Legislation and a Solution
That Benefits Small Businesses and Entrepreneurs, 9 OHIO ST. ENTREPRENEURIAL BUS. L.J.
201, 218 (2014) (observing that a congressional bill would essentially switch[] the traditional
assumption of American legal jurisprudence that parties pay their own attorney fees).
12 Cf. 35 U.S.C. 285 (2012) (providing that [t]he court in exceptional [patent-
infringement] cases may award reasonable attorney fees to the prevailing party).
13 See Smith, supra note 11, at 217 (discussing a bill ostensibly designed to target patent
trolls).
14 Cf. John M. Golden, Patent Trolls and Patent Remedies, 85 TEX. L. REV. 2111, 2112
(2007) (noting criticism of the patent trollapparently one of a class of patent owners who
do not provide end products or services themselves, but who do demand royalties as a price
for authorizing the work of others).
15 Compare Protecting American Talent and Entrepreneurship Act, S. 1137, 114th Cong.
3-7 (2015) (proposing patent litigation reforms), and Innovation Act, H.R. 9, 114th Cong.
3 (2015) (same), and Prachi Agarwal, Patent Troll: The Brewing Storm of Patent Reform in
the United States of America, 15 J. MARSHALL REV. INTELL. PROP. L. 63, 76-81 (2015)
(describing provisions of the Innovation and PATENT Acts), with Jared A. Smith & Nicholas
R. Transier, Trolling for an NPE Solution, 7 HASTINGS SCI. & TECH. L.J. 215, 238-39 (2015)
(listing various bills with direct and indirect anti-troll provisions).
16 See, e.g., Agarwal, supra note 15, at 64 ([P]atent trolls stifle, discourage, and threaten
innovation.); Smith, supra note 11, at 201 (noting that the rise of certain patent-assertion
entities . . . has renewed discussion . . . about the state and effectiveness of the current patent
law).
17 According to Lex Machina, over four thousand five hundred patent suits were filed in
2016 compared to just over two thousand three hundred in 2000. See LEX MACHINA,
https://lexmachina.com/ (last visited Aug. 31, 2017).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1779
side several hundred thousand dollars.18 Further, the concentration of new suits
in just two of the nations ninety-four federal judicial districts,19 the Eastern
District of Texas and the District of Delaware, has become astounding.20
According to a representative tally, in each year from 2012 through 2016, as
well as in the first several months of 2017, over 40% of all new patent suits have
been filed in these two districts.21 A May 2017 decision by the Supreme Court
on patent venue22 will most likely shuffle the deck of suit locations but appears
unlikely to fully address concerns with forum shopping. In the immediate
aftermath of the decision, filings in the Eastern District of Texas predictably
decreased, but filings in the District of Delaware (also predictably23) increased,
with the result being that the cumulative percentage of filings in the two districts
remained at about 40% of the total.24
In recent years, multiple tweaks to patent law have responded to concerns
about patent assertion and litigation. Courts have taken a more restrictive
approach to granting injunctions against adjudged infringers, thereby curtailing
the ability of patent holders, particularly PAEs, to extract exorbitant licensing
fees by threatening to shut down a factory or line of business.25 Courts have also
18 AM. INTELLECTUAL PROP. LAW ASSN, 2015 REPORT OF THE ECONOMIC SURVEY 37
(2015) [hereinafter AIPLA 2015 SURVEY] (reporting median costs to pursue a patent suit to
completion of $600,000 when less than $1 million is at stake, $2 million when between $1
million and $10 million is at stake, and over $3 million when more than $10 million is at
stake).
19 Court Role and Structure, U.S. COURTS, http://www.uscourts.gov/about-federal-
OFFICE SHOULD DEFINE QUALITY, REASSESS INCENTIVES, AND IMPROVE CLARITY 14-16 (2016)
(observing that, in 2015, nearly 50% of all patent infringement defendants were named in
cases filed in the Eastern District of Texas); id. at 17 fig.3 (indicating that Delaware is the
second most popular district in which to bring a patent infringement suit).
21 This information was obtained using Lex Machinas search functionality. See LEX
applied to domestic corporations, reside[nce] in [the patent venue statute] refers only to the
State of incorporation. (first alteration in original)).
23 See infra text accompanying note 166.
24 See Matthew Bultman, Gilstraps Venue Test an Encouraging Sign for Patent Owners,
general rule in favor of granting injunctions against adjudged infringers); Thomas F. Cotter
& John M. Golden, Empirical Studies Relating to PatentsRemedies, in RESEARCH
1780 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
tightened the standards for awarding reasonable royalty damages26 and have
made the shifting of attorney fees more likely in light of meritless positions in
litigation.27 Other court decisions have strengthened patentability requirements
of subject-matter eligibility and nonobviousness, thereby making many suits
more likely to fail in response to a motion for dismissal or summary judgment.28
Additional reforms have been more purely procedural. Various district courts
have adopted local rules specific to patent cases that, in principle, should speed
up and streamline litigation but might have contributed to growth in case
filings.29 Through the AIA, Congress expanded opportunities for post-issuance
review of patent validity by the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO).30
Congress also restricted joinder in patent cases in a way intended to reduce the
number of defendants sued by PAEs.31 In 2015, amendments to the Federal
Rules of Civil Procedure abrogated a model form for pleading that had enabled
patent holders to file complaints featuring little more . . . than the name and
number of the patent and an allegation of infringement.32
(abrogating a Federal Circuit rule requiring both subjective bad faith and objective[]
baseless[ness] for a court to award attorney fees for pursuing a weak litigation position).
28 Cf. id.; Golden, supra note 26, at 605 (mentioning Supreme Court decisions that
drivers and make traffic congestion worse, litigation reforms can aggravate, rather than
alleviate, tendencies toward excessive litigation.).
30 John M. Golden, Working Without Chevron: The PTO as Prime Mover, 65 DUKE L.J.
1657, 1666 (2016) (The AIAs provisions for inter partes, post-grant, and covered business
method review notably empower the [USPTOs Patent Trial and Appeal Board (PTAB)] to
conduct more trial-like proceedings than those previously conducted by the [US]PTO.).
31 In response to complaints about PAEs simultaneously suing numerous unrelated
accused infringers in inconvenient venues, Congress overrode the Federal Rules of Civil
Procedures liberal approach to joinder in favor of patent-specific rules that generate a greater
prospect of litigating the same factual and legal questions numerous times. David O. Taylor,
Patent Misjoinder, 88 N.Y.U. L. REV. 652, 654-55 (2013).
32 Matthew Bultman, Stricter Pleading Requirements Take Effect Dec. 1, LAW360 (Nov.
Nonetheless, the flow of patent disputes into the district courts and USPTO
post-issuance proceedings remains high,33 and complaints about abusive patent
litigation continue seemingly unabated.34 This should not be a surprise. The
tweaks to the patent system have not altered three fundamental structural
problems. First, each year the USPTO continues to receive hundreds of
thousands of patent applications and to issue hundreds of thousands of patents.35
At these rates, one cannot reasonably expect the USPTO to perform more than
a relatively cursory examination of patents before they issue.36 Although the
USPTO contributes its own partial corrective by processing about two thousand
petitions for post-issuance review each year,37 these post-issuance efforts still
leave much cleanup work on patent validity to private parties and the courts.
Second, the USPTO contributes even less to the resolution of questions about
patent scope and infringement than it does to the resolution of questions about
patent validity. Indeed, even in adversarial post-issuance proceedings, the
USPTO does not address questions of patent infringement.38 Moreover, in both
pre-issuance and post-issuance proceedings, the USPTO uses a different
[t]he pending abrogation of Rule 84 and all thirty-six of the official forms following the
[Federal Rules of Civil Procedure]).
33 See infra notes 279-81 and accompanying text (describing how, despite various patent
reforms, the filing rates for new patent suits and USPTO post-issuance proceedings remain
high).
34 See, e.g., Impact of Bad Patents on American Businesses Before the Subcomm. on
Courts, Intellectual Property and the Internet of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 115th Cong.
3 (2017) (statement of Sean Reilly, Senior Vice President and Associate General Counsel,
The Clearing House Payments Company L.L.C., also Clearing House Association L.L.C.,
also Financial Services Roundtable) (expressing concern about the ability of patent holders to
extract settlement payments in meritless litigation).
35 U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, U.S. PATENT ACTIVITY: CALENDAR YEARS 1790 TO
THE PRESENT (2016) (reporting that, in every year from 2006 through 2015, the USPTO
received over four hundred thousand utility patent applications and issued over 150,000 utility
patents and over twenty thousand design patents).
36 See infra notes 73-76 and accompanying text (discussing the time available for review
3 (2016) [hereinafter PTAB STATISTICS 2016] (reporting the filing of between one thousand
seven hundred and one thousand nune hundred petitions for inter partes, covered business
method, or post-grant review in each of fiscal years 2015 and 2016); U.S. PATENT &
TRADEMARK OFFICE, EX PARTE REEXAMINATION FILING DATA (2016) (reporting between two
hundred and two hundred fifty filings for ex parte reexamination in each of fiscal years 2015
and 2016).
38 John M. Golden, Patentable Subject Matter and Institutional Choice, 89 TEX. L. REV.
1041, 1053 (2011) ([T]he USPTO has historically had no direct involvement with
determinations of whether an accused infringers conduct in fact constitutes
infringement . . . .).
1782 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
standard for claim construction than that used by the district courts.39 Third, the
several hundred thousand to several million dollar price of patent litigation40
creates real concerns about nuisance suits and access to justice.41 The cost barrier
of patent litigation can be especially problematic for small businesses, which are
generally unable to appear in court pro se.42
Substantially effective patent reform needs to address one or more of these
fundamental problems. This Article addresses the fundamentals by proposing a
new administrative filter for patent suits that, in its complete form, would apply
automatically to all patent suits filed in the district courts. Unlike the USPTO,
this Articles proposed Patent Litigation Review Board (PLRB) would review
questions of claim construction, infringement, and unenforceability, as well as
validity, and it would use a claim-construction standard identical to that of the
courts. Further, the PLRB would focus not on providing final decisions on a
complete record, but on providing non-binding assessments of whether, even at
a preliminary, pre-discovery stage, there is clear evidence that a party to the case
should prevail on one or more issues.43
The details of the proposed framework for PLRB review are intended to be
measured, but this would not be a minor reform. The institution of PLRB review
would constitute the most significant institutional change to the patent system
since 1982, when patent appeals were centralized under a new United States
Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit.44 The general imposition of PLRB
39 Cuozzo Speed Techs., LLC v. Lee, 136 S. Ct. 2131, 2144-45 (2016) (upholding a
41 FED. TRADE COMMN, PATENT ASSERTION ENTITY ACTIVITY: AN FTC STUDY 4 (2016)
(observing that the typical license royalties earned by a class of PAEs that typically sued
potential licensees and settled shortly afterward were less than $300,000, an amount
approximat[ing] the lower bound of early-stage litigation costs).
42 John M. Golden, Litigation in the Middle: The Context of Patent-Infringement
Injunctions, 92 TEX. L. REV. 2075, 2093 (2014) (U.S. courts have ruled that business entities
generally cannot be represented pro se . . . .).
43 A previous proposal for mandatory reexamination of patents asserted in litigation
contemplated USPTO reexamination of a limited subset of validity issues, rather than non-
binding, preliminary review for any potential question of patent validity, enforceability, or
infringement. See Benjamin J. Bradford & Sandra J. Durkin, A Proposal for Mandatory
Patent Reexaminations, 52 IDEA 135, 164-65 (2012) (noting the currently limited scope of
reexaminations while proposing possible extension to encompass additional sources of prior
art and challenges based on a charge of inadequate patent disclosure or patent claim
indefiniteness).
44 Cf. John M. Golden, The Federal Circuit and the D.C. Circuit: Comparative Trials of
Two Semi-Specialized Courts, 78 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 553, 555 (2010) (describing the
creation of the Federal Circuit as an even more recent and radical experiment in semi-
specialization than the preceding creation of the D.C. Circuit).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1783
45 Cf. Irina D. Manta, Bearing Down on Trademark Bullies, 22 FORDHAM INTELL. PROP.
MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 853, 867 (2012) (proposing USPTO review of trademark cease-and-desist
letters).
46 See 35 U.S.C. 154(a)(1) (2012) (describing the patent owners right to exclude); id.
for patent infringement, that party need not know of the infringed patent.48 Nor
need the party have derived the covered subject matter in any way from the
patents inventors or owners.49 Although knowledge of a relevant patent is
generally required for liability for indirect infringement in the nature of aiding
and abetting,50 direct infringement by engaging in such acts as manufacture, use,
sale, or importation occurs regardless of whether any of the parties have
knowledge of the pertinent patent and regardless of the fact that the manufacturer
independently developed all the relevant technology.51 Hence, if a consumer
uses in the United States a smartphone, which was purchased from a retail store
in the United States and imported by a manufacturer who independently
developed all the technology associated with the smartphone, the consumer,
retail store, and manufacturer could all be liable for direct infringement of a U.S.
patent covering technology in the smartphone.
When a patent owner suspects that its patent is being infringed, the owner can
sue in district court52 for relief such as lost profits or reasonable royalty
damages,53 enhanced damages,54 or an injunction.55 The patent owner who
brings such a suit need not be the inventor of the patented technology or the
owner of the relevant rights at the time the patent issued. By statute, patent rights
may be assigned to others.56 This assignability permits the sale of patent rights
to entities that specialize in the acquisition and assertion of patent rights without
any direct involvement in the development, sale, or use of the covered subject
48 Commil USA, LLC v. Cisco Sys., Inc., 135 S. Ct. 1920, 1926 (2015) (observing that
([U]nlike copyright infringement, patent infringement does not require copying and, as a
general rule, does not excuse independent creation.).
50 Global-Tech Appliances, Inc. v. SEB S.A., 563 U.S. 754, 765 (2011) (concluding that
over patent cases); 35 U.S.C. 281 (A patentee shall have remedy by civil action for
infringement of his
patent.).
53 See 35 U.S.C. 284 (providing for compensatory damages for patent infringement);
JANICE MUELLER, PATENT LAW 321 (4th ed. 2013) (describing lost profits and reasonable
royalty as the two primary analytical methods of computing compensatory damages for
patent infringement).
54 35 U.S.C. 284 ([T]he court may increase the damages up to three times the amount
found or assessed.).
55 Id. 283 (granting courts the power to grant injunctions in accordance with the
an instrument in writing).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1785
57 NPEs, which are distinguished from practicing entities (PEs), are patent holders that
do not themselves produce the sort of saleable products, services, or components thereof that
infringement suits tend to target. Mark P. Gergen, John M. Golden & Henry E. Smith, The
Supreme Courts Accidental Revolution? The Test for Permanent Injunctions, 112 COLUM. L.
REV. 203, 244 (2012).
58 LANNING G. BRYER, SCOTT J. LEBSON & MATTHEW D. ASBELL, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY
STRATEGIES FOR THE 21ST CENTURY CORPORATION: A SHIFT IN STRATEGIC AND FINANCIAL
MANAGEMENT 145 (2011) (listing various monikers for so-called [p]atent trolls).
59 See Phillips v. AWH Corp., 415 F.3d 1303, 1313 (2005) (en banc) (Importantly, the
person of ordinary skill in the art is deemed to read the [patent] claim term not only in the
context of the particular claim in which the disputed term appears, but in the context of the
entire patent, including the specification.).
60 See ROBERT PATRICK MERGES & JOHN FITZGERALD DUFFY, PATENT LAW AND POLICY:
CASES AND MATERIALS 13-26 (6th ed. 2013) (describing the patent document and its relation
to the application).
61 Ariad Pharms., Inc. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 598 F.3d 1336, 1351 (Fed. Cir. 2010) (en banc)
(holding that 112 of the Patent Act contains a written description requirement demanding
that the disclosure of the [patent] application relied upon reasonably conveys to those skilled
in the art that the inventor had possession of the claimed subject matter as of the filing date).
62 35 U.S.C. 112(a) (2012).
Community: A Call for an Attorney-Plus-Artisan Perspective, 21 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 321,
322 (2008).
64 35 U.S.C. 112(b).
1786 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
65 See Golden, supra note 63, at 322 (Claimsnumbered clauses at the end of a patent
are meant to provide notice of what a patent covers and to describe a patented invention in a
way that distinguishes it from prior art.).
66 See Festo Corp. v. Shoketsu Kinzoku Kogyo Kabushiki Co., 535 U.S. 722, 732 (2002).
67 See F. Scott Kieff, The Case for Registering Patents and the Law and Economics of
Present Patent-Obtaining Rules, 45 B.C. L. REV. 55, 70-71 (2003) (noting that the
examination process is also called patent prosecution).
68 See MUELLER, supra note 53, at 321 ([T]he substantive threshold for satisfying the
70 See supra text accompanying notes 61-62 (discussing U.S. patent laws written
application reaches an examining group, it is assigned to the appropriate art (i.e., technology)
unit and then to a particular examiner.); MERGES & DUFFY, supra note 60, at 52 (noting the
specialization of the examiners, who are assigned to a particular technology).
73 See U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, U.S. PATENT STATISTICS CHART: CALENDAR
applications filed per year.75 In these thirty hours, the examiner must: (1) read
the application and understand its technical subject matter; (2) search and review
antecedent material (prior art) that could indicate that the claimed invention
lacks novelty or nonobviousness; (3) evaluate satisfaction of patentability
requirements; (4) write up any relied-upon bases for rejecting the application;
and (5) possibly engage in telephone or in-person interviews with the applicant
or the applicants agents.76
Limits on examiner time suffice to indicate that the USPTOs pre-issuance
review can act only as a rough screen for patent application quality. But there
are other reasons to suspect that the USPTO issues a large number of patents or,
at least, individual patent claims that do not really satisfy requirements for
patentability.77 Not only are examiners limited in the time that they can search
prior art, they are generally limited in their ability to consult outside experts78
and other sources of information, including the Internet, during the eighteen
months that applications typically remain confidential.79 Moreover, examiners
bear the burden of proof. From the moment of a patent applications filing, an
entitlement to an issued patent is effectively presumed: the examiner must show
75 See CALENDAR YEAR PATENT STATISTICS, supra note 73 (showing that USPTO received
589,410 utility patent applications, 39,097 design patent applications, and 1140 plant patent
applications in 2015); cf. John M. Golden, Proliferating Patents and Patent Laws Cost
Disease, 51 HOUS. L. REV. 455, 496-97 (2013). More realistic estimates of examiner time
per application put the average time available for these activities at about twenty hours per
application, rather than thirty. See Chris J. Katopis, Perfect Happiness?: Game Theory as a
Tool for Enhancing Patent Quality, 10 YALE J.L. & TECH. 360, 373 (2008) (It is estimated
that, on average, an examiner must examine eighty-seven applications per year, spending
approximately nineteen hours on each application.); Mark A. Lemley, Rational Ignorance
at the Patent Office, 95 NW. U. L. REV. 1495, 1500 (2001) (The total average time the
examiner spends on all these tasks over the two- to three-year prosecution of the patent is
eighteen hours. (emphasis omitted)).
76 See KIEFF ET AL., supra note 72, at 99-102, 101 nn.38-43; Lemley, supra note 75,
at 1500.
77 See Joseph Farrell & Robert P. Merges, Incentives to Challenge and Defend Patents:
Why Litigation Wont Reliably Fix Patent Office Errors and Why Administrative Patent
Review Might Help, 19 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 943, 944-45 (2004) (discussing grounds for
believing that the USPTO issues many patents that should not be enforced, either on
economic or on legal grounds).
78 Cf. Doug Lichtman & Mark A. Lemley, Rethinking Patent Laws Presumption of
Validity, 60 STAN. L. REV. 45, 62 (2007) (advocating a review process enabling examiners
not only to spend at least one full month researching each purported invention, but also to
hire relevant outside experts).
79 See MPEP 904.02(c), at 900-44 (rev. 9th ed. Nov. 2015) (stating that examiner Internet
use must comply with confidentiality requirements); Golden, supra note 63, at 336
([E]xaminers face tight restrictions on their ability to consult any outside evidence, never
mind outside experts.).
1788 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
80 Sean B. Seymore, The Presumption of Patentability, 97 MINN. L. REV. 990, 1023 (2013)
(noting an examiners dual burden of building a prima facie case of [non]patentability and
carrying the ultimate burden of persuasion).
81 Patrick A. Doody, How to Eliminate the Backlog at the Patent Office, 37 AIPLA Q.J.
KIMBERLY A. MOORE, PAUL R. MICHEL & TIMOTHY R. HOLBROOK, PATENT LITIGATION AND
STRATEGY 50 (3d ed. 2008) (Declaratory judgment actions can be a sword for the alleged
infringer as well as a shield.).
83 See 35 U.S.C. 282(b) (2012) (identifying potential defenses in any action involving
Office Grant Too Many Bad Patents? Evidence from a Quasi-Experiment, 67 STAN. L. REV.
613, 621 (2015) (noting the frequently cited statistic that courts invalidate nearly half of all
litigated patents that make it to final judgment).
86 See id. at 621-22 (observing that litigated patents are a highly select sample of patents
88 Gregory Dolin, Dubious Patent Reform, 56 B.C. L. REV. 881, 899 (2015) (noting that
reexamination processes established in 1981 and 1999 were intended to increase the
reliability of issued patents).
89 Id. at 883-84 (discussing the increase in post-issuance review mechanisms beginning in
1981).
90 See U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, PATENT TRIAL AND APPEAL BOARD STATISTICS
92 See 35 U.S.C. 311; MERGES & DUFFY, supra note 60, at 1050-51.
94 See Eric C. Cohen, A Primer on Inter Partes Review, Covered Business Method Review,
and Post-Grant Review Before the Patent Trial and Appeal Board, 24 FED. CIR. B.J. 1, 22
(2014) (The transitional proceeding [for covered business method patents] employs the
standards of post-grant review, except that there is no nine-month deadline for filing and the
estoppel provisions of post-grant review do not apply to civil actions.).
95 See Golden, supra note 30, at 1667 (From mid-2014 through the third quarter of 2015,
filings for inter partes post-issuance proceedings before the PTAB arrived at a rate of about
one hundred fifty per month.).
1790 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
Experience in the Far East with Oppositions Suggests an Alternative Approach for the United
States, 7 N.C. J.L. & TECH. 261, 270 (2006) (describing ex parte reexamination as unduly
favorable to the patentee because of the very limited involvement of the third-party
requester).
99 See AIPLA 2015 SURVEY, supra note 18, at 38.
100 See, e.g., James Bessen, Jennifer Ford & Michael Meurer, The Private and Social Costs
litigation itself.101 This Part describes reasons for concern that patent litigation
has become a morass that often undermines the objectives that Congress intends
patents to serve.
101 See Golden, supra note 49, at 517-18 (discussing costs imposed by the patent system
and noting that excessive rewards from patent rights could induc[e] the diversion of
resources from more socially productive activity).
102 See infra text accompanying notes 103-31.
103 FED. JUDICIAL CTR., 2003-2004 DISTRICT COURT CASE-WEIGHTING STUDY: FINAL
2016).
105 See id. at 5-3 (describing claim construction as one of the most distinctive aspects of
patent litigation).
106 See id. at 5-5 to 5-6 (discussing practices with respect to discovery both before and after
claim construction).
107 Ronald J. Schutz & Jonathan D. Goins, Case Management Issues in Patent Litigation,
5 SEDONA CONF. J. 1, 2 (2004) (Markman briefs and hearings are a critical part of patent
litigation proceedings . . . .).
108 MENELL ET AL., supra note 104, at 5-15.
1792 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
109 See id. at 2-4 to 2-5; Pauline M. Pelletier, The Impact of Local Patent Rules on Rate
and Timing of Case Resolution Relative to Claim Construction: An Empirical Study of the
Past Decade, 8 J. BUS. & TECH. L. 451, 467 (2013) (noting that the Markman order is so
called after the seminal case on claim construction).
110 See Schutz & Goins, supra note 107, at 2 ([T]he courts rulings on claim construction
cases).
112 See MENELL ET AL., supra note 104, at 6-10.
114 Devon Curtis Beane, Note, Whose Right Is It Anyway?: The Evisceration of an
Infringers Seventh Amendment Right in Patent Litigation, 2011 U. ILL. L. REV. 1853, 1858
(noting courts differential treatment of cases where plaintiffs seek damages and those
where the patentee seeks only injunctive relief).
115 Mark A. Lemley, Why Do Juries Decide If Patents Are Valid?, 99 VA. L. REV. 1673,
1674 & n.1 (2013) (Lawyers, scholars, and judges take for granted that when a patent case
goes to trial, that trial will almost always be before a jury.).
116 MENELL ET AL., supra note 104, at 9-2.
117 Id.
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1793
118 See John M. Golden, The Supreme Court as Prime Percolator: A Prescription for
Appellate Review of Questions in Patent Law, 56 UCLA L. REV. 657, 664 (2009) (describing
the patent jurisdiction of the Federal Circuit); John M. Golden, Response, Too Human?
Personal Relationships and Appellate Review, 94 TEX. L. REV. 70, 77 (2016) (discussing the
location and national jurisdiction of the Federal Circuit).
119 MENELL ET AL., supra note 104, at 9-21.
120 See infra note 123.
121 Daniel Klerman & Greg Reilly, Forum Selling, 89 S. CAL. L. REV. 241, 265 & n.131
(2016) (Nationwide, the median time to trial in [patent cases from 2000 to 2007] was two
years.).
122 Golden, supra note 42, at 2077 & n.15.
123 See AIPLA 2015 SURVEY, supra note 18, at 37-39 (listing median litigation costs
through discovery that generally either approximately equal or exceed half of median total
litigation costs).
124 Edward G. Poplawski, Selection and Use of Experts in Patent Cases, 27 AIPLA Q.J. 1,
3 (1999) ([E]xpert testimony is virtually essential in assisting the trier of fact to understand
the evidence and to resolve factual issues in [patent] litigation.).
125 See Lisa C. Wood, Making Your Case with Graphics: An Interview, 22 ANTITRUST 103,
104-05 (2008).
126 See supra note 18 and accompanying text.
1794 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
127 Martin J. Adelman & Gary L. Francione, The Doctrine of Equivalents in Patent Law:
Questions that Pennwalt Did Not Answer, 137 U. PA. L. REV. 673, 682 (1989) ([U]ncertainty
about the scope of patent protection hinders both patent holders and potential defendants from
assessing the possible outcome of litigation or from making other business decisions . . . .
(footnote omitted)).
128 Cf. KIEFF ET AL., supra note 72, at 68.
129 Cf. Colleen Chien, Startups and Patent Trolls, 17 STAN. TECH. L. REV. 461, 472 (2014)
Value, 5 INTL REV. L. & ECON. 3, 3 (1985) (stating that a plaintiff could be likely to
prevail . . . but . . . still not want to go to trial because the litigation costs would exceed the
expected judgment).
131 See Sergio J. Campos, Christopher S. Cotton & Cheng Li, Deterrence Effects Under
Twombly: On the Costs of Increasing Pleading Standards in Litigation, 44 INTL REV. L. &
ECON. 61, 67 (2015) (describing nuisance lawsuits as frivolous lawsuits intended to entice
settlement from a likely innocent defendant who wants to avoid litigation costs).
132 LEX MACHINA, supra note 17; see also Lauren Cohen, Umit G. Gurun & Scott Duke
Kominers, The Growing Problem of Patent Trolling: Cash-Hungry Patent Trolls Are
Squelching Innovationand Should Be Screened Out, 352 SCIENCE 521, 521 (2016)
[hereinafter Cohen et al., Growing Problem] (The last decade has seen a sharp rise in patent
litigation in the United States . . . .); Lauren Cohen, Umit Gurun & Scott Duke Kominers,
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1795
Patent Trolls: Evidence from Targeted Firms 5 (Natl Bureau of Econ. Research, Working
Paper No. 20322, 2014) [hereinafter Cohen et al., Patent Trolls], http://www.nber.org/
papers/w20322.pdf [https://perma.cc/7XE7-DDDV] (The amount of patent-related litigation
has increased tenfold since 2000.).
133 See supra text accompanying note 31 (describing change in joinder rules); see also
Christopher A. Cotropia, Jay P. Kesan & David L. Schwartz, Unpacking Patent Assertion
Entities (PAEs), 99 MINN. L. REV. 649, 655 (2014) ([M]ost of the differences between the
years [2010 and 2012] are likely explained by, and attributable to, a change in the joinder
rules adopted in 2011 . . . .).
134 Matthew Sag, IP Litigation in U.S. District Courts: 1994-2014, 101 IOWA L. REV. 1065,
1082 & tbl.3 (2016) (The real trend in patent litigation over the past two decades can be seen
in the number of defendants filed against.).
135 U.S. GOVT ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, GAO-13-465, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY:
ASSESSING FACTORS THAT AFFECT PATENT INFRINGEMENT LITIGATION COULD HELP IMPROVE
PATENT QUALITY 21 (2013) [hereinafter 2013 GAO REPORT].
136 Id. at 25 n.46.
137 See, e.g., JAMES BESSEN & MICHAEL J. MEURER, PATENT FAILURE: HOW JUDGES,
BUREAUCRATS, AND LAWYERS PUT INNOVATORS AT RISK 187 (2008) (contending that, because
software is an abstract technology, software patents are especially likely to have unclear
boundaries and give rise to opportunistic litigation (emphasis omitted)).
1796 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
138 Alice Corp. v. CLS Bank Intl, 134 S. Ct. 2347, 2352 (2014) (holding that merely
requiring generic computer implementation fails to transform [a specified] abstract idea into
a patent-eligible invention).
139 See 2013 GAO REPORT, supra note 135, at 45 (suggesting that software-related patents
might be a better focus of patent reform efforts than any particular class of patent owners, and
also noting that most of the suits brought by [patent monetization entities from 2007 through
2011] involved software-related patents).
140 Lauren Cohen, Umit G. Gurun & Scott Duke Kominers, Empirical Evidence on the
Behavior and Impact of Patent Trolls: A Survey, in PATENT ASSERTION ENTITIES AND
COMPETITION POLICY 27, 28 fig.3.1 (D. Daniel Sokol ed., 2017) [hereinafter Cohen et al.,
Empirical Evidence].
141 See, e.g., Timo Fischer & Joachim Henkel, Patent Trolls on Markets for Technology
An Emperical Analysis of NPEs Patent Acquisitions, 41 RES. POLY 1519, 1526 (2012)
(NPEs acquire patents that, on average, lie in denser technology fields, received more
forward citations, have more claims, are older, and lie in more crowded technology fields than
patents acquired by practicing firms.); Michael Risch, Patent Troll Myths, 42 SETON HALL
L. REV. 457, 481 (2012) ([T]raditional patent quality measures imply at the very least that
NPE patents look a lot like other litigated patents. If one believes that these measures indicate
patent quality, then NPE patents would appear to be of equal or higher quality.); Sannu K.
Shrestha, Note, Trolls or Market-Makers? An Empirical Analysis of Nonpracticing Entities,
110 COLUM. L. REV. 114, 146 (2010) (citing data indicating that the NPE patents in the
sample have disproportionately higher values than randomly selected litigated patents and the
analyzed set of litigated peer patents).
142 See Cohen et al., Empirical Evidence, supra note 140, at 35 (noting concerns about the
143 Josh Feng & Xavier Jaravel, Who Feeds the Trolls?: Patent Trolls and the Patent
145 John R. Allison, Mark A. Lemley & David L. Schwartz, How Often Do Non-Practicing
Entities Win Patent Suits? 40 (Stanford Law Sch. John M. Olin Program in Law & Econ.,
Paper No. 485, 2016), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2750128
[https://perma.cc/7SS2-5MUQ] (Operating companies won more often [in litigation] than
NPEs in our data set.).
146 Brian J. Love, An Empirical Study of Patent Litigation Timing: Could a Patent Term
Reduction Decimate Trolls Without Harming Innovators?, 161 U. PA. L. REV. 1309, 1312
(2013) (Product-producing companies predominantly enforce their patents soon after they
issue and complete their enforcement activities well before their patents expire. NPEs, on the
other hand, begin asserting their patents relatively late in the patent term and frequently
continue to litigate their patents to expiration.).
147 28 U.S.C. 1400(b) (2012).
In 1990, the Federal Circuit held that this definition determines the scope of
residency for purposes of patent venue.150 Under this ruling, companies that
produced consumer products sold throughout the United States could often be
sued for patent infringement in any of the countrys ninety-four judicial
districts.151 A Supreme Court decision issued in May 2017 overruled the Federal
Circuit, however, holding that a domestic corporation resides only in its State
of incorporation for purposes of the patent venue statute.152 Partly because a
patent infringement suit may also be brought in the judicial district . . . where
the defendant has committed acts of infringement and has a regular and
established place of business,153 the practical significance of the Courts
holding on residency remains to be determined.154
In any event, for at least some patentees, there is an alternative forum beyond
the district courts. Upon complaint by a private party, the International Trade
Commission (the ITC), an independent agency created [t]o protect domestic
industry from unfair practices,155 can launch proceedings that culminate in an
order prohibiting the importation of specified articles or prohibiting domestic
activities involving imported matter.156 But the overall number of ITC
proceedings to enforce patents is much smaller than the number of district court
cases. Whereas several thousand patent suits are initiated annually in district
courts,157 the ITC lists less than eighty total Section 337 proceedings as having
been instituted in each fiscal year between 2010 and 2015 and estimates that less
150 VE Holding Corp. v. Johnson Gas Appliance Co., 917 F.2d 1574, 1584 (Fed. Cir. 1990)
(describing personal jurisdiction as the first test for venue), abrogated by TC Heartland
LLC v. Kraft Foods Grp. Brands LLC, 137 S. Ct. 1514 (2017); Elizabeth P. Offen-Brown,
Note, Forum Shopping and Venue Transfer in Patent Cases: Marshalls Response to TS Tech
and Genentech, 25 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 61, 64-65 (2010) (discussing interpretation of 28
U.S.C. 1400(b)).
151 Jeanne C. Fromer, Patentography, 85 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1444, 1451 (2010) ([A] patent
plaintiff may frequently choose to initiate a lawsuit in virtually any federal district court.);
Mark Liang, The Aftermath of TS Tech: The End of Forum Shopping in Patent Litigation
and Implications for Non-Practicing Entities, 19 TEX. INTELL. PROP. L.J. 29, 39 (observing
that patentees commonly can sue in essentially any district because of the nationwide scope
of sales).
152 TC Heartland LLC, 137 S. Ct. at 1517.
154 Raytheon Co. v. Cray, Inc., 2:15-cv-01554, 2017 WL 2813896, *12 (E.D. Tex. June
29, 2017) (concluding that a fixed physical location in the district is not a prerequisite to
proper venue based on the location of infringing acts and place of business).
155 Sapna Kumar, The Other Patent Agency: Congressional Regulation of the ITC, 61 FLA.
district courts).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1799
than fifty such proceedings will be instituted in each of fiscal years 2016 and
2017.158 Because ITC proceedings account for only a small fraction of patent-
infringement litigation, this Article focuses on suits filed in district courts.
There has been strong evidence of rampant forum shopping in the district
courts. Broadly based venue in patent cases enabled a remarkable concentration
of new patent suits in two federal districts commonly lying far from the centers
of infringers operations, the District of Delaware and the Eastern District of
Texas.159 According to data compiled by Lex Machina,160 more than 40% of the
thousands of new patent-infringement suits filed in each year from 2012 through
the first several months of 2017 were filed in one of these two districts.161 In
2015, nearly 45% of suits were filed in the Eastern District of Texas alone.162
Further, evidence suggests that, among patent holders, PAEs and other NPEs
were especially likely to sue in the Eastern District of Texas.163 Plaintiff-friendly
local procedural and administrative rules and realities, such as local rules that
expedite pretrial proceedings,164 comparatively predictable assignment of judges
158 U.S. INTL TRADE COMMN, ANNUAL PERFORMANCE PLAN, FY 2016-2017 AND ANNUAL
PERFORMANCE REPORT, FY 2015, at 83 tbl.C.2 (2016) https://www.usitc.gov/documents/
usitc_2016_2017_app_and_2015_apr.pdf [https://perma.cc/E36E-2MFZ] (outlining total
Section 337 proceedings instituted and completed for fiscal years 2010 through 2015 and
estimating total Section 337 proceedings expected to be instutituted and completed in fiscal
years 2016 and 2017).
159 See J. Jonas Anderson, Court Competition for Patent Cases, 163 U. PA. L. REV. 631,
632 (2015) ([N]early half of the six thousand patent cases filed in 2013 were filed in just two
of [the ninety-four districts in the United States]: the District of Delaware and the Eastern
District of Texas.); Klerman & Reilly, supra note 121, at 249 tbl.1 (listing the Eastern
District of Texas and the District of Delaware as the two most popular venues for patent cases
from 2007 through the first half of 2015).
160 Lex Machina makes data on intellectual property litigation in the United States freely
available to qualifying public interest users such as university scholars. Public Interest, LEX
MACHINA, https://lexmachina.com/public-interest/ [https://perma.cc/TCN4-4R8Q] (last
visited Sept. 18, 2017).
161 This information was obtained from a Lex Machina page entitled All Court Case
163 Cohen et al., Growing Problem, supra note 132, at 521 ([T]he preponderance of NPE
patent litigation . . . is brought in the Eastern District of Texas . . . .); cf. Allison, Lemley &
Schwartz, supra note 145, at 30 (finding that only 8.2% of suits brought by PEs and litigated
to judgment were filed in the Eastern District of Texas, whereas the analogous figure was
26.9% for litigated-to-judgment suits brought by NPEs).
164 Liang, supra note 151, at 43-46 (pointing to procedural factors such as filing-to-trial
time).
1800 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
165 Klerman & Reilly, supra note 121, at 254 (Patentees have the unique opportunity in
the Eastern District of Texas to choose their judge.); id. at 281 (observing that the District of
Delawares small sizefour allotted judgeships, with a vacancy for most of the past
decadeprovides significant judicial predictability).
166 Liang, supra note 151, at 43-46; see also Klerman & Reilly, supra note 121, at 251
([J]udges in the Eastern District of Texas grant summary judgment at less than one-quarter
the rate of judges in other districts.); id. at 281 (The District of Delaware has . . . a low
summary judgment rate.).
167 Klerman & Reilly, supra note 121, at 254 ([J]uries in the Eastern District [of Texas]
have a pro-patentee reputation.); Yan Leychkis, Of Fire Ants and Claim Construction: An
Empirical Study of the Meteoric Rise of the Eastern District of Texas as a Preeminent Forum
for Patent Litigation, 9 YALE J.L. & TECH. 193, 210-11 (2007) (reporting a 90% win rate for
patentees in jury trials in the Eastern District of Texas from 1998 to 2006, as opposed to the
national win rate of 68%).
168 Sean J. Griffith & Alexandra D. Lahav, The Market for Preclusion in Merger
Litigation, 66 VAND. L. REV. 1053, 1054-55 (2013) (More than half of all public companies
and over 60% of the Fortune 500 are incorporated in Delaware.).
169 See supra text accompanying notes 19-24.
170 See, e.g., Mary Garvey Algero, In Defense of Forum Shopping: A Realistic Look at
Selecting a Venue, 78 NEB. L. REV. 79, 111 (1999) (concluding that forum shopping should
be recognized as a legitimate practice); Debra Lyn Bassett, The Forum Game, 84 N.C. L.
REV. 333, 335 (2006) (contending that forum shopping is a legitimate, expressly authorized
action when more than one forum satisfies the requisite legal criteria).
171 See Anderson, supra note 159, at 634-35 (hypothesizing that forum shopping in patent
law is driven, at least in part, by federal district courts competing for litigants); Klerman &
Reilly, supra note 121, at 250 (contending that judges in the Eastern District [of Texas] have
consciously sought to attract patentees . . . by departing from mainstream doctrine in a variety
of procedural areas).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1801
172
Markman v. Westview Instruments, Inc., 517 U.S. 370, 390 (1996) (It was just for the
sake of such desirable uniformity [in treatment of individual patents] that Congress created
the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit . . . .); Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss, The Federal
Circuit: A Case Study in Specialized Courts, 64 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1, 7 (1989) (stating that
proponents of the Federal Circuits creation contended that channelling patent cases into a
single appellate forum would create a stable, uniform law and would eliminate forum
shopping).
173 See Megan M. La Belle, The Local Rules of Patent Procedure, 47 ARIZ. ST. L.J. 63, 65
(2015) (observing that, [w]ith the surge of patent litigation in recent years, district courts
around the country have crafted unique procedural rules for patent suits).
174 Golden, supra note 49, at 509 (describing the utilitarian goal that is standard in modern
accounts).
175 See, e.g., Fritz Machlup & Edith Penrose, The Patent Controversy in the Nineteenth
177 Colleen Chien et al., Santa Clara Best Practices in Patent Litigation Survey, 42 AIPLA
Q.J. 137, 180-81 (2014) (Nuisance suits are suits for patent infringement that the defendant
is motivated to settle due to the high cost of litigation, even if the patent is weak or its
economic value is low.); William H.J. Hubbard, A Fresh Look at Plausibility Pleading, 83 U.
CHI. L. REV. 693, 722 (2016) ([T]he defendants primary objective in a nuisance suit is
avoiding its litigation costs.).
1802 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
178 See Golden, supra note 49, at 517 & n.71 (Patents can impair dynamic efficiency by
impeding follow-on development . . . .); Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Noncompliance,
Nonenforcement, Nonproblem? Rethinking the Anticommons in Biomedical Research,
45 HOUS. L. REV. 1059, 1079 (2008) (discussing survey results on how concerns of patent
clearance can affect innovative activities).
179 See Carl Shapiro, Injunctions, Hold-Up, and Patent Royalties, 12 AM. L. & ECON. REV.
Infringement Injunctions Scope, 90 TEX. L. REV. 1399, 1409 (2012) (suggesting that design-
around activity might best be viewed as a means to mitigate the patent systems costs, rather
than as a primary justification for patents); Golden, supra note 14, at 2154 (observing that
patent dtente is neither costless nor uninterrupted and can involve use of patents to create
barriers to new entrants (footnote omitted)).
182 See David L. Schwartz, The Rise of Contingent Fee Representation in Patent Litigation,
64 ALA. L. REV. 335, 358 (2012) (reporting survey results indicating that contingent-fee
lawyers for patent cases decline two-thirds to over ninety-nine percent of potential cases).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1803
183 See Arti K. Rai, Specialized Trial Courts: Concentrating Expertise on Fact,
17 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 877, 877-78 (2002) (arguing for a specialized patent trial court
because difficult questions of scientific fact are likely to arise more routinely in patent law
than in virtually any other field of law); cf. Thomas F. Cotter, Reining in Remedies in Patent
Litigation: Three (Increasingly Immodest) Proposals, 30 SANTA CLARA HIGH TECH. L.J. 1, 21
(2013) (expressing a belief that the right to trial by jury contributes to the high cost of patent
litigation and to overinflated damages awards).
184 Golden, supra note 49, at 580 (noting classic arguments that [courts] average
royalty rates, which can inform later court awards, a number of commentators have suggested
reasons that vagaries in the assessment of patent damages might not average out over time.
See, e.g., Einer Elhauge, Do Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking Lead to Systematically
Excessive Royalties?, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 535, 546 (2008) (contending that, under
various circumstances, royalty rates are likely to be suboptimal); William F. Lee &
A. Douglas Melamed, Breaking the Vicious Cycle of Patent Damages, 101 CORNELL L. REV.
385, 438 (2016) (contending that [t]he current reasonable royalty doctrine systematically
overcompensates patent holders); Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Patent Holdup and
Royalty Stacking, 85 TEX. L. REV. 2163, 2164 (2007) (contending that patent law
systematically overcompensates patentees whose inventions are only one component of a
larger product); Jonathan S. Masur, The Use and Misuse of Patent Licenses, 110 NW. U. L.
REV. 115, 144 (2015) (discussing how use of patent licenses to calculate reasonable royalty
damages likely depresses damages more than any [upward] distortion that patentees can
introduce by inflating license prices).
186 See Golden, supra note 49, at 581.
1804 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
one side to patent cases, likely that of patent holders, tends to dominate the
choice of forum.187 Further, significant discrepancies in treatment at the district
level can encourage socially wasteful strategic behavior in the form of races to
the courthouse.188
In short, there are substantial causes for concern that patent litigations high
costs, duration, and susceptibility to error or bias might undermine the patent
systems aim to promote technological progress or social welfare more
generally. The next Subsection highlights how PAEs can aggravate these causes
for concern.
187 See Kimberly A. Moore & Francesco Parisi, Rethinking Forum Shopping in
Cyberspace, 77 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1325, 1328 (2002) ([I]f some individuals are statistically
more likely to be plaintiffs than defendants . . ., the opportunity for forum shopping may have
biased distributional effects with a potential impact on the ex ante incentives of the parties.).
188 See id. (noting that racing to the courthouse can accelerat[e] the filing process and
bring[] to trial cases that may not have matured into court claims had they been left to the
choice of the natural plaintiff); Harvey I. Saferstein & Nathan R. Hamler, Location,
Location, Location: A Proposal for Centralized Review of the Now Largely Unreviewable
Choice of Venue in Federal Litigation, 90 OR. L. REV. 1065, 1067 (2012) (Motions to change
venue . . . are often preceded by a race to the courthouse, especially in patent
litigations . . . .).
189 See EXEC. OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT, PATENT ASSERTION AND U.S. INNOVATION 3
(2013) (discussing how [p]atent intermediaries can play a useful social role).
190 See Brian T. Yeh, CONG. RESEARCH SERV., CRS R42668, AN OVERVIEW OF THE
PATENT TROLLS DEBATE 6 (2013) (PAEs have frequently been accused of imposing a tax
on innovation . . . .). But cf. Mark A. Lemley & A. Douglas Melamed, Missing the Forest
for the Trolls, 113 COLUM. L. REV. 2117, 2125, 2151 n.148 (2013) (finding evidence
inconclusive on the extent to which trolls increase or decrease the amounts that fund
innovation).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1805
Model, 45 HOUS. L. REV. 1165, 1184, 1189 (2008) (observing that situations involving high
switching costs . . . may cover many scenarios involving patent trolls); Robert P. Merges,
The Trouble with Trolls: Innovation, Rent-Seeking, and Patent Law Reform, 24 BERKELEY
TECH. L.J. 1583, 1590-91 (2009) (The patent troll strategy is to take advantage of lock-in
that occurs as a result of [sunk cost] investments.).
193 547 U.S. 388, 394 (2006).
198 See Golden, supra note 14, at 2151 (noting party positions on reasonable royalties that
differed by factors of about one hundred twenty and two hundred); see also Apple, Inc. v.
1806 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
Motorola, Inc., No. 1:11-cv-08540, 2012 WL 1959560, at *3-7 (N.D. Ill. May 22, 2012)
(reporting expert opinions for reasonable royalty damages differing by a factor of one hundred
forty for one patent and by a factor of three hundred fifty for another), revd in part and
vacated in part, 757 F.3d 1286 (Fed. Cir. 2014).
199 See, e.g., Timothy R. Holbrook, Equivalency and Patent Laws Possession Paradox,
23 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 1, 46 (2009) (discussing uncertainty about patent scope resulting from
the doctrine of equivalents); Jason Rantanen, The Federal Circuits New Obviousness
Jurisprudence: An Empirical Study, 16 STAN. TECH. L. REV. 709, 717 (2013) (discussing the
real challenge involved in assessing an inventions nonobviousness).
200 Lemley & Melamed, supra note 190, at 2126 (defining bottom-feeder trolls as patent
holders that rely on the high cost of patent litigation . . . to induce the parties they sue to
settle for small amounts of money rather than pay millions to their lawyers).
201 Tom Ewing, Indirect Exploitation of Intellectual Property Rights by Corporations and
Investors: IP Privateering and Modern Letters of Marque and Reprisal, 4 HASTINGS SCI. &
TECH. L.J. 1, 70 (2012) (explaining how the prospective investor itself [can] bring the
litigation as a means for lowering the investment targets valuation price).
202 See Edward Wyatt, Obama Orders Regulators to Root Out Patent Trolls, N.Y. TIMES
competitors of Nokia and Sony soon after acquiring over a hundred patents and
patent applications in which those companies had ownership interests.204
These storylines provide plausible bases for worrying about the proliferation
of PAE activity, but the net social costs of PAE activity remain subject to heated
debate.205 This Article does not attempt to resolve this debate. For this Articles
purposes, it seems enough to note two generally accepted facts. First, PAE suits
and the number of PAE-suit targets have grown substantially over the last two
decades, with annual numbers of new PAE suits and PAE-suit defendants now
tending to be in the thousands.206 Second, concerns about PAE activities
highlight systemic weaknesses that would be worrisome even without PAEs,207
including (1) limited USPTO review that leaves substantial doubt about the
validity and scope of many patents;208 (2) high litigation costs that impede access
to the courts and can foster nuisance suits and settlements;209 and (3) vagaries in
litigation outcomes that, from a social standpoint, can (a) excessively deter risk-
averse parties from suit or defense, (b) frustrate desirable settlement efforts, and
(c) encourage patent-holder rent seeking in a litigation lottery.
CORNELL L. REV. 387, 390-91 (2014) (reporting that, over the last few years, NPE litigation
has reached a wholly unprecedented scale and scope); Cotropia, Kesan & Schwartz, supra
note 133, at 649 (observing that, [i]n the last decade, the landscape of patent litigation has
radically shifted toward enforcement by PAEs).
207 Cf. David S. Olson, On NPEs, Holdups, and Underlying Faults in the Patent System,
99 CORNELL L. REV. ONLINE 140, 150 (2014) ([I]n some ways, patent assertions by NPEs do
not raise unique problems . . . so much as they increase the severity of pre-existing
problems.).
208 See supra text accompanying notes 73-81.
209 See supra text accompanying notes 176-78. AIPLA survey data indicates that the costs
of defending patent-infringement suits brought by PAEs are generally roughly comparable to,
albeit often somewhat less than, those of defending against suits by other forms of patentees.
See AIPLA 2015 SURVEY, supra note 18, at 37-38.
1808 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
Without need for reference to PAEs, these weaknesses of the patent system
by themselves justify this Articles proposal for patent litigation administrative
review. After all, as early as 1813, Thomas Jefferson proposed that, to better
guard our citizens against harassment by lawsuits, questions about the validity
of patents might best be turned over to a board of Academical professors
instead of the courts.210 The later institution of pre-issuance examination by
professional patent examiners was a step toward realization of Jeffersons vision
but a far from complete one. This Articles proposal can be understood as taking
a further step toward that vision.
210 Letter from Thomas Jefferson to Isaac McPherson (Aug. 13, 1813), in 6 THOMAS
JEFFERSON, THE PAPERS OF THOMAS JEFFERSON: RETIREMENT SERIES 384 (J. Jefferson Looney
ed., 2009).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1809
even when one assumes parties have symmetric information and beliefs. To the
extent asymmetric information is a cause of problematic patent litigation or
patent-assertion behavior, these models most likely underestimate the benefits
of PLRB review because the models do not reflect the fact that, by inducing
valuable information exchanges and providing early administrative feedback on
party arguments, PLRB review can significantly reduce information
asymmetries before parties undertake the costly process of litigation-related
discovery.211
Sections III.B and III.C close the case for PLRB review. In addition to laying
out a specific legal framework for PLRB review, Section III.B presents a third
economic model to respond to concerns that private parties could dissipate the
social value of PLRB review by flooding the PLRB with claims and arguments.
This model shows that parties own interests in limiting private costs will likely
cause them to be selective in assertions before the PLRB, thereby helping to
preserve the PLRBs capacity to have a net positive effect on social welfare.
Section III.C follows by explaining how other recently implemented or proposed
adjustments to the patent system do not undermine the case for early-stage
administrative review.
211 See infra text accompanying notes 223-29 (describing the process of PLRB review).
212 See Louis Kaplow, Multistage Adjudication, 126 HARV. L. REV. 1179, 1225 (2013)
(suggesting that, [a]s an initial, rough cut at the problem [of ordering steps in multistage
adjudication], it seems that the step with a higher diagnosticity/cost ratio should be earlier);
cf. Reilly, supra note 7, at 239 (advocating staged litigation in which [d]iscovery is
limited . . . until the plaintiff demonstrates a meritorious case by prevailing on the initial
issue(s)).
1810 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
213 See Robert G. Bone, Modeling Frivolous Suits, 145 U. PA. L. REV. 519, 593 (1997)
verifiable by a court. The probability that the court finds for P is (),
and this probability is increasing in . If the court finds for P, it awards
damages of > 0 to P; otherwise, it enforces a penalty 0 on P that
is transferred to D by a court award of attorney fees. P faces an
administrative review cost and incurs an additional cost for
litigating through a full court decision. D must pay to see the suit
through a decision by the court.
() + (1 ()) = ()( + ) ( )
()( + ) + ( ).
= ()( + ) + ( ),
Suppose that, after suit is announced (i.e., after the payment of , but before
settlement negotiations), PLRB review yields a signal that is informative about
the probability that the court will find for P. Specifically, assume that the
probability density of for a given value of , f ( | ), has the monotone
likelihood ratio property in . The quantity (,) is the probability of a win for
P as a function of and , increasing in both arguments. We assume that (,)
and () are equally responsive to , in the sense that their derivatives with
respect to are equal: (,) = ().214 D then expects to receive
214 This equality of derivatives with respect to generally corresponds to (,) equaling
() + g(), where () and g() fall within a range of values such that 0 () + g() 1 for
all pertinent values of and .
1812 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
E[(, ) | ] + (1 E[(,) | ]) =
E [(,) | ]( + ) ( )
if it pursues a court decision. Consequently, P brings suit if and only if
0 < E[(,) | ]( + ) ( + ).
a. Model Structure
Consider a discrete-time, three-period setup where patent assertion and
litigation decisions occur as indicated in Figure 1 and Table 1.
The choice of assertion occurs at time T0. If assertion is chosen by the patent
holder P after incurring a cost , the alleged infringer D then decides at the
immediately following time T whether to settle with P or to fight the
infringement allegation. If D settles, it will pay out a quantity set by the model,
which can be conceived as equaling the product sV, where V is an expected
value associated with the litigation (e.g., the expected value to P of any payment
from D to P if the case proceeds) and s is the fraction of that value that D pays
to P in a settlement. If, instead of settling at T, D fights the infringement
allegation, the PLRB will review the case. This will cost D the amount ,
which, assuming this proceeding is decided on papers only, is the cost to D of
collecting and providing the limited supporting documentation, including
appropriate briefing, to make its arguments. The PLRB process will cost P the
amount , which includes not only the cost of collecting and providing the
limited supporting documentation to make its case for infringement to the PLRB,
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1815
At time T1 following the PLRBs decision, P decides whether to drop the suit
or to continue pursuing charges of infringement. If P chooses to continue, then
D decides how to respond at immediately subsequent time T1+. If D settles with
P, the settlement value equals the product sV1+, where s is again the settlement
fraction, this time applied to a base value V1+, which is an expected value
associated with continuing the litigation after the PLRBs decision. If, instead of
settling at T1+, D fights the infringement allegation in court, D will incur
litigation costs , and P will incur litigation costs .
Ds net expected proceeds from continuing litigation at time T1+ will depend
on both the information revealed by the PLRBs decision and the underlying
claim quality q. For example, if the PLRB issues a plaintiff-disfavoring
judgment of Bad, Ds expected court award (or loss) will equal 1
. Subtracting her cost of fighting in court yields net
expected proceeds of 1 . The
corresponding expected payoff for P of going to court after the PLRB judgment
215 Cf. Geoffrey P. Miller, Preliminary Judgments, 2010 U. ILL. L. REV. 165, 167 (using
the term preliminary judgment somewhat differently to refer to a tentative assessment . . .
based on the same sorts of information that the courts already consider on motions for
summary judgment).
1816 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
b. Illustrative Results
In this Subsection, we take the model and examine its implications by
applying it to eight illustrative calibrations, which are scenarios specified by
assigned sets of parameter values. An Online Appendix prepared as a
supplement to this Article presents additional examples that further indicate the
robustness of this Articles conclusions.216 Interested readers can explore the
dynamics of the model and use it in follow-on work. The Online Appendix also
includes the Mathematica code used to run calibrations.217
Generally in our examples, P will choose not to file at time T0 or not to
continue the patent-infringement suit at time T1 if, without the possibility of
settlement at immediately subsequent time T or T1+, respectively, the net
present value of suit for P is negative. This aspect of the modeled examples
corresponds to assuming that, at both of the discrete settlement times T and T1+,
D will not offer anything above $0 to settle the case unless P has a credible threat
of continuing the case absent a nonzero settlement offer.
For purposes of the examples allowing settlement, we assume that parties
settle for the expected value of the end payout in the case (e.g., the expected
value of a court award if the parties are at settlement time T1+). In other words,
for the settlement-based examples, we assume a settlement fraction s of 1 (that
is, 100%), and we apply this settlement fraction to values for V and V1+ that
equal the expected value of the amount, excluding next-stage plaintiff process
costs or , that P expects to gain if litigation continues beyond the current
settlement stage.218 Under this approach, settlement saves each party its expected
costs of undertaking the next stage of administrative or court process. Thus, in
situations where P has a credible threat of continuing litigation even without
immediate settlement, settlement is rationally desired by both parties and always
occurs at time T by taking into account the probabilistically weighted
settlements that would otherwise occur at time T1+.
To demonstrate the expected effects of PLRB review, we separately model
circumstances in which settlement is allowed and, under the model, always
occurs and in which settlement is not allowed but plaintiffs can still terminate
216 Lauren H. Cohen et al.,Troll Check? A Proposal for Administrative Review of Patent
218 Thus, in a situation in which the PLRB has issued a plaintiff-disfavoring judgment of
Bad, the proffered settlement amount sV1+ will equal the expected court award to the P after
such a PLRB judgment: 1 .
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1817
negative net present value suits at times T0 and T1. Within these two basic sets
of circumstances, we analyze four subclasses of scenarios involving:
I. Weak Suitswithout PLRB
II. Weak Suitswith PLRB
III. Strong Suitswithout PLRB
IV. Strong Suitswith PLRB
Eight tables for the calibrated scenarios appear as Tables 2 through 9 below.
Each set of calibration results ends by reporting a value E(Ex Ante Plaintiff
Payoff) that equals the ex ante expected value for P of pursuing the relevant
claim of patent infringement against D. Because P will drop the suit at T0 if the
net present value (NPV) of filing the suit is less than zero and because P will
have incurred costs of no more than before arriving at time T0, the minimum
value of E(Ex Ante Plaintiff Payoff) in our modeled results will be . Further
discussion of the calibrations and their implications follows.
c. Analysis of Results
In this Subsection, we analyze the calibration examples of Tables 2 through
9. These examples show the effects of PLRB review on Weak and Strong
suits. The Weak Suits are comparatively low-merit cases modeled as having a
plaintiff-win probability of 15% in the absence of the PLRB.219 The Strong
Suits are comparatively high-merit cases modeled as having a plaintiff-win
probability of 75% in the absence of the PLRB. For purposes of assigning
illustrative parameter values, P is assumed to be a patent holder and D is
assumed to be an accused infringer. Likewise, for simplicity, D does not threaten
a countersuit, whether for patent infringement, an antitrust violation, or
otherwise.
Both Weak and Strong Suits are assumed for purposes of the examples to
involve relatively low stakes by patent litigation standardsnamely, a
plaintiffs claim for an overall monetary award of $1.5 million.220 We view this
219 The Weak Suits combination of low plaintiff-win probability and relatively low stakes
compared to typical litigation costs might earn them designation as nuisance suits. See
supra notes 131, 178 and accompanying text.
220 According to a litigation study by PricewaterhouseCoopers, median court-awarded
damages in patent suits ranged from $2.0 million to $17.0 million for the twenty-year period
from 1997 through 2016, and the median damages award for the five-year period from 2012
through 2016 was $5.8 million. PRICEWATERHOUSECOOPERS, 2017 PATENT LITIGATION
STUDY: CHANGE ON THE HORIZON? 9 (May 2017), https://www.pwc.com/us/en/forensic-
1822 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
services/publications/assets/2017-patent-litigation-study.pdf [https://perma.cc/A9VM-
TR28]. Further, the median damages award for NPEs was nearly $11.5 million for the twenty-
year period from 1997 through 2016 and $15.7 million for the five-year period from 2012
through 2016. Id. at 16. Although the characteristic values of patent suits in general might
differ significantly from that for the subset of patent suits that result in court-awarded
damages, these figures provide at least some basis for viewing the assumption of stakes of
$1.5 million as relatively conservative.
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1823
The increase in NPV for the Strong Suit when subject to PLRB review
highlights the second main benefit the PLRB can bring to the patent litigation
landscape. In addition to discouraging a substantial number of low-merit suits,
PLRB review should encourage patent-rights enforcement and compliance in a
substantial number of cases in which patent holders have high-merit claims. This
follows from the expectation that a positive ruling from the PLRB will increase
the expected odds of winning in later district court proceedings, thereby
generating a rise in patent-infringement suit NPV that can more than pay for the
costs to the patent holder of PLRB proceedings.
We concede, however, that there will almost inevitably be patent holders with
meritorious claims who do not benefit so substantially from PLRB review. This
failure could result because the strengths of their claims are difficult to convey
in summary proceedings that precede discovery. The point that Calibrations IIIS
and IVS make is that, as a reform designed to make the patent system work better,
PLRB review will be balanced in the sense that it will have pro-patentee effects
in some situations and anti-patentee effects in others, with pro-patentee effects
tending to occur in high-quality lawsuits. The key question for PLRB review is
not who is making a claim but how strong or weak that claim can be shown to
be at the outset of litigation.
221 See False Claims Act Cases: Government Intervention in Qui Tam (Whistleblower)
for patent owner response and USPTO decision on a request for inter partes or post-grant
review. See 35 U.S.C. 314(b), 324(c) (2012); 37 C.F.R. 42.107(b), 42.207(b) (2016).
226 Jonathan Stroud, Linda Thayer & Jeffrey C. Totten, Stay Awhile: The Evolving Law of
District Court Stays in Light of Inter Partes Review, Post-Grant Review, and Covered
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1827
Business Method Post-Grant Review, 11 BUFF. INTELL. PROP. L.J. 226, 237-38 (2015)
(discussing statutory provisions and judicial practices with respect to stays of district court
litigation pending inter partes or post-grant review).
227 Cf. Kaplow, supra note 212, at 1227 (arguing that it often may make sense to organize
staging by type of evidence, perhaps begin[ning] with key documents or only a few central
witnesses).
228 The standard for a substantive determination is a variant of the standard for assessing
whether a patentee has a sufficient likelihood of success in a patent suit to justify a preliminary
injunction. Trebro Mfg., Inc. v. Firefly Equip., LLC, 748 F.3d 1159, 1165 (Fed. Cir. 2014)
(An accused infringer can defeat a showing of likelihood of success on the merits by
demonstrating a substantial question of validity or infringement.).
229 Lemelson v. United States, 752 F.2d 1538, 1551 (Fed. Cir. 1985) ([I]n order for a court
to find infringement, the plaintiff must show the presence of every element or its substantial
equivalent in the accused device.).
1828 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
The PLRB would generally publish its reasoning and determinations,230 and
the PLRBs opinions and judgments would be admissible in court. On the other
hand, to avoid constitutional concerns with jury rights and the prerogatives of
Article III courts,231 the PLRBs determinations on substantive matters would
only be advisory. There would be no judicial review of the PLRBs
determination independent of continuation of the original district court action or
analogous proceeding. The trial court would conduct a trial de novo, but the
courts would give the PLRBs determinations weight in the manner prescribed
by Skidmore v. Swift & Co.232 for agency statutory interpretations. In other
words, the trial court would give those determinations weight in accordance with
the PLRBs expertise, its care in deliberation, the unanimity or consistency of
its judgments, and the quality of evidence before it.233 The provisions for trial
de novo and restriction of judicial review otherwise would be statutorily
specified, thus overriding any otherwise applicable default provisions on judicial
review under the Administrative Procedure Act.234
PLRB determinations would have effects beyond their ability to influence
later court decisions. First, if the PLRB found that, under the clear and
convincing plus standard, a patent claim is invalid based on grounds that are a
permissible basis for USPTO post-issuance review, the PLRBs determination
would give the successful challenger a right to post-issuance review, as opposed
to the mere opportunity to petition for such review. Even if the challenger does
not exercise this right, the USPTO would automatically receive notice of the
PLRBs determination and could decide sua sponte to launch an ex parte
reexamination.235 Second, if a party uses court proceedings to challenge an
adverse PLRB determination and if the party loses that challenge on grounds
identical to those invoked by the PLRB, that party would presumptively have to
pay the opposing sides associated additional court costs and reasonable attorney
230 As with court opinions, confidential information might be redacted from publicly
available versions of PLRB opinions.
231 RICHARD J. PIERCE, JR., SIDNEY A. SHAPIRO & PAUL R. VERKUIL, ADMINISTRATIVE LAW
AND PROCESS 3.7 (5th ed. 2009) ([T]he [Supreme] Court has established some boundaries
beyond which Congress cannot go concerning Article III and the Seventh Amendment.); cf.
Oil States Energy Servs. v. Greenes Energy Grp., 85 U.S.L.W. 3575 (U.S. June 12, 2017)
(granting writ of certiorari for question about the constitutionality of an administrative process
for reviewing the validity of issued patents).
232 323 U.S. 134, 140 (1944).
233 Cf. id. (describing bases for deference to administrative opinions even when not
which includes its provisions on standards for review, does not limit or repeal additional
requirements imposed by statute or otherwise recognized by law).
235 35 U.S.C. 303-304 (2012) (setting forth the Directors power to initiate
fees. Third, and relatedly, if a party loses before the PLRB, the party might need
to pay costs and, in exceptional cases, reasonable attorney fees associated with
the PLRB proceedings. Fourth, PLRB determinations could factor into later
assessments of whether district court litigation involves a violation of Federal
Rule of Civil Procedure 11 or whether a court should enhance patent-
infringement damages because of egregious infringing behavior.236 Finally, if
the PLRB rules in favor of a party that lacks the capacity to appear in court to
defend itself, the PLRB would intervene in associated district court proceedings
to make its reasoning and determination part of the record and, thus, a potential
basis for denying judgment against the non-appearing party.
How would the PLRB obtain funding to cover its administrative costs?
Generally speaking, complainants who initiate the relevant suits in district court
would pay for the PLRBs preliminary review through administrative fees
determined by rule.237 As with various USPTO fees, there would be substantially
reduced fees for small entities and micro-entities that are not stand-ins for better-
monetized entities.238 Further, by request, parties, including business entities,
might qualify for in forma pauperis treatment, under which the PLRB would
waive fees and cover relevant costs through surplus from PLRB fees collected
from others or through a patent system cost added to USPTO patent issuance
and maintenance fees. If there remains concern that the fees required to pay for
PLRB review would be too high to serve interests in access to justice, PLRB
review could be supported more generally through increases to preexisting fees
associated with the obtaining and maintenance of patent rights. If USPTO fees
for post-issuance review proceedings are a reasonable guide, administrative
costs associated with the operation of the PLRB might be expected to be in the
nature of $10,000 to $30,000 per case, or about $50 million to $150 million per
236 Halo Elecs., Inc. v. Pulse Elecs., Inc., 136 S. Ct. 1923, 1932 (2016) (Awards of
enhanced damages under the Patent Act . . . are . . . designed as a punitive or vindictive
sanction for egregious infringement behavior.).
237 If fees for inter partes and post-grant review serve as guides, standard administrative
costs might be in the nature of $10,000 to $30,000. America Invents Act (AIA) Frequently
Asked Questions, U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, http://www.uspto.gov/patent/laws-
and-regulations/america-invents-act-aia/america-invents-act-aia-frequently-asked
[https://perma.cc/3Y2G-M8UZ] (last visited Sept. 18, 2017). In fact, average administrative
costs for PLRB review might tend to be lower than this range suggests. Because PLRB review
would involve nonbinding assessment according to a clear and convincing plus standard as
opposed to binding judgments according to a preponderance of evidence standard, costs for
preliminary review might be significantly lower than USPTO fees for inter partes and post-
grant review. Moreover, if neither party raised any issues for review by the PLRB, there would
be no need for PLRB review and the PLRB might then waive the complainants administrative
fees.
238 Michael D. Frakes & Melissa F. Wasserman, Does Agency Funding Affect
accompanying text, and there are still about five thousand patent suits filed in district courts
each year, see supra note 132 and accompanying text, PLRB administrative costs would total
to about $50 million to $150 million per year, an amount that could be raised by obtaining
$170 to $500 in additional fees for each of three hundred thousand issued patents.
242 Golden, supra note 49, at 550 (observing that the terms of patent-licensing
rates do not provide a great indication of the underlying percentage of issued patent claims
that are invalid).
244 See AIPLA 2015 SURVEY, supra note 18, at 37 (reporting median estimated attorney
fees of $600,000 per side for patent-infringement suits with Less than $1 Million at Risk
and $5 million per side with More than $25 Million at Risk).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1831
review appears justified by the benefits that such review promises. Direct
benefits from PLRB review, such as reduced overall litigation costs, increased
accuracy in dispute resolution, and enhanced access to justice, might themselves
justify the investment. Even if these direct benefits are not as large as expected,
the systemic benefits of at least a few years of PLRB information-gathering
could make the investment more than worthwhile.
PLRB information-gathering could have diminishing returns over time,
however, and the information gathered could itself suggest there are better ways
to improve the patent litigation landscape. Thus, Congress might be wise to
consider terminating an experiment with PLRB review after a few years. Even
if termination of the PLRB is not advisable, Congress might need to tweak
statutory provisions for PLRB review to respond to private parties success in
gaming the system as originally devised.
Consequently, this Article proposes that Congress initially adopt PLRB
review on a pilot basis. Absent additional congressional action, the PLRB pilot
would terminate after a specified period, perhaps three years, that allows a
reasonable time for both the maturation of PLRB practice and the gathering of
information to aid future policymaking. If Congress wishes to restrict the impact
and burden of PLRB review further, it might apply such review only to a subset
of patent casesfor example, a sample of randomly selected cases or a subset
of cases involving particular types of subject matter such as software or business
methods.
245 Benjamin J. Christoff, Comment, Blurring the Boundaries: How the Additional
Grounds for Post-Grant Review in the America Invents Act Raise Issues with Separation of
Powers and the Administrative Procedure Act, 39 U. DAYTON L. REV. 111, 126 (2013).
246 Id.
247 See Bristol-Myers Squibb Co. v. Ben Venue Labs., Inc., 246 F.3d 1368, 1378 (Fed. Cir.
2001) ([I]t is axiomatic that that which would literally infringe if later anticipates if earlier.).
248 Tun-Jen Chiang, The Upside-Down Inequitable Conduct Defense, 107 NW. U. L. REV.
249 See, e.g., Eric B. Chen, Conflicting Objectives: The Patent Offices Quality Review
Initiative and the Examiner Count System, 10 N.C. J.L. & TECH. ONLINE EDITION 28, 30
(2008) ([S]everal challenges continue to plague the USPTO, namely the backlog of
unexamined patent applications, concerns over examiner attrition, and the increasing volume
of continuing applications and ex parte appeals . . . . (footnotes omitted)).
250 See CALENDAR YEAR PATENT STATISTICS, supra note 73 (showing that the number of
U.S. utility patent applications grew from 117,006 in 1985 to 589,410 in 2015); cf. Golden,
supra note 75, at 463 (noting that, at least for . . . utility and design patents, the general long-
term trend has been for the number of patents issued each year to increase at an accelerating
pace.).
251 Golden, supra note 38, at 1098.
252 See PTAB STATISTICS 2016, supra note 37, at 3 (noting that the USPTO received 1894
and 1683 petitions for inter partes, covered business method, or post-grant review in fiscal
years 2015 and 2016, respectively).
253 See Frakes & Wasserman, supra note 238, at 69.
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1833
(PCAOB).254 The latter model would permit the PLRB to avoid standard
federal pay scales, thereby enhancing its ability to recruit highly qualified
professionals.255 In either case, members of the PLRB could be appointed by the
President for a statutorily set term of years, subject to removal by the President
only for cause.256
254 See Free Enter. Fund v. Pub. Co. Accounting Oversight Bd., 561 U.S. 477, 484 (2010)
(describing the PCAOB as modeled on private self-regulatory organizations in the securities
industrysuch as the New York Stock Exchange); Mick Bordonaro, Recent Development,
The Public Accounting Oversight Board After Dodd-Frank, 30 REV. BANKING & FIN. L. 474,
475 (2011) ([T]he PCAOB is a non-profit corporation under the supervision and control of
the [Securities and Exchange Commission].).
255 See Free Enter. Fund, 561 U.S. at 484-85 (noting that the PCAOBs technically private
status enables it to recruit its members and employees from the private sector by paying
salaries far above the standard Government pay scale); Bordonaro, supra note 254, at 476
([T]he PCAOB does not follow the standard federal pay scale.).
256 Cf. Free Enter. Fund, 561 U.S. at 487 (accepting the belief that the Commissioners
cannot themselves be removed by the President except under the Humphreys Executor
standard).
1834 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
257 One might expect that an inconclusive ruling by the PLRB will have a negative effect
on the expected value of the litigation for the petitioner: the case will thereby become one in
which the petitioner has failed to prevail before the PLRB, rather than one in which the
petitioner only had a probability of failing to prevail before the PLRB. But because the
standard for prevailing before the PLRB is intended to be very demanding, we assume any
such negative effect to be negligible to a first approximation.
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1835
258 One could argue that payments to individuals such as attorneys, expert witnesses, and
PLRB employees are fundamentally just wealth transfers that presumptively lack a first-order
effect on overall social welfare. See Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrusts Protected Classes, 88
MICH. L. REV. 1, 14 (1989). But for purposes here, policymakers can be viewed as primarily
seeking to assess whether PLRB review can achieve net value through cost savings relative
to district court litigation costs or other process costs that will be incurred without PLRB
review. In substantial part because such cost savings form the most readily estimable and,
likely, surest benefit of PLRB review, assessing when and whether the analogous costs of
PLRB review outweigh the expected benefit of PLRB review seems a reasonable approach
for first-cut cost-benefit analysis.
259 Golden, supra note 191, at 616 ([A] patent challenge can generate significant positive
of the cost to society of PLRB proceedings divided by the social value added by
those proceedings. If we assume that a PLRB ruling declaring a partys position
to be weak or strong will often lead to the associated issue dropping out of further
litigation and that the ratio between the costs of PLRB proceedings and the costs
of litigation before the district courts will roughly track the ratio of costs
associated with current USPTO inter partes review proceedings and the costs of
litigation before the district courts, then we have reason to believe that the ratio
Csoc/Vsoc will equate to a value of 10% or lower. In other words, because district
court patent litigation seems, generally speaking, to result in litigation costs that
are at least about ten times higher than those characteristic of administrative
proceedings,260 litigation cost savings alone appear likely to cause the ratio
Csoc/Vsoc to take a value that is no more than about 10%. In short, there is reason
to believe that PLRB proceedings will produce net positive value for society as
long as parties restrain themselvesor are restrained through appropriate rules
governing proceedingssuch that the overall success rate of their filings is at
least about 10%.
Such private-party discretion in raising issues in preliminary proceedings is
more than theoretically plausible. In the face of an arguably more demanding
standard for success than the PLRBs proposed clear-and-convincing-plus
standard, patentees already restrain their filing of motions for preliminary
injunctions so that such motions have a success rate of nearly 20%.261 This real-
world example suggests that, as long as PLRB policies and the PLRBs decision-
making record make clear that a petitioner has only a very limited chance of
obtaining a favorable affirmative judgment, parties are likely to restrict their use
of PLRB proceedings sufficiently to make PLRB review socially worthwhile.
The PLRB could adjust procedure to encourage or effectively force further
restraint as needed. Hence, worries about private parties overinvesting in PLRB
processes do not appear to provide a strong basis for rejecting this Articles
proposed reform.
260
See AIPLA 2015 SURVEY, supra note 18, at 37-38.
261
Kirti Gupta & Jay P. Kesan, Studying the Impact of eBay on Injunctive Relief in Patent
Cases 12 tbl.2 (Univ. of Ill. Coll. of Law Legal Studies Research, Paper No. 17-03, 2015)
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2629399 [https://perma.cc/4UFK-VBQP] (reporting that over 17%
(115 of 663) of preliminary injunction motions in patent cases have been granted since eBay
was decided in 2006).
262 Cf. F. Scott Kieff & Henry E. Smith, How Not to Invent a Patent Crisis, in REACTING
TO THE SPENDING SPREE: POLICY CHANGES WE CAN AFFORD 55, 55 (Terry L. Anderson &
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1837
Richard Sousa eds., 2009) (noting rapid, and we would argue excessive, changes that have
already occurred in the courts).
263 See Patent Cases Pilot Program, Pub. L. No. 111-349, 124 Stat. 3674, 3674 (2011);
265 See John M. Golden, Flook Says One Thing, Diehr Says Another: A Need for
Housecleaning in the Law of Patentable Subject Matter, 82 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 1765, 1768-
74 (2014).
266 See Jason Rantanen, The Federal Circuits New Obviousness Jurisprudence: An
Empirical Study, 16 STAN. TECH. L. REV. 709, 764 (2013) (concluding that appellate case law
on nonobviousness has effectively tightened the nonobviousness requirement).
267 Nautilus, Inc. v. Biosig Instruments, Inc., 134 S. Ct. 2120, 2130 (2014) (abrogating an
apparently loose standard for patent claim definiteness that had appeared in Federal Circuit
case law).
268 Ariad Pharms., Inc. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 598 F.3d 1336, 1340 (Fed. Cir. 2010) (en banc)
(We now reaffirm that [35 U.S.C.] 112, first paragraph, contains a written description
requirement separate from enablement . . . .).
269 eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388, 394 (2006) (emphasizing that the
decision whether to grant or deny injunctive relief rests within the equitable discretion of the
district courts).
270 See, e.g., LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Comput., Inc., 694 F.3d 51, 78 (Fed. Cir.
2012) (finding abuse of discretion in the district courts admission of certain evidence on
reasonable royalty damages); Douglas G. Smith, The Increasing Use of Challenges to Expert
Evidence Under Daubert and Rule 702 in Patent Litigation, 22 J. INTELL. PROP. L. 345, 350-
73 (2015) (discussing developments in the admissibility of expert testimony in patent cases).
271 John M. Golden, Patent Laws Falstaff: Inequitable Conduct, the Federal Circuit, and
Therasense, 7 WASH. J.L. TECH. & ARTS 353, 371-72 (2012) (discussing a shift toward a
leaner doctrine of inequitable conduct).
1838 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
272 Octane Fitness, LLC v. ICON Health & Fitness, Inc., 134 S. Ct. 1749, 1755 (2014)
(holding that a Federal Circuit framework for when attorney fees may be awarded was
unduly rigid).
273 Williamson v. Citrix Online, LLC, 792 F.3d 1339, 1349 (Fed. Cir. 2015) (en banc in
relevant part) (overruling precedent characterizing as strong the presumption that a [patent
claim] limitation lacking the word means is not subject to [35 U.S.C.] 112, para. 6).
274 Medtronic, Inc. v. Mirowski Family Ventures, LLC, 134 S. Ct. 843, 846 (2014)
(reversing a Federal Circuit holding that a licensee bears the burden of proving non-
infringement in a declaratory judgment action); MedImmune, Inc. v. Genentech, Inc., 549
U.S. 118, 137 (2007) (holding that a patent licensee was not required . . . to break or
terminate its 1997 license agreement before challenging the patent in a declaratory judgment
action).
275 Paul R. Gugliuzza, The New Federal Circuit Mandamus, 45 IND. L. REV. 343, 346
(2012) ([T]he Federal Circuit has, on ten occasions since December 2008, granted
mandamus to order the U.S. District Court for the Eastern District of Texas to transfer a patent
case.).
276 Pelletier, supra note 109, at 478 ([T]he Northern District of California is the
acknowledged model and pioneer of local patent rules, having adopted its first version in
2000.).
277 MENELL ET AL., supra note 104, at 2-14 to 2-15 (reporting that patent local rules were
developed to facilitate efficient discovery and that they promote efficient case
management); La Belle, supra note 173, at 63 (Today, thirty district courts in twenty
different states have comprehensive local patent rules, and many more individual judges have
adopted local-local rules or standing orders that apply to patent cases in their courts.).
278 Ryan Davis, Patent Troll Targets Getting Boost from State Laws, LAW360 (Nov. 24,
such laws, alleged infringers have begun invoking state consumer protection
laws in counterclaims against patentees.279
But these now relatively longstanding adjustments have proven inadequate to
answer continuing concerns that patent assertion has become a drag on
innovation. The rate of new patent-suit filings in district courts remains more
than double that of the year 2000,280 and these suits are now supplemented by a
comparable rate of new filings in USPTO post-issuance proceedings.281 Part of
the failure of past reforms reflects adjustments by patent holders. For example,
patent holders have deployed multiple responses to new joinder limitations, such
as increasing the number of filings against individual defendants who would
have previously been named in a single complaint; employing multidistrict
litigation (MDL) procedures to bind cases for pre-trial activities; and
incorporating in Delaware to pursue defendants in a forum where consolidation
of cases is likely because of the forums relatively small size.282
More recent changes to the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure offer little
assurance of relief. In 2015, the Supreme Court approved new Federal Rules of
Civil Procedure that seek to control[] the expense and time demands of
litigation and to promote prompt and efficient resolutions of disputes.283
Steps to these ends include shortening the default deadline for a trial judges
mandatory scheduling order;284 limiting authorized discovery to nonprivileged
matter proportional to the needs of the case;285 and apparently tightening
patent-suit pleading requirements by eliminating the ability of patentees to rely
on Form 18, a model complaint for patent-infringement suits.286 But these
279 Id. (noting use of state consumer protection statutes by [s]ome accused infringers).
280 See supra note 132 and accompanying text (noting that the number of patent suits filed
in district courts rose from about two thousand in the year 2000 to over four thousand five
hundred in 2016).
281 See PTAB STATISTICS 2015, supra note 90, at 3 (reporting that, from fiscal year 2014
to fiscal year 2015, the number of petitions for inter partes review, post-grant review, and
covered business method review increased from 1489 to 1897); see also PTAB STATISTICS
2016, supra note 37, at 3 (reporting that, in fiscal year 2016, 1683 petitions for inter partes
review, post-grant review, and covered business method review were filed).
282 Smith & Transier, supra note 15, at 231-32.
283 CHIEF JUSTICE OF THE SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES, 2015 YEAR-END
286 Id. at 49 (showing abrogation of Rule 84); see Bultman, supra note 32 (The changes,
a rewrite of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure . . . eliminate a rule that allowed filers of
patent suits to rely on a bare-bones model complaint.).
1840 BOSTON UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 97:1775
changes appear to leave much to trial judges discretion287 and seem unlikely to
have great effects in the many district courts that already have special local rules,
standing orders or practices to regulate pretrial processes in patent cases.288
Additional adjustments might be forthcoming from Congress or the courts. In
recent years, members of Congress have introduced various bills focused on
patent litigation reform289 or the pre-litigation demand letters290 that have
attracted the attention of state legislators.291 Litigation reform bills have
proposed changing aspects of litigation such as pleading requirements, rules for
attorney-fee shifting, the rules regulating allowable venues for district court
litigation, and the scope of allowable discovery.292 But, so far, efforts to enact
such bills have stalled.293
In contrast, in May 2017, the Supreme Court effectively enacted venue
reform by overturning longstanding Federal Circuit precedent that had adopted
a liberal understanding of the statutory requirements for venue.294 The change
287 See Alexsam, Inc. v. IDT Corp., 715 F.3d 1336, 1342 (Fed. Cir. 2013) (A district
courts decision to sanction a litigant [for a discovery violation] under Rule 37 is reviewed
for abuse of discretion.); Abbott Point of Care Inc. v. Epocal, Inc., 666 F.3d 1299, 1302 (Fed.
Cir. 2012) ([T]his court reviews the district courts denial of discovery, an issue not unique
to patent law, for abuse of discretion, applying the law of the regional circuit . . . . (quoting
Patent Rights Prot. Grp., LLC v. Video Gaming Techs., Inc., 603 F.3d 1364, 1371 (Fed. Cir.
2010))); Kaplow, supra note 212, at 1285-86 (suggesting that the plausibility pleading
standard might effectively leave much up to the idiosyncratic views of individual district
judges).
288 See supra notes 276-77 and accompanying text (discussing local rules and standing
orders adopted by district courts for patent cases); cf. Robert G. Bone, Twombly, Pleading
Rules, and the Regulation of Court Access, 94 IOWA L. REV. 873, 878 (2009) (contending that
the Courts plausibility standard marks only a modest departure from notice pleading).
289 See Gugliuzza, supra note 202, at 283 (Of the fourteen patent reform bills introduced
Cong.; Innovation Act, H.R. 9, 114th Cong. 2 (2015); Gugliuzza, supra note 202, at 283.
293 Sources Say Patent Bills Not Right-Sized But Goodlatte, Pro-Bill Lobbyists Keep
Fighting, 90 PAT. TRADEMARK & COPYRIGHT J. (B.N.A.) No. 2234, at 3624, 3624 (2015)
(reporting indications that patent litigation reform legislation was unlikely to move forward
in its current form).
294 See TC Heartland LLC v. Kraft Food Brands Grp. LLC, 137 S. Ct. 1514, 1517 (2017)
(concluding that a domestic corporation resides only in its State of incorporation for
purposes of the patent venue statute); Mark Curriden, The Rocket Docket Starts to Fizzle:
Patent Infringement Cases Filed in East Texas Federal Courts Down for First Time in 3
Years, HOUS. CHRON., Jan. 30, 2017, at B1, B2 (reporting that, if the Supreme Court reads
venue provisions narrowly, it would likely mean fewer cases filed in East Texas).
2017] TROLL CHECK? 1841
will likely have only limited impact on the litigation concerns motivating this
Articles proposal, however. Neither this change to the understanding of venue
requirements nor other proposed reforms obviate the value promised by PLRB
review. Indeed, those reforms would not provide for the sort of automatic and
impartial early-stage review of substantive questions in patent litigation that the
PLRB would make availableand hence, those other reforms cannot offer the
informational advantages for individual parties and society that PLRB review
provides. In short, even if various alternative reforms are implemented, this
Articles framework for patent litigation administrative review will still promise
to substantially improve how the patent system operates.
CONCLUSION
The time has come to take seriously a variant of Jeffersons proposal for a
board of Academical professors for patents295here, a proposed Patent
Litigation Review Board of experienced patent professionals with broad access
to scientific and technical expertise.296 Early-stage PLRB review of patent suits
can improve the patent systems immediate economic performance and provide
information that enables further improvements. Patent litigation in the United
States currently bears many hallmarks of a process ripe for, and indeed marked
by, opportunistic behavior. High litigation costs, long delays in obtaining
clarifying decisions, and substantial continuing limitations on USPTO review
suggest that a robust process of early-stage administrative review can mitigate
current problems with patent litigation. Such administrative review seems
particularly likely to be justified on a cost-benefit basis to the extent it focuses
on the tails of party assertions in patent litigation: discouraging the weakest
assertions and encouraging the strongest ones. This Article has shown that
multiple economic models, using realistic figures for the costs of review, support
the argument that early-stage administrative review will improve the patent
system.
On the other hand, dramatic litigation reforms such as the institution of PLRB
review can sometimes generate unexpected effects. Consequently, this Article
recommends adopting the proposed framework on a trial bias. A sunset
provision would require policymakers to reevaluate the framework within a few
years. Innovative policymaking with a continuing commitment to information
gathering and reevaluation are crucial to ensuring the optimal performance of
dynamic legal regimes like the patent system. This Articles proposal for PLRB
review is an ideal first step along this path.