Telecommunications
Telecommunications
Telecommunications
IMAGE ETHICS
The Moral Rights of Subjects
in Photographs, Film, and Television
Edited by Larry Gross, John Stuart Katz,
and Jay Ruby
CENSORSHIP
The Knot That Binds Power and Knowledge
By Sue Curry Jansen
THE GLOBAL VILLAGE
Transformations in World Life and Media in
the 21st Century
By Marshall McLuhan and Bruce R. Powers
SPLIT SIGNALS
Television and Politics in the Soviet Union
By Ellen Mickiewicz
TARGET: PRIME TIME
Advocacy Groups and the
Struggle over Entertainment Television
By Kathryn C. Montgomery
TELEVISION AND AMERICA'S CHILDREN
A Crisis of Neglect
By Edward L. Palmer
PLAYING DOCTOR
Television; Storytelling, and Medical Power
By Joseph Turow
THE VOX DEI
Communication in the Middle Ages
By Sophia Menache
THE EXPORT OF MEANING
Cross-Cultural Readings of DALLAS
By Tamar Liebes and Elihu Katz
TELEVISION IN EUROPE
By Eli Noam
TELECOMMUNICATIONS IN EUROPE
By Eli Noam
Telecommunications
in Europe
Eli Noam
9876543
Printed in the United States of America
on acid-free paper
Preface
This book, together with its companion, volume, Television in Europe, cov-
ers many subjects and many countries. It is therefore necessary, at the outset,
to state what it is and what it is not.
The book is an analysis of the rise and beginning fall of the telecommuni-
cations monopolies in Europe. These Post, Telegraph, and Telephone admin-
istrations (PTTs) are vast and powerful; in many countries they are the largest
employer, investor, and buyer. They often run vast financial savings and pay-
ment systems, and even provide services such as bus transportation in some
countries. Their physical presence is ubiquitous, and their services reach daily
into almost every home and office. But despite the importance and scale of
these institutions, social scientists have paid little attention to them. 1
One reason for such lack of interest is that the subject of telecommunications
seems forbiddingly technological. Actually, most of the issues in telecommu-
nications are quite accessible once they are stripped of needless jargon. Another
reason is that for a long time most experts had grown up within the traditional
system and mutually reinforced each others' views. Only recently did expertise
begin to diversify, and more detached judgments became possible.
To understand the future one must know the past. Hence, this book deals in
some detail with the historical and political context. This is done especially in
Part I which describes the dynamics of changes and the forces that transform
the traditional PTT system.
Part II is given to discussions of individual countries. All Western European
countries are analyzed, hence this section serves as somewhat of a handbook
on Western European countries' telecommunications systems, and provides a
bird's-eye view of the continent. At present, telecommunications knowledge is
highly segmented along territorial lines. It has proved to be an enormous un-
dertaking to treat so many countries and write a book that tries to transcend
national systems and go beyond theorizing. Some priorities had to be set, and
several of the larger countries received a more detailed treatment. Eastern Eu-
rope, whose societies have only recently rejoined the European mainstream and
the dynamics of its telecommunications evolution, is treated only briefly.
In the discussion of some countries, I have selected particular issues for
emphasis. For example, procurement of equipment by a PTT is given greater
attention in the chapter on Germany; industrial policy is emphasized in the
chapter on France; and the United Kingdom chapter looks at a PTT reorgani-
vi Preface
zation and its aftermath. Thus, the country chapters, taken together, also pro-
vide a mosaic of policy issues across Europe.
Part III discusses several special topics in European telecommunications, such
as industrial policy, the struggle with American interests, internationalization
of conflict, and vertical integration into new fields. Value-added services, in-
tegrated networks, transborder data flows, and international services are further
examples of new policy issues. The last part of the book analyzes the future of
networks, the instability of the international system, and the modularization of
networks. It concludes with an outlook on the future policy agenda and the
emerging new open network environment, which is very different from the
traditional one.
The book is not a comparative study in the sense of contrasting different
countries' approaches to a problem and evaluating the best of them. This is
done only occasionally, both among European countries and with respect to the
United States. More interesting than the comparative approach"which PTT
procurement system is best?"is the institutional one"how and why did
Germany's procurement system evolve? How and why is it changing?"
Although the treatment of an entire subcontinent with some specificity is
worthwhile, it is also difficult. In each country there are numerous experts who
know more about the subject matter for their own country than any single
author could. Hence, it is easy to be critical of the broader analysis by refer-
ence to superior knowledge of the details in a subplot. I have tried to deal with
the specifics by investing much time in visits; in reading academic, trade press,
governmental, and consulting literature; and in engaging in voluminous corre-
spondence. Drafts of the chapters were sent in each country to a dozen or more
individuals and institutions, sometimes in several rounds, and most of the com-
ments and corrections were incorporated. Often the replies and corrections from
the same country were contradictory, mirroring the policy debates in those
countries themselves. Even after the corrections, I am sure that national experts
will be able to identify some inaccuracies. Some may be based on sources, of
which many are unavoidably secondary rather than primary; others will be due
to updates to information presented in the book. Some perspective is necessary.
Although a change in the particulars may be of critical significance to those
directly involved, the broader picture is rarely affected by it.
In numerous contacts with PTT officials, I have become used to defensive
reactions to any suggestion that the traditional arrangement was not solely aimed
at optimally serving the public's need for a telecommunications infrastructure.
One form of response was dismissal of alternative views as having an "Amer-
ican perspective" (i.e., not being grounded in the traditions of another coun-
try). It is, of course, true that all institutions are historically grown. Indeed,
that is the very premise of this book. But PTT officials, who are typically
electrical engineers turned civil servants, are rarely familiar with the genesis
and evolution of their own systems. Their perspective tends to be ahistorical.
Indeed, a second type of response, at tension with the first, has been that the
discussions in this book are relevant to the past but are "dated" in that things
have recently changed, perhaps due to a reorganization, a new technology, or
Preface vii
a new directive yet. This is as if one negated the relevance of childhood and
youth to an evaluation of an adult. Episodes along the way do not become
irrelevant to the understanding of an ongoing institution simply because the
rules have recently been changed. A third and related type of response has been
the flight into detail. It is this expert-oriented view of the world, favoring the
trees over the forest, that has kept discussions of telecommunications policy
out of the public realm.
Another form of defensiveness is to consider an evaluation that contains a
critique of the monopoly system as adversary and possibly inspired by business
designs. I have no such ties or commercial engagements. Nor do I ignore the
significant historical contribution made by PTTs to the evolution of their coun-
tries' communication infrastructure. PTTs were very important in the first phases
of network evolution; but as this book argues, telecommunications are moving
into a third stage, that of the pluralistic network. Its origin lies in the success,
not the failure, of the traditional system. The unravelling of that system by
various centrifugal forces cannot be contained, and we are merely at the begin-
ning of that process. Such a conclusion may be unwelcome, but it is not ad-
versary.
This is not a book about U.S. telecommunications. To be critical of a prac-
tice in a European country does not necessarily mean to approve of its U.S.
counterpart. But it is of course true that the perspective of this book has bene-
fitted from participation in American telecommunications policy and research.
I should clarify that much of it has been written or conceived before I took a
leave as a professor at Columbia University and as director of its Center for
Telecommunications and Information Studies (now the Columbia Institute for
Tele-Information: C.I.T.I.), and before I was appointed to the New York State
Public Service Commission. Nothing in this book reflects the views of that
regulatory body (whose international involvement is, at any rate, negligible).
The PSC and its staff of 650 regulate intrastate telecommunications for 10
million lines in the state, as well as electricity, gas, and water. It is in frequent
disagreement and litigation with the Federal Communications Commission in
Washington.
Thus, the views of this book do not defend the views of official Washington.
The New York State PSC, for example, instituted low-income telephone ser-
vice, based on a blueprint by the author, that provides basic telephone service
for about 1.5 million poor households for $1 per month, with similarly low
installation charges. This makes telephone service virtually free for poor peo-
ple. I mention this because one of the self-images of traditionalists in telecom-
munications policy is that only they are socially concerned. A large body of
literature sees change in telecommunications as a challenge by large business
interests, many of them multinational firms, to existing socially motivated and
home-grown arrangements. The reality, however, is much more complex. Do-
mestic monopolies are less rooted in social benevolence than its defenders claim.
The imperatives of an information-based economy and a rapidly developing
technology do not leave unscathed the institutional structure under which the
informational nervous system of society functions, and it makes little sense to
viii Preface
slay the messenger of that news. Changes came to the surt'ace first in America,
and subsequently reached Europe and Japan. It would be surprising if this pro-
cess were not to continue for decades and if at its end the various national
systems were not very different from those of today.
At the conclusion of this project, thanks are owed to a large number of people;
only a few can be recognized in these pages, and none should be held respon-
sible.
The project was made possible by financial assistance from the German Mar-
shall Fund of the United States and later from the Gannett Foundation. Peter
Weitz and Gerald Sass deserve the credit for supporting the work and keeping
it alive as its scope grew.
At Columbia, a lively collection of student assistants, editors, cite and quote
checkers, and typists participated in the project, later helping to update the
information. They were supervised first by Christopher Dorman and then by
Richard Kramer, who contributed in many valuable ways. Assisting them were
Hiiseyin Bayazit, Andrew Blau, Theresa Bolmarcich, Laura Bulatao, Dawn
Chang, Paul Chew, Andrew Day, Peggy Danneman, Sherry Emery, Christine
Enemark, Valere Gagnon, Rhonda Harrison, Christopher King, John Kollar,
Jessica Lee, Junno Lee, Catherine Lim, Alfred Lucas, Michael McManus, Kurt
Miller, Altagracia Miranda, Erica Simmons, Wendy Stryker, My-Phuong Tran,
and Mark Young. Barbara Martz was enormously helpful with press and arti-
cles from many sources. Roberta Tasley and Douglas Conn, as managers of
the Columbia Center, provided the necessary organizational structure. Aine
Ni'Shuilleabhain supervised the last and strenuous phase of the project. Rachel
Toor, Herbert J. Addison, and Steve Bedney of the Oxford University Press
guided the project to conclusion.
Among academics, private experts and public officials, both at home and
elsewhere, I am grateful to Per Klitgaard Andersen, Elena Androunas, Fran-
cisco Pinto Balsemao, Johannes Bauer, Marino Benedetti, Hans Bergendorff,
Catherine Bertho, Martin Bullinger, G. Buyck, Tom Byrnes, Farrell Corcoran,
Andrea Costa, James Cowie, William Drake, Martin Elton, Beth Eres, Ugo de
Fusco, Paul W.J. de Graaf, Bruce Greenwald, Karl Erik Gustafson, Jaakko
Hannuksela, Mario Hirsch, Johann Hjalmarsson, Wolfgang Hoffmann-Riem,
Janos Horvat, Elfriede Hufnagl, C. Jacobaeus, Herman Cohen Jehoram, Tuen
de Johngh, Tanya Kiang, Leon Kirsch, Christian Kobelt, Ismo Kosonen, Geo-
vanni Lanza, Michael Latzer, S. C. Littlechild, Giovanni Maggio, Pennetti
Mannisto, Horst Edgar Martin, Fergus McGovern, Heikki Myllo, Gosta Neo-
vius, Godefroy Dang Ngyuen, Sam Nilsson, Mogens Kuhns Pedersen, Francois
Pichault, G. Russell Pipe, Gerard Pogorel, Remy LeChampion, Sheizaf Ra-
faeli, Anthony Rutkowski, Shaul Hai, Joachim Scherer, Donald Smullin, Charles
Stabell, Matthias Steinmann, Jan Thurmer, Sylviane Toporkoff, Rudolf Trach-
sel, Sergio Treves, Jeremy Tunstall, Thierry Vedel, Timo Viljakainen, Lennart
Weibull, Christian von Weizsacker, Eberhard Witte, and Glenn Woroch. To
those whose names have been inadvertently omitted, my apologies.
Preface ix
Most of all, I owe this book to my wife Nadine Strossen, champion of free
speech and human rights in America and abroad; to my mother, who provides
the bridge across the Atlantic; and to the memory of my father.
7. Germany 69
8. The United Kingdom 103
9. France 133
3
4 Public Telecommunications: A Concept in Transition
and in 1614 established a state-run postal monopoly (Stephan, 1859). Thus, the
PTT system was born as a creation by the absolutist state for the absolutist
state. Later, this system was rationalized as based, depending on one's point
of view, on economies of scale, national sovereignty, cross-subsidies, or public
infrastructure needs; but the early creators of the postal monopoly system were
quite forthright in their mission to generate profits for the state and its sover-
eign. The postal system became a major source of revenue, at a time when
European rulers had insatiable needs for cash. As the goose that would lay the
golden eggs, the system was ardently protected through the centuries against
encroachment by private competitors and by other states.
When the telegraph emerged in the nineteenth century, it was rapidly inte-
grated into the monopoly. Later, much was made of the military importance of
state control over telegraphy. Although this consideration may have been sig-
nificant for the major powers, it was less relevant for the many other countries
that also banned private telegraphs. Even for the larger states, the strategic
importance of the new medium did not really require operations by the state
itself any more than it did for overseas mailan important service in the era
of imperialismwhere private delivery under contract was regularly used.
When the telephone made its appearance in 1876, it too was soon integrated
into the state monopoly once its financial viability became clear. Here official
histories claim that the purpose was to bring telephony to rural areas neglected
by commercial interests. This is true in some cases, but in other instances (for
example, Norway), the historical record is quite different, and does not lead to
find an aim of spreading telecommunications service across the country. At the
same time, telecommunications were integrated into an international system of
collaboration, with the official goal of technical coordination, but also, from
the beginning, with a cartel agenda on prices and service conditions.
For almost a century, a tightly controlled system of telecommunications was
in place in most developed countries. Its structure was supported by a broad
coalition that provided political support in return for a share in the monopoly
rents. This rent-seeking coalition can be termed the "postal-industrial com-
plex." It encompasses the government PTT as the network operator and the
private equipment industry as its supplier, together with residential and rural
users, trade unions, the political left, and the newspaper publishing industry,
whose postal and telegraph rates were heavily subsidized. The traditional sys-
tem worked in particular to the benefit of the equipment industry, which was
provided large markets by huge PTT procurements, especially after World War
II. These markets were also almost always protected from foreign competition
by buy-domestic policies. Within most industrialized countries, equipment
manufacturers often collaborated in formal or informal cartels that set prices
and allocated shares of the large PTT contracts. The structure of telecommu-
nications in the United States, although private, was not all that different, be-
cause it was a near-monopoly, with a full integration of network operation and
equipment manufacturing. Its corporate ideology was shaped by AT&T's pa-
tron saint, Theodore Vail, himself a former postal man as the head of the U.S.
Railway Mail Service.
Public Telecommunications: A Concept in Transition 5
The system was profitable and reassuring for insiders, and its inefficiencies
were hidden by the general downward trend in the cost of electronic technology
(which was due, on balance, more to computer and component firms than to
traditional telecommunications firms.) The PTTs also set standards for equip-
ment in a way that would often discourage or delay outsiders, and they often
collaborated with favored domestic firms in equipment development and in ex-
port promotions.
In Switzerland, for example, the PTT in 1984 set standards for cordless
telephones by issuing a fifty-five page specifications manual and requiring no
less than forty duplex channels and automatic scanning. Because of these rules,
which were allegedly passed to protect the users, only one company, a Swiss
one, could meet the standards quickly (and not surprisingly, since it had played
a major role in developing the rules). Moreover, the manufacturer's estimated
price to the PTT for a set was almost $800, and monthly rentals came to about
$15 (Wolf, 1983). At the same time, one could buy a simpler but perfectly
adequate cordless telephone in the United States for less than $75. Swiss users
resorted to buying cheaper but illegal foreign equipment in the many stores
where they were marked "for export only."
Although the traditional monopoly systemthough not always its execu-
tionoperated to the economic advantage of equipment firms, its principle long
enjoyed broad public approval from the constituent groups of the postal-indus-
trial coalition. The monopoly followed concepts of public service: universal,
accessible, affordable, and redistributive. As a public service, telephony was
outside the mechanism of the market, even in otherwise free-economy coun-
tries. Any change in that status was bound to be controversial; an expansion of
the realm of the market into the realm of rights and politics has always been a
painful transition.
Thus, a partial relocation of telecommunications from the public domain into
the economic one was objectionable to many. Indeed, the single most powerful
argument in defense of the traditional centralized system is a value preference
for the principle of state ownership in infrastructure as distinguished from the
"scientific" arguments that a monopoly is necessary for engineering and eco-
nomic reasons.
PTTs were not entirely frozen in their institutional development. After many
decades of stability, some of them were transformed in the late 1980s into
"PTOs", public telecommunications organizations. The new designation con-
notes a separation from postal services, and change from a governmental ad-
ministration into a state-owned semi-independent organization. Furthermore,
some new types of activities such as value-added services and mobile telephony
were permitted to be offered by private firms. But these changes do not prove
that a major reorientation had taken place, and that the problem of state mo-
nopoly had been resolved in most countries.
The exaggeration of the extent of actual change can lead to bureaucratic
doublespeak. For example, the Danish government, in creating the PTO
teleDenmark, declared, "As a consequence of decisions made at the EC level,
there will be competition within all spheres of telecommunications in the next
6 Public Telecommunications: A Concept in Transition
few years, apart from telex, ordinary telephones, radio-based mobile services,
satellite services, the infrastructure and the use of telecommunications network
for broadcasting. . . ." (Ministry of Communications, 1990). In other words,
"everything" will be competitive, except for the remaining 95%. In almost
every country there still exists a tight monopoly over transmission infrastruc-
ture, switched services, and voice servicethe vast majority of telecommuni-
cations activities. The liberalized exceptions are minor in comparison, and, in
the case of value-added services, consist of sophisticated computer-based activ-
ities in which the PTTs had only a limited participation. Similarly, the separa-
tion from postal service and the creation of a more independent status repre-
sents no reduction in economic power. To the contrary, postal services had
become a financial drag on telecommunications. Independence permitted a
branching into new activities, including the vertical expansion into manufactur-
ing, and the horizontal expansion internationally. Regulation was left to tiny
government departments that were hard-put to control some of their countries'
largest and most complex organizations.
This is not to say that no change has taken place. The traditional PTT system
was stable for a century. But in the 1980s pressures emerged, just as they did
in the television sector, that could no longer be contained. This was accompa-
nied by harsh political disputes. By the end of the decade, change was in the
air everywhere. The postal and telephone monopolies were being reorganized
in most countries; some competitive suppliers were emerging; intraorganiza-
tional private networks were increasingly taking traffic from the public net-
work; and the European Commission in Brussels was hectoring the national
governments to loosen restrictions. The actual extent of the change should not
be exaggerated, given the inertia of the past; but once the process is set in
motion, further transformation is inevitable. This process will continue, and
will lead to a telecommunications infrastructure that is very different from to-
day's.
These are the themes this book discusses, both in general and in country-
specific terms.
2
The Establishment of the PIT System
7
8 The Establishment of the PTT System
time, regular routes developed, centered around inns at which messengers would
rest. It became customary for patrons to leave messages for delivery and trans-
portation at these "posts," and for messengers to exchange horses, thereby
considerably speeding up transportation. Two basic forms of organized postal
service emerged. The first was private service, subject to governmental author-
ity. Its prime example was the Thurn-and-Taxis postal system. The second was
a state-operated postal service, such as the ones in Prussia and in England that
became the direct ancestors of the modern European PTTs. These two types of
systems and their struggle with each other will now be described.
Now the government authorities' appetite was whetted. The previously ig-
nored postal service was recognized as a rich source of revenue, and this led
to bitter disputes about the rights of regional principalities and of the free cities
to operate their own systems. It was readily understood that the coexistence of
The Establishment of the PIT System 9
rival services would lower profitability. The Taxis were supported by the Ger-
man emperor, who advanced the legal theory, profitable to both, that the right
to grant a postal franchise was an imperial prerogative. But this was frequently
challenged or ignored, and the Taxis had to work ceaselessly at suppressing
other private messenger services and governmental postal services of smaller
principalities and cities.
In particular, during the period of the Dutch rebellion against Spain, the
Taxis system of a loose family confederation operating under various govern-
ment concessions unraveled, and competing local messenger guilds emerged.
Since competition posed a threat to the imperial revenues, Emperor Rudolf II
initiated in 1579 what has since become second nature to European govern-
ments: He prohibited private competition and appointed a blue-ribbon commis-
sion to study postal reforms. The commission included two members of the
Fugger familybankers to the emperors and large-scale merchants (in today's
terms, user and creditor representatives). The commission, unsurprisingly, re-
stored control to the Taxis. In 1595, Leonhard von Taxis was appointed impe-
rial postmaster general. He and Emperor Rudolf II sent notices around to sup-
press the "lesser, butcher and messenger posts."
But competitors and rival authorities kept disputing the monopoly privileges
granted to the by now Count von Taxis. Duke Frederick of Wurttemberg an-
notated the emperor's missive, in his own hand: "Because there is no obliga-
tion, one must not obey, as we will not do, but ask Your Majesty to place your
posts elsewhere, as it has been in past days, so it shall remain" (von Beust,
1748). The states also accused the Taxis monopoly of unreliable service and of
excessive charges. Yet subsequent Hapsburg monarchs renewed the Taxis rights.
Charles V even extended them, after his coronation in 1630, for his entire
realm, over which the sun did not set. The Thirty Years War complicated the
Taxis fortunes by introducing commercial, religious, and diplomatic intrigues
of major proportions. Emperor Ferdinand III, whose war finances depended
upon Taxis contributors, was induced again to proclaim the prohibition of rival
messenger service where the Taxis operated, even though this antagonized many
cities and principalities that still operated their own systems.
The eighteenth century was the zenith of the private Taxis system. The Em-
peror's financial needs continued, of course, and the head of what had been a
humble family of messengers was now promoted to hereditary imperial prince,
head of the House of Thurn and Taxis. But this concealed the decline of the
system: The powers of the emperors were waning, and with them the founda-
tion of Taxis power. The Thirty Years War had created a more decentralized
governmental structure in Central Europe, and the territorial rulers no longer
recognized the imperial postal monopoly claim. Whatever the constitutional
legalities, the territorial rulers controlled roads over which postal service had
to pass. Furthermore, the emperor's arguments for a monopoly system were
much weakened when he established state-owned posts in his own Austrian
domains.
These disputes over postal monopolies lasted for centuries. The major states
unilaterally established their own posts on whatever routes they found profit-
10 The Establishment of the PIT System
The Prussian Post established the institutional model of a state postal adminis-
tration for much of Europe and the rest of the world. Its early history is one of
a centuries-long struggle against the private Taxis system. And although most
of this rivalry is long forgotten, traces of antagonism are no doubt left within
its institutional subconscious.
The direct ancestor of today's giant German Bundespost Telekom system
started out as tiny semigovernmental service in Brandenburg (Prussia's predecessor)
with twenty-four messengers. Initially, the system operated only for govern-
mental use. Soon, however, some private service was provided on the initiative
of the postmasters who directly shared in the profits. In 1649, the Prussian
government formally took over the system and expanded routes, relay stations,
postmasters, and agreements with foreign governments.
Government monopoly did not necessarily mean state provision of postal
services. Local postmasters were not paid a salary, but could levy charges on
letters. Private concessionaries that were compensated by the local postmasters
provided much of the actual transportation of the mail. They were required to
keep to the established schedules; fines were levied for tardiness.
Soon rivalries flared up with the messenger services of free cities who were
prohibited to pass through Prussian territory. Danzig messengers armed them-
selves; pitched battles broke out and led to temporary warfare that also involved
other states. The Taxis were able to buy rights of transit through Prussia, but
were prohibited from picking up or distributing any letters on Prussian territory.
The state's monopoly was extended to transporting coach passengers, an ar-
rangement directly leading to today's railroad monopolies.
Where state monopolies were not enforced, a wide diversity existed. In 1695,
postal customers in the Free City of Hamburg could choose among local postal
offices affiliated with Sweden, Denmark, Prussia, Brunswick, Thurn and Taxis,
Holstein, Mecklenburg, Saxony-Gotha, and Nuremberg, plus various private
messenger and delivery services. In 1712, the General Prussian Postal Order
was issued, reiterating the governmental monopoly. On occasion, private op-
erators were licensed, but only on routes or for time periods that were noncom-
peting. They were usually not permitted to change horses and were otherwise
restricted. However, the suppression of private service providers was not easy.
As Heinrich Stephan, later the Prussian Postmaster General, writes:
The civil and military administrations were instructed to carefully seek the main-
tenance of the state postal rights. If the efforts in that respect were not always as
successful as desired, one should not overlook that the total elimination of the
previously very extensive private-messenger institutions is a difficult task, whose
The Establishment of the PIT System 11
Figure 2.1. Revenues, Expenditures, and Profits of the Prussian Postal Service.
(Source: Stephan, 1859, pp. 130, 297-299.)
successful solution could have been reached only gradually. (Stephan, 1859, p.
51).
The postal system became highly profitable. In 1662, Prussian postal profits
were 7000 Thalers on 10,000 Thalers expenses. Twenty years later, profits had
quadrupled to 29,058 on 22,902 expenses, a substantial margin. And in 1688,
they were 39,213 on 40,758 of expenses (Stephan, 1859, p. 59). See Figure
2.1. The profits of local postmasters were similarly considerable. Neumann,
the postmaster of Konigsberg, enjoyed an annual income of about 2000 Tha-
lers. To put these figures in perspective, in 1623 a meal of about four courses
in a Berlin inn "suitable for persons of nobility" cost about 1/4 of a Thaler;
day labor cost 1/24 of a Thaler, plus meals. Messengers were compensated at
1/12 of a Thaler per day, plus about 1/5 of a Thaler for an average day's
mileage.
In subsequent years, the profits of the Prussian postal service continued to
increase. These profit figures are still understated, because they do not include
the sale of postmasterships.
What were the profits used for? In 1699, the first year for which a breakdown
is available, profits were a remarkable 85,000 Thalers on 68,000 expenses. Of
the net gain, 45,000 Thalers went to the monarch individually, 6000 to his
wife, 6000 to the crown prince, and 4000 into construction of the elector's
Berlin residence. Three thousand Thalers were used to support the sciences
(Stephan, 1859, p. 130). Thus, almost two thirds of the considerable profits of
12 The Establishment of the PIT System
the post directly benefitted the royal family, and 4 percent went into what we
would call today research and development.
During the forty-six years of Frederick the Great's rule, the postal service
generated 20 million Thalers, much of it going directly to the king, who de-
pended considerably on this revenue. In addition, appointment to a postmaster-
ship was accompanied by payment to the royal coffers. The king paid an ex-
traordinary amount of attention to the details of the postal service. Given the
rich flow of revenues, protection against postal competition became an impor-
tant part of foreign policy.
Seeking still higher returns to defray the cost of the Seven Years War, Fred-
erick the Great decided to raise postal rates considerably and to expand the
state monopoly to packages. A group of French fiscal specialists organized the
changes. Users and foreign postal administrations initially refused to pay the
higher rates, but to no avail. For the postal civil servant Heinrich Stephan (later
a celebrated postmaster general), writing in a later age in which postal admin-
istrators were still guilelessly proud of making profits for the state rather than
skillful in understating them, this was proof of the strength of the monopoly:
In the seventeenth century when private companies still existed, "a general
increase in the letter mail rate would have been a signal for the ruin of the
postal institution, and for the reemergence of a whole number of private postal
institutions" (Stephan, 1859, p. 294). But this was no longer true in the eigh-
teenth century. The power of the absolutist state made it possible to increase
rates that a century before would have been unsustainable because of competi-
tion.
Internally, however, the increase of postal rates was controversial. Freder-
ick's ministers, in a report to their sovereign about the decline of Prussian
commerce, ventured respectfully that the postal rate increase was a contributing
factor. This 1766 report is a remarkable document in its aversion to mercantil-
istic restrictions and its support for a free-market philosophy, in the same vein
as Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations, published a decade later. The report is a
direct ancestor of today's pleas by various ministries of economics or industry
in favor of less restrictive postal policies. And it was similarly controversial.
Within twenty-four hours, the king strictly prohibited his ministers from engag-
ing in any discussion along these lines. But it turned out that the king's min-
isters, accused by him of ignorance, malice, and corruption, had a better un-
derstanding of economics than their sovereign, since the total revenue of the
postal service declined for some time. Even the absolutist monarch was unable
to abolish demand elasticity. Moreover, several foreign postal services avoided
Prussia as a transit route. Thus, whatever competition that did exist for routes
exerted itself. In time, revenues recovered. But to Heinrich Stephan, the archi-
tect of the telecommunications monopoly system a century later, one of the
lessons of the initial setback must have been that rate coordination between
neighboring countries was necessary to protect monopoly power, just as do-
mestic exclusivity was its precondition.
In the 1720s, several European states contemplated the establishment of a
The Establishment of the PIT System 13
cooperative postal arrangement that would permit a route from Amsterdam all
the way to Danzig and Petersburg, entirely bypassing Prussia and establishing
a major alternative to its postal service. Prussia stood to lose 75,000 Thalers a
year in revenue. It took all its diplomatic, secret service, and commercial ef-
forts to stifle the establishment of the rival system, but the competitive pressure
also led to considerably improved postal service on the threatened route. Most
important, it entered into an alliance with its long-time rival Taxis, which was
similarly threatened by the proposed new system. In 1723, the former compet-
itors reached a treaty against the common enemy; they agreed upon a code of
conduct, and divided routes among themselves. Though they hardly needed the
reminder, they also promised to be vigilant in their suppression of independent
postal carriers. The relations between the Prussian and the Taxis systems be-
came even closer, when Alexander von Taxis, elevated to prince in 1754 be-
cause of his enormous wealth and financial support of the emperor, also sought
to buy a seat in the imperial electoral college, which included the handful of
the highest nobles of the realm. Frederick the Great supported him in return
for postal concessions. But the agreement proved short-lived, because of the
Seven Years War that engulfed Europe. Taxis eagerly displaced Prussian posts
when Frederick's war fortunes were low, and when Prussia turned the tide of
war, it too expelled the Taxis postmasters and substituted its own.
During the Napoleonic Wars, the Prussian Post and the Taxis system were
again in conflict over their rights. When the Holy Roman Empire came to an
end in 1806, the position of the Taxis post, based upon the grant by the em-
peror, had lost its foundation. In a conflict with strong secular powers, it was
pushed aside, regardless of its performance as a carrier.
After the Vienna Congress in 1815, the increased flow of traffic led to a
large number of bilateral agreements modeled after the Prussian-Taxis arrange-
ments, which regulated the relationships of postal services. In the following
decades, coordinating bodies developed both for post and for the newly devel-
oped telegraphy. A regional postal union was created in 1850 and was soon
expanded to telegraphs. It provided the model for later European and later
global collaboration of state telegraphs and telephones.
In 1866, the Thurn und Taxis Reichspost, which still existed in fifteen small
states, had shrunk to 15 percent of the size of the Prussian Post. In that year,
Prussia went to war with Austria over hegemony in Central Europe, and occu-
pied Frankfurt, the Taxis's headquarters. Thus ended the 350-year-old Taxis
system. The family, left with a huge fortune but no postal routes, was hence-
forth relegated to an active role in the society pages.
Von Stephan, Germany's postmaster general and later state secretary and
minister, played a remarkable role in the development of European postal and
telecommunications institutions. Born in 1831, as the son of a tailor, he began
working as a postal scribe and rose rapidly (Grosse, 1931). A man of unusual
breadth, he wrote monographs on the history of transportation and postal ser-
vice, contributed such innovations as the postcard, and restructured German
and international postal service. Stephan became postmaster general and inte-
14 The Establishment of the PIT System
grated the German postal systems; later he was instrumental in the international
agreements that led in 1874 to the establishment of the International Postal
Union.
In 1876, the newly established German state decided to expand its backward
telegraph system. Von Stephan, a postal man, was appointed to head the tele-
graph office. Within a short time, he had merged the two services, despite
opposition from the more technical telegraph personnel. Von Stephan also rap-
idly introduced the telephone. Its purpose, however, was distinctly different
from that of its American counterpart, where the telephone became established
in private homes and businesses. The Reichspost viewed the telephone as an
extension of state telegraphy, to be used in rural post offices, where trained
telegraph operators were economically infeasible.
In the German state of Wurttemberg, which maintained its independent postal
system even after the German unification, the American Bell Telephone Com-
pany sought a government concession to provide telephone service in the cap-
ital city of Stuttgart. Impatient after bureaucratic delays, the Bell representative
started wiring without a license until he was stopped by the police. The postal
authorities soon took over. This was Germany's only brush with private tele-
phone service for more than a century, until the 1990s. In 1892, the compre-
hensive telephone authority of the state was cemented into law.
An account of the further history of German telecommunications is provided
in Chapter 7 on Germany.
In the United Kingdom the monopoly for postal and telecommunications ser-
vices was also far from "natural," but rather the outcome of fierce economic
and political battles for control. This struggle for a British postal monopoly and
its extension to telecommunications will be discussed in greater detail than the
similar developments that took place in other European countries.
British postal service began with informal messengers for the royal house-
hold. In 1481, Edward IV created a more organized route system for govern-
mental use with stations 20 miles apart. It was not a monopoly, however.
Private letters had to be carried by a variety of messengers until 1512, when
Sir Brian Tube, the first recorded English postmaster general, opened the Royal
Post to nonofficial letters. The system stagnated during the reign of Queen
Elizabeth (1533-1605). In 1590, John Lord Stanhope was made hereditary master
of the posts. Stanhope obtained a national monopoly and subcontracted specific
postal routes to local postmasters, often for substantial sums. These postmas-
ters, frequently innkeepers, also held the local monopoly over the hiring out of
horses to travelers. For some services, particularly international ones, the offi-
cial postal service had to compete with the rival Foreigner's Post and the Mer-
chant Adventurers' Post (Hemmeon, 1912).
In 1591, a royal proclamation affirmed the government's claim to monopoly
over postal services to foreign countries. But in 1619, a rival operator by the
The Establishment of the PIT System 15
name of de Quester, attracted by the potential profits, obtained from the King
the monopoly rights for "foreign parts," leading to protracted litigation and
intrigue. Eventually, de Quester transferred his interests to Thomas Withering,
who revolutionized English postal history in 1635 by transforming a tottering
system whose profits accrued to licensed private operators into a rich source of
revenue for the state (Clear, 1940, pp. 21-32). Withering, supported by Charles
Fs royal proclamation, brought remarkable operational planning to his postal
reorganization, which endured for more than two centuries. Withering spear-
headed a postal reform that regularized and speeded up service considerably,
to up to 120 miles in twenty-four hours. In the process of reform, however,
Withering made enemies: Within two years he was dismissed and replaced by
the two powerful secretaries of state, Lords Coke and Windebank (unlike With-
ering members of the High Nobility) and by a wealthy creditor to the king.
Petitions by the London merchants to retain Withering's control were to no
avail.
Under Cromwell's Commonwealth, the farming out of postal routes was re-
sumed. The postmaster-generalship itself cost an annual 10,000. After the
Restoration, Lord Stanhope resurfaced with claims, but the monopoly patent
was eventually given to the Duke of York, in a grant estimated by Parliament
as worth 21,500 per year. Another 5000 of postal income was assigned by
the king to his mistresses and favorites. Slowly, postal service improved with
political stability. But the Royal Post still operated primarily on a handful of
great roads emanating from London. "Cross-and-bye" posts linking provincial
towns were rare, and neither urban nor rural service was provided. These could
be offered by private "common carriers." Disputes between the official and
private posts led to physical casualties and forced the government service to
cut its rates substantially.
In 1680, a London entrepreneur, William Dockwa, set up a remarkable pri-
vate urban mail system, the London Penny Post, which created at once a level
of service unsurpassed ever since: hourly collection at 179 postal points, four
daily deliveries for residences, and six to eight for business centers. The charge
per letter and parcel was a uniform 1 penny for up to 1 pound. Postage was
payable in advance and was credited by stamping the letters, a novelty. Dock-
wa's venture required a risky initial investment of 10,000; but when it proved
highly profitable, the Duke of York muscled in with the help of the courts.
Dockwa was pushed aside, and compensated with a minor pension, while a
multitude of courtiers with no connection to the postal system drew large rev-
enues. The Duchess of Cleveland, for example, was given 4700 a year. In
contrast, the universities of Edinburgh and Glasgow received a meager subsidy
of 210 each from the postal revenue. The lease of postal offices generated
crown income of 65,000 in 1685. In 1650, when a London municipal postal
service was proposed whose profits would benefit the poor, Parliament sup-
pressed it.
More fortunate than Dockwa was another private businessman, Ralph Allen,
who obtained permission in 1721 to serve the cross-and-bye posts linking pro-
vincial towns in return for 6000. After two years of heavy losses, the service
16 The Establishment of the PIT System
Figure 2.2. Revenues, Expenditures, and Profits of the Post Office in Great Brit-
ain. (Source; Hemmeon, 1912, pp. 245, 247, 252.)
turned very profitable. (Allen died with an estate reportedly worth 500,000.)
After 1765, major road improvements were undertaken, which led to the estab-
lishment of stage coach service by private operators who soon undercut the
official postmasters by also carrying mail. The Royal Post set up its own rival
"mail coaches" in 1784.
Postal service was highly profitable, as Figure 2.2 illustrates. Until the mid-
nineteeth century, for each pound of expense there were more than one or even
two pounds in pure profits. Nevertheless, the appetite of the exchequer for
more revenues was unlimited; the urban Penny Post became the Two-Penny
Post in 1801, and soon thereafter the Three-Penny Post. Interurban and inter-
national rates were similarly increased. Part of the reason for the rate increases
was the need to finance the Napoleonic Wars. Another significant reason was
the need to cover the increasingly costly exemptions from postagethe frank-
ing privilegeof members of Parliament, which at times degenerated into ex-
tensive rackets operated by members for their constituents and supporters. The
revenue drain was estimated at 140,000 for the year of 1763 alone. Another
major revenue loss was the virtually free mailing of newspapers.
Throughout the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, royal proclamations
reaffirmed the government's monopoly over the lucrative postal service. Their
very repetition suggests a steady challenge of the exclusivity of mail service,
particularly when it was expensive and unreliable. Many of the private common
carriers conveyed some letters over the official routes, and government regula-
tions were enacted literally to slow them down. Later, the 1855 Annual Report
The Establishment of the PIT System 17
of the British Postmaster General argued forthrightly: ' 'The object of the Crown
in establishing this letter post was probably quite as much the formation of a
profitable monopoly as the accommodation of the public" (Stephan, 1859).
The system became intolerable for a country in the midst of the industrial rev-
olution. In its late stages, the monopoly was widely evaded. Private parcels
crammed with letters were sent by coach to the major cities for redistribution
and delivery. Stagecoach guards traveled with pockets full of letters which they
posted in their city of destination (Edwards, 1879, p. 87). In one location,
calculations showed that only one letter in fifty went through the official post
office. One witness freely admitted violating the postal monopoly about 20,000
times and being caught only once. The postmaster of Manchester testified that
probably half of all letters between Liverpool and Manchester were transported
illegally. Another witness estimated that more than five-sixths of all letters
between London and Manchester bypassed the postal service.
Thus, postal reform was not only proposed to aid commerce, but also to
reduce the role of private services.
In 1840, the postal service underwent major change. Sir Rowland Hill, a
noted reformer of taxation and education, though no postal expert, issued a
private report in 1837 advocating that postal service be a tool for promoting
economic activity rather than an instrument of revenue generation (Hill and
Hill, 1880; Smyth, 1907). The key to reform was a significant reduction of the
postal rate for a regular letter to a distance-insensitive penny, creating the fa-
mous "penny post." Another feature was the use of postage stamps for pre-
payment of charges. Th'ese measures radically reduced the cost of handling a
letter. Before the postal reform, the tariffs for a regular letter were, for ex-
ample, 4 pennies for distances up to 15 miles or 9 pennies for a destination
between 18 and 120 miles away. Hill expected traffic volume to increase and
eventually offset the revenue lost due to rate reduction. In the first year after
reform, traffic volume more than doubled, and the number of routes increased.
Postal revenues dropped, however, from 12.4 to 11.4 million. It took ten
years for the old revenue level to be regained, and almost twenty years to reach
the former profit level. When the post office showed a 7 million deficit, the
Whig government, which had instituted the "supply-side" reform as a measure
of its initiative to liberalize trade, was compelled to resign from office. The
reform, nevertheless, greatly improved postal service in Britain. It also secured
the previously discredited state monopoly system by making it uneconomical
and illegal to compete against the low penny rate.
The telegraph was introduced into the United Kingdom almost at the same time
as the postal monopoly was made secure. Edward Cooke and Charles Wheat-
stone filed for a patent in 1837, four months before Samuel Morse registered
his own system in the United States. In contrast to Morse's system of dots and
dashesan early variant of digital transmissionthe British telegraph relied on
18 The Establishment of the PIT System
threatened to make the government policy toward the telegraph look even worse
than it already did.
In 1850, a submarine telegraph cable was laid from England to France, but
it failed after a short time. A transatlantic cable project was started by the
Atlantic Telegraph company but was soon abandoned. In 1858, another trans-
atlantic cable between the United States and Britain resulted in exchanges of
messages between Queen Victoria and U.S. President Buchanan, but the cable
broke down almost immediately and could not be revived. Eventually, another
cable provided more durable service.
The establishment of a British telephone monopoly was also anything but nat-
ural. When the telephone arrived in Britain, its spread was slow compared to
the United States and several continental European countries. This was not due
to a lack of public attention to the new technology; indeed, from the beginning
the telephone created a sensation. Alexander Graham Bell gave demonstrations
to audiences that overflowed into the streets, and he was received by Queen
Victoria for a private showing. Government users, however, were conservative
in adopting the new medium. The chief constable of Exeter, for example, did
not seek to have an office telephone installed until 1901 (Perry, 1977, pp. 69-
96). The advent of the telephone was not enthusiastically received by the Post
Office, which had only recently taken over the telegraph. Its chief civil servant
questioned the practicality of the new instrument. In 1878, the postmaster gen-
eral, Lord John Manners, declared that there were no plans for the Post Office
to use telephones as a supporting part of telegraphy.
Since the telephone was regarded a luxury, its development received no priority.
And indeed, the telephone was expensive. Limited local service cost three times
as much as employing a maid or messenger boy. It could pay for a household's
annual expenses for coal, firewood, and electricity. When in 1902 the London
County Council protested against high telephone rates, The Times editorialized,
"When all is said and done the telephone is not an affair of the millions. It is
a convenience for the well-to-do and a trade appliance for persons who can
very well afford to pay for it" (Perry, 1977, p. 75).
The growth of the telephone industry was further affected by patent disputes.
Both Bell and Edison had received British telephone patents and were soon
involved in litigation (Meyer, 1907). Both companies offered the patent rights
to the Post Office, but negotiations failed. The parties then jointly formed the
United Telephone Company in 1880. In the meantime, the government tried to
include authority over the telephone in a pending telegraph bill. This proved
unsuccessful in Parliament, but a court of law soon held that the original 1869
Telegraph Act encompassed telephones.
The postmaster general then offered to license the United Telephone Com-
pany if it waived its right to appeal the court decision; a royalty payment of 10
20 The Establishment of the PIT System
percent was required. The Post Office concession did not include the power to
erect poles or use public rights-of-way. For this it was necessary to obtain the
local authority's or private property holder's permission. The concession was
not exclusive, and additional licenses could be granted to other companies as
well as to the Post Office itself. Furthermore, the provision of long distance
telephone communications was severely restricted in order to protect the gov-
ernment's investment in the telegraph system. For the same reasons, public pay
telephones were precluded in most instances. When a local company in Man-
chester wanted to provide public pay telephones at 2 cents per conversation, it
was required to charge 24 cents, the equivalent of the charge for a twenty-word
local telegram.
Similar protectionist restrictions were put on messenger services' use of the
telephone. In 1891, messenger companies were forced to be licensed under the
following conditions: that they not use the telephone, that they pay a minimum
license fee per year, that they affix a 2-cent stamp on every letter delivered by
messenger, and that no messenger take more than six letters at a time from one
center. Moreover, messenger companies were prohibited from using a messen-
ger call box with telephone attachment, an American invention that could sum-
mon a messenger.
United Telephone applied for and received a license for London. For other
areas, it set up regional firms that it provided with patent rights in return for
equity. These subsidiaries then applied for Post Office operating licenses.
In 1882, when a competitor to the United Telephone Company applied for a
license, the application was granted by postmaster general Henry Fawcett, one
of the leading economists of the time. Fawcett favored competition and free
trade between private firms and between the private firms and the government.
He opposed nationalization and abolished restrictions such as size limitations
of exchange areas; he also permitted the company to engage in some long
distance transmission.
In 1884, the Post Office began to install telephone exchanges itself, despite
the opposition of the Treasury, which did not want the government to engage
in competition against private firms. The Post Office also eliminated the pro-
hibition of private interurban trunk lines, and interconnected several local ex-
changes. With a growing national network, the United Telephone Company
began a consolidation, eventually absorbing twelve subsidiaries into the Na-
tional Telephone Company (NTC).
By 1892, telephones were installed in about 400 cities by the NTC. The
company suffered, however, from problems in acquiring way-leaves (rights-of-
way). Finally, in 1892, partly in response to pressure from the newspaper pub-
lishers, the government improved the company's rights-of-way situation by a
quid pro quo that sought to protect the ailing long-distance telegraph service,
which could barely cover costs after Parliament had reduced its charges by half.
In return for the NTC's right to acquire rights-of-way, the Post Office sought
full control of long-distance telephone service. Under pressure and dependent
on the government (the telephone company's long-distance lines were strung
The Establishment of the PIT System 21
along government railroad tracks), the company sold its trunk lines to the Post
Office in 1896.
However, the agreement required the company to obtain the consent of the
local authority for each right-of-way. This turned out to be an insoluble prob-
lem and made the agreement virtually useless. The slow expansion of the
national trunk system created another bottleneck. The Post Office and the Trea-
sury were apprehensive about incurring financial obligations. Trunks were laid
only if local authorities guaranteed adequate revenues for the construction and
maintenance of the new line. The company was forced in many instances to
issue that guarantee.
Local authorities demanded approval rights for telephone service partly to
obtain financial payments. Many cities refused to give rights-of-way, because
some wished to operate a municipal telephone service themselves. Circuitous
routings became necessary, and there was no access to certain areas. For ex-
ample, in 1885 the NTC was unable to reach the Middle and Inner Temple
areas in London in which most barristers had their offices. The arrangement
also delayed the introduction of so-called metallic circuits which were of sub-
stantially higher quality than single-wire circuits, and of underground cables.
The situation was further complicated by the emergence of the Duke of Marl-
borough as a promoter of a rival venture, the New Telephone Company. Founded
in 1884, it had obtained a Post Office license but was not actually operating.
In 1891, the Duke began to campaign for his company with several letters to
the Times, in which he offered to provide London subscribers with metallic-
circuit telephone service for a flat rate of 12 guineas for an unlimited number
of calls, a rate much lower than the existing one. In 1892, stock for the New
Telephone Company was offered to the public at a fairly high price. The Na-
tional Telephone Company bought one-third to keep leverage over the potential
rival. But when the time came to make the promises real, the Duke published
yet another letter in the Times, this time repudiating the possibility of low-cost,
high-quality telephone service. Referring to himself as having "bleated a good
deal" about the lower-priced telephone (Meyer, 1907, p. 102), he vaguely
referred to future efficiencies that would establish the conditions he had de-
scribed in promoting his venture. The remainder of the New Telephone Com-
pany's shares were subsequently acquired by the National Telephone Company
for $2.2 million although actual property value was estimated at $1 million or
less.
Beyond the blue-sky aspects of these securities transactions, some of their
long-run effects were to unreasonably raise expectations. Public opinion, once
made to believe in cheap flat rate service, saw higher rates as an expression of
private monopoly power. The tide began to shift toward the advocates of na-
tionalization.
The House of Commons appointed a select committee in 1895 to report on
the feasibility of municipal telephone service. The government's own attitude
ran at first from lukewarm to negative. The postmaster general, Arnold Morley,
declared in a parliamentary debate in 1895 that telephony was not a specific
22 The Establishment of the PIT System
26
Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly 27
the Supreme Regulator: "And the Lord spake unto Moses, saying . . . You
shall also make it a grating, a network of brass . . ." (Exodus XXVII, 4). In
the original Hebrew, the word is reshet (net), similarly used today for telecom-
munications and other networks.
The term is used by most academic disciplines, and with a variety of mean-
ings. Chemists apply it to arrangements of molecules (Zacharisen, 1932, pp.
38-42); biologists, to cell structures (Knox, 1830, p. 214); mathematicians, to
topology (Klingman and Mulvey, 1981); electrical engineers, to distribution
systems (for high voltage), or for circuit configurations of components (for
weak voltage) (Kami, 1986, pp. 1-4).
Operations researchers use a network terminology to solve shortest-path
problems, maximum-flow models, and optimal routing (Elmaghraby, 1970, pp.
1-3). Computer scientists apply the term for computer interconnections in
hardware and to implementation algorithms in software.
In the social sciences, political scientists use the concept of networks in
discussing hierarchies, interactions, gatekeepers, and policy communities
(Richardson et al., 1985, pp. 6-8). For sociologists and social anthropologists,
networks are a major way to see the world; a basic point is that the nature of
linkage affects behavior (Barnes, 1954; Bott, 1971; Boissevain, 1979). Soci-
ologists speak of network dyadsinterpersonal linkage between two persons in
which each is indebted to the other, similar in some ways to the exchange
relation of economics.
Among the social science disciplines, economists have probably paid less
attention to networks. There is no body of analysis for the network concept.
Somewhat related is work on market structure by some industrial organization
theorists (Baumol et al., 1982). Closer are public choice theories of group
formation, discussed in the following section. Other writings on networks are
by Noam (1988), Heal (1989), and Economides (1989).
Corresponding to different disciplines' use of the network concept, econo-
mists also approach concrete applications differently. Thus, when it comes to
telecommunications networks and network policy, several ways of thinking can
be distinguished. They are the golden calves worshipped by different profes-
sional denominations.
For technologists a primary organizing concept is economies of scale and
their first cousin, standardization. Economists, on the other hand, worship at
the altar of competition, mostly to the trinity of structure, conduct, and perfor-
mance. The increasing disenchantment with this view is represented more in
academia than in the regulatory environment.
Lawyers in this field often judge policy issues in terms of conflict of interest,
which translates here to potential for cross-subsidies. This perspective is partic-
ularly developed in the United States (hence, the AT&T divestiture).
Finally, many other social scientists as well as most politicians and journal-
ists organize reality in telecommunications policy around the concept of income
distribution (i.e., around the question of who pays and who receives and of
what factors of political power lead to such distribution).
All these concepts are legitimate but have been carried by their proponents
28 Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
Technological Explanations
The technological perspective comes in two variants:
Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly 29
Political Explanations
There are three related political explanations, all using the perspective of coun-
tervailing powers:
3. "In the information age, a telecommunications monopoly becomes too
powerful and its scope needs to be limited."
4. "Government regulation proves incapable of controlling a monopoly and
is therefore replaced by policies encouraging a competitive industry struc-
ture."
5. "Large business users successfully fight the monopolistic restrictions."
The problem with these views is that the introduction of a multiplicity of
carriers is only one policy option out of several. An alternative response to
political power or regulatory inefficiency might well be a stricter or more ef-
fective regulation, as would be nationalization or a size reduction along geo-
graphical and/or functional lines while maintaining monopoly. Thus, it is not
clear why competition is the necessary remedy to monopoly power.
Nonsustainability Explanations
Another view is that a monopoly, even if efficient across its multiple products,
cannot protect itself from entry into some lines of business:
6. "The diversification of telecommunications makes it difficult for any one
provider to serve all submarkets without competitive entry."
This view is essentially that of an economic nonsustainability theory ad-
vanced by Baumol et al. (1982), applied to telecommunications (Woroch, 1990).
It can explain the emergence of entrants for new products of a multiproduct
firm, but it does not adequately cover competition in traditional core markets
of a telecommunications monopolist, unless one accepts very restrictive as-
sumptions (Shepherd, 1983).
30 Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
This view of success undermining its own foundations is, from the monop-
oly's perspective, deeply pessimistic, because it implies that the harder
their efforts and the greater their success, the closer is the end to their special
status. As in a Greek tragedy, their preventive actions only assure their
doom.
A Model of Networks4
It may be useful to ask why there is usually only one public telephone network
in a country. It is not for the interconnectedness of all participants, since this
justification would lead one to have only one large bank for all financial trans-
actions. Interaction does not usually require institutional integration. This was
Adam Smith's major insight. To distinguish telecommunications from this ob-
servation by labeling it infrastructure requires us to define that term in a way
that is not vacuous or circuitous, an almost impossible task.
Another explanation is "natural monopoly." Although such a monopoly may
exist for a local exchange area, the examples of the United States, Canada,
Denmark, and Finland prove that a widespread horizontal integration of local
exchange areas is not required. Even if it were, one must ask, why these econ-
omies end miraculously at the national frontier. Has there ever been a national
monopolist that asked a larger neighbor to take over its system in order to reap
the benefit of economies of scale? Moreover, it has not been established that
an integration of local and long-distance service is based on economies of scale.
These services are institutionally separated in several countries.
Perhaps the best way to look at a network is as a cost-sharing arrangement
between several users. Fixed costs are high, marginal costs low, and a new
participant, C, helps incumbents A and B to lower their cost. In this respect a
network is similar to a "public good," such as a swimming pool or national
defense. But although there is basically only one national defense system, there
are many types of arrangements for swimming pools. A user may want to share
the pool with a few dozen families, but not with thousands. A pure public good
admits everyone, a pure private good admits only one. But there is a wide
spectrum between the pure private good and the pure public good (Buchanan,
1965). A telecommunications network is one intermediate example. It is not a
private good yet it does not meet the two main conditions for a public good:
nonrival consumptions and nonexcludability. In fact, nonexcludability has to
be established as a legal requirementthe universal service obligation. What
has been happening in recent years to telecommunications, and what goes by
the more dramatic labels of divestiture and deregulation, is largely a shift in
the degree of its intermediate position, a shift toward the direction of private
good.
We shall now develop, in a stepwise fashion, a model for network evolution
and diversification to explain the breakdown of the network monopoly.
32 Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
Let the total cost of a TC network be given by a cost function that depends on
the number of subscribers.6
(1)
Let an individual's utility be given by a function u(P, n), where P is the price
for network usage and n is the number of network members.7 We assume that
the more members there are on the network, the better it will be for an individ-
ual subscriber, other things remaining equal (including network performance
and price),8 that is, we assume that network externalities exist. This means that
(8u/dn > 0), though at a declining rate (82u/8n2 < 0).
We assume that the network membership is priced at average cost (i.e., that
users share costs equally). Then price P is also a function of n: P = P(n).
(This assumption will be dropped later.9)
These relations can be shown schematically in Figure 3.1, where u(ri), the
benefit of participation in a network, is steadily increasing with network size,
though at a declining rate. The price of participating in the network
Critical Mass
Subscribers will find it attractive to join a good-sized network, because total
costs are shared by many, making average costs low, while the number of
Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly 33
subscribers n adds to utility. This can be seen in Figure 3.1, where the utility
of joining a network rises at first. Conversely, where the network is small, the
average cost is high, and externalities are small. In that range, below a "critical
mass" point HI, a network will not be feasible, unless it is supported by exter-
nal sources. We define critical mass as the smallest number of users such that
a user is as well off as a nonuser u(n) = P(n).I0
To reach n\ requires a subsidy of sorts, either by government or by the
network operator's willingness to accept losses in the early growth phases of
operations. The strategic problem is to identify in advance a situation in which
such a break-even point n\ will be reached within the range n < N, where N
= total population. Such a point may not exist, and subsidies would have to
be permanent to keep the network from imploding. We shall return to the crit-
ical mass issue later in the section entitled "Subsidies for Reaching Critical
Mass."
Private Optimum
Through the cost-sharing phases of network growth, the earlier network users
can lower their cost by adding members. However, at some point average cost
AC increases in the range beyond the point n0 where AC = f(n).
Beyond n0, expansion becomes unattractive for the members of the network
for cost reasons because (for example) they are in more remote locations with
lesser population density, and thus are more costly to serve. But some further
expansion would be accepted by the network members, since newcomers be-
yond the low-cost point would still add to utility. This will be up to the point
2 where the total derivative with respect to the number of users is equal to
zero.
(2)
(3)
The optimal point lies in the range of increasing AC. Graphically, n2 would lie
where the two derivatives are of equal size, u'(P) = '() Left to themselves,
the existing subscribers of the network would not accept members beyond n2,
the private optimum. From size 0 to size n2. the network is in its cost-sharing
stage.
Social Optimum
From a societal point of view, however, the optimal network size in an equal-
price system may diverge from the private optimum.
Assume social welfare given by the sums of utilities.
34 Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
(4)
so that its derivative
(5)
(6)
Since u(n) > C(n)ln below the point of intersection n 4 , social optimum 3 is
greater than private optimum n 2 . (It should be noted that the same size will be
chosen by an unconstrained monopolist that sets the price at P = u(n^) to
exhaust consumer surplus.)
What is the implication? Left to itself, the network will cease growth beyond
2. at least as long as costs are equally shared. Existing network subscribers
would not want to admit newcomers beyond 2 - Latecomers beyond that point
add cost, because they raise AC and add fewer externality benefits. [In reality,
of course, networks are "public" and not able to reject members (B. Green-
wald, 1990, communication).] The socially optimal size 3 will not be reached
by itself, but requires some external direction (e.g., governmentally mandated
expansion and/or a differentiated pricing scheme) or some internal politics of
expansion, which will be described later.
(7)
This exit point may lie beyond the total population, 4 > N. But this seems
unlikely under an average-pricing scheme, because the last subscribers may
impose a heavy burden on the rest of subscribers, and the subsequent departure
of some subscribers would lead to further reduction in the utility of the remain-
ing members and may induce a secondary exodus. Thus, assuming n^ < N, a
government's aim to establish a truly universal service, without resorting to a
subsidy mechanism or price discrimination, is likely to be infeasible. In other
words, a universal service policy is likely to depend on a redistributive policy.
In the range of size 2 to 4, the network is in its second phase, the redistri-
butive stage.
dynamics of network members will take the network toward universal service
and toward its own disintegration.
As has been shown, a network will cease to grow on its own after private
optimum n2. But this conclusion was based on a pricing scheme of equal-cost
shares. Yet there is no reason for such equal-cost shares to persist if they are
allocated through a decision mechanism that permits the majority of network
users to impose higher-cost shares on the minority. (This assumes that no ar-
bitrage is possible.) Unequal prices and a departure from cost could be ration-
alized benignly as merely "value-of-service" pricing (i.e., higher prices for
the users who value the telephone greatly).
Suppose for purposes of the model that decisions are made through voting
by all network members." Let us assume at this stage that all users are of
equal size (or that voting takes place according to the number of lines a sub-
scriber uses, which in terms of the model is the same thing) and that early
network users have lower demand elasticity for network use. The determinative
vote is provided by the median voter located at n/2. A majority would not wish
to have its benefits diluted by a number of beneficiaries larger than necessary.
This is the principle of the "minimal winning coalition." Its size would be
n/2 + 1.
A majority will establish itself such that it will benefit maximally from the
minority. The minority that can be maximally burdened are the users with less
elastic demand for telephone service, which are the early subscribers. But there
is a limit to the burden, given by utility curve u(ri). If price gets pushed above
u(n), subscribers will drop off. Hence, the majority (2/2 + 1) will burden the
minority (n2/2 1) with a price up to positive utility, and they will bear the rest
of the cost. The minority's price P\ will be such that
(8)
12
The majority's price will then be
(9)
those beyond network size n-i who desire telephone service but were previously
excluded.
This exit would deprive the majority of the source of its subsidy and is
therefore held undesirable. The only way for the majority to prevent this "cream
skimming" or "cherry picking" is to prohibit the establishment of another
network, both by those wanting to leave the original network and by those not
admitted to it in the first place because they are beyond 2 - Thus, a monopoly
system and the prevention of arbitrage become essential to the stability of such
a network system.
At the same time, the model predicts that the network will expand beyond
2. For the majority, there is added utility from added network members, while
most of its cost is borne by the minority, who are also willing to bear a greater
burden as the network expands due to its greater utility. The majority will
therefore seek expansion beyond 2- The cost to the majority is only that the
subsidy by the minority must be shared with more network participants. There-
fore, the majority would admit new members up to the point ns where marginal
utility to its members is equal to the marginal price increase due to the diluted
subsidy.
But this is not the end of the story. With expansion to 5. the majority is
now 5/2 rather than n2/2 (i.e., larger than before), and it can tax a larger
minority (s/2) than before. Hence, the expansion process would take place
again, leading to a point 's > ns. This process would continue until an equi-
librium is reached.
n*5 is the point up to which the network will grow under the internal dynam-
ics described earlier. The greater the marginal utility from added network mem-
bers, and the smaller the marginal costs, and the greater the fixed costs are, the
larger n*5 will be.13
Network Tipping
As this process of expansion takes place, the minority is growing too. The
likelihood that its size will increase beyond the point of critical mass n\ is
increased, and the utility of its members, given the burden of subsidy, may
well be below that of membership in a smaller but nonsubsidizing alternative
network. We have so far assumed that there is only one network and that a
user's choice is whether to join or not. Suppose there are no legal barriers to
the formation of a new network. In that case, a user's choice menu is to stay,
to drop off altogether, or to join a new network association. Assume that the
new network has the same cost characteristics as the traditional network. (In
fact, it may well have a lower cost function for each given size if there has
been accumulated monopolistic inefficiency in the existing network and rent-
seeking behavior by various associated groups.) Then minority coalition mem-
bers would find themselves better off in a new network B, and they would
consider such a network, abandoning the old one. The only problem is that of
transition discontinuity. A new network, in its early phases, would be a money-
losing proposition up to its critical mass point n ' i . 1 5
38 Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
The point where exit becomes possible, given the redistributory burden that
keeps utility just balanced with price, is the point n beyond where
(10)
which is at the critical mass point. Hence, the minority will strive to exit the re-
distributory network once its size is more than twice the size of critical mass.16
The majority may attempt to alleviate these pressures to exit by reducing the
redistributory burden and thus keeping the minority from dropping out. But
that means the network size 7 would not be optimal to the majority anymore,
and members would have to be forced out. And this, in turn, would reduce its
majority, so that it would have to drop the subsidizing burden from at least
some minority members as the n/2 point separating the majority from the mi-
nority shifts to the left.
This means either higher burdens on the shrinking minority frustrating the
purpose of bribing it into stayingor still less benefits for the majority if it
wants to keep the network from fragmenting. Such a disequilibrium process
will continue up to the point where network size n = 2 n\ (i.e., where the
minority may be too small to create a self-supporting new network). One might
call this the effect of potential exit by the minority, and it results in a lessened
redistribution of newcomers to the network in order to keep the first entrants
inside.
It might be argued that in a new network, internal redistribution based on
coalitions might exist. But this is not likely. Once the possibility of exit is
established, each burdened subgroup can simply join another network. Thus,
internal redistribution will happen only if a network is unique, and thus if a
burdened user will not readily switch into another network.
the median voter whose preferences govern is at a network size greater than
the median point of the network size. The more the distribution of lines is
skewed (the larger the coefficients A and a) the further to the right is ,. And
the more skewed the distribution, the more likely it is that the voting minority
will reach by itself a size beyond the critical mass point.
Interconnection
The process of unraveling of the existing network would commence even ear-
lier if a new network has the right to interconnect into the previous one, be-
cause in that case it would enjoy the externality benefits of a larger reach nA
+ nB, while not being subject to redistributory burden. This is why intercon-
nectivity is a critical issue for the establishment of alternative networks, as the
historical U.S. examples demonstrate, from the Kingsbury Commitment in 1913
to MCI Execunet in 1976 and today's ONA and collocation proceedings.
Since the benefits of network reach remain, a subscriber's exit decision is
cost-driven, and takes place if C(nB)lng < c(n)ln. With redistribution under the
primary network, but not in the new network B, the test would be, for a sub-
scriber /', if c(nB)/ns < PI (n).
Would there exist, for any subnetwork, internal redistribution based on coa-
litions? Once the possibility of exit is established, each burdened subgroup
could join another network. Thus, internal redistribution will happen only if a
network is unique to its users.
Network interconnection means that the network still centers around a soci-
ety-wide concept of interconnected users. But it consists now of multiple sub-
networks that are linked to each other. Each of these subnetworks has its own
cost-sharing arrangements, with some mutual interconnection charges. Inter-
connection facilitates the emergence of new networks and lowers entry barriers.
But given entry, it may reduce competition by establishing cooperative linkages
instead of end-to-end rivalry (Mueller, 1988). Interconnection is a useful con-
cept, because it responds to the frequent claim that a single network is neces-
sary for universal reach. This assertion is clearly incorrect. Interaction does not
usually require institutional integrations. Otherwise, we would have only one
large bank for all financial transactions, as mentioned. But as the next section
will show, it may also lead to market failure in the establishment of the original
network.
We have mentioned that waiting for demand to materialize prior to the intro-
duction of a network or network service may not be the optimal private or
public network policy. Demand is a function of price and benefits, both of
which are in turn functions of the size of the network. Hence, early develop-
ment of a network may require internal or external support to reach critical
mass.
40 Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
This suggests the need, in some circumstances, to subsidize the early stages
of the networkup to the critical mass point n\when the user externalities
are still low but cost shares are high. These subsidies could come either from
the network provider or its membership as a start-up investment, or from an
external source (e.g., a government) as an investment in "infrastructure," a
concept centered around externalities. The question is how the internal support
is affected by the emergence of a system of multiple networks.
The private start-up investment in a new form of network is predicated on
an expectation of eventual break-even and subsequent positive net benefits to
members. But if one can expect the establishment of additional networks, which
would keep network size close to n\, there would be only small (or no) net
benefits realized by the initial entrants to offset their earlier investment. This
would be further aggravated by interconnection rights, because a new network
could make immediate use of the positive network externalities of the member-
ship of the existing network that were achieved by the latter's investment. Hence,
it is less likely that the initial risk would be undertaken if a loss were borne
entirely by the initial network participants while the benefits would be shared
with other entrants who would be able to interconnect and thus immediately
gain the externality benefits of the existing network users, but without con-
tributing to their cost sharing. The implication is that in an environment of
multiple networks that can interconnect, less start-up investment would be un-
dertaken. It pays to be second. A situation of market failure exists.
How could one offset this tendency if it is deemed undesirable? Patents are
one solution. If a contemplated new network arrangement is technologically
innovative, it might obtain a patent protection for some period. Where a service
is innovative but not patentable, one might create a "regulatory patent" for a
limited period of protection, or the initial approval (where necessary) might be
accelerated. Similarly, interconnection rights might be deferred for a period, or
joint introductions might be planned that eliminate the first entrant penalty. But
these measures would also reduce the usefulness of alternative networks and
hence could lead to the dynamics of political expansion, redistribution, and
break-up described earlier. Another approach is to require access charges that
cover the externality benefits for interconnection. But this requires market power,
since otherwise no price above cost could be sustained. And if that market
power exists, it could be exercised in a restrictive fashion.
It is quite possible that none of these measures would be as effective in
generating the investment support as a monopoly network that can reap all
future benefits. This would mean that the private and social benefits of net-
works in the range between n\ and 4 would not be realized. In such a situa-
tion, there may be a role for direct outside support, such as by a government
subsidy. At first, this may seem paradoxical. One would expect a competitive
system of multiple networks to be less in need of government involvement than
a monopoly. But there is some economic logic to this. Just as the subsidies to
individual network users that were previously internally generated by other net-
work users would have to be raised externally (through the normal mechanism
of taxation and allocation) if at least some users are still to be supported, so
Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly 41
Conclusion
The theoretically based analysis of the model means that a network coalition,
left to itself under majority-rule principles, expands beyond a size that would
hold together. Such an arrangement is therefore inherently unstable. It can stay
42 Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
These trends have a logical progression. At first the network expands be-
cause it makes economic and technical sense. Later it expands because it makes
political sense. But as the network provider succeeds in providing full service
to every household, it also undermines the foundation of its exclusivity.
Most countries in the world are still in the phases of the cost-sharing or
redistributory networks. In Europe, first stage countries are Portugal, Turkey,
Greece, and the nations of Eastern Europe. All others have reached substantial
universal penetration of telecommunications for a number of years, and it is
here that the transformation of the network system has begun progressing toward
its third stage, which the United States entered first, followed by Japan. Since
there is a strong correlation of economic growth and telephone penetration
(roughly an additional telephone per $50,000 GNP), countries with high eco-
nomic growth are likely to progress rapidly through the first two stages. Even-
tually, through economic growth and the instabilities transmitted from the more
advanced nations, many other countries will move into a pluralistic network
environment and will be faced with the policy issues inherent in such a system.
43
44 Forces of Centrifugalism
We have seen how the centralized and hierarchical system of the traditional
network, despite its public popularity, has been subject to forces of centrifu-
galism that have undermined its stability. The present chapter looks at the con-
tributing factors that make this breakup more likely. Technology is one such
factor, though one should not exaggerate its contributions. It is not microwave
and satellite transmission that has made long-distance telephone competition
possible. Several other factors have contributed to the disintegration of the cen-
tralized monopoly.
The driving force for the restructuring of telecommunications has been the phe-
nomenal growth in user demand for telecommunications, a force that in turn is
based on the shift toward a service-based economy. The largest users of tele-
communications are major providers of services; they include corporate head-
quarters, banks, insurance firms, airlines, health delivery organizations, engi-
neering and consulting firms, law offices, and media organizations. The growth
of these service industries in highly developed countries has been due in part
to diminished competitiveness in traditional mass production, where newly in-
dustrialized countries have excelled. It was also partly due to their large pool
of educated people skilled in handling information. These advantages were
reinforced by productivity increases in information transactions through com-
puters and advanced office equipment. Information-based services, including
headquarters activities, therefore emerged as a major comparative advantage of
developed countries. Manufacturing and retailing, at the same time, became
far-flung and decentralized.
Within the service sector, the number of people performing functions related
to information and its creation, processing, and manipulation has grown partic-
ularly large. According to one study (Beniger, 1986), 37 percent of the work
force in 1980 was engaged in information jobs, 22 percent in industrial jobs, 2
percent in agriculture, and 29 percent in other services. Another study asserts
that 54 percent of the American work force and 63 percent of all working time
are now devoted to information work (Strassman, 1985, p. 56). An earlier
study found a similar trend (Porat, 1978).
As electronic information transmission (i.e., telecommunications) became in-
creasingly important to the new services sector, it turned into a major expense
item. For instance, for Citicorp, America's largest bank holding firm, telecom-
munications are the third largest cost item, after salaries and real estate. Con-
sequently, the purchase of communications capability at advantageous prices is
much more important than in the past. Price, control, security, and reliability
have become variables requiring organized attention. This, in turn, led to the
emergence of the new breed of private telecommunications managers whose
function is to reduce costs for their firms, establishing for the first time sophis-
ticated telecommunications expertise outside the postal-industrial coalition. These
managers aggressively seek low-cost transmission and customized equipment
Forces of Centrifugalism 45
systems in the form of private networks of power and scope far beyond those
of the past (Schiller, 1982). These private networks, which start out as systems
of dedicated lines leased from the monopoly network carriers, can become large
and far-flung. Some require hundreds of skilled technicians and managers to
operate and administer, and they are carving out slices from the public net-
work. It does not take a large number of private networks to have an impact.
In the United States, for example, the largest 3 percent of users typically ac-
count for 50 percent of all telephone revenues. These activities are spearheaded
by private firms but are not exclusive to them: Nonprofit institutions (e.g.,
hospitals and universities) and public organizations (e.g., state and local gov-
ernments) are actively pursuing similar cost-reduction strategies. The U.S. gov-
ernment, for example, awarded in 1989 a $25 billion contract for a "private"
network to serve its civilian activities (FTS-2000).1
The model of Chapter 3 argued that the expansion of a single network can
eventually lead to its fragmentation. What has been the path of such expansion?
For a long time the primary policy goal of most industrialized countries was to
establish a network that would reach every household; this also benefited the
supplying industry. Even in highly developed countries, the achievement of
substantial network penetration is a very recent phenomenon. In West Ger-
many, penetration in 1960 was 12 percent. In 1980, it was 75 percent (Schulte,
1982); and in 1990 it was getting close to 100 percent (Pfeiffer and Wieland,
1990). In France, it was 6 percent in 1967 (Guerard and Lafarge, 1979), 54
percent in 1983 (AT&T, 1983), and 97 percent in 1990 (Steckel and Fossier,
1990). Similar trends existed in almost all European countries. Hence, the im-
position of the costs of the last subscribers is a fairly new development, and
responses to it are only now beginning to work themselves out. In the United
States, universal service was substantially achieved some twenty-five years ear-
lier.
Once universal penetration was reached, the industry had to reorient itself,
because its activity level would otherwise have dropped dramatically.
Having been successful in spreading telephony, the supplying industry too
became a victim of its own success. It was left with several strategies:
1. Upgrade. After achieving universal penetration, the equipment industry
advocated an upgrade of the network. This means an accelerated supply
push rather than demand pull. It also means moving into videotex, inte-
grated services digital networks (ISDN), integrated broadband networks,
and cable television as ways to provide the industry with procurement
contracts.
46 Forces of Centrifugalism
tions, in three to five years fiber will be cheaper to install than copper (Elton,
1991; Egan, 1990).
In terms of the model, as the cost curve drops, the critical mass point n\
shifts to the left to a smaller minimal size, and it becomes easier to start an
alternative network. The growth of large users also means that it takes fewer
of them to reach any given network size n. This reduces transaction costs of
organizing and coordinating a new network club and makes it possible for a
smaller number of users to enjoy the economies of scale.
Over the years, low-cost subscribers have been added to the network earlier
than high-cost subscribers. As the network reaches universality, connecting the
last members increases cost. In the Bell system, the average capital investment
cost per new telephone grew steadily (in 1982-1983 dollars) (Telecom Fact-
book, 1986):
1945: $1928
1955: $2050
1965: $2580
1975: $3960
1985: $46244
Forces of Centrifugaiism 49
and powerful, and allying the public interest with that of its largest economic
organizations. The PTT system is a classic example of this approach.
But the mass production view of economic advancement needs revision. Sig-
nificant activity takes place in small and medium-sized firms, and it is difficult
to reconcile their role with the mass production theory.
One way to do so is to take note of the clustering of small firms. The ability
to provide specialized services through clusters of firms creates economies of
scale too. One need not think of the economic process as having to take place
under a single roof or ownership structure. The entrepreneurial function is to
bring together factors of production, not necessarily to own them. Thus, in
terms of neoclassical economic theory, whether the services are performed by
employees or outside contractors, by owned or leased capital is immaterial,
though Marxist economists will not agree.
Hence, the logic of continuing specialization may lead to clustering of firms.
Instead of large-scale vertical integration, a functional specialization may lead
to a disintegration of the traditional functions of a firm. Within those special-
ties, supplier firms may have horizontal economies of scale even though their
size may be moderate because of their high specialization. In the aggregate,
these firms form a production and service complex that can be large, but it is
not under one corporate control. The easy availability of telecommunications
and information technology plays a key role in this development, because it
makes decentralization possible. Telecommunications networks provide the glue
that keeps such a production system together. At the same time, this trend leads
to specialized network functionalities and equipment options, which in turn
accelerate the evolution of telecommunications into a pluralist system.
Provider Specialization
As the information flow requirements of large users become larger, they also
become increasingly specialized. Equipment offered by numerous vendors per-
mits many configurations to accommodate the requirements and procedures of
organizations. It is no longer as necessary to forgo benefits of specialization in
order to benefit from cost sharing.
By their very nature, the traditional networks provide standardized and na-
tionwide solutions, carefully planned and methodically executed. In the old
days, sharing a standardized solution was more acceptable to network mem-
bers, because the consequential loss of choice was limited and outweighed by
the benefits of the economies of scale gained. As the significance of telecom-
munications grew, the costs of nonoptimal standardized solutions began to out-
weigh the benefits of economies of scale, providing the incentive for nonpublic
solutions. Furthermore, some users aggressively employed a differentiation of
telecommunications services as a business strategy to provide an advantage in
their customers' eyes, and affirmatively sought a customized rather than a gen-
eral communications solution. Although these considerations are most impor-
Forces of Centrifugalism 51
tant for large firms, the differentiation of communications needs for small busi-
ness and residential users has been moving rapidly as well.
The desirability of opting out of the traditional sharing arrangement depends,
among other things, on traffic densities. Where these are high, private networks
of different types emerge, depending on the degree of traffic specialization. For
high-density general-purpose use, private networks emerge, but for low-density
general purpose use the shared public network may last longest. For interme-
diate density, "virtual private networks" provide an intermediate option. For
specialized services, the network types to emerge, depending on traffic densi-
ties, are strategic private networks, closed-use group networks, and value-added
networks. These classifications5 can be charted as follows:
Network Specialization
Traffic
Density General Specialized
Dense Private networks Strategic private
networks
Intermediate Virtual private Closed-use group
networks networks
Low-density Public networks Value-added net-
works
As traffic densities and usage specialization grow, the core of the traditional
public network (the lower left corner) shrinks.
Telephony has gone far beyond simple switched voice connections. Many
"value-added services" have been developed and introduced, including voice
mail, videotex and audiotex, and electronic message interchanges. Concep-
tually, most advanced telecommunications services can be analyzed as four
layers superimposed on each other: basic transmission, data packet transmis-
sion, generic services, and applications packages. Although in many instances
several of these layers can be integrated within the same carrier, they need not
be. Thus, when a bank customer uses an automatic teller machine, several
functionally different service providers may be involved on the same layer, and
several other firms may provide communications on different geographical seg-
ments. The underlying banking transaction, in turn, may trigger interbank elec-
tronic transfer networks of similar complexity. Such structure calls for special-
ized service providers and packagers. This will be described in greater detail
in the chapter on value-added services.
The attractiveness of global transactions has increased as cost has become less
sensitive to distance (Pool, 1990). For satellite transmission, in particular, the
marginal cost with respect to distance is virtually nil. Fiber-optic links have
also lowered distance-sensitive costs. As a result, communication flows can be
routed indirectly to circumvent regulatory barriers and restrictive prices. This
will be discussed in Chapter 32.
If a country's PTT exercises restrictive policies, its firms will be disadvan-
taged internationally, and foreign firms may choose not to domicile themselves
in the country. Similarly, companies in countries with those restricted policies
may pressure for change when they learn about options available elsewhere.
The challenge to the monopoly is that once it is breached by one country,
the change may become irreparable. If the United Kingdom, with its liberali-
zation policy, or one of the smaller European countries finds it profitable to
change its policies and become a communications "haven," it becomes diffi-
cult to contain the dynamics. There are strong incentives for arbitrage if a
carrier tries to charge above cost. This will be discussed in Chapter 40.
Merging of Technologies
Regional Collaboration
of their civil service benefits at the same time. As its constituent parts began
to redefine their interests, the PTT's traditional coalition weakened.
This chapter has described the centrifugal forces which have led, after a long
period of stability, to changes in Europe. The policy options will be the subject
of the next chapter.
5
Defense of the Telecommunications
Monopoly
55
56 Defense of the Telecommunications Monopoly
railroads. Nor is there any reason for the source of a subsidy to be the telecom-
munications system itself. It can be provided from general revenues and raised
through general and progressive taxation.
The usual response to these points is that they are politically unrealistic.
Advocates of the monopoly argue that the political system would not permit
massive cross-subsidies if they were transparent to the government and the
legislature of a country. This is probably true in Europe, as it is in the United
States. But the argument is at heart antidemocratic. If European governments
and legislatures, faced with a transparent choice, choose to cut back some sub-
sidies in favor of other social goals, they merely exercise their role of setting
priorities for public expenditures. (In the author's view, some such subsidies
can be justified; he drafted New York State's lifeline program, entitling 1.5
million poor households to telephone service at $1 per month. See, addition-
ally, the arguments for a critical mass subsidy to initiate a service, provided in
Chapter 3.)
The cross-subsidy rationale is normally used in support of basic services for
disadvantaged categories of users or areas. But similar arguments have also
been advanced to support new and advanced services such as data transmission
and value-added services, with the claim that new technological services gen-
erally lose money initially, and their introduction therefore necessitates some
form of critical mass subsidy. But this argument can easily become circular. A
government monopoly is defended on the grounds that it is necessary to en-
courage the introduction of new services that would not otherwise be supplied
by private firms. But the private firms cannot enter because they are not al-
lowed to undercut the monopoly that is deemed necessary to support the new
services.
Many people sincerely believe that universal service depends on a public
monopoly. This, however, is not correct. First, for most of the monopoly pe-
riod there was nothing close to universal service in existence, and investments
were targeted highly unequally. In France, for example, telephone service was
offered far more extensively in the Paris region than in the provinces (see Fig-
ure 9.1, p. 141). At the turn of the century, Berlin and New York City had
similar telephone densities (one telephone per twenty-nine persons in New York,
and one for forty-three in Berlin). But in the rural state of Iowa, telephone
density was twice as high as in New York State (one telephone per nineteen
people), with 170 different telephone companies and cooperatives providing
service, whereas rural districts in Germany had one phone per 500 people, less
than one-tenth of the Berlin density (Brock, 1981). In 1960, the percentage of
German farmers with telephones was an extraordinarily low 9 percent (Schulte,
1982). In 1980, it had gone up to 80 percent. In France, it was 9 percent in
1968, 73 percent in 1980, and 93 percent in 1985 (T. Vedel, 1988, commu-
nication). In the United States, according to the Rural Electrification Adminis-
tration, 96 percent of all farms had telephones in 1988. In typical farm states
such as Iowa and Kansas, telephone densities were higher, with 95.1 and 95.2
per 100 households, than the national average of 92.4 (Federal-State Joint
Board, 1988), even after a more liberalized telecommunications regime. 1
Defense of the Telecommunications Monopoly 57
Natural Monopoly
A serious argument for PTT exclusivity is that communications services are a
"natural monopoly," that is, that single-firm production is cheaper, at every
level of output, than multifirm production. This is true when average (and mar-
ginal) costs are continuously declining with output. In that case, there are effi-
ciency advantages to the largest network the market will bear. But if the un-
derlying characteristics are truly naturally monopolistic, there should be little
or no danger of competitive entry, since new entrants, unless they could sup-
port losses for a sufficiently long growth period, would inevitably fail. What
then is the purpose of prohibition of entry if economic barriers would be enough?
The counterargument is that, although theoretically no entry would be prof-
itable, in reality the rate structure is based on social goals, which leads to tariffs
above cost for some services in order to provide for the subsidization of others.
These high-profit services would then become the object of "cream-skimming"
in a liberalized environment, even though it would be economically inefficient
to provide them outside the monopoly. This reasoning links the cross-subsidy
argument with the natural monopoly argument.
The most sophisticated analysis along these lines was advanced in the United
States as part of new industrial organization theory linked to William Baumol
and others such as Elizabeth Bailey, Gerald Faulhaber, John Panzar, and Rob-
ert Willig. These writers demonstrated that in a multiproduct setting (i.e., where
a firm supplies an array of related items), such a firm may have overall econ-
omies of scale, but under certain conditions its position may become "unsus-
tainable" because particular product lines are vulnerable to competition, even
in the absence of cross-subsidies (Baumol et al., 1982). Such loss of the mo-
nopoly would result in a loss of economies of scale and scope, that is, of
size and of joint production. This implies that even in a system free of cross-
subsidies, a natural monopoly could be subject to competitive entry. The ar-
gument is effective in the abstract, but it is based on certain theoretical and
empirical assumptions that have been criticized (Shepherd, 1983).
There are other problems with the economies-of-scale argument. The first is
the question of whether they actually exist beyond some point, a question that
is a theoretical and empirical morass. Most older U.S. and Canadian econo-
metric studies of economies of scale, in the days of the AT&T monopoly, seem
to show that they are of a modest size (Meyer et al., 1980). A review of several
studies finds that, excluding one AT&T study, the range of scale elasticities for
the Bell system was between 0.98 and 1.24 (Mantell, 1974). Another study
(Nadiri and Schankerman, 1981) finds a much larger value of around 1.8, though
it was declining over time. An AT&T submission in the antitrust law suit (AT&T,
1976) shows a great range (0.74-2.08). Much lower results were found for
Bell Canada (0.85-1.11) (Dobell et al., 1972; Fuss and Waverman, 1977). The
FCC concluded, based on most of these studies, that the existence of econo-
mies of scale was not definite.
Furthermore, even if the existence of economies of scale is accepted, they
58 Defense of the Telecommunications Monopoly
Network size
Figure 5.1. Economies of Scale and Shift of Cost Curve.
must also be shown to offset the inefficiencies of monopoly and regulation. For
example, regulation of rate of return has been shown to create an incentive
for overcapitalization (the Averch-Johnson effect). There is also the matter of
simple, accumulated high-cost operations. The operating costs of MCI per
revenue-minute were estimated as 24.8 cents, only three-fourths of the costs of
the much larger AT&T, which were estimated as 31.8 cents per revenue-minute
at the end of its near-monopoly phase (Chrust, 1985, p. 10).
These numbers indicate that economies of scale cannot be observed in the
abstract but must be considered with reference to the competitive pressures on
efficiency under which they are realized. The shape of average cost curves may
be downward-sloping, but the actual location of the cost curves is not indepen-
dent of different institutional arrangements and their dynamics. In other words,
one must distinguish between movement along a cost curve and a shift of the
cost curve itself. The latter, induced by competition, may be greater than the
lost economies of scale.
In Figure 5.1, for example, the average cost in the monopoly network is
declining, suggesting benefits of economies of scale.
At size H I , the cost is C\. However, suppose that competition is permitted.
A second network enters, and its rivalry leads to a lowered cost function at
each level of production, for either network, depicted as A ' , B'. Let us assume
that both networks split the market equally, that is, that the network size of
each is n\IT.. At that size, the cost of each is 2, which is lower than the cost
in the monopoly network.
This does not even take into account the increased demand due to lowered
prices and increased marketing efforts of the competitors, which should move
average cost further downward on the competitive-cost curve. In other words,
the existence of economies of scale does not dispose of the question of lower
cost.
Defense of the Telecommunications Monopoly 59
Technical Integrity
Compatibility
A close cousin to the technical integrity argument is the claim that a monopoly
is necessary to ensure that all participants can actually communicate with each
other. If several carriers supply services and equipment, technical incompati-
bility could fragment the network, leading in time to the need to have multiple
telephone instruments on one's desk. This argument is flimsy at best. Standards
setting takes place in numerous industries without the need for monopoly pro-
duction. In telecommunications, much of it already takes place through various
international bodies. There are also economic incentives to compatibility. But
where these are not adequate, legal requirements and technical standards of
interconnection and access can assure that there will not be fragmentation into
incompatible networks.
Comprehensive Planning
Policy Options
Given the forces of change, what are the policy directions? It is necessary to
distinguish between several very different reform concepts that are frequently
intermingled under the vague heading of "deregulation."
Corporatization
Under corporatization, the status of telecommunications operation is trans-
formed from a state administration (i.e., part of the civil service) into a publicly
owned corporation. Such a course is usually advocated to encourage efficiency
and flexibility. The monopoly status is not touched by corporatization as such,
though once the close link to the government is severed, a process is set in
motion that makes further changes more likely. Sometimes the corporatized
entity is described as a "private" firm, in the sense that it may be organized
under private law provisions (which determine its status in, for example, con-
tract and labor law), but that description confuses legal detail with the reality
of control, which is still governmental. Corporatization is usually accompanied
by the creation of a regulatory mechanism of government, typically as part of
the PTT ministry.
Privatization
A privatization policy may follow corporatization as the government sells part
or all of the shares in the telecommunications entity to private investors. Pri-
vatization, too, need not affect the monopoly status. In the United States, AT&T
was private and a near monopoly for a very long period.
Ownership per se does not determine economic performance. For example,
the nationalized French banks have performed quite well. More relevant is the
extent of state political interference. Such interference can take place in nomi-
nally private organizations such as Italy's SIP. In contrast, a government or-
ganization such as France Telecom has established significant independence
regardless of its legal status.
61
62 Policy Directions
Liberalization
Liberalization involves a more pronounced change in market structure. By opening
equipment supply and services to entry, liberalization changes the nature of
markets and the power of the established suppliers. Privatization is more dra-
matic, but liberalization is by far the more important policy. Advocates of
telecommunications reform tend to combine and sometimes confuse these two
policies.
Devolution
A prime example of devolution is the divestiture of AT&T in America. It is
not necessary for either liberalization or privatization, although it addresses the
problems of competitive barriers and market power. A devolution can also be
part of liberalization, where some segments of the market are opened up, and
others are not. If different regulatory treatment of carriers active in both open
and restricted markets is sought, a policy of devolution may make sense. De-
volution is also possible without liberalization. In Denmark and Italy, for ex-
ample, the public network had been segmented but monopolistic.
Deregulation
The American historical experience, for a long time, followed the expected
path from relatively unbridled laissez-faire capitalism to a regulatory system
that kept steadily but unspectacularly expanding in the decades following the
Great Depression and World War II. The unusual aspect of recent develop-
ments in U.S., U.K., and Japanese regulatory policy is their reversal of this
historical trend.
Within the spectrum of European policy response, one extreme is the United
Kingdom, whose government, under former Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher,
supported a free-market economy. The British government brought about sep-
aration of the telecommunications monopoly British Telecom from the postal
services, and reorganized it as a privately owned corporation subject to some
competition.
While Britain was consciously attempting to raise its high-technology stan-
dards through market forces, with the government attempting to create an en-
trepreneurial environment, French policies increased the governmental role. The
Socialist government set development of a high-technology electronics industry
as a national priority and nationalized much of the French electronics and tele-
communications equipment industry to gain a lever for the achievement of this
goal. This policy, only partly reversed by conservative government, had the
support of a large part of the public and intelligentsia. The effect is that the
French actually created, for a time, a state-owned analog of the old AT&T
system: a vertically integrated complex of equipment manufacturing coupled
with a telecommunications transmission monopoly and an R&D laboratory. At
the same time that the Bell telecommunications monopoly in the United States
was being segmented into several component parts, the French did the opposite
and integrated, for the first time, the major elements of telecommunications
under one ownership (though the French state is admittedly a very large um-
brella whose spokes may be at odds with one another). Equipment manufacture
was partly privatized again and the telephone administration was made more
independent in 1990. But the state and its affiliated institutions are strongly in
charge.
The telecommunications policy of the Federal Republic of Germany lies
somewhere between the liberalization of the United Kingdom and the nation-
alization of France. For a long time, the Deutsche Bundespost was loath to
relinquish its monopoly power over domestic and international telecommuni-
cations, and it has labored to protect the status quo. Only reluctantly, under
the prodding of other parts of the government and following the Dutch ex-
ample, were institutional reforms moved forward in 1988. The telephone ad-
ministration was separated from postal matters and corporatized as a state or-
ganization, with greater operational separation from the PTT Ministry, which
now functioned as the regulatory agency. Similar courses were taken by the
Netherlands, Denmark, and several other countries.
These four positionscorporatization, privatization, liberalization, and de-
volutionconstituted the primary policy menu of European countries in the
1980s. Yet for all their differences, European strategies also had an important
common element: assigning the national telecommunications carrier a role as a
64 Policy Directions
How was the government to deal with IBM, "one of the great actors on the
world stage"? The growing interaction between computer technology and tele-
communications made control possible. Although governmental influence over
the computer industry was limited, the latter's overlap with telecommunica-
tionsover which the state traditionally had controlprovided the state with a
lever of power.
[National governments need to] strengthen their bargaining position with a solid
mastery of their communications media. . . . However, the difficulty lies even
more in the fact that no country can play that role alone. . . . But the internation-
alization of the stakes means that today no economic Gallicanism is sufficient to
keep Rome out of Armonk. Independence would be vain and as easy to outflank
as a useless Maginot Line if it were not supported by an international alliance
having the same objectives [Nora and Mine, 1980, pp. 72-73].
Nora and Mine coined the term telematique for the sector that is also var-
iously referred to as IT, C & C, informatics, or compunications. Their analysis,
which may be termed political telematique, became extraordinarily influential
as PTTs embraced its notions, which assigned to them a central role in high-
technology policy and in the preservation of the national interest against Amer-
ican (and later Japanese) economic and technical interests. The equipment in-
dustry was also supportive since the Nora-Mine report created a presumption
in favor of government subsidies and protectionism as a matter of preserving
national sovereignty.
Policy Directions 65
69
70 Germany
phone. But the purpose of German telephony was distinctly different. Stephan
viewed the telephone as an extension of state telegraphy, to be used in rural
post offices where trained telegraph operators were not economically feasible.
It took Emil Rathenau, a noted Berlin industrialist with a particular interest in
applications of electricity, to establish the concept of public telephony on users'
premises.
Because Bell's telephone was introduced in Germany three months after the
German patent law was passed on July 1, 1877, Bell's invention fell between
the cracks and received no patent. Thus, the manufacture of Bell equipment
was free in Germany, and Werner Siemens began producing and improving it
(Siemens, 1949, p. 199). Through their companies, Siemens and Rathenau
henceforth became the main protagonists in German telecommunications equip-
ment manufacturing. Together with Stephan, they created German telecommu-
nications, from the beginning a close alliance of governmental and business
interests.
Stephan called upon Rathenau to organize the Berlin business community for
the first telephone exchange in Germany. Rathenau, one of the more interesting
figures in German economic and political history, agreed to work on the intro-
duction of telephone service in Berlin (Goetzler, 1976, p. 6). After consider-
able difficulty, the Berlin exchange opened in January 1881, connecting eight
subscribers. Official German accounts of the introduction of telephone service
traditionally describe the Berlin exchange as the country's first. Actually, the
first system was established in Mulhouse in what was then German Alsatia,
and by private rather than postal initiative. However, not wishing to be up-
staged by its reluctant province, the Berlin authorities denied the Mulhouse
system an official permit to operate until after the Berlin state system was
opened.
Local exchange areas were consolidated into territorial districts, and after
1884 these were interconnected by long-distance trunks. Telephone service ex-
panded, and Germany had 10,000 local post offices with telephone service by
1890. Besides these state-run telephones, however, there was little penetration.
But the spread of electronic outposts into the countryside was immensely wel-
come, and the Reichspost, and Stephan at its helm, became enormously popu-
lar.
In 1882, the Reichspost established conditions of private interconnection with
the public network. Ten years later there were more than 2000 private lines
connecting with the public system, and almost 3000 purely private telephone
systems within private properties such as factories. In 1892, the comprehensive
telephone authority of the state was established by law.
The next decades witnessed steady improvements of technology, services,
and penetration of the telephone. In 1886, the first international public tele-
phone communications were established between a town in Alsace and Basel,
Switzerland. A trial for an American-made automatic exchange was inaugu-
rated in 1900, and German equipment came on line in 1908. In 1909, wireless
telegraphy was introduced.
After the initial push into rural post offices, the development of telephony in
Germany 71
Germany was much more centered in the cities than in the United States. In
1902, overall telephone density in the United States was one telephone for each
thirty-four persons, as compared to a much lower density of one telephone per
128 people in Germany. But for the cities, the ratio was more similar. The
number of people per telephone in New York was thirty-nine, in Chicago,
thirty; and in Boston, nineteen. In Berlin the density at the same time was
forty-three persons per telephone. It was fifty-two in Hamburg, seventy-seven
in Frankfurt, and thirty in Stuttgart. But in rural areas the matter was quite
different. In New York State, telephone density was one telephone per thirty-
one inhabitants; in Illinois, twenty-four, and in Iowa, a largely agricultural
state, one per nineteen. In Germany, on the other hand, one eastern Prussian
district had one telephone for 634 inhabitants, and in many others the density
was less than one per 500 (Holcombe, 1911, p. 432).
During the years of the Weimar Republic, technology, subscribership, and
services all steadily expanded. In 1923, subscriber trunk dialing was introduced
in Bavaria. Intercontinental telephone service to the United States was inaugu-
rated in 1928.
Rampant postwar inflation made the Reichspost dependent on government
subsidies, until the 1924 Imperial Postal Finances Act (Reichspostfinanzgesetz)
established financial autonomy and control by an administrative council rather
than parliament.
When the National Socialists assumed power in 1933, Adolf Hitler appointed
W. Ohnesorge as state secretary (later upgraded to minister) in charge of the
Reichspost.'
of an hour, took the Wheatstone system seven hours, postal authorities shifted
their preferences. Siemens adopted the new equipment but found himself al-
most immediately embroiled in a public debate about the effectiveness of his
buried telegraph lines. After he published a pamphlet that criticized the state
authorities' construction method, the firm lost all governmental contracts and
almost went out of business. Fortunately, other governments, particularly Rus-
sia's, had their own needs for telegraph equipment and the firm was thus kept
alive.
Siemens and his brothers set up operations in several major European coun-
tries (Scott, 1958). Werner was the "Berlin Siemens," and the driving force
of the main firm, Siemens & Halske. (The related firm, Siemens & Schuckert,
manufactured locomotives and heavy electrical equipment). A gifted engineer
and a courageous entrepreneur, he was also a political liberal of sorts who did
not hesitate to have himself elected to the Prussian Parliament as an opposition
deputy, despite the fact that the government was the major customer of the
fledgling company. His brother, Carl Wilhelm, who lived in London and even-
tually became Sir William Siemens, was the main figure in the separate British
firm Siemens Brothers. Heinrich, known as the St. Petersburg Siemens, looked
after the family's substantial Russian business. A close relative, Georg Sie-
mens, was the founder and head of the Deutsche Bank, which rapidly became
the most important financial institution in Germany and which still remains the
Hausbank of the firm.
With his relatively liberal views, Werner Siemens was similar to two other
major figures in the German electric industry, Emil Rathenau, the founder of
AEG, and later Robert Bosch, founder of the Bosch Company (Heuss, 1946).
AEG-Telefunken became the second most important German telecommunica-
tions company. After its decline in the 1970s, its position was assumed by the
increasingly diversified Bosch, a very successful firm that began in automotive
component supply and consumer durables and increasingly moved into tele-
communications. The electronics industry was progressive and internationalist
in comparison with the heavy industry that set the image of German business.
The relationship between Rathenau and Siemens was characterized by both
competition and cartel behavior. Rathenau founded the German Edison Com-
pany in 1883. According to an agreement, Siemens stayed out of electric dis-
tribution, which was reserved to Rathenau's firm, which in turn bought all of
its equipment, except for light bulbs, from Siemens. Rathenau introduced elec-
tric lighting into Germany by creating a complex supporting structure. His firm
was transformed into AEG (Allgemeine Electricitaets Gesellschaft, or General
Electric Company), with the Siemens firm as one of its major investors. When
alternating current was developed as a rival to the untransformable direct cur-
rent, both Siemens and Rathenau fought its introduction vehemently, just as
Edison did in the United States against Westinghouse, and just as unsuccess-
fully.
At Stephen's request, Siemens started to produce unpatented telephone
equipment. When Michael Pupin, a Columbia University professor, developed
the so-called Pupin coil, which greatly improved the amplification of signals,
Germany 73
Siemens acquired the German patent rights for a large sum and defended the
patent against challengers, which included the Reichspost. He told the inventor,
"As far as I know, this is the highest price that has ever been paid for a
mathematical formula; it goes far beyond the hundred oxen of the Pythagoras.
The Post Office knows very well why it led us in such a dance last year, for it
is now its turn to pay" (Siemens, vol. I, 1957, p. 181). Previously only one
among several competing firms for local systems, Siemens now acquired tech-
nical leadership in long-distance telecommunications equipment through the Pupin
license.
Siemens still had no dominance in switching, however. When the Reichspost
experimented with the introduction of the Strowger automatic telephone ex-
change, a clear advance over the hand-operated exchanges, Siemens waved the
flag to discourage the purchase of American equipment. Serious about auto-
matic switching, the Reichspost set up a consortium of companies to develop
such equipment. The consortium included Siemens despite its lack of experi-
ence in the area, but it eventually became the driving force and acquired the
German rights for the Strowger patent, and improved it. This was the beginning
of Siemens dominance in German switching equipment. As a family member,
Georg Siemens, wrote, "Siemens and Halske had created for themselves, with
their [exchange] systems, a technical monopoly" (Siemens, vol. II, 1949, p.
53). To deal with this situation, the Reichspost united other exchange equip-
ment companies in joint ventures.
Competition, cartelization, and the breaking of cartel agreements continued
to characterize relations among Germany's main electric equipment producers.
The "Big Three" of power generation agreed that they would explore and
inform each other of each request for a bid over a specified value. They also
agreed that they would bid predetermined prices that varied only slightly from
each other, and that they would permit the contracting firms to give price dis-
counts only if the order threatened to be lost to an outsider. This agreement
operated under the code name V.C., for Vertrauliche Corresponded, or con-
fidential correspondence. Similar relations existed in the production of incan-
descent lamps. According to Georg Siemens, "Due to senseless price slashing,
it had come to the point where lamps which twenty years earlier cost twenty
Marks, cost the same amount in Pfennig, and this could not go on. Thus in
1904, the 'Sales Organization United Incandescent Lamps' was established in
Berlin, a syndicate in which Siemens & Halske and AEG held a quota of 21
percent of total production" (Siemens, vol. II, 1949, p. 240). To tighten cartel
cooperation, a joint firm for incandescent lamps (Osram) was established in
1919, into which Siemens, AEG, and Auer brought their production facilities
and patents. Another selling cartel syndicate was founded in 1911 for insulated
wires. As Georg Siemens describes it, the wire cartel "claimed in its favor that
it kept its members to a strict adherence to the standards of the Association of
German Electro-technical Engineers, and provided them in return with a fairly
undisturbed independently wealthy existence" (Siemens, vol. II, 1949, p. 24).
Perhaps the longest-lived and most successful cartel in the German electrical
sector was the cable cartel, which dates back to 1876 and a large cable order
74 Germany
by the Reichspost to Siemens & Halske and Felten & Guilleaume. That cartel
set supply quotas for members in 1914 and established an enforcement office
that instructed each firm what price it could quote for an order. Any violation
led to a large contractual penalty. If a firm exceeded its quota, it was instructed
to quote high prices to avoid winning further contracts. The system operated
very successfully under strict cartel management which had access to relevant
financial records of the firm.
At AEG, meanwhile, Emil Rathenau was succeeded as president by his son
Walter. In addition to being a company executive, Walter was a novelist, es-
sayist, designer of the value-added tax (which fifty years later was adopted in
Europe), and head of Germany's wartime economic planning. After World War
I, the younger Rathenau gave a speech that discussed critically the reasons for
Germany's defeat. Even though he had been an essential figure in the economic
mobilization during the war, his speech led to vituperations against him that
were frequently anti-Semitic. According to Georg Siemens, "Particularly in the
circles of heavy industry, a virtual boycott against AEG was commenced, and
a number of large and important orders, which it would have received other-
wise, went to various competitors, primarily the Siemens-Schuckert firm" (Sie-
mens, vol. II, 1949, p. 283). AEG's central administration, aghast at its pres-
ident, forced him to resign. He then entered the political arena and served as
minister of foreign affairs until he was assassinated in 1922 by right-wing stu-
dents.
In the early development of the radio, Siemens and AEG were competitors.
Later, Emperor Wilhelm II, who was obsessively interested in naval matters
and therefore in the development of radio for navy and merchant marine, ex-
pressed his displeasure that two German groups were competing against each
other and weakening themselves in relation to the Marconi company. The mil-
itary authorities preferred a uniform solution. This led to a great deal of polit-
ical pressure on Siemens, and in 1903 to the formation of a joint company with
AEG. The joint company became the renowned Telefunken company, eventu-
ally part of AEG. The pioneer of German broadcasting, Hans Bredow, was a
director of Telefunken before he moved to the Reichspost, which he then es-
tablished as the undisputed ruler of the airwaves.
Telefunken held rights to an extraordinarily important amplification tube un-
der the Lieben patent. Without it no other company could produce an effective
radio set. For a while, Siemens, AEG, and Telefunken all sold the identical
product with different exteriors, under the protective umbrella of Reichspost
licensing.
In telephone equipment, Siemens produced a 2500-subscriber central battery
telephone exchange in 1909, the first PBX in 1912, automatic trunk dialing
equipment in 1923, and long-distance public telephones in 1929. In 1930, the
development of a full-wire transmission technique made possible a nationwide
telephone service, and in 1933 the company established the first telex network
in the world.
During the Nazi period, the firm's leader, Carl Friedrich von Siemens, kept
some distance from the regime, but the company benefitted from the rearma-
Germany 75
ment that took place. The war caused major destruction to Siemens plants, and
a large portion of its facilities in Berlin was dismantled by the victorious Rus-
sians. Both Siemens & Halske and Siemens & Schuckert were restructured,
and most of the headquarters was moved to Munich. The firm soon resumed
its place as the foremost name in the German electronics sector.
The company had 21,000 employees in 1989 and was successful in worldwide
home electronics business, in particular through its television sets and digital
television system DigiVision.
SEL played a major role in the development of ITT's System 12 digital
switch. With the Bundespost's order for System 12 in 1982, SEL obtained
potentially 30-40 percent of the German digital exchange market.
Bosch, long a leader in automotive parts and household durables, is con-
trolled by a private charitable foundation. Like SEL, it is located in the Stutt-
gart area. It acquired Telenorma and its 18,000 employees from AEG, and
added more than 40 percent of ANT (a company with 6500 employees and a
leader in digital broadband switching, communications satellites, fiber optics,
and cellular telephones). Bosch also owns the mobile radio company Blau-
punkt, which is also active in automobile video display systems, television and
stereo, and Btx terminals. Bosch increased its investments in Telenorma, JS
Telecommunications, in France; Hasler, in Switzerland; and Telettra, in Italy
and created a mobile communications division. Taken together, the Bosch group
is a contender for the number two position in German telecommunications
equipment.
Nixdorf Computer was perhaps the greatest challenge to the established order
of Germany's electronic industry. The company was founded by Heinz Nixdorf
in a factory basement in 1952 with an investment of $6000, and it has remained
innovative and untraditional. By identifying market niches in the computer field,
it left behind large companies such as Siemens, Triumph-Adler (formerly of
AEG), and Kienzle. For example, Nixdorf had a large share of the German
market in computerized banking equipment and automated teller machines. In
1983, Nixdorf introduced Germany's first digital PBX, and by 1989, telecom-
munications accounted for over 10 percent of its revenues.
Nixdorf was also one of Europe's largest software developers. Four thousand
of its 20,000 employees are directly involved in the development of software
and provided about half of total revenues. Unlike other European computer
companies, Nixdorf also moved aggressively into the American market.
In 1978, Volkswagen made a bid to acquire a controlling share of Nixdorf
but was rebuffed. Eventually, however, Nixdorf's undercapitalization and tech-
nical ambitions caught up with the company. After its 1989 losses of close to
DM 1 billion, it was forced to sell a 51 percent stake to Siemens. Siemens then
merged its own computer operations into Siemens-Nixdorf Informations Sys-
tems, which became Europe's largest computer company.
Expansion of Service
Figure 7.1. Telephone Main Lines per 100 Households by Occupational Group
in Germany. (Source: Schulte, 1982.)
penetration had been less than 10 percent for these social groups! But for white-
collar employees too penetration was 84 percent in 1980, in contrast to 42
percent in 1970 and about 15 percent in 1960. Thus, for the vast majority of
German households, the telephone is a fairly recent acquisition. In Germany, a
sense of appreciation still exists toward the supplier of the service, the Bundes-
post, for making it possible to join the telecommunications network.
With the task of universal service largely completed, the next phase in tele-
communications, starting in the early 1980s, was to refocus priorities to in-
creasingly sophisticated telecommunications services, and this meant toward
the needs of large users, whatever the official philosophy proclaimed.
New Services
The usage and density of telex service in Germany are high. Germany's telex
network is the world's largest, three times denser than that of the United States,
and had thirty-nine telex accesses per 10,000 inhabitants in 1988. In 1988,
there were about 155,000 telex subscribers, down from the 1986 figure (ITU,
1990). Most likely, this number will continue to decline because of the emer-
gence of fax and electronic mail, known as teletext. (Teletext should not be
confused with the broadcast text service of the same name).
Teletext was introduced by the Bundespost after seven years of development
in 1981, following the recommendations of the blue-ribbon Commission on
Communication Techonology (KtK) panel. Growth was disappointing.
ISDN and videotex in Germany are discussed in other chapters of this book.
A few details will suffice here. In 1986, Germany conducted two ISDN trials
in Stuttgart and Mannheim. In addition, the Bundespost tested, after 1983,
fiber-optic broadband networks under the name of BIGFON, providing to users
two digital telephone lines, data and text services, two to four centrally switched
TV channels, twenty-four stereo audio channels, and a videophone video ca-
pability. 5
Regular ISDN service was introduced in 1989 at a Hanover trade fair. The
DBF signed up its first ISDN applications customer, a retail drugstore chain in
August 1989, but subsequent user demand was low (Schwarz-Schilling, 1990,
p. 58). The DBF therefore created a "U2000" network strategy, shifting em-
phasis from ISDN transmission to an intelligent network. ISDN plans were
expanded to include the distribution of 50,000 microcomputer boards to stim-
ulate demand (Gilhooly and Schenker, 1989).
firm. This comparison is even more impressive, since most of the Bundespost's
activities are domestically achieved.
Similarly significant are profits. The Monopoly Commission report found a
real profit of approximately DM 5 billion in 1980. It noted that, according to
the calculation of the Association of Postal Users, another DM 0.75 billion
ought to be considered profit, which would result in a profit margin of 15.8
percent. Total telecommunications profits are even larger if one disaggregates
them from postal services, which have been substantially in the red for many
years.
Telecommunications accounted for 70 percent of total DBF's revenue, with
postal services 26 percent and banking and financial services 4 percent.
By its own estimate, the Bundespost's share in Germany's GNP more than
doubled between 1960 and 1982, from 1.4 percent to 3.4 percent. In 1982, the
Bundespost provided secure jobs for more than 500,000 employees (about
216,000 in telecommunications). Not counting the effect of technology devel-
opment on exports, its procurement orders and investments provided jobs for
an additional 200,000 people (DBF, 1982a). Together with the hundreds of
thousands of retirees, relatives, and neighbors, this means a very large voting
constituency. In 1988, the combined DBF had DM 52.5 billion in revenues
and DM 16.9 billion in investments. The Postal service reported losses of DM
2.26 billion (Blau, 1989; Moschel, 1988; ITU, 1990).
Article 87 of the Basic Law (constitution) of the Federal Republic of Ger-
many postulates governmental control of telecommunications. The Postal Ad-
ministration Law of 1954 established the Bundespost as the organization serv-
ing the communication needs of Germany (Elias et al., 1980). The
Telecommunications Facilities Law of 1928 gave the Bundespost what it inter-
preted as the sole right to erect and operate telecommunications facilities. The
exceptions were private facilities not crossing property lines (and, under certain
conditions, connections between separate properties of the same owner) and
certain government authorities (such as the state railway Bundesbahn and the
armed force Bundeswehr) which are allowed to run their own internal com-
munications operations. The Minister of Postal Affairs could, in principle, grant
waivers to other providers, though this had not been done for many years.
Overall responsibility for the Bundespost lies with the Federal Minister of
Post and Telecommunications, who is a cabinet member and typically an influ-
ential party figure.
The DBF operated a substantial telecommunications technical center (FTZ)
in Darmstadt, a central approval office for telecommunications in Saarbruecken
(FZZ), two engineering colleges, a scientific institute, and more than 18,000
post offices throughout the country. Until 1982, the Bundespost also provided
a far-flung postal bus service that carried 281 million persons during its last
year of operation. For a long time, it was the largest bus operation in Europe
(Stuebing, 1982). The Bundespost had no monopoly over its bus routes but
could establish them virtually everywhere, while private competitors could run
lines where the Post buses already operated only by demonstrating that addi-
tional service was necessary.
Germany 81
Procurement Practices
Genera/
Procurement practices of the DBF have been a particular bone of contention,
both internationally and domestically. The German Monopoly Commission found
equipment prices to be generally higher domestically than in North America,
and the equipment was of a costly design.
In 1960, only 25 percent of total procurement was subjected to at least a
limited bidding process. This increased over the next twenty years to 40 per-
cent. A set-aside process was used in competitive procurement: Bids for part
of the quantity were solicited first, with the resultant price the upper limit for
the remaining quantity. The problem is that the supplying companies could
82 Germany
tacitly agree on a price leader and then set a high "market price" for the
second stage in which they would participate. In 1976, the Cartel Office im-
posed fines totaling DM 1 million against twelve telephone equipment manu-
facturers and twenty of their managers, after finding that in 1974 and 1976 they
had rigged bids for DBF terminal equipment.
The DBF's renowned research and development arm, the Fernmeldetechn-
isches Zentralamt (FTZ), played a key role in the process through its power
over the selection, licensing, and development of equipment. Almost 60 per-
cent of the DBF's procurement contracts were awarded by the FTZ. Tradition-
ally, it collaborated with a chosen supplier to develop products, with the other
manufacturers acting in effect as subcontractors to the primary firm.
In 1963, the German Federal Accounting Office issued a report criticizing
the Bundespost's procurement practices. A two-volume DBF response asserted
that it saw "no reason and no possibility for a fundamental change" (Scherer,
1985, p. 79). The theme of liberalization was then sounded by academics
(Mestmacker, 1980). Similarly, the German Monopoly Commission, in a major
report, found in 1981 that the DBF's practices contributed to the rigidity of the
supply market structure by its reliance on uniform equipment technology, and
a de facto concentration of procurement (Monopolkommission, 1981). The
principle of uniform technology (Einheitstechnik) was a key element in the
Bundespost's procurement practice. All suppliers had to conform to an agreed-
upon technology for a product; the four main development firms (Entwicklungs-
firmen) shared patents that were obtained in the course of the product devel-
opment. The Bundespost defended this policy, citing its advantages for tech-
nical planning, in particular in the postwar reconstruction, where it reduced
duplicative R&D. For digital switching, the Bundespost modified its principles,
but it had in any event no realistic alternative. It also opened procurement of
public packet switching systems to international bidding, and Northern Tele-
com, despite its views about domestic market restrictions quoted earlier, ob-
tained the order.
of today's SEL (Mix & Genest), as well as DeTeWe, Lorenz, Berliner, and
other manufacturers, in return for an assured procurement quota. Starting in
1924, together with its small partner, Siemens received a set quota of 60 per-
cent of the procurement for the next five years. The agreement was renewed in
1927. In 1933, with the National Socialists in power, the nine major telecom-
munications equipment manufacturers, some of them now under new Aryan
ownership, entered into the so-called Telecommunications Domestic Contract
with each other. This contract governed all telecommunications transactions
with state agencies and private users. They carved up the market among them-
selves, with the Siemens group receiving 54 percent; the Standard group (which
consisted of Mix & Genest, C. Lorenz, and Berliner), 36 percent; and De-
TeWe, 10 percent of the Reichspost procurement volume. The contract was to
run for ten years. The Reichspost was notified of the agreement and stayed
within its provisions.
For the six firms that survived World War II, the quotas were maintained,
now justified by the need to stabilize the market where overcapacity existed
and to permit national planning. After 1951, the Bundespost notified the central
exchange manufacturers, by then three in number, to plan their production ca-
pacity each for a specific volume. In the following years, the watchdog Federal
Accounting Office began to show concern about the arrangement. The Bundes-
post insisted that even though the participants acknowledged the nature of its
coordination, it was only an internal administrative matter and did not include
an agreement between the Bundespost and firms or between the firms them-
selves. After 1954, the exclusive circle was expanded to include the firm T&N
(later renamed Telenorma), following that firm's legal pressures.
In 1955, the Bundespost decided to substitute its System 55 with the new
HMD switch developed by Siemens. Because it did not wish to depart from its
practice of using only one type of equipment, rival equipment by SEL was not
adopted. However, the DBF required Siemens to grant licenses to the other
three switch manufacturers. The decision to move to the new switch was un-
dertaken without involvement of the Bundespost's Supervisory Council. As part
of these transactions, in 1955 a highly confidential agreement was signed by
the Bundespost and the four industry manufacturers. The preamble of this "Heads
of Agreement" document stated that the Bundespost wished in the future to
include T&N in switching equipment contracts. The firms then agreed to a
quota of 46 percent for Siemens, 31.3 percent for SEL, 15.2 percent for De-
TeWe, and 7.5 percent for T&N. For trunk switches, a quota of 55 percent for
Siemens, 32 percent for SEL, 10 percent for DeTeWe, and 3 percent for T&N
was agreed upon (Scherer, 1985, p. 441). The firms also agreed not to contest
each others' market shares.
In subsequent years the Bundespost, with considerable legal agility, denied
the existence of quotas, but it largely adhered to the figures of the Heads of
Agreement. These market shares, combined with the Bundespost's detailed three-
to five-year projections of its total equipment needs, made reasonably accurate
production planning by the firms possible. In practice, orders for equipment
came up from the regional telecommunications directorates, together with pref-
84 Germany
erences for equipment suppliers. These orders were then aggregated, and, if
necessary, centrally modified to reach the target quotas. In other words, the
preferences of the Bundespost's own regional directorates could be disregarded
in order to meet the industry's agreement. Although the practices were criti-
cized by the Federal Accounting Office, the Bundespostdefying reality, eco-
nomics, and common senseinsisted that the quotas were only representing
real market shares and that its procurement practices did not establish any eco-
nomic power relationship or market concentration.
In the mid-1970s, as residential telephone service neared saturation and the
economy suffered from recession, telephone expansion dropped considerably.
In 1971 the waiting list for telephones had been 600,000, but by 1974 it had
shrunk to 17,000. Equipment volume contracted, and workers were laid off.
Alternative export markets were not easily available. The reliance on the safe
and traditional electromechanical switching technology, by then twenty years
old, left the manufacturers without a product that was competitive in the world
market.
In 1975, the Bundespost started to introduce price competition by permitting
limited changes in the procurement quota, according to prices offered. As a
result its bargaining position strengthened. The system provided for a quota
increase of 2 percent above that of the previous year for the lowest bidder. If
the Bundespost considered the lowest bid to be still too high, it could withdraw
the entire offer. If other firms lowered their prices to that of the lowest bidder,
they would share the remainder of the market among themselves, absorbing the
2 percent reduction of market share.
One problem in the adoption of the procurement method was that the small-
est and the most recent of the suppliers, T&N, behaved like a maverick, in-
sisting on a larger share than before. This forced the Bundespost to ask for the
blessing of the Federal Cartel Office for the scheme, which it received. T&N,
however, did not give in, and argued that violations of German and European
anticompetitive laws were taking place and demanded a quota of 15 percent.
This led again to intense negotiations with the four firms, the Bundespost, the
Cartel Office, and the Ministry of Economics. The firms and the Cartel Office
reached an agreement, but the Postal Ministry, in an uncharacteristic procom-
petitive stance, decided to challenge it. Eventually, a compromise was reached
that protected T&N's market share from an undue retaliatory drop. In 1977,
the Bundespost cemented T&N's cooperation by giving it the largest increase
in its share, from 7.5 percent to 8 percent.
The development of first-generation electronic switching proved to be a dis-
mal chapter in the joint R&D efforts of Bundespost and private industry. In a
major miscalculation, a fully digital development was considered and then dropped
in favor of a semielectronic space division system. The project foundered, be-
cause technical progress occurring during its development continuously led to
changes in the project goals, and because the firms had problems coordinating
the development among themselves. The system was intended to be introduced
in 1977 or 1978, but these target dates were pushed back to 1981 or 1982. It
became clear that the TDM digital technology was considerably superior to the
Germany 85
one on which the Bundespost and the manufacturers had bet. In 1979, Bundes-
post Minister Kurt Gescheidle pulled the plug on the development program. He
declared that technical development hit the Bundespost and its suppliers like a
"natural catastrophe" but that the Bundespost had learned from its mistakes,
and as a result, it would now closely follow technical developments in the
international telecommunications markets. The large losses in the project were
borne chiefly by the equipment industry.
After the dropping of the ill-fated analog system, the Bundespost initiated a
crash program in digital switching. It approached the major manufacturers to
submit new development models, though only up to three models would be
tested by the Bundespost, and of those, at most two would be chosen, with
cutover dates in 1984-1985. This led initially to three proposals, by SEL (ITT),
by Siemens and its affiliate, and by DeTeWe, T&N, and Tekede. The latter
group, possessing no digital exchanges of their own, did not meet the May
1982 deadline to continue the project, and thus only two models were presented
to the Bundespost. A competitive selection was not instituted, and both the
EWSD system of Siemens, and ITT's System 12 were accepted in 1983.
Similar cartel arrangements existed for PBXs. Since the first private branch
exchange (PBX) was introduced in Germany in 1900, the penetration of PBXs
was substantial. There are more than a million PBXs in Germany, connecting
about 10 million extension stations. About 60 percent of total traffic volume
originated from or reached a PBX (ZVEI, 1983). The DBP's market share was
about 40 percent of units, but less in DM volume.
Until 1934, the market for PBXs was relatively free. All private suppliers
could enter and install equipment on private premises, though the Reichspost
was also a supplier. Competition led to technological development, but it also
led to severe price wars. In particular, the Reichspost was being undercut by
private competitors in a variety of ways. Until 1934, only compatibility stan-
dards were set for PBXs. In 1934, however, the PBX manufacturers considered
the price competition to be "ruinous" and set out to stabilize it. This was
accomplished through the establishment of uniform technical requirements and
performance standards.
The private suppliers agreed to conform to uniform conditions of supply as
well as to the prices of Reichspost-supplied PBXs. Any new supplier had to be
admitted to the production of PBXs. In other words, the Reichspost achieved
the elimination of competition that would undercut its own position while pro-
viding an umbrella for a price-fixing agreement among private suppliers.
The 1934 PBX rules also explicitly aimed to slow down technological de-
velopment. They sought to "cut back the overdeveloped(uberspitzte)technol-
ogy to the actual needs and to the associated reasonable extent, and to assure
that in further development only pertinent considerations would be determina-
tive" (Wittiber, 1934, p. 184, footnote 48).
In the 1980s a government report described the historical growth of this
86 Germany
regulatory system since the 1930s and found that "The result was a cartel
situation which divided the market among the suppliers. This did not come
about through prices, but through . . . standards regulation" (Mestma'cker,
1980, p. 185). The DBF bought, leased, and resold customer terminal equip-
ment. Traditionally, it was the sole supplier of simple terminal equipment. It
also provided, though not exclusively, PBXs, modems, and other more sophis-
ticated equipment, including telefax equipment. It had exclusive rights for ser-
vicing telex equipment but did not supply it.
Problems with this arrangement arose due to the Bundespost's triple function
in the telecommunications field: It regulated, operated, and competed. It was
the primary telecommunications regulatory authority of the country, with the
powers of government. At the same time, it was also the predominant network
operator: In equipment supply, it competed with private firms. The tension
between these several functions led to the appointment of a Kommission Deutsche
Bundespost in 1969-1970, which drafted a new charter, including the organi-
zational separation of political leadership and supervision, on the one hand,
and the actual operation, on the other hand. This bill was not passed by the
Bundestag (Elias et al., 1980).
The industry's attitude toward the Bundespost as a supplier was complex.
The DBF is, after all, its major customer and often a friendly supporter of the
industry's technical development and exports. But as a supply competitor, it
enjoyed advantages they resented: The Bundespost's equipment licensing au-
thority provides it with information about its own competitors' products; it had
no risk of bankruptcy; it did not have to set its pricing according to costs; and
it was able to subsidize its products internally for market penetration and deter-
rence of competitors (Monopolkommission, 1981).
The legal framework supported any DBF pricing policy. When equipment
was offered at a loss, it could be justified as a fulfillment of a public obligation;
when it was profitable, it was said to be part of the Bundespost's function to
balance its budget or to raise revenue for the federal budget.
In the customer terminal equipment market, there are eighteen firms, of which
the usual four (Siemens, SEL, T&N, DeTeWe) are the "development firms,"
while the others are "follower firms." According to the Monopoly Commis-
sion, these four have protected their technology through hundreds of patents.
The commission maintained that the "overlap [of patents] is obviously toler-
ated with mutual good will. Apparently the comprehensiveness of patent li-
censes is not utilized offensively to restrict competitors, but rather serves de-
fensively to secure individual production programs. The development firms show
a common interest in a peaceful coexistence in technological competition"
(Monopolkommission, 1981, para. 131).
The remaining eight suppliers of terminal equipment had a substantial 60
percent of the terminal set market. Those companies are fairly obscure and
depend on the Bundespost's good graces. They have no domestic distribution
system and have no need for one, since the Bundespost is their predominant
German customer.
The industry's ardent defense of the Bundespost suggests the symbiotic re-
Germany 87
lationship between the network monopoly and the equipment suppliers. The
trade association's (ZVEI) position on the role of the Bundespost has been:
"The German telecommunications industry is convinced that the functional in-
tegrity of the public telecommunications network, the nationwide availability
of services under the same conditions, the compatibility of communications
networks with all terminal devices, and the resulting freedom for all users to
communicate can be guaranteed only by a network monopoly" (ZVEI, 1983,
p. 43). The industry also defended the Bundespost's role as a distribution sys-
tem for small producers. "Participation of the Deutsche Bundespost in the ter-
minal equipment market is extremely advantageous for small and medium-sized
communication companies, which cannot meet the costs of a nationwide sales
and services network of their own, and therefore supply their product directly
to the Deutsche Bundespost. This allows them to achieve a notable share of
the market" (ZVEI, 1983, p. 45). This was in conflict with other industries,
where medium-sized producers were able to market their products, whether
through their own sales organization or through agents and intermediate whole-
salers, rather than having to depend on a state organization.
A complex bidding system was employed for terminal equipment that pro-
vided for greater competitiveness than for switching equipment. In the mid-
1970s the Bundespost charged suppliers with a breach of the price and quantity
agreement. They were fined, and the DBF tightened its procurement rules.
Immediately, the new system proved unworkable. The Siemens bid was by far
the lowest, and only SEL agreed to match it. The other ten firms refused and
made their high prices a David vs. Goliath issue for the survival of small and
medium sized companies. With business organization, unions, and politicians
being involved, the Bundespost retreated and announced its willingness to ac-
cept not the highest, but rather the third highest price as its guide. This was
accepted by eight of the ten companies, but the small firms were still unhappy
about the loss of the previously cozy arrangement. With the Federal Cartel
Office joining in to support the existence of a diversity of firms, the Bundespost
retreated still further.
The Bundespost strongly opposed the liberalization of terminal equipment on
legal grounds, based on a Telecommunications Order that declared terminal
equipment to be part of the public network. The order was confirmed by the
Federal Constitutional Court in 1978. The DBF also argued on technical grounds
that the separation of network and terminal equipment was impractical, since
terminal equipment fulfills a network protection function. To a certain extent
this is true, though other means of protection can be easily established. The
logical consequence of the Bundespost's view was that much of the office
equipment, as it becomes "smart" and connected to the network, could be
claimed to be subject to the Bundespost's regulatory jurisdiction and potential
control.
Conflicts about the Bundespost's role in equipment supply go far back. In
later years, controversy arose over telefax service initiated by the Bundespost
in the 1970s. The Bundespost wanted to ensure that it would play a major, if
not exclusive, role in the expected success of telefax equipment. The matter
88 Germany
came before the Administrative Council of 'he Bundespost, which was con-
scious of the potential controversy with office equipment manufacturers. The
union representatives on the board were unanimously opposed to a provision of
telefax equipment by private suppliers only and considered exclusive provision
by the Bundespost a viable alternative.
Within a short time, a rare public debate concerning the liberalization of
equipment began. In particular, the Federal Ministry of Economics championed
a liberalization, and in 1977, it opposed Bundespost participation in advanced
terminal equipment. It argued that such participation was not necessary, that it
was potentially discriminatory against its competitors which were also its sup-
pliers, and that it encouraged internal subsidies that distorted competition. The
Bundespost countered that operational experience with equipment was essential
for a network provider to be able to improve services. The Economics Ministry
pointed out, however, that the Bundespost could easily acquire equipment for
its own use and in that way gather operational experience. The Conference of
the State Economics Ministers took up this matter in 1978 and came out on the
side of the Federal Ministry of Economics. When that ministry conducted a
public "telefax-hearing" in August 1978, Siemens, the largest manufacturer,
favored a role of the Bundespost as equipment supplier.
The Ministry of Economics softened its position and demanded that (1) there
be a ceiling on market share of the DBF for telefax equipment at 15 percent
and (2) the DBF not be able to refuse its customers use of competing suppliers'
equipment. Eventually, the minister for posts and telecommunications agreed
but did not make a commitment to a specific percentage of market share, except
that it would not be a "market-dominating" position. In German cartel law
this terminology implies a share of less than 20 percent.
Equipment cases were a constant source of friction. Because much of the
terminal equipment was Bundespost owned, a slower rate of technological change
in the network and in terminal equipment was suspected, since the Bundespost
had to consider whether innovations would make its own equipment base ob-
solete. Under such an argument, network performance and design become the
prisoner of the existing terminal equipment base. But it is also true that change
in network performance could make much of the terminal equipment base ob-
solete, and that is an argument for an integrated provision of network and
terminal services.
In a study commissioned by the Monopoly Commission, three economists
Carl Christian von Weizsacker, Jurgen Miiller, and Giinter Kniepsargued that
the Bundespost's participation in terminal equipment was not a serious prob-
lem, because it already held a monopoly in telecommunications services, which
are closely complementary to equipment. Since the Bundespost did not produce
terminal equipment itself, it had an interest in seeing terminal equipment as
inexpensive and as widely distributed as possible, creating a positive contribu-
tion to its network monopoly. The terminal equipment was characterized by a
supplier oligopoly, which led to prices that were above cost. Therefore, the
participation of the Bundespost could lower prices; its large economies of scope
and scale allowed it to underprice the other market participants. Thus, the DBF
Germany 89
The Bundespost fiercely protected its equipment monopoly. At one time, its
advertising subsidiary informed potential customers of other advertising agen-
cies that the Bundespost's permission was necessary to affix a sticker contain-
ing an emergency number and an advertising message to the telephone set. The
competitors sued. The lower courts found that this behavior was an attempt to
extend the postal monopoly into the competitive realm.
This case corresponds to the American Hush-A-Phone decision, in which the
Bell System had similarly tried to prevent a trivial nonelectrical attachment to
its equipment but was rebuffed in court. In Germany, however, a 1980 court
decision accepted the prohibition of stickers on telephone equipment owned by
the Bundespost. "The prohibition of attaching stickers serves therefore the se-
curity and maintenance of an undisturbed telecommunications operation . .
(DBF, 1981, para. 76).
Despite (or because of) such defensive measures, pressures on the Bundes-
post grew. In 1981, the state economics ministers created a working commit-
tee, Deutsche Bundespost and Telecommunications Monopoly, and charged it
with proposing a modification of telecommunications equipment law. The pro-
posals asked for a DBF exclusion from equipment provision, except when tech-
nical, economic, and reasons of national economy, or other interests of society
required it. In 1982, partly because of diffuse criticism against its dual role of
supplier in competition with private firms and as the approval authority, the
DBF established a new central office for telecommunications licensing (ZZF)
with a semi-independent status and a location in Saarbriicken, at some distance
from the Bundespost establishment in Bonn and Darmstadt.
The DBF was slow to approve modems and similar devices. Until 1986 only
the DBF could sell modems. Its modem monopoly was broken after a 1985 EC
Commission intervention. Even after 1986, the DBF continued to drag its feet
on accepting the technical specifications approval of different modem suppliers.
It wanted data communication to use its public data networks. Similarly, up to
1989, the DBF would not allow standard fax boards on the telecommunications
network since it did not want the fax machines permanently connected (Pfeiffer
and Wieland, 1990, p. 84).
In 1982, the European Commission joined the chorus, issuing a complaint
against the DBF regarding modem and baseband equipment, citing it in viola-
tion of Articles 85 and 86 of the Treaty of Rome. European legal provisions
specifically, Articles 37, 85, 86, and 90have some applications to the behav-
ior of postal authorities. Article 37 requires member states of the European
Community to treat their trading and distribution monopolies so as to eliminate
potential discrimination among countries. This article has exceptions for rea-
sons of governmental function, security, and consumer protection. Article 90
applies competitive requirements to companies imbued with the public interest.
This area and the application of antimonopoly rules require much more judicial
clarification. (For an analysis, see Scherer, 1985, and Mestmacker, 1980). The
DBF subsequently modified its practices. In 1986, it also agreed that modems
could be sold by manufacturers directly to users rather than relying on the
bulky SEL or Siemens modems it had provided. These restrictions, coupled
Germany 91
with the Bundespost's own marketing, were important, since only 59,000 mo-
dems were in use in the entire country at the time, in comparison with 300,000
in the United Kingdom and 115,000 in France (Bruce, 1986). The decision had
to be made by the German Cabinet, so strong was the resistance of the Bun-
despost. The DBF, however, was left with the powers of setting standards and
approving all modems, an arrangement that could cause considerable delay.
(The firm Deutsche Fernsprecher Gesellschaft, for example, waited more than
a year before receiving approval for a modem). Furthermore, modems con-
nected to the Btx videotex service remained under Bundespost monopoly.
In 1985, the European Commission also forced the Bundespost to give up
its monopoly over cordless telephones. A Siemens cordless phone sold for $665,
whereas similar Japanese models cost $79 in the United States (Schares, 1989,
p. 137).
The American government, prodded by its industry, was critical of German
procurement practices. Negotiations over liberalization of the German telecom-
munications market reached some agreement about a reduced domestic orien-
tation by the Bundespost, as well as tenders that permitted a streamlining of
the approval process, greater ease for leased lines, and liberalized specifications
for PBXs.
As part of the 1989 reforms, Germany's equipment market, including first
sets, was officially liberalized on July 1, 1990. The Telecommunications In-
stallation Act (Fernmeldeanlagengesetz) specifies a "no harm to the network"
standard for type approvals.
Reform Debates
For a long time there was no public discussion of the Bundespost's role, in
marked contrast to the intense discussion in Germany over cable television and
media policy in general.
More than interest group politics is at work in Germany. The ideology of a
mixed economic system goes back a long time and has intellectual roots in an
important school of thought, Gemeinwirtschaftslehre (Public Economics), which
argues for government involvement in economic activities (Thiemeyer, 1983;
Snow, 1983). The Gemeinwirtschaftslehre goes back to Adolph Wagner, who,
in "Wagner's law," postulated the necessary growth of the public sector (Wag-
ner, 1887).9
Reform discussions of German postal affairs are not new; organized attempts
to study the system and recommend reforms go back at least to 1579, when
Emperor Rudolf II appointed a blue-ribbon panel (including representatives of
large postal users and financial institutions) to report on the Thurn and Taxis
postal monopoly. Four hundred years later similar questions were still being
studied. In 1969 a commission was set up to investigate the organization and
role of the Bundespost. The panel proposed the separation of political supervi-
sion from management of the Bundespost and recommended that a presiding
body of five, without the traditional civil service status, manage the PTT in the
92 Germany
maintenance of the existing policy, it did so typically as the lesser of the evils,
and rarely without a fairly negative analysis of the existing system.
The leading spirit behind the report was Professor Ernst-Joachim Mest-
macker, who served at the time as the commission's chairman. He thought it a
"mercantilistic view of the state" to believe that the public interest is ade-
quately served by a monopoly enterprise simply because it is the state that
operates it (Mestmacker, 1980, p. 196).
The Monopoly Commission concluded that economies of scale were not par-
ticularly important for the connection of network and terminal equipment but
that the DBF's involvement with the terminal equipment market had negative
effects for market structure and competition. The commission also determined
that the argument of natural monopoly had to be doubted, based on the Amer-
ican experience, particularly in long-distance communications. However, it was
better, at least for a while, not to go ahead with a development of parallel
network infrastructure, given the necessary large investment. But the commis-
sion held that specialized, privately supplied value added services should be
permitted on Bundespost facilities. Direct network competition could be per-
mitted with the development of technology, in case of a potential deterioration
of DBF services, and a reduction of internal subsidies to some of the DBF's
services. Given its own scathing criticism of the existing arrangement, the com-
mission's policy conclusions were somewhat modest and probably represented
an adjustment to the political realities.
Also in 1981, the German Bundestag, in a major effort to formulate public
policy in this field, created an Inquiry Commission on New Information and
Communications Technologies. The commission had as its mandate the explo-
ration of all international aspects of the new technologies. The major political
parties appointed their communications experts to the commission. For ex-
ample, the Christian Democrat representative was Christian Schwarz-Schilling,
who soon thereafter became minister for post and telecommunications. The
parties also appointed seven nonparliamentary experts from the outside, includ-
ing Wolfgang Hoffmann-Riem, a law professor and head of the media research
center Hans-Bredow Institut in Hamburg.
The commission was active in its two years of existence. But the heavy party
politicization of media issues which is prevalent in Germany as in much of
Europe, prevented constructive proceedings. Another set of conflicts existed
between the commission and the federal states. During the commission's ten-
ure, the government changed hands, and elections were held sooner than ex-
pected. No final report could be agreed upon by the deeply divided commis-
sion. A lengthy preliminary report was supported by parts of the commission
and eventually printed as a publication of the German parliament. The report
reflects what must have been frustrating proceedings. Dissenting opinions, even
on purported factual matters, appear frequently, as do references to the lack of
agreement on many of the questions. Even on the simple statement that tech-
nologies not only provide "opportunities" but also "could lead to dangers,"
the commission could find no agreement. The commission discussed the liber-
94 Germany
that the Federal Republic lagged far behind in the number of public telephones,
with 162,000 compared with the 1.7 million in the US and 828,000 in Japan,
and that it had for a long time no itemized billing, cordless phones, call-wait-
ing, call-forwarding, etc." (Moschel, 1988, p. 3).
In 1984, the government published another report to serve as a conceptual
document for the advancement of information technology. The report, Regi-
erungsbericht Informationstechnik 1984, stressed the importance of govern-
mental initiative in order to keep German information technology competitive
(Lange, 1984).
In the 1980s, even the Social Democratic Party, which had faithfully sup-
ported the Bundespost monopoly, began to criticize its rate of upgrading of the
network. Its General Secretary, Peter Glotz, himself a media expert, criticized
the Bundespost's low level of investment in digital switching (Glotz, 1983),
and urged a rapid development of the Bundespost networks. As Glotz asserted,
if no modern public networks would be offered, private networks would emerge
on leased lines, which would provide the same efficiency benefits, but would
be less sensitive to social politics and other requirements such as data protec-
tion.
Partly in response to pressure for liberalization from the United States and the
European Community, a commission was established in 1985 to make recom-
mendations for the reform of telecommunications policy. The panel, chaired
by Eberhard Witte of Munich University, who had also headed the KtK, was
composed of twelve members who represented the four major parties and a
spectrum of economic interests. From the beginning, the commission was sub-
ject to criticism. To some it was a threat to the established order; to others it
was a legitimization of minimalist reform steps which largely served the Bun-
despost's interests. It took almost one year to set up the panel, and another two
and one-half years until it produced its report in September 1987.
Internally, the commission was split in various ways. The free market or
liberal wing consisted of the Free Democratic Party representatives, a law pro-
fessor, the banks' representative, and the president of the Federal Associate of
German Industry. In the past, the telecommunications industry interests had
generally defined the position of the German industry association. The orien-
tation of the association's president was thus significant, because it indicated
that users and other electronic firms' interests had gained in importance and
influence.
The traditionalist wing consisted of the trade unionist, the Social Democratic
delegate, and in key questions, the representative of the Bavarian Christian
Democrats. That conservative party favored the status quo, because it wished
to satisfy its large rural population, and perhaps because Munich was the head-
quarters of Siemens, which also did not wish to see an upheaval in well-estab-
lished relations.
96 Germany
The commission was split six to six over the key question of whether to
permit competition in physical networks. Chairman Witte, who had two votes,
elected not to break the tie, which was likely to have been in favor of network
competition, for pragmatic reasons: Even if a majority had recommended such
competition, the minority would have included the representatives of three of
the four major parties, representing more than 80 percent of the parliamentary
deputies. Political realities had to be taken into account if the recommendations
were to be adopted. The economically liberal opponents believed that the rec-
ommendations had to reflect what was best, not just what was most realistic
politically. The approach ultimately taken by the commission majority on this
issue was to initiate a process and then to expect its dynamics to lead in future
development. Thus, it recommended a number of modest pro-competitive steps
that would, in time, its majority hoped, obtain a momentum of their own and
lead to a more significant change in German telecommunications.
It is important to note that the commission found that the existing telecom-
munications monopoly was not enshrined in, or protected by, the German Basic
Law. Structurally, it recommended a separation of telecommunications from
postal services, and a separation of "sovereign tasks," or regulation, from the
entrepreneurial tasks of organization. It recommended that regulatory tasks be
vested in the ministry and others reside with operational organization Deutsche
Telekom, which would have greater operational and legal independence. Deutsche
Telekom would also have greater flexibility in compensation, payment meth-
ods, and deployment of labor. Deutsche Telekom would retain its monopoly
on the basic network and on voice telephony. But data, text, and other non-
voice communications would be open to competition from the private sector,
using the Telekom network. It would also lose its monopoly on the basic tele-
phone set, and the terminal equipment market would be fully liberalized. The
commission also proposed that tariffs be set by the Ministry of Communica-
tions and be more in line with costs, thus eliminating tariff distortions. Greater
freedom would be granted in the interconnection of leased lines with switched
service. In a departure from existing controversial practice for leased lines,
Telekom would develop a tariff structure not based on volume-sensitive charges.
Satellite-delivered slow-speed data would be opened to transmission by others,
another first.
The commission also recommended that the government reevaluate market
conditions every three years, with the option of permitting the establishment of
competing networks if the market was not developing satisfactorily (Witte, 1987).
The commission thus provided, at least rudimentally, for a previously missing
mechanism of policy change.
Most of the recommendations were accepted by PTT Minister Schwartz-
Schilling and by the government in a somewhat more restrictive bill. It rejected
a conditional DBF monopoly but allowed the following: value-added services,
a second cellular network, usage-sensitive leased-line tariffs, liberalized termi-
nal equipment, liberalized type approval, slow-speed satellite service for data,
and limited resale. It imposed special obligations on private carriers (Moschel,
1988, p. 17). But the new telecommunications organization was not to be fully
Germany 97
freed under its own board of directors, and its name was slightly but pointedly
changed to DBF Telekomindicating its ties to the Bundepost. It must con-
tribute 10 percent of income to the Federal budget. (The total that the DBF
paid to the government through its annual contribution in 1988 amounted to
5.25 billion DM, approximately 10 percent of its annual income). After the
reforms, the three different sectors of the DBF are subject to taxes, as if they
were private enterprises. Furthermore, an "infrastructure council" with mixed
state-federal membership was established to respond to the desire of several
states to have input into telecommunications policy and to address their fear of
neglect by a profit-oriented Telekom.
After bitter debates and opposition by the trade unions, the Law on Restruc-
turing the Bundespost passed on July 1, 1989.
The objective of the 1989 reform was to eliminate the structural conflict
between the regulatory and the production activities of the DBF and to encour-
age participation and competition from the private sector for new services and
hardware. To accomplish this, a separation of responsibilities was mandated.
Managerial responsibilities over the PTT were taken away from the Ministry of
Posts and Telecommunications, so that the ministry could in the future concen-
trate on regulatory issues without any conflict of interest. The ministry, which
would retain cabinet representation, would now set and implement standards,
establish access rules, allocate spectrum, license entrants, and so on.
The 1989 Reform (the Poststrukturgesetz) created three distinct public cor-
porations, for telecommunications, for postal service, and for the PTT's tradi-
tional financial services. Each of these corporations would have its own board
of directors, its own published balance statements, and its own organizational
structure. Further, these new entities would have the legal responsibilities of
private corporations to their customers and suppliers, rather than their previous
protection of being part of the German state.
The chairpersons of each of these distinct entities meet in a single Deutsche
Bundespost directorate, which is responsible for consolidating the individual
balance sheets of the different PTT entities, coordinating service between the
different groups, and handling joint labor compensation issues. Each of these
entities, however, was still required to make a profit on its own.
The staff members of the new operating entities are still civil servants, and
as such retain their traditional protections from dismissal. It remains difficult
to reward employees for merit.
The telecommunications entity, DBF Telekom, retained exclusive right to all
voice transmission. Since this service amounts to 90 percent of all the telecom-
munications business in Germany, it is still in control of the most important
and profitable sector. Further, in part because of monopoly conditions, it can
charge above cost for these services. The rationale for allowing DBF Telekom
such profit was that it would be able to invest this money into infrastructural
changes, including fiber optics and to cross-subsidize service to more remote
regions in the country.
No alternative physical network can be set up except under very special
circumstances (internal use of public administration or transportation concerns,
98 Germany
or between singly owned parcels of land no more than 25 kilometers away from
any of the other parcels of land). Many users complained that the new law still
allowed DBF Telekom to move slowly in servicing their needs. In response,
Schwartz-Schilling drafted stronger legislation in 1990 aimed at reducing DBF
Telekom's ability to block competitors with limited access and high tariffs.
Competition for nonvoice transmission began shortly thereafter. Germany
already had 185,000 cellular subscribers in 1989, connected to .DBF's then
monopoly service. But in May 1989 the government solicited bids for the con-
struction of a second (D2) cellular network, based on the European GSM stan-
dard. Several American firmsNYNEX (with BT and Daimler-Benz), Bell
South (with Siemens, Olivetti, and Shearson-Lehman-Hutton), and Pacific Te-
lesis (with Mannesmann and Deutsche Genossenschaftbank)sought licenses.
Mannesmann, a large steel and engineering conglomerate, led the winning con-
sortium, but its service was delayed by a year of negotiations with DBF Tele-
kom over interconnection and carriage tariffs. A third and digital, in principle,
mobile telephone network was decided upon in 1991.
In 1991, the ministry granted 22 companies licenses for private satellite net-
works that did not interconnect with the public network. Services above 15
kbps required special approval. Most systems are, at least in part, over the 15
kbps threshold. Licenses were also awarded for paging and radio data.
Although it is important to note the DBF's new services, a perspective must
be kept. Most of the DBF's telecommunication revenues derived from tradi-
tional telephone service. Of the DM 38.4 billion of telecommunications reve-
nue, traditional telephone service made up DM 34.2 billion, or 90 percent.
Data services (including videotex) and telegraph were DM 2.67 billion (7 per-
cent), and radio and other telecommunications sources were DM 1.5 billion.
Of the data service figure, 40 percent was earned by leased lines (Pfeiffer and
Wieland, 1990, p. 11), until rates were drastically rebalanced.
owned company of the type that predominated in the German Democratic Re-
public's centralized economy.) The MPF also controlled the "Kombinat Na-
chrichtenelektronik," a state cartel that organized and directed all fourteen of
the VEBs that manufactured telecommunications equipment. In addition, the
Minister headed a government commission that coordinated the various state-
owned networks and directed their interconnection with the public network, and
the MPF controlled a public frequency commission that oversaw the allocation
of radio spectrum space.
In addition to its telecommunications services, the DP provided extensive
postal services, such as distribution, billing and marketing for all newspapers
and magazines. It also was responsible for radio and television receivers and
transmission stations, as well as all studio production equipment. The PTT's
control over public communication was so extensive that if individuals needed
a microphone for any public purpose, they had to rent it from the PTT (Neu-
mann, 1990).
Before 1989, the telecommunications equipment industry had been under the
control of a manufacturing industry ministry. Under that arrangement, the PTT
was forced to report its investment requirements to a central planning bureau-
cracy that allocated resources based on its own political priorities instead of on
the needs of the telecommunications sector. Telecommunications services were
considered a nonproductive part of the economy and were thus assigned a low
priority. Conversely, equipment export was a high priority, and approximately
75% of all telecommunications goods were sent abroad, especially to other East
European countries. In 1989, the telecommunications industry was put under
the control of the MPF in a controversial effort to improve economic perfor-
mance and turn its productive capacity to domestic uses (Neumann, 1990).
The 1985 Law on Posts and Telecommunications gave the state the exclusive
right to provide postal and telecommunications services. While some leased
line networks were operated by businesses that had obtained waivers to do so
from the MPF, the only nonpublic telecommunications systems were those op-
erated by the army and the police. All terminal equipment was provided by the
PTT, except for a small number of PBXs that received a special waiver. There
was no private telecommunications equipment market.
Although the GDR had one of the most advanced telephone systems in the
Eastern Bloc, the infrastructure was inadequate and outdated. There were only
very basic services. In 1965, there were 1.6 million telephones, with a waiting
list of 84,000 people. The waiting list for phones grew to 660,000 in 1983 (A.
Rutkowski, 1990, communication; Kelly, 1990, Figure 2). By 1990, there were
1.8 million main exchange lines, twice as many as 1969, serving 4 million
telephones. Nevertheless, only one out of seven households had a phone, and
party lines were common. Moreover, the few residential phones available were
unevenly distributed. In East Berlin, 50 per cent of homes had service, while
in other cities, such as Dresden, only one out of nine homes had service. By
1990, the official waiting list was approximately 1.2 million people (almost as
many people as had telephones), and was growing twice as fast as installed
main lines. At the previously planned rate of construction, the backlog would
100 Germany
have taken at least ten to fourteen years to fill (U.S. Department of State, 1990,
p. 51); some estimates suggest as much as a twenty year delay. Moreover, as
in many Eastern European countries, the list probably did not include discour-
aged potential users.
Telegrams were a significant form of public communication. In 1965, 8 mil-
lion domestic and 3 million international telegrams were sent from 6000 telex
connections. In 1989, those figures were 11 million and 3 million telegrams,
respectively, and 18,000 telex connections.
The East German network structure prior to unification was composed of
1,500 local networks, 2,700 local switching centers, and 182 switching centers
at the trunk level. While almost all of the main exchange lines were connected
to automatic exchanges, just 20 per cent could be switched automatically for
international calls. Almost a quarter of the local and trunk switches were an-
cient, installed between 1922 and 1934, while 42.6 per cent were installed in
1950. Another 28.1 per cent were installed between 1963 and 1965. Part of
the switching system was so old that it had already been fully depreciated more
than twice. At the local and trunk levels, the switches were analog and electro-
mechanical; 25 per cent of all East German switches were crossbar. Most of
the transmission system was analog, although since the mid-seventies PCM-
systems were used. Fiber optic cable amounted to less than 1 percent of the
transmission network.
The network could barely support facsimile and data transmission, and there
was neither a circuit-switched nor packet-switched data network. The first mo-
dem use was reported in 1969 when eight modems were put on line. By 1983
there were 500. There was an operator-assisted data network that connected
1,500 subscribers, and another 3000 subscribers leased lines for data transmis-
sion. (The PTT had planned to build a packet-switched network since the
mid-eighties and had signed an agreement with Siemens to do so, but CoCom
restrictions on the packet-switching technology prevented the project.) As a
result, only a few hundred fax machines and modems were in use before uni-
fication, while over 10,000 prospective subscribers were on the waiting list for
data connections. Mobile and value added services were unavailable. There
were 18,000 telex connections, transmitting text at 50 bps over thirty to forty
year-old technology, and 3,000 data circuits with a capacity of 2.5 kbps (Gart-
ner and Habenicht, 1990, p. 13). The only well-developed part of the telecom-
munications network was that operated by the GDR's secret police for surveil-
lance and domestic control (Hafner, 1990).
The German political unification in 1990 created an urgent need to upgrade
East Germany's antiquated infrastructure. In December, 1989, a Joint Govern-
ment Commission was created by the East and West German governments to
manage the process of unification for all aspects of telecommunications. The
government of Prime Minister Hans Modrow, still a Communist party official,
decided to shift the PTT toward financial independence from the government
and make it a public enterprise. By early 1990, the MPF concluded that it
would move toward the West German organizational structure in an effort to
secure necessary support. In March 1990, a non-Communist East German gov-
Germany 101
ernment was elected. Soon thereafter, it replaced the old PTT structure with
three public enterprises along the same lines as West Germany.
Simultaneous with the negotiations on economic and currency union, the
East and West German Ministers of Posts and Telecommunications negotiated
a Joint Declaration that outlined the plan for integration. Targets were for the
East German network to be on par with West Germany's by 1997. DBF Tele-
kom planned to install 7.3 million new subscriber lines, 10 million miles of
fiber-optic and copper cable, 68,000 public phones, 360,000 facsimile connec-
tions, and 50,000 packet-switched connections by that time, and add 2000 dig-
ital central office switches. The newly united PTT planned to add 100,000 East
German subscribers in 1990, 300,000 in 1991 and over a million annually
thereafter. In contrast, the growth rate before unification had been approxi-
mately 60,000 subscribers per year. In addition, DBP Telekom, which needed
to rely on satellite and cellular services to accommodate the extra load as the
landlines were being installed, planned to add 300,000 mobile phone connec-
tions. The quick availability of cellular service relieved some of the pressure
on the standard network, which experienced a 500 percent increase in traffic
within eight weeks following unification (Hafner, 1990; Gartner and Habenicht,
1990).
Before unification, consideration was very briefly given to the possibility of
privatizing the PTT. While such a move could be done fairly straightforwardly
through legislation (as opposed to the situation in West Germany, where pri-
vatizing the DBP would probably require a constitutional amendment), this
option was not pursued. The interest in unifying the East and West German
systems took precedence. Instead, the Eastern DP was merged into the Western
entity. Almost all employees were retained (the exceptions were primarily the
numerous secret police workers within the PTT whose major function was to
wiretap calls and open letters).
Another option was to operate the East German network as a separate re-
gional company interconnected with the Western DBP Telekom. Such an ar-
rangement would have made the transfer of investment funds and expertise
from the West to the East more difficult, though creative alternatives could
have been devised. But the tradition of national monopoly was too strong for
such an option to be seriously considered.
The merger of East Germany's telephone system into DBP Telekom was not
a smooth one. Soon, East Germany's 130,000 postal and telecommunications
employees went on strike for a more rapid equalization of pay levels. DBP
Telekom, meanwhile, was asked by the government to contribute an additional
1.3 billion annually to the federal budget for four years, to help pay for the
general cost of unification. This was beyond the substantial amounts that were
needed to upgrade East Germany's telecommunications. It was also difficult to
move West German technical employees to the East, where their skills in dig-
ital communications were needed. Another problem was how to integrate the
two dozen East German private networks, a legacy of the GDR's separate min-
isterial and state industries' systems, into the national system. One of them was
acquired by the West German chemical industry for its own use. Service up-
102 Germany
grade in the East was slow, leading to some calls in the East for the entry of
alternative service providers. In an effort to speed up development, the govern-
ment initiated turnkey projects in which SEL, Bosch, DeTeWe, Deutsche
Aerospace AG (Daimler-Benz), and Siemens would construct full-scale local
networks in various cities. These substantial burdens gave ammunition to those
traditionalists in the Bundepost and the Ministry who had never been happy
about liberalization, and who could argue for slowing down its pace. Indeed,
had German unification burst upon the scene only one year earlier than it did,
it is probable that the entire Bundespost reform would have been put on hold.
The Monopoly Commission in Bonn, on the other hand, looking at the same
set of problems, advocated the relaxation of monopoly to accelerate the devel-
opment in the East. Thus, the old controversies continued.
In 1991, DBF Telekom invested about $4 billion in eastern Germany, and
anticipated the need for an additional $100 billion before the year 2000. These
huge financial demands took place at the same time that revenue-eroding lib-
eralization was being introduced by the telecommunications ministry for ter-
minal equipment, value-added and mobile services, interconnection of private
leased-line networks, satellite data, and even resale and switching. The com-
pany was also criticized for having some of Europe's highest rates for leased
lines.
DBF Telekom, run by Helmut Ricke, a manager hired from outside the or-
ganization, responded with a massive rebalancing of tariffs, systematically re-
ducing leased-line and long-distance rates, and raising rates for local service.
It moved into value-added services, forming a joint venture with IBM. Still,
the company was limited by law from certain activities, for example, directly
offering service in the newly opened countries of Eastern and Central Europe.
In consequence, the government in 1992 gave serious consideration to changing
DBF Telekom's status, and privatizing up to 49 percent of its shares through
an international offering. Such plans, unthinkable only a few years earlier,
demonstrate how far the dynamics of change have taken hold in transforming
Heinrich von Stefan's monolithic state instutition.
8
The United Kingdom
103
104 The United Kingdom
that private management would increase efficiency and permit easier access to
capital markets. Run as a public corporation since 1969, BT was subject to
restrictive rules on borrowing, and had to self-finance approximately 90 percent
of its investments, an extremely high rate (Department of Industry, 1982). By
1982, after two years of energetic prodding, BT's per capita investment was
still only two-thirds that of France's and just over half that of West Germany,
and revenue per employee was $4200, compared with $4900 in France, $6200
in West Germany and $7900 in the United States (Journal of Commerce, 1983).
A second telecommunications bill was introduced in 1982 to implement the
privatization goals of the White Paper. Although the bill was not immediately
passed because of the general election, it was reintroduced after the Conserva-
tives formed the new government.
As part of the privatization terms, the government forgave or assumed 2.9
billion of BT's long-term debts and shouldered pension obligations of 1.25
billion. Together, 4.15 billion of liabilities were taken off BT's books, a huge
amount in relation to the 4 billion for which 51 percent of the entire enterprise
was sold.
One of the major obstacles to privatizing BT was its sheer size. The sale of
BT for about 4 billion accounted for 30 percent more than the total amount
raised for all U.K. companies in 1983, itself a ten-year high. It was therefore
feared that the floating of BT shares would disrupt the capital markets. This
led briefly to the suggestion of an AT&T-style divestiture whereby BT would
be sold in parts, either by functionlocal, long-distance, international, and
business servicesor along geographic lines, or both. Prime Minister Thatcher
allegedly favored this idea for a brief time. In the end, 51 percent of an undi-
vided BT was offered to the public. To assure the success of the issue, the
government chose a fairly low share price. Opponents argued that the Tory
strategy was to make it expensive and unpopular for the next government to
renationalize BT. The Labour opposition called for a renationalization, to be
financed by an exchange of shares for nonvoting bonds; their initial price would
be the stock issuing price and would thus not reflect appreciation of shares.
And an appreciation there was. On the first day of its public offering, the
price of BT's shares almost doubled. But the success of the public offering also
had its cost in terms of subsequent policy flexibility, because it created a large
constituency opposed to deregulatory actions which might reduce BT's profit-
ability.
Prior to privatization, British Telecom had almost a quarter of a million
employees, most of whom belonged to one of BT's several labor unions. The
largest of these was the National Communications Union (NCU)formerly the
Post Office Engineering Union (POEU); others include the Union of Com-
munications Workers, the Society of Telecom Executives, and several smaller
unions.
BT's unions strongly opposed privatization and competition. Their opposi-
tion was based on fears that labor would bear the brunt of the 25 percent cost
savings that BT's chairman, Sir George Jefferson, publicly projected for the
first three-year period. The unions also felt that opening the market to compel-
106 The United Kingdom
ing networks was a step toward eroding BT's monopoly position and profits,
in which they indirectly shared. They also stressed the negative impact on res-
idential service and R&D and feared a change in their civil servant status.
Consequently, the unions fought the licensing of a competing carrier and staged
work protests against the new company. Union fears proved not unfounded. In
its first year as a private company, BT reduced its staff by 17,000 employees,
mostly by attrition. However, although the number of BT's employees de-
clined, its total labor costs increased (Oftel, 1985a).
BT's unions argued that the government should reestablish the monopoly
over the trunk network and the first telephone set, integrate Mercury into BT
at market value, and, most importantly, maintain control of 75 percent of the
company's shares. They also advocated filling 50 percent of BT's board with
employee representatives, with other directors coming from consumer organi-
zations, other industries, major users, and the government.
authority to set rates and can only make recommendations. However, almost
from the beginning Oftel has expanded the scope of its investigation into rate
issues under its mandate to assure the provision of "good services to consum-
ers" and to insure that BT does not abuse its monopoly power.
Oftel supervises existing licensees and makes recommendations on applica-
tions for new licenses. Licensees include British Telecom; Hull Telephone
Company, the only independent local telephone company; Mercury, the new
long-distance carrier; Cable & Wireless, its parent, with many international
involvements; value-added networks; Vodaphone and Cellnet, the cellular ser-
vice companies; and other telecommunication service providers.
Despite Oftel's activity, the Department of Trade and Industry has retained
significant authority over telecommunications, including spectrum allocations,
cable television, technical licensed satellites, and resale of BT capacity (S.
Littlechild, communication, 1989). Customer and manufacturer concerns are
also channeled to Oftel through Advisory Committees on Telecommunications
in England, Scotland, and Wales (Manning, 1988).
Consumer and advocacy organizations have criticized Oftel's powers to pro-
tect consumers as inadequate, claiming that Oftel can only require BT or other
communications carriers to respond to grievances. Actually, Oftel can also sue
in court or alter and amend the operating license; and although Oftel's power
to protect consumers directly may be limited, they are far larger than those of
the earlier consumer protection body, POUNC, which had a primarily consul-
tative role. But Oftel's procedure is not open to the public when it comes to
information. British Telecom, for example, was not required to make public
the information on revenues, profits, costs, and quality performance that was
provided to Oftel for a determination of its price formula.
Bryan Carsberg, a professor of accounting at the London School of Econom-
ics, was appointed as the first director general of Oftel in 1984.' Carsberg
established a more active supervision over the telecommunications industry than
many expected, helping, for example, to prevent a venture between BT and
IBM on value-added networks, forcing an interconnection policy on BT that
was favorable to Mercury, and requiring BT to change its accounting system
to make it more possible to detect cross-subsidization. However, Oftel drew
criticism when it involved itself in BT's procurement practices. Carsberg rec-
ommended that BT's purchase of digital exchanges from a second source
("System X") be limited to 20 percent, for at least three years. This looked
like a protectionist measure that favored the "System X" of the British firms
GEC and Plessey. In public, BT rejected Carsberg's "recommendation" for a
voluntary purchase quota, though as a practical political matter it went along
with the allocation.
One important initial decision involved the basic choice of regulatory tech-
nique (Littlechild, 1983a). An interministerial working group recommended
linking the BT license to a maximum rate of return on capital and a specific
rate of return for the local, long-distance, and international services, with a
share of excess profits returned to consumers. As long as the rates of return
were not exceeded, specific prices would not be subject to control. The U.S.
108 The United Kingdom
With British liberalization, Cable & Wireless (C&W) became one of the most
interesting telecommunications carriers in the world. Until the 1980s, it was a
sleepy postcolonial governmental enterprise. But thereafter it became the first
truly global telephone company, linking the world's major trading centers.
C&W, which was nationalized in 1947, used to operate Britain's interna-
tional telegraph service as well as telecommunications services in many of Brit-
ain's overseas possessions. After decolonialization, the company continued to
operate domestic public telecommunication services in more than two dozen
countries, and the international communications of 37 countries. Many of C&W's
overseas operations were joint ventures with local governments or local private
interests.
In 1981, the Conservative government privatized more than half of the com-
pany; in 1985, the remainder of C&W was sold in the second largest stock sale
in British history after the BT sale earlier that year.
Privatization made it possible for C&W to expand rapidly and aggressively.
As a government company it needed Treasury approval to spend more than 10
million, but as a private firm it could freely invest in new projects. C&W's
profits increased rapidly from 90 million on sales of 500 million in 1981, to
360 million on revenues of 1.3 billion in 1985 and 500 million in revenues
of 2.2 billion in 1990.
The centerpiece of C&W's operations and profits is in Hong Kong, where it
operates the franchise for international telephony and holds a controlling inter-
110 The United Kingdom
est in the Hong Kong Telephone Company, of which it sold a 20 percent share
in 1989. The firm also has an agreement with the People's Republic of China
to upgrade the Chinese telecommunications network in the nearby provinces,
in Beijing, and in the Yangtze Delta, and has a 49 percent interest in the
Shenda telephone company in a Chinese special economic zone next to Hong
Kong. C&W also owns 75 percent of telephone operations in Macao and op-
erates international and domestic service in Bahrain, the commercial center of
the Persian Gulf region, through a firm in which it has a 40 percent interest.
In 1990, C&W had operations in forty-eight nations, including most Caribbean
countries.
In the United States, C&W operates through TDX Systems and has become
the fourth largest long-distance company. Another C&W activity is its joint
venture PTAT for a private submarine fiber-optic cable between the United
Kingdom and the United States. C&W also participates in the trans-Pacific
cable venture IDC, and increased its share to 17 percent. It is also represented
in domestic Japanese service through Fair-way. These pieces fit together as part
of a strategy to link the four major financial centers in the worldLondon,
New York, Tokyo, and Hong Kongwith Bahrain and Singapore as additional
link-up possibilities. Aside from the PTAT and North Pacific cables, C&W also
backed the Asiasat project and co-won a mobile license in Germany (Cable &
Wireless, 1990, p. 8). C&W also entered in 1991 telecommunications in Swe-
den through the first competing public network service. Tele2 AB was owned
40 percent by Cable & Wireless and 60 percent by Kinnevik, and used fiber
lines belonging to the Swedish railroad. C&W also established facilities man-
agement centers in continental Europe.
Mercury
In the U.K., C&W is the sole owner of Mercury, the alternative to BT in long-
distance service. Originally, C&W's partners in Mercury were British Petro-
leum and Barclay's Merchant Bank. Although Mercury was modeled on the
U.S. company MCI, there are great differences between the two. Whereas MCI
was a small, maverick firm that entered the market by prevailing in court over
the opposition of both AT&T and the federal authorities, Mercury was born
with three silver spoons in its mouth and the government as its godparent.
Mercury emerged through a classic insider deal rather than on the basis of
competitive bidding. Furthermore, because the Conservative government staked
the credibility of its telecommunications on Mercury's effectiveness, it pro-
tected the company by giving it an exclusive license to compete with BT until
1990. There are, however, similarities to MCI. Both initially stated that their
intention was only to provide limited service offerings, in particular leased
lines, aimed at users underserved by the monopoly. However, their ambitions
grew rapidly, and they sought to gain many additional customers by intercon-
necting into the public network and by providing switched public domestic and
international long-distance service.
Mercury's intentions raised the stakes for BT considerably. To both BT and
The United Kingdom 111
AT&T it seemed unfair that they should be required to let competitors use their
carefully nurtured local distribution network. The notion of common carriage,
however, is based on the premise that service must be provided to anyone who
pays the posted price. Although British Telecom was understandably not enthu-
siastic about its new competition, Mercury's presence provided the basis for
further liberalization of BT's operations, which was a positive prospect for the
large company.
After Mercury's initial license was granted in 1982, it quickly established a
microwave network service within London, and connected this network by dig-
ital microwave with Birmingham and Manchester. It also began construction
of a national fiber-optic trunk system centered in Birmingham. In London it
made substantial use of subway tunnels and acquired rights to lay cable through
the underground cable network of the London Hydraulic Power Company.
Mercury, as a subsidiary of C&W with its substantial international presence,
also established itself abroad. In 1983, it received permission to provide inter-
national service. In 1984, transatlantic service to the United States was intro-
duced. In 1987, Mercury also penetrated the continental European market when
it arranged to exchange public telecommunications traffic with Italy. This was
troublesome for BT, which derived about 20 percent of its profits from inter-
national service.
To meet its switching equipment needs, Mercury went outside the traditional
British manufacturers GEC and Plessey to Northern Telecom in Canada. In
1986, Mercury entered an agreement with the largest domestic computer com-
pany, ICL (through their parents C&W and STC), for a joint venture in spe-
cialized data communications and value-added services.
Although Mercury's regular license, granted in 1984, is similar to British
Telecom's, it has several important differences: (1) Mercury does not have to
fulfill BT's universal service obligations; (2) it does not operate a full national
system and is under no obligation to do so; (3) it cannot provide maritime
services other than for offshore installations; and (4) it is not price regulated.
Mercury started its public switched operations in Britain on May 15, 1986,
with long-distance rates that were about 15 to 20 percent lower than BT's,
despite the latter's anticipatory tariff reductions. Mercury's goal was to reach a
5 percent market share by 1990 (about 8 billion) and a much larger share of
large user business.
By 1987, 37 percent of major telecommunications users in Britain were us-
ing Mercury for some of their service. Of eighteen financial institutions in the
City, seventeen became Mercury customers. The share of large users in BT
revenues is about 30 percent. It was not merely a matter of price: large users
were seeking to be less dependent on one supplier, an important factor in a
country as prone to strikes as Britain. But when it came to small and medium-
sized users Mercury was lagging.
BT's primary leverage over Mercury is through interconnection into its local
distribution network, and the regulatory determination of that interconnection
relation is therefore critical. The question of how much BT can charge Mercury
involves murky conceptual and accounting issues. Additionally, technical as-
112 The United Kingdom
pects such as the numbering system, the points of interconnection, the quality
of service, the number of digits to be dialed, and so on, have to be considered.
BT has some reasons to be less than fully cooperative, and Mercury has an
incentive to cry wolf and seek an advantageous interconnection arrangement.
Without a period of protection, Mercury argues, it could not compete with BT,
and its failure would undermine the entire base of government pro-competition
policy. It would be embarrassing (at least for the Conservatives) to see Mercury
fail. One government minister commented:
If we opened up to free competition, there is a danger that British Telecom would
be able to wipe the floor with all the tiny competitors. We think the method of
introducing a little competition begins with the Mercury rival network. It is our
duty to look after Mercury, to nurse it. (Jason, 1985, p. 4)
Hence, Mercury has a certain leverage over British policy makers that is dis-
proportionate to its economic power. With a Labour government in power, the
reverse is possible and Mercury could be choked to death by "technical" reg-
ulatory decisions rather than by decisions debated and passed by Parliament.
The problem of interconnection, and the respective licenses of BT and Mer-
cury, came before Oftel. In 1985, Bryan Carsberg decided on a framework for
the interconnection of Mercury and BT, a ruling that was considered a major
success for Mercury. The ruling stipulated that BT had to provide Mercury
with local interconnections at both ends of a telephone connection, set the com-
pensation that Mercury must pay BT, and established a time schedule of pay-
ment for one-half of the cost of providing the additional capacity. BT must also
provide full international interconnections for Mercury.
The issue of fair interconnection is complicated. In the United States it has
led to two decades of dispute and was a major issue leading to the AT&T
divestiture. The Justice Department, and with it Judge Harold Greene, con-
cluded that one could not expect a local monopoly to provide genuinely non-
discriminating access to its long-distance competitors. The divestiture estab-
lished the principle of complete and equal access and allowed users to choose
a "primary long-distance carrier." But the question of the cost for such access
to the local network, whether by AT&T or by its competitors, precipitated
fierce battles between long-distance carriers and local exchange companies, and
among long-distance carriers themselves.
The issues are hardly trivial. The total of access charge payments that long-
distance companies must pay to the local exchange companies can comprise
more than half of their entire revenues; they are also a major source of revenue
for local exchange companies (Noam, 1986). In the United States, according
to some calculations, the actual cost of access to the local company was ap-
proximately $0.03 per minute, but charges to the long-distance carrier were
between $0.07 and $0.08 per minute. This substantial gap exists because, in
most views, long-distance calling has subsidized local telephony. In a compet-
itive environment, a substantial markup for access above cost creates an incen-
tive for long-distance carriers to "bypass" the local public switched network
entirely and reach users directly. Especially for large users it begins to make
The United Kingdom 113
economic sense to lease local circuits from the local telephone carrier to the
long-distance carrier, which are not governed by the access line charges, or to
create communication links entirely outside of the local telephone network.
At the heart of this complex matter is the question of the allocation of the
joint costs, largely of a fixed nature, that are incurred to make the provision of
both local and long-distance services possible. Conceptually and practically,
the allocation between the two types of services is difficult, and in some views,
arbitrary. After much dispute, the FCC decided to resolve this problem by
imposing a flat-rate "user charge" to be borne by end users. In theory, this
charge would be partially offset by lower long-distance charges, as carriers
would pass on their savings from reduced access charges to end users. The
economic logic was that since flat-rate user charges were not usage sensitive,
users could not avoid them by decreasing the number of telephone calls they
made through the local public switched network. Hence, it would reduce the
incentive for "uneconomic" (i.e., purely regulation-induced) bypass.
A related question is whether a differentiated access charge should be set for
different long-distance carriers for access to the local exchange network. (AT&T
had to pay more than its competitors.) Once customers could use all carriers
under equal terms, unequal access charges for different carriers appeared to be
unequitable. However, because the alternative long-distance carriers did not
have the economies of scale of AT&T, equal access rates could have, in effect,
made them uncompetitive. Therefore, the alternative carriers asked for at least
a temporary handicapping of AT&T in their favor.
Mercury reached profitability in 1989. However, its total income was 1.6
percent of BT's and its shares of international traffic (4.3 percent), inland phone
calls (0.7 percent), and leased lines (7.6 percent) were miniscule. Mercury
invested a total of 825 million from 1981 to 1989, less than one-third of BT's
investment for the year 1990 (Arlandis and Gille, 1989).
Mercury's status was reviewed in the 1990 'duopoly review,' leading to fur-
ther opening of telecommunications and to potential competition for Mercury.
This review is discussed at the end of this chapter.
direct debit arrangements between customers and banks, computer access for
storing and forwarding messages, and the extension of radio paging services to
include storage and forwarding of messages. All these services were impossible
because they required the sharing of leased circuits. BT permitted a number of
value-added services as long as they did not require private switching or com-
pete with BT's actual or planned services. Other proposed services, however,
were turned down. In Beesley's views, these restrictions were only the tip of
the iceberg because innovative services do not flourish in the abstract; they
await opening of the rules under which business can take place (Beesley, 1981).
BT estimated that unconstrained reselling of capacity would result in a net
loss of revenue from domestic calls of 30 million for 1984-1985. With more
generous assumptions for potential "cream skimming," it calculated a net rev-
enue loss of 110 million. If these figures are taken as the lower and upper
ranges, they represent between 0.4 percent and 1.5 percent of BT's gross rev-
enues and between 3.2 percent and 12 percent of its profit. A 12 percent re-
duction of profit is hardly a small loss. Beesley, however, did not share this
apprehension, for he believed those estimates to be very "vulnerable." Even
using BT's estimate, Beesley found that revenue loss would amount at the
maximum to only 6.4 per residential customer, a loss that would be offset by
about an 11 percent increase in the residential rate. This would, however, be
accompanied by gains to consumers in reduced long-distance rates and by po-
tential innovations in services. Beesley concluded that resale should be permit-
ted without use restriction because it would encourage ingenuity in meeting
customers' demands with favorable effects on productivity and exports.
Beesley also expanded the analysis to international service. BT was highly
sensitive on this issue, considering the great profit contribution of international
traffic. One study estimated that a hypothetical London to New York private
satellite link would cost 5300 per year, in contrast with the BT tariff for such
a connection of about 50,000. For approximately the same distance, a leased
line coast-to-coast in the United States costs 4500 per year, again less than
one-tenth of BT's price. The pricing of international calls seemed to be close
to its revenue maximizing high. According to Beesley, for a three-minute U.S.-
to-U.K. call the mean expected elasticity was -0.936. For a U.K.-to-U.S. calls,
it was -1.094. These figures are close to the maximizing 1.0, which indicates
revenue vulnerability to a price reduction induced by competition or resale.
Beesley recommended easing all restrictions on the offering of all services
on the BT network, including resale. He further recommended that constraints
on BT's pricing be reduced or eliminated so that rates could move toward
costs. BT, in turn, should be free to enter nonvoice markets as a competitor,
provided safeguards were in place to prevent unfair competition. Domestically,
leased rates ought not to discriminate on the basis of total usage. Internation-
ally, however, differentiated rates could be instituted. And this liberalization,
Beesley argued, should be seen in the context of a possible rival entry into
transmission and switching, which he advocated.
BT opposed the recommendations of the Beesley Report, pointing again to
revenue losses. BT's chairman, Sir George Jefferson, conceded that "change
The United Kingdom 115
destination . . . in the same form that it was received without any additional
services having been provided . . . " (Department of Trade and Industry, 1985,
p. 16). Drawing on the experience of other countries, especially the United
States, the government wisely regarded its definitions as only temporary.
More specific rules for VANs were set in 1982 (Department of Trade and
Industry, 1985). By February 1987, 841 VANs were licensed, operated by 221
different companies (Department of Trade and Industry, 1987). Of these, the
most popular were store and retrieve systems (112), mailboxes (90), protocol
conversion between incompatible computers and terminals (90), customers' data-
bases (66), deferred transmission (63), user management packages (58), view-
data videotex services (62), wordprocessor/facsimile interfacing (46), multiad-
dressing routing (56), and speed and code conversion between incompatible
terminals (49). Other VANs include automatic ticket reservations, conference
calls, long-term archiving, secure delivery services, telesoftware, and text ed-
iting.
VANs with a volume of more than 250,000 per year were subject to rules
that prevent the establishment of a dominant market position. These limitations
were aimed at BT and IBM. Under its license, BT must provide services na-
tionwide, unlike some of its VAN competitors. BT is also subject to rules that
prevent a cross-subsidy of its VANs out of its other services.
In 1986, the VAN rules were further modified to encompass managed data
networks, which had thrown the separation between basic service and VANs
into disarray, thus illustrating the complications of partial liberalization and
partial approval requirements. The legislation was again changed in 1987 when
the VANs license was replaced by the Class License for Value Added and Data
Services (VADS). Under the new classification, those wishing to run under
license from Oftel, other than major service providers, need no longer register
with Oftel.
In 1984, BT and IBM teamed up and announced their intention to establish
a joint VAN venture for data network management services, and applied for a
value-added license under the name JOVE. This set off a strong domestic pro-
test in Britain, and about 100 computer and communications companies regis-
tered their opposition. They were concerned with the reliance on IBM's SNA
architecture, which they feared would threaten British industry and government
development toward an open systems interconnection (OSI). The two partners
argued that their venture allowed for an OSI protocol standard, but by then the
opposition had grown to a clamor. There was also much concern expressed
about the feasibility of competition if two dominant firms in closely related
markets were permitted to link together. With Britain actively introducing com-
petition into its telecommunications and computer fields, the government felt
that such a move would have been counterproductive. Not only would it make
competitive entry more complicated, but it would remove the potential rivalry
between IBM and BT.
Other critics of the JOVE venture feared that it would permit IBM to achieve
some measure of control over BT. They pointed out that IBM-UK had six
employees in 1951 and 16,000 by 1984 (Bird and Huxley, 1984). Given the
The United Kingdom 117
Cellular Telephony
With Oftel especially concerned about competition in new service, mobile radio
received special attention. Professor Bryan Carsberg was interested in protect-
ing new services offerings against BT dominance and concluded that "BT should
not be a network operator, either directly or indirectly, or have more
than a minority share in providers of service for new p.m.r. [public mobile
radio] networks." A public telecommunications operator running a public mo-
bile radio system would have "unmatchable advantages over competing sys-
tems" (Oftel, 1985b, p. 2).
After applications were solicited, licenses were granted to two providers,
Cellnet and Vodaphone, with the obligation to cover almost the entire country
by 1989. Cellnet is a consortium of BT and Securicor, a security services com-
pany that had also been active in telemetry services; Vodaphone is a joint ven-
ture of Racal, Millicom, and Hambros. The competitive structure that had been
set up gave advantages to early starters, and the two companies rushed head-
long into the service. Cellular telephone service became operational in 1985,
drawing a very strong demand.
Cellnet and Vodaphone, however, cannot sell directly to users, they must go
through service providers who resell to the public in return for a commission
of approximately 15 percent. The terms for dealing with these service providers
must be published and must be equal for all, with the exception that the terms
can be volume-related. For service providers, the commission is approximately
15 percent. In practice, the principals of the two cellular telephone operations
set up their own independent retail service providers to deal with the public:
BT established BT Mobile Phone, and Racal set up Racal Vodac. Importantly,
however, these companies cannot receive advantages over other service provid-
ers. Service providers are allowed to market both networks; and resellers, in
turn, can employ independent agents for transactions (Fuller and Mitchell, 1986).
In 1987, there were about fifty reselling organizations, including established
firms such as Marconi and Motorola. Also involved in the sale or resale of
equipment and installation was a legion of local agents, ranging from garages
and telephone stores to office equipment suppliers. This structure permitted the
emergence of vigorous competition, although mostly for equipment packages
rather than for "air time" tariffs. Because the retailers share in the profits from
cellular phone calls, they often sell equipment at low cost to increase the sub-
scriber base. In 1990, mobile phones were available for as little as $300. There
were 650,000 subscribers.
In the competition between the two network operators, Cellnet started with
the significant advantage of BT's resources, an established telephone network,
and existing mobile telecommunications operations with an established cus-
The United Kingdom 119
tomer base. With the privatization of BT, it also had the good will of millions
of British shareholders. Racal's Vodaphone, on the other hand, was an un-
known entity. Its advertising slogan was "Racalthe largest company you've
never heard of" (Raggett, 1986).
The relation between two companies moved from hostility to cooperation,
partly because there was enough business for both companies' services in the
initial phase. BT provides interconnection service for Vodaphone, thus creating
a delicate relationship. In the technical field, the companies must cooperate to
achieve the required full cellular interconnection that would permit "roaming"
between the two systems. By 1990 there were nearly 800,000 cellular users,
the second highest number in Europe behind Sweden, split evenly between
Cellnet and Vodaphone. Each had invested some 200-300 million in their
networks and each was gaining 15,000 new subscribers monthly. Even with
success in gaining subscribers, there was substantial user criticism with the
performance of Racal (22 percent dissatisfaction in a survey) and Cellnet (32
percent dissatisfaction.
In 1989, the United Kingdom moved to the forefront of mobile communica-
tions by licensing two entirely new forms of operation, Telepoint and PCN.
Telepoint or CT-2 (cordless telephone second generation) consists of hand-held
units that can be used within 200 meters of a base station.
Telepoint service operators install low-cost base stations ($180-$500, de-
pending on estimate). In 1988, the DTI awarded four Telepoint licenses to
Ferranti, Phonepoint (BT, France Telecom, STC, NYNEX, and the German
DBF), Callpoint (Mercury, Motorola, and Shaye), and BYPS Comms (Bar-
clays, Philips, and Shell).
CT-2 employs a frequency division multiple access system, as opposed to
the EC's Digital European Cordless Telecommunications (DECT) standard, which
uses time division multiplexing and which was especially promoted by Erics-
son. The DTI asked for the European Telecommunications Standards Institute
(ETSI) to determine the appropriate standard, GSM or DECT, for the U.K.
system after operators were unable to reach an agreement (Green, 1990b).
Personal Communications Networks (PCN), is another form of mobile com-
munications. It employs very small mobile transceivers (though at low power,
with less reach and less mobility than cellular).
DTI received eight applications for PCN service and granted licenses to three
consortia in 1989: Mercury PCN (C&W, Motorola, and Telefonica), BAe (British
Aerospace, Millicom, PacTel, and Sony), and Unitel (STC, Thorn EMI, US
West, and the DBP). BT's Cellnet and Racal's Vodaphone did not receive li-
censes but will be allowed to configure their systems for PCNs. Each consor-
tium aimed to invest $1~$2.5 billion for service available by 1992 (Sims, 1989;
Oftel, 1990a, p. 1).
Optimistic projections of 12-30 million Telepoint and PCN users by the year
2000 were quickly scaled back. For Telepoint, only 3500 transmitters were
installed in 1990, compared with 86,000 public call boxes and 358,000 private
pay phones (Lynch and Hayes, 1990). By 1991, Telepoint had proved to add
120 The United Kingdom
little value to existing cellular service, and all but one of the operators had
gone out of business. PCN did not fare much better. PCN figures were adjusted
downwards and yearly losses were foreseen until the turn of the century.
Britain's liberalization policy put the United Kingdom into conflict with its
partners in the European Economic Community and the European Conference
on Post and Telecommunications (CEPT), the organization of European PTTs.
This conflict was exemplified in the "British Telecom Case" before the Euro-
pean Court, a case that illustrates the British dilemma of reconciling its Euro-
pean role while pursuing a telecommunications policy somewhat different from
its partners.
Britain had about 100 private message forwarding agencies, which receive
or transmit telex messages from customers who themselves do not have a telex
subscription (Dumey, 1983). At first operating only within the United King-
dom, several agencies then expanded their message relaying service into con-
tinental Europe, North America, and Asia. This was profitable because British
Telecom's international telex rates were quite low, particularly to North Amer-
ica, creating an incentive for continental European users to route their telex
traffic via London when sending their telex messages across the Atlantic. Ini-
tially, firms went directly through their British subsidiary's office if they had
one. For users without related U.K. branches, the telex forwarding agencies
started to fulfill the same function. In some instances, the agencies offered
superior service, including a money-back guarantee if the message was not
transmitted within a certain time.
The PTTs, facing the loss of revenue and an emerging competitive price
regime, fought back by mustering the rules of CEPT and the CCITT that "har-
monize" the PTTs behavior. CCITT telegram recommendations required PTTs
to block telegram and telex messages that were sent to forwarding agencies for
transmission in order to "evade" full charges of the complete route. In 1975,
the British Post Office, still operating under the traditional policy guidelines,
clamped down on the forwarding agencies and required messages to be charged
a rate by the forwarding agencies equal to the tariff that would have been paid
for a direct telex route bypassing the United Kingdom. But it was impossible
to enforce this provision. The telex bureaus had no incentive to check on rates
122 The United Kingdom
between third countries. In early 1978, the provision was dropped. It was,
however, replaced by other and stricter rules prohibiting telex agencies from
providing international services for their customers altogether when messages
were in data form (from computer to computer) and were received through the
telephone lines and then converted to telex, facsimile, or other visual form.
One of the telex agencies lodged a formal complaint with the Commission
of the European Communities in June 1979. Proceedings took place in 1980,
while the British government reorganized its telecommunications system and
set up British Telecom. BT at first maintained the previous prohibitions. The
case before the European Commission therefore proceeded, and the decision
was announced in December 1982 (Official Journal, L360, 1982, p. 36). In its
decision, the commission found BT's rules to be a violation of Article 86 of
the Treaty of Rome. Ironically, however, BT had withdrawn these restrictions
two months earlier, in light of Britain's changed attitude toward service com-
petition; the issue was thus moot as far as the British situation was concerned.
In its decision, the commission found that the Post Office, and later BT, had
abused their position as a statutory monopoly. The 1976 restrictions would
have required telex agencies to discriminate in their rates for equivalent trans-
actions according to the country of the customer or the country of destination.
The 1978 restriction was similarly discriminatory, because it prohibited telex
traffic both to and from countries, including EEC members. It also found that
the prohibition of use of a combined telephone line and telex link for computer
data transmission imposed restrictions on the development of a new market and
new technologies, as well as on the efficient use of existing facilities, thus
restricting interstate European trade.
The British government, when it was still opposing the telex bureaus, used
Article 90(2) of the Treaty of Rome in its defense, contending that this section
exempted public enterprises from the EEC competition rules. That section,
however, contains a broad principle that applies competitive rules of the treaty
to public monopolies where important services of "general economic interest"
are at stake. Hence, where the PTT's obligation is to cooperate with other
PTTs, the commission found that the "development of trade must not be af-
fected to such an extent that it is contrary to the interest of the community,"
even if this resulted in the inability of the PTT to fulfill its duties. Thus, the
limitation of Article 90(2) did not apply.
Though the court ruled against BT's provisions of 1976 and 1978, it imposed
no fine, taking a number of factors into account: BT had acted originally under
the pressure of other European PTTs; it had not profited by these rules in the
sense of additional revenues; and it had suspended and not enforced the prohi-
bition during the commission proceedings (Dumey, 1983).
Thus, the commission announced that the restraints upon telecommunications
services, even when undertaken within a concerted European policy, were in
violation of the European antitrust provisions. This could have been the end of
the story, but the commission's principle was too important to be left unchal-
lenged. The British government, by now firmly embarked on a course of lib-
eralization and possibly coveting the role of London as a communications hub,
The United Kingdom 123
was in no mood to appeal the decision, but other European countries were. The
Italian government therefore took up the defense of BT's lost virtue and chal-
lenged the commission's decision before the European Court of Justice (case
41-83) in an appeal that had implications far beyond telecommunications. It
was the first time that a Common Market member state had appealed a decision
of the commission in an individual competition case. Moreover, it was the first
time that a member state appealed a decision that concerned a company over
which it did not have direct jurisdiction.
The Italian government made several arguments. It claimed that BT's actions
were part of the exercise of legislative power, rather than entrepreneurial activ-
ity, it claimed that these activities were regulatory and public law activities
essential to BT to accomplish the task of providing telecommunications ser-
vices domestically and internationally. Furthermore, Italy argued that BT, as a
member of the ITU, was required to implement international regulations adopted
by the ITU (such as the 1947 Atlantic City Convention) such that international
agreements must be honored even if the effects were contrary to the EEC treaty
rules. Furthermore, according to Article 222, the treaty "does not prejudice the
system of property ownership within the Member States." Italy argued that the
legality of BT's action in its capacity as monopoly could not be brought into
question without questioning the legality of the monopoly itself. Instead, the
claim continued, the British government needed to protect itself from unfair
competition by cream-skimming enterprises that jeopardized the economic in-
tegrity of the telecommunications systems.
The commission had declared the regulations against telex message forward-
ing to be anticompetitive and in violation of Article 86 of the Treaty of Rome.
In response, Italy argued that the Community's competition rules did not apply
to monopoly telecommunications services authorities and that regulatory activ-
ities of public companies should not be considered as an activity of an "under-
taking" within the meaning of Article 86.
The European High Court of Justice announced its decision in March 1985,
two years after the case was appealed to it and ten years after BT's regulations
of 1975 and 1976 (Court of Justice of the European Communities, 1985). The
court firmly rejected all of Italy's claims, thus putting an end to the legal at-
tempt to block third-party traffic in telex. In all likelihood, similar arbitrage
services by a European country functioning as a communications hub will thus
be upheld against PTT cartel prohibitions.
Telecommunications Services
The introduction of Marconi's wireless telegraphy around the turn of the cen-
tury greatly worried those who held shares in British submarine cables. The
Post Office, which after 1889 operated submarine cables between Britain and
its European neighbors, also felt negative effects. In an effort to forestall the
development of radio, the Wireless Telegraphy Act of 1904 was passed, pro-
hibiting installation and operation of wireless telegraphy stations without li-
cense by the postmaster general. Although proponents of the Act claimed they
were acknowledging the importance of wireless to national security, it is clear
that the government feared the emergence of a new monopoly, which it would
then have to purchase. An application in 1905 by the private General Interna-
tional Telegraph and Telephone company for a commercial license for wireless
service within Britain was refused because it was in direct competition with the
128 The United Kingdom
age liability against BT. A BT line averaged a technical problem every two
years, ten times the rate of the Bell companies in the United States. Even BT
conceded the fault rate to be two to three times higher than that in the United
States (Hudson, 1987).
Overall penetration in 1988 was forty-two main lines per 100 households.
As a private firm subject to some competition, BT's sensitivity to its customers
increased. Business customers, in particular, benefitted from service improve-
ments and rate reductions. The waiting time required to install private circuits
in the City of London, used to be several months, was rapidly shortened. Per-
formance profit centers were created within the company. Management em-
ployment contracts began to include performance and profitability clauses and
were limited in duration in order to break a civil-service, lock-step salary en-
vironment. A sales force with major-account managers was created in 1980 to
help the company protect and increase its business.
The U.K.'s liberal telecommunications policy and relatively lower interna-
tional telephone rates helped attract large users. The Ford Motor Company, for
example, set up the communications center for its European operations in the
United Kingdom. Nevertheless, there was much dissatisfaction with BT's ser-
vice. In an effort to rebut the criticism directed at it for service quality, in 1987
BT announced a quality strategy that included expenditures of over $400 mil-
lion to improve both international and domestic service. In response to the
complaints, Oftel resumed its publication of survey figures on service quality.
Oftel's 1990 Annual Report noted and increase in complaints, from 23,800 in
1988 to 31,650 in 1989, despite increases in percentage of faults repaired in
one day from 65 percent to 86 percent (Oftel, 1990a, p. 8).
Table 8.1 shows the comparison in quality of service between British Tele-
com and New York Telephone. The quality performance of New York Tele-
phone does not rank high among the more than thirty telephone companies in
New York State. However, Table 8.1 shows that its service quality is above
BT's.
According to Sir Brian Carsberg, head of Oftel, "The largest area of com-
plaints is billing. People say they could not have run up the amount that ap-
pears on their bill . . . In the United States where they have itemized billing,
The United Kingdom 131
Mercury's status was reviewed in the 1990 'duopoly review.' After Oftel
submitted a report in 1990, the review was opened to public comment. Over
200 groups responded. In 1991 the Department of Trade and Industry, which
oversees Oftel, presented its findings in Competition and Choice: Telecommu-
nications Policy for the 1990s, a title reminiscent of the government's parallel
efforts in television liberalization through the broadcasting White Paper (Home
Office, 1988). The duopoly review decision signalled a move from managed
competition to a more open system, but with a more level playing field.
Equal access provisions were envisioned only in two stages, and not before
the 1992/3 review of BT tariffs, since BT (and some user groups) had argued
that the costs (300 million) and technical problems of developing switching
capability for multiple operators were extensive. The decision also changed
British Telecom's tariff structure; it included international services in the tariff
basket after a one-time 10 percent reduction, and it tightened the price cap to
RPI-6.25 percent from RPI-4.5 percent. While cable, satellite, and cellular firms
received greater flexibility (and interconnectivity) to offer telecommunications
services, there was no symmetry. BT was prohibited from offering cable tele-
vision service until at least 1997.
The reaction to the White Paper was mixed. Some welcomed its further
liberalization and viewed it as a challenge to BT's market power. Others thought
it too lenient on BT, perhaps in order to protect the value of government shares
prior to full privatization. They also saw Mercury as the loser since it faced
new competition in its core business of serving large users. BT also received
the right to grant special tariff packages to large users. On the other hand, the
consortia which were expected to offer telecommunications services (such as
British Rail, British Waterways, Racal, British Aerospace, and the Post Office)
were hampered by the unresolved interconnection issues. And few cable oper-
ators actually had networks in place that might have offered local services.
Thus, British telecommunications policies have created an entity similar to
the predivestiture AT&T in the United Statesa private, dominant, and regu-
lated carrier with a limited competition in the long distance field. Such a system
had been considered problematic in the United States (even without BT's do-
mestic quality problems), and led to further liberalization and divestiture. Anal-
ogously it was unlikely that the transformation of British telecommunications
had reached a stable equilibrium.
9
France
133
134 France
fully introduced a proposal to initiate a route from Paris to Lille. Chappe called
his invention the tachygraphe ("rapid writer"), but this fortunately was changed
into the term telegraphe for "distance writer," and this Graeco-Latin desig-
nation has stuck.
The Paris-Lille telegraph route was completed in 1794. Signals were con-
veyed by various positions of mechanical arms on windmill-like stations lo-
cated on hilltops at intervals of 6-12 miles. In 1803, the route reached Brussels
and a few years later, Amsterdam. In 1798, another Chappe brother established
a line to the German and Swiss borders. Lines were extended to Milan in 1805,
and Venice in 1810. The Napoleonic Wars made rapid communications impor-
tant. After the Bourbon Restoration, the systems continued to expand within
France. By 1845, the system encompassed 535 optical telegraph stations link-
ing Paris with twenty-nine cities. The Chappe optical telegraph system
and variant systems were also used in England, Scandinavia, Prussia, and
Austria.
A message from Paris to Lille, a distance of 225 kilometers, was relayed by
twenty-two stations and required, in theory, only several minutes for transmis-
sion. But the Chappe system was complicated and required a skilled operator,
usually trained and supervised by military officers. The British optical system
was simpler but slower. Signals on the Chappe telegraph could be transmitted
at a rate of one signal every sixteen seconds. Because of this time-consuming
procedure, elaborate codes were developed for standard phrases and expres-
sions. Codes also served to protect the secrecy of the official messages. Trans-
mission at night or in bad weather was not possible and the system was plagued
with problems. It was exceptional for a telegraph line to transmit even six
telegrams of about twenty words a day. The entirety of this network could
handle a maximum of 7000 dispatches annually. It was therefore not surprising
that military, diplomatic, and administrative messages of the state claimed ab-
solute priority and that the system was operated by a board of the Ministry of
the Interior. Initially, no private messages at all were transmitted on the sys-
tem. In 1833, Alexander Ferrier created a private company to respond to pri-
vate demand. Although his effort failed, it demonstrated the interest in devel-
oping a private telegraph.
In 1837, such private efforts were outlawed by a law that declared the tele-
graph a government monopoly within the expanding postal monopoly. Private
communications networks were discouraged primarily to inhibit the exploitation
of financial information by speculators. A French legislator argued: "Govern-
ments have always kept to themselves the exclusive use of things which, if
fallen into bad hands, could threaten public and private safety: poisons and
explosive are given out only under the state authority, and certainly the tele-
graph, in bad hands, could become the most dangerous weapon. Just imagine
what could have happened if the passing success of the Lyon silk workers
insurrection had been known in all corners of the nation at once" (Brock,
1981). The law provided substantial fines for unauthorized transmission. Suc-
ceeding governments of varying political persuasions have never significantly
France 135
deviated from this principle. The French government monopoly over telecom-
munications was thus established by law even before the introduction of electric
telegraphy. When the latter arrived, the French government was far from en-
thusiastic. An explicit ban on private electric telegraph lines was quickly de-
clared when the advent of the railroad led to an attempt to create a private
telegraph line between Versailles and Saint Germain. Although private entry
was thus made impossible, the government was reluctant to enter electrical
telegraphy itself because it feared undermining its own elaborate optical tele-
graphic system. The advent of the electric telegraph threatened state power, as
one minister complained: "No, the electric telegram is not a sound invention.
It will be always at the mercy of the slightest disruption, wild youth, drunk-
ards, bums, etc. . . . All that is unnecessary with the electric telegraph are
those destructive elements within only a few meters to a wire over which su-
pervision is impossible. . . . The visual telegram, on the contrary, has its
tower, its high walls, its gate well guarded from inside by strong armed men"
(Allentier, 1973, p. 100).
Eventually, however, the French government constructed an electrical tele-
graphic system which was operated and controlled by a unit of the Interior
Ministry until 1878, primarily for governmental and only secondarily for public
use. In 1853 the optical telegraph was discontinued, its low capacity and rela-
tively high cost of operation being factors in its rapid demise.
In 1852, in an important departure, Louis Napoleon Bonaparte (Napoleon
III) allowed private users to access the telegraph system. Control was gradually
relaxed, though state control was still used against opposition newspapers and
coded messages (Bertho et al., 1984), to name two examples.
When it came to international submarine telegraph cables, England had, until
1880, virtual control, and French colonies often had to use English lines to
communicate with Paris. Given her rivalry with Britain, France found such
dependence intolerable. Meanwhile, several attempts by French companies to
enter the submarine cable market ended in failure or in buyouts by American
or English companies. The Ministry of Posts and Telegraph began to invest in
several cable companies. After 1879, the government operated its own cables
to Algeria and Africa. The Compagnie Franchise au Cable Telegraphique (CFCT)
was formed in 1889 and operated privately until its nationalization in 1945.
The telephone debuted in France at the Paris World Fair of 1878 (Holcombe,
1911). In contrast to Germany, where it was the state that seized upon the new
invention with enthusiasm, in France the private sector played a significant role
in the establishment of the new medium. The Third Republic was pushing for
economic liberalism in areas of public services, usually through concessions to
private companies which would shoulder the burden of investment and risk.
The telephone was included in this framework, and in 1879 the government
136 France
announced its decision to award private concessions. But all construction had
to be supervised by state engineers.
Concessions were not exclusive and lasted only five years; a 10 percent roy-
alty payment was required, and the government could purchase all the tele-
phone equipment it needed from the concessionaires at an agreed upon or ar-
bitrated price. At the same time, there was no rate regulation. The concessionaires
thus had both the incentives and the ability to try to recoup their investment as
quickly as possible. In 1879, licenses were issued to the firms of Edison, Gower,
and Blake-Bell. Before construction began, however, these franchises were
merged into the Societe Generale de Telephone (SGT). This process of consol-
idation was based on cartel advantages as well as the Paris municipality's wish
to avoid multiple and unsightly wire networks.
The first Paris exchange opened in 1881. Development however, was slow.
Service was limited in quality and expensive. The two viable policy options
were either to increase the government's role or to allow telephone companies
to expand and develop. The government instead chose to increase restrictions
on private operations, without strengthening its own role as an operator by
committing resources.
In 1882, the government determined that the SGT was inclined to provide
services only to the dozen or so large French cities. The National Assembly
was persuaded to support governmental telephone construction in various
medium-sized cities. But the annual budget allocation for this endeavor was a
paltry FFr 250,000.
In 1884, the French government renewed the existing private licenses over
strong opposition, but without a clear-cut policy of its own. Soon it became
desirable to link the local exchanges by long-distance connections. The tele-
graph authority, sensing a threat, began construction, starting in 1885 between
Paris and Rouen, and in 1887 between Paris and Brussels.
In subsequent years, French policy continually changed. In 1887, Grannet,
the minister in charge of telegraphy, introduced legislation to strengthen private
telephony to alleviate the backward condition of French telephony. His succes-
sor, however, opposed the plan. With some justification, the public believed
the French telephone system had become a complete morass in less than ten
years. By 1889, the Grannet plan was rejected, largely on the argument that
private telephony would jeopardize the financial soundness of the state tele-
graph system (Holcombe, 1911).
Backed by a coalition of dissatisfied business users, small towns, and leftist
republicans, the government soon decided to take over the entire network. Op-
ponents argued against too much state power and against support for what was
considered a luxury. But the French National Assembly approved nationaliza-
tion in 1889, at the end of the second five-year concession period, fired by the
national enthusiasm of the revolution's centennial. The companies' installers
were given the option of setting up installation businesses of their own, origi-
nating a system of private installation firms still in use today, and whose origin
is thus not a liberalization but a nationalization. 1
France 137
Since the SGT refused to surrender its property willingly, it was literally taken
over by force, with compensation paid after the fact. At the time, there were
only 8500 subscribers, of which only 2000 were outside Paris (Nouvion, 1984).
After extensive court action, the company received about FFr 11 million, twice
the amount the telegraph authority had been willing to pay, but less than the
company had demanded.
Having taken control of the telephone and telegraph, and having placed it
under the Office of the Under secretary of State for the Postal and Telegraph
Service, the government now had to figure out what to do with it. Because the
telephone held no priority in general economic development, the government
was not prepared to make the significant investment necessary to finance con-
struction. It had, over two generations, built up an extraordinarily high general
debt burden and was reluctant to increase it.
Instead, it devised a system in which potential subscribers and municipalities
were forced to extend interest-free loans that would eventually be repaid from
the profits derived from their own receipts. Futhermore, subscribers were re-
quired to purchase telephone sets themselves to save the state's money. This
was the origin of France's subscriber equipment policy, which was presented
in the 1980s as an example of liberalism.
This system of financing was also expanded to long-distance transmission.
Local systems resembled cooperatives in that they united the first group of
subscribers, who paid for the construction of the network. As in other cooper-
ative ventures, the admission of newcomers and the potential integration of
systems into the national network presented problems.
Financing proved problematic when it came to the replacement of obsolete
equipment or making improvements. By 1900, this situation was referred to as
a "telephone crisis." The system was congested, unreliable, and expensive.
There were still only 30,000 telephones in the entire country! By comparison,
in 1909, there were 27,000 telephone lines alone in the 100 largest hotels of
New York City (Attali and Stourdze, 1977, p. 106).
A number of improvements were achieved under A. Millerand, a Socialist
who became minister of the PTT. Millerand established a new system of fi-
nancing telephone expansion out of public revenue rather than subscriber charges,
but he was unsuccessful in obtaining appropriations from the legislature. Even
the French business community shortsightedly opposed additional budget allo-
cations. The Chamber of Commerce argued that construction had to be financed
not by government budget but by greater internal economies of PTT operations.
Millerand was dropped from the cabinet.
In the early years of the century, service remained abysmal. There was only
one line between Paris and Marseilles, and during one twelve-month period
(1905-1906), it had 204 interruptions with an average duration of 14.5 hours.
Between Paris and Lyon there were five lines, with 550 interruptions of an
138 France
average duration of ten and a half hours (Holcombe, 1911, p. 302). Local
exchanges were enormously congested. In 1905, operators in Paris took almost
two minutes on average to make a local connection.
By 1906, the government acknowledged the problem and a special law passed
to transfer the Post and Telegraph Department from the Ministry of Commerce
and Industry to the Ministry of Public Works. It also authorized a budget of 19
million francs but required that the funds be spent within the same fiscal year,
leading to insufficient planning and excessive costs. Millerand, back in the
government, instituted a labor relations reform for PTT workers, featuring eight-
hour days, security of tenure, overtime payment, and full payment during ill-
ness.
The destructiveness of World War I further deteriorated the telephone net-
work. Industry was not up to the task of rebuilding it. French equipment mak-
ers were merely manufacturers of general electrical machinery, small compa-
nies, or subsidiaries of foreign firms. In 1920, when the Paris network was to
be upgraded, several foreign firmsWestern Electric, Siemens, Ericsson, and
ITTsought the business. ITT bought two French manufacturing firms, created
a large research laboratory in Paris, and studied the needs of the French net-
work in depth. As a result of its commitment, it was awarded the major French
orders for automatic central offices. But this foreign dominance created resent-
ment in the 1930s and after World War II, leading to a French industrial buildup
against ITT's position.
The first automatic exchange opened experimentally in 1913 in Nice using
the Strowger system. The PTT also ordered semiautomatic systems from the
French company Le Materiel Telephonique (LMT) then owned by AT&T and
using Western Electric's rotary technology. The first such exchange opened in
Angers in 1915 (Nouvion, 1984, p. 80). However, the spread of the automatic
exchange was slowed by World War I and the economic problems in its after-
math. Crossbar exchanges were not introduced in Paris until 1964. Six years
later, the electronic time division switch, the E10, was introduced, leapfrog-
ging a generation of technology.
During the period of economic conservatism of the 1920s, the magnitude of
the investments required for the telephone network sparked a debate over its
denationalization. Two proposals emerged from the debate: ITT, eager to put
down roots in the French market, offered to take over and operate the entire
national network as it did in Spain; the second proposal was from the Societe
Industrielle du Telephone (SIT), a predecessor of the telecommunications op-
erations of CGE.
In 1921, a law was advanced to study denationalization. Louis Deschamps,
who advocated privatization of various government monopolies, including the
telephone, served briefly as PTT minister. Because of the project's difficulty
and opposition from PTT employee associations, his successors did not pursue
his course. From 1923 onward, the PTT was instead directed to operate like an
administration with industrial and commercial purposes, under a separate bud-
get (subject to parliamentary approval) and required to cover its costs.
In 1920, the PTT awarded the concession for international radio-electric links
France 139
from France to the private company Compagnie Sans Fils (CSF), which created
Radio France for this purpose. The concession to CSF caused a vigorous de-
bate. Because the international radio-electric link posed promising opportuni-
ties, the labor unions and the political opposition were against privatizing this
sector.
FIT relations with Radio France were generally poor because radio links of
the PTT and Radio France (SRF) were at times in competition. A FFr 60 mil-
lion station opened in 1923, allowing France to build a wireless network that
included PTT links to Africa and Indochina, communications links to central
and northern Europe, and Radio France transmission to most of the world.
Meanwhile, the PTT slowly upgraded the domestic telephone network, with
the first long distance cables in France using Pupin coils put into service in
1924. Still, the average wait for an interurban connection was five hours. To
address this problem, the government adopted a separate budget for the PTT as
an annex to the general budget, giving it access to special loans. In addition,
it approved another modernization plan for the telephone network. Between
1924 and 1934, the number of subscribers increased annually by an average of
45,000, almost double the previous rate, though growth was still excruciatingly
slow.
The automation of the Paris network started in 1925 and led to major indus-
trial struggles over procurement contracts. The competing firms included the
French Compagnie des Telephones Thomson-Houston, and the Societe Indus-
trielle du Telephone (SIT), both of which proposed a Strowger system. LMT,
now acquired by ITT, proposed a rotary system, and the Ericsson subsidiary
proposed its own method. The French Compagnie Generate de Telegraphic et
de Telephonic was also in contention, but its system depended on a Siemens
patent, and the French government did not want Parisian telephones to rely on
German technology.
At the time, ITT had experienced several setbacks in Europe: Germany and
England chose the Strowger system, and although Spain opted for exclusive
use of ITT's rotary system in 1924, the Spanish could have changed their minds
if the French had not also chosen that system. With so much at stake, ITT
hedged its bets and bought the Thomson-Houston telephone division in 1925
(later to become CGCT), giving it a stronger position for the French procure-
ment. This was accomplished just as Thomson-Houston patented its new R6
switching system.
The PTT awarded the project to LMT (the ITT subsidiary) in 1926. The
firm's promise to build a large manufacturing facility and to release its pro-
cesses to other companies designated by the PTT weighed heavily in the deci-
sion. These companies were the Societe Grammont, which withdrew in 1931
because of financial problems, and Ericsson.
The ITT contract, however, did not eliminate demand for the R6 system.
Rural exchange contracts went to Thomson-Houston, ITT's other subsidiary,
which was considered "more French" than LMT. The PTT also extended a
license for the R6 to SIT. This period marked the low point for French switch-
ing firms and the high point for ITT. Through its two subsidiaries it dominated
140 France
this key sector. A few years later, in 1932, the large French electrical firm
Compagnie Generale d'Electricite (CGE) took control of SIT and sought un-
successfully to forge links with the American firm Automatic Electric of Chi-
cago. This marked the beginning of the CGE's long march against ITT. With
substantial help from the French government, it eventually took control of ITT's
worldwide telecommunications equipment operations in 1986, more than half a
century later.
Between 1924 and 1934, the number of lines increased an average of 7.6
percent annually. Because of budgetary restrictions, this rate fell to 2.6 percent
between 1935 and 1939. The number of lines served by automatic systems rose
from 3.6 percent in 1926 to 45.6 percent in 1938. The corresponding 1938
figure for Germany was 84.9 percent, and for the United Kingdom, 54 percent.
While telephone penetration in France rose, it was still very low: 3.7 per 100
inhabitants in 1938, compared to 4.6 in the UK, 15 in Germany (Nouvion,
1983, p. 84), and 15.1 in the United States (U.S. Department of Commerce,
1939). Even that figure for France overstates the actual situation, because of
the imbalance in favor of Paris. Only a handful of the French departments had
a telephone density above five telephones per 100 inhabitants. In many, the
density was less than two.
World War II destroyed parts of the French telephone network, though some
of the long distance telephone network had been expanded by the German oc-
cupiers for military use (Bertho et al., 1984). From 1941 to 1944, the Vichy
government consolidated various research centers into one organization, the
CNET, as part of a modernization effort. After Liberation, telecommunications
fell behind the rest of Europe in rebuilding because of inadequate investment
funds. The network became a drag on France's otherwise rapidly developing
economy. This is not to say that there was no innovation; there was progress
in switching, transmission, and telex. France was the first European country to
use coaxial cable for long distance trunks (Paris to Toulouse, in 1947). France
was also first to use such a cable for a totally automatic service, starting in
1952. Yet demand for telephone lines vastly outstripped supply. Telex ad-
vanced partly through the exertions of the firm Sagem and the liberal equipment
policy for telex and PBXs. Complaints became endemic.
In 1969, the PTT admitted that the average long-distance call had to be
placed three times before it found a clear circuit, an efficiency rate of less than
40 percent. According to a Western Electric report, only one call out of four
during business hours was completed on the first attempt. The report also claimed
that in 1969 "it was not unusual for a telephone subscriber to wait anywhere
from 30 minutes to more than an hour and a half for a dial tone and more than
two days to get a call through" (Western Electric, 1978, p. 1). Under pressure
to improve this performance, the government budgeted FFr 45 billion for tele-
communications development in its Sixth Plan (1971-1975). This amount was
ten times greater than that provided in the Fourth Plan, but it was still far from
adequate.
Telephone distribution was also quite unevenly spread across the country.
Figure 9.1, from a Direction General de Telecommunications (DGT) staff study,
France 141
shows the vast difference in telephone density between Paris and other cities
and regions of the country (Guerard et al., 1979).
On the horizontal axis, the telephone density is mapped. Vertically, tele-
phone usage per main line is traced for the year 1977. As can be seen, the
telephone density for Paris was almost twice that of major areas of activity in
the provinces, which were, in turn, much higher than in the countryside.
By the mid 1970s, French telephone performance had deteriorated to the point
that it became one of the campaign issues in the 1974 presidential election that
brought to power Valery Giscard d'Estaing, a right-of-center finance minister
with a technocratic image and an interest in telephone issues. Giscard d'Estaing,
as an Assembly deputy, had introduced legislation in 1967 to establish the
telephone administration (DGT) as an independent entity. In 1974, the bitter
joke was that half of the country was waiting to get a telephone installed, and
the other half was waiting for a dial tone. Only 5 million lines served a popu-
lation of 52.6 million, whereas the United Kingdom, with roughly the same
population, had twice the number of telephone connections. In 1974, telephone
densities were extraordinarily low. For blue-collar workers they were only 10
percent; for junior executives and clerks, 22 percent; and for the agricultural
professions, 19 percent (Logica, 1979).
In 1975, the French government set a national priority of modernizing and
expanding the domestic network, while at the same time using telecommuni-
cations as a base to develop a high-technology industry strong enough to com-
pete in the world market. President Giscard d'Estaing launched a five year plan
aimed at giving the entire population access to telephone service, with empha-
142 France
sis on bringing the particularly low quality of telephone service in the provinces
in line with the standards enjoyed in Paris. The number of subscribers quadru-
pled in eight years to over 20 million in 1983, aided by the Vlth and Vllth
Plans, which allocated FFr 405 billion and FFr 120 billion, respectively, for
telecommunications (Scientific American, 1983).
Telecommunications were set as the first priority in the Vllth five-year plan
for the French economy. Its goals were to reach parity in density with West
Germany and the United Kingdom and to reduce the wait for a telephone from
16.4 months in 1974 to 0.5 months in 1982. In equipment, accelerated conver-
sion to electronic switching was planned, both for increasing the effectiveness
of the French system and as a basis for export (Connaughton, 1982).
With money and attention, French telecommunications were remarkably
transformed. For the first time in their history, they were a national priority
supported by the state and by now a largely indigenous industry. In 1976 alone,
2 million lines were added. This number increased to 2.7 million in 1979, and
almost 3 million in 1980. In 1981, the number of new installations began to
plateau and decline. This was an impressive performance, but less unusual in
the European context than is often believed. Other European countries were
also rapidly increasing their investment in telecommunications infrastructure at
a similar pace. French telecommunications investments, as a percentage of the
total national investment, were 3.36 percent in 1981. In Germany, without
telecommunications being proclaimed a national economic priority, it was 3.20
percent at the same time. Italy spent 3.26 percent, and the United Kingdom
spent 3.5 percent (Benedetti, 1983).
France Telecom
Until 1989, the Ministry of Post, Telegraph and Telephone (PTT, later PTE,
when it also included the space portfolio) controlled French telecommunica-
tions, operating through the Direction Generale de Telecommunications (DGT),
renamed France Telecom (FT) in 1988. Postal service was provided by another
PTE General Directorate, the DGP (later La Poste). The DGT, established as
an autonomous directorate in 1946, employed about 166,000 people (about 7.2
per 1000 lines) and was composed of twenty-two regional directorates, which
were in turn divided into operational subregions. Some of its operations were
carried out through a subsidiary or a separate entity, and others through a mixed
investment firm controlled by the state but constituted according to private
company law. In 1985, these subsidiaries were placed under the control of the
state holding company Compagnie Generale de Communication (COGECOM).
Two dozen of these subsidiaries operated in foreign countries or ran satellite
ground stations and submarine cables. In 1989, COGECOM had revenues of
more than $1.8 billion. Other subsidiaries operated in France, including Entre-
prise Generale des Telecommunications (EOT), for advanced terminal equip-
ment, and France Cables et Radio for new services to large users. Telesystemes
France 143
Services
Partly because of its fairly recent major expansion, the French telephone system
achieves high technical standards. Development was particularly successful in
both digital switching and transmission. In 1989, 71 percent of all lines were
electronically switched, with the rest using crossbar switches; rotary type switches
had been totally phased out. 2 In 1989, nearly 4 million electronic lines were
put into service. By 1989, 58 percent of switches were digital, 12 percent
analog, and 30 percent crossbar. Total network digitalization was set for 1996
(Steckel and Fossier, 1990, p. 22).
France was a leader in public packet-switched networks. Available since 1978,
Transpac is the world's largest packet-switched network. Subscribers were es-
pecially attracted by the distance-independent tariffing. Private companies are
involved in the network, which the GCE subsidiary SESA designed. Transpac
was originally operated through a mixed public-private economic organization.
To spread risk, maintain commitment, and increase input, Transpac users were
also shareholders. Later only 3 percent remained in private hands. In 1985,
Transpac was placed under the control of the state holding company COGE-
COM.
Transpac had 5.5 million users (including the 5 million subscribers of the
French Minitel service) and 86,000 direct access points in 1991, carrying 2
billion characters per month. It also introduced a range of new services, includ-
ing Atlas 400, a X.400 electronic data interchange, and a mass market elec-
tronic mail system, Minicom. Transpac also moved internationally by acquiring
a 15 percent stake in the U.S. VAN Infonet, together with several European
PTTs. It entered ventures with the German DBP Telekom and the Swiss and
Danish PTTs. In 1991, Transpac began to offer service in the United Kingdom,
as part of an international expansion program. Other data services are Transfix,
Transcom (a medium-speed public switched service), and Transdyn (a satellite
service). These services were bundled and upgraded as Transmic.
France Telecom moved toward ISDN, known in French as RNIS (Reseau
Numerique a 1'Integration de Services). In 1987, the DGT introduced its ISDN
service Numeris in Brittany. By 1989, 18 million telephone subscribers had
potential access to Numeris and several dozen companies were developing ap-
plications in partnership with France Telecom.
Limited resale of leased line capacity was allowed for data services in 1987,
but tariffs were set to prevent arbitrage. Sources were divided into Category I
(under 3.5 Mbps) and Category II networks. All networks required a license.
By 1990, some 120 applications were filed but only one authorization was
granted for a Category II network. Restrictions on VANs were further lifted in
a 1989 regulatory ruling, which allowed automatic authorizations of Category
I (Roussel, 1989d, p. 13). VAN providers were still limited to a single connec-
tion to the public network, ruling out network bypass, and they must support
OSI protocols for data transmission (Steckel and Fossier, 1990, p. 10).
French policy toward VANs has been somewhat reluctant. When the Euro-
France 145
As part of a high-technology renaissance, the Vllth Plan of 1975 set the devel-
opment of France as an international leader and exporter of telecommunications
equipment as a main goal of French telecommunications policy. Since the gov-
ernment wanted to retain domestic control over these key industries and the
major subsidies they received, government policy aimed to minimize foreign
competition in the electronics industry in France. Thus, the government finan-
146 France
world electronics market, including France's former colonies. France had only
0.3 percent of the U.S. electronics market (Scientific American, 1983)
Furthermore, government plans had generated little success for French con-
sumer electronics, office equipment, and computers. In 1982, Bull amassed
losses of FFr 1.35 billion, while IBM France posted identical profits.
To improve this situation, the incoming Socialist government's five year plan
of 1982 provided as one of its four main objectives the development of French
expertise in electronics. At that time, telecommunications had a turnover of
about FFr 26 billion (i.e. sales revenue), and comprised more than one quarter
of France's filiere electronique, the chain of technical, social, and economic
activities associated with the electronics industry. The investment target for the
five year-period (governmental, private, and academic) was FFr 140 billion
(approximately $21 billion) for the five-year period. This was approximately
$4 billion annually, a sum comparable in magnitude to IBM's $2 million R&D
expenditure at the time (Darmon, 1985, p. 79).
For a long time, France maintained a policy of promoting "national cham-
pion" firms and projects of high prestige and visibility such as the Concorde,
the first light water nuclear power plant, the largest solar energy furnace, and
a high-speed train. Le Monde dubbed these projects the "new cathedrals" (Crane,
1979). A major theoretician behind the Mitterrand government plans and poli-
cies was Jacques Attali, counselor to the president, who described his French
economic model as "based on a mathematical model influenced by linguistics
and psychoanalysis."
The Socialist government implemented its policy in three major steps. The
first was the nationalization of the electronics sector. The second was a restruc-
turing that, in effect, assigned specialized functions to the various nationalized
companies: CII-Honeywell-Bull (CII-HB) was designated for computers; Al-
catel for telecommunications and office automation; Thomson and Matra for
semiconductors; and Thomson for consumer electronics. The third step was a
five-year, $20 billion government development plan for electronics, which was
only partly implemented.
Industrial planning designated the electronics area as the hoped-for "loco-
motive" for French industry. Economic models of the demand for goods and
services corresponding to the growth of telecommunications services supported
this industrial plan. Studies concluded that telecommunications represented one
of the best investment choices for the stimulation of production (Bonan et al.,
1985). Nationalization and government control were justified by the charge that
French private business had not been stoking the locomotive hot enough. Ac-
cording to Jean-Pierre Chevenement, then the minister of research and industry,
"If capitalism had worked the way it was supposed to, things might be differ-
ent todaybut capitalism did not work" (Locksley, 1983, p. 134). Similarly,
for Pierre Dreyfus, the French minister of industry and one-time head of the
Renault automobile company, "private enterprise in France does not take risks;
it is chilly, timid, shy, against taking risks even when they are necessary for
new products and long-term needs" (Delamaide, 1982, p. 167).
148 France
Still, France had fared relatively well in the global recession of 1981, and it
is not obvious why the governmentalready the dominant force in the elec-
tronics industry through the DOT, military procurement, and R&D financing
had to target this sector for nationalization.
Americans speak of nationalized industries, but the French call them na-
tional industries. France has a well-established tradition of national industries,
including firms such as the tobacco monopoly, Seita; the advertising agency
and communications firm, Havas; the automobile firm, Renault; and all the
major banks, in addition to the more conventional state activities in heavy in-
dustry, utilities, and transportation. The state's role in industrial policy dates
back at least to Colbert, under whom state enterprises such as the Gobelins
tapestry and Sevres porcelain works were established in 1681. Three centuries
later, in 1982, Prime Minister Pierre Mauroy celebrated this tradition by pro-
claiming "nationalization is a form of the French genius" (Delamaide, 1982,
p. 167).
The industry is enormously dependent on government procurement. In 1988,
France Telecom provided a market of $2.5 billion, or 45 percent of production,
for the French telecommunications industry, whose exports accounted for 15
percent ($800 million), with the French private sector and the military together
adding another 40 percent (Steckel and Fossier, 1990, p. 6). The industry is
also highly concentrated. Of the forty companies comprising the sector, the
largest five accounted for 90 percent of total production. Three of these five
were nationalized: CGE (including CIT-Alcatel), Thomson (Thomson-CSF and
LMT), and CGCT. Additionally, the computer manufacturer CIT-Honeywell-
Bull, and the defense and electronics firm Matraboth increasingly moving
into telecommunicationswere nationalized. Altogether, the French state be-
came an owner of three quarters of the telecommunications equipment busi-
ness. Several smaller groups remained in private hands, such as G3S, which
included CSEE and SAT (Societe Anonyme de Telecommunications Radio-
electrique et Telephonique) affiliated with the Dutch company Philips and ac-
tive in microwave, radio, and data communications and switching. The com-
pany Jeumont-Schneider produced electronic PBXs.
The nationalization of the electronics industry was part of a larger pattern.
By 1982, 30 percent of the country's entire industry was state owned, and the
government had holdings in more than a thousand firms. These firms controlled
95 percent of bank assets and about half of all French business activities (Mon-
sen, 1984). But by the end of 1983 the franc had been devalued three times,
and nationalized companies had lost an estimated $4.5 billion. Whereas ini-
tially they retained considerable flexibility under Industry Minister Dreyfus,
who as head of Renault had learned the benefits of decentralization, they were
subsequently burdened by much more interference under his successor, the more
left-leaning Jean-Pierre Chevenement. This led to a rebellion of company pres-
idents, who appealed directly to Mitterrand. Laurent Fabius, the pragmatic bud-
get minister, was reassigned to the ministry of industry. After becoming prime
minister of France in 1984 at the age of thirty-seven, Fabius renewed a flexible,
France 149
tral office equipment and PBXs, which had been unable to make the transition
to electronic switches and maintain its 10 percent share of the market. The
Socialists did not want AOIP to die. It also preferred the DOT to have several
equipment manufacturers to choose from. The government had already inter-
vened in 1979, requiring Thomson and CIT-Alcatel to hire part of AOIP's
personnel, to use its factories, and to manufacture a switch developed by the
AOIP, the URA 2G. CIT-Alcatel already had an equivalent product, and it
could dodge the order, but Thomson had to comply. Some of the difficulties
Thomson experienced in the early 1980s can be traced to its forced adaptation
to the URA 2G (Darmon, 1985, p. 171).
CGE's telecommunications, on the other hand, prospered. The emergence of
digital exchanges coincided with the great expansion of the French network.
Together, they made CGE the European leader in TDM switching. In 1977,
the DOT opted for the CIT-Alcatel E-10 as the centerpiece of its large-scale
expansion. To reduce CIT-Alcatel's bargaining strength, the DOT also desig-
nated the Thomson MT system as its second source. CGE's Alcatel produces
TDM switching systems, submarine cable systems, PBXs, and PCM equip-
ment. Its subsidiary, Alcatel Electronique, is involved in peripheral equipment.
Another subsidiary, SESA, is a leader in packet switching networks (Quatre-
point, 1984). CGE was also active in transmission lines and cable television
through its subsidiary Cables de Lyon. It also became dominant domestically
in nuclear reactor construction.
The second major player in the telecommunications equipment field, already
repeatedly mentioned, was Thomson-CSF a part of the Thomson Group ag-
glomeration of more than 100 companies and subsidiaries. Under a variety of
labels, it held over 30 percent of the European Community's color television
market. In 1987, it also acquired RCA's consumer electronics division in ex-
change for some of its own subsidiaries (particularly those involved with med-
ical equipment), and became the world's second largest TV manufacturer.
Thomson owned the major German television set manufacturersAEG, Tele-
funken, Nordmende, and Sabaaccounting for about one-quarter of the Ger-
man market.
The Socialist government nationalized Thomson in 1981. To facilitate its
nationalization plan, it pledged $900 million in financial support to Thomson
for telecommunications development. Alain Gomez, a graduate of ENA and
the Harvard Business School and a former leftist, was appointed to replace the
previous group of managers, whose career backgrounds had been predomi-
nantly in the military and who were known for a slow moving management
style. Of the top eleven managers under Thomson's former regime, only two
had come from civilian industry. Five top executives, including the president,
hailed from the navy. The company focused on military business and was less
profitable in consumer markets. When it became a state-owned enterprise, it
was directed to focus on consumer markets. The government hoped to avoid
repetition of Thomson's failure to exploit the potential of video disc players.
In 1972, the company had been at the forefront in developing the video disc
player, but rather than applying the technology commercially, it sold it as a
154 France
tool for teaching the maintenance of military equipment, without promoting its
applications in consumer electronics. Eventually, Thomson left video disc pro-
duction and licensed its technology to a Japanese firm, which produced the
machines at half the French cost (Pierrand, 1984). (Of course, it was in good
company, since Philips and RCA were similarly unsuccessful.) Thomson is
also the largest French producer of electronic components. In 1987, Thomson
merged its semiconductor activities with those of the Italian firm SGS, then a
member of the STET group.
As part of its nationalization activities, the French government bought out in
1982 ITT's remaining French telecommunications companies, mainly CGCT.
ITT valued its French companies at $375 million but got much less in compen-
sation. The government argued that CGCT was unprofitable, but this was a
self-fulfilling prophecy. ITT lost money in France because its equipment, which
sold well around the world, was rejected by the DGT in favor of French switches.
As a result, the government could point to the company's relative lack of com-
mercial success and argue for a low compensation for its expropriation.
The government assured CGCT's allocated share of about 16 percent of the
DGT procurement. This was augmented by government contributions of FFr
188 million to CGCT's capital. Still the company asked for FFr 1 billion in
various forms.
But things kept changing. In 1983, Gomez reached a transfer agreement with
George Pebereau, director-general of the CGE, handing over all of Thomson's
civil telecommunications activities in exchange for CGE's departure from mil-
itary procurement until at least 1990.3 Thomson was heavily in the red, having
not only devoted itself to developing the MT system, but spread itself using
over different switching systems (Darmon, 1985, p. 95). The reorganization
was by no means forced on the companies by the government. Gomez and
Pebereau persuaded Laurent Fabius that France's telecommunications needed
consolidation and "rationalization" in order to be internationally competitive.
The restructuring was unprecedented in its size or scope in Europe. Its main
aspect was that CGE and Thomson swapped major assets. After the exchange,
a new telecommunications group was created that combined the telecommuni-
cations businesses of Thomson and CGE, controlled by the CGE subsidiary
CIT-Alcatel. Thomson, for its part, received CGE's electronics component
business, military division, and consumer electronics operations. There were
several reasons for the reorganization. It attempted to simplify the existing
structure (i.e., to reduce competition 4 ) and generate economies of scale. But
more important, it attempted to stop the substantial financial losses at Thom-
son, which had been FFr 2.2 billion in 1982, with no end in sight.
The DGT, however, opposed consolidation because it did not wish to be
dependent on a single equipment supplier. In its view, rivalry between com-
petitive suppliers would benefit technological innovation (a perspective it did
not usually extend to its own operations) and make the DGT less dependent on
one company. For the previous right-of-center government, it had been axio-
matic to provide for multiple French suppliers; it had encouraged Thomson-
CSF to enter by having it absorb ITT's LMT and Ericsson's interests. To pre-
France 155
vent the CGE-Thomson reorganization, the DOT argued that a single domestic
supplier could only provide about 65 percent of these needs, whereas two na-
tional suppliers could provide about 90 percent. Thus, it concluded that the
consolidation had negative implications for the French balance of trade and for
French jobs by opening up the domestic market to foreign competitors.
In the end, Fabius accepted the Gomez and Pebereau proposal and consented
to financial support: In 1984, FFr 1.7 billion in capital endorsements and FFr
250 million in public credits were extended toward the reorganization, with FFr
500 million earmarked for 1985. Ironically, Thomson got the same amount of
government money for leaving the field as it had unsuccessfully requested in
order to stay in the telephone business (Darmon, 1985, p. 96).
The agreement led to the creation of Alcatel-Thomson, a manufacturer with
sales of FFr 12 million and 40,000 employees. The combination represented
70 percent of French domestic telecommunications production and ranked at
that time fifth in world telecommunications production. Alcatel-Thomson con-
trolled 85 percent of public switching, 75 percent of electromagnetic transmis-
sion, 6 percent of cable, and 60 percent of private telephone sets.
In the past, the American and French markets for telecommunications equip-
ment had barely overlapped. In the mid-1970s the U.S. Department of Com-
merce found that imports were only 3-4 percent of total telecommunications
equipment sales in France, and of those, the U.S. share was only 1 percent of
the total, made up primarily of teleprinters, modems, microwave components,
and test equipment. (This, however, did not include ITT's substantial activities
in France; its ownership was American but its production and R&D European.)
The DGT created or continued cartels with leading manufacturers (U.S. De-
partment of Commerce, 1975, p. 3). Sotolec was formed in 1947 for compa-
nies in transmission equipment. Two years later, Socotel was similarly estab-
lished for the switching equipment industry, continuing an arrangement of the
Vichy regime. Members of the Sotolec cartel included the firms LMT, SAT,
TRT, CGE, CIT-Alcatel, and Thomson-CSF, and their main purpose was to
"prohibit ruinous and savage competition." Though sometimes characterized
as paper organizations, these cartels controlled equipment specifications, pat-
ents, and development. CNET maintained technological control over suppliers
and at the same time provided suppliers with access to design specifications
and to each others' patents on a royalty-free basis.
French firms similarly found much of the U.S. market difficult to reach. But
with the AT&T divestiture, the close link between the Bell Operating Compa-
nies and AT&T, which had assured AT&T dominant access to the world's
largest market for telecommunications equipment, was severed, and French
producers began eyeing this opening with great hopes. In consequence, CGE's
Alcatel subsidiary worked hard at breaking into U.S. markets.
French telecommunications equipment exports to the United States grew from
156 France
4.4 percent of the French export market in 1983 to 19.3 percent in 1988. Total
French exports in 1988 were Ffr 10.156 billion, more than double the 1983
figure. Exports to Western Europe, on the other hand, declined relatively from
17.3 percent to 13.8 percent. However, Alcatel's success was limited mostly
to the small independent telephone companies. Eventually, the firm reduced its
U.S. switching activities for lack of a major market success.5
During the same period, AT&T found itself unable to crack the French mar-
ket. This led to an important agreement in 1985 between AT&T-Philips (APT)
and Alcatel involving a partial mutual opening of each others' markets. Behind
the agreement was the question of what to do with the remaining French public
switch manufacturer, CGCT, which the French government had nationalized
from ITT in 1982. CGCT was losing large sums of money, but it had one
major asset, the traditional allocation of 16 percent of the French public switch-
ing market, or approximately 300,000 lines per year, as a second source for
the DOT. CGCT was initially given the task of manufacturing the Thomson
MT digital switch under a license, but it was in no position to develop and
upgrade it for the future. The question then of who would be the second source
supplier to the DGT therefore remained unresolved. One would think that the
DGT itself would be the one to decide with what other firm it would like to
deal. However, CGE, which already held 84 percent of the market, was in fact
negotiating with a foreign consortium about whether it should be admitted to
the market as CGE's competitor, in return for export benefits to CGE. CGE
was, in effect, selling the share of the French market that, for political reasons,
it did not supply. Specifically, CGE agreed that APT would receive CGCT's
16 percent market share for its 5-ESS PRX switch, to be manufactured in
France by CGCT and adapted to French standards. CGE would receive several
types of benefits: AT&T would supply marketing and technical assistance in
adapting its El0-5 switch for North American use; it would include it in its
product line and pay indemnities if sales did not reach a specified amount.
Second, Philips would transfer the microwave equipment manufacturing of its
French TRT subsidiary into a joint venture controlled by CGE, while AT&T
would undertake to buy at least $200 million of such microwave transmission
equipment over four years. In other words, Philips would relinquish control
over one of the few activities competitive with CGE in France, and AT&T
would help sell the products in the United States. Lastly, CGE would receive
$100 million.
CGCT, unenthusiastic about AT&T, preferred to deal with Siemens or
Ericsson, but for CGE, AT&T was a more compliant partner. Given the close
European collaboration between France and Germany, including the heavy in-
volvement of French companies in German consumer electronics, a company
such as Siemens, once it had a toehold in the French market, could not be
easily subjected to political protectionism. In contrast, any AT&T involvement
in France could receive much greater government scrutiny and future pressure,
since public opposition against it could always be easily organized.
The agreement required government approval and was criticized on a variety
of grounds. First, French trade unions sought guarantees, fearing that AT&T
France 157
own problems. ITT's System 12 has advanced fully distributed processing, and
when widely deployed, the intercommunication between its different modules
can cause overloads. The MT20 switch was transferred to Alcatel from Thom-
son in 1983 and found few fans, even in France. Alcatel's own E10 switch
itself was losing international market share and needed modernization. Alca-
tel's main challenge, however, was not technical, but political and managerial:
It had to hold together a wide array of subsidiaries functioning under divergent
policy environments, management styles, and product lines.
The newly merged firm became the second largest international telecommu-
nications firm after AT&T, amassing $7 billion in assets, almost $10 billion in
sales, and 150,000 employees. It supplied a huge 42.5 percent of all European
public telephone switches. CGE heralded the agreement as establishing, for the
first time, a large-scale European telecommunications firm, but few Europeans
got enthusiastic over such a French state-dominated arrangement. CGE claimed
that it required the merger to give it sufficient size to operate the economies of
scale necessary for success. In other words, it asserted that it took almost half
the European market to be economically viable.
This deal finally established the French victory over ITT after more than half
a century of struggle. Georges Pebereau had been its strategist. But soon after
his triumph, the new conservative government replaced him with Pierre Suard.
The deal put into question CGE's separate arrangement, also negotiated by
Pebereau, with AT&T. Now, with CGE inheriting much of ITT's footholds in
many other European countries, it was likely that these countries would expect
greater reciprocity. In return, the 16 percent market share that had been allo-
cated to AT&T might be more usefully employed to assuage one or several
European countries, notably Germany. In other words, it was time for CGE to
reassess its contract with AT&T. The tug-of-war grew acrimonious. Within the
French government, the DGT preferred APT, while other ministries did not
wish to antagonize Germany, which was backing Siemens. The rival companies
successively sweetened their bids. In the end,the French government chose the
Swedish Ericsson as a neutral compromise, together with the French defense
firm Matra, which thus gained a foothold in its country's telecommunications.
Subsequently, Alcatel Chairman Pierre Suard strongly opposed AT&T's in-
volvement in Italy. Suard stated that the goal of European telecommunications
policy must be to maintain and improve the leadership of European industry.
In 1989, CGE had 210,300 employees, an increase over the 192,000 in 1982,
but this concealed significant staff cuts prior to and following its integration of
ITT's international telecommunications operations in 1987. For example, Al-
catel cut its new acquisition's work force by 25,000 to 125,000 and closed
seven of ITT's eighteen national research labs (Tully, 1989). As CGE became
the second largest manufacturer of central switching equipment worldwide, ac-
tive in over 100 countries, it lent the domestic French industry a major inter-
national presence.
Alcatel's opposition to the AT&T/Italtel partnership contributed to its acqui-
sition of Italy's Telettra in 1990. Alcatel thereby bought Telettra's 33 percent
market share in tranmission equipment in Italy and a 45 percent share of the
France 159
same market in Spain. Combined revenues of Alcatel and Telettra were $10.9
billion in 1989 compared with total of $11.1 billion in 1990. But in an effort
to reduce anti-competitive vertical integration, the European Commission re-
quired Spain's Telefonica telephone monopoly to divest itself first of its 21
percent share in the Spanish Alcatel subsidiary and of its 10 percent share in
Telettra, as well as open its purchasing policy. Alcatel merged its satellite op-
erations with Aerospatiale and bought the transmission equipment division of
U.S. giant Rockwell.
The early mainstay of the domestic French computer industry was Groupe Bull,
which began in 1931, when a French group, partly owned by the Callies fam-
ily, cousins of the Michelin tire owners, bought the patent for punched card
machines from the Norwegian inventor Fredrik Bull. Its first significant product
was a tabulator-printer that successfully competed against the French subsidi-
ary of IBM, which had been established in 1920 (Mclnnes, 1964).
In 1952, Bull introduced its first computer, reputedly more innovative than
IBM's most advanced 604 computer, though IBM was just then starting in the
computer business. Bull's revenues rose tenfold in the decade from 1952 to
1962; exports grew 30 percent annually, and its labor force increased sixfold
to 14,000. Bull became the darling of the Paris Bourse, with its shares reaching
a price of 1470 francs by 1960, although its earnings never exceeded 3.80
francs per share.
Trouble soon followed, as IBM's more advanced 650 computer started to
recapture market share from the Bull models. Bull fell further behind when
IBM introduced its 1401 transistorized computer. While trying to recoup its
losses with the high-priced and innovative Gamma 60 computer, Bull's produc-
tion and development lagged behind schedule. The machines had chronic prob-
lems, and Bull sold or leased only fourteen of them. IBM came out with a still
more advanced series, the 7070 model (Bransten and Brown, 1964, p. 154).
Stymied in its products development, Bull sought help in America, entering a
ten-year agreement for the sale of RCA's computers in France under the Bull
label. It also obtained access to RCA's patents and production knowhow and
soon marketed RCA's Model 301 in France, promoting it as a French product
competing with those of the foreign IBM (some of whose products were man-
ufactured in France for export to other European countries). Unfortunately for
Bull, RCA soon left the computer business altogether.
Despite the success of its shares, Bull was undercapitalized and met with
economic difficulties. Instead of reducing their control to raise equity, the own-
ers took on large debts. When they faced the necessity of raising equity, the
stock had begun to drop and it was too late. Between 1959 and 1962, total
indebtedness increased fivefold, exceeding capital and reserves. In desperation,
Bull restructured, to gain access to the Swiss financial markets, and sold off its
share in Olivetti-Bull, a computer venture with Olivetti in Italy.
160 France
By 1963, the French government urged the state banks to assume control of
Bull. Bull's chairman, Callies, sought links with the American company Gen-
eral Electric, at that time a computer maker with European ambitions, as pref-
erable to control by the French government. Although GE agreed to buy 20
percent of Bull, the two companies had not reckoned with President Charles de
Gaulle, who personally ordered the deal stopped, believing it contrary to the
French interest in its computer industry to have an American firm share own-
ership. But after the government failed to line up French support, it was, em-
barrassingly, forced to permit an even larger participation of GE in Bull (49
percent) than the one it had previously vetoed, and at a lower sale price,
amounting to a virtual control of Bull by the American company. The French
government insisted, however, on segregating GE's control from Bull's defense
contracts, which at that time involved developing France's nuclear capability.
The deal was rationalized as part of a strategy of teaming up with another
American giant against IBM.
Not surprisingly, General Electric soon experienced major headaches with
Bull. Though it was clear that Bull was overstaffed, GE had committed itself
to not reducing employment. When it was confronted with reality, a period of
labor strife ensued. GE also canceled two ongoing computer developments at
Bull. Eventually, GE left the computer business entirely, with Honeywell as-
suming its share in Bull, to form the Honeywell-Bull company.
French concerns over computer "sovereignty" were not ill founded. The
French were shocked by the U.S. State Department's refusal of an export li-
cense for large scientific computers to the French atomic energy commission
for use in H-bomb research. Realizing its vulnerability, the government for-
mulated its Plan Calcul in 1966 and 1967, among other projects, merging two
French-owned computer manufacturers, CAE (owned by CSF and CGE, both
important telecommunications manufacturers) and SEA (a subsidiary of the
Schneider industrial group) to create the firm CII (Compagnie Internationale
pour 1'Information). Another element of the Plan Calcul was financial support
to establish consortia for the development of electronic technology. Bull, the
main computer firm, was excluded from the Plan Calcul because of its Ameri-
can links. A computer czar, with the title of "Delegate Generate," was to
oversee the projects and the government procurement, although the position
largely became a public relations affair.
Plan Calcul delineated goals for. the development of scientific computing,
leaving much of commercial office computer market to IBM. This misjudged
the explosive growth of business applications of computers, while failing to
recognize the innovativeness of the American Control Data Corporation (CDC)
in the scientific computing field.
The product strategy behind the Plan Calcul also missed other developments.
The emergence of time-shared use of computers, linking terminals to a power-
ful central computer, led the Plan to predict a future with only a few giant
mainframes and consequently to set product development priorities toward de-
veloping such machines. The subsequent trend was almost the opposite; mini-
and microcomputers proliferated, and IBM was not the dominant firm in that
France 161
market. On the other hand, one benefit from the Plan Calcul was to provide
digital technology skills to Thomson and to CGE, which were later applied to
digital telecommunications switches. This link was not foreseen in the Plan
Calcul, but it was its major success.
A second Plan Calcul was instituted in 1971, again amidst much publicity:
in absolute terms, however, the support levels were small. For the first Plan
between 1966 and 1971, government support had been $140 million. For the
second five years (1971-1976) support was $263 million.
CII had been nursed along with infusions of government capital. But after a
while, a strategic rift developed between CH's two major owners, Thomson-
Brandt and CGE, then rivals in the telecommunications field. The French gov-
ernment, Thomson, and CII were in favor of CH's participation together with
Philips and Siemens in the European computer venture Unidata, designed as a
competitor to IBM. However, CGE wanted a link with the second semi-French
computer company, Honeywell-Bull, and refused to put up money for Uni-
data.
By 1976, neither CII nor Honeywell-Bull were doing well; with some gov-
ernment pressure and financial help, they were merged into CII-Honeywell-
Bull, which was 53 percent French and 47 percent owned by Honeywell. The
new firm had an extraordinarily complex structure to assure participation by
major French electronic firms, by the French government itself (9.5 percent),
and by Honeywell. Recognizing the importance of orders, the government
promised $800 million of public sector procurement within the next four years,
to provide necessary economies of scale. If that target was not met, major
contractual damages would have to be paid to the company by the government.
It turned out to be expensive for the French public sector to buy the French
computers to replace IBM systems. In particular, the cost of converting soft-
ware turned out to be much higher than the cost for computers themselves. For
the government, this more than doubled the amount it had planned to spend on
CII-Honeywell-Bull computers.
With the Mitterrand nationalizations, Honeywell was forced to reduce its
involvement in Bull substantially. But because its participation was still deemed
to be desirable because of its access to advanced technology and the American
market, it retained 19.9 percent of Bull and entered into a ten-year marketing
and technology agreement with it. The French government also invested 1.5
billion francs in Bull. In 1986, Honeywell exited from computer manufacturing
altogether.
In the 1980s, Groupe Bull's guiding philosophy shifted. It had not been able
to manufacture its DPS7 computer, which was on the drawing board since
1979. Bull began to rely on cooperative agreements with other firms, including
Honeywell, Convergent, Trilogy, and NEC. Such a strategy brought with it the
risk of transforming Bull into a marketer of others' products, while contradict-
ing notions of French autonomy in the computer field that underlie much of the
government's financial efforts.
Bull was the twelfth largest computer manufacturer in the world. In the Eu-
ropean market for minicomputers, it was second, with 11 percent of the total.
162 France
It was weaker in low-end minis and especially mainframes; the latter market
was dominated by IBM (57 percent) and Siemens (15 percent), leaving Bull
with a 6 percent share. In 1988, Bull received 18 percent of its revenues from
U.S. operations (Schenker, 1989a, p. 13). It then sought a greater share of the
U.S. market and acquired in 1989 the computer division of Zenith, an Ameri-
can manufacturer in financial difficulties because of its television manufactur-
ing.
Groupe Bull continued to receive some $150 million annually from the French
government (Petersen, 1989, p. 80). But its finances were in trouble. At the
turn of the decade, Bull suffered heavy losses. In 1990, Bull's incurred a $1.2
billion deficit, necessitating a $700 million government contribution together
with France Telecom. Bull also sought minority participation by NEC. The
Japanese company already provided it with mainframe technology.
Sem/cont/ucfors
In 1982, French companies accounted for only 5 percent of their domestic
microprocessor and MOS/memory market (though this number rises to 45 per-
cent when foreign companies producing in France are included). To increase
the French share has been a major development priority for the government's
filiere electronique industrial policy in the 1980s, an "action program for the
electronics sector" aimed at creating at least 1000 jobs. To attain its aims, the
government encouraged the creation of two new French-American ventures,
Matra-Harris Semiconductors (MHS) and Eurotechnique, by Saint-Gobain and
National Semiconductors (Malerba, 1985). Other major French microcompo-
nent manufacturers were Thomson and Schlumberger; The latter acquired the
American company Fairchild, a pioneer in integrated circuits that had lost its
leadership position partly because of the flight of some top personnel into en-
trepreneurial start-ups. Schlumberger played an important role for a while, headed
by the legendary Jean Riboud, an intimate of President Mitterrand. It was at
one time called the best managed enterprise in the world, but Riboud died in
1985 and the company was beset by problems in its declining oil drilling busi-
ness. Heavy losses on its Fairchild semiconductor operation led Schlumberger
to sell it in 1986.
A second "Components Plan" (Plan Composants) was adopted in 1983,
seeking to promote specialized components in telecommunications, military ap-
plications, and MOS (metal oxide) technology. The plan's economic goals in-
cluded raising French volume of production to 4.65 billion francs in 1986. The
plan's budget was FFr 3.2 billion (FFr 700-800 million annually), mostly
benefitting four companies. The government's telecommunications research arm
CNET also played an important role in this area.
In 1987, Thomson merged its semiconductor operations with those of SGS,
France 163
the microchip firm controlled by the Italian government's STET group, to form
Europe's second largest microchip firm after Philips.
Communications Satellites
France Telecom itself continued to widen the scope of its activities. It had
155,000 employees and revenues of $166.6 billion in 1989. It had 27 million
access lines, forty-five main lines per 100 persons. It established international
partnerships in Germany, Spain, Italy, and Singapore (the latter cable project
involved a $600 million fiber optic cable from France through the Middle East
to Singapore), and joint projects with Germany's DBF Telekom, a Phonepoint
bid with BT, as well as participation in Infonet and a Pacific Cable with other
partners (Steckel and Fossier, 1990). After the Chirac conservative government
came to power in 1986, Gerard Longuet, a leader of the right-of-center Repub-
licans, became PTT minister. Although the conservative government took an
early and active role in privatizing the broadcasting field, it moved more care-
fully in telephony. It promised to propose legislation that would establish pri-
vate competition in the telecommunications field by the end of 1987.
Marcel Roulet, a PTT veteran, was appointed as the Chirac government's
director of the DOT. He recommended ending the DGT's dual role of network
operations and regulation and establishing the DOT as a state enterprise rather
than as a government administration. Under this plan, the industrial policy role
of the DGT would move to the Ministry of Industry and some of the DGT's
164 France
competitive subsidiaries would be partly privatized. At the same time, the DOT
would be free, under such an arrangement, to participate in joint ventures with
private companies and to purchase its equipment more freely.
Longuet was succeeded by his party colleague, Frangois Leotard. He ex-
panded the High Authority of the Audiovisual Sector, an agency created by the
Socialists a few years earlier to supervise broadcasting, into a National Com-
mission for Communications and Liberties (CNCL), with some regulatory pow-
ers also over telecommunications. In October 1986, the ministry set up the
Mission a la Reglementation to handle postal and telecommunications regula-
tion. Jean-Pierre Chamoux headed this task force, developing new policy ini-
tiatives along these lines, but many of its proposals were slowed down when
the labor unions threatened disruption and presidential elections interfered.
The government did not recommend an opening to competing service provid-
ers in transmission. This left the liberalization of value-added networks services
(VANS) as a major focus. Since 1987, VANS had been legalized and usually
needed only to notify the PTT administration to commence operations. The
decree distinguished between closed, user group networks and universal net-
works open to third parties.
The Chirac government moved more actively in the reprivatization of the
electronics industry. CGE was sold, undivided, to the public in May of 1987
for $3.7 billion. Thus, a private near-monopoly in telecommunications equip-
ment succeeded the public one. Next was CGCT, which was sold to Ericsson
and Matra in January 1988. The privatizations of Thomson and Bull were de-
layed after the stock market crash of 1987 and were later abandoned after the
presidential elections confirmed Mitterrand in 1988.
Furthermore, it was more difficult to privatize painlessly the two money los-
ing companies. In 1990, Thomson had a deficit necessitating a $350 million
contribution by the government. Bull's deficit was $1.2 billion. Alcatel's profit
for the same year was $750 million.
Chirac's efforts at privatization had been opposed by Paul Quiles, former
oil company engineer and minister of defense, though not particularly well
versed in telecommunications issues. A savvy politician, Quiles became PTT
minister in the Socialist government that soon returned to power. At the same
time, the PTT became the Ministry of PTEPost, Telecommunications, and
Spacereflecting the growing importance of satellite to network communica-
tions.
In 1988, the regulatory and operational functions of the DGT were split into
the Direction de la Reglementation Generale (DRG), and France Telecom, the
new name for the DGT. The DRG (the former Mission a la Reglementation)
has authority over type approval, value-added services, and the electromagnetic
spectrum (Roussel, 1989b). Its first head was Bruno Lassere, formerly legal
counsel to the DGT, while Marcel Roulet was appointed the first director gen-
eral of France Telecom. The DRG also represents France in international ne-
gotiations. Authority over France Telecom's most significant decisions such as
network investments, public service obligations, and management remained un-
France 165
der the control of the PTE through the Direction des Services Publiques (DSP).
The DRG had only authority over competitive services, which was still limited
to a handful of VANs and a small second cellular service provider, and its
powers to bring competition to the French market were limited.
In 1989, Quiles commissioned an analysis of French policy from civil ser-
vant Hubert Prevot. Originally a defender of the DOT monopoly, Quiles stated
publicly that growth should not be constricted by "archaic structures." Quiles
also had the support of France Telecom's management, which had complained
about political control (Dawkins, 1990b). The Prevot report recommended the
formal separation of post and telecommunications services, and the removal of
France Telecom's equity from the Treasury to create a more autonomous and
competitive entity. The autonomy would also change the civil servant status of
employees. This resulted in union opposition. Led by the Communist CGT
labor federation, one fifth of PTT workers went on to strike in 1990. Despite
the national debate they triggered, the proposed reforms passed the National
Assembly with surprising ease. In the Senate, however, the proposal's detrac-
tors were many. The strongest criticism came from a group of conservative
senators led by Gerard Larcher, a strong supporter of former PTT minister
Longuet. They issued a scathing report that charged Quiles with being weak-
kneed in his proposed reforms. The report claimed that, despite gaining auton-
omy, France Telecom would still answer to the government in setting tariffs
and before making large investments or purchases. The senators found partic-
ular fault with the program's hiring provisions, labeling them too rigid to stop
the chronic "brain drain" from management ranks.
The Larcher committee also proposed that a larger contingent of lawmakers
be chosen for the proposed twenty-one-member France Telecom board and that
more autonomy be given to the board than was recommended by Quiles. The
Senate conservatives also wanted to create a European Telecommunications
Foundation to promote the continent's interests in telecommunications.
After promises of job security for employees, the government's reform pro-
posals passed the National Assembly and Senate in May 1990. The law pro-
vided that France Telecom be separate from La Poste and managed by a twenty-
one-member board, including representatives of French ministries and users
groups. France Telecom's president is nominated to a three-year term by the
government. It must negotiate its budget with the government and set rates
according to a price-cap scheme, instead of the past 6 percent rate-of-return
system. In addition, the COGECOM subsidiaries, including TDF, Transpac,
and France Cables et Radio, were all removed from the control of the Finance
Ministry.
Paul Quiles was succeeded in 1991 by Jean-Marie Rausch, and in 1992 by
Emile Zuccarelli, head of a small leftist party and a mayor in Corsica, but
without a telecommunications background. The position of PTE Minister was
downgraded to a junior minister reporting to the Minister of Finance, Economy
and Budget.
Limited proposals to liberalize terminal equipment and value-added service
166 France
markets were introduced in 1990, and France Telecom's monopoly over basic
telephone, telex and national network services was reaffirmed. V-sat licenses
were issued in 1991 to France Telecom, but also to BAeCom, Alpha Lyracom,
Reuters, and PolyCom. A second mobile license was awarded to SFR.
Thus, the first steps in what will be a continuing journey toward an industry
structure of greater openness had been initiated, though they still represent pri-
marily a strengthening of the traditional operator, liberalizing its ability to func-
tion successfully rather than altering the structure of the communications sec-
tor.
Telecommunications in Benelux
and the Alpine Countries
This page intentionally left blank
10
The Netherlands
169
170 The Netherlands
Services
Telephone line density increased more than sixfold in twenty years, from 1
million in 1960 to 6.4 million in 1980. This growth rate slowed in the 1980s
The Netherlands 171
from 13 percent to 4 percent and lower, since most households had been reached.
Long waiting lists of potential subscribers had accumulated during the 1970s,
peaking in 1977 at 200,000. By 1982, this backlog had been reduced to 1
percent of main stations.
By 1988, telephone density in the Netherlands reached sixty-six sets per 100
population. According to the OECD, the 1990 tariffs in the Netherlands are
Europe's lowest for business services, $430.21 yearly, and the third lowest for
residential customers ($224.48 yearly), behind Iceland and Sweden. The den-
sity of the Dutch network allows the Netherlands to offer low rates (Montgo-
mery, et al., 1990).'
Despite the country's small size, PTT Telecom was the world's eighth larg-
est international carrier in 1988.
In 1962, the Netherlands became the second country in the world, after Swit-
zerland, to achieve a fully automated national telephone service. Electronic
switching started in 1972, with the Ericsson AKE-13, a stored-program-con-
trolled (SPC) exchange. The Philips PRX-205 local switch followed in 1974.
In 1980, Ericsson's AXE exchange was also put into service in order to provide
a second supplier. In that year, 30 percent of subscribers were served by SPC
switches, the highest such density in the world at the time according to ITT.
Since 1984, fully electronic exchanges have gradually replaced electromechan-
ical exchanges as part of a fifteen-year investment program to digitalize the
network, using AT&T technology after 1983. PTT Telecom inaugurated a pilot
test of international ISDN service in October 1989, linking Rotterdam with
Diisseldorf.
The public packet switching service Datanet-1 operated from 1982 on a trial
basis, and since 1984 commercially, with transmission rates up to 48 kbps. It
provides international access. Telex penetration in the Netherlands is among
the highest in Europe, but falling. Since 1984, an electronic mail service was
offered over Datanet-1. Multisat provides international broadband data com-
munications via satellites.2
Most post offices in the country carry Faxpost, a public facsimile service.
Other services include cellular telephone and radio paging through the Benelux
system. Videotex, under the name of Viditel, was introduced in 1980. The
broadcast text service teletext was started in 1980 by the broadcast associations
and NOS, their umbrella state organization. The PTT and several Dutch cable
operators formed a joint company in 1989 to develop a videotex service. How-
ever, PTT cooperation with cable television was controversial (Tutt, 1990).
Protracted debate occurred on privacy legislation. Following a commission's
reports of 1974 and 1976, a bill was introduced in 1981, but it was complex
and was withdrawn. The simplified substitute was debated for several years (de
Pous, 1988). After twenty years of discussion, a Data Protection Act was adopted
in 1988 and came into effect the next year. The Act required self-regulation in
the collection of personal data and established the right of individuals to access
and correct information files for a minimal fee.
172 The Netherlands
Equipment
In procuring equipment, the PTT has traditionally been close to the Dutch com-
pany Philips. Prior to the digitalization of the exchanges, Philips supplied about
70 percent of the PTT's SPC switches, with Ericsson's Dutch subsidiary sup-
plying the rest. In 1985, the PTT awarded a major contract for its 5ESS-PRX
digital switching system to the joint APT venture of Philips and AT&T. The
government also required the PTT to contract with a third and junior supplier
for digital switching, in addition to Ericsson and APT, to satisfy CGE-ITT
(Alcatel) with its subsidiary Nederlandsche Standard Electric Maatschappi
(NSEM) and its System 12. Subsequently, Alcatel, the second largest telecom-
munications firm in the world, established its formal headquarters in the Neth-
erlands, partly to soften its image as French dominated and to give it instead a
pan-European image. Much of Alcatel's actual management remained in France.
In the recent past, the PTT has had an extraordinary hold over customer
equipment. However, there has always been a distinction between the relative
severity of the letter of telecommunications regulation and the more flexible
reality. For example, large users understood well that the prohibition of sharing
leased lines was not an enforcement priority of the PTT. Similarly, although
the PTT had a total monopoly on all regular telephone sets until 1989, in prac-
tice, much customer equipment was purchased from private vendors (Hins and
Hugenholtz, 1986). The PTT also enjoyed a monopoly on the installation and
maintenance of PBXs and of the telephone sets attached to them. The PBX
remained the property of the PTT and was only leased to the user. In theory at
least, the PTT had the right to extend its monopoly into answering machines,
telefax, modems, and other data terminals, though it refrained from asserting
such broad authority.
Philips
Philips is the largest European electronics manufacturer and by far the largest
Dutch high-technology company (Tagliabue, 1987). Founded in 1894 by Anton
Frederik Philips and his brother Gerard to make electrical lamps, the company
keeps the name Gloewlampenfabrieken (incandescent lamp factory) in its title,
even though, beginning with the period after World War I, it has vastly ex-
panded its product line. Gerard, a mechanical engineer and chemist, initiated a
scientific tradition in the company that Gilles Hoist continued after World War
I. The company pioneered the electric dry shaver and was active in X-ray tubes
and hot gas engines. Gerard was childless, and the succession of control moved
to his brother's children (Philips, 1978).
Philips was hard hit by the Depression and later by the German occupation.
In anticipation of the occupation, Philips moved its legal headquarters to Cur-
acao, a Dutch possession safely located in the Western Hemisphere. Its exten-
sive American and British interests were placed in two separate trusts that were
The Netherlands 173
legally separate from the Dutch company. This maneuver guarded these parts
of the firm from take-over by the Allies after the German occupation of Hol-
land.
World War II put the company into the difficult situation of complying with
German-appointed supervisors while simultaneously trying to avoid attracting
Allied bombardment. The German supervisors were not interested in merely
running the company. In one instance, Philips was pressured to give up two
paintings by Lucas Cranach the Elder and coveted by Field Marshall Hermann
Goering, lest its raw material supply be cut off (Philips, 1978).
The Germans ordered Philips to reduce prices for its light bulbs. Frederik
Philips' comments on this incident in his corporate history provides a glimpse
into the protected Dutch electrical equipment market:
The former manager of our sales organization for the Netherlands and her colonies
had firmly believed in high prices for our lamps and would never budge. The result
was that, at the beginning of the occupation, there were in Holland no less than
twenty-three lamp factories, large and small, which survived under this heightened
price umbrella. Possibly the manufacturers loved us for this, but our lamps were
more expensive in Holland than abroada fact that the public knew. I decided that
we would lower our prices after the war by 50 percent. However, the Germans
were ahead of us: they suddenly ordered a substantial cut in retail prices [Philips,
1978].
After liberation, the company expanded substantially into other European
countries, the United States, and the Third World. It acquired Pye in Britain
and part of a major cable manufacturer in Germany. Philips became a world
pioneer in consumer electronicsfor example, in compact audio cassettes and
in video cassette recorders, where it introduced the world's first consumer VCR
(Video 2000) in 1972. In 1986, it adopted the Japanese VHS standards under
license for its VCRs, and withdrew its own system. However, by 1990 Philips
had only a small share of the European VCR market and a much smaller pro-
portion globally because of vigorous Asian competition. Together with the Jap-
anese firm, Sony, Philips established standards for optical laser compact disc
systems, but here, too, it was left behind by Japanese price competition. Sim-
ilar pressure on its other product lines led Philips to change its strategy from
in-house development to one of joint ventures with American, Japanese, and
other European firms. In 1984, only 20 percent of Philips' products were man-
ufactured by one of its own companies; many of the others were produced by
other companies and sold under the Philips label.
Philips spent over $1 billion a year on research and development, the third
largest such budget after IBM and AT&T (Tagliabue, 1984). It was Holland's
most important firm in the development of microprocessors and other semicon-
ductors, with its subsidiaries Valvo (Germany), Mullard (Britain), Complelec
(France), and Signetics (America) (Malerba, 1985). Philips also took over the
German firm Grundig, which, before faltering financially, had been Europe's
second-largest consumer electronics company. Together with Siemens, Philips
worked on developing advanced memory "megachip" components.
In telecommunications, Philips concentrated on cable transmission, tele-
174 The Netherlands
phone sets, PBX terminals, and smaller switches rather than on large central
office switches. Because it had little advanced digital technology, it entered
into a joint venture with AT&T in 1982. APT (AT&T-Philips Telecommuni-
cations) was carefully structured as a European venture; chartered in the Neth-
erlands, its subsidiaries are entirely European. The venture led Philips to stop
developing its own PRXD digital switch and adopt the AT&T 5ESS-PRX switch.
APT competed unsuccessfully in Britain and Italy; it received a Dutch con-
tract, some Saudi Arabian business, and a larger Indonesian award, and com-
bined with Alcatel to modernize the Venezuelan telephone system.
The joint venture was not as successful as originally hoped. Furthermore,
Philips was under financial pressure. In 1989, AT&T increased its share from
60 percent to 85 percent in the joint venture. Later that year, Italy's Itatel and
AT&T formed a joint venture (the former took a 20 percent stake in the proj-
ect). In 1990, AT&T purchased Philips' remaining 15 percent share and sold 6
percent to Spain's Telefonica (Wilde, 1990).
In 1990, Philips took a huge $1.4 billion charge against earnings and elimi-
nated 10,000 jobs from its workforce of almost 300,000 worldwide, mostly
because of its faltering computer and electronics divisions.
An early attempt at policy discussion took place in the early 1960s, when the
so-called Goedhart Committee studied the possibility of PTT autonomy in in-
vestments and borrowing. But the committee's 1963 recommendation for greater
flexibility was never acted upon (Wieland, 1986).
In 1981, widespread dissatisfaction among users and equipment suppliers led
the government to appoint a new commission, chaired by Frans Swarttouw,
chairman of the Fokker aircraft manufacturing firm, to investigate the present
and future of the PTT and to recommend necessary reforms. In 1982, this
commission proposed to grant the PTT more autonomy in order to enter finan-
cial markets independently and to set rates and services with greater flexibility.
At the same time, it recommended that private competitors be permitted to
enter the terminal equipment market, while leaving intact the PTT's monopoly
for traditional services. The commission advised that the PTT be transformed
into a limited-liability company owned by the government, rather than remain
a part of the Ministry of Transport and Public Works. It further urged that the
new "enhanced" serviceslinking computers and communications to poten-
tially include videotex, video conferencing, and electronic mailshould be opened
to private service providers using the PTT network. Telecommunications op-
erations would be separate from postal operations, and PTT financial activities
would be placed into a separate "postbank."
Shortly after the report's release, the previous center-right government was
displaced by a left-of-center coalition. This enabled Philips (the major equip-
ment supplier) and the trade unions to block the recommended changes. In
1985, however, the Christian Democrats and Liberals regained power and de-
The Netherlands 175
corporation, it was not as dependent on the PTT's status quo as some manufac-
turers in other European countries.
The government cabinet approved the Steenbergen proposal in 1985 and es-
tablished a phase-in period lasting until January 1, 1989. The proposal was
approved by the Dutch parliament in 1986 and included further provisions to
privatize much of PTT Telecom by selling its shares to the public by the mid-
1990s. A new department of telecommunications was created in the Ministry
of Transport and Public Works. The ministry oversees operator licenses, equip-
ment type approvals, and public service requirements.
Following the 1989 restructuring, PTT Telecom Nederland had exclusive
responsibilities for basic service, transmission, telex and telegraph service and
data transport services. Valued-added services and customer premises equip-
ment were liberalized.3 But these changes still left many large users, VANs,
and equipment suppliers dissatisfied. PTT Telecom faced complaints from users
over this role as equipment supplier and service provider. It did not allow
interconnection with the public network. Value-added services may be provided
only on the condition that the public infrastucture is used.
The $800 million equipment market was liberalized in 1989 but exclusive
distribution contracts between the PTT and Ericsson and Philips limited com-
petition and raised prices. The PTT still supplied a majority of basic phone
sets. However, a significant portion of the PTT's PBX market now belongs to
Ericsson and Philips. A Philips PBX costs 25 percent to 33 percent more in the
Netherlands than in the United States or West Germany. Responsibility for
testing was given to two independent institutes, KEMA and NTK.
A blue-ribbon panel, the Zegveld Commission, was appointed to investigate
the newly organized PTT's possible relationships with the municipal, indepen-
dent, and private cable networks. In 1986, it advised the gradual integration,
over a period of twenty years, of the cable network with the PTT-owned infra-
structure.
11
Belgium
With the erosion of its traditional economic base of heavy industry, Belgium's
economic priority is to become Europe's administrative center. Brussels already
serves as the headquarters for both the European Community and NATO. The
country also seeks to draw nongovernmental organizations; its capital city is
home to the European headquarters of many overseas companies and associa-
tions. Telecommunications links should therefore be an especially important
factor in the country's economic development. However, Belgium's traditional
monopolist Regie des Telegraphes et des Telephones (RTT), financially con-
strained in its goal to be at the forefront of service provision and development,
has been one of Europe's strongest defenders of traditionalism. In this position
it was supported by its major equipment supplier, Alcatel's BTM, and by the
labor unions. As a consequence, Belgium has not become a center of European
telecommunications, a role that would be otherwise natural. Partly in order to
achieve that goal, a 1991 reform reorganized RTT into the semi-independent
Belgacom.
The telephone was first demonstrated in Belgium in 1876. When the govern-
ment showed no interest in the new invention, a private telephone company
was formed in 1879. Other companies soon followed and intense competition
developed in several cities. Encouraged by national and local governments, the
private firms merged in 1881 into the Compagnie Beige des Telephones Bell.
In 1883, telephone service was made subject to concessions granted in the
context of the public telegraph monopoly. Concessions were granted for twenty-
five years, at the end of which the physical plant was to be turned over to the
government at no cost to the state; the government also had the option of choosing
to purchase the plant after ten years. Concessionaires had to compensate the
government at the rate of 5 francs per telephone station.
In 1884, the government began construction of interexchange long distance
lines. Two years later, it started to provide local exchange service to small and
medium-sized cities that were left out by the private concessionaires and it
stopped issuing new licenses. When the ten-year option periods began to run
178
Belgium 179
out, the government took over the private Bell telephone systems. By 1896, no
private telephone exchanges remained.
The first central battery network in Europe was opened in Brussels in 1902,
with 4800 subscribers. Much of the telephone plant was destroyed during World
War I, and it took until the end of 1920 to reestablish regular service. In 1922,
the first automatic central office was inaugurated. The establishment of tele-
phony and its improvement were hampered, however, by the weak financial
situation of the government. A submarine cable to England was laid in 1926
and established Belgium as an important transit point for international traffic.
A 1930 parliamentary act removed the telephone monopoly from direct state
control and placed it under the authority of the newly created RTT, an inde-
pendent state agency that has since been the nation's sole provider of telecom-
munications services. The act provided parliamentary controls, and RTT was
subject to the Ministry of PTT. It gave RTT some accounting flexibility, which
a pure state service would not have been granted. In an effort to unify the
status of the various semipublic organizations, however, parliament changed
the law in 1954, making RTT also report to the ministers of the budget, fi-
nance, and civil service, all of whom had some authority over aspects of RTT
operations. Subsequently, RTT lost even more autonomy. This was the reverse
of trends elsewhere, where PTT organization became more independent over
time. As a result, prior approval from one or several of the ministers in ques-
tion was needed before RTT could take action. Decision-making speed was
thus considerably reduced just when the opposite was needed in light of tech-
nological and business developments. These restrictions were supplemented by
additional ones, including controls on equipment procurement implemented in
1976.
During the early 1980s, RTT found itself in dire financial straits and had
difficulties meeting its debt burden. In 1985, its total outstanding debt was
about Bfr 180 billion ($3 billion), the service of which required nearly 30
percent of the agency's revenues. This situation created particular problems in
light of RTT's intention to enter in a significant way into digital switching.
The debt crisis created an impetus for rethinking the role of RTT, a process
that divided both the government and the PTT Ministry itself. In 1985, the
minister for communications, Herman de Croo, advocated a loosening of the
RTT monopoly. In contrast, RTT itself, the labor unions, and his parliamentary
state secretary, who was a member of another party, were opposed to such a
step, because they viewed these measures as steps toward privatization. Only a
limited liberalization of RTT activities took place; in 1985, the RTT was given
permission to invest in private telecommunications companies and to establish
"joint economy companies." Within RTT, there is a generational transition.
Older managers defended the monopoly, based on their notion of its social and
engineering function; younger managers tended to be more willing to experi-
ment with new structures.'
In 1986, the government established a commission of four university profes-
sors headed by F. DeBount to look into the question of RTT autonomy. This
commission of "four sages" delivered a very cautious report, staying within
180 Belgium
BTM (66 percent) and ATEA (33 percent) (Miiller, 1988). Technically, both
companies are controlled by firms in other EC countries. The procurement pro-
cess is also complicated by the traditional rivalry between Flanders and Wal-
lonia. During price negotiations, the firms asked for $514 per line, whereas the
RTT refused to offer more than $420 per line. The RTT then decided it would
place the extra $92 per line into a R&D budget independent of the individual
suppliers but benefiting them (Euro-Telecom News, 1987). In the United States,
digital exchange for 1987 delivery was priced between $180 and $213 per line,
according to the U.S. Justice Department (U.S. Department of Justice, 1987).
In 1987, RTT filed a complaint against GB-Inno, a supermarket chain that
was selling nonapproved second telephone equipment. GB replied with a coun-
terclaim against RTT's equipment approval methods. European court proceed-
ings revealed that RTT's charges for equipment testing were often inflated.
Further inquiries demonstrated that the RTT was more likely to approve Bel-
gian equipment: 45 percent of overseas terminals applications failed compared
with 11 percent of Belgian terminals 3 (Tutt, 1989).
In 1989, the government reluctantly agreed to follow EC liberalization poli-
cies; but the actual process fell behind other European countries because of the
government's fear for the impact on jobs. It similarly opposed the EC's policies
on tariff principles and Open Network Provision.
Services
In 1988, telephone set density was 49.8 per 100 population (RTT, 1987). There
were 3.7 million telephone main lines in 1990. Rates were sixth lowest for
business and eighth lowest for residential service among the twenty-four OECD
countries. Residential and business users faced up to a six-month wait for ser-
vice.
An important first occurred in 1956, when RTT inaugurated, together with
France, international direct-dial telephone service, the first such service in
Europe. The installation of semielectronic space division stored program-con-
trol switches began in the early 1970s. The first fully electronic digital ex-
change became operational in 1983. In 1989, digital exchanges comprised 20
percent of the total network.
Data transmission began to grow strongly in the early 1980s. The RTT had
a monopoly on low-speed modems. It was strict in preventing resale. Shared
use was authorized under certain conditions, provided that volume tariffs were
applied. RTT was particularly concerned with the leakage into the public switched
network of calls carried on international leased lines (Pichault, 1985). Alcatel
entered the data services market in 1990 through a joint venture with RTT to
operate private networks and VANs.
Telex is also well developed in Belgium, though declining. (ITU, 1990a).
Mailbox service and video conferencing were made available experimentally in
1986.
Belgium 183
In 1982, a packet-switched network was put into operation under the name
of Data Communication Service (DCS-NET), with transmission rates up to 48
kbps. In 1990, RTT agreed to lift restrictions on international leased lines,
including mandatory routing through DCS-NET, after a lawsuit by GE Infor-
mation Services charged RTT with violating the EC competition policy.
In 1984, RTT initiated prototype ISDN trials, using the BTM System 12 and
ATEA switches. Belgium became the fourth European country to launch an
ISDN service, under the name of Aline.
Mobile telephone service was first provided in 1977, with equipment provi-
sion under the monopoly of the RTT and produced by BTM. A cellular system
went into operation in 1987 and is integrated within a Benelux system. In 1989,
RTT chose Siemens and Philips as the suppliers of a new digital mobile net-
work.
Videotex was launched by the RTT in 1986. Databases are mainly supplied
by private parties. One important and delicate task in language-divided Bel-
gium is how to allow connection to the surrounding countries that follow dif-
ferent protocols. Therefore, the system follows the British Prestel standard used
in the Netherlands, but it also allows the French Antiope standard, with access
to host computers in France. Connection to the German Btx was also provided.
In 1990, the RTT began testing the service over cable networks, since over
half a million Belgian television sets had teletext decoders suitable for some
videotex service.
12
Luxembourg
Luxembourg's tiny size and population seem to provide little incentive for new
entrants. The country is active in international financial services, incorpora-
tions, television, satellites, and even shipping registration. Telecommunications
is an important input for each of them. The PTT, under the supervision of the
minister for transport, communications, and information, held the national ser-
vice monopoly. It followed a policy of providing services compatible with those
of neighboring countries. In contrast to Luxembourg's minor role in telecom-
munications, its position in mass media transmission was far more significant.
Here both the television company CLT and the broadcast satellite provider SES
were at the forefront of Europe-wide change.
Between 1862 and 1880, the Luxembourg government installed a telegraph
network connecting Luxembourg with its neighbors to promote the country's
economic expansion. Telephone service was introduced in 1881, initially only
for verbal transmission of telegraph messages. In 1883, the administrations for
posts and for telegraphs were united to become the Administration for Posts
and Telecommunications (APT), and the Ministry of Finances proposed the
first telephone legislation. Under the provisions of the law of 1884, which is
still in effect, the government was authorized to construct or operate the tele-
phone network for its own use or to concede construction or operation to a
private firm. The government decided to undertake the project and built a net-
work in the capital city, which was eventually expanded (Bode, 1985). This
network opened in 1885.
To deal with low rural penetration, public phone booths, called auxiliary
telephone agencies, were installed, managed by private individuals but financed
by the state. Communities without such service could connect a line to the
general network for an annual fee and the cost of line construction.
User tariffs were flat-rate (unlimited communications) until 1920, when a
volume-based tariff replaced it. But this led volume to fall by 66 percent in the
first year of its implementation.
Luxembourg's geographical position fostered the early development of an
international network, with connections to Belgium in 1898 and to France,
Germany, and Switzerland by 1904. During World War I, Germany controlled
the network and suspended civilian communication until the 1918 armistice.
Following the war, Luxembourg made an effort at modernization. In 1922
184
Luxembourg 185
The Swiss PTT is one of Europe's last "classic" PTTs: It is an exclusive and
monopolistic government administration where telecommunications subsidize
the postal service with which they are fully integrated. In its equipment inter-
connection policy and procurement practices, the Swiss PTT is among the more
rigid in Europe. At the same time, the quality of its servicein terms of both
equipment and manpoweris good, and the density of its coverage is among
the highest in the world. Thus, the traditional arrangement has worked reason-
ably well when the priority was to spread service to every household and when
technology and large-user demands were relatively stable.
Switzerland is a traditional center for financial and other international ser-
vices. However, rural interests are also very strong. In telecommunications
policy, they are allied with the labor movement and the advanced but high-cost
electronics sector, which in turn has close ties with the banking industry that
owns much of it. Nevertheless, it seems inevitable that Switzerland will have
to reconcile telecommunications with its traditional economic function as an
international cross-roads. The increasingly electronic form of financial transac-
tions and their resultant distance-insensitivity puts Swiss banks into direct com-
petition with such centers as London, New York, Singapore, Tokyo, and Hong
Kong. It is therefore likely that the country will move toward a more liberal
system that has characterized the rest of its economy, while finding new ways
of safeguarding its traditional concerns.
History
Historically, the postal service has been one of the relatively few central gov-
ernmental functions of the Swiss Confederacy. With the advent of the telegraph
in 1851, telegraph service was similarly put under national control of the Tele-
graph Directorate. The Swiss telegraph network began operation in 1852 and
international telegram service was started in the following year (Swiss PTT,
1983). When the telephone was introduced, the Swiss Federal Council passed
restrictive licensing regulations, distinguishing between telephone traffic in areas
where telegraph service existed and areas where it did not. Where the govern-
ment telegraph monopoly was affected, a license fee had to be paid that amounted
186
Switzerland 187
to at least two to three times the costs that had already been spent on telegraph
service in the area. Protection of the state monopoly was a major policy goal
from the beginning of the development of Swiss telecommunications. An early
telephone pioneer, Wilhelm Ehrenberg, challenged these restrictions, but his
proposal was rejected. The Telegraph Directorate was slow in providing service
itself, however. After a series of discussions, a license was extended to a com-
pany led by J. Ryf, a member of parliament, and T. F. Wild, a partner in a
major publishing and printing firm. As it later transpired, Wild also represented
the International Bell Telephone Company.
In 1880, the private Zurich Telephone Company was granted a license. Ser-
vice began almost immediately. In the first telephone directory, more than 10
percent of the subscribers were affiliated with Wild's publishing firm (Hof-
rnann, 1980). The status of the new company, however, soon became uncer-
tain. Following a series of disputes, the International Bell Telephone Company
withdrew, leaving the Zurich Telephone Company as a purely Swiss enterprise.
But this did not help to alleviate the political problems concerning the scope of
the Zurich company's license. The term of its franchise was reduced from twenty-
five years to five years. Recognizing the profitability of telephone service, the
Swiss government then decided to cease granting further private licenses and
instead to establish a state-operated service wherever feasible. In December
1880, this decision was ratified by the parliament, which wrote into law the
telephone monopoly of the federal government.
The telegraph administration opened its first urban telephone system in Basel
in 1881 and then in Berne at the bankers' association initiative. In 1883, the
first local networks were interconnected. In 1884, the operating license of the
private Zurich Telephone Company expired and was taken over by the govern-
mental system, with compensation paid. Today the Swiss PTT is more gracious
than other PTTs in acknowledging the role of early private operations. Its of-
ficial publication notes that "with hindsight, one must concede that the Zurich
Telephone Company performed a valuable service in acting as a driving force
and saving the Federal Government from paying dearly for their experience"
(Kobelt, 1980). By 1892, nearly all local systems were interconnected. Trunks
were initially run on overhead lines along railroad tracks and were later buried.
Because of Switzerland's status as an international financial center, interna-
tional telephone communications were implemented almost immediately. Ex-
periments were undertaken as early as 1878 with a connection to the Milan
telegraph office using telegraph lines. Cross-border telephone service on a reg-
ular basis was started in 1886 from Basel to Alsace and then rapidly expanded
to other countries. The first transatlantic radio telephone service opened in 1928
via London. During World War II, direct shortwave service to the United States
was introduced. In 1956, the PTT offered transatlantic calls over submarine
telephone cables, and after 1965, via satellite.
Semiautomatic switching was begun in 1917, using equipment from the Bel-
gian Bell Telephone Manufacturing Company (BTM). BTM, then owned by
AT&T, set up the Swiss subsidiary Standard Telephone and Radio (STR) and
became a major supplier. As an ITT company, STR introduced the crossbar
188 Switzerland
switch into Switzerland in 1965. Much of the automation of the network was
done with Strowger switches in cooperation with Siemens through a Swiss sub-
sidiary that is now named Siemens-Albis. Automatic long-distance service be-
gan in 1950 and was completed by 1959. Automated international service was
introduced in 1964. Some international telecommunications services were also
provided by the government-owned Radio Suisse.
Services
Switzerland has one of the highest telephone densities in the world. In 1988,
density was fifty-four telephone lines and eighty-eight telephone units per 100
population. Like Sweden, Switzerland's neutrality during the world wars spared
it from the destruction and resource drain that other countries suffered (Ducom-
mun and Keller, 1980).
Expansion in international traffic was especially great. More international
calls are made per capita from Switzerland than from any other country, aver-
aging twenty-eight per person yearly. Calls to West Germany, France and Italy
account for over 60 percent of that total (ITU, 1989, p. 764; Staple, 1990, p.
35). With Germany, Switzerland has the highest telex service density in the
world, with 530 telex connections per 100,000 population in 1988. Switzer-
land's extensive telex service is partly due to its importance in the financial
sector.
Not surprisingly for the world's center of watch making, Switzerland's first
special service was the transmission of the time signal: In 1935, a "speaking
clock" was introduced. Also provided today are regularly updated weather
forecasts, reports on avalanches and on ski and road conditions; sports results
and betting information.
Additional services include car radio paging, introduced in 1958, and mobile
telephony, available regionally since 1952 and nationwide since 1980 under the
name of Natel. Cellular telephony was introduced in 1978, and digitally after
1991. In 1982 the public packet-switched network Telepac became available.
Other PTT services include teletex (electronic mail), telefax, as well as a pop-
ular call forwarding service, Omnitel. Leased lines are available, under restric-
tions, and the need for private networks must be demonstrated. According to
the PTT, customer requirements should generally be met through the public
network. In 1988, the PTT began a Communes Modeles Suisses pour la Com-
munication (CMC) program. This introduced advanced servicessuch as vi-
deoconferencing, remote database, access and distance learningto twelve mu-
nicipalities to assess their communications needs. Videotex operations began in
1983 as a field test, and in 1987 as a regular service, with a faster Supertex
version offered in 1989. Switzerland has been and remains among Europe's
leaders in cashless public telephony, with its prepaid "taxcards" (Purton, 1990).
The PTT has been in charge of radio transmissions for the official Swiss
Broadcasting Corporation (SBC) since 1931. It offered, almost from the begin-
ning of radio, transmission service over wire lines in areas of poor reception,
Switzerland 189
its service principles are to work for the benefit of the community, to provide
service for the entire country under the same conditions and economic princi-
ples, to provide unrestricted access, to protect privacy, and to be aware that
"not everything technically achievable and economically viable is necessarily
beneficial for society as a whole." In interpreting the specific applications of
these principles, the PTT has considerable discretion.
Following the takeover of the private Zurich Telephone Company in 1890,
the government had promulgated an installation monopoly for the telegraph
administration. This was changed in 1921, after pressures from the Association
of Swiss Electrical Installation Firms, when the government ceded interior in-
stallations to officially licensed private firms. Despite agitation in the 1930s,
only equipment supplied and maintained by the PTT could be used for all
telephone sets and telex machines. Approved data and fax terminals could be
privately supplied. PBXs were supplied by the PTT, and only PTT modems
were permitted for data transmission over the switched network.
Because the Swiss telecommunications law dates back to 1922, many new
telecommunications services have had to be governed by regulations and de-
crees. The Swiss political system makes it particularly difficult to modify the
telecommunications structure. Any legislation must be approved by the Swiss
upper chamber, in which the rural cantons, with their small populations, have
a disproportionate influence. They resist any modification that might lead to an
increase in telephone rates or postal service in rural areas.1 During the 1980s,
questions began to be raised about the scope of the PTT's monopoly. In 1980,
Zurich groups sought a referendum initiative to reduce PTT power, but they
did not succeed in getting enough signatures (Knieps, 1985a).
These signs of public dissatisfaction started a legislative reform process in
1981, when the PTT directorate general decided to draft provisions to revise
the old Telecommunications Law. In 1983, the council of the PTT approved
an early version of such a bill. However, other parts of the government and
various interest groups claimed that the draft was overly protective of the PTT
and demanded a draft legislation to be designed by a body independent from
the PTT. In 1984, the minister of transportation and energy appointed a study
commission for a new telecommunications law. The commission, however,
was chaired by the secretary general of the ministry itself. Other members
represented interest groups, such as PTT officials, the PTT union, the national
chamber of commerce, the consumer federation, the small business association,
the equipment industry, and large users. Independent members included Pro-
fessor Carl Christian von Weizsacker, an economist who had also been active
in German telecommunications commissions. In 1985, the commission submit-
ted to the department a preliminary report that was endorsed by the governing
PTT boards.
The study group's recommendations and the 1985 draft legislation were cau-
tious. Even in terminal equipment, some areas would be left entirely to the
PTT, with governmentally drawn lines based on vague criteria such as "interest
of the country" and "security of transmission." Main stations terminal equip-
ment and telex machines would remain under the control of the PTT. Further-
Switzerland 191
more, approval was left to the PIT and thus subject to its time schedule. The
proposal also prohibited resale of transmission capacity (Blankart and Knieps,
1985).
The partial liberalization of terminal equipment was largely a confirmation
of reality. PTT exclusivity for simple terminal equipment had been undercut by
the illegal attachment of widely available telephone sets, marked "for export
only." Article 28 of the draft law provided that terminal equipment can be
advertised, sold, leased, or rented only if it is technically approved, that the
PTT has the right to control all terminal equipment, and that the owner of a
terminal must provide physical access to it. In accordance with Article 3, the
cabinet would decide which types of terminal equipment would be exclusively
provided by the PTT.
The ministry describes such restrictive equipment rules as a "step-wise lib-
eralization," which is an overstatement unless the government exercises its
line-drawing powers in a liberalizing fashion. The government's report alleged
that a competitive system would put into question the ability of some customers
to reach others, and that it would create disparities within the country. It also
stated that a small country such as Switzerland could provide an efficient tele-
communications network only under a single organization, and according to
unified norms. Despite these assertions, interconnection and compatibility could
be legally mandated; even if additional or specialized Swiss networks were not
economically feasible, there could still be general or specialized Europe-wide
networks, which would have the economies of scale that Switzerland might be
unable to provide. It would be pure happenstance if the optimal size of the
network coincided with the size of Switzerland.
The PTT also argued that the Swiss telecommunications industry cannot
presently compete with foreign imports:
features, and performance, Swiss equipment could be sold more widely across
Europe, America, and the developing world.
In 1989, a parliamentary draft of the new law proposed that services be
divided into basic and extended categories, with the former, such as transmis-
sion and switching, remaining the sole province of the PTT. Extended services
"which complement, modify, store, or otherwise manipulate messages" would
be opened to private competition. This would include second telephone sets,
telefax, modems, PBXs, and teletype terminals. Regulatory and operational
functions of the PTT would be separated.
to the merging of the top two firms, Hasler and Autophon, in 1987 as part of
the Ascom holding company, which in turn owned 50 percent of Zellweger and
has a connection to the German firm Bosch. Ascom, through a holding com-
pany, became the dominant Swiss equipment firm, strengthening the position
of the purely Swiss companies versus Siemens-Albis and Alcatel's STR. An-
other cooperative venture is the Tritel telephone production agreement involv-
ing Gfeller, Autophon, and Zellweger (Union Bank, 1986).
After 1970, the PTT cooperated with Siemens-Albis, STR, and Hasler to
create the Integrated Telecommunications System, or ITS. The primary aim
was to develop a digital system to replace about 1000 analog switches. In 1983,
140 million Swiss francs later, the PTT decided instead to opt for a foreign-
developed system and was criticized that it had not established an effective
project management organization for such a large-scale project and that the
scope of the project had been underestimated (ASUT, 1983) .
The PTT decision did not, however, eliminate the three companies as poten-
tial suppliers of a digital switch. After the failure of the initial IPS concept, it
introduced in 1985 the concept of a new IFS-Swissnet, with foreign-developed
switches. Both Siemens-Albis and STR provided their parent companies' elec-
tronic switches, EWSD and System 12. Hasler, a Swiss company, offered the
AXE 10 switch of its traditional technology source L. M. Ericsson. However,
digitalization of switching was slow, with the first full digital exchanges being
put into operation in 1987 (Ducommun, 1987). The PTT predicted the connec-
tion of 90 percent of subscribers to SWISSNET by 1995 (Trachsel, 1987).
In the supply of customer equipment, the cumbersome system of approval
and adoption of PTT-owned equipment led to a substantal gray market. A con-
sumer movement magazine reported that the annual rental price for the PTT
telephone model TS85 with twenty-number storage was SFr 192, whereas a
corresponding foreign model could be purchased illegally in a store for only
SFr 125. Cordless telephones were officially introduced only in 1985, although
an active market in illegal equipment already existed.
When the official equipment was introduced, the monthly rental charges were
SFr 26 (then about $12). In the United States, these rates would pay for pur-
chasing the equipment in less than half a year. This also corresponds to a study
that found that the cost of some equipment available for purchase in the United
States was equal to its rental fee for three to four months in Switzerland (Blan-
kart and Schneider, 1984).
In 1983, the PTT still believed that the cordless equipment would cost SFr
1500-2000 (about $1000) per station. After much criticism, this was reduced
to a still high SFr 1000. At the same time, a letter to the editor of the major
newspaper Neue Ziircher Zeitung pointed out that they were available in the
United States for only $59. After a lengthy development process, the PTT in
1984 and 1985 issued a fifty-five page technical specifications manual that hap-
pened to match the system developed by the largest Swiss telecommunications
manufacturer. For example, the PTT required that each telephone have forty
duplex channels and an automatic frequency search scanner. Furthermore, the
timing of procurement for distribution was a few months hence, which was
194 Switzerland
almost impossible for foreign competitors to meet (letter to Neue Ziircher Zeit-
ung, January 6, 1984). The PTT's response (Neue Ziircher Zeitung, January
20, 1984) was that the cheaper equipment was probably an inferior Far Eastern
product and that it permitted others to eavesdrop or to illegally use someone
else's main stations.
Switzerland was not under a liberalization pressure from Brussels like most
of its neighbors since it was not a member of the EC. But in time, it could not
remain apart from the broader trends, with EFT A moving close to the EC. In
1990, even the PTT's telecommunications head admitted that
Switzerland has too long under-estimated the significance of developments outside
its borders. Given the worldwide expansion of markets and the European Com-
munity's internal market, our insular solutions could no longer be tolerated, espe-
cially for telecommunications. If our country is to profit from the economic liber-
alization and deregulation of Europe and remain competitive, liberalization is un-
avoidable (Wuhrmann, 1990).
Telecommunications in Liechtenstein
Although the principality of Liechtenstein is independent, its telephone service
is largely handled by the Swiss PTT. Telephone service in Liechtenstein dates
back to the turn of the century, when it was operated by the Austrian govern-
ment telegraph administration and was linked to the Austrian system. With the
outbreak of World War I, Liechtenstein telephone service was totally isolated
from the rest of the world for a year, until it was connected to Switzerland.
Since 1921, the Swiss PTT has operated Liechtenstein telephony as part of
Swiss domestic service.
14
Austria
History
195
196 Austria
Services
In response to criticism throughout the 1960s that the PTV's restricted budget
and bureaucratic organization prevented modernization, the government granted
it a five-year investment plan. As a result, the organization could expand the
reach of the network.
Between 1970 and 1988, telephone density almost tripled from 13.1 to 39.5
per 100 population. At the end of 1989, there were 3.1 million main telephone
stations and about 21,500 telex connections in a population of about 7.6 mil-
lion. Telex density was a very high 0.34 percent of the population, but telex
traffic dropped 25 percent from 1988 to 1989 alone. It should be noted that
there is a marked difference between the number of main line installations and
actual telephone sets (3 million lines to 4.1 million sets in 1988) due to the
frequency of party lines. After 1970 there were periods when the waiting list
contained more than 200,000 applicants for telephone service and when delays
were over two months. But by 1989, the number of applicants on the waiting
list had greatly decreased to 35,000 (ITU, 1990).
Tariffs are high. Calls placed from Austria to other European countries tend
to cost twice as much as calls traveling in the opposite direction (TDR, 1988,
p. 9). Although the PTV claims to be adapting tariffs to real costs, Austria's
rates for business ($1408 per year) and residential ($529 per year) users are
among Europe's highest (Montgomery et al., 1990).
The Austrian telephone network is technically complicated, because it em-
ploys two sets of technologies, one of which uses nonlinear hybrid circuits at
the junction of two- and four-wire circuits, and thus suffers from performance
problems in data transmission. ITT electromechanical (HK8) and semielec-
tronic (11E) exchanges were installed in the south, west, and northeast of the
country. Elsewhere, Siemens ESK-A3, A5 and F semielectronic switches were
primarily used.
In 1978, the PTV decided in favor of digitalization. A concept was devel-
oped by the consortium organization OFEG, which brought together the Re-
public of Austria (51 percent), represented by the PTV and the Social Partners,
and the telecommunications manufacturers Siemens, ITT (now Alcatel), Kapsch,
and Schrack, which are collectively known as the Four Sisters. Not surpris-
ingly, the consortium decided to "carefully adapt" a foreign system to Aus-
trian specifications under control of the Four Sisters and the PTV, thereby
foreclosing the market to others.
Two supplier groups were chosen. The first group was comprised of the two
domestic Austrian firms Kapsch and Schrack, and offered a version of the Ca-
nadian Northern Telecom DMS-100 switch as the OES-E system. The second
group, Siemens and ITT, offered a Siemens EWSD system. There was some
competition between the two groups whereby the lower bidder receives an extra
10 percent of orders while the higher bidder adjusts its prices to the lower bid.
In 1986, digital operation commenced in Vienna. By 1990, there were more
than 500,000 digital subscriber lines linked to seventy switching centers. PTV
198 Austria
planned to increase that number to 2.3 million, or about two-thirds of all phones,
by 1995 (Sindelka, 1990, p. 50; CWI, 1990, p. 4). Since 1989, the PTV in-
vested in its broadband fiber trunk network ("6-Netz") (Purton, 1990, p. 13).
ISDN trials began in 1991.
In 1982, two new data servicescircuit-switched, Datex-L and packet-switched
Datex-Pwere introduced. Together with the existing telex network, they form
the integrated telex and data network (IFSD). In 1988, Datex-L had about 4000
subscribers and Datex-P had 2500. All Datex services had 10,300 total sub-
scribers in 1989.
Videotex, known in Austria as Btx, was introduced to the public in 1985.
Btx telephone rates are the same as those of local calls, even though the trans-
mission distance may be considerably greater. However, indicative of user ap-
athy, there were only 9717 registered subscribers in 1989.2 The Austrian Btx
terminal MUPID failed to gain acceptance after nine years of state support.
The market for videotex terminals was subsequently liberalized in 1989 (M.
Latzer, 1990, communication).
Cellular mobile telephony (Network C) was introduced in 1984 with Moto-
rola equipment, joined shortly thereafter by Ericsson (with Schrack) and Sie-
mens (with Kapsch). In 1990, the PTV awarded a contract for digital mobile
radio to Motorola, in cooperation with Austrian firms.
Private leased lines are available. Resale of lines is not permitted, but be-
cause of the difficulty of enforcement it exists informally. Since the introduc-
tion of its data networks, the PTV has discouraged, through rate setting, the
use of leased private circuits, and even aimed for regulatory measures to con-
vert all private leased circuits into circuits that can be used by public data
networks (Bruckner, 1982).
Because the Austrian telecommunications law has not been updated, the le-
gal status of value-added services by alternative providers is a complex matter.
The law does not differentiate between equipment and service. Approval by the
PTV is required for both the technical specifications of the connected equip-
ment and the corresponding software of value-added network services. The
extent of scrutiny varies between the various regions and depends partly on the
use of public networks versus leased lines and the applicability of public versus
private laws and contractual arrangements (J. Bauer, 1987, communication).
Equipment
may appear. In 1987, the PTV alone maintained all telex terminals and it had
certified only four telex models. The Four SistersSiemens, Alcatel 3 , and the
domestic firms of Kapsch and Schracksupply from 90 percent to 95 percent
of telecommunications equipment to the PTV (Bauer and Latzer, 1988;
CWI, 1990). They employ 20,000 people, with 11,000 in their telecommuni-
cations divisions. A comment in a PTV report reveals its attitude to foreign
equipment: "Since only a small share of the computer market is held by Aus-
trian equipment manufacturers, no restrictions are imposed on foreign [com-
puter] equipment" (Bruckner, 1982, p. 12). 4
This page intentionally left blank
Telecommunications in Scandinavia
and the North Atlantic
This page intentionally left blank
15
Sweden
History
From 1853, Swedish telegraph service was mainly run by the government, but
no legal state monopoly on telecommunications existed when the telephone was
introduced (Holcombe, 1911). Initially, the government refrained from involve-
ment in telephone service, but by the 1890s its role had changed dramatically.
The first telephone connections were established in Stockholm in 1877. One
of the earliest users, H. T. Cedergren, later founded the General Telephone
Company (Gustafsson, 1987). In 1880, the International Bell Telephone Com-
pany opened local systems in Stockholm, Gothenburg, and Malmo. Almost
immediately, several domestic firms were attracted to this market by Bell's
high prices. Although Bell would not sell equipment to its competitors, L. M.
Ericsson entered the field in 1878 and proved a viable alternative in the absence
of telephone patents. The first non-Bell network, established in 1881, charged
lower rates than Bell. In 1883, Cedergren started the General Telephone Com-
pany, Allmanna Telefonaktiebolag, and within one year served three times as
many subscribers as Bell. The two firms engaged in a lively head-on competi-
tion in price and service, particularly in Stockholm. In 1887, General Tele-
phone opened the world's largest exchanges (7000 lines). By 1888, Bell suc-
cumbed and relinquished control to its Swedish competitor, which merged the
two systems.
Still, the demise of Bell did not signal the end of competition, although
Sweden's second phase of competition was less dramatic than its first. Small
stock companies, mutual associations, cooperative societies, and municipal sys-
203
204 Sweden
tems rapidly established themselves in rural areas and began to coexist through
long-distance trunk lines. The government Telegraph Company (Telegrafver-
ket) also began to construct long-distance lines, and in some instances acquired
or built local networks. In 1881, it started a local network interconnecting gov-
ernment offices. In 1883, a Royal Ordinance required the state's permission for
interconnection, and it has survived to the present day.
In 1889, General Telephone applied for rights-of-way to establish trunk lines
to connect its three municipal systems. Thus prompted to review its role in
long-distance telephony, the government decided to be the main builder of in-
terurban lines. Significantly, long-distance telephone service would only be readily
available to subscribers of state local exchanges. In 1891, General Telephone
reached an agreement with the state. It was licensed to operate and use other
rights-of-way for fifty years and allowed it access to the state's long-distance
lines. Outside a 70-kilometer radius from Stockholm, the telegraph authority
imposed access fees and technical requirements on private systems that were
so burdensome that many sold out to the government. Within three years, the
government had taken control of three-fourths of all the local systems.
General Telephone, however, did not give in. The government thereupon
expanded its small system in Stockholm, which had previously operated for
official administrative use only, into a general public network. In 1905, an act
on wireless telegraphy strengthened the state's centralized authority in granting
transmission rights (Heimburger, 1931), and by 1907, it renounced its willing-
ness to interconnect. At that time, General Telephone had 37,000 subscribers
in Stockholm, and the government had 13,000, but in the competition between
the two that ensued, the government, with its resources and long-distance in-
terconnection, held the upper hand.
Within Stockholm the vigorous rivalry led to reduced rates, high technical
performance, and experimentation by the government with new types of service
and billing (including usage-measured tariffs), making Stockholm's telephone
system the most advanced in the world. Whereas the original flat rate of the
Bell company had been about $40 in the inner city of Stockholm and $60-70
elsewhere, after a few years of this unique competition, rates fell to about $12
for residential customers and $15 for businessesthe lowest in Sweden (Hoi-
combe, 1911).
The government, with its superior resources and power, ultimately took con-
trol of General Telephone in 1918, and integrated it by 1923. General Tele-
phone's management moved to L. M. Ericsson, which became General
Telephone Company-L. M. Ericsson. The Swedish telecommunications ad-
ministration, subsequently named Televerket, thus assumed its role as sole ac-
tor in Swedish public telecommunications. The exceptions to its monopoly are
several other state administrations that can provide for their own communica-
tionsthe state railway company, the state power board, and the Swedish de-
fense forces, to name a few. The only real private encroachment to the monop-
oly since General Telephone has recently emerged. Technically, however,
Televerket never held a legal monopoly. To satisfy the distinction, in the fol-
lowing the word monopoly should be read as de facto monopoly.
Sweden 205
Televerket
Telecommunications in Sweden became more vertically integrated than almost
anywhere else in the world after the United States broke up much of AT&T's
integrated structure. Televerket (often referred to internationally as Swedish
Telecom) had a de facto service monopoly over local, long-distance, and inter-
national communications; in 1988, however, Comvik AB received permission
to begin an international satellite communication network. Televerket has also
long held a connection monopoly over much of the customer equipment in
voice telephony and telex, though that was stepwisely relaxed. In 1989, ter-
minal markets were fully liberalized for PBXs and high-speed modems (Thorn-
gren, 1990). Televerket still produces much equipment itself. Not even AT&T
in its heyday had the same end-to-end control over production, services, and
equipment connections; AT&T had no monopoly on international service, was
excluded from telegraphy, coexisted with about 2000 other local telephone
companies, and had to share its equipment patents with others.
Part of Televerket's reason for success has been that it has been long outside
the postal administration. It is a public service corporation and reports to the
Ministry of Transport and Communications. But whereas Televerket has over
40,000 employees, of whom about 30,000 serve basic telephony, the entire
ministry has seventy employees, of whom only six deal with telecommunica-
tions issues (Televerket, 1989, p. 7). In 1989, Sweden's pool of telecommu-
nications policy expertise was severly depleted by the deaths of the finance
director of Televerket and several members of the Ministry of Communication
in a plane crash.
Since 1975, Televerket has been organized into twenty local areas, each
operating with substantial independence. Televerket's board, appointed by the
government, represents the political parties, the business and scientific com-
munities, and several of Sweden's labor unions. A director general manages
day-to-day operations. In the past, the annual budget was proposed by the gov-
ernment and passed through the budgetary process of the parliament. Profits
had to be returned to the Treasury. Since 1980, the budget became independent
from the public sector budget, and profits are now returned to the Treasury
only at a predetermined rate-of-return on the capital that the government sup-
plies to Televerket. Televerket has also been allowed to borrow on the open
market and is thus unencumbered from general state budget difficulties, nor
does it need to subsidize other governmental functions, such as the postal ser-
vice. Since 1984, Televerket's supervision has followed three-year programs,
which it submits to the government for parliamentary approval. This plan in-
cludes an investment and finance schedule, production goals, and a rate-of-
return proposal. Once this plan is approved, Televerket is substantially free to
operate within its parameters. In 1989, Televerket proposed the expansion of
the existing de facto price cap system (Krzywicki, 1990), and in 1990, it sought
to be privatized.
Sweden's telephone penetration is high. Like Switzerland, Sweden was lucky
206 Sweden
to escape the drain and destruction of two world wars, and it experienced the
Great Depression in a relatively mild form only. Between 1930 and 1940, the
number of telephones increased by 70 percent (H. Bergendorff, 1987, com-
munication). The country enjoys high standards of public services and signifi-
cant income equality. In 1988, telephone density was 66.2 main lines per 100
inhabitants (ITU, 1990). (For a discussion of Televerket's data, see Chapter
32.)
Vertical Integration
The Televerket monopoly, for a time, extended beyond services to all customer
hand sets; after the 1970s it was liberalized for secondary sets, telex, and low-
speed modems. It maintained PBXs and high-speed modems until 1989.' Vid-
eotex terminals and cellular telephone equipment were never restricted (Brown,
1985).
With respect to equipment provision, Sweden is therefore similar to the more
liberal parts of Europe. The difference to most other countries is that Televerket
is also involved in equipment manufacturing and R&D in two major ways: first,
through its wholly owned manufacturing arm, TELI, which dates back to 1891;
second, through its partnership with L. M. Ericsson in the development firm
ELLEMTEL,
TELI has 3500 employees and produces much of Televerket's domestic
equipment. Ninety percent of TELI production is destined for Televerket. Tel-
everket also buys some equipment from Ericsson, but Ericsson relies primarily
on export markets for its revenues. TELI produces digital AXE switches, PBXs
(including Northern Telecom-licensed products), hand sets, and a variety of
other transmission and data-processing equipment, as well as a limited number
of electromechanical switches. It has also been involved in the production of
low-cost computers used especially for school instructional purposes.
Ericsson and TELI established ELLEMTEL in 1970 after earlier disappoint-
ing experiences for each in the development of electronic SPC switches. They
developed independently the prototypes (ATE 12 in 1968 and A210 in 1970,
respectively). However, both Ericsson's chairman Wallenberg and TELI feared
the large costs of such endeavors and decided to pool expertise and costs. As
part of this decision, the two partners divided the market for ELLEMTEL prod-
ucts, especially its AXE digital switch, with TELI getting its traditional Swed-
ish (i.e., Televerket) market and Ericsson getting the rest of the world. Losses
are shared by Televerket (27 percent) and Ericsson (73 percent) according to
expected sales (OECD, 1987). In 1990, Televerket purchased Ericsson's do-
mestic telecommunications sales interests.
Televerket claims that vertical integration into manufacturing enabled it to
purchase equipment at favorable prices and pass these savings on to its custom-
ers. It also sought to avoid being captive of one national equipment firm. Be-
fore liberalization, however, subscriber terminal hand sets were available in
competitive markets at one quarter of the Televerket price (Brown, 1985). Lib-
Sweden 207
unions. The three unions (for blue-collar, white-collar and college-trained staff)
are involved in all major decisions and must be consulted on matters affecting
workers. Most Swedish firms operate similarly. The unions have opposed
equipment liberalization, relaxation of monopoly, and the transformation of
TELI into a corporation.
Ericsson
first used outside the Bell System by special common carriers and indepen-
dents. Customers included MCI, Western Union, ITT, and US Sprint. The
opening of the Bell market through the AT&T divestiture increased Ericsson's
potential customers dramatically. But in 1979, the U.S. markets comprised
still a minor share of Ericsson's business, representing 5 percent of sales,
mostly in traditional technology. By boosting its AXE system with a new cen-
tral processor and increasing its capacity, Ericsson made it a viable choice for
American local exchanges. Although its critics complain that it is based on a
central rather than on a distributed processor, the AXE system's modular ar-
chitecture, for which it is noted, has advantages over more customized designs.
Ericsson's hopes of penetrating the Bell companies' central office market, how-
ever, were slow to materialize.
In the United Kingdom, Ericsson's AXE switch successfully won acceptance
in the public switching market, the first such entry by a foreign firm in decades.
This was accomplished when British Telecom, in order to be less dependent on
the delay-plagued System-X switch developed by Plessey and GEC, sought a
second supplier, dubbed System Y. It picked Ericsson's venture with Thorn
EMI, greatly disappointing the French, in particular, who argued that the choice
of a non-EC firm was a step in the wrong direction.
Ericsson operates in Italy through its subsidiary Fabbrica Apparechiature
Telefoniche Materiale Elettrico (FATME) and several smaller operations which
together comprise 19 percent of the Italian market, employ about 5000 persons,
and have received export orders for AXE exchanges from Cyprus, Swaziland,
Ethiopia, Guatemala, and Mozambique, among others.
In Latin America, Ericsson holds a strong position, particularly in Mexico,
Brazil, Venezuela, and Colombia. Ericsson is also strong in Australia, the
Netherlands, Denmark, and Spain, where its subsidiary Spain Intelsa has al-
most 50 percent of the digital public exchange market. In 1990, more than
2000 digital exchanges, including cellular exchanges, were in service in some
seventy-five countries, with 27 million lines installed or on order. In 1987, it
received a $46 million contract from the People's Republic of China for AXE-
10 digital switches, and thirty-six were installed by 1990. Similarly successful
was Ericsson's mobile cellular telephone technology, which was selected by
numerous countries.
By 1992, Ericsson found itself under financial pressures and a potential merger
partner.
Services
Formally, Televerket does not have a legal monopoly over network services.
De facto, however, it was the only supplier of public or private network ser-
vices, with the minor exception of networks of a few governmental departments
too powerful to overcome.
To make competition fair, the government resolved in 1986 to permit a move
210 Sweden
The Finnish telephone system is one of the most interesting in Europe. Instead
of a national monopoly, there are about fifty companies, either subscriber co-
operatives, municipal enterprises, or private firms, that provide local telephone
service and are directly accountable to subscribers. There is also a national PTT
(the P&T), which is the largest operator of local telephone service (covering
about one-third of all subscribers and three-quarters of the land area). The P&T
also offers domestic and international long-distance service, mobile telephony,
and other services.
Thus, the Finnish telecommunications system has forgone the economies of
scale and the unity of control that are sanctified elsewhere. Yet its telephone
system is among the most advanced in the world, moved along by a healthy
rivalry among the various participants, and especially by the responsiveness of
local companies to their subscribers/shareholders. The number of equipment
options is high. Despite the country's small domestic market, Finland's elec-
tronics and telecommunications industries are quite successful both in domestic
and export markets.
History
The Finnish state postal system dates back to 1638, when Queen Christina of
Sweden issued an edict that led to the establishment of five post offices. This
system first operated as part of the Swedish and later as part of the Russian
post. In 1812, the system became semiautonomous, and it received a monopoly
status in 1874. Savings bank services were added in 1886, which led to a rapid
increase in the number of offices. After national independence, a postal admin-
istration was set up in 1918 and was combined in 1927 with the Telegraph
administration into the P&T (Finland PTT, 1983).
The first telephone sets arrived in Finland as early as 1877. Within five
years, a number of local telephone companies began operation, the first started
by a Helsinki telegraph mechanic, Daniel Johannes Waden. Since Finland was
still a Russian province, it was subject to the Russian telegraph bureaucracy.
By forming local cooperatives, the Finns became less dependent on the Russian
authorities. After 1917, the new Finnish government inherited the imperial Russian
212
Finland 213
role in telegraphy and some long distance service, but independent local tele-
phony was already in place in the cities.
In 1894, the Interurban Telephone Company of Southern Finland was started.
The P&T, which gradually established telephone service in the northern part of
the country, acquired this company in 1935. Since then, the P&T has operated
long-distance service as a monopoly. Service with Russia began in 1909, ex-
tending to Sweden by 1919. Automatic telephone exchange was first introduced
in Helsinki in 1922 (AT&T, 1975).
The P&T acquired a private long-distance company, and expanded it until it
included all long-distance and international service, plus the new offering of
telex. It also provided local service in those areas where local organizations did
not exist (Bruce et al., 1986).
The basic laws of Finnish telecommunications were set by the Czarist Tele-
phone Manifest of 1886, the Telegraphy Law of 1919, and the Radio Law of
1927. Efforts were made to update the laws, but for a long time there was no
political consensus to accomplish more than minor changes (OECD, 1982, p.
10). Eventually, a new telecommunications law was passed and became effec-
tive in 1987. It provided a legislative framework to promote development of
the telecommunications industry. The traditional operational division of respon-
sibilities between the telecommunications bodies remained the same, but the
Ministry of Transport and Communications assumed the supervisory functions
previously under the jurisdiction of the P&T.
The local companies are either private firms or cooperatives owned by their
subscribers or municipal companies. In the 1930s, over 800 private telephone
companies operated (Williamson, 1986, p. 52). The smallest company supplies
approximately 1900 connections; the largest, the Helsinki Telephone Company,
supplies almost 650,000. By their charters, the cooperatives' pricing is sup-
posed to be cost-based and not for profit. Subscribers elect management and
directors, either at a general meeting or by mail. This process is taken seri-
ously. At the board election of the Helsinki Telephone Company, 50 percent
of the 350,000 owners participated in the mail balloting. Subscribers, when
joining the system, provide a payment and receive a negotiable share certifi-
cate. Nearly three-quarters of subscribers are shareholders. No single share-
holder can have more than twenty votes, however, and each shareholder must
pay an annual telephone subscription, whether a telephone is used or not, which
discourages the holding of multiple shares and of speculation. This system af-
fords about 1 million telephone subscribers a direct role in telecommunications
matters (Myllo, 1984). A wide variety of organizational structures exists among
the companies, including in several cases outright municipal ownership. Merg-
ers have reduced the numbers of companies to fifty-one. In matters of service
quality and tariffs, the independent telephone companies are bound by general
conditions of their concessions and are otherwise free to set their own policies.
No direct popular involvement exists for the P&T, but it has public advisory
committees and is subject to oversight by the government.
The state-owned P&T is Finland's largest employer, with 45,000 employees.
Of those, more than 20,000 worked in telecommunications in 1988. It is a
profitable organization: in 1988, its surplus was 13 percent of revenues (which
was contributed to the state budget) and its return was 20 percent of fixed assets
(ITU, 1990). Before 1989, it was headed by Pekka Tarjanne, who became the
secretary general of the ITU in Geneva.
In 1988, P&T's profits were about FIM 800 million ($200 million). The
1989 telecommunications act requires the P&T to contribute a fixed amount of
profits, about $100 million, to the general budget each year. The P&T contri-
bution is more than that of all other state industries combined. Sixty percent of
P&T revenues come from domestic service, with the rest split among mobile
equipment leasing and international and telex service (Whitehouse, 1989b).
The relation between P&T and the local companies is characterized by both
cooperation and conflict. The local operators are collectively represented by the
Association of Telephone companies of Finland. Known also as toimilupalai-
tokset, or "licensed ones," they are a strong voice against the P&T. The P&T
has long claimed that to ensure the goal of social equity, a full national mo-
nopoly is required; but the local companies have stressed, just as adamantly,
their century-old tradition of technical progressivity and political legitimacy
through the participation of owners/subscribers. Friction arises over the extent
of the P&T monopoly, control of advanced services, and revenue and cost
allocations.
Finland 215
Services
Telephone density and quality of service are high in Finland. In 1988, density
was 49.86 subscribers and 68.5 sets per 100 people (ITU, 1990). This is par-
ticularly remarkable in light of the low population density. Although Finland is
Western Europe's fourth largest country, its total population is less than 5 mil-
lion. Also, despite its rural character, Finland maintains rates well below the
OECD average for residential and business lines (OECD, 1990).
Local exchange automation dates back to 1922 and was completed in the
1960s. Long-distance automation began in 1958, with Ericsson ARM equip-
ment. Electronic Analog SPC switches were introduced in the 1970s, and dig-
ital trunk exchanges were introduced in 1978. The P&T introduced digital
switching in the trunk network as well as in the local exchange in 1983.
Finland 217
Equipment
For a country with a small population, Finland has a well-developed electronics
industry. In principle, the equipment market is open to foreign firms, but most
equipment is supplied by domestic companies, such as Nokia or the Finnish
subsidiaries of Ericsson, Siemens, and Alcatel. Telephone companies attempt
to buy from several sources to maintain competition among suppliers. There
are four digital exchange suppliers: Telenokia, with 40 percent of the market;
Ericsson, with 34 percent; Siemens, with 25 percent; and Standard Electric
Puhelinteollisuus (formerly ITT, subsequently Alcatel), with 1 percent.
Telex terminals are provided solely by the P&T; cellular telephones and pag-
ing equipment generally are privately supplied, rather than provided by tele-
phone companies. This is due to the liberalization of interconnection rules. In
the past, the telephone companies and the P&T provided most equipment,
including telephone sets, modems, and data terminals. Interconnection of
subscriber-owned equipment has subsequently become permissible.
Other internationally successful Finnish Telephone equipment manufacturers
are VISTACOM (videophones), BENEFON (mobile telephone) and TECNO-
MEN (paging, automatic voice-messaging, encryption). The largest Finnish
equipment manufacturer is Telenokia, part of the electronics division of Nokia,
Finland's largest private company. In 1989, it controlled 19 percent of the
Finnish telecommunications market (Northern Business Information, 1990). The
Nokia group is also involved in forest products, machinery, plastics, and chem-
icals. A sister organization, Nokia Data Systems, produces PBXs, LANs, and
other equipment and terminals. Nokia Cables is an important European cable
manufacturer. Still another sister company, Mobira, is Scandinavia's largest
producer of mobile telephones.'
In 1989, Nokia had approximately 37,000 employees and its turnover was
about $5.6 billion (Nokia Annual Report, 1989, p. 3). Although in the early
1970s Nokia was not very active in the electronics field, by 1990, electronics
and electronic products comprised 90 percent of the group's business, mainly
in the consumer area. Telecommunications represented 9 percent of sales, or
$570 million.
Nokia is active in exports. Only 32 percent of its sales in 1989 were in
Finland, with other Scandinavian countries accounting for another 16 percent
(Nokia, 1989). It holds 35 percent of the digital transmission market in Swe-
den, 95 percent in Qatar, and supplies the U.K., France, China, and the United
Arab Emirates with its DX-200. In 1990, Nokia had 37 percent of the mobile
Finland 219
History
The Norwegian state telegraph company was established in 1855, four years
after the first telegraph line was installed. The telephone was introduced in
1880 by the International Bell Telephone Company. Within a year, Bell estab-
lished local franchises in Oslo and Dramrnen. A second private system was
launched in the capital to compete with the Bell System, but the two were
combined in 1886 into the Christiana Telephone Company when the vigorous
competition between them yielded what municipal officials deemed were
counterproductive results. The city government thus committed itself to a role
in the development of Oslo's communications system and retained a share in
the new company (Holcombe, 1911).
Norway soon faced the question of who would provide the long-distance link
between the Oslo and Drammen exchanges and what role the government should
play in telephony. In 1881, the parliament established state control over tele-
phony and telegraphy and provided for private telephone concessions. A private
project for the Oslo-Drammen line collapsed when the state telegraph authori-
ties demanded full compensation for all revenue losses incurred as a result of
intercity telephone service. The project was also impeded by the merchants of
Drammen, who feared that a readily available means of communicating with
the capital would hurt their businesses. Similar to other European states' short-
sighted protection of the telegraph, the state telegraph office decided not to
provide long-distance service on its own to guard the health of the telegraph.
In an attempt to block all intercity telephone service, the telegraph administra-
tion forced local exchange systems of adjoining communities to maintain a 2-
kilometer buffer area between their respective service areas. However, as de-
mand in rural areas increased and companies responded with expanded service,
interconnection was permitted, although still only where no equivalent tele-
graph connection existed. This restriction was abolished as it became increas-
ingly clear that the telegraph could not substitute for the telephone. In 1885,
the first interurban telephone line parallel to a telegraph route was constructed
and some telegraph offices were converted to public telephone offices. But
where telephone companies interfered with its revenue sources, the telegraph
administration still required compensation for the resulting falloff in its busi-
ness.
220
Norway 221
tions: one for basic monopoly services, another for competitive activities in
equipment markets, and a third for technical control functions (Nyheim, 1984).
In 1986, the parliament adopted a resolution to reorganize the NTA begin-
ning in 1988. The parliamentary plan allowed the NTA to keep its basic net-
work monopoly but required that its unregulated businesses be consolidated
under a separate subsidiary, Televerkets Konkurranseorganisasjan (TBK).
Structural safeguards have been implemented against cross-subsidization of TBK
by NTA's monopoly. After the defeat of the social democratic government, the
new coalition government began to consider further deregulation. The value-
added network services were opened for competition. When the market was
opened, there were no competitors. With some reluctance, NTA participation
in this market was permitted. Applications for a second cellular service were
received from Netcom, owned by Norway's Nova Industrier and Orkla Borre-
gaard and Sweden's Comvik. Aside from telecommunications services such as
VANs, TBK markets, sells, installs, and services user equipment and offers
cable TV systems.
The reorganization also included the establishment of the Norwegian Tele-
communications Regulatory Authority (NTRA), overseen by the Ministry of
Communications, which represents Norwegian interests before bodies deter-
mining international standards and handles licensing, spectrum allocation, and
equipment type-approval.
The privatization of 49 percent of NTA and divestiture of TBK promised by
the conservative and Progress parties was averted by a narrow Labor/Left vic-
tory in 1989. But competition was assured for mobile telephony.
Services
Penetration of main lines reached 47.7 per 100 persons in 1988 (ITU, 1990).
These investments are financed by rates, identical for business and residential
customers, which are among the highest in Europe, despite the 1981 elimina-
tion of connection charges. (Foreman-Peck and Manning, 1988). In a contro-
versial move, NTA in 1989 decreased the price of international leased lines
while increasing domestic leased line prices by 16 percent.
Telex service began operating in 1946. Data transmission, using circuit-
switched Datex-L service, is available. A public packet-switched network, Nor-
pak, operating since 1980, offers international connections. In 1990, Norway
ordered X.400 and X.500 systems from the British firm ICL. The 1983 gov-
ernment commission recommended the development of ISDN, and in 1986 the
NTA started an ISDN research laboratory and a pilot ISDN project. Videotex
trials began in 1981 (Nyheim, 1984).
A mobile telephony network began operating in 1966 and was automated
and integrated into the Nordic Mobile System in 1981. In 1989, Norway had
the highest rate of mobile communications penetration in the world, thirty-two
subscribers per 1000 persons. ROGALAND radio, established in 1927 and ex-
panded in 1960, also provides maritime services. A GSM network in Oslo was
Norway 223
Equipment
One peculiarity of Norwegian network and equipment has been that since the
introduction of automatic dialing in the early 1920s, equipment in the Oslo
area has operated with a reversed dial (i.e., the digit 1 gives nine pulses, etc).
In contrast, the rest of the country operates on the regular system. Interconnec-
tions required dial connectors in the public network and in the leased private
networks, and equipment had to be available for both systems. This problem is
gradually being solved by the introduction of electronic-tone equipment.
Most telecommunications equipmentincluding data transmission terminals,
paging receivers, and private handsetsis privately available with NTRA type
approval. Telex terminals and PBXs were once supplied only through the tele-
communications authority, though that did not appear to be lasting. Domestic
public switch manufacturers were Standard Telefon of Kabelfabrik (STK) (for-
merly the Norwegian subsidiary of ITT and subsequently of Alcatel) and the
Elektrisk Bureau (EB) Group. EB supplied electromechanical switches. But in
1983, the NTA began to digitalize and adopted STK's System 12 switch. In
1989, STK had monopoly control over Norway's public switching market. By
1991, 40 percent of Norway was digitalized, with STK providing 1.2 million
lines.
All this affected EB negatively. Previously owned by L. M. Ericsson, EB
was one of Norway's strongest private industry groups. In 1987, EB and Erics-
son established EB Ericsson Information Systems to manufacture terminal
equipment in which each company has a 50 percent interest. In the same year,
Asea of Sweden acquired a majority interest in EB, which it soon merged with
its two Norwegian subsidiaries. Asea, in turn, joined the Swiss company Brown
Boveri to form the Asea Brown Boveri group. EB became Norway's second
largest privately owned industry group and employed 15,000 people, of whom
2800 were in its telecommunications division. However, in 1989, EB traded
its public switch, PBX, mobile telephone, and other telecommunications oper-
ations to L.M. Ericsson in return for the latter's road and railway signalling
interests, and concentrated on satellite and power line communications. Erics-
son thus acquired a direct role in Norwegian markets.
There are several manufacturers of PBXs. Northern Telecom acquired an
interest in one of the larger ones, G. A. Ring. Other domestic telecommuni-
cations manufacturers include Universal Communications, for modems; Tand-
berg Telecom, for videocodecs; Stentor, for advanced intercoms; SysScan, for
optical scanning devices; Simonsen Electro, for mobile telephones; and Scan-
vest Ring Communications, for telemetry.
18
Denmark
Structure
The government holds the legal telegraph and telephone monopoly concession
in accordance with a 1897 law; it franchised three regional telephone compa-
niesfor Copenhagen (KTAS), Jutland (JTAS), and Funen (FKT)to provide
service. A fourth concessionary company (Tele Sonderjylland), under the
224
Denmark 225
Danish Post and Telegraph office (PTT), was added to provide service to the
South Jutland region after it was returned to Danish rule in 1920. The individ-
ual companies operated trunk lines within the areas of their individual fran-
chises, and the government played no role in local operations for a long time.
Thus, telecommunications services were supplied by two sources, the PTT
and four local telephone companies. These local companies were not private.
The government held a majority control of the Copenhagen and Jutland tele-
phone companies as well as 100 percent of the South-Jutland telephone com-
pany. The Funen Company was a cooperative of local councils, and the gov-
ernment owned the remaining 45 percent. KTAS operates on the islands of
Zealand, Lolland-Falster, and Bornholm, and serves 45 percent of the popula-
tion and 49 percent of all telephones. JTAS has 39 percent and FKT has 8
percent. In 1990, all regional companies were placed under a PTT holding
organization, with partial privatization involving investors close to the govern-
ment (such as pension funds).
The need for long-distance interconnection and approval of rates suggested a
government presence. In 1950 an agreement was reached between the state and
regional companies (the concordate) in which the state acted as arbitrator for
issues of standards, pricing and cost-sharing, and traffic planning (Olsen, 1988).
But this agreement proved unstable in the 1980s when new technologies were
being introduced. In 1982, the minister of public works, who holds overall
responsibility for telecommunications policy, established and appointed a Tele-
communications Council comprised of thirteen members, representing the min-
istries, the PTT, the independent telephone companies, subscribers, industry,
and employees.
In 1986, the Telecommunications Council was reduced in significance when
the general directorate for Telecommunications was carved out of the PTT.
This reorganization came in the wake of the so-called Bernstein Committee
report. The regional structure was strengthened by adding a fourth concession-
ary state enterprise for South Jutland, which was divested from the PTT, though
it was still owned by it. The PTT, which in 1978 had still called for a unified
system under its control, also lost its operating divisions for data transmission,
mobile telephone terminals, telex, telefax, and other customer services to the
four concessionary companies. In addition, the PTT was divided into a general
directorate for political, administrative, and regulatory functions (including rate
setting, spectrum management, equipment certification, and licensing) and two
operating divisions for postal service and telecommunications. The latter was
named Telecom Denmark, and was in charge of connections between conces-
sionary areas, international long-distance service, the national trunk network,
nationwide cellular mobile telephones, and broadcasting. The Telecommunica-
tions Council was reduced to an advisory capacity, and regulatory matters were
more independently lodged in the ministry and the general directorate (Peder-
sen, 1987).
The creation of the general directorate was significant in unification and con-
solidation of regulating authority. The weak arbitrator's approach of the former
226 Denmark
Equipment
Services
and direct broadcast satellites. For example, households could have access to
their own or community satellite antennas to the exclusion of the established
telephone carriers.
In 1983, a Royal Commission on Mass Media proposed that a national
broadband network be established that would provide both television and tele-
phone linkages. The independent telephone companies were in favor of a na-
tionwide broadband system because it would free them from prior agreements
with the FIT (Qvortrup, 1984). The PTT, however, preferred to separate tele-
phone from broadband services, with a narrowband ISDN network to link tele-
phone connections and a broadband network to interconnect the national cable
television and master antenna systems. The latter would use a nationwide PTT
microwave system and PTT-operated satellite earth stations. These issues were
resolved in the Bernstein Committee's 1988 recommendations, which left
broadband services such as data transmission and video service providers to the
local companies.
Much of the country was cabled for the Digital Optical CATV Trunk (DO-
CAT) system, which allows transmission of eight television and twelve FM
channels on each broadband optical fiber.
The PTT and the telephone companies were given a monopoly for the recep-
tion of television programs from communications satellites, thus forcing house-
holds to partly finance the advanced national cable system. This led to much
unhappiness among cable firms and the numerous housing associations that
operated master antenna satellite systems. Provocative violations of the law
ensued. In consequence, the parliament changed the law in 1987 and permitted
a system by which private parties could receive satellite-delivered programs and
compete with the traditional telephone carriers, which themselves can transmit
these satellite programs to master antenna associations as "hybrid network con-
nection" (hybrid both in terms of analog-digital and fiber-coax combinations).
The notion of the unified national broadband network was thus significantly
affected, since the new law permitted broadband reception and limited distri-
bution outside of it.
19
Iceland
230
Iceland 231
History
The United Telephone Company opened its first exchange (with five subscrib-
ers) in 1880.' United was taken over in 1882 by the Telephone Company of
Ireland, which oversaw a slow growth to 500 lines in Dublin by 1988. The
operation was acquired in 1893 by the National Telephone Company, which
rapidly developed the network to encompass fifty-six exchanges by 1900. The
Post Office, which operated the telegraph and feared revenue losses, began in
1893 slowly to invest in trunk lines and submarine cables. By 1908 the Post
owned thirty-three exchanges to National's eighty-five (Litton, 1961).
The threat of Post Office take-over of National Telephone became a reality
in 1905; the postmaster general forced a sell-out at the end of National's license
period in 1911, paying only 12.4 million where the company had claimed its
value was 20.9 million. Military involvement in network construction began
in 1909, completely replacing civilians until the outbreak of World War I. By
1918, there were 12,500 lines, half of them around Dublin; three counties were
still without exchanges. The network was greatly damaged in the Anglo-Irish
and civil wars of the 1920s.
In 1924, the Post Office launched a vigorous program to rebuild and expand
the crippled network. By 1930, only western pockets of Mayo and Donegal
counties were without exchanges. Dublin received the country's first automatic
exchange system in 1927, but economic hardship in the 1930s stalled the net-
work's growth.
In 1937, there were still fewer than 40,000 lines in service (Department of
Industry and Commerce of Ireland, 1944). Except for the emergency installa-
tion of telephone lines to coastal lookout posts, progress halted altogether dur-
ing World War II. In 1945 the government earmarked 10 million for a pro-
gram to reach 100,000 subscribers within fifteen years, which was achieved
ahead of schedule. The country's first transatlantic cable was laid in 1956, and
Limerick began operating Ireland's first crossbar switch in 1957 (Telecom Ei-
reann, 1987). By 1960, however, Ireland still had only 145,000 telephones in
service, fewer than any European nation except Greece, and line density in
Dublin was a mere 9.25 percent (Department of Industry and Commerce of
Ireland, 1969).
By the late 1960s, connections were accelerated. By 1979, a total of 436,000
232
Ireland 233
lines were in operation, but the waiting list was still lengthy (Central Statistics
Office, 1979, p. 322).
Telecom Eireann
For Irish telecommunications, the 1980s was an era of catching up. In 1978,
the inferior quality of services provided by the government's Department of
Posts and Telegraphs forced the newly elected Fianna Fail government to com-
mission an external and independent group to review Irish telecommunications
(Raggett, 1984). Upon completion of its task, the commission issued a report
that urged immediate action. The inadequacy of telecommunications was ac-
knowledged. The government established an interim Telecoms Board, and as
part of a broad infrastructure program it approved accelerated development.
Soon after, under the P&T minister Albert Reynolds, the government launched
a five-year telecommunications spending program of over $1 billion for the
early 1980s. The program aimed to modernize and upgrade the network to the
quality of other European countries and to increase its availability throughout
the country (Ergas and Okavana, 1984). The implementation of this program
helped to change the government's previous tendency to consider telecommu-
nications as a money maker for its other services.
The government published legislative proposals based on the review group's
report, but enactment of the legislation was impeded by five changes of gov-
ernment in the three years of the interim Telecom Board. The proposals as
outlined, however, encountered little political opposition (Keenan, 1985; Rag-
gett, 1984).
Eventually, the Postal and Telecommunications Services Act of 1983 was
passed. It created two state-sponsored enterprises, the Bord Telecom Eireann
(TE), for telecommunications, and An Post, for the national postal service.
Carved from the Department of Post and Telegraphs, a Department of Com-
munications was created to supervise general policy on telecommunications is-
sues (NTIA, 1985). Actual telecommunications operations are provided by
Telecom Eireann (TE). Tom Byrnes, an Irish-American who has been the man-
aging director of IBM Ireland, served as Chief Executive of TE. TE was re-
quired to operate on a profit basis, with near-monopoly rights of service, and
embarked on an ambitious modernization program. In 1987, foreign loans helped
fund 50 percent of TE's investment program (Garnett, 1987).
After separating from the PTT, Bord Telecom Eireann was still a state-owned
enterprise but operated with greater autonomy, under an exclusive government
license. It has an "exclusive privilege," which is somewhat less than a mo-
nopoly, up to and including the connection point in the customers' premises.
Where TE decides not to provide service, another network operator can be
licensed, as in the case of cable service. Such a license can be issued by the
PTT minister or by TE itself. Where services are uneconomical, the govern-
ment can force TE to provide them. In 1985, the cable television committee,
established by Communications Minister James Mitchell, recommended the es-
234 Ireland
Equipment
Services
For a long time, Irish international traffic used to be routed through Britain. In
1984, however, Ireland established an Intelsat earth station near Cork. Since
then, it has vied to become an international gateway for European traffic, but
this goal clashed with tariff reality. Calls placed from Ireland to a number of
other European nations tend to cost considerably more than calls traveling in
the opposite direction (Transnational Data and Communications Report, 1988).
Exceptions are calls to generally high-priced countries (Belgum, Greece, Italy,
236 Ireland
Spain, and Portugal). In 1990, however, rates for digital lines were reduced
significantly.
Since 1981, international packet switching service has been available, and in
1984, TE introduced the packet-switched network Eirpac. It allows access to
bibliographic and full-text databases. Eirpac also connects to national and in-
ternational videotex services.
A major VAN service is Cognotec, established by the Confederation of Irish
Industry in 1984 and restructured in 1987 with strong insurance industry partic-
ipation. Its Corporate Treasury service provides company controllers with ac-
cess to financial information. In partnership with Istel (a subsidiary of AT&T),
Cognotec launched its Corporate Treasury service in the U.K. market in 1990.
Cognotec's other major service is Clientbank, which gives insurance brokers
access to host computers of leading insurance companies.
Agriline, an agricultural videotex database, was launched in 1986 following
a two-year EC-supported trial. It offers weather, market prices, a calendar of
events, and farm business news as well as information on crops and livestock
management.
Eircell mobile communication is provided by TE. The system uses the TAGS
technical standard and had 19,000 subscribers in 1990, the EC's third-highest
penetration per working population, at comparatively low rates for Europe (F.
McGovern, 1990, communication). Eirpage is a joint venture with Motorola
Ireland in which TE has 51 percent. It holds the monopoly on national paging
services in Ireland.
Data and Special Services Network (DASSNET), launched in 1990, is a
significant improvement of the digital leased-line network, providing 64-kbit-
2-Mbit connections. The Government Telecommunications Network, linking
government departments in Dublin and five provincial centers, planned to use
the advanced DASSNET.
Telecommunications in the
Mediterranean Countries and
Eastern Europe
This page intentionally left blank
21
Italy
239
240 Italy
History
Italy's postal service originated in medieval times when the major cities and
trading companies established Europe's first courier services. In Venice, a
guildlike messenger organization existed and operated in a monopolistic fashion
after 1305. Milan's system dates to 1385, and Naples created a runner course
for southern Italy in 1444 (Dallmeyer, 1977). The Tassis family, which became
a major presence in the postal system of much of Europe, also established
service in Italy. The Italian PTT was established in 1870, during the unification
of Italy.
Italian telephony started as a private business. The first large company, So-
cieta Generate di Telefonia, was established in 1881 (Holcombe, 1911). Lim-
ited telephone service began in Rome in 1878; the American Bell Company
opened exchanges in Rome and Milan in 1881. Also in 1881, the first inter-
urban service was provided between Rome and Tivoli on an experimental basis.
Rival companies and competitive service emerged in some of the larger cities.
Pressure to consolidate soon mounted. Within a short time, only two private
telephone companies remained. In 1883, a royal decree established uniform
obligations for concessionary firms, and burdensome requirements were im-
posed to protect the telegraph authority. Concessions were not awarded exclu-
sively, and ran for only three years. The telegraph authority approved all public
call offices as well as the private telephone rates. It levied a heavy concession
fee on local exchanges and permitted municipalities to purchase the private
telephone systems after twelve years. However, only one municipality wound
up owning a local telephone ownership. In 1907, there were 141 local networks
with 43,000 subscribers. In that year, the Italian parliament voted to purchase
eighteen long-distance lines and twenty-seven local exchanges, then operated
by the two major private telephone companies (Societa Generale Italiana de
Telefonia e Applicazione Elettriche and Societa Telefonica dell'Alta Italiana,
accounting for 75 percent of Italy's telephones). Under the plan, compensation
to the owners of these companies was to be paid over eleven years out of future
telephone profits.
Between 1907 and 1925, telecommunications were jointly provided by the
state and by sixty-three regional private concessionaires. Local telephony was
legally franchised to private firms, but long-distance communications remained
under state control. Subsequently, under Mussolini, five telephone regions were
established and assigned to different concessionaires: STIPEL, TELVE, TIMO,
TETI, and SET. The PT organization ASST was established to provide long-
distance interconnection between the five regions and international services with
European and Mediterranean nations. This interexchange network was com-
pleted in 1928.
Forces for further centralization were strong. In October 1933, three of the
concessionary firms were absorbed into the government holding company STET,
which in turn was part of the government's industrial reconstruction institute,
IRI. In 1958, the two remaining regional companies, TETI and SET, became
Italy 241
part of STET. In 1965, these five concessionaires were among nine firms merged
into the Societa Italiana per 1'Esercizio Telefonica (SIP), a company that had
started as a northern Italian electrical utility. About 70,000 shareholders owned
approximately 45 percent of SIP's capital; STET controlled the remainder. In
turn, about 50,000 shareholders controlled 42.3 percent of STET, with the
remaining 57.7 percent held by IRI.
In the meantime, international communications also consolidated. Interna-
tional telegraph service was initially divided between the radio provider, Italia
Radio, and the submarine cable provider, Italcable, and was centralized in 1941
when Italcable acquired its rival. It was further consolidated in 1965, when
Italcable became a subsidiary of STET. Telespazio, Italy's satellite commu-
nications provider, was established as part of STET in 1963.
Structure
tions: the Post and Telecommunications Administration (FT) and the State Agency
for Telephone Services (ASST). The PT conducted postal telegraph, telex, te-
lefax, and radio electric services. ASST, an autonomous public corporation,
operated the primary long-distance transmission network that connected the
twenty-one telecommunication "compartments" of the country. ASST also op-
erated international telephony within Europe and the Mediterranean basin.
Through the PT, the MPT provided a coastal station network (DCR) for com-
munication with ships, minor islands, and Albania. It also provided broadcast-
ing transmission for government operations such as embassies abroad. Two
other companies, Sirm and Telemar, operated radio equipment aboard Italian
ships, and potentially other services where no private concessioniaries can be
secured. The national network's layout consisted of twenty-one regional com-
partments, subdivided into 231 districts, each with its own area code. These
were, in turn, divided into about 1400 sectors and 10,000 local exchanges, of
which more than half have less than 500 subscribers.
Perhaps the best way to conceptualize the allocation of services in Italy is to
imagine four concentric rings, in which the responsibilities alternated between
the government-controlled STET holding company and direct government pro-
vision. At the core, STET's subsidiary company SIP operated local distribu-
tion. SIP also provided domestic packet-switched service. The next ring around
it, corresponding to a greater distance of communication, was domestic long-
distance transmission, operated by ASST. (For a long time, SIP also ran long-
distance service in many rural districts.) The next ring, international service
within Europe and many countries in North Africa, was also in the domain of
ASST. The third ring was international transmission outside of Europe and
North Africa, which was operated by the STET companies Italcable (for terres-
trial and submarine transmission) and Telespazio (for satellites). Both also pro-
vided the PT administration with international record traffic.
SIP is by far the largest Italian service operator, with a turnover of 14,900
billion lire and 77,000 employees in 1989; the next largest, ASST, had reve-
nues of 2,400 billion lire and under 13,000 employees.
An interesting side-effect of this system was that the separation of firms by
different functions makes internal cross-subsidization more difficult (Benedetti,
1983). The creation of a cross-subsidization fund in 1980, the Cassa Conquag-
lio per II Services Telefonico, did not clarify this complex accounting process.
SIP's local service was separate from ASST's long-distance service. Thus, where
contributions existed, they were by payment to another entity or by contribu-
tions to a parent company, and were thus more transparent than internal subsi-
dies would be within a unified PTT system.
In 1985, the PTT ministry (MPT) initiated a study of the feasibility of sep-
arating postal and telecommunications activities. The study proposed separate
agencies within the ministry to administer each of these activities throughout
the country. The recommendations, however, were not instituted. In 1987, a
bill was introduced that would change the PTT role from operating services to
planning and coordination and that would divide service provision so that Ital-
Staly 243
cable would provide the entire international service and SIP would provide the
domestic one. Additionally, the bill proposed that Telespazio operate indepen-
dently, providing satellite service for SIP, Italcable, and RAI. ASST's opera-
tions would be assumed by SIP, Italcable, and the ministry. The bill's oppo-
nents focused on job relocation and preserving the state control.
Subsequently, the Christian Democrats offered a plan in 1988 to consolidate
the telecommunications agencies into a "Super-STET"including SIP, ASST,
Italcable, and Telespazioaggregated as "Italia Telecom." It would have rel-
egated the ministry to a watchdog role (Rosenbaum, 1988). But this project
was blocked by the PTT minister, trade unions, and southern Italian Christian
Democrats, who traditionally were influential in MPT matters and were con-
cerned with loss of telecommunications and postal patronage. An example for
the politicization of the decision process: ASST was headed by the leader of
the Christian Democratic Italian Union Workers' Confederation. After the pro-
posal failed, an alternate plan to create a "Super-SIP" was introduced by So-
cialists, but this was also blocked by the Christian Democrats as well as by top
management. In 1990, two bills were introduced to break the logjam. One bill
proposed a change in the union contract for ASST, to protect those members
opposed a move to the private-sector IRI-STET group where they would lose
the right to retire after twenty years and receive a smaller pension. The other
bill proposed separation of post and telecommunications activities of the PTT.
In 1990, the telecommunications ministry recommended a "Super-STET"
under which the government's ASST would be transferred to STET. But the
push for structural reform lost some of its steam when a government crisis led
to the replacement of Minister Oscar Mammi, a member of the economically
liberal Republican Party.
Italy was slow to focus on the role of telecommunications in the development
of its economy. Although it was advanced in completing a universal subscriber
trunk dialing, the system stagnated in the late 1970s, when, for political rea-
sons, rate increases lagged behind rapid inflation. The major problem in up-
grading Italian telecommunications has been reconciling the cost of moderniz-
ing the network and of trade union demands for high wages and flexible working
conditions with political pressures to keep telephone rates from rising. This
dilemma became particularly acute in the late 1970s, when local rates were
frozen even with inflation raging at 20 percent. In consequence, no funds re-
mained for investment. The ratio of SIP's self-financing (the contribution of a
company's own earnings to capital formation) plummeted to 10 percent in 1980,
when the firm reported losses of 538 million lire (Benedetti, 1983). SIP had to
resort to indirect ways to increase rates, such as requiring subscribers to in-
crease their deposits. It also had to borrow at the prevailing high interest rates.
Subsequently, interest payments at times ate up 30 percent of its total income.
The investment slowdown, in turn, adversely affected equipment suppliers and
penetration. Italy's telephone density was about half of West Germany's; there
were only half as many telex subscribers as in France and one-third as many
as in the United Kingdom. Telephone switches were largely electromechanical
244 Italy
rather than electronic, and the system was chronically congested. Italy was also
late in introducing national data networks, which were implemented eleven
years after Germany and seven years behind France's Transpac (Pozzi, 1987).
Tariffs were often set by politics, resulting in a complex split of local, long-
distance, and international revenues. A parliamentary committee finally rec-
ommended streamlining the cumbersome and restrictive rate-setting process and
permitting rates to reflect inflation. The government responded in 1986 by in-
creasing rates, giving SIP more pricing flexibility and fine-tuning the rate struc-
ture with time-measured local calls and peak load pricing. It also used a com-
pensation fund, the Cassa Conquaglio, to transfer carrier profits from ASST
and Italcable to SIP. It even temporarily reduced SIP's concession fee from 4.5
percent to 0.5 percent of its revenues, invested in its shares, and guaranteed
purchase of the remainder. SIP's self-financing ratio increased to almost 50
percent by 1983 as a result of these actionsstill low by comparison. France's
DOT had a ratio of approximately 65 percent, that of British Telecom was 60
percent, and the Bundespost's was 100 percent (Benedetti, 1983). By 1988,
SIP's self-financing had reached 90 percent of its capital expenditures.
In 1982, the PTT ministry also formulated a ten-year plan for the telecom-
munications sector. The targets for 1990 were a density of thirty-eight subscrib-
ers and fifty-seven telephones per 100 population (up from twenty-four and
thirty-eight in 1981), and a digitalization, by the year 2000, of 50 percent local
and 80 percent long-distance switching. In 1989, digitalization predictions were
revised upward for 55 percent of all switches by 1993 and 100 percent by 2000.
Trunk lines would be 85 percent digital by 1993 (Benzoni, 1990).
Even after streamlining, the rate-setting process was extremely complex. Users
making fewer than fourty calls per month paid 40 lire per billing unit, and
others paid 127 lire. Italy's 3.9 million business users paid rates well above
the OECD average, and telex service was Europe's most expensive. Interna-
tional rates were also the highest in Europe in 1988, with a three-minute call
from Milan to London costing 33 percent more than a call in the other direction
(OECD, 1990, p. 30; Schenker, 1990). Perhaps because of its high rates, Italy's
international traffic was half that of France's and one-third of Germany's, ac-
counting for less than 1 percent of network usage. Even Switzerland generated
more total minutes of international calling. Those three nations accounted for
50 percent of Italy's traffic, with an additional 20 percent going to the United
States and the United Kingdom (Staple, 1990; Smau, 1990).
SIP greatly reduced the waiting list for basic service, from 750,000 in 1981
to 118,900 in 1988, though penetration rates were relatively low (34.9 main
lines and fifty-one telephones per 100 persons). A great disparity persisted be-
tween telephone penetration in the industrial north/central region (fifty-seven
per 100 persons) and the rural south (thirty-seven per 100) (ITU, 1990).
In 1989, SIP launched a four-year investment and expansion plan called Piano
Europa to invest $8 biliion above the already budgeted $18 billion to connect
4 million new basic subscribers by the end of 1992, 43 percent of which reside
in southern Italy.
Italy 245
SIP planned to procure the majority of its exchanges from the National Pole
and the remainder from either FACE, then an ITT subsidiary, or FATME,
Ericsson's subsidiary, both of which were domiciled in Italy. However, since
the employees of the loser among FACE and FATME would likely have to lay
off employees, both companies were chosen as suppliers with the vague expec-
tation that their systems would be modified into a uniform switch. In 1985, the
National Pole (Italtel, GTE, Telettra) received two-thirds of the $900 million
contract, FACE had 14.2 percent, and FATME had 20.4 percent. This was a
continuation of their already existing and quasi-established market shares. Those
steady market shares for switching equipment had been Italtel, 52 percent; Te-
lettra, 1 percent; FATME, 18 percent; FACE, 17 percent; GTE (later Siemens),
12 percent (R. Lauro, 1987, communication).
In developing the Proteo system, Italtel first entered into a joint venture co-
operation agreement with the American-owned GTE Telecomunicazioni and
Telettra, the Fiat subsidiary. It soon required another major partner. This led
to a major joint venture between AT&T and Italtel, which won a large portion
of the $28 billion that Italy planned to spend on network equipment by 1992
(Colby and Hudson, 1989, p. 27). The Italtel-AT&T deal followed some heavy-
handed lobbying for the partnership position, including personal intervention
by Francois Mitterrand for Alcatel and Ronald Reagan for AT&T. Alcatel
chairman Pierre Suard played the European card, stating that the "goal of Eu-
ropean telecommunications policy must be to maintain and improve the lead-
ership of European industry" (Roussel, 1990). Germany, on behalf of Sie-
mens, threatened to block $4 billion in subsidies for Italy's steel industry. Former
Prime Minister Bettino Craxi, a socialist, supported AT&T (Hayes, 1988). Ul-
timately, AT&T paid the government $130 million, the difference in value of
the stock swap of its 20 percent share of Italtel and Italtel's 20 percent stake in
AT&T's Network Systems International.
In response to the AT&T-Italtel partnership, Alcatel acquired Telettra in
1990, thereby gaining Teletra's thirty-three percent market share in transmis-
sion equipment in Italy and forty-five percent in Spain. But the European Com-
mission first required Spain's Telefonica telephone monopoly to divest itself of
its shares in Alcatel (21 percent in the Spanish subsidiary) and Telettra (10
percent), as well as to open its purchasing policy.
and Eutelsat. Like the American Comsat, it is a carriers' carrier. It also pro-
vides remote sensing services. Its revenues in 1985 were $43 million, and it
employed about 640. One-third of Telespazio is held by the broadcast authority
RAI, which uses its services.
The Selenia-Elsag group was another major STET subsidiary. It is exten-
sively involved in manufacturing civilian and military electronic systems and
industrial automation and employs 13,000. Elsag won a major contract award
from the U.S. Postal Service to automate its system, an export achievement
that received much attention because of its size and because of the implicit
affirmation of Italy's high-technology capability. In 1989, STET sold its con-
trol in Selenia and Elsag.
SGS, until 1989, was a STET company in the microelectronics field and is
the major Italian manufacturer of integrated circuits. In 1985, its revenues were
$300 million and it employed almost 10,000. In 1987, it entered into a joint
venture for component manufacture with the French electronic giant Thomson.
But the venture did not flourish and STET sold its share in 1989. Other major
STET subsidiaries include Seat, a publishing company for telephone directories
and electronic yellow page directory service, and Consultel, a telecommunica-
tions consulting firm active in the developing world. STET's research & devel-
opment organization is CSELT, established in 1984.
Olivetti
Olivetti (formally Ing. C. Olivetti & Co.), headquartered in the northern city
of Ivrea, is perhaps Italy's most noted entrepreneurial firm in advanced elec-
tronics. For a time it was renowned for its equipment's design rather than its
marketplace success. This changed when Carlo De Benedetti assumed its lead-
ership. De Benedetti is to Italy's electronic sector what Silvio Berlusconi is to
its broadcasting: an empire builder of the first order. He managed the automo-
bile firm Fiat for a short while, until he had a falling-out with the Agnelli
family, which controls it. In 1978, De Benedetti acquired 15 percent of the
financially ailing Olivetti.
Within a few years Olivetti became Europe's largest office equipment maker
and the world's second largest producer of personal computers. In 1982, AT&T
acquired 25 percent of the company for $230 million, with an option to raise
its share to 40 percent in 1987. With its AT&T connection in the United States,
Olivetti aimed to become the world's number 2 company in professional desk-
top computers. But in 1988, AT&T, frustrated at its absence of control, de-
clined to increase its financial involvement and cut its computer order by 75
percent (Guyon and Colloy, 1988).
In 1988, the West German firm Volkswagen acquired a 5 percent stake in
Olivetti, for which Olivetti received the large German office equipment maker,
Adler-Triumph. Olivetti also bought interests in dozens of international high-
tech firms, many of them in the United States. In the United Kingdom, Olivetti
bought most of the small computer maker Acorn. It also joined with GeDa, a
computer services company, to form Olinet, providing database management,
Italy 249
data processing, and so forth. Thus, Olivetti had a highly international set of
owners, subsidiaries, and markets, all part of De Benedetti's strategy of making
it a global electronics company.
In the process, De Benedetti's own shares multiplied in value. He had ac-
quired 15 percent of Olivetti for $17 million. By 1986, this was worth half a
billion dollars. He also embarked on building a personal business empire dis
tinct from Olivetti. He acquired for a time Italy's largest food company, Bui-
toni, and several smaller food companies, an automobile component maker, a
tobacco equipment manufacturer, a share in the publishing house Mondadori
(where he fought with Silvio Berlusconi for control), and an investment bank.
He also established close relations and an ownership share with Pirelli, the
large tire manufacturer. In 1987, he embarked on a take-over bid for Belgium's
huge but stodgy conglomerate Societe Generale de Belgique (SGB). Though
established Belgian and French interests succeeded in beating him back, the
effort proved profitable for De Benedetti. In the early 1990s, Olivetti experi-
enced serious deficits again, raising questions about its long-term prospects as
an independent company.
Services
In data transmission, the structure of the system reflects the complexity of the
underlying carriers. The PT administration (not to be confused with the State
Administration for Telephone Services, ASST) provides slow-speed data trans-
mission services. Italcable provides intercontinental data transmission lines. SIP
supplies slow data transmission over the switched network, and higher rates
over leased circuits.
Telex emerged under restrictive regulation. A message could only be sent by
its originator; only PTT-supplied devices could be attached to the equipment;
and a deposit of $2,000 to $3000 plus annual fees of $2000 made use expen-
sive. Poor service and installation waits that exceeded two years compounded
the problems. Users circumvented some of these restrictions by forming asso-
ciations enabling members to use a community-owned telex.
Since i983, SIP has operated a circuit-switched data network, Rete Fonia-
Dati (RFD), using a technology by Telettra. In 1986, a new digital circuit-
switched network, CDN, went on line. Itapac, the packet-switched network
operated jointly by SIP and MPT, opened in 1986 for general use. In the first
year of full operation, it expected 5000 subscribers but only had 2700. Itapac's
main problem was operational, since each of the two partners controls separate
parts of the network. In addition, high tariffs and low-speed connections pre-
sented problems. Switches were Italtel-modifted Siemens equipment. After 1989,
Itapac was run by SIP alone.
Dedicated private network facilities are permitted only for services not pro-
vided by the public network and exist in a gray zone of tacit agreement among
large corporations. Resale is technically prohibited, but appears to exist.
Because of the administrative complexity of the Italian telephone system,
250 Italy
Telecommunications in Malta
Telephone service in Malta, an island nation between Italy and Tunisia, dates
back to 1882. Service is operated by the private Malta Telephone Company,
which was taken over by the government in 1933. The telephone network was
largely destroyed during World War II. In 1957, the manual system was up-
graded by STC to a stronger automated system. Later, Siemens exchanges were
added. Overseas telephone service to London was established in 1947, and
service to Rome began in 1952. A submarine cable to Italy soon became the
main connection.
22
Spain
History
251
252 Spain
Organization
Overall regulation of the Spanish telecommunications sector lies with the Junta
Nacional de Telecomunicaciones (National Telecommunications Board), an in-
terministerial commission answering to the Ministry of Transport, Tourism,
and Communications. The board is responsible for assigning radio frequencies,
setting investment guidelines, and maintaining relations with foreign adminis-
trations.
Within the Ministry of Transport, Tourism, and Communications, two sep-
arate agencies have responsibility for telecommunications matters: the Direc-
cion General de Correos y Telecomunicaciones (Directorate General of Post
and Telecommunications, or DGCyT), which provides postal service as well
as telegraph, telex, facsimile, electronic mail, and message switching; and Di-
reccion General de Electronica y Informatica (Directorate General for Electron-
ics and Informatics, or DGEI), which is in charge of promoting the develop-
ment of a domestic electronics industry.
An independent communications network is run by the broadcast authority
RTVE, which operates its own transmitters and relay stations (Lopez-Escobar,
1985). Most of telephone operations, however, are the domain of Telefonica,
which was given monopoly status by government decree in 1970. Television
and limited voice and data services have also been offered by Retevision since
1989. Holding about 36 percent of shares in Telefonica, the Spanish govern-
ment acts as the majority holder of the company and, importantly, appoints its
chairman. The remainder of the firm's stock is held by more than 750,000
private shareholders, including a number of foreign interestsmostly Ameri-
can, British, and German institutional investors. American investors held about
17 percent of the company's stock in 1990.
The company's stock was a favorite of small investors; in 1985, CTNE ac-
counted for 17.2 percent of the entire Spanish stock market's capitalization! In
comparison, the ten largest stocks on the New York Stock Exchange account
for 15 percent (The Economist, 1985). Because Telefonica's capital needs are
so great relative to the size of the Spanish economy as a whole, it had problems
in raising adequate funds to finance its investments, and in 1985 it began to
offer its stock on foreign exchanges. As a "strategic sector" firm, the Spanish
Spain 253
government refused to raise the ceiling on the amount of Telefonica stock that
could be held by foreign interests from 25 percent. A large portion of the
state's holdings in Telefonica are administered by the central bank of Spain and
the Institute Nacional de Industria (INI), a public holding authority that was
established in 1941 modeled after Mussolini's IRI. By 1982, INI firms had
more than 200,000 employees, about 7 percent of the country's labor force. Its
losses, however, amounted to $1 billion. Telefonica's semiprivate, semigovern-
mental structure has made the privatization versus nationalization debate less
pressing than that in most European countries.
Telefonica's presence in the Spanish economy is colossal and is reinforced
by its vertical integration. With 71,000 employees, Telefonica is Spain's larg-
est company. It holds stock in numerous firms, including Amper-Elasa, SIN-
TEL, TEFISA, TIDSA, and Cetesa (de Moragas et al., 1987). It accounts for
nearly 4 percent of gross national capital formation in Spain and 2.7 percent of
the gross added value in the service industry. Telefonica has one of Europe's
highest rates of telecommunications investment as a share of gross fixed capital
formation (3.9 percent) (ITU, 1990).
In 1985, the government proposed legislation to reorganize and centralize
the telecommunications sector, with the specific objectives of creating an inte-
grated network, defining telecommunications services in a consistent manner,
and coordinating CTNE, RTVE (broadcast transmissions), and DGTyT (tele-
graph, telex). But the proposed expansion of governmental influence was crit-
icized by large users as running counter to the trend of reducing the state's role
in telecommunications.
In 1986, three narrower bills were substituted for the more comprehensive
effort, providing for the reorganization of telecommunications, private tele-
vision, and the postal service. The telecommunications bill provided for keep-
ing CTNE's monopoly as a telephone carrier intact and for the liberalization of
the terminal equipment and VAN markets as well as for the transfer of respon-
sibility for equipment approval from the telephone authority to the Ministry of
Industry (White, 1986). The liberalization, intended to proceed gradually from
1988 to 1992, began with three corporations requesting Ministry of Industry
approval. Under this plan, Telefonica's carrier monopoly was extended for an-
other thirty years.
Services
The penetration of telephone service in Spain has lagged behind that in other
European countries. In 1990, there were 30.4 telephone lines per 100 people
(ITU, 1990). In the same year, however, applications for basic service in-
creased 51 percent over the previous year, and the growth of usage of existing
lines increased 5 percent. The wait for a new telephone connection was typi-
cally still over half a year, although this figure varied, depending on the region.
In metropolitan areas service was faster, but in rural areas there were longer
waits and greater costs of connection.
254 Spain
ica could not own part of both CTC and ENTEL, Chile's long-distance carrier,
in which it also held a 20 percent stake. Telefonica appealed the decision to
Chile's Comision Resolutiva.
Telefonica was also a bidder for a part of Mexico's telephone system; it also
purchased a stake in the U.S. firm Infonet (5 percent), along with other Euro-
pean telecommunications organizations, as well as in Geostar (3 percent) and
in Mercury's PCN subsidiary (10 percent). It also gained a 40 percent share in
1991 in Venezuela's privatized system, in a consortium led by GTE.
Equipment
Telefonica has a direct stake in determining which firms are allowed access to
the equipment market, since it owns a majority of the stock of a dozen equip-
ment firms and holds minority interests in several others. Telefonica controlled
21 percent of Alcatel Standard Electrica; 20 percent of Citesa, another Alcatel
subsidiary; 10 percent of Telettra, the Spanish subsidiary of the Italian telecom-
munications manufacturer of the same name, then owned by Fiat; and 7.6 per-
cent of Amper, a Spanish telephone set manufacturer (Telefonica, 1989). Thus,
until the 1986 reform giving equipment approval power to the Ministry of In-
dustry, the manufacturer not only had to meet both CCITT and CTNE technical
standards, but also often needed to cultivate a good relationship with Telefon-
ica, their own competitor, including the disclosure of information, in order to
secure approval for the sale of their products.
In the past, CTNE gave clearance only to its own or to Spanish-made equip-
ment. In 1981, foreign suppliers provided only 13 percent of the company's
equipment (MarTech, 1983). However, the 1987 regulatory statute ley de or-
denacion de las telecomunicaciones (LOT) partially opened CPE markets. But
it was challenged by the European Commission since it still enabled control
over terminal equipment by the vertically integrated Telefonica. Telefonica's
practices were also subject to two 1990 investigations, one by the Spanish anti-
monopolies board over bundling of connection to the network with purchase of
more expensive equipment, and one by the Spanish consumer's advocate over
a tariff structure that decreased the advantage of off-peak rates.
The Socialist government that came to power in 1982 increased Telefonica's
importance in the equipment field by giving it a central role in its ambitious
high-technology plans. Telefonica, RTVE, and the Ministry of Defense were
each required to establish four-year plans of investment and development. When
Standard Electric threatened to eliminate 6000 manufacturing jobs in 1985, the
government pressured Telefonica to increase its purchases of that company's
equipment.
In 1991, Telettra was acquired by France's Alcatel. This lead the European
Commission to require that Telefonica divest itself of its shares in Alcatel and
Telettra, as well as to open its purchasing policy.
Luis Solana, Telefonica's president until 1988, actively sought to spur the
256 Spain
Telecommunications in Gibraltar
In Gibraltar, the British possession at the tip of Spain, telephone service first
operated in 1892 for civilian service, with a parallel military system. In 1926,
the city council established an automatic Strowger exchange service. In 1969,
the operation of the telephone service was taken over by the government of
Gibraltar, and in 1973 a crossbar exchange was opened.
International service was opened to Spain in 1927. This service was broken
off in 1969 for several years because of the dispute over control of Gibraltar.
Spain 257
258
Portugal 259
1978 to 1987, the investment per line rate was the third lowest among OECD
nations. However, 1988 figures show a significant shift in priorities, placing
Portugal first in the European Community in terms of telecommunications in-
vestment as a percentage of fixed capital formation (ITU, 1990).
In addition, the separation of the telecommunications and postal authorities
and the merger of the three telephone service companies became topics of dis-
cussion. Telecom Portugal and TLP agreed in principle to a statute that pro-
vided for their merger; they share administrative and fiscal counsel, as well as
the same chairman as part of the General Board. Legislation passed in 1989
brought Portugal more in line with E.G. directives, (de la Cal, 1990, p. 13).
The law also created a Communications Institute of Portugal to coordinate de-
velopment and liberalization.
To increase capital resources and to prepare for the single European market
in 1992, the center-right government which came to power in 1987 announced
a process of "partial privatization" to begin after 1990. The government would
keep 51 percent of the three companies, with the remaining shares sold to
private investors. Foreign holdings were limited to 10 percent, and 20 percent
are owned by small investors and employees.
A 1990 law created a holding company for the telecommunications opera-
tors, named Telecom Portugal. The state retained control over 51 percent of
TLP. The law also created the Institute das Communicacoes de Portugal to
coordinate development and liberalization; regulatory powers remained with the
Ministry of Communications.
Services
Telephone density in Portugal stood at eighteen lines per 100 persons in 1988,
the lowest in Western Europe. The government's goal is to have 32 connections
per 100 population by 1993. In 1988, the average wait for a telephone was 9.4
months, down from almost three years. The waiting list was still 15 percent of
the total of main lines (ITU, 1990).
Data transmission service is available on analog leased lines over the public
switched telephone network at rates of up to 2.4 kbps. Portugal restricted the
creation of private networks based on the use of leased circuits, and customers
were consequently not allowed to install their own data multiplexers (Eurodata
Foundation Yearbook, 1983). This provision was lifted in 1986. Telpac, a packet-
switched network featuring Northern Telecom equipment, was opened in 1984
under the control of Transdata, an organization set up by CTT and TLP. The
expansion of data usage was curtailed by the limitations of the Portuguese net-
work. A 1990 survey by the European Association of Information Services
(EUSIDIC) found that 64 percent of international data test calls made in 1990
from Portugal failed at three times the average rate for the fourteen countries
studied, which were themselves low in performance (EUSIDIC, 1990).
Portuguese international rates are high; calls placed from Portugal to other
260 Portugal
European nations tend to cost twice as much as calls traveling in the opposite
direction (Transnational Data and Communications Report, 1988).
Given the priority of developing basic services, Portugal has been slower
than other European countries to introduce cellular mobile telephony, teletext,
and videotex. In 1984, public telefax service was introduced through the post
office. In 1987, Portugal selected Germany's C-Netz standard for cellular radio
and contracted Siemens to supply the infrastructure (Purton, 1987). By 1990,
cellular phone service was available to 90 percent of Portugal's population in
30 percent of the country, but subscription levels were low.
Equipment
The two local operating organizations held a monopoly over the first telephone
sets. Since 1983, it has been legal to obtain second sets from other sources.
There is no government monopoly over the PBX or modem market, although
they are also supplied by operating companies.
There are two main telecommunications manufacturers in Portugal: Standard
Electrica, a subsidiary of ITT and subsequently of Alcatel, which has had a
presence in the country since 1932, and Centrel, a wholly Portuguese company
(ITT, 1983). Centrel goes back to the British Plessey, at one time the second
leading telecommunications equipment supplier in Portugal, which left the country
in 1979 and sold its Portuguese factory for 1 to the then unknown local firm,
Centrel.
Standard Electrica is the country's largest communications equipment and
electronics manufacturer. According to its own estimates, the company has
trained about 60 percent of Portugal's telecommunications engineers, a fact that
reflects the extremely close relationship that it maintains with the operating
companies. Standard Electrica supplies 50 percent of Portugal's telecommuni-
cations equipment, producing two crossbar exchange switches (one of which is
Portuguese developed) as well as System 12 switches. It also provides PBXs
(holding a 90 percent market share), telephone sets, television sets (60 percent
of all black-and-white sets sold in the country), and transmission equipment.
Its share of Portuguese telex switch sales rose to 35 percent after Siemens's
thirty-year hold over supply was ended.
Products by Centrel, the other manufacturer, include systems, repeaters, public
switches of the crossbar and Strowger types, handsets, coin box telephones,
and transmission equipment. Centrel's public switch division, using Siemens
technology, accounted for more than half of the company's total revenue. Al-
though the bulk of the firm's output is purchased within Portugal, it also ex-
ports.
The allocation of the larger Portuguese procurement orders for central elec-
tronic switches was a multiyear story of intrigue on many levels. Throughout
much of the organization's history, the traditional Portuguese supplier to CTT/
TLP had been ITT's Standard Electrica. In March of 1985, however, a coali-
tion government opened up the switch contract bidding to seven different com-
Portugal 261
262
Israel 263
dependence was one reason that the telephone organization wanted to reduce
direct governmental operational supervision. Another factor was that many of
the telephone administration employees sought to extricate themselves from
civil service salaries, particularly when they had technical skills and prestigious
engineering degrees. Telecommunications were also subsidizing postal ser-
vices, a bottomless pit since postal rates were kept low for political reasons.
In the 1960s, the Dinstein Committee was formed to examine the status of
public utilities. It recommended splitting these operations from government
control, but nothing came of it. In 1970-1972, the Herzog Commission (chaired
by the future president of the state, Chaim Herzog) was appointed by the min-
ister of communications (and later Prime Minister) Shimon Peres, to report on
the status of telecommunications.
In 1978, under a newly created right-of-center government, an expert con-
sulting body was created that consisted primarily of academics from the fields
of business administration, economics, law, and engineering. Their task was to
prepare a concrete proposal to transfer the governmental function to a new
company. The proposal was completed in 1979, with Yitzhak Modai, the then
minister of telecommunications providing strong support. The Bezeq law was
prepared and passed by the Knesset in 1982. A prime bone of contention was
the status of employees. Without union agreement the plan was politically in-
feasible. In 1982 and 1983, intensive negotiations took place. The labor unions
did not actively oppose the reform, once they received a virtual veto right over
certain aspects of the organization and had them written into the law. Within
the Labor party, Gad Yaacobi, a future minister of communications, was also
supportive. The strongest opposition came from the bureaucracy, particularly
the Ministry of Finance, which feared the loss of substantial revenue contribu-
tions from the telephone service. This reflected the main problem of the past:
the perception of telecommunications as a cash cow rather than as a public
service or infrastructure.
Two collective bargaining agreements preserved the various rights and se-
niorities that telecommunication employees had accumulated. Another agree-
ment with the government settled the transfer of the assets and service obliga-
tions. On January 31, 1984, the reorganization became effective, including the
transfer of 8000 employees from government service to company service. The
government changed from a service provider to a service receiver, and the
Communications Ministry was transformed from an operating department to a
policymaking, regulatory, and supervisory department.
The reorganization of the telephone system was undertaken under Minister
of Telecommunications Mordechai Zippori. After the elections of 1984, Pro-
fessor Amnon Rubinstein, a prominent reformist member of parliament, be-
came minister and established early agency direction for policy planning, reg-
ulation, development, licensing, spectrum management, and equipment approval.
The Ministry of Communications regulates Bezeq's tariffs by approving rate
increases and general changes in rate structure, in consultation with the finance
minister and the economic committee of the Knesset. Rubinstein considered the
264 Israel
work connects to similar networks in other countries, but at a higher usage cost
than similar networks. Also, the initial cost of connection is high. The high-
speed data network SIFRANET, designed to serve large users, began service
in 1988, with the government signing on as the first customer. Demand for
data services consistently outpaced supply. One study found that the 16 to 18
percent annual growth rate for leased data circuits would not keep pace with
the 45 percent annual growth for VANS (Bainerman, 1989). A government-
appointed panel, the Fogel Commission, recommended that rates be reduced.
This was done in 1990, as part of a tariff rebalancing.
Bezeq also provides radio paging, alarm systems, and, in a joint venture
with Motorola and Tadiran, cellular telephone service, where it holds 35 per-
cent of the market. Competitors in paging services are Iturit, Page-call, and
Beeper.
By law, Bezeq is the only company to receive a "general permit" for tele-
communications services, although there are no restrictions on the minister's
granting special licenses to others for particular services. A wide-ranging li-
cense was granted to the Postal Authority in 1990. Other organizations provide
telex service, data transmission, and remote data processing. The leading com-
pany is Aurec, which supplies electronic mail services as a node of Dialcom in
addition to other value-added services in partnership with Bezeq. Other com-
panies provide wireless communications and wireless telex or licenses in the
international field (Israel Statutes, 1982). The license fee is 11 percent of rev-
enues.
Rival international telex service is provided by the Postal Authority, Ram
Telex, and Cosmic Telex, all of which use Bezeq's telephone and data trans-
mission lines to capture a combined market share of about 25 percent. Bezeq
competes with these firms, subject to its own tariffs. The large labor union-
controlled industrial group Koor owns a domestic value-added network under
the name of Koornet, offering telefax, telex, and data transmission services.
Koornet also competes with Aurec and Kav Manche in electronic data inter-
change (EDI) and VANS. Two popular services are telefax and BITNET, a
heavily used standard mode of communications both domestically and internation-
ally. Israel participates in three Mediterranean submarine cables: Tel Aviv--
Marseilles, which has operated since 1968; also Tel Aviv-Rome-Marseilles,
in operation since 1975; and the Eastern Mediterranean Fiber Optic Cable Sys-
tem, in operation since 1990.
In 1986-1987, Bezeq's contribution to the government was $169 million,
out of a total revenue of $738 million for royalties, interest, and taxes. In the
same year, Bezeq's rate of return was only 2.5 percent because of a general
governmental price freeze in 1985 (S. Hai, 1988, communication). This made
even a partial privatization unattractive to potential investors. In 1988, the Min-
istry of Communications approved a tariff increase of 8 percent. That year
Bezeq's revenues grew to $932 million, but it returned only $6.5 million in
profits (ITU, 1990). Bezeq was also required to transfer $190 million to the
government. In 1990, proposals to privatize Bezeq and sell 20 percent of the
company to a foreign owner were made. Fifteen percent of Bezeq's stock
266 Israel
was offered to the general public. A ceiling of 25 percent was set, but soon
raised, with an anticipated additional nine percent going to foreign shareholders
and fourteen percent to strategic investors. A government commission also rec-
ommended partial opening to competition.
The major manufacturer of telecommunications equipment in Israel is Tel-
rad, wholly owned by Israel's largest industrial group, Koor Industries, which
is in turn owned by the Histadrut labor union federation. Telrad was established
in 1951 and became a major developer of the civilian and defense communica-
tions network. By 1990, the company had installed more than 165,000 civilian
telephone lines per year and had supplied more than 750,000 lines of electronic
digital equipment for public systems. Telrad also supplies secure communica-
tion systems to the Israel Defense Forces (R. Sitter, 1990, communication).
Telrad's products include electronic switches, key telephones, terminal
equipment, modems, transmission equipment multiplexers, and PBXs. Of the
telephone handsets in the country, more than 90 percent are manufactured by
Telrad. In 1990, the company employed 1200 people and sales totaled $150
million, about a fifth of which were from exports.
Another Israeli telecommunications producer is Tadiran, which has a broad-
based product line and is one of the world's leading manufacturers of lithium
batteries. Tadiran has 12,000 employees and is owned by the labor unions'
Koor. Like Telrad, Tadiran and its subsidiary Tadiran Elisra supply systems
and equipment to both defense and commercial markets. Among its products
are tactical radios and data terminals, communication devices and radio tele-
phones. Tadiran also manufactures and installs public telephone exchanges (Al-
catel's System 12) and PBXs. Among industrial firms, Tadiran has Israel's
largest research and development effort.
Elron Electronics, a large electronics concern, owns several subsidiaries, among
them Elbit Computers, Elscint (for computer-based diagnostics), and Fibronics
(for fiber-optic systems). Other Israeli telecommunications firms are ECI Tele-
com, Electric Cable, Zion Cables, and Paliadent. Because of the rapid growth
of demand for data services, numerous small firms arose to challenge the "Big
Three" Telrad, Tadiran, and ECI. These firmsAdacom, Rad Data, Bitcom,
Efrat Future Technologies, Keren, Teledata, IAI, Fiobronics, Cvalim, Motor-
olahave filled niche markets, often teaming up with American firms.
In 1990, Raphael Pinhasi of the ultra-religious Shas party became commu-
nications minister, leading to a replacement in Bezeq's leadership. Chairman
Yoram Alster was succeeded by Akiva Atoun, a founder of Ofek Computers
and Software Research and Development. Atoun's father was a member of the
Council of Torah Sages, which oversees the Shas party, and this raised ques-
tions over the minister's ability to exercise regulatory functions over Bezeq.
In 1991, the so-called Boaz Committee recommended further liberalization
in equipment approval, international telephony, data communications, VANs,
and mobile service.
25
Turkey
Telephone service began in Turkey in 1881 with lines connecting various post
offices, government buildings, and banking branches. In 1909, a more com-
plete network was created in Istanbul. In 1913, three government exchanges
were established, followed by an exchange operated by a foreign company.
International telephony was established during World War I, with service to
Germany, Turkey's ally. After the war, international service was interrupted
until 1931, when service to Sofia, Bulgaria, was reopened.
In 1926, the first automatic exchange was opened by the state in Ankara. In
Istanbul, foreign companies played an increasingly important role. In 1935 and
1937, however, the state acquired the private exchanges in Istanbul and Ismir.
In the 1940s, new exchanges used equipment made by Ericsson and the LMT
Company.
The initial development of telecommunications was part of the modernization
of Turkey after World War II. However, the pace of development was mark-
edly slow. In 1954, Ericsson was contracted for switches to serve thirty cities,
but it was not until the mid-1960s that telecommunications again became a
priority. Fully automatic domestic telephone service was finally established in
1976, followed by similar international service in 1979.
The Turkish PTT holds a monopoly control over telecommunications and is
supervised by the Ministry of Transportation and Communications. In the mid-
1980s, the government considered a separation of telecommunications from
postal services and the privatization of telecommunications services.
In 1982, the average waiting time for a telephone was seven years (OECD,
1982)! More than 70 percent of villages had no telephones. In 1983, the PTT
announced its plans to give high priority to an expansion of service to all parts
of the country and to an increase in penetration. At the time, telephone line
density was only 3.5 per 100 population (Altay, 1987). The goals of the plan
included the elimination of the waiting list for telephone service by the end of
1995, modernization, and new services.
From 1985 to 1988, investment quadrupled to more than $365 million an-
nually (ITU, 1990). Financing was accomplished through the PTT's own sources
and through domestic and international borrowing. By 1986, the PTT had
achieved a number of improvements. The number of subscribers to telephone
service increased by 67 percent, and the ratio of the number of demands for
telephone service to the number of subscribers had fallen from a huge 1.09 in
267
268 Turkey
1985 to a still considerable 0.27 in 1988. Penetration went from 4.3 phones
per 100 population in 1985 to 12.2 in 1989. The waiting list dropped from 2.1
million to 1.3 million in 1988, but it increased again to 1.9 million in 1990
(ITU, 1990; General Directorate of the PTT, 1990). The percentage of villages
without telephones decreased in a few years from 72 percent to 28 percent in
1989. Although the wait for service had dropped to two to three days in Istan-
bul and Ankara by 1990, in more remote areas the wait was still two to three
months (Anik, 1990). But there was no longer a waiting list for telex service.
In 1990, Turkey had a total of 7 million phones.
After 1984, the PTT also introduced new services. These include digital
exchanges, fiber-optic cables, digital radio relay, multiaccess radio relay in
rural areas, paging, dial-up modems, telecard payphones, cellular and cord-
less telephones, teletext, and public telefax. The circuit-switched DATEX-1
data network and the packet-switched data service Turkpak were also intro-
duced.
The government embarked in particular upon an ambitious plan to improve
the infrastructure of Istanbul, a city of 6 million inhabitants that experienced
especially rapid growth during the 1980s. Istanbul was attempting to position
itself as an international business center linking the Middle East and Europe,
but it woefully lacked advanced telecommunications. In 1986, booking over-
seas calls sometimes required several attempts. In 1988, the country's two in-
ternational gateway switches were replaced with DMS 300 digital exchanges in
Istanbul and Ankara. Turkey's first communications satellite was scheduled for
launch in 1993.
After 1988, telephone sets, telefax machines, and mobile telephones were
available from private sources, as well as from the PTT. Equipment not sup-
plied by the PTT is subject to its approval. For terminal equipment, Turkish-
made equipment that meets established standards is generally used. Procure-
ment by the PTT is in principle by public tender, but with the major loophole
that tenders need not be undertaken where the equipment is produced by com-
panies in which the PTT holds an interest.
In 1967, the PTT embarked on a course to upgrade Turkish equipment man-
ufacturing: to design and construct transmission equipment, partly under license
from the Belgian ITT subsidiary BTM. It established the firm Netas in collab-
oration with Northern Telecom for the production of crossbar exchanges. It also
decided to spin off its Aria research laboratories, which had become quite large,
into the new firm Teletas, a joint venture with Alcatel-BTM, and expanded it
to serve as a second source for digital switches with its System 12. In 1987,
Siemens became Turkey's third digital switch supplier with 100,000 digital
EWSD lines, and it has since added 300,000 more. Yugoslavia's Iskra was
brought in to provide small rural switches.
Though the PTT privatized Netas and Teletas, it maintains a strong influence
through its research labs. Netas also manufactures telephone sets and the lo-
cally developed rural switch ELIF, as well as PBX equipment. Teletas also
manufactures transmission equipment, teleprinters, and telephone sets, and the
Turkey 269
firm TTE produces rural switches. According to the PTT, about 85 percent of
network equipment is produced in Turkey (Raggett, 1986). Supported by this
high level of domestic PTT procurement, Netas and Teletas also sought export
markets in northern Africa and the Middle East, and in 1991 Netas won a
contract in the Soviet Republic of Azerbaijan.
26
Greece
270
Greece 271
per line was Western Europe's lowest by far, a paltry $21.71, compared with
the OECD average of $572.13 (OECD, 1990).
In 1984, telephone density in some districts was only seven to fifteen per
100 (OTE, 1985). The telephone failure frequency per 100 inhabitants was
57.5. About one-half of switches were still of the rotary type, with the rest
being crossbar and other varieties. In 1983, the time required to satisfy the last
application for main connection was 4.04 years. The mean waiting time to
establish an operator-assisted international call was sixteen minutes in the main
cities and in Athens (OTE, 1985, p. 30).
In 1985, the waiting list for main connections was over 970,000, about a
third of total main lines (3 million, half of which were in the greater Athens
region). By 1988, telephone density had grown to approximately thirty-six per
100 and there were about 3.6 million main lines. The wait for a private tele-
phone installation was typically three to five years, and the waiting list had
grown to 1.05 million requests (ITU, 1990). Even the highest-priority orders,
those for hospital and business users, required at least several months and as
much as one year to fill. Digital exchanges began to be introduced in 1986 and
1987, but in 1990, OTE was unable to supply digital lines to private VAN
operators (Schenker, 1990, p. C5).
Equipment used by OTE is supplied primarily by Ericsson and the Greek
subsidiaries of ITT and subsequently Alcatel, Philips, and Siemens. OTE pro-
vides Siemens PBX equipment, but users are free to order from other vendors.
Telephone handsets, however, are supplied and maintained by the PTT. OTE's
approval policy for private terminal equipment is relatively liberal, but the sub-
mission of a detailed technical description in Greek is required, and the proce-
dure usually necessitates a representative in Greece. Modems for leased circuits
are privately supplied, although OTE will install them. Telefax equipment is
also available from private suppliers, but attachment requires OTE permission.
Telex equipment can be obtained from either the OTE or private firms and must
have both Latin and Greek characters.
Relatively little data transmission takes place over the public switched net-
work because of its poor quality. Though rates of more than 1200 band are
available, error rates are relatively high. As a result, only 5 percent of all Greek
modems were connected to the PSTN in 1985. OTE regulations specified that
each leased line may be used to transmit only one form of information. For
example, despite the backlog in request for lines, a line could not be used for
both voice and data. In 1987, the public-packet switched data network Hellas-
pac began operation, with transmission rates of up to 40 kbps. Its largest cus-
tomer in 1980 was the on-line documentation center of the Greek Ministry of
Industry, Trade, and Research.
In 1984, OTE decided to replace 400,000 telephone sets. It rejected several
international supply offers and instead chose an offer from a joint venture of
Eommex and the Greek firms Intracom, Elinda, Azinko, and Hourdakis. Eorn-
rnex is an organization of small and medium-sized businesses headed, in 1984,
by Vaso Papandreou, no relation to then Prime Minister Andreas Papandreou,
but a close associate of his. Eventually, Intracom handled most of the order.
272 Greece
The primary argument for using the Greek suppliers was the promise of sub-
stantial domestic manufacturing. It soon was charged, however, that most parts
were imported from abroad and merely assembled in Greece. An outside inves-
tigation revealed a 47 percent Greek value added instead of the guaranteed 73
percent.
At that time, OTE was also embroiled in charges of improprieties involving
its new headquarters building. Construction of the building proceeded at a very
slow pace for ten years, and the building stood empty for a number of years
thereafter.
In the early 1980s OTE decided to introduce digital technology into its net-
work and exchanges. A 1988 agreement with Greek assembly chose Ericsson's
AXE and Siemens's EWSD switches among four bidders. Northern Telecom
supplied crossbar equipment. A special committee headed by a high-ranking
official of the Industrial Development Bank was established to negotiate their
purchase. The negotiating team included two economists, two university-based
technologists, and the deputy managing director of the OTE. This structure,
over which OTE did not predominate, led to constant clashes with the manag-
ing director of OTE, Theofanis Tombras, who was accused of continuous in-
> Tvention in the negotiations.
Influential in OTE personnel matters is the FIT union, which plays an un-
official but important role in managerial appointments. It is about one-third
conservative, one-third socialist, and one-third communist.
In 1987, the minister of transport and communications expressed pessimism
about the future of OTE: "OTE desperately tries to identify capital sources to
satisfy over one million pending petitions for new service . . . but the required
amount is presently a dream." And he pledged to "bring order to OTE's chaos."
Shortly thereafter, the minister was removed. The real power in Greek telecom-
munications was OTE's director general Tombras, who was appointed by Prime
Minister Papandreou in 1981. Tombras had been a military officer who was
part of a leftist army group; he was accused of a plot, went into exile, returned,
and was close to the prime minister. In that position, he was useful to the
government. Tombras bragged to the press about wiretapping opposition lead-
ers by a special department of OTE. He also cut communication links to broad-
cast stations of the opposition during the election campaign.
Telephone investments were made based on political considerations (where
loyal voters were), and it was alleged that to receive priority on the waiting
line required political patronage.
As the government's point man, Tombras became well known in Greece,
and the opposition announced its intention to bring him to trial if it were to
win the election.
The elections were held under a cloud of scandal in government, when a
former Crete banker confessed to massive improprieties in the handling of state-
owned organizations' funds, which benefited government officials and the rul-
ing Pasok party. After several inconclusive elections, the conservatives came
to power in 1990.
Not surprisingly, this climate was not conducive to the development of tele-
Greece 273
Cyprus
Introduction
274
Telecommunications in Eastern Europe 273
Hungary
Despite its relatively high per capita income, Hungary has one of the least
developed telecommunications networks among East European countries (EESTR,
1990a). At the same time, Hungary earned a reputation as a leader: It was the
first Eastern Bloc country to invest in Western digital switching technology,
first to introduce cellular service, and first to apply for membership in the Con-
ference of European Postal and Telecommunications Administrations (CEPT),
the organization of (West) European PTTs.
Hungary's first telephone exchange was installed in 1881. Development slowed
during and after World War II, when priorities shifted toward economic cen-
tralization and the military. Existing facilities deteriorated for lack of invest-
ment funds; annual growth in telephones from 1967 to 1987 was 4.3 percent,
the lowest among countries of similar economic development (Datapro, 1990).
Demand for telephone lines grew with the economic reforms of 1968, when
economic planners allowed greater horizontal relations between companies. In
1983 the PTT Magyar Posta was turned into an organization separate from the
Ministry of Transport, Communications and Construction. In 1989, Magyar
Posta was split into three bodies, for telecommunications, broadcasting, and
traditional postal service. In anticipation of a privatization, the telecommuni-
cations group was renamed the Hungarian Telecommunications Company
(HTC). The Telecommunications Act was revised in 1989 to allow limited
private investments in Hungarian service providers (EESTR, 1990a). Shares of
HTC were offered to Hungarian firms in 1990 and to foreign investors in 1991,
with total foreign ownership limited to 25 percent. HTC's investments were still
directed by the Ministry for Transport, and rates are approved by the State
Price Control Office. Further legislation proposed competition in value-added
services and the establishment of private local telephone companies, leaving
the PTT with a monopoly over long-distance services.
In 1984 Magyar Posta announced plans for fully automatic switching by
276 Telecommunications in Eastern Europe
had awarded a cellular license to the American firm Contel, but the new one
switched the franchise to US West and HTC.
Poland
The Polish public telecommunications system suffers from forty years of ne-
glect on top of a devastating war. It was not a priority to allow citizens access
to a well-developed communications network, and there was consequently little
investment or R&D in telecommunications. As a result, the system suffered
from inadequate technology and bottlenecks at every level. With political and
economic reform, Poland's financial limitations led to an approach toward in-
stitutional reform that went further than that of Hungary, embracing full de-
monopolization of the PTT and allowing foreign interests to compete directly
with it.
Communications in Poland dates back to 1558, when King Sigismund Au-
gustus established the Polish mail between Cracow and Venice. The Polish Post
Office, Telegraph and Telephones (PPTT) was formed between the two world
wars and built a telecommunications network with foreign financial assistance.
The system was greatly damaged in World War II. By 1944, the Soviet Union,
Britain, Sweden, and the United States were supporting efforts to rebuild it.
The number of telephones more than doubled between 1960 and 1972, reach-
ing a penetration of 3.62 per 100 (Poland: A Handbook, 1974). In 1990, there
were 3.28 million subscribers, or 8.3 phones per 100 people. The average wait
for service was thirteen years, and delays as long as thirty-three years were
reported. The 2.2 million people waiting for a phone may be only a portion of
those actually interested in telephone service. Poland's network employs local
exchanges dating from the 1930s and the 1960s. Fifteen percent of switches
are over thirty years old, and the 1990 call completion rate was only 30 percent
(EESTR, 1990b).
The PPTT was removed from the control of the Ministry of Communications
in 1987, after the ministry was merged into the Ministry of Transport and
Shipping, which gained control over rates and technical policies. In 1990 a
new ministry was created to oversee the PPTT, the Ministry for Posts, Broad-
casting and Telecommunications.
The PPTT operates the national network and ran postal and broadcast ser-
vices (Datapro, 1990). The PPTT is financially self-sufficient but must contrib-
ute 40 percent of its income to the government and is obligated to subsidize
the post office. In 1991, postal, broadcast, and telecommunications services
were separated into individual operating units as a step toward privatization.
Telecommunications were provided by Telekomunikacja Polska SA. Long dis-
tance services were also separated from local ones, which were to be offered
by independent regional companies, potentially private and with minority for-
eign participation.
The 1991 Telecommunications Act permitted competition with the TPSA in
many services, such as local, cellular, and domestic long-distance. Regulation
278 Telecommunications in Eastern Europe
was by the Ministry and its subagencies PIT and PAR. The government's re-
form plans were ambitious. TPSA was to be privatized in the future, and per-
haps divided into a national long-distance organization and several regional
companies. Foreign applicants could not own a majority of shares, except for
local service companies.
The post-reform Polish government made upgrading the telecommunications
system one of its two economic development priorities and targeted Warsaw
and the Silesia region. PPTT goals were to quadruple telephone penetration by
2000, setting a goal of 10-12 million subscribers by that time. In addition, the
PPTT estimated that as much as 60 percent of the embedded network will also
have to be replaced or significantly improved. The PPTT sought to upgrade
international capacity and to modernize the network through AT&T. To im-
prove the domestic network the PPTT bought eight transit exchanges from
Alcatel-Spain on generous terms arranged for by the Spanish government.
In 1990, the PPTT installed Kommertel, a separate overlay business network
in Warsaw. Installation fees and line charges were five times the normal, but
interconnection was immediate. Poland had Eastern Europe's highest telex ser-
vice penetration. Satellite services were offered through Intersputnik. Poland
joined Eutelsat in 1990.
Before the reforms of the late 1980s, manufacturing had been handled by
United Telekom (UT), a state monopoly with 20,000 employees. In 1989, UT
was split into three separate entities that are to compete with one another: ZWUT,
Teletra, and the Polish Transmission Works. The three firms were expected to
produce 1.8 million lines; of those, the PPTT orders came to 1 million lines
per year, and the remainder was aimed for export (Datapro, 1990).
The country was open to joint ventures with Western equipment providers.
Domestic manufacture was directed by the Ministry of Industry in partnerships
with Western firms. ZWUT produces the EWSD switch with Siemens, and
Alcatel produces its E10 and System 12 switches with Telettra and the Polish
Transmission Works (PZT). In 1990 Siemens bought a 49 percent stake of
ZWUT for DM 50 million. Ericsson was involved with Telecom Telfa. AT&T,
Italtel, and Samsung were also active. Customer premises equipment was lib-
eralized subject to type approvals of the PPTT's Institute of Telecommunica-
tions.
Twenty-five companies offered bids for cellular overlay networks. Sweden's
Televerket, Finland's P&T, and British Telecom formed the Baltic Mobile
Telephone System (BMTS) consortium, which bid to expand the NMT 450
cellular system now operating in the Scandinavian countries to the Baltic-rim
countries, including Poland. A franchise was won by a consortium of Ameri-
tech and France Telecom.
Czecho-Slovakia
Czecho-Slovakia's telecommunications network is controlled by the Federal
Ministry of Posts and Telecommunications (PTT), which was separated from
the Ministry of Transport in 1990. All equipment is produced under the super-
Telecommunications in Eastern Europe 279
YugoslaviaCroatiaSlovenia
The Yugoslav postal and telephone system was highly decentralized, with six
republic PTTs under a weak federal administration. Although each of these
individual organizations ostensibly determined the prices for its services, the
government oversaw rates and manages revenues and expenses within the state
budget (Lakicevic, 1970).
The number of telephones and automatic exchanges doubled from 1939 to
1950 (Byrnes, 1957), but growth was slow until the mid-1970s. Since 1979,
280 Telecommunications in Eastern Europe
Bulgaria
Romania
Romania's telephone network has been operated with some rotary switch equip-
ment since 1933. The equipment in the network's central offices is estimated
to be thirty years old on average (U.S. Department of State, 1990). Following
the overthrow of President Ceaucescu, however, the new government moved
to significantly upgrade all its basic services and to establish some value-added
services. It also separated the Ministry of Post and Telecommunications from
the Ministry of Transportation. As in most Eastern Bloc nations, telecommu-
nications heavily subsidizes the postal service.
Romania's first automatic telephone exchange, a rotary switch built by ITT,
began operation in 1927 in Bucharest. The network continues to rely on such
rotary equipment, although in 1968 a licensing agreement was signed with ITT's
Belgian BTM that allowed domestic production of more advanced Pen-
taconta automatic switches for local and trunk traffic (Popescu, 1990). In 1990,
Romania contracted Alcatel FACE to provide System 12 switches for Bucha-
rest.
Estimates of Romanian telephone penetration vary from 6.7 to 7.4 main Sines
per 100 in 1990 (Fidler, 1990). The government's own official estimate is ten
lines (including party lines) per 100 persons. Service is unevenly distributed
between urban and rural areas. Penetration in Bucharest runs at thirty lines per
100 persons, with other urban areas averaging fifteen per 100. The rural aver-
age is 2.5 lines, and 3300 villages have yet to receive service (Popescu, 1990).
The number of subscribers tripled from 1965 to 1975, and an aggressive five-
year plan was proposed for 1976-1980 that called for a minimum expansion in
facilities of 30-40 percent to accommodate international traffic, with special
emphasis on data (Avramescou and Celac, 1980). By 1990, 89 percent of tele-
phone subscribers were served by some form of automatic switch, but data
services had not improved. For example, there were only 200 facsimile ma-
chines in the country in 1990.
A backlog of 800,000 orders for telephone service in urban areas alone has
resulted in a ten-year wait for service. The government forecast an additional
2.5 million lines to meet rural needs and has set a goal of 50 percent penetra-
tion in the next fifteen to twenty years. To meet these needs, the aim was
400,000 new lines per year, assisted by a joint venture to manufacture digital
equipment at Romania's Electromagnetic Plant.
The government also planned to upgrade the network by completing the ex-
isting analog trunk network and adding electronic switches, digital microwave
lines, fiber-optic cable, digital multiplexing systems, and a cellular network. In
addition, there were plans to develop a high-speed, packet-switched data trans-
mission network to upgrade the previous ROMPAK network.
In 1990, all international traffic was handled by a single crossbar switch with
a 340-line capacity that had been in place since 1974. To modernize interna-
282 Telecommunications in Eastern Europe
tional access, the PTT purchased a Siemens EWSD digital switch. Siemens
also acquired 49 percent of the manufacturer EMCOM. Romania joined Eutel-
sat and became the first Eastern Bloc country to gain membership in Intelsat in
1990.
For much of this technology, the new Romanian government sought joint
ventures with Western companies, and the PTT indicated that it will privatize
mobile cellular systems, packet switching equipment, and terminal equipment
for value-added services, but not for basic services. Rom Telecom was sepa-
rated from the PTT and assisted by France.
Albania
telephone lines and nine times the number of residential lines. However, the
Soviet Union under Mikhail Gorbachev put telecommunications development
more into the forefront. Whereas 1 million new lines were installed annually
from 1980 to 1985 (already a major increase over the 1970s), twice as many
were added in the second half of the decade, and residential service became a
greater priority. At the same time, the process of disintegration into constituent
republics led to an increasingly decentralized telecommunications system.
Organizational Structure
In the former Soviet Union, telecommunications facilities, services, and man-
ufacturing were state monopolies, long under the Federal Ministry of Posts and
Telecommunications (MPT). The Ministry of Communications, known as
Minsviaz, operated national and international networks and services, as well as
postal services and TV and radio broadcasting. In addition to national Mins-
viaz, each of the fifteen republics had its own Minsviaz, which was subordi-
nated to the national ministry as well as to the government of the respective
republic. (The Russian Minsviaz was created fairly late, its functions having
been undertaken before by the national ministry. Even then, telecommunica-
tions in the city of Moscow were still run by the national ministry.)
The national Minsviaz' responsibility was for overall system coordination
and operation of overarching activities, such as national long-distance service,
communication satellites, and national broadcast services. Minsviaz seemed to
have no oversight responsibility over important intraorganizational networks,
such as those of the defense establishment, the KGB, and the ministry of In-
ternal Affairs (Campbell, 1988).
Subordinated to Minsviaz were several chief administrations, including those
for industrial enterprises (GUPP), science and technology (GNTU), satellite
and radio broadcasting (GKRU), postal services (GUPS), long-distance trans-
mission (GUMTS), telegraphy (GTU), and urban and rural services (GUTS).
The republic ministries were responsible for services in their territory, provided
through regional organizations (PTUS) and production enterprises (RUS). Most
of Minsviaz' 7000 such enterprises had some financial independence, but finan-
cial subsidies and redistribution were also necessary, especially since more than
1000 lost money. Overall development plans were formulated by Minsviaz and
were part of the national five-year plans. But actual investment funds had to be
provided by the republics, regional and local governments, and even industrial
and agricultural users. Thus, network construction was to some extent at the
mercy of the investment priorities and red tape of numerous agencies. With the
increasing independence of the republics, telecommunications became increas-
ingly controlled by the various republics' ministries, and their coordinating
committees' became critical.
Services
The Soviet telecommunications network was organized to serve official and
administrative rather than household needs. Military and industrial communica-
284 Telecommunications in Eastern Europe
tions were especially well developed for utilities departments such as railroads,
pipelines, and power, which have separate networks comprising about 6.5 mil-
lion lines, 40 percent of which are connected to the public network. Frequently,
those systems utilize Minsviaz leased lines. The department networks occupied
20 percent of Soviet exchanges (Campbell, 1988). The 1966-1970 Five Year
Plan (FYP) mandated a Unified Automated System of Telecommunications
(EASS), conceptualized as an integrated network with the capacity to carry
voice, video, and data traffic in anticipation of an ISDN-type facility. How-
ever, little network integration actually took place and common facilities were
used only to a limited extent.
Once telecommunications became more of a priority, penetration increased
from 29.1 million phones in 1980 (of which 23.7 million were connected to
the public network) to 37.2 million in 1985, with 31.1 million connected to
the public network. Of all lines in Russia, 55 percent are residential, compared
with 84 percent in the United States.
In 1985, the central government initiated a program for telecommunications
growth and converted some military communications manufacturing to civilian
production. The twelfth five-year plan, covering 1986 to 1990, sought to add
12.1 million new lines to the system, shift to semielectronic exchanges, and
introduce fiber-optic and digital technology. Telecommunications budgets grew
from 1.2 billion rubles annually in the eleventh five-year plan to 2 billion in
the twelfth. Keeping with the emphasis on residential service, 75 percent of the
new installations were to be residential. As part of the ongoing effort to de-
velop the EASS, 2Mbps and SMbps digital lines were put in some major cities
(Datapro, 1990).
Structurally, the network consisted of a fairly rigid hierarchy of local single
or interlinked exchanges; zonal systems (about 175-200) that were assigned
area code numbers; and a third-level national trunk network with fifteen interre-
gional transit offices linked through Moscow, using foreign equipment such as
the French MT-20. Moscow was also the prime link with the Intersputnik and
Intelsat systems.
Domestic long-distance voice communications are mostly terrestrial. But ex-
tensive satellite facilities are available, as befitting a space power. The Orbita-
Molniia and Raduga satellite systems are used primarily for broadcasting and
play only a limited role in telecommunications. The next generation of satel-
lites, named Mayak, aimed to have high elliptical orbits. Also planned was a
giant 18-ton, 30-meter diameter communications satellite platform for launch
in 1993.
In 1989 there were 40 million telephones or 13 per 100 population inhabi-
tants. But regional disparities in penetration are great; 25 percent of urban
households have phones, compared with 10 percent of rural households. Rela-
tively high penetration (from 30-50 lines per 100 households) was reported for
Moscow, St. Petersburg, Kiev, Armenia, and the Baltic republics, whereas
Siberia and the Central Asian regions have less than one line per 100 homes.
Moscow accounts for 11 percent of all telephones; 20 percent of all residential
subscribers use party lines.
Telecommunications in Eastern Europe 285
Tariffs were set favorably for users. Although handsets and installations were
costly, subscribers paid only 2.5 rubles per month for unlimited local service
(Campbell, 1988), among the least expensive rates in the world. Local mea-
sured billing was introduced experimentally in a number of locations but was
unreliable. Installation costs rose 500 percent, but they were below the actual
cost of 250-500 rubles (Frankl, 1989). Rural service was heavily subsidized;
in 1980 its loss was 74 percent of cost. Partly in response, a 1983 price reform
moved prices closer to cost. All state and collective farms have been connected
to the network. The allocation of telephone service was not by price, but fre-
quently as a privilege for well-connected individuals. The wait in 1989 aver-
aged four years and the waiting list included twelve million households. The
availability of pay phones was limited. Nationally, in 1987, there were only
35,000 pay phones that could reach out of the local exchange (in the United
States, the number was sixty times as high), and one survey found that half of
pay phones were out of service. In 1988, GEC Plessey Telecommunications
(GPT) formed a joint venture called Comstar with Minsviaz to provide and
operate approximately 100 credit card pay phones, principally for use by for-
eigners in airports and hotels (Dixon, 1988a). Comstar failed to show signifi-
cant results after two years.
Two joint ventures with the United States for international data transmission
were also planned. Sovam Teleport, which began operations in 1990, connects
to public data networks and electronic mail service around the world. Sprint
Networks U.S.S.R. was a 1990 joint activity of US Sprint and the Moscow
telephone organization.
In 1985, one-third of all long-distance calls still required operators. Where
operators are necessary, it can often take a very long time to establish a con-
nection. Even for automatic trunks blockage rates are 3 percent or more on
almost one half of the automatic trunks. At the same time, the rigid hierarchy
of network architecture leads to underutilization of many circuits. All interna-
tional calls were routed through one gateway switch in Moscow with 1500 lines
and approximately twenty operators to serve the entire country. In 1989, 11
million international calls were made from the Soviet Union.
The goal for the year 2000to reach 90-100 percent urban penetration and
50 percent in rural areaswill require 60 million lines in the 1990s (i.e., 6
million lines per year as opposed to 2 million in the late 1980s and 1 million
earlier in the decade). To meet these targets, the republics, like other East
European administrations, must increase spending to more than three times their
already accelerated investment rate of the late 1980s (Nulty, 1990). It was not
clear where the funds would come from. In one effort to develop innovative
financing, Minsviaz formed a commercial bank for deposits from the public
and as a financial clearinghouse for its various operations. Another strategy was
for Minsviaz to retain more of its earnings for reinvestment. Its profits in 1988
totaled 5.3 billion rubles, but it claimed that 75 percent of this was returned to
the central government budget (Campbell, 1990).
The analog network supported data transmission at 9.6 kbps on some dedi-
cated lines (which are very expensive), but the number of users was low be-
286 Telecommunications in Eastern Europe
Equipment
A key reason for the backwardness of the Soviet telephone system was the
country's weakness in the design and production of advanced equipment. And
this had structural reasons. Whereas in the telecommunications industry Mins-
viaz controlled the operations of the network, it had only weak powers when it
came to the guidance of the development and production of the equipment that
in the aggregate constituted the network. Although Minsviaz had some produc-
tion plants under its own control, the equipment area was the province of sev-
eral ministriesMinradioprom (radio equipment), Minelektronprom (electronic
components and transmission systems), Minelektrotekhprom (electrical equip-
ment), and especially Minpromsviaz (Communications)that were part of the
defense industry and were controlled by the military industrial commission,
VPK. Within the Soviet bureaucracy, Minsviaz was no match for the powerful
VPK, which allocated resources to defense and space and away from civilian
electronics uses. The telecommunications equipment ministry did not even have
a civilian branch. In one year, 30 percent of the telegraph equipment received
by Minsviaz from Minpromsviaz was defective. One of the important changes
of the twelfth five-year plan in 1985 was to shift some control over the elec-
tronics to Minsviaz and to civilian goals. To further the separation of military
Telecommunications in Eastern Europe 287
and civilian institutions, the government in 1989 abolished altogether the Min-
istry of the Industry of Communications Equipment (Minpromsviaz, or MPSS).
Most of MPSS's responsibilities for manufacturing and service provision and
12,000 workers were transferred to Minsviaz. But the former MPSS minister,
Erlen Pervyshin, became Minsviaz' new head.
Much of the Soviet telecommunications system relied on outdated equip-
ment, some of which was installed before the 1917 revolution! Soviet authori-
ties acknowledged that copper wire laid by Ericsson in 1907 was still carrying
traffic (Gulyaev, 1990). Most of the switches were analog and electromechan-
ical. Forecasts indicate that local industries cannot produce more than a fraction
of the equipment needed for the ambitious expansion plans (Frankl, 1989).
Since the 1970s, terminal equipment was owned by subscribers. PBXs, al-
though rare, could also be owned by the user. In the past, much of Soviet
switching equipment, handsets, and cables had been imported under a deliber-
ate program of support for East European countries. Over 600,000 handsets
were imported from Bulgaria in 1986, mostly from the Sofia Telecommunica-
tions Plant, and constituted more than half of that country's production. Czech-
oslovakia had also provided 2 million handsets to the Soviet Union by 1976
and several million more since. East Germany (NEK) was a major supplier of
exchanges, and Hungary served the Soviet Union with the some advanced
equipment, under Western license. Poland and Yugoslavia were also equipment
sources, as were a number of Western countries, most notably Finland. The
Finnish firm Nokia supplied exchanges and cables, and France's Thomson CSF
also provided switching equipment. With the abolition of Minpromsviaz, Mins-
viaz wrested control of the main Soviet telecommunications manufacturers from
the military industrial commission VPK. Even before, Minsviaz also controlled
a number of relatively small and undersupported manufacturing plants.3 But
the more significant development efforts were those of the VPK ministries,
which were traditionally shrouded in secrecy. Among these enterprises, of par-
ticular importance is VET in Riga, Latvia, a company originating before the
Soviet annexation. Other major plants are in Peraa, Kaunas, Vilnius, and other
locations (providing a nucleus for electronic industries in the newly indepen-
dent Baltic States). VEF developed the semi-electronic Kvant PBX. Kvant was
plagued by design and production problems. It did not interconnect easily with
the Soviet network. It was used only within bureaucratic administrations' pri-
vate networks and developed outside of Minsviaz' own priorities. It was being
adapted as a rural exchange. After eight years the switch could only handle 62
percent of its designed capacity. The first electronic automatic exchange was
not introduced until 1986, and domestic manufacturers were still producing
step-by-step switches as late as 1988.
Because of the variety of foreign suppliers and the increase in transmission
capacity without modern switching equipment, the Soviet network was poorly
interconnected. Among the major switches used were Alcatel's MT-20 (im-
ported or built under license), the Finnish Nokia's EATS-200, the Czech ATS-
K crossbar, the East German ATS-K, the Yugoslav Metaconta or IOC (licensed
from old ITT technology), and Soviet-made Kvarts and Istok switches. The
288 Telecommunications in Eastern Europe
Reforms
PTT Institutions
From the inception of early postal systems, communications were a highly in-
ternational affair. The checkered map of central Europe usually permitted alter-
native postal routes and thus made intergovernmental agreements desirable. As
postal administrations evolved throughout Europe, they prioritized the mainte-
nance of stable international arrangements as a central policy concern. Rooted
in this tradition, "integration" and "harmonization" achieved importance in
the value system of PTTs beyond purely technical needs. They led to interna-
tional organizations, one of whose important function was to shore up interna-
tionally the domestic arrangements and to anchor national monopolies in an
international cartel arrangement. These international organizations worked very
successfully to coordinate the old order. Not surprisingly, they were not partic-
ularly well-suited to be vehicles for reform. Given their traditional role, as well
as their control by traditional PTTs, change was not initiated by the interna-
tional organizations of telecommunications, but essentially outside and even
despite them. Of course, the international organizations served useful functions
as fora for discussion and as structures to channel change. But the main reform-
ing countries were quite prepared to ignore the restrictiveness of the traditional
international regime if necessary. They also began to activate international or-
ganizations associated with interests other than the PTTs, such as the Organi-
zation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), the European
Community (E.G.), and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT).
293
294 The International Organizations of Telecommunications
The Telegraph Union gave little attention to the coordination of the emerging
telephony. Until 1925, it was not even obligatory for the various telephone
administrations to interconnect with other countries. Eventually, national tele-
phone administrations led by the French FIT created a new body, the Interna-
tional Consultative Committee for Long Distance Telephony, initially outside
of the ITU, to address telephone coordination issues.
Radio communications were also organizationally separate from the ITU;
coordination began in 1903 at a conference convened by Germany. Here too
technical issues coexisted with economic and political ones. Various countries
tried to counter the market power in wireless communication by the Marconi
Wireless Telegraph Company, which had instructed its radio operators to com-
municate only with those using Marconi equipment and to refuse all others.
This was an economic and strategic threat to other countries' emerging wireless
operations, manufacturing, and shipping. Germany had embarked on an ambi-
tious naval build-up in rivalry with Britain, and, given the importance of radio
communications for fleet operations, sought to break Marconi's power. Great
Britain and Italy, both of which had Marconi's interests at heart, consequently
boycotted the 1903 conference. The meeting established a protocol that pro-
vided rules of noninterference and interconnection. Another international con-
vention was passed in 1906, again in Berlin, establishing the framework (still
in existence today) of allocating radio bands to particular services to avoid
intermixing. Frequencies could be used on a first-come basis, but notification
had to be given. In 1912, the Marconi Company agreed to stop refusing com-
munications with rival equipment. World War I put an end to collaborative
arrangements. After the war, a 1920 conference drafted many of the principles
upon which today's ITU operates. The most difficult issues, not surprisingly,
dealt with a mechanism for frequency allocation and allotment; no agreement
was reached. Parallel to these efforts, the emergence of private radio broad-
casting led to a meeting in 1925, convened by the BBC, that created an inter-
national radio conference to deal with problems of interference. Eventually, at
a joint meeting in Madrid in 1932, the International Telegraph Union and the
loose International Radio Telegraph Conference were merged in 1934 and re-
named the International Telecommunication Union.
Initially, the Swiss government staffed, financed, and managed the ITU's
office in Berne. But as the ITU became a specialized diplomatic agency to the
League of Nations (and later part of the United Nations), its secretariat was
moved to Geneva and both its staff and financial support were international-
ized. To induce the United States to join, the new ITU convention was kept
general and flexible. A major meeting was held in Washington in 1927. The
U.S.S.R. was precluded from attendance, because of opposition to its govern-
ment. Thus, the alleged "nonpolitical" history of the ITU and U.S. adherence
to such principles should not be exaggerated.
Until World War II, the United States maintained an attitude of benign ne-
glect toward the ITU and its policies. It did not send government delegates or
observers to the ITU (leaving this to private firms) and did not participate in
the international consultative committees when they were formed in the 1920s.
296 The international Organizations of Telecommunications
It opposed the creation of the unified telecommunication ITU since this ex-
tended the potential for an international cartel (Rutkowski, 1982, p. 33). The
United States participated more actively, but still reluctantly, in the interna-
tional radio telegraph conferences, though it made clear its suspicions that they
served to retard the development of radio. The exceptions in the U.S. attitude
were the periods following the world wars, when it was more closely interested
in creating stable international arrangements. For the United States to sign the
telegraph regulations took until 1949, eighty-four years after the first set had
been approved and only after major changes.
The postwar interest of the United States led to Atlantic City conferences in
S947 that reshaped international communications into structures that have en-
dured until today. At the end of the meeting, the ITU framework was in place.
In 1952, an International Frequency Registration Board (IFRB) was created as
a body for the record-keeping of international frequency use and for dispute
resolution. In subsequent years, membership increased dramatically with de-
colonization.
The ITU's system is complex. It includes four secretariats, a multinational
Administrative Council, Plenipotentiary Conferences, World Administrative Radio
Conferences, World Administrative Telegraph and Telephone Conferences, the
IFRB, Regional Administrative Radio Conferences, Consultative Committees
on Radio (CCIR) and on Telephone and Telegraph (CCITT), and droves of
subcommittees and study groups. The ITU currently performs clearing house
activities, coordinates standards and spectrum allocations, and provides tech-
nical assistance to developing countries. Despite the elaborate structure, or per-
haps because of it, the pace of discussions, particularly in comparison with the
rapid advance of technology, has been torpid for a long time, though there
have been exceptions.
Private sector experts, particularly in the equipment industry, can participate
in the Consultative Committees of the ITU. In the American case, a majority
of committees were attended only by private-sector representatives.
The ITU was run in the 1980s by Richard Butler of Australia. Butler ably
managed an unprecedented expansion of membership and scope of responsibil-
ities and initiated reforms to move the organization from a federal to a more
centralized structure. He was succeeded as secretary general by Pekka Tar-
janne, a former physics professor, leader of Finland's Liberal party, and direc-
tor general of the Finnish PTT. A merger of CCITT and CCIR was proposed
but postponed. An independent Bureau for Telecommunications Development
(BDT) was created with status equal to CCITT and CCIR, subsuming the ex-
isting Center for Telecommunications Development, strengthening recommen-
dations made in 1982 in the so-called Maitland Report, "The Missing Link"
(Butler, 1989). Since assuming his post, Tarjanne has advocated greater re-
gional cooperation and a lessening of state control over telecommunications for
economic and administrative reasons.
A majority of ITU members in the 1980s were against any form of liberali-
zation. In this matter, the European PTTs until recently saw eye to eye with
virtually all developing countries and with the Soviet bloc. Hence, for the lib-
The International Organizations of Telecommunications 297
The CCITT
Of particular importance in the telecommunications field is the Consultative
Committee on International Telegraph and Telephone. The CCITT's predeces-
sor was established at the initiative of Britain and France subsequent to a Paris
meeting in 1923. In its first years it mainly concerned itself with the establish-
ment of desirable characteristics for long-distance international telephone lines.
In 1924, the organization was given the name of International Consultative
Committee on Long-Distance Telephone Communications, and it established a
permanent secretariat in Paris. Later it was renamed CCIT (International Con-
sultative Committee on Telephone), which became in 1956 the CCITT. It was
largely separate from the ITU for almost a quarter century. The organizations,
with the International Consultative Committee on Radio (CCIR), were brought
under the umbrella of the ITU in 1949 subsequent to its 1947 Atlantic City
meeting. The technical committees of the CCIR and the International Broad-
casting Union were united at that time.
The CCITT operates through administrations, operating agencies, non-
common carrier enterprises, and international organizations (A. Rutkowski, 1990,
communication). Working groups include representatives of governments and
private operating firms. After 1927 it also operated a laboratory under the name
of the Telephonometric Laboratory. The CCITT issues only recommendations
and has no enforcement power. It does not function as a treaty organization
with binding resolutions. Though developing countries and new electronics firms
have become more active, developed countries and established manufacturers
still dominate the discussion. Government representatives as well as represen-
298 The International Organizations of Telecommunications
Intelsat
Intelsat is the international organization providing international civilian satellite
communications. By the terms of the Intelsat Agreement entered into by mem-
ber states, it has exclusivity over these services, though this is under dispute.
The international Organizations of Telecommunications 299
Intelsat was formed in 1964 largely at the initiative of the United States, and
is headquartered in Washington, D.C. At the time, the United States was still
firmly in the camp of monopoly; Intelsat is a reflection of the U.S. desire to
embed its own technical lead in satellites and launchers in an international
regime of coordinated monopoly, subject to a weighted voting that benefits
industrialized countries. Intelsat operates through an Assembly of Parties (rep-
resentatives of government members to the agreement), which usually meets
every two years to discuss long-term issues. There are also Signatories' Meet-
ings in which the designated telecommunications entities are represented. A
board of governors, whose members are representatives of the larger users and
regional groups, deals with budget matters, procurement, and policy issues.
Intelsat business itself is conducted by its executive organ, which is headed by
a director general and employs about 600 people.
Intelsat satellites have evolved seven full and two half generations. The first
Intelsat satellite was Early Bird in 1965, with Hughes as the private contractor.
Its capacity could accommodate up to 240 telephone circuits or one TV chan-
nel. Design life was a brief eighteen months, though it operated satisfactorily
twice as long. In 1967 and 1968 the Intelsat II and III generations were launched,
produced by Hughes and TRW. Intelsat III had a capacity of 1500 circuits or
four TV channels. Multipoint communications were possible, and design life-
time was now five years. In 1971, the Intelsat IV generation was put aloft,
produced again by Hughes, and providing 4000 circuits. The satellite antenna
system was much more advanced and permitted spot beams and other features.
In 1975, the Intelsat IV-A satellite generation expanded capacity to 6000 two-
way circuits. Five years later, the first Intelsat V was launched with Ford Aero-
space as the prime contractor. Capacity doubled to 12,000 two-way telephone
circuits and two TV channels. The system was further improved in 1985 with
Intelsat V-A/B to 15,000 circuits and a variety of antennas. Hughes' Intelsat
VI was launched in 1986, with a capacity of 30,000 circuits and three TV
channels, using a variety of polarizations that make multiple usage possible.
The next generation, Intelsat VII, is ready for the 90s. Most of these satellites
are physically quite large. Intelsat VI measures 6.4 meters high and 3.6 meters
wide. These are very heavy pieces of equipment, densely packed with high-
performance electronics, and they are correspondingly expensive.
Critics contend that Intelsat created an overcapacity in order to reduce incen-
tives for others to enter. It also operates on very-low-power systems, which
require an expensive earth station segment that makes usage by smaller parties
other than the national PTT's less desirable. This also makes it expensive for
smaller countries with low traffic density to participate (Cowhey and Aronson,
1985).
Intelsat's director general in the beginning of the 1980s was Richard Colino,
an American lawyer. In 1986, it was discovered that Colino and a close asso-
ciate had arranged a real estate transaction in which they personally benefitted.
Colino was dismissed from his position and later convicted by an American
criminal court and sentenced to six years in prison. He was succeeded by Dean
Burch, former chairman of the American FCC and an insider in Republican
300 The International Organizations of Telecommunications
politics since 1964, when he was the campaign manager for Barry Goldwater's
conservative candidacy. Burch died in 1991. In 1990, Intelsat was criticized by
competing operators, who claimed it had set monopoly prices and refused to
use the most cost-effective technology. PanAmSat filed a $1.5 billion lawsuit
against Comsat, charging anticompetitive behavior.
Faced with added capacity and dropping prices, Intelsat's revenues stagnated
in 1989 and dropped almost by 20 percent in 1990. Jolted, this organization of
(largely) government organizations began to consider selling 49 percent of its
shares to the public, and its new head Irving Goldstein sought renegotiation on
launch contracts.
Policy issues involving Intelsat are discussed in greater detail in the chapter
on international communications and new entrants, both satellites and fiber cables.
CEPT
Eutelsat
Eutelsat was created in 1977 with an objective of creating and operating a
European system of satellite telecommunications. The organization is head-
quartered in Paris. It includes an Assembly of Signatories, which sets general
policy and objectives for the organization and addresses questions related to
external organizations and the division of markets. Another agency, the Euro-
pean Space Agency, deals mainly with the coordination of satellite develop-
ment. It places satellites in orbit for Eutelsat.
Although established for telecommunications, Eutelsat's main business be-
came the transmission of television programs to cable networks and national
broadcasters. In 1990, telephony and business telecommunications accounted
for a quarter of revenues, and television broadcasting for the rest.
The newer satellite generation, Eutelsat II, in operation after 1990, has 60
percent more communications capacity than the Eutelsat I series. It has sixteen
television transponders at 50 watts of power. Eutelsat II is built by a consor-
tium of Aerospatiale and Alcatel Espace, of France; Aeritalia, of Italy; CASA,
of Spain; Germany's MBB; and Sweden's Ericsson. Eutelsat was shaken in
1991 by the B.C. Commission's intention to seek an "open skies" policy that
would free users to interconnect into other satellite systems and deal with Eu-
telsat directly rather than through a PTT.
302 The International Organizations of Telecommunications
European Workshop for Open Systems. Another standards group, the European
Computer Manufacturers Association (ECMA), was founded in 1961 with the
participation of US and European firms. ECMA, which specializes in private
networks, works more quickly than its bureaucratic cousins and frequently sub-
mits its reports to CCITT and ISO for adoption (Gibbons, 1989a).
29
Brussels Takes On the
Traditional System
305
306 Brussels Takes On the Traditional System
work. CEPT had repeatedly changed the rules applied to SWIFT with the aim
of recouping revenue lost to telex service. SWIFT, not a meek organization
itself, lodged a complaint with the commission charging a price cartel and
abuse of individual and collective dominance. Negotiations then took place that
ultimately resulted in the lowering of its rates.
Another case was a 1986 complaint by the French DOT against the German
Bundespost. The DOT charged the Bundespost with restraint of marketing when
it did not accept the French Minitel videotex terminal, preferring to keep
the distribution of more integrated models for itself (Schulte-Braucks,
1986).
In 1984, the member states of the European Community agreed on the details
of a European telecommunications technology policy. The B.C. proposals in-
cluded the following: definition of medium- and long-term European policy
objectives; a new forum for European telecommunications issues; collaborative
European technological projects; common equipment interconnection standards;
a common European front towards outsiders; opening of national European
markets to unbiased procurement from other European countries; and collabora-
tion in the development of new transnational services, such as ISDN, broad-
band networks, and satellites.
France was initially active in pushing for a joint European telecommuni-
cations policy. Given its own high standard of telecommunications technology
within Europe, it saw itself as a potential beneficiary. The French PTT minister
Louis Mexandeau argued for a reciprocal and open European Community mar-
ket, which could also include the non-European Community members of CEPT.
His plan specified a delay in the reciprocal opening of the market with the
United States, Canada, and Japan.
In 1987, eleven out of the twelve E.G. countries (with the exception of
Greece) were separately and actively reassessing their telecommunications pol-
icies. Assuming a responsibility for preventing diverging paths and seeking to
accelerate the process, the commission issued a Green Paper aimed at "achiev-
ing maximum synergy between current developments and debates within the
Member States" and "to launch a debate" (CEC, 1987, p. 2). The paper's
recommendations included a phased opening of competition in the terminal
equipment market. This was, in part, merely an acknowledgment of gray-mar-
ket liberalization. Accordingly, the paper sought mutual recognition of type
approvals for terminal equipment and mutual opening of procurement contracts.
Most importantly, the paper asserted unequivocally that the (liberal) competi-
tion rules of the Treaty of Rome apply to telecommunications, in particular
where PTTs engage in commercial practices rather than basic 'reserved' ser-
vices. It called for the creation of a European telecommunications standard
body to set common standards.
The paper's second recommendation aimed at the unrestricted provision of
competitive (in particular nonvoice) services both within and among member
states, including an obligation for PTTs to provide access to transfrontier value-
added networks. This "open network provision" would permit such a network,
once licensed in one country, to operate throughout Europe. Such liberalization
Brussels Takes On the Traditional System 307
The second type of policy pursued by the European Community was to en-
courage technology development. Several joint projects were initiated. In ad-
dressing domestic protections, the commission argued that the Common Market
represents 30 percent of the world market for information technologies but that
it produces only 15 percent of such products. The European Strategic Program
of Research and Development in Information Technology (ESPRIT) whose goal
was to triple the E.C.'s share in the world market by 1990, was initiated to
alleviate this imbalance.
ESPRIT was established in 1984, seeking to promote cooperation between
European enterprises, research institutes, and universities. The total budget for
the first four years was $1.2 billion. A report of the French Senate delegation
for the European Communities noted, somewhat breathlessly, that, "The pro-
gram is a chanceperhaps the lastfor the countries of Europe to rejoin the
pack at the head of the industrial nations in new technologies, and to therefore
maintain technological autonomy . . ." (TDR, 1985, p. 49). Major European
manufacturing companies, including Bull, CGE, Thomson, ICL, Plessey, GEC,
Siemens, Nixdorf, AEG, Philips, and Olivetti supported ESPRIT, hoping for
its largesse.
In its first year, ESPRIT selected 90 projects out of 441 proposals, matching
Brussels Takes On the Traditional System 309
industry financing with equal subsidies for projects joining firms from at least
two E.G. countries. Although small companies and universities gained, the
prime beneficiaries were the established large electronics firms.
ESPRIT has five main research themes: microelectronics, software, advanced
information processing, office electronics, and integrated computerized design
and production. Biotechnology, nuclear energy, and processing of radioactive
wastes were added later. Because of various turf-battles, telecommunications
policy was conspicuously missing, except indirectly through components and
applications.
To deal with this absence, the European Commission established the Re-
search and Development in Advanced Communications Technologies for Eu-
rope (RACE) program to target telecommunications issues. The program's re-
search priorities are very-high-speed integrated circuits; high-complexity inte-
grated circuits; broadband switching; fiber-optic components; components for
long-distance, high-power links; specialized communications software; and large
format, flat-screen display technology (Telediffusion de France, 1985).
A major goal for RACE is to develop a European integrated broadband com-
munications network (IBN) by 1995. Given its planned and periodically uncer-
tain budget, only a relatively minor amount could be spent at first on develop-
ment. In its initial phase, RACE defined a European model of IBN and provided
the necessary equipment and cooperation methods among different firms and
countries. The main phase, from 1986 onward, includes field trials (systems),
technology development (technology), and standardization (integration) under-
taken in integrated broadband technology to provide a "framework for subse-
quent competitive product development" (CEC, 1987). The commission con-
tributed $500 million.
In 1990, the European Commission considered a plan to accelerate RACE
and achieve pan-European broadband communications as early as 1993. Under
the three-phase plan, broadband "islands" would be linked by existing 140
Mbps fiber optic lines. By 1994, the system would connect about 100 compa-
nies. Starting in 1996, fiber-optic cable would bring residential subscribers into
the broadband network.
EUREKA, the European Research Coordination Agency, is a third joint Eu-
ropean development program and is based on an initiative proposed by French
President Mitterrand. EUREKA concentrates on six broad scientific areas: op-
Ironies, high-speed microelectronics, large computers, artificial intelligence, high-
power laser and particle beams, and new materials.
For each of these areas, a management committee is made up of members
from governments, industry, and research institutes. Financing is shared by the
national governments and the firms. EUREKA's goal was defined as the devel-
opment and potential manufacture of marketable products, with an eye toward
the perceived major European weaknessnot research, but its translation into
successful products. EUREKA is not specifically a project of the European
Community. Non-E.C. nations also participate in the program.
EUREKA was stressed as the European and civilian alternative to the Amer-
310 Brussels Takes On the Traditional System
ican militarized research effort. Skeptics like The Economist described EU-
REKA as "[promising] to take more money from taxpayers to bribe rich Eu-
ropean companies to do the sort of R&D they should be doing anyway if they
want to stay in business."
Another program, the Special Telecommunications Action for Regional De-
velopment (STAR), began in 1988 to assist development of telecommunica-
tions services in less-developed E.G. nations, primarily Portugal, Greece, Ire-
land, Spain, and southern Italy (Lalor, 1987). The JESSI program (Joint European
Submicron Silicon Initiative) was developed to provide $4 billion in financing
for chip makers.
Space Development
In 1975, eleven European countries created the European Space Agency (ESA).
Its origins began with European efforts to catch up with the American and
Soviet space programs. In 1960, the European Preparatory Commission for
Space (COPERS) was established, and in 1964, the conventions for the Euro-
pean Space Vehicle Launcher Development Organization (ELDO) and the Eu-
ropean Space Research Organization (ESRO) were signed. These organizations
were forerunners of ESA (ESA, 1984).2 ELDO developed a European booster
using British, French, and German rockets as stages and launched them from
Woomera, Australia. Three European scientific satellites were developed and
launchedby American rocketsin 1968.
ESA began operations in 1975, when eleven European countries signed its
convention. It moved into the development of weather forecasting and telecom-
munications satellites, and in 1985 launched a mission to explore Halley's comet.
Meteorological satellites were first launched in 1981 and operated by the Eu-
ropean Meteorological Satellite Organization (EUMETSAT), established in 1983.
In 1983, the American space shuttle launched Spacelab, the European space
laboratory, which carried the first ESA astronaut into space.
The Ariane space launcher program was started in 1973. In 1979, the first
successful test flight was completed, followed by consecutively more powerful
Ariane generations. Ariane IV can lift 4 tons into a stationary orbit. Technical
responsibility for the development of the launcher lies with CNEE, the Centre
National d'Etudes Espace. The firm Aerospatiale coordinates its systems inte-
gration. Arianspace operates commercial launches, and competes with NASA
for customers in the launching of telecommunications satellites. NASA's space
shuttle requires launch to a low orbit in a manned vehicle, from where a second
launch is undertaken to reach the geostationary orbit. In that second boost, a
number of problems occurred. Both organizations charge each other with unfair
competition by subsidized launches, and it is difficult to determine what the
"economic" cost is, particularly in a multipurpose mission such as a manned
space shuttle flight.
In 1983, the Ariane rocket launched the first European Communications Sat-
ellite (ECS). The ECS system, in turn, is operated by Eutelsat, the satellite
organization of the European PTTs. A new generation of European satellites
was approved in 1984 under the name of Apollo.
Within Europe, some of the larger countries felt reluctant to share their tech-
nology and its application with other countries. For example, France and Ger-
many did not develop broadcast-strength satellites through ESA, but instead
collaborated and produced them (joined later by Sweden).
30
Telecommunications Policy as
Industrial Policy
Convergence?
312
Telecommunications Policy as Industrial Policy 313
ilarly, many dominant European intellectuals believe that "technique has be-
come autonomous; it has fashioned an omnivorous world which obeys its own
laws and which has renounced all tradition" (Ellul, 1964, p. 14).
Western Europe and the United States are of course diverse in their economic
institutions, as are European countries among themselves. But if one looks at
the first derivativethe changerather than at the absolute, the United States
and Europe exhibited roughly similar trends for more than half a century. After
a relatively free-wheeling 1920s, the interventionist role of the state increased
considerably in the 1930s on both sides of the Atlantic under the effect of the
Great Depression. World War II led to a still increased governmental role. In
the 1950s, Europeans and Americans pursued an essentially conservative pro-
business policy in economic development, coupled with adherence to the wel-
fare state programs of the 1930s and late 1940s. Central to the economic sys-
tem of the postwar years was reliance on the large business corporation. In the
1960s, more liberal or social democratic trends emerged on both sides of the
Atlantic, followed by a tumultuous period of internal unrest.
In the mid-1970s, however, the economic theories of the Chicago School
a noninterventionist philosophybecame influential among economists and
provided the economic legitimization of a policy that called for a reduced gov-
ernmental role. During that period and not unrelated, American economic de-
velopment shifted from the traditional centers of production, primarily in the
northeast, to the west and south. The new firms responsible for the shift were
smaller or medium-sized, frequently run by entrepreneurs rather than by cor-
porate bureaucracies, and hostile to unionization. Meanwhile, the American
government had been substantially discredited by the disasters of Vietnam, Wa-
tergate, inflation, and social problems despite the reform programs of the 1960s.
These interacting forces contributed to America's move toward an increasing
withdrawal of the state from economic control.
In Europe, the state had not squandered public trust to the same extent.
European intellectuals were not moving generally to the right as in America,
though there were increasingly exceptions. European societies were comfort-
able with large bureaucratized firms; a pro-competitive policy had genuine sup-
port only from small liberal parties of the center. A further stabilizing force
was environmentalism. "Green" parties called for strict governmental regula-
tion and specifically advocated control over technology-driven change.
In continental Europe, corporatism as an ideology is palatable both to the
political right and left. Accordingly, in Europe the state has frequently acted to
encourage consolidation in order to make national industry viable in world
competition. In the United States however, antitrust policy, rooted in anti-big-
ness populism, was important for a century, even though its enforcement had
its ups and downs.
Thus, the 1980s witnessed a marked divergence of the paths of European
and American high technology development: In Europe, large firms were more
important than ever; in the United States, the giants were attacked by small
competitors and challenged by various take-over financiers, corporate empire-
314 Telecommunications Policy as Industrial Policy
Institute of Technology (MIT) were chosen to direct research. The project would
fuse American technical know-how with European social concern and human-
ism in the service of society and the Third World. It was generously financed
by the French government and was lavishly presented to the public (Etheridge,
1983).
Yet within one year the center was paralyzed and the Americans had left.
What had gone wrong? Among other reasons, the American scientists and the
French politicians had different conceptions of the center. The French wanted
to demonstrate France's national commitment to technological leadership. The
MIT technocrats took the humanist mission of the center more seriously and
favored a democratic style of management, which clashed with the style of the
French government officials who controlled it. Instead of becoming a world
forum with an international outlook, the center became a backwater catering to
domestic manufacturing interests.
This episode illuminates the dilemma facing European leaders. They are aware
of the importance of this sector, they want to attain rapid results, and are will-
ing to commit money and prestige. In the end, however, their efforts are ham-
pered by fundamental constraints: the self-interests of bureaucracies, the narrow
perspective of domestic manufacturers, and technological nationalism, even in
the European context.
trial costs of a new product by tending to be its first major user and assuming
some of the costs of the early shake-outs and of the early production runs.
PTTs therefore subsidized the development of products that were then offered
in the world market, often at costs below the domestic ones. Domestic tele-
phone users, in effect, subsidize the export activities of industrial firms.
For example, deviations from competitive world market prices of up to 120
percent existed for PTT central office equipment procurement in 1985. In Bel-
gium, this 120 percent markup allegedly supported company R&D. Germany
and Italy paid prices 100 percent above cost. France's payments for equipment
were only 50 percent above world prices, but the DGT funded R&D directly,
not through equipment purchases (Miiller, 1987, p. 12). The attempts to use
the telecommunications network as a motor for more general industrial policy
is not uniquely European. Japan, Korea, Singapore and Taiwan, for example,
have pursued similar policies. In the United States, too, there have been many
voices recommending such a direction in light of the decline of U.S. strength
in electronics. Their weight is partly dependent on the success of the European
efforts and its demonstration effects.
The weakness of some equipment firms once the protective bond of the postal-
industrial alliance is loosened means that, at least in the short term, the tradi-
tional network operator may gain rather than lose strength in a liberalized envi-
ronment. It would be naive to expect that reorganizing a PTT as an independent
corporationwhatever its ownership statuswould lead it automatically to strive
for improved efficiency. If the exhortations to act like a business are taken seri-
ously by a PTT and are acted upon, they result in an expanded set of activities.
In Europe, the network operators, now often permitted to do so, have inte-
grated horizontally and vertically and extended their reach. It is likely that we
are merely at the beginning of a process in which effective telecommunications
carriers move into adjacent lines of business.
In the United Kingdom, British Telecom began to pursue several avenues of
vertical integration. In the equipment field, it bought the Canadian PBX man-
Telecommunications Policy as Industrial Policy 321
ufacturer Mitel. The regulatory body, Oftel, and almost the entire British
equipment industry then argued that the acquisition would not be in the public
interest because it would strengthen BT's power in terminal equipment and
threaten British PBX manufacturers. Although it acknowledged the problem,
the Monopolies and Mergers Commission accepted the merger, with some con-
ditions attached. But even those conditions were waived by the government,
which approved the acquisition. In the end, the acquisition was not successful
economically, but that does not mean that future vertical integration is pre-
cluded.
BT is not unique in seeking to expand its market power vertically. In Spain,
the semi-private telecommunications monopoly, Telefonica, has a strong in-
volvement in manufacturing. It held a large interest in the Spanish ITT-Alcatel
subsdiary Standard Electrica, which was by far the largest electronics manufac-
turer in Spain, and it had major stock interests in a dozen other equipment
firms and minority interests in seven more. The aggregate output of these firms
accounted for about a third of total Spanish telecommunications production.
Vertical integration also existed for a long time in Italy. The predominant
telephone carrier, SIP, is part of the holding company Societa Finanziaria Tele-
fonico, which in turn is partly private, and mostly controlled by the government
holding organization Institut per la Reconstruzione Industriale (IRI). STET also
owns several major manufacturing firms, including Italtel, the country's largest
telecommunications equipment firm, and several leading components and high
technology firms.
Similarly, the Swedish national telephone administration, Televerket, has
substantial manufacturing operations in its TELI and other subsidiaries. Japan's
NTT formed within one year of privatization almost seventy subsidiaries or
new ventures that were active in new products, services, and marketing.
These instances of vertical integration by the network operators indicate that
liberalization transforms the relationship between PTTs and equipment firms
from one of partnership into one of potential rivalry. And while this has com-
petitive advantages, at least in the lengthy transition phase, the potential for
vertical integration increases rather than decreases the role of the network op-
erator.
The conclusion is that in their role as the state-sanctioned engine of domestic
technological developments, and through their ability to extend their market
power vertically, the PTTs, now transformed into semi-independent PTOs with
greater flexibility, will be even more important and powerful than in the past.
It is also conceivable that a similar role might be assigned in the U.S. to tele-
phone companies, as alarm grows over the Japanese lead in high technology.
Several congressional bills point in that direction. Thus, convergence may be
resurrected, after all.
31
Transatlantic Trade Friction
Developments in the United States challenged the traditional status quo in the
European telecommunications field, threatening its traditional postal-industrial
coalition. For a long time, European interpretation of U.S. developments was
colored by the prevailing views of telecommunications experts, most of whom
were closely affiliated with the traditional system. The AT&T divestiture itself
was generally described as advantageous to AT&T: It was dropping the costly
baggage of the regulated operating companies and could now take on IBM.
European PTTs had a great amount of respect and sympathy for the old
AT&T. Although the American telephone operating company was privately
owned, its dominance was similar to that of European administrations. Inter-
national cooperation in such areas as transatlantic communications resulted in
close links as partners rather than competitors. The dismantling of AT&T be-
wildered the PTTs. The decision seemed arbitrary, inefficient, and political. It
should be noted that the belief that the competent and successful AT&T had
been needlessly dismembered by the government is at odds with the view that
the divestiture was a great success for AT&T.
The notion that the United States, with its advanced technology and success-
ful telecommunications monopoly, would choose voluntarily to dismember such
a system was unsettling. Whereas in the past, the development and adoption of
new technologies provided security to the PTTs, it now seemed to undermine
them. This perception resulted in strong defensive reactions. The American
circumstances were generally portrayed as inherently different from those in
European countries and hence not applicable to their situation, and little effort
was made to isolate those elements that could be seen as part of a generalizable
network evolution.
In some ways, the PTTs' views closely resembled the instant nostalgia that
occurred in the United States after the announcement of the AT&T divestiture
agreement. AT&T, which had been a favorite object of criticism, was suddenly
seen as an efficient and benevolent organization torn apart by economic zealots.
This ignored decades of major complaints about AT&T and its vast power in
the American economy. The lawsuit against AT&T by the Antitrust Division
of the Justice Department was the result of long-standing problems and was
pursued by both Democratic and Republican administrations.
322
Transatlantic Trade Friction 323
in terms of trade. This created problems of trade reciprocity that spilled into
the political arena.
The AT&T divestiture led to the emergence of AT&T as a competitor in
international markets, a sharp break with the past. This development received
much attention and led to fears of an American telecommunications equipment
offensive into Europe. But the opposite happened in the 1980s. American tele-
communications equipment makers were repulsed and almost expelled from the
European market, with ITT, GTE, and Honeywell largely departing. AT&T
and the Bell regional holding companies were only partly successful after large
scale efforts.
For more than fifty years, AT&T had stayed out of international equipment
activities, despite its position as the largest such manufacturer in the world.
But this had not always been the case. In the early years of the telephone, the
Bell System had licensed several European equipment manufacturers, acquired
others, built its own facilities in Europe, and had a substantial manufacturing
and distribution presence in several major countries. But in the 1920s, the com-
pany was under much U.S. pressure to sell its international operations, as
American critics of AT&T charged that American ratepayers were subsidizing
AT&T's international operations. For that and other reasons, the company in
1925 decided to sell its European operations to the then relatively insignifi-
cant firm ITT, run by the Virgin Islands entrepreneur Sosthenes Behn and his
brother.
This event marked ITT's entry into the big league of telecommunications.
ITT's major European operations included Standard Telephone Company (STC)
in the United Kingdom; Standard Lorenz Elektrik (SEL) in Germany; FACE in
Italy, Bell Telephone Manufacturing Company (BTM) in Belgium, Standard
Electrica in Spain, and LMT and CGCT in France. Other subsidiaries existed
in Norway, Denmark, Portugal, Austria, Ireland, and so on. Given the nation-
alistic nature of the telecommunications equipment market, it was to ITT's
advantage to have a physical presence in each country, because this allowed it
to present itself as a domestic rather than an American company; local ITT
companies often downplayed their U.S. connections.
The ITT companies included, among others, Standard Radio and Telefone
AB, Sweden; the Bell Telephone Manufacturing Company, Belgium; FACE,
Italy; ITT, Austria; ITT, Netherlands; Standard Electric Kirk A/S, Denmark;
Standard Electrica, Spain; Standard Electrica, Portugal; Standard Elektrik Lor-
enz (SEL), Germany; Standard Telephone and Radio, Switzerland; Standard
Telefone og Kabelfabrik A/S, Norway; Standard Telephone and Cable (30 per-
cent ITT owned), Britain; and an Australian subsidiary. ITT's sales were not
normally broken down by country, though one study reported the following
1976 sales figures (Northern Telecom, 1980):
company of the main operating company SIP. Italy had slated its lagging tele-
communications network for a major upgrade and expansion. But Italtel, the
main domestic supplier, was in need of a foreign technology source. A struggle
between Siemens, Alcatel, and AT&T for the huge contract ensued and led to
lobbying efforts by Presidents Mitterrand and Reagan. In 1989, AT&T was
selected. Italtel, in return, received a share of AT&T's European operations.
AT&T also entered into other international involvements in Korea, Spain, Ire-
land, and Taiwan, all primarily off-shore manufacturing efforts that provided
some local presence. In 1990, Spain's Telefonica upgraded its involvement
with AT&T. Telefonica became a participant in AT&T Network Systems In-
ternational, with 6 percent of the equity. AT&T had 59 percent, Italtel 20
percent, and Philips 15 percent, until the latter ran into financial difficulties and
sold out to AT&T. These partnerships opened the prospect for AT&T's entry
into Spain's expanding equipment market. Next, it established itself in Ukraine's
network operations, and in Armenia and Kazakhstan. Thus, AT&T seemed to
have finally established a European presence.
Another major move by AT&T was to try, unsuccessfully, for an agreement
with the dominant French firm of CGE, which unleashed a round of diplomatic
and economic intrigue. In particular, the German government began to lobby
on behalf of Siemens, pressuring the French government at the highest levels
to substitute Siemens for AT&T-Philips in the spirit of European solidarity, as
well as in reciprocity for the newly acquired German Alcatel subsidiary SEL.
The tug of war grew acrimonious. FCC Chairman Mark Fowler sent pointed
inquiries to major American telephone companies regarding their use of equip-
ment from countries where U.S. firms were being discriminated against. Within
the French government, the PTT preferred APT, but other ministries did not
wish to antagonize Germany. In the end, the French government chose the
Swedish Ericsson as a neutral compromise, together with the French defense
firm Matra, which thus gained a foothold in its country's telecommunications
market. Further details on AT&T and ITT in France are provided in the chapter
on that country.
Overall, the European equipment market was $18 billion in 1987 and had
grown to $28 billion by 1990, with huge modernization and digitalization
programs in Spain, France, Italy, and other countries; the European Commis-
sion predicted a 9 percent yearly growth rate for equipment and services. Within
the European market, Alcatel, Siemens, and Ericsson were the dominant sup-
pliers. In 1987, Alcatel was the largest supplier of public switching equipment
(with 40 percent of the market), private switches (20 percent), terminal equip-
ment (19 percent), and transmission systems. Siemens was second in public
switches (20 percent), terminal equipment (16 percent), and transmission
equipment (15 percent), followed by Ericsson in each category. Northern Te-
lecom was the only non-European company to break into the top three, with
an 18 percent share of private switching equipment. But with the saturation of
the domestic market for basic service expansion, exports became more impor-
tant to equipment manufacturers.
Transatlantic Trade Friction 327
The U.S. market is not only the largest domestic market in the world for tele-
communications products, but it is also relatively free, and it has a large num-
ber of potential customers in the 1200 local exchange companies, the various
new carriers and telephone companies. There are more networks as potential
customers in the United States than in the rest of the world put together. (Most
of the companies are, of course, quite small.)
The U.S. market for local exchange and transmission equipment was char-
acterized before the AT&T divestiture by competition only in the procurement
of equipment by non-AT&T telephone companies. Even GTE's local exchange
companies were tied to their parent company's manufacturing units. AT&T was
largely precluded from the independent market by the terms of legal agreements
with the Justice Department, butperhaps as a resultmany other companies
were active in it, including foreign suppliers such as Ericsson and Northern
Telecom. On the other hand, the vast Bell system and all of its customers
comprising 80 percent of the local marketwere largely inaccessible to other
suppliers because of AT&T's ties to its manufacturing subsidiary Western
Electric.
The U.S. liberalization provided non-U.S. manufacturers with opportunities.
The Bell operating companies, which prior to divestiture of AT&T had relied
mostly on Western Electric, were now free to buy equipment from other sup-
pliers, and have indeed actively done so.
Interconnection of customer premises equipment was also significantly lib-
eralized in the United States. Whereas it once was more restrictive than in
many European countries, it became much freer in the wake of regulatory and
court decisions. The relaxed rules ("Part 68") followed the 1968Carterfone
case. Now equipment sellers need only to register their products with the FCC
as complying with standards before marketing them. Registration requires the
disclosure of a unit's technical specifications, so that the FCC's staff can, if it
wishes, identify possible system degradation prior to installation of the equip-
ment. But there is no approval process. (There is a national security exception
to the registration requirement. If a federal agency certifies that compliance
with registration procedures would jeopardize security interests, equipment may
be connected to the network without publication of technical data.)
Although most analysts expected the BOCs to cling to AT&T as their equip-
ment supplier, they in fact rapidly embraced a wide variety of non-AT&T
equipment. In one instance involving equipment allegedly affecting defense
communications, the Defense Department reportedly used pressure to influence
a carrier not to buy Japanese equipment. But this was a widely noted exception.
Generally, the opening of the U.S. market to non-AT&T and foreign equip-
ment was rapid.
Network standards are coordinated for the BOCs by their joint organization,
Bell Communication Research (Bellcore). Although Bellcore's information re-
328 Transatlantic Trade Friction
It is obvious that no European company, French or not, can remain a world com-
pany if it does not have a significant position in the American market, which rep-
resents 40 percent of the world market and, in addition, is from the point of view
of technology the best testing grounds one can imagine. Happily, we have a
historic opportunity to develop ourselves in the U.S., with the deregulation of
AT&T. . . . If, sadly, CGE's presence in the U.S. failed, we would need more
than a decade to regain the confidence of our American customers [L'Expansion,
1985].
But Alcatel, which bought ITT's switching systems division worldwide (in-
cluding the United States), was not successful at introducing ITT's switch into
America. It closed its U.S. switching division and cut back its efforts to sell
cable and transmission equipment. Northern Telecom, however, performed very
well in the U.S. market, securing a leadership position as a second source.
Three contenders for the number three slot were Siemens, Ericsson, and Fu-
jitsu. None of them emerged as a clear leader. Siemens, with the strongest
presence, had over 1 million installed lines as of 1990. Ericsson's success has
been mostly in rural applications of its AXE switch, and Fujitsu had various
trials in place throughout the United States.
The major problem, from the U.S. perspective, is that the opening of the
U.S. telecommunications equipment market to foreign suppliers was not matched
by a reciprocal opening of their markets to U.S. producers.
In 1981, the United States had a $6.04 billion trade surplus in electronics-
based products, which included telecommunications and computer goods. By
1986, the U.S. deficit in this area was $16.06 billion (NTIA, as cited by Rob-
inson, 1987).
In the subcategory of telecommunications products, the United States had a
$817 million trade surplus in 1981, and a $2.5 billion deficit in 1987. In the
Transatlantic Trade Friction 329
for testing the system (the so-called Phase E review), but it also costs $100
million or more to modify the system to North American standards and soft-
ware practices. There are technical differences that create barriers to entry by
European suppliers. But there is no evidence that these technical standards,
which evolved over decades some time ago, were set or are applied with a
protectionist purpose.3
In 1990, the European Commission issued a directive on public procurement
that included a "buy Europe" clause, stipulating that E.G. bids must be ac-
cepted if they are less than 3 percent higher than non-E.C. offers (for orders
over 600,000 ECU). Only bids from firms with more than 50 percent B.C.
ownership would be given this preference. The law was scheduled to take ef-
fect in 1992, except in Spain, Portugal, and Greece. Shortly after the directive
was passed, the French Ministry of European Affairs called for resistance to
the "invasion" by U.S. and Japanese firms. It claimed that Japan had a 95
percent share of the facsimile machine market, that Motorola had 25 percent of
cellular equipment, and that AT&T had increased from a 2.5 percent market
share in switching in 1985 to 13 percent in 1990 (Roussel, 1990).
The following are unconfirmed (and quite likely non-comparable) numbers
for digital switches that were provided by several market participants about
competitors' and suppliers' bids and contracts. The figures should be treated
with great caution, because each deal may include different packages of hard-
ware, software, and support. But the numbers, nevertheless, serve to illustrate
the order of magnitude of the high premiums charged domestically over the
lowest bid made by the same firm internationally in the early 1990s. The fig-
ures show a very significant domestic premium, indicating that much of R&D
and other initial costs are paid for by PTTs and borne by domestic rate payers
in those countries where foreign entry is disfavored over domestic "industrial
champions." The U.S. seems to have competitive pricing, with a small pre-
mium only. Japan, despite the four major vendors of the "NTT family," has
prices above world market prices. And European premiums are substantial.
The clash between the different policy approaches taken on the two sides of
the Atlantic was particularly acute in international communications, partly be-
cause of its great profitability. Historically, U.S. policy on international tele-
communications had carved up the market into distinct segments, assigning
each segment to different kinds of carriers. In the 1970s and 1980s, however,
the United States radically restructured its own rules of the game and forced
the European countries to respond to a new situation. This led to frequent
disputes. American changes destabilized the traditional European system, as
analyzed later with the theoretical model of Chapter 40.
The volume of international telecommunications traffic increased much faster
than international trade in general. From 1970 to 1981, for example, interna-
tional calls originating in the United States increased by a factor of 11.3, whereas
American international trade grew, in real terms, by a factor of 3 (Antonelli,
1984).
One part of the impetus behind this rise in international traffic was the dra-
matic decrease in investment cost for a transatlantic circuit, from $1.4 billion
per voice circuit on TAT-1 in 1956 down to $44,356 per circuit for the fiber-
optic TAT-8 cable in 1988 (Stanley, 1988). An FCC study found that the cost
per minute on transatlantic cable dropped from $2.53 in 1956 to $0.04 in 1988
and was expected to fall to $0.02 in 1992. In the same period, the number of
available voice circuits grew from 89 to 37,800. Satellite circuit costs similarly
fell from $32,000 each on the Early Bird satellite in 1968 to $4,680 for the
Intelsat-VI satellite generation in 1982.
However, this drop in costs was not matched by an equal drop in prices;
consequently, the profit margin on international service remains very high. Ac-
cording to one study, British Telecom charged $750,000 for a direct-broadcast-
grade connection between London and New York in 1981, whose cost to BT
was only $53,000, which in turn contained an Intelsat charge that already was
well above actual economic cost (Stapley, 1981).
Closely related to these high prices is their asymmetry. An FCC study showed
that the weighted average for foreign tariffs was almost 95 percent higher than
the American tariff (Kwerel, 1984).
Lower rates in the United States are partly the result of a long struggle among
331
332 Internationa! Telecommunications Services
In a series of rulings in 1979 and 1980, the FCC also largely removed the
dichotomy of voice and record carriage, eliminated the rules prohibiting AT&T
and the IRCs from entering each other's markets, and expanded the number of
gateway cities from which international traffic could be sent.'
The FCC also eliminated rate-of-return regulation and tariffing. Only domi-
nant carriers (i.e., AT&T and GTE's Hawaiian Telephone Company) needed
to file international tariffs. Other carriers had merely to report their activities.
The FITs observed all this with some misgivings, for these rulings chal-
lenged long-established partnership arrangements and rate structures. But once
their initial distaste for the increased complexity in the international telecom-
munications regime subsided, they recognized the potential advantages. As the
only address within their countries for AT&T, MCI, Sprint, and others, the
PTTs were in a position to profit by forcing rival American carriers to compete
against each other for operating agreements.
To prevent the IRCs from being thus "whipsawed," the FCC in 1977 en-
forced a Uniform Settlements Policy requiring all U.S. carriers to have uniform
settlement rates with all other carriers for the same routes. When the Benelux
PTTs and Nordtel (the Inter-Scandinavian telecommunications body) invited all
potential suppliers of data communication services to submit bids that included
the division of accounting (i.e., an element of price bids), the American reac-
tion was swift. Despite normally championing liberalization, the FCC ironically
requested that U.S. carriers collectively defer negotiations with Nordtel. Nord-
tel backed off and notified the carriers that it did not plan to use its monopoly
power for exclusive bids.
When different entities provide international telecommunications service at
each end of a circuit, they agree upon a division of the revenues between them.
The entities create an "accounting rate" or "settlement rate" to be paid to one
carrier by the other carrier collecting from a customer. The accounting rate
may bear little or no relationship to the actual customer charge or "collection"
rate. As a hypothetical example, the accounting rate for the first three minutes
of a telephone call between New York and Paris might be $3.00; the charge
for the call in the United States, $4.50; and the charge in France, $6.00. When
U.S. customers call, they pay $4.50 to AT&T, which credits $3.00 to the
French PTT. When French customers call, they pay $6.00 to the French PTT,
which credits $3.00 to AT&T. The Uniform Settlements Policy does not regu-
late U.S. carriers' rates on the U.S. end, but attempts to protect U.S. compa-
nies from whipsawing by foreign PTTs by requiring that all U.S. carriers pay
them a uniform rate.
But given the profit margins it must be difficult to prevent non-price conces-
sions. In 1985, an example of whipsawing occurred when RCA filed a com-
plaint with the FCC, charging TRT and FTCC, two other international record
carriers, with using so-called special drawing rights instead of the established
gold franc settlements in their international telex accounts with the PTTs of
Finland, France, Norway, and Spain. RCA charged that this arrangement re-
duced the accounting rate they would receive from $1.38 to $1.14. FTCC de-
fended itself, arguing that it would actually receive $1.21 under the special
334 International Telecommunications Services
drawing right settlement, but it admitted that the figure was still lower than the
gold franc rate.
In 1984, the European PTTs affirmed their policy on the limitation of entry
by American competitors. The PTT organization CEPT recommended that its
members not open their markets to any new American carriers unless they
would provide better technical service at a lower cost (to PTTs) than at present.
New carriers were permitted for new types of communications services such as
videotex, teletext, facsimile, and packet switching, but the CEPT guidelines
restricted each to providing only one type of new service.
In an attempt to reduce the barriers to entry created by the PTTs' negotiation
requirements, MCI bought an existing IRC, Western Union International (re-
named MCI International) from Xerox. MCI International created a convenient
international outlet for MCI's American involvement in electronic mail and also
provided MCI with an already established relationship with the PTTs. The
company concluded agreements with several countries and established London
and Hong Kong as international hubs for its traffic to other countries. It also
complied with a host of burdensome requirements and procedures that made
service to some countries unprofitable.
A related question was the way in which European PTTs pick American
long-distance carriers for communication originating in Europe. For European
customers calling American cities, the PTT chooses which U.S. long-distance
carrier will transmit the call within the U.S. and realize the subsequent reve-
nue.
Of course, it would be possible to permit the European users to indicate
which American long-distance carrier they prefer. This could be accomplished
through the use of not one but several country codes for the United States (or
North America), with a different numeric access code assigned to each U.S.
international carrier.2 But such a choice of services, together with the possibil-
ity of advertising campaigns by various carriers directed at European custom-
ers, would have visibly demonstrated that network competition was feasible,
and this type of consumer choice was not granted to most European users.
Instead, negotiations centered on the ways in which the PTTs might allocate
their U.S.-bound traffic between AT&T and its competitors. One possibility
was to negotiate market shares in advance; another was to use a fixed share
allocation formula. The easiest was to allocate America-bound traffic to Amer-
ican carriers in the same proportion that those carriers supply traffic to Europe.
In addition to extending its pro-competitive and deregulatory policies to in-
ternational services, the FCC sought to increase competition between types of
transmission media and service providers.3
An important distinction is made in international communications between
transmission by submarine cable and transmission by satellite. The several sub-
marine cables linking North America and Europe are owned and operated by
consortia of European and North American telecommunications administrations
and firms. In contrast to their part-ownership in the submarine cable operations,
AT&T and the other American international carriers as well as domestic satel-
lite operators were specifically excluded from international satellite transmis-
International Telecommunications Services 335
sion, which was reserved for Comsat, the American designated carrier of the
international satellite organization Intelsat. Created in 1964 at the instigation of
the United States, Intelsat is a cartel-like organization with a considerable mo-
nopoly over satellite transmission of international public telecommunications.
Each member country designates a carrier to manage outgoing and incoming
Intelsat communications traffic. For most countries, this carrier is the govern-
mental PTT authority. Following intense domestic debate in the United States,
however, Congress denied AT&T this role in an attempt to limit its power. The
role was instead given to Comsat, which was created through the Communica-
tions Satellite Act of 1962 as a publicly chartered, privately owned company.
Under the 1962 legislation, Comsat was solely a "carrier's carrier"; neither
AT&T nor the IRCs were permitted direct access to Intelsat, and Comsat could
not connect directly with users. In 1965, Comsat had a 61 percent share in
Intelsat, reflecting its share of traffic. Its share later declined to approximately
25 percent.4
The FCC subsequently permitted Comsat to go beyond its role as a carrier's
carrier and to provide services to customers directly. The FCC made this con-
ditional upon a major restructuring of Comsat separating its unregulated com-
petitive activities from its regulated activities. Comsat sold its earth stations
and divested its manufacturing subsidiaries in 1988 and 1989.5
lished, against its use as a transfer point to other countries. As with other
cartel-like agreements, this was only as strong as its weakest link. Given its
general evolution toward liberalization of telecommunications and its privati-
zation of British Telecom, the United Kingdom did not remain agreeable to the
plan. Similarly, as in the case of tax havens, one could expect other European
countries to find it advantageous to become international transmissions hubs by
permitting down-links from non-Intelsat carriers. Moreover, limitations against
retransmission might not be supported by the European antitrust laws, as the
case of the British telex bureaus demonstrates.
Still, the delaying tactics took their toll. After a while, PanAmSat was the
only project that could afford to pursue its goals actively. In 1988, the Pan-
AmSat, with twenty-four C-Band transponders, was launched. Its combative
chairman, Rene Anselmo, promised to crack the monopoly of Intelsat with
service to Central and South America, the continental United States, the Carib-
bean, and, significantly, Western Europe. In 1990, PanAmSat filed a $1.5 mil-
lion lawsuit against Intelsat and won an easing of restrictions. In 1991, Intelsat,
having in 1985 been forced to agree to coordinate with separate systems, agreed
for PanAmSat to be interconnected with public switched networks in the Carib-
bean and Eastern Europe, with up to 100 circuits. Orion restructured itself into
a limited partnership including British Aerospace, General Dynamics, and Ma-
tra, with a 1994 launch date.
Although a single global system may be desirable because of its economies
of scale, a distance- and border-insensitive technology such as satellite trans-
mission cannot be successfully restricted for long. Sooner or later, companies
larger than Orion and PanAmSat will establish themselves in the market. Do-
mestic or regional PTT satellites with spare capacity will play a similar role.
Intersputnik, the Soviet-dominated Eastern European system was another pos-
sibility, and it began to offer its services to Western countries as its East Eu-
ropean customer base declined. Partly to preempt competitive entry, several
European operators began VSAT (very small aperture terminals) service, aimed
at the private networks of large users, particularly those with pan-European
communications needs such as automobile makers. Both British Telecom and
Mercury made plans for VSAT service. In 1990, only in Germany and poten-
tially in Britain could such service be offered outside the traditional carriers. In
1991, the European Commission drafted a directive to create a competitive
European satellite market. Soon, various PTOs began to coordinate their VSAT
plans, partly out of concern that VSAT service could be used to bypass national
networks.
Intelsat's revenues stagnated in 1989 and dropped by almost 20 percent in
1990. Jolted, it considered privatizing itself by selling 49 percent of its shares
to the public.
Even in the absence of competing satellites, Intelsat arrangements are threat-
ened by rivalry from already emerging competitors in private submarine cable
facilities. Two companies, Tel-Optik and Submarine Lightwave Cable Com-
pany (SLCC), applied for licenses to operate an international submarine cable
(PTAT) in the United States. The submarine cable applications did not raise
338 international Telecommunications Services
issues under the Intelsat agreements. Moreover, AT&T, the major American
owner of submarine cable systems, did not file any substantial objections. The
FCC thus moved expeditiously to grant the Tel-Optik application in 1985. Cable
& Wireless and E. F. Hutton participated in that venture. Soon one Bell re-
gional holding company, NYNEX, acquired an option, thereby raising the
question of the permissibility of Bell companies' international involvement in
this form, which was eventually denied. The plan was for two cables to be
operated in conjunction with Cable & Wireless in the United Kingdom, with
the first cable completed in 1989 and the second in 1992. Similar applications
were made and approved for Pacific routes.
Liberalization of entry led to the emergence of international carriers in Brit-
ain, Japan, and Sweden. Cable & Wireless (C&W) was the prototype for the
new generation of international carriers. As discussed in the chapter on U.K.
telecommunications, C&W's goal was to become the first global telephone car-
rier, and its strategy targeted the world's financial centers: London, New York,
Tokyo, Hong Kong, and Bahrain. It was already a dominant presence in Hong
Kong, where it owns the local telephone company. In Britain, C&W became
the sole owner of Mercury, which provided it with domestic long-distance ca-
pability within Britain and access to several European countries. C&W was a
major partner in the PTAT transatlantic fiber-optic cable to New York and held
transcontinental rights in the United States through its ownership of TDX, an
American long-distance carrier.
In Japan, the liberalization of long-distance communications also reached
international service. Two consortia applied for a license to provide such ser-
vice in competition with the previous monopolist KDD. The first was Interna-
tional Telecom Japan (ITJ), owned by fifty-three large users, including Mitsu-
bishi, Somitomo, Mitsui, Matsushita, and the Bank of Tokyo. The second con-
sortium was International Digital Communications (IDC), in which C. Itoh &
Co. and Cable & Wireless were the largest partners from among thirty-five
companies, including Toyota. The Ministry of Posts and Telecommunications
tried to convince the two ventures to merge. Part of the agreement would have
been to reduce C&W's share to 3 percent for reasons of "national security"
and to exclude it from a role in management. The British and American gov-
ernments opposed these restrictions as nontariff barriers. Both services were
launched in 1989. By 1990, they had captured 35 percent of all international
traffic between Japan and the U.S.
In time the distortions of the traditional system reached the attention of the
public. Hugo Dixon of The Financial Times, in particular, argued that users
were overcharged by $10 billion because of cartel-like tariff arrangements. Costs
for international calls were estimated at $0.25 to $0,50, but rates averaged $1
per minute. It was estimated that $30 billion in revenues would generate $20
billion in profits in 1990 (Dixon, 1990a). BT reported 60 percent profit rates
International Telecommunications Services 339
We will now turn briefly to some comparisons of carriers. As was stated in the
introduction to this book, this is not a comparative study in the sense of mea-
suring the performance of various countries' PTTs and issuing report cards.
The study is concerned more with vertical changes over time than with hori-
zontal cross-country analysis. However, some comparative data will be pro-
vided in the following section, largely from OECD figures. But first, it is nec-
essary to discuss the difficulties of cross-country analysis.
The difficulties inherent in any comparison task can be shown with the ex-
ample of Sweden's Televerket reporting of its own performance.
One Televerket study shows the number of working hours required for an
average industrial laborer to pay for annual fixed telecommunication service
basket (Roos and Loenqvist, 1984). In Sweden, the basket required thirty hours
of work. For Great Britain, in contrast, it was eighty hours; for France, sixty-
five; for Germany, fifty-five; and for the United States, fifty. But nowhere in
the report is the telecommunications "basket" defined, and attempts to obtain
that information from Televerket were unsuccessful. Mitchell (1983) comes to
very different conclusions in that forty-two hours of work purchased one year
of residential service in the United States. In Sweden, the same service requires
fifty-five hours; in the United Kingdom, ninety-eight; in Italy, 111; in Ger-
many, 126; and in France, 165. Clearly, every country has different prices and
usage patterns for different components, permitting arbitrary comparisons. In
the United States, there are very different rates among customer types and
340 international Telecommunications Services
geographic regions; there are alternative competing carriers and substantial off-
peak discounts. For example, while Televerket assumes that U.S. terminal
equipment is rented by users, most Americans buy it, since that is much cheaper.
The same study uses the average industrial wage as a measuring rod, which
creates a bias toward richer countries, and within these countries toward those
with strongly unionized economies, where industrial wages are relatively high.
Televerket uses for local rates New York City as a typical representative. Un-
fortunately, for a variety of reasons, New York is at the high-cost end.
It is also difficult to define services. In the United States, operator assistance
and itemized bills are included. Swedish network quality, as measured by the
percentage of unsuccessful calls due to overload or technical faults, was at 2.4
percent of trunk calls in 1985 (Televerket, 1986, p. 9). In the United States,
the percentage of unsuccessful trunk calls was 1 percent for only twenty peak
hours per year, with the other times being lower.
It appears that in some comparisons virtually every judgment call ends up
with unfavorable assumptions, or noninclusion of favorable factors. Although
some simplifications are unavoidable, an analysis should not consistently err to
one side if it is to shed light.
In the decade between 1972 and 1982 alone, at least fourteen international
comparative studies of residential telephone rates were undertaken (see Mitch-
ell, 1983). Subsequent comparisons include Siemens (1988); Logica (1989);
McDowall (1987); and Morton and Donovan (1987). The results vary widely
but are consistent insofar as they usually favor the sponsoring administration.
Normally, the definition of the basket (local versus long-distance) can strongly
affect results, depending on the extent of subsidization of local calls. Given the
large number of variables to be considered and judgments to be made, one
could conduct defensible statistical studies that would show probably several
countries as the cheapest telephone country.
Perhaps the most thorough comparative study of rates and quality is a lengthy
OECD report issued in 1990. But it too makes numerous assumptions that are
problematic for the U.S. system, which has a structure considerably different
from European ones.
The OECD methodology uses an average ratio between fixed and usage-
sensitive charges (2:3 for residential subscribers 1:4 for business users). In ap-
plying these ratios to the U.S. situation, the OECD study apparently does not
take into account the fact that most U.S. monthly residential fixed service charges
include provisions for unlimited local calling. It is hard to understand how the
study could find residential fixed charges of $175.10, higher than those of busi-
ness charges, which were calculated at $174.67 (OECD 1990, p. 46). This
misconception skews the subsequent analysis. Other assumptions are similarly
unfavorable, such as the use of New York City as the comparison city; the
absence of quality factors; the lack of credit for operator availability and item-
ized billing; the assumption of AT&T as long-distance carrier; and the use of
only partial off-peak discounts.
The study itself concedes that: "on balance, the model works best for the
countries of Western Europe which tend to have similar tariff structures and
International Telecommunications Services 341
342
Figure 32.2 and 32.2a. OECD Basket of Residential Telephone Charges, in US$
Exchange Rates and PPPs, November 1989. (Source: OECD, 1990, p. 53.)
343
Source: OECD Tariff Comparison Model.
Figure 32.3 and 32.3a. OECD Basket of International Telephone Charges,
Ranked by Country, November 1989. (Source: OECD, 1990, p. 61.)
344
Source: OECD Tariff Comparison Model.
Figure 32.4 and 32.4a. OECD Basket of Mobile Telephone Charges, Ranked by
Country, November 1989. (Source: OECD, 1990, p. 64.)
345
Figure 32.5. Basket of Charges for 1.5/2.0 Mbit/s Leased Lines. (Source: OECD, 1990, p. 70.)
Figure 32.6. Waiting Time for Telephone Installation, Selected OECD Member Countries, 1979-1987. (Source: OECD, 1990, p. 126.)
348 International Telecommunications Services
costs in the U.S. $267 using MCI. For 2 megabits per second capacity, prices
in Europe ranged from $3,415 (Mercury) to $49,044 (DBF Telekom). Other
major European countries charged more than $10,000. In the United States,
this service is offered by U.S. Sprint for $3,100 (upwardly prorated T-l line)
(Hey wood, 1991).
Price is not the only performance dimension of significance. OECD figures
adapted from the ITU statistics reveal great variation in the amount of time it
took to obtain telephone service (Figure 32.6). The OECD average shows a
significant drop in the amount of waiting time between 1979 and 1987 to around
ten months, and the installed base of main lines grew 37 percent. Potential
subscribers in Greece and Turkey had to wait six and seven years, respectively,
for installation. This stood in stark contrast to the situation in Denmark and
Finland, where waiting time was negligible. Greece was the only country among
those shown where the wait actually increased between 1979 and 1987, while
at the same time its installed base of main lines increased 71.1 percent. Portu-
gal and Ireland both cut waiting periods significantly between 1979 and 1987,
but still ranked weak on this dimension.
The growth rates of installed lines in OECD countries for the same eight-
year period were remarkable (see also Figure 32.6), with Turkey (211 percent),
France (106 percent), and Ireland (93 percent) leading the way. Growth was
International Telecommunications Services 349
The past chapters have discussed the evolution taking place in various coun-
tries. The next sections will deal with more general issues of European com-
munications. The first of them is ISDN.
The Setting
350
The Economics of ISDN Integration 351
equipment. It thus provides the capability to dispense with parallel lines for
analog voice and for digital services and instead puts them together in one
integrated bit stream of digitalized voice and data.
As long as ISDN simply implies no more, it is hard to find fault with this
development, which is part of a broad technological trend. ISDN, however, is
more than such upgrading, in Europe and elsewhere; it is also part of a business
and political strategy of telephone administrations. "Integration" is thus not
simply an issue of technology.
Economies of Scope
networks can provide a competitive environment that can lead to cost reduc-
tions and technical innovation. In other words, the cost curves in a separate
environment can be dynamic. What starts out as the cost relation C(V) and
C(D) can become, under rivalry, C'(V) and C'(D), with the assumption that
(3)
The integrated network should then be more accurately required to meet the
condition
(4)
Economies of Scale
V D (V+D)
F 8 9 16
R 11 12 21
(F + R) 16 20 35
V D (V + D)
F 9 10 19
R 11 6 17
(F + R) 20 16 36
preventing users from moving toward superior technology that they would oth-
erwise choose, by signalling to them that they will lose the benefits of leaving
the coalition around the major standard that the monopolist controls (Farrell
and Saloner, 1986b).
The investment in a major upgrading of the network has the effect of raising
barriers to entry in the following ways: First, it increases the required initial
investment that a potential rival needs to match the upgraded technical capabil-
ities of the existing network. Second and similarly, where there is a trade-off
between fixed costs and marginal costs, as there often is, the latter are lowered
by the investment, making it more difficult for a rival to enter and match mar-
ginal cost pricing. Third, by raising the initial investment, one can stretch the
range of economies of scale (declining average cost) and thus of "natural mo-
nopoly." The trough of a U-shaped cost curve is shifted to a higher level of
production by an increase in fixed costs.
The theoretical analysis of the past sections demonstrated that the economic
case for ISDN, on purely analytical grounds, has not been made persuasively.
Empirical figures have not been presented in support of ISDN which would
prove the advantages of integration in light of the issues discussed earlier. This
is not to say that such a case cannot be made. However, the battles over ISDN
have never been fought on the grounds of economics. To understand why, one
has to go back to the history of ISDN. This will be done in the next chapter.
34
The Political Economy of ISDN
360
The Political Economy of ISDN 361
perts may see ISDN merely as a technical issue, but massive investment pro-
grams are rarely free of other considerations. ISDN is no exception, unless one
entirely ignores the historic struggles over exclusivity in which most major
PTTs are engaged.
A similar implicit assertiveness to expand the range of the PTTs' activities
also lies in the potential of future integrated broadband networks (B-ISDN, or
IBN). This is likely to become a major issue. The cost of glass fiber terminal
equipment will soon permit the use of fiber to a point near the home or even
into it. The development of broadband switching has also progressed enor-
mously. Given these favorable technological and economic trends, telephone
carriers will be able in the foreseeable future to provide video program services
(even switched ones), and become rivals of traditional cable television carriers
and over-the-air transmitters. Conversely, cable carriers could engage in alter-
native local telecommunications transmission, challenging the FTT exclusivity
over the local loop (Noam, 1986). The British government's duopoly review
of 1990 recognized and encouraged such evolution. 1
The conflict of telecommunications providers with the computer industry
centered on IBM. For a long time, many Europeans endowed IBM with near-
mythical abilities, which justified drastic government actions. The preoccupa-
tion with IBM led to recommendations to use telecommunications, which gov-
ernments control, as a lever over the computer industry, now that the two
sectors are overlapping. This strategy was spelled out in the influential 1978
Nora-Mine report to the French president, which was discussed earlier, and
which, with its combination of brilliance, gloom, and nationalism, deeply in-
fluenced French and European policymakers and intellectuals.
Controlling the network system is thus an essential objective. This requires that its
framework be designed to serve the public. But it is also necessary for the state to
define access standards; otherwise the manufacturers will, utilizing the available
routes but subjecting them to their own protocols. The level of standardization will
thus shift the boundary between the manufacturers and the telecommunications or-
ganizations; it will be a bitter struggle, since it will develop out of a reciprocal
play for influence. But the objective of public control indicates the strategy to
follow: increase the pressure in favor of standardization [Nora and Mine, 1980, pp.
74-75].
ISDN and its standardization thus promised to be a tool of the kind advocated
by Nora and Mine at the time when ISDN planning moved into its serious
stage.
[SJince only two other countries out of 159 members of the International Telecom-
munication Union (ITU) have any aspect of competition in their carrier industry,
technical decisions made in this forum have a tendency to be biased toward mo-
nopoly. This is not to imply that other countries seek to impose their industry
structure on the United States intentionally; rather they are focusing on their own
situations and honestly do not understand the implications of the US industry struc-
ture [Marcus, 1985, p. 33].
The FCC declared that customer provision of the network termination device
(NT1) should be a national option.2 It described as fundamental that CCITT
recommendations must be flexible enough for national options and that the
American distinction between basic and enhanced services must be maintained.
It turned out to be complicated to work out the proper interface point be-
tween the domain of the network and that of the users. Essentially, three de-
marcation points are possible, known, respectively, as the S, T, and U points
in CCITT terminology. The S point is closest to the end user, and hence carries
the network-controlled portion furthest upstream.3 The PTTs wanted point 5 as
the interface between user and network because they could control equipment
The Political Economy of ISDN 363
Hegemonic ISDN
ISDN has always meant different things to different people, from a simple and
partial upgrading of digitalization to more ambitious undertakings encompass-
ing everything up to video transmission. However, recent international stan-
dardization efforts have narrowed the term for the present. But these different
definitions revolve around technology. A different classification of ISDN is
based on its purpose: it distinguishes "hegemonic" from "upgrade" ISDN.
The latter is a step in the technical evolution of telecommunications. The for-
mer, on the other hand, is part of a general attempt at maintaining control over
networks.
The key element of the coalition between bureaucracy and established equip-
ment manufacturers is strongly evident in the discussions on ISDN, and for
good reason. In most European countries, the decades following World War II
were periods of very active expansion in telecommunications. The combination
of war-damage repair and the expansion of telephone penetration from the busi-
ness and upper classes to universal use has kept telephone authorities busy and
manufacturers profitable. But this expansion reached its natural plateau when
most households were served. Whereas in 1960, only some 20 percent of the
German households had telephones, by 1982, over 80 percent did. In France,
after a major development push, penetration by 1984 was over 80 percent. The
implications for equipment manufacturers were clear; the domestic market was
close to saturation in terms of standard equipment and would decline; this would
leave them only with the export market, of which, according to an OECD
study, only 15 percent was free from protectionism. Furthermore, the absence
of a strong domestic market is also likely to make exports more costly, since
they would not benefit from economies of scale in production. One way to
activate the sagging domestic market was therefore to launch an ambitious pro-
gram of upgrading, and ISDN was just such a project. Figure 34.1 illustrates,
for Germany, the role of ISDN digital upgrade for both transmission and switching
(Schon, 1985).
The PTTs, seeking support for their domestic position, courted their tradi-
tional allies by dangling ISDN before them. Germany's Bundespost, for ex-
ample, argued that ISDN was important for the export success of domestic
industry and that it required the ability of the Bundespost to play a role in the
equipment supply field, a role that was under attack by Germany's Monopoly
Commission and the Ministry of Economics.
The PTT that takes on the leading role internationally when a new service is stan-
dardized gives the communications industry in their country a big head start in this
364 The Political Economy of ISDN
service. . . . The Deutsche Bundespost has so far played a prominent part in this
context. . . . Anyone who blocks this influence in his own country damages the
innovative force of a future technology and ultimately the entire economy [Schon,
1984, p. 22; emphasis in originall. 5
trast, raised entry barriers by providing a highly integrated network. ONA un-
bundles, whereas ISDN consolidates.
The concept of open network architecture must be distinguished from the
similarly named open systems interconnection (OS I) of the International Orga-
nization for Standardization which provides a definitional framework of seven
broad layers of the entire network process. ONA takes this further by not only
going into more detailed subfunctions of several of these layers, but also pro-
posing their functional separation, together with a business and regulatory pol-
icy concept. It must also be distinguished from the E.C.'s Open Network Pro-
vision, a concept that established access for value-added services, especially
across European frontiers, and which is much less far-reaching in its unbun-
dling.
A preliminary variant of ONA is also known as comparably efficient inter-
connection, or CEI.6 The FCC required the major carriers to submit ONA plans
in 1988 as a step in its evolution. The states (most notably New York and
California) also began to evolve ONA regulatory concepts (Noam, 1988a).
ONA is a framework of network components that disaggregate in such a way
as to permit open access; it operates on the concept that all central office func-
tions consist of fundamental components or Basic Service Elements (BSEs) and
that these components can and should be unbundled. Different communications
services use different BSEs, or different configurations of them, sequenced in
various ways. The open network architecture permits the use by outside parties
(users or third-party service providers) of the building blocks of their choice.
Where any of the blocks could be provided cheaper or better from another
supplier, it could be substituted and combined with BSEs or equipment of the
local exchange company. In other words, competition would exist for the var-
ious functions of the central exchange switch by unbundling its multiple func-
tions. To make such a system work, service providers conceivably could in
some instances collocate their own nodes on the physical premises of the local
exchange company. The third-party service providers are partly a form of value-
added networks, competing physical networks on the local level, and simple
resellers. In all of these functions they would compete head on with the local
exchange companies, who act both as retailers and as wholesalers of these
services (Noam, 1989).
Through ONA, local exchange carriers in effect permit the resale of separate
parts of their services, down to separate functions of the local exchange. This
is a radical reversal of past practice, where the monopolistic telephone compa-
nies tried to prevent resale. Now they have begun to recognize that their net-
work is their prime asset and that they should sell its capabilities as much as
possible, to the point of encouraging use by outsiders. In this fashion, the
network can be utilized more and a telephone company can still profit.
Once the building blocks are separated from each other, a pricing mechanism
need be put into place that can establish transparent and nondiscriminatory pric-
ing. For those building blocks where competition exists, deregulation can be
instituted. Elsewhere, tariffed rates would be set. Clearly, a wide array of com-
plex regulatory questions needs to be resolved in the process of introducing
366 The Political Economy of ISDN
ONA (Marks, 1986; Noam, 1988b, c). For example, the FCC announced the
possibility of extending ONA in the future into basic service access arrange-
ments (BSAs) of the local carriers. This step was taken by the New York State
Public Service Commission, which established ONA rights for basic transport
and created a type of access (collocation) in which alternative transport provid-
ers can physically locate their equipment in the central offices of the traditional
carriers, and vice versa (or do so in a functionally equivalent, i.e., "virtual"
form). Collocation also permits alternative carriers to provide network monitor-
ing and control of their own.
In technical terms, the ONA approach is not contradictory to ISDN, since
an ISDN operator could similarly provide for the subdivision of its functions,
selling them separately and permitting various reconfigurations and resale to
third parties. This is likely to happen in the United States in the future. But
attitudinally, the ISDN concept, as presently held by its champions abroad, is
widely different. Whereas the open network architecture is another step in the
segmentation of American networks, the PTTs' purpose for ISDN is another
step in its centralization.
ONA is not the only move toward segmentation in central office switching.
Already mentioned were shared tenant services, by which multiple users share
a common (nonpartitional) PBX. This concept has already begun to move into
the clustering of office buildings and provides a nucleus of alternative central
switches (Noam, 1986). Another manifestation is the emergence of interorgan-
izational networks (lONs) or enterprise networks.
Europe's ONP seeks to harmonize conditions of access, usage, interopera-
bility, and data protection among the networks of E.G. member states by elim-
inating the need for special adaptation of services between countries; it thus
provides a framework for a pan-European liberalized market for value-added
services. In 1988, the B.C. commission outlined its goals for ONP, including
the gradual establishment of technical standards, rules of interconnection, and
equal access to value-added services (Ungerer, 1989). Decisions concerning
technical standards were referred to the European Telecommunications Stan-
dards Institute (ETSI). Parameters were developed concerning service quality,
shared use, and resale of network capacity. Also, the commission intends to
implement a mutual recognition process of authorization for services, whereby
one member state can certify a supplier to serve the entire European Commu-
nity.
ONP has none of the unbundling elements of ONA and its establishment of
central office subfunctions, nor its related collocation and transport competi-
tion. (Avoiding the latter two is also the position of the American local ex-
change telephone companies.) Yet ONP, while a modest step, nevertheless cre-
ated a European rift.
Several PTTs (those of France, Italy, Belgium, Greece, and Portugal) were
reluctant to accept the liberal ONP guidelines. A compromise was reached. The
French proposed the licensing of data service providers, but the B.C. retained
approval of licensing procedures. Less-developed European countries were given
The Political Economy of ISDN 367
Outlook
The past two chapters have asserted that the issue of integration stands for
much more fundamental questions of control over the telecommunications net-
work.
In a wider sense, it is part of a contest over where the intelligence in the
network resides (i.e., at the center or the periphery), who controls it (users or
network operators), who builds it (the telecommunications or the computer in-
dustry), and who runs the network (public providers or private ones).
Whether "segmentation" or "integration" are optimal solutions for net-
works is a matter that cannot be determined a priori. It is a trade-off of four
economic principles in two combinations: the efficiency of specialized produc-
tion and of a competitive environment versus the productivity contributions of
economies of scale and scope and the reduction of uncertainty. One cannot
generalize on which might work best.
35
Value-Added Networks and Services
369
370 Value-Added Networks and Services
sessions a day (Link Resources, 1984). In 1986, GTE Telenet was combined
into GTE's joint venture with United Telecommunications, soon dominated by
the latter, which in turn contributed its own Uninet (levels 2 and 3) and a
substantially fiber-optic physical network (level 1).
Tymnet was originally an internal operation of Tymshare, but its initial ad-
vantage of having a customer base of time-sharing computer users turned out
to be a problem later on, as time-sharing went into a steep decline with the
advent of inexpensive mini- and microcomputers. Users typically accessed the
packet-switched networks' nodes either through leased lines (digital or analog)
or through a regular public dial-up line. Tymnet and its parent Tymshare were
acquired by the aircraft manufacturer McDonnell Douglas, which resold it in
1989 to British Telecom.1
Other U.S. entrants were Graphic Scanning (Graphnet), PCI, CompuServe
Network, Autonet, MarkNet, Cylix, IBM Information Network, and MCI Data
Transport and EDS.2
In 1986, the FCC's Computer III ruling established the important policy
concept of open network architecture (ONA), discussed in the previous chapter
of this book. Under ONA, VANs can obtain special unbundled service ele-
ments from the telephone carriers, add network building blocks of their own
choice, and add their own blocks to them.
million), and GE Information Services ($450 million). Tymnet (BT after 1989)
and Istel (owned by AT&T after 1990) were the fourth and sixth largest pro-
viders, with revenues of $430 million and $170 million in 1989.
In some instances, technical problems slowed the spread of VANs. In 1988,
a survey by an end-user association found a failure rate of 25 percent in 5700
attempted data calls (Lill, 1988). Similar large-scale surveys found a 24 percent
failure rate in 1989 and 25 percent in 1990 (18.7 percent failing for telecom-
munications reasons) (Roussel, 1989; Schenker, 1990a).3
Another barrier to VAN services was the high cost of leased lines. A 1989
report noted that the average cost in Europe of 9.6 kbps leased-lines was, on
average, $1,500 for national circuits and $2,400 for international circuits. But
for national service, Spain charged eleven times that amount ($16,000) and
Germany's tariffs were six times costs. On international circuits, Italy charged
a 1700 percent markup, to $42,500, followed by Spain ($31,000) and Sweden
($30,000) (Woollacott, 1989a). Another study claimed that most European PTTs
priced their public data networks too low and lost money on them, while leased
lines were priced very high (Purton, 1989).
In 1987, after many large European users expressed dissatisfaction with the
CCITT X.25 public packet-switched network structure, the European PTTs,
through CEPT, promoted a joint Managed Data Network Services project. But
the European Commission, concerned about cartel behavior, limited MDNS to
offering three pan-European services and restricted it from advanced gateways
and network management. The project was abandoned after a year, and the
PTTs focused on their own projects, such as Eucom, Tymnet, Infonet, and
Syncordia.
Infonet was the fifth largest European VAN. In 1989, it was acquired by a
powerful cast of owners: France Telecom, DBF Telekom, Telefonica, Belga-
com, PTT Netherlands, and the Swiss PTT. MCI held the largest share, 25
percent. The European Commission investigated France Telecom, the Bundes-
post, and others for conflicts of interest in their investments in Infonet.
In 1988, the DBF and France Telecom also formed Eunetcorn, a joint ven-
ture for industry-specific VANs. In 1991, several major carriersBritish Te-
lecom, DBP Telekom, and NTTannounced their intention to set up a global
facilities management service named Syncordia, possibly with France Telecom.
The following sections describe the more important upper-level VAN services.
Voice Mail
Voice messaging (also known as VSR, or voice storage and retrieval, not to be
confused with electronic mail) is a service that permits a computer to store
digitalized voice messages, like an answering machine. Different configurations
are possible: voice mail can be part of PBXs; it can be resold by service bur-
374 Value-Added Networks and Services
eaus; and it can be embedded in the central telephone switch. Typical level 4
users' applications of voice mail (level 3) are purchase-order-taking systems,
ticket reservations, scheduling of work crews, hospital paging, and hotel res-
ervations and guest messaging.
Electronic Mail
In Europe, CEPT has set standards for "e-mail" service known as teletext (not
to be confused with broadcast videotex known in many countries as teletext
too). Particularly active in the development was the German Bundespost and
the firm of Siemens. In the United States, electronic mail, much more hetero-
geneous, was offered by a number of firms. ITT's ailing Dialcom was acquired
by British Telecom in 1986.
Video Conferencing
Video conferencing is an active but commercially not particularly successful
area. Many large firms have video-conferencing facilities but do not use them
to capacity. Several U.S. hotel chains have nationwide interconnected video-
conferencing facilities.
Part of video conferencing's slow acceptance derives from the need for ex-
pensive dedicated studio-like conference rooms and wide-band transmission.
Both of these problems are being reduced through equipment capable of slow-
scan transmission and data compression and enhancement, which permit video
use in regular offices and require only one regular telephone line.
Telemetry
Alarm systems can be offered based on a new "derived channel transport" that
overlays the regular voice channel with a second narrow channel, creating an
independent transmission path for low-rate data. In addition to alarms, it can
be used for utility meter reading and for pay-per-view cable television control.
Alarm service can also be carried by cable television networks.
Call Forwarding
For some years, telephone service providers have offered enhanced services
such as call waiting, automatic call forwarding to other numbers, speed dialing,
and three-way calling.
Call Identification
New common channel signaling systems permit an identification of the incom-
ing call and make possible several features: call screening (blocking of unde-
sired callers), a selective call forwarding, identification of incoming call num-
bers, call-back of last number(s) that had called in but were not connected, and
special rings for preselected incoming calls, to permit, for example, separation
of incoming personal and business calls. These services are important in a
376 Value-Added Networks and Services
broader sense, since they give some measure of choice over the telecommuni-
cations process to the party being called, who in the past has had to guess at
the nature of the incoming call. They also permit verified billing arrangements.
They also raise important privacy issues.
percent. Participating banks derive benefits from the service because of reduced
transactions and better control of costs. A SWIFT message costs BFr 18 ($0.48)
independent of distance.
To start operating, SWIFT had to establish standards for international trans-
actions; these have since been instituted worldwide. The nature of its business
requires strict security measures. SWIFT accepts liability for all losses due to
errors or cheating, underscoring its confidence in the system. It has never had
to fulfill this guarantee. SWIFT achieves this level of security with a hierarchi-
cal network structure. Individual banks connect to national nodes (regional pro-
cessors or RPs) via leased or dialed lines. The RPs encrypt, store, and pass the
messages on to the System Control Centers (SCCs) in Washington, D.C. or
Leyden, Holland.4 In 1989, European, African, and Middle Eastern banks gen-
erated 68 percent of SWIFT's transactions. About 13 percent of messages came
from the Pacific Rim nations, and North America accounted for 18 percent
(Hayes, 1989).
To obtain its leased lines, SWIFT had to negotiate special arrangements with
each country. It pays a set amount per message plus a volume-based tariff; the
volume-based pricing often causes SWIFT to pay more than four times the
ordinary leased-line tariffs. The PTTs thus extract a premium from SWIFT for
leased lines, but this was also an advantage, since SWIFT obtained special
licenses when there was no similar offering. It is therefore more difficult for
new entrants to emerge.
In time, SWIFT encountered competition from IBM, which set up a global
banking network of its own, and from Reuters. Furthermore, some of SWIFT's
bigger members set up their own networks to counter what they see as SWIFT's
subsidization of smaller banks. Thus, the exit mechanism discussed in Chapter
4 applies also to subnetworks.
The SWIFT network grew from 27,000 messages daily in 1977 to 1 million
in 1989, and rapidly neared its capacity.5 A more advanced network, SWIFT
II, was authorized, and SWIFT chose Northern Telecom for network equip-
ment. It will be a distributed network, unlike the more centralized SWIFT I,
with more value-added services, including messaging and EDI. Fast-packet
switching was introduced in 1991.
The following services are part of the variety of specific applications of level
4 VAN-type services that have emerged. Several other applications have al-
ready been mentioned.
Outlook
The list of VAN services and applications is not indicative of their commercial
or technical success. There is no reason to assume that today's mix of offerings
is more than temporary. It would not be surprising if half of today's offerings
and services would be gone in a few years and replaced by other services and
offerers. Given the rapid developments in hardware, software, and user orga-
nizations, the main attribute of a VAN system is not predictability of success
but flexibility of process. It is hard to see how restrictive rules on VANs could
be effective in the long run. If VAN services are successfuland it is impor-
tant to a competitive economy that they arethey will dance electronic circles
around the restrictions.
When it comes to policy liberalization, VANs ride on the coattails of equip-
ment. A liberalization of equipment has meaning primarily when the equipment
can be used in varied ways. Conversely, one cannot expect dynamic VAN
development if users are limited in their choices of equipment to a few slowly
approved models. VANs can be important to manufacturers because much of
the pure equipment can become a merchant market, with East Asian countries
serving as the low-cost producers. Hence, a link of equipment to services, of
hardware to software, and of hardware elements to each other by networks can
be critical to competitiveness.
This raises a final question. Are VANs another instance of "supply-side
telecommunications," with appeal to computer enthusiasts, equipment manu-
facturers, and telecommunications carriers, but not to regular users? There is
no question that many VAN services have been excessively hyped, and the
reality invariably fails in comparison. In the aggregate, the VAN service indus-
try is not yet particularly large in dollar terms. In the United States, level 2
VANs (packet switching) were in 1988 estimated at $850 million; for the higher-
level application levels 3 and 4 they were about $1.5 billion. In comparison
with basic voice telephony, these amounts are trivial. However, the market is
very innovative and is developing expertise in fashioning configurations of users,
equipment, and services. A market cannot move much faster than the users,
which had to absorb entirely new systems, work procedures, and organizational
Value-Added Networks and Services 381
patterns. These things take time. But users are steadily becoming more appli-
cations-conscious; several industries have already reached the stage of depen-
dence on them. Thus, the VAN services sector is riding a favorable trend.
Today VANs are "discretionary" services. Over time, however, some of
them may become first essential, and then basic services, as happened to voice
telephony.
36
Videotex
Videotex emerged in 1970, when the British Post Office started work on its
viewdata system Prestel, with the aim of integrating the telephones, computers,
and the television sets. France followed suit in 1972 with Antiope. In Ger-
many, the Bundespost bought and built upon British rights in the development
of its Btx system. In 1979, Canada developed Telidon, which, unlike the oth-
ers, is based on a geometric rather than an alpha-mosaic display.
All systems contended before the CCITT for recognition as the single inter-
national standard. The American position held that it was too early to imple-
ment standardization because of the rapid development of technologies. Euro-
peans suspected that this view was based on the Americans' absence from the
forefront of videotex development. In 1980, the CCITT recognized three sys-
temsAntiope, Prestel, and Telidonand agreement on a common protocol
seemed impossible. In 1981, AT&T established its Presentation Level Protocol
(PLP), closely related to the Canadian standard. In 1982, the American Na-
tional Standards Institute (ANSI) agreed upon a more mature version of PLP,
the North American Presentation Level Protocol Standard (NAPLPS), and sub-
mitted it to the CCITT. The European PTTs agreed on a common overarching
CEPT standard in an attempt to harmonize their systems and make them com-
patible. They also induced other European countries, including Italy and Spain,
to join them in those CEPT standards, and launched an export offensive.
In the meantime, a variety of nonvideotex computer information host sys-
tems emerged in the United States. These host systems are accessed over tele-
phone lines by a microcomputer as a terminal and a modem, usually via a
packet-switched network such as Telenet or Tymnet. Other database providers
are accessed directly, without an intermediary host. The on-line service provi-
sion has become known as electronic publishing, and traditional and new pub-
lishers have entered the field. Compared to videotex, these on-line services
require more intelligent terminals, but they can also perform more tasks. With
the rapid decline in the cost of microcomputers and monitors, there has been a
great increase in the number of households with microcomputers. For these
users, access to databases such as computer and mail-box service becomes rel-
atively simple. These data services do not package the information in multico-
382
Videotex 383
lored graphics, as videotex often does. In 1990, there were about twenty-seven
million microcomputers in U.S. businesses and homesa much larger number
than Minitel terminals in France, and with greater intelligence of equipment.
Videotex offers primarily five basic types of services: information (such as
news, weather, financial data, and regional movie listings), commercial trans-
actions (such as airline ticket orders), closed user-group interactions, electronic
mail and mailboxes, and information processing. For the latter, an intercon-
nected computer system (such as the one implemented by the German Bundes-
post) facilitates customer use. In effect, a PTT's videotex system can operate
as a computer utility. With interconnection, it can also interact with computers
of other service vendors.
By 1990, videotex had not become a success in any European country, with
the exception of France, where over 5 million Minitel terminals had been dis-
tributed. Germany had 200,000 subscribers; Great Britain, 95,000; Italy, 100,000;
and the Netherlands, 28,000. All other countries had less than 5000. There
were only 5000 subscribers in Japan, and 10,000 in Canada, mostly for farm
reports.
The differing philosophies on telecommunications policy are reflected in four
countries' approach to videotex. Britain's service developed only slowly, caught
between the government's prevalent indecision between deregulatory tele-
communications policy and pro-active technology policy. In Germany, the Bun-
despost set up a huge centralized system and promoted it heavily, but demand
was low. In France, in contrast, the government was massively engaged in
direct subsidization, buying millions of terminals from domestic manufacturers
and literally giving them away. It financially supported the usage, information
production, and equipment, in the hope that in time the subsidized egg would
hatch a chicken. Usage has been brisk, but the costs of keeping the system
going have been high. In the United States, videotex was left to the market,
and the local Bell telephone companies were restricted to protect competition.
There is little videotex in America, though much usage of its on-line cousins.
First, we see them as two technological developments in that Britain now leads the
world and which must be promoted, because of the commercial and industrial ben-
efits which can accrue to the nation. Second, we see teletext and viewdata as swing
doors through which the country can gain an entry into what some people are
calling the "second microelectronics revolution." 1 mean, of course, information
technology. Third, it provides employment for set manufacturers, component man-
ufacturers, and software companies. The government is convinced that information
technology is going to be the key growth sector in this country's economy [British
Business, 1981, p. 1480].
Videotex in Germany
Videotex in France
the telecommunication fees. Teletel 2, which is for both private and commer-
cial usage and for which the user pays all communication costs, costs $0.08
per two minutes. And Teletel 3, or "Kiosk," which is also for private and
commercial usage, requires the user to pay the communication costs of $0.10
per minute plus a time-sensitive service fee. On the Kiosk system, there are
five levels of service fees, with the private providers and the telecommunica-
tions authority receiving varying proportions.
Penetration has been large because the terminals have been distributed at no
charge. Government support was also given to information providers to en-
courage them to use the medium.
France Telecom's own 1987 figures for total hours of usage divided by the
number of households results in an average monthly usage of sixty-two minutes
per household (Telematique News, 1987). Disregarding the revenue loss be-
cause of lower long-distance calling, and making the generous assumptions that
two-thirds of the network usage is newly generated traffic rather than replace-
ment of calls to airlines, for example, and that two-thirds of new revenue is
pure France Telecom profit, the added revenue should come to an average of
FFr 90 million (about $15 million) per month. At that rate, a terminal, which
costs about FFr 2000, is paid for in about five years.
For the total actual and planned Minitel investment of FFr 17 billion from
1984 to 1995, 54 percent goes toward the development of Minitel, 18 percent
to the packet-switched network Transpac, 15 percent for additional lines, and
13 percent for the DOT network. Annual investment costs are FFr 1.5 billion
($240 million). At the present utilization and revenue rate given earlier, annual
system investments per subscriber are FFr 750 ($150), while revenues are only
FFr 550 ($90) (T. Vedel, 1988, communication).
The financial performance of the project is not readily apparent, sin'ce several
public subsidies are involved. In 1984, Teletel expenses were FFr 2 billion
($320 million) and brought in FFr 407 million ($68 million). According to
French critic Jacques Darmon, there will be a permanent deficit (Darmon, 1985,
p. 108). France Telecom disputes this, claiming that Teletel increases usage of
the network.
On the revenue side of France Telecom performance, there are a number of
empirical and conceptual problems to overcome. France Telecom discloses rev-
enue and minutes of usage on Teletel, but it does not provide net figures. A
Teletel call for travel information provides revenues, but at the same time it may
replace a regular telephone call. Indeed, the distance-insensitive (local) Teletel
call may replace toll calls, thus causing a net revenue loss. Similarly, an elec-
tronic directory assistance call replaces the revenues of a similar call to a human
operator.
In addition, not all revenues of new types of calls, such as those of the chat-
lines, should be allocated to Teletel per se. Such conversations could have oc-
curred on privately provided bulletin boards or computer conference systems. In
the Unites States, there are about 25,000 such systems, many of which are ar-
ranged by teenagers and computer hackers. The resources of the centralized state
are not required to accomplish communications among the people. Thus, even
388 Videotex
Changing a screw on a Minitel takes a year! Then there is the price. Our ambition
is to see the price of the Minitel reduced. To give it the advantage of added func-
tions would condemn us to pay more, and just imagine the FIT having to manage
a market of several million microcomputers which would very quickly become
obsolete. That would be untenable. And who would rapidly develop software for
these micros? Not the PTT! We are not a service company [Clavaud, 1984, p. 37].
At France Telecom, there are two contrasting strategies for the future devel-
opment of the Minitel. One strategy advocates the rapid development of an
intelligent second-generation Minitel in order to forestall the flood of cheap
microcomputers. The other stresses the expansion of the market for the first-
generation Minitel by freely distributing the terminals and allowing the private
market to supply more advanced attachments.
France has exported Teletel development worldwide. In the United States,
the Minitel Services Company has made French services available over Bell-
South, US West, and Southwestern Bell gateways. In 1987, Intelmatique estab-
lished Minitelnet, an international interconnection service with Transpac.
Agreements with Germany, Belgium, and Luxembourg to permit access to its
services were reached in 1988, and in 1989 Intelmatique made services avail-
able to Japan's Mitsui Knowledge Industry Co., complete with a Japanese lan-
guage interface. Switzerland and Spain also allowed interconnection with the
Minitel network, as did Italy in 1990. Also, in 1989 Mercury considered adopt-
ing the French standard for its service instead of the Prestel system. However,
despite the number of countries reached, only 30,000 hours of connection time
out of 85 million hours of total traffic came from outside France in 1989, or
390 Videotex
0.05 percent of total traffic (France Telecom News, 1990; Roussel and Rock-
well, 1989).
For all its birth-pains that were described above, French engineering in the
videotex field is indisputably outstanding. As an example of forward looking
government strategy, Teletel may well provide a triumph in the future. This
high visibility project can succeed in technical, social, and economic terms,
and prove the viability of videotexand more generally of PTT supportin
establishing a critical mass for a new information service.
Many other European nations have experimented with videotex and similar
electronic information services. None have matched the penetration of the French
system.
In Finland, databases and data processing industries have developed at a fast
pace, and the country's dynamic publishing industry has been a leader in de-
veloping electronic information services. The remote access data processing
industry is fairly open to outside suppliers. Finland was the second country to
offer videotex, known as Teleset; it was started experimentally in 1978 by the
Helsinki Telephone Company, together with Nokia Electronics (equipment) and
the Sanoma Corporation (information), using a Prestel-like system. Teleset
standards conform to European standards. American DEC computers are used;
decoders are supplied by the two Finnish TV set manufacturers. The informa-
tion provided is primarily business and consumer information, news, statistical
data, and local municipal announcements. No P&T license is necessary for
videotex, but initially the P&T unsuccessfully argued that videotex, as a text
transmission, was part of its monopoly on "telegraphy." The P&T also oper-
ates its own videotex operation, Telset, which had some paying subscribers in
its Helsinki system (Howkins, 1982). Other local telephone companies in Turku
and Tampere also followed the model, entering cooperative ventures with
newspaper publishers.
In Italy, videotex services are provided by a number of STET subsidiaries
SARIN, SIP, and SEAT. In 1980, these services began experimental operation
under the name Videotel, and the telephone company, SIP, has operated vid-
eotex on a regular basis since 1986. Users can access the host computer, lo-
cated in Milan, from throughout the country with a local call. Videotel is base
on Italtel and CEPT standards, and concentrates on business subscribers. SARIN
handles the engineering and market research aspects of telematics. It develops
the mainframe and system software to support Italy's Mediatel terminals and
provides the X.25 and Italpac packet-switched services. On the marketing side,
SARIN offers telemarketing, advertising services and user profiles, all geared
toward encouraging on-line usage.1
In the United States there have been several unsuccessful pilot videotex proj-
ects in the period from 1981 to 1985, including such companies as the New
York Times and AT&T, in Coral Gables, Florida; Time, Inc., and AT&T, in
Videotex 391
Computers and information storage led to fears about the use and abuse of
electronic data.' The tremendous ability of computers to store vast amounts of
information, to centralize individual data from a large number of sources, and
to recall and disseminate it rapidly makes this new technology an effective tool
for government surveillance and business power. For example, government in-
392
Transborder Data Flows 393
plete, up-to-date, and relevant to the needs of the collector; use of the data
ought to be specified at the time of collection, and its disclosure should be in
conformity with the purpose of collection; assurances must be made against
unauthorized access, use, and disclosure; and data should be open to inspection
and correction by the individual to whom it refers (OECD, 1979).
The Council of Europe had considered privacy issues since 1969. In 1980,
it incorporated the OECD guidelines in a convention on the Protection of In-
dividuals with Regard to Automatic Processing of Personal Data. The proposal
achieved binding status after ratification in 1985 by a majority of Council of
Europe members. The convention affected all transborder data flow among Eu-
ropean countries and with other countries, such as the United States. Multina-
tional firms became nervous about all this, since the convention provided that
any country could restrict the transmission of data to another country that did
not have data protection legislation comparable to its own or that had not rati-
fied the convention. This provided a means of affecting transnational opera-
tions. Theoretically, any country could restrict the flow of data to other coun-
tries by the simple device of raising the level of its own privacy protection.
Since firms conducting international transactions generally prefer to have uni-
form procedures for transactions in various countries, procedures were likely
to conform to the strictest of the national rules.
In 1985, the OECD's ICCP adopted a Data Declaration on transborder data
flows as a more specific framework for data flow policy, or "rules of the road
on TDF" (Robinson, 1990). TDF issues were also examined by the U.N.'s
Intergovernmental Bureau for Informatics (IBI) a Rome-based Third World-
oriented communications body that eventually folded for financial reasons.
UNESCO also showed involvement (Roche, 1984). The United Nations' Cen-
ter on Transnational Corporations similarly initiated a TDF project to increase
developed and developing countries' sensitivity on the issue (Sauvant, 1986).
Even the Vatican took a position: "There is important work to be done to
harmonize [national regulations] at the international level and finalize them by
using suggestions coming from different social contexts and by employing con-
tinuing technological developments" (in Pipe, 1984a).
Europe-wide efforts at ensuring privacy continued with a 1989 Council of
Europe recommendation on protection of personal data used for employment
purposes (TDR, 1989). In 1991, the E.C. passed a directive covering also man-
ual files, and forcing legislation by member states. Yet, at the same time,
European police data collaboration was substantially upgraded (Masden, 1992).
France
In 1974, a Commission on Information Policy and Civil Liberties was estab-
lished within the Ministry of Justice to regulate databases and protect individual
Transborder Data Flows 395
Germany
As mentioned, the state of Hesse enacted the first data protection law in 1970;
in 1977, a national law was passed. The discussion of data privacy in Germany
in the 1970s was colored by a fierce debate over how to contain a small group
of political extremists who engaged in terrorism. Data issues were described as
a choice between Datenschutz versus Tatenschutz (protection of data versus
protection of criminal deeds). Social Democrats were concerned with protection
of employees' privacy. Law-and-order conservatives, on the other hand, pushed
for elaborate police matching of various databases in order to identify potential
criminal suspects. They also supported a national machine-readable personal
identification card that would permit the tracking of individual movement; this
led to an anti-data-collection backlash. The 1983 national census was opposed
by many groups, and in an important decision, the Federal Constitutional Court
invalidated the holding of the census on the grounds of "informational self-
determination." In the meantime, several social democratic states pushed ahead
with their own legislation. In the state of Hessen, for example, the automated
processing of medical and psychological data is prohibited where information
is judgmental rather than factual. The use of data laws was not confined to
matters of privacy. It also provided a lever in other disputes. A 1984 decision
of the German High Court for Industrial Relations required the express consent
of a workers' council for the introduction of a computer system that would be
used to collect information on the performance of data technicians. The deci-
sion gave unions some influence over computerization where it affects employ-
ment security.
In 1988, telecommunications regulations were instituted that provided some
protection in calling identification and collection of subscriber data through
ISDN. Data compiled on Btx videotex and Temex may be used only for billing
and must be erased six months after collection (Gebhardt, 1990). Unification
extended privacy laws into the Eastern Lander.
United Kingdom
In the United Kingdom, the Advisory Council on Applied Research and Devel-
opment (ACARD), a consultative body to the prime minister and the cabinet,
recommended that one government agency coordinate all policies concerning
information technology and its applications, development, and operations. In
November 1982, the government adopted ACARD's recommendation by appoint-
ing a minister of state for industry and information technology to serve under
the secretary of state for industry. It was the first such appointment anywhere.
In response to another ACARD recommendation and spurred by the Council
of Europe's Convention on Data Protection, which the United Kingdom signed
in 1981, the government introduced a bill that eventually became the Data
Protection Act 1984. The Act requires the registration of data banks containing
personal information and sets other limitations on data collection and access
(Niblett, 1984). The home secretary designated as the first data protection re-
Transborder Data Flows 397
gistrar a computer expert, Eric Howe. Initially critical of the legislation, the
data-processing industry was partly mollified by Howe's appointment. The du-
ties of the registrar include the establishment of public files of data users and
data-processing bureaus. He is also an ombudsman for complaints of data abuse
and inaccessibility of records. Data subjects have the right to a copy of the data
held about them, and if such information is not provided, they may complain
to the registrar or to a court, both of which are empowered to order access.
There is also a right to compensation for damages resulting from inadequate
data security precautions. By 1990, approximately 153,000 companies and or-
ganizations with computerized lists of information on individuals had registered
with the Home Office representing 130,000 data users (Sixth Report of the Data
Distribution Registrar, 1990, p. 22).2
In 1987, the United Kingdom adopted a Model Code of Practice for telecom-
munications service operators that forbids unauthorized dissemination of data
on users (Gebhardt, 1990).
Privacy is not an absolute value. As the traditional clash between the privacy
rights of the individual and the free speech rights of the press illustrates, dif-
ferent societal objectives must be balanced against each other. It is by no means
clear that a maximum of privacy is desirable. If files that included personal
information could not be maintained, it would be difficult for the press to de-
velop an investigative story or for banks to extend credit.
Free speech is perhaps the main consideration that must be balanced against
the data privacy principle. Western democracies guarantee freedom of speech
in their constitutions. Labeling some types of speech "information flows" and
subjecting them to restrictive rules of a tradelike nature does not remove the
constitutional protection. Thus, the U.S. government may not enter into agree-
ments restricting the free speech of its citizens without subjecting itself to court
challenges.
Privacy protection can conflict with other societal interests. Law enforcement
is a consideration, as is technological advancement. Other countervailing fac-
tors to consider are protection of consumers (who may be preyed upon by third
parties whose identity is being protected), operational ease for networks, and
conflicting privacy interests. Although these factors do not obviate the need for
privacy protection, they suggest that a balancing of interests needs to take place.
Privacy, broadly defined, consists of two distinguishable but related aspects:
1. The protection against intrusion by unwanted information. This is some-
times termed "the right to be left alone" (Warren and Brandeis, 1890),
analogous to the constitutional protection to be secure in one's home against
intrusion by government.
2. The ability to control information about oneself and one's activities; this
is related in some ways to proprietary protection accorded to other forms
of information through copyright laws.5 A related aspect is the protection
of information about oneself from being tampered with by others.
The common aspect of both these elements is that they establish a barrier to
information flows between the individual and society at large. In the first case,
it is a barrier against informational outflows.
The concept of privacy is not without its detractors. There are three major
criticisms:
1. "Only the guilty need privacy." To the contrary, privacy is one of the
touchstones of a civilized and free society.6 Authoritarian or backward
societies do not value a private sphere, since they rarely respect individ-
uality and subordinate it to the demands of rulers or social groups.7
2. "Privacy is a drag on the economy." Privacy protections raise the cost
of information search. Potential employers and buyers, for example, would
have to spend more effort and money to find out who they are dealing
with if access to personal information is restricted. Deception becomes
easier, and transaction costs rise (Posner, 1981).
400 Transborder Data Flows
But there are also good economic arguments for privacy. It ensures
the ability of companies and organizations to hold on to their trade secrets
and details of their operations and to protect themselves from leaks of
insider information and against governmental intrusion. Information often
has actual value, and since much of it has no protection through property
rights, it must be protected through confidentiality or secrecy.8 To permit
its easy breach9 would lead to a lesser production of such information. It
has been shown in a theorem by Noam and Greenawalt (1979) that under
normal conditions "information of value, once released to one person (or
very few persons at most) will spreadin the absence of collusion
to all participants." Hence, the absence of privacy protection to stem out-
flow of information will lead to suboptimal production of such informa-
tion.
Similarly, anonymity may increase economic risk taking (though in-
crease risk for the partners to a transaction); certain investments may be
curtailed if the identity of their investors were disclosed. In that sense,
privacy protection acts as a spur to investment, as does the protection of
limited liability offered to corporations. (Of course, illegal activities are
also made easier.)
The loss of privacy also leads to inefficiency in information flows, just
as excessive privacy protection may. In the absence of privacy, people
use all kinds of hints or codes to reduce the outflow of information. Or
they may meet face to face instead of using the telephone.
Partly in response to economic and social needs, many transactions
have been specifically accorded special informational protection, known
as privileges (e.g., between attorney and client, penitent and clergy, pa-
tient and doctor, citizen and census taker). The idea in each case is that
the protection of information leads to a socially superior result even if it
is inconvenient in an individual instance to others.
3. "Privacy is of interest to a small elite only." To the contrary, attention
to privacy is widely shared. For example, according to information from
the New York Telephone Co., 34 percent of all residential households in
Manhattan and 24 percent of all its residential households in the state
have unpublished telephone numbers at subscribers' request. Most police-
men, doctors, or judges, to name but a few professionals, have unlisted
numbers. Elsewhere, it appears that the spread of unlisting is still further
advanced, reaching 55 percent in California.10
Pacific Bell planned in 1986 to sell subscriber information such as new
phone orders; more than 75,000 complaints came in, and the company
backed off.''
Sovereignty
The fact that foreign institutions and governments have access to domestic data
can be troublesome to many countries. A 1979 Canadian study found that nearly
50 percent of U.S.-based information bureaus storing data on Canadian trans-
actions would have provided data access to U.S. organizations such as credit
bureaus, law enforcement agencies, employers insurance firms, and govern-
ment agencies (CCITCS, 1979).
Similarly, Sweden became alarmed when the fire department of the city of
Malmo accessed data on chemical storage and truck routing on a computer of
the American firm TRW, located in Cleveland, Ohio. Swedes feared that the
U.S. government could interfere with Malmo's fire-fighting efforts. In conse-
quence, the fire department began using a data file located, apparently more
safely, in Holland (Feketekuty and Aronson, 1983).
The French government was concerned with the use of American-based
econometrics models in the projection of French economic trends. It feared that
the U.S. government could access those models and gain insight into the French
economy.
To be fair, the United States has given Europeans some cause for concern.
In one often retold episode, it tried unsuccessfully to pressure European coun-
tries to cancel a major gas pipeline deal with the Soviet Union. When that
failed, the American government ordered the producer of the essential com-
pressors for the project, Dresser Industries, to lock out French engineers from
the design database (Botein and Noam, 1986). Another example involved
Lockheed's Dialog on-line database. Dialog contracted with the International
Institute for Advanced Systems Analysis (IIASA) in Vienna to provide access
to its publicly available database. Since the Soviets had access to the IIASA
data gateway, the U.S. government became concerned that they could establish
easy access to U.S. data systems, and it restricted Dialog access through IIASA
(Pipe, 1984b).
The United States is not consistent in its advocacy of a free flow of infor-
mation (Cass and Noam, 1990). In fairness, however, these departures are ex-
ceptions. Furthermore, to argue legitimately for the principles of free flow of
information, one need not be virtuous beyond reproach.
The United States enjoyed a headstart in on-line databases from which it still
benefits. In 1983, worldwide revenue from on-line services was about $2 bil-
lion, of which the United States accounted for more than three-quarters (An-
derla, 1983). In 1983 figures, an OECD report found sales of on-line data
services in Western Europe to be less than 10 percent of sales in the United
States.
As with most information produced initially for a domestic market, the mar-
Transborder Data Flows 403
ginal cost for the export of these databases is low. With a head start and a
substantial domestic customer base, U.S. databases provide tough competition
for European systems. Although the availability of low-cost and well-tested
foreign databases would be in some cases welcome, since domestic replication
is made unnecessary, in most cases, other countries fear informational depen-
dency.
Given this database and data-processing discrepancy, some American firms
believe that what TDF is really about is economic protectionism in favor of
local data processing firms. A Canadian study found that, in 1985, the value
for imported computing services was about $1.5 billion, which could fund an
estimated 23,000 jobs in the Canadian data-processing industry. With greater
frankness than is normally offered, the study conceded that issues of privacy
and protectionism are closely intertwined. The report found that the major problem
inherent in flows of Canadian data to the United States is "not one of privacy
of Canadian data subjects being invaded by data about them being stored in the
United States. It is rather that data processing in the communications business
may be lost to Canadians as a result of this foreign flow" (Turn, 1979, p. 6).
To combat this trend, the Canadian Banking Act of 1980 required that customer
data be processed and stored in Canada, thereby forcing U.S. banks to dupli-
cate their hardware and software instead of relying on existing data-processing
facilities across the border.
Among Third World countries, Brazil has been particularly active in data
and telematics issues, and its policies have received wide publicity. Instituted
during the military dictatorship, the thrust of Brazil's policy is evident in the
statement of its top information officer, in both senses of that title:
In Brazil, a license must be obtained from the special Secretariat for Informat-
ics before establishing international data links. Applications for foreign pro-
cessing, software import, and database access are rejected if domestic capabil-
ity exists. The rules are an attempt to strengthen and develop the domestic
industry. The policy was strongly embraced by the Brazilian military dictator-
ship and its business and industrial allies, and it was admired by many observ-
ers who otherwise feel no kindness toward right-wing juntas.
Beyond the issues of privacy, sovereignty, and protectionism, data flows also
affect the future of PTT monopolies. The 1980s witnessed an acceleration in
the creation of private data networks, and technology offered many possibilities
for data flows bypassing PTTs. Privacy protection provides an argument for
service monopoly, given that private systems, especially if they are shared by
several users, cannot be trusted to enforce data protection provisions.Thus, in
Germany, the media policy spokesman and secretary general of the Social
404 Transborder Data Flows
Democratic party, Peter Glotz, argued that the network monopoly of the Ger-
man Bundespost was necessary for data protection.
Another German official, Spiro Simitis, the pioneering data protection com-
missioner for the state of Hesse, argued that it was necessary to enact special
hardware standards:
[T]he rudiments of a possible set of regulations are emerging. Until now legislation
has been chiefly concerned with storage; the conditions governing processing hav-
ing been abstract and controlled general procedures. Now we must turn our atten-
tion directly to hardware, in order to find out whether and how far technical devices
conforming to data protection laws can be built into all the equipment in question.
A decisive number of statutory requirements could then be met through construc-
tion standards [Simitis, 1985].
At present, the possible effect of TDF restrictions on trade has been largely
theoretical. But since the United States will probably not adopt data protection
legislation to match West European strictness, data flows across the Atlantic
could be impeded. This would affect trade, because the amount of electronic
data flow that accompanies business transactions has increased dramatically.
Can one truly expect a leak-proof system of data protection? Not surpris-
ingly, "data havens" soon began to emerge, including Monaco and Liechten-
stein, and Andorra.
In the friction that ensued on TDF issues and in the traditional manner of
international compromise, which acknowledges that there is merit to the claims
of both sides, the formula of "regulated free flow" emerged. But no elegant
formula could easily cover the differing attitudes toward transborder data flow
on the two sides of the Atlantic.
IV
THE FUTURE OF
TELECOMMUNICATIONS
This page intentionally left blank
38
Networks in the Future
407
408 Networks in the Future
countries. The new group networks do not create a global village; they create
the world as a series of electronic neighborhoods.
In the past, neighborhoods had economic and social functions. In New York,
for example, there are Chinatown, Little Italy, the Garment District, Wall Street,
Madison Avenue, and the Theater District. All have defined social and eco-
nomic functions. There are regions with specialized productionSolingen and
Sheffield for cutlery; Lyon for silk; Hollywood for films; Silicon Valley for
microelectronics (Piore and Sabel, 1984). Production clusters create economies
of aggregation that substitute for the economies of scale and scope of the giant
multiproduct firm. Physical proximity was a key. But now group networks can
serve many of the functions of physical proximity. They interconnect special-
ized producers, suppliers, buyers, experts, and markets. They create new ways
of clustering, spread around the world.
Some of these electronic neighborhoods will be nicer than others. They will
perform better, faster, and often even cheaper. In developing countries, the
networks of those transacting with the world are already becoming better than
those of local people. In places like China or Egypt, a two-tier communications
system has emerged.
Networks might also be stratified along socio-demographic dimensions. Al-
ready, some long-distance resellers in the United States offer bonuses to churches
if they sign up their members. Such marketing efforts can lead over time to
identification of some network with particular ethnic, religious, or political groups.
Similarly, some networks may be shunned by labor union members if they have
a history of labor problems.
3. Personal networks will emerge. But why stop at networks for groups? If
the trend is from national public networks covering the entire population to a
pluralist system, why not expect still further disaggregation? This additional
step means individualized networks. Before dismissing the notion of personal
networks (PNs) as extravagant, let us remember that twenty years ago nobody
expected computers on everybody's lap either.
What does a personal network mean? It means an individually tailored net-
work arrangement. It does not mean a separate physical system, except for
inside wiring and maybe the last mile of circuits, plus some radio-mobile links
and terminal equipment. The rest could consist of virtual networks, provided
by a whole range of service providers and carriers, and packaged together to
provide easy access to an individual's primary communications needs: friends
and family; work colleagues; frequent business contacts, both domestic and
foreign; data sources; transaction programs; frequently accessed video publish-
ers; telemetry services, such as alarm companies; bulletin boards, and so on.
Contact to and from these destinations would move with the individuals, whether
they are at home, at the office, or moving about.
4. Networks will assume political power as quasi-jurisdictions. Historically,
the nation-state was at tension with cross-border allegianceswhether proletar-
ian international solidarity, rebellious youth culture, international financial cap-
ital, or ethnic minorities. The new network environment weakens national
cohesion. It strengthens particularism and internationalizes it. It is difficult for
Networks in the Future 409
a state to extend its powers beyond traditional frontiers, but it is easy for the
new networks to do so.
Furthermore, these network associations possess and acquire powers of their
own. They already may link powerful entities and can bring their combined
powers to bear. For example, the combined weight of the members of the
SWIFT banking network got the powerful national PTT monopolies to cave in
on a number of crucial issues. And there is no reason to expect the power of
network combinations to be directed only at communications issues. Once groups
are in constant touch, they may as well get organized on other issues too. The
communications network becomes the political network.
They will coordinate in the economic sphere. When it comes to the role of
information, the line between competition and cartel coordination has always
been a fine one. In the 1920s, various American industries established so-called
fair-price bureaus that gave each member of the industry a convenient look at
what its competitors were charging. This practice was outlawed in a series of
antitrust cases. Imagine if one leaves instead information exchange to a series
of artificial intelligence programs communicating internationally. One has a
real problem of conceptualizing, detecting, and preventing international cartels.
One person's collusion is another person's programmed trading. The network
becomes the cartel.
The network associations are also likely to become quasi-jurisdictions them-
selves. They have to mediate the conflicting interests of their members. They
have to establish cost shares, sometimes creating their own de facto taxing
mechanism as well as redistribution. They have to determine major invest-
ments, to set standards, to decide whom to admit and whom to expel. As a
network becomes more important and complex, control over its management is
fought over. Elections may take place. Constitutions, bylaws, and regulations
are passed. Arbitration mechanisms are set up. Members are assessed finan-
cially. Networks become political entities.
Thus, we may be witnessing the creation of new and often extraterritorial
forms of new quasi-jurisdictions that are not clearly subordinated to others. In
response, governments might create forms of domestic and international regu-
latory mechanisms for specified sets of problems, possibly based on global
networks themselves that continuously collect and exchange information, track
activities, and coordinate enforcement.1
5. Networks will exercise power toward their members. A major question is
whether a network group can dominate its own members or be restrictive in
allowing others to join. The power of the network becomes most obvious when
it is operated by a dominant entity. For example:
The network of a university such as Columbia can legally exercise restric-
tions toward its members. It can and does limit terminal equipment and
options and charge monopolistic prices, and it could legally refuse to serve
political groups that are disfavored.
The major U.S. videotex service, Prodigy, prevents its users from dis-
cussing politics or Prodigy itself on the system. When Prodigy, which
410 Networks in the Future
restrictions on the exercise of speech over their network and assert that their
status is akin to publishers, with no rights for users. They can exclude certain
subjects from being discussed or certain speakers from having access to the
network. This could become particularly an issue when telecommunications
networks gain the ability to transmit video programs. It is true that individuals
could form alternative networks if they are being restricted. Thus, market forces
could help, but not if some of the networks control some segments of a chain
of communications, or where the ability of any link in such a chain to institute
content-based tests would impose transaction costs on the entire system.
In this context, the exercise of freedom of association may lead to group
formations that restrict speech. Hence, the evolving pluralistic structure of tele-
communications may bear the seeds for a new type of bottleneck to the free
flow of information that did not exist on the traditional public network and its
common carriage.
These conclusions point to bottlenecks, instability, conflict, and new forms
of restrictions, all within an environment rich with communications. What are
the long-term implications for policy? In the past decade, policy discussion was
correctly focused on creating openness by reducing barriers and permitting en-
try. In Europe, this process is only in its early stages. But as the diversification
of the network environment is proceeding, the next set of issues is to create
points and rules for integration that permit the continued interoperability of a
"network of networks." These issues are more difficult to deal with than the
policy questions of the past. They require the conceptualization of a post-
liberalization environment.
39
Toward a Modular Network
In the future it will become increasingly difficult to define what "the network"
is. The distinctions between private and public, basic and enhanced, terminal
and network equipment, national and international, will fade. It is best to think
of the network as a federation that must interact. The traditional arrangement
was based on the notion of sharing of resources in terms of technology, eco-
nomics, and politics. But the evolution of networks moves away from this
sharing arrangement, because of new entry by suppliers, and, perhaps even
more important, of exit of major users from the old sharing coalition. It may
be more efficient on some level to share, but by the same logic one should not
buy books but use the library, or one should not buy a car but hire a taxi. In
other words, the efficiency of capacity utilization is not the only economic
force driving an economic system. What is important for policy is not to ban
the private car, figuratively speaking, but to make sure that there are basic rules
of the road for interaction, based on the principles of compatibility, intercon-
nection, nondiscrimination, and reciprocity, that make it possible for the emerging
quarrelsome network family to live and work together. It is true that in the
short term, revenues may be lost to the public network operator and that addi-
tional costs may be incurred. But one must take the long view: Cost tends to
come down with competition; network revenues will go up as utilization goes
up, and new applications should increase utilization. Where there are still rev-
enue losses, regulators should help make them up elsewhere, such as through
access charges, rather than stop the evolution of the network. Contributions to
traditional social services could also be made by the newer members of the
network family.
The trends toward technical integration and toward institutional and business
diversity are, to some extent, substitutes for each other. To advance technolog-
ically, one can upgrade a telecommunications system by more powerful inte-
gration, such as through integrated narrowband and broadband networks (ISDN
and IBN), and benefit from their economies of scale and scope and from their
greater technical standardization and compatibility. Or one can choose a more
competitive diversity and benefit from its dynamism and cost consciousness.
Figure 39.1 maps the strategies of several countries over the past few years.
Generally speaking, the European PTTs stressed ISDN-style integration,
whereas the United States mostly followed the path of diversity, the compara-
tive advantage of its society. Japan's approach has been fairly balanced in com-
412
Toward a Modular Network 413
Technical integration
bining a major push for both in terms of diversity and integration. Diversity
can lead to innovation, but it can also retard innovation where there are many
independent parts of a system that must interact. Then change can become
much harder.
The implication is not that one should go to the other extreme and protect a
monopoly system, but rather that it is necessary to provide the system with
some tools of integration where they are not self-generating.
A Network Grid
As these islands grow, they must operate together in a sensible manner in terms
of technical standards, protocols, and boundaries. This is why it is necessary
to establish a network blueprint. It would be, conceptually, a grid of defined
vertical and horizontal coordinates, and the technical standards of interconnec-
tion and interface between them. In this fashion it would set out a system of
modularity that would make possible an interconnecting modular network sys-
tem. Within the modules, providers could do more or less whatever they wanted.
And they could connect modules together. But one could replace one module
with another, and it could interact with the rest of the network.4
The transfer from one module to the next will not be free. The charges can
be structured to support traditional concerns, such as universal service, and
assure the viability of the core network.
Modularity enhances competition and will therefore be viewed negatively by
the traditional carriers. On the other hand, it would make them much less de-
pendent on any particular equipment manufacturers, since there is likely to be
more competition to supply any specialized module than to provide an entire
central office switch, which is a billion-dollar development effort. Thus, the
modularity of software will free carriers from switches with multimillion-line
programs.5
Today most computer hardware is designed to accommodate an operating
system such as DOS or UNIX with applications programs such as spreadsheets
and word processing. Telephone digital switches, though similar to computers,
in effect mix the operating system with the applications, so that it is difficult
for telephone companies or independent software companies (as opposed to
switch manufacturers) to write the new applications software either because its
millions of lines are impenetrable or because they cannot touch it legally. Mod-
ularity would also deal with the inevitably increasing competitive overlap be-
tween telecommunications and computer industries and would assure that intel-
ligence does not migrate into the terminal equipment periphery of the network
for purely regulatory reasons.
Market niches for small hardware suppliers would open. The carriers could
encourage the development of software applications by outside suppliers, just
as IBM did by opening software applications for its personal computers. This
would enhance the telephone carriers' flexibility. Right now, changing network
capability and services is a ponderous process.
416 Toward a Modular Network
It would be similarly possible for the VAN service providers to provide new
applications by placing them among the central office software functions them-
selves. In other words, software by outsiders would be put into the central
exchange. This could be called software collocation. PTTs will shudder today
at the notion. But it may be attractive commercially to them, as long as it
conforms with standards and protocols, does not displace their own functions
because of limited capacity, is limited to higher-layer applications rather than
network control functions, and of course yields revenues. This could open up
a scenario of exciting applications.
40
Telecommunications Liberalization:
An Expansionary Process?
417
418 Telecommunications Liberalization: An Expansionary Process?
ities would be necessary to restore stability. And since this power does not
exist, or is usually not deemed desirable, regulatory strictness may unravel.
The following pages provide a simple analysis of regulation in its intersec-
toral and international dimensions. We start off by narrowly defining regulation
as the setting, by a regulatory agency, of a price vector R for a set of economic
activities. A total prohibition is an infinite price set by the state; a totally
laissez-faire regime means a market price. Most regulation, however, is some-
where in between and can be viewed as a way of making an economic activity
costlier (as in pollution control) or cheaper (as in residential telephone usage).
Various interest groups are affected by the setting of these prices, and they
seek favorable P's by exercising pressure through the political process.
Where will R be set? This depends on the optimizing function of the regu-
lator. For purposes of the argument, it is not necessary to specify this function
in detail, but to assume an interest group model of politics. Regulatory behav-
ior is affected by the groups according to their power and stake in the outcome.
Let us assume two interest groups, A and B, each with a "political weight" of
WA and WB. Each group is affected by the regulation R, with the effect E
described by , = gi(R). We assume for simplicity that the two groups are
impacted differently by regulation, in that one gains from a higher R, whereas
the other loses from it.
(1)
Each group asserts pressure P, according to the strength of impact ,, weighted
by the group's political weight Wt.
(2)
The various pressures are in equilibrium when
(3)
which is where the ratio of the benefit functions is equal to the inverse of the
political weights of the respective groups. Since the W[ and g, are given, we
can determine the expected regulation R in such a system as
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
Supraregulation
Supraregulation is encompassing regulation, either across jurisdictions (e.g., a
supranational policy) or across functions (i.e., "supra-modal"). This expands
regulation to a higher level of institutions (e.g., to the European Commission)
or to a wider institution, such as the Interstate Commerce Commission in the
United States which regulates all modes of surface transportation.
How is Supraregulation set? By analogy to the single-jurisdiction case, the
two sets of interest groups are assumed to affect the joint jurisdiction in an
aggregated fashion, if the suprajurisdiction is answerable to the body politic.
(8)
This can be higher or lower than uncoordinated outcomes. Supraregulation
is not invariably stricter than particularist regulation, for the reasons discussed.
In telecommunications, for example, the regulatory principles of the European
Commission are less strict than those of most of the member states. In the
United States, the same holds true for the FCC vis-a-vis the state Public Utility
Telecommunications Liberalization: An Expansionary Process? 421
Commissions. But the reverse is also often the case (e.g., in the regulation of
securities).
One question is "Why would interest groups (or a whole country) consent
to supraregulation?" Would this not dilute the power of dominant groups? This
is indeed true. Therefore, a dominant group will normally consent to a shift to
supraregulation only where its favored policy would be enhanced (e.g., if the
balance of power of interest groups in the other sector is even more favorable
to its concerns). However, for symmetrical reasons, the dominant group in the
other sector would then oppose supraregulation lest it dilute its own influence.
Log rolling aside, this then leaves two primary scenarios (the second of which
is the more important) in which mutual joining of supraregulation will occur:
1. When the balance of power is essentially equal in the two sectors, so that
supraregulation does not make much difference. This is why policy co-
ordination is easier among Western European countries than, for ex-
ample, East Asian ones.
1. When supraregulation establishes a policy cartel to avoid separate regu-
lation to affect each other and to lead to results that are considered sub-
optimal by the dominant groups. This is more likely to be important where
the cross-elasticity of regulation is high, which is likely to be the case
with sectors or countries that interact strongly with each other.
In other words, the advantage of the elimination of uncontrolled interaction
must be greater than the value attributed to control and independence. Of course,
de facto independence already had been lost through the mechanism of inter-
action, and supraregulation reflects this.
A related issue is that of uniformity in regulation. Here the issue is not the
strictness per se, but the importance of being identical. There are situations
where efficiencies exist in uniformity or connectivity. (The width of railroad
gauge or protocols in telecommunications are examples.)
Technologists tend to favor standardization. Economists have more mixed
views, because uniformity has its costs. To have cars with identical pollution
controls in both Norway and Belgium may not necessarily be optimal for either
or for both jointly.
In terms of the model, uniformity is given by the 45 line, which is likely to
be off the equilibrium point /?*. Uniformity is the dominant policy throughout
if at least one reaction function is sloped at 45 (i.e., where at least one juris-
diction reacts to the other's change by an identical change so as to preserve
uniformity). But that is an exceptional situation.
There may be great incentives for one state to be nonuniform. Examples are
large countries for whom international interaction may be small in relative terms
(e.g., the United States, which for example affords a nonmetric system of mea-
surements). At the same time, many other examples are small jurisdictions:
Switzerland in banking; Delaware in coiporation law; Hong Kong in tariff du-
ties; Liechtenstein in taxes; Monaco in gambling; and Luxembourg in broad-
casting. These examples suggest that small countries have incentives to be non-
conforming, probably since the loss in revenue, control, and so on, from their
422 Telecommunications Liberalization: An Expansionary Process?
own relatively small domestic economies is more than offset by the inflow from
the larger countries resulting from nonconformity. To prevent such nonuni-
formity, the other states may have to impose substantial pressure on the mav-
erick jurisdictions or pay significant compensation.
Regulatory Treaties
Another possibility of coordination is to establish interjurisdictional or intersec-
toral treaties. Here there is no supraregulation by a suprabody, only an agree-
ment, and each side must be better off than before to enter into it. Agreement
will stop at the point where marginal benefits of marginal regulation will begin
to be negative for at least one jurisdiction. Thus, such a system is a convoy
traveling at the speed of its slowest ship. It can be extended further where
compensation to some participants is possible, which is one of the ways the
European Community operates in the agricultural field.
Regulatory Colonialism
An extreme example for regulatory coordination could be called regulatory co-
lonialism, when one jurisdiction can set regulations for another jurisdiction solely
to benefit itself. Britain's imposition of regulations on cotton spinning in India
or on opium trade in China are examples. Other illustrations are the use of the
Interstate Commerce Commission by American railroads to impose regulations
on trucking, or the successful pressure put on the FCC by American broadcast-
ers to restrict cable television for a number of years.
Instability
The problem of any coordinated regulatory structure is its instability. First, no
equilibrium may be possible, because the reaction functions do not meet the
stability criterion described earlier. Second, one jurisdiction's adherence to an
agreement provides the other with an opportunity of gain by seeking a non-
cooperative policy. In each jurisdiction there are pressures to seek one's own
ideal regulatory level, which is likely to be different from the agreed upon level
or from the interactive equilibrium. Going it alone can be due to shortsighted-
ness or lack of understanding of the interaction involved. But it can be based
on the rational desire to gain advantages over others by breaking joint policy,
at least in the short run.
In telecommunications, for example, communications "havens" are possible
and likely to emerge. The example of telex service is instructive. As discussed
repeatedly in this book, in the 1980s, London-based telex bureaus started to
retransmit traffic between North America and continental Europe in defiance of
CCITT cartel "recommendations" against such retransmission. It was profit-
able for U.K. firms to break these rules, since this generated more traffic and
made the United Kingdom more attractive as a business location. In time, the
cartel rules were held to be illegal.
Telecommunications Liberalization: An Expansionary Process? 423
Outlook
Is there anything to stop the process? At some point, the cost of instability and
diversity becomes high enough for a coordinated regime to be reestablished.
But this is not likely to be stable over time, especially since no real interna-
tional enforcement or compensation mechanisms exist, and their absence has
domestic reverberations. For example, if international airline cartels break down,
domestic ones are threatened. One can fly from Toronto to Vancouver through
the United States, if Canadian prices are too high.
Applied to telecommunications, one should therefore expect an overall trend
toward liberalization, though accompanied by efforts to stabilize its collabo-
rative aspects. As the matrix of interrelations becomes steadily more cross-
elastic, one could have some oscillations. But the overall tendency should lead
to reduced regulatory strictness internationally. In that sense, liberalization is
an expansionary process. It may not be just an ideological choice but a re-
sponse to an internal inability to structure a stable equilibrium that serves mul-
tiple domestic interests and goals. One has to predict that similar inconsisten-
cies will spread throughout the system, even where they are riot based on the
424 Telecommunications Liberalization: An Expansionary Process?
same domestic pressure to change that led to the original instability in the other
jurisdiction.
Traditional telecommunications operated through national monopolies pro-
tected internationally by a cartel arrangement. Now, a challenge to domestic
monopolies threatens the international cartel, and the breakdown in interna-
tional arrangements threatens the domestic stability of others. It is difficult to
see how the simplicity of the traditional system can be maintained or restored.
Most likely we are merely at the beginning of a lengthy, dynamic, and untidy
process, of which the presently asymmetric liberalization across the two sides
of the Atlantic is a manifestation.
41
Regulatory Tasks for the Future:
Interconnectivity in the
Pluralist Network
425
426 Regulatory Tasks for the Future
tion and diversity. The advantages of uniformity derive from greater industry
and service stability, and increased compatibility and portability between dif-
ferent hardware and software. Its primary disadvantages involve reduced free-
dom to innovate and experiment, and the loss of flexibility to adopt to changing
conditions. What is needed is a process to weigh and balance the various needs,
and a hierarchy of uniformity.
Experience and the theoretical economic literature on standards setting and
game theory show that standards do not necessarily evolve optimally, smoothly,
or speedily in a purely voluntary setting. This would suggest a governmental
role in interoperability, as long as one can prevent their use for protectionist
purposes. Europe's ETSI is an institutional response to that need.
2. Legal interconnectivity: protection of interconnection and access. The
tension between the integrative and pluralistic forces is most pronounced on the
front where they intersect: the rules of interconnection of the multiple hardware
and software subnetworks and their access into the integrated whole. Policy
must structure ways in which network interconnection is granted, defined, priced,
and harmonized. To control access arrangements is to control the network. This
is detailed in Chapter 42, where an open network system is discussed (NYPSC,
1989; NYPSC, 1990c).' The liberalization of terminal equipment interconnec-
tion and open network provision in Europe are steps in that direction. But they
are only the first steps in a long journey.
3. Content interconnectivity: regulatory treatment of telephone carriers in
their capacity as mass media. The upgrading of the telephone network toward
broadband capability and its use for video, data, and text transmission brings
telephone transmission ever closer to mass media. Audio mass announcement
services are already widely offered, and video broadband is a likely future
scenario for telecommunications carriers.
In the United States, there have been claims by network operators to possess
the status of "broadcasters" or "publishers" of information, or at least the
arbiter of what fits their organization's image, with the right to select the infor-
mation carried over their network. In Europe, these issues are beginning to
arise, and the television field itself is in the turmoil of change, as discussed in
the companion volume to this book (Noam, 1991c).
In the common law tradition, carriers and other businesses "affected with
the public interest" had an obligation to provide service to all indiscriminately.
They provided transport or transmission function, with no influence over or
liability for the content of transmissions, as common carriers. Common car-
riage is among the most important long-term issues in telecommunications pol-
icy. Common carriage is a form of content interconnection in an intermedia
environment. As such, it is a cousin of the other forms of interconnection.
What does common carriage mean? That is a surprisingly difficult question
for such a well-worn term.2 It is often used imprecisely as a synonym with
other terms. For example, it does not mean universal service, that is, the re-
quirement to serve anyone equally, regardless of geography. Nor is it a syn-
onym for monopoly, public utility, or regulated firm. It is best defined for our
purposes as a "carrier of electronic information offering service on demand to
Regulatory Tasks for the Future 427
the general public, for hire." Its attributes are neutrality among similar users
and usages, content neutrality, and no liability for content and user actions.
This is nothing new. For centuries under English common law, transportation
carriers had special obligations when dealing with the public, primarily the
responsibility to treat customers equally.
Early forms of common carriage date back at least to the Roman Empire,
which developed law on the duties of shipowners, innkeepers, and stable keep-
ers. Early English common law established rules on businesses that were con-
sidered "public callings." These included bakers, brewers, cab drivers, ferry-
men, innkeepers, millers, smiths, surgeons, tailors, and wharfingers (Phillips,
1988, p. 83). Common, in this sense, meant "open to public service."3 By
force of common law enforced by the courts, common carriers were required
to serve, upon reasonable demand, any and all who sought their services (Aust,
1990).
The concept of common carriage crossed the Atlantic and became part of the
American legal system. Common carriage was applied to railroads and later to
other distribution mediums. In 1901, the U.S. Supreme Court affirmed that
under common law a telegraph company is a common carrier and owes a duty
of nondiscrimination.4
In today's legal terms, common carrier obligations translate into nondiscrim-
ination and noninterference with content. What are the benefits of such a sys-
tem? In economic terms, common carriage is one of those arrangements whose
purpose is to reduce transaction costs, like limited liability, legal tender, or
negotiable instruments.
As with other efforts to balance private and public interests, common car-
riage is at times burdensome to the carrier. Yet it is probably fair to say that
the common carrier system has served telecommunications participants well: It
has permitted society to entrust its vital highways of information to governmen-
tal administrations or for-profit companies, without the specter of discrimina-
tion and censorship by government or private monopolies; it helped establish a
free flow of information; it reduced administrative costs and the burden of lia-
bility because the network operator did not need to concern itself with content;
and it protected the carriers from pressure groups who wanted to exclude tele-
phone service to some other groups or activities they opposed. This system has
probably resulted in a broader, more useful, lower cost, and more profitable
network system than would have developed without it.
Although common carrier principles go back a long time, their applications
are in a constantly shifting terrain and require continuous updating, particularly
in an extraordinarily dynamic period in telecommunications.
Perhaps the most important change has been the emergence of the telephone
network as a carrier of mass media messages, provided mostly by other infor-
mation suppliers. Examples include videotex, dial-it, mass announcement ser-
vices, interactive services, and future telephone broadband services, including
video. This raises the question of the regulatory status of such a new mass
medium. Here it is helpful to understand what the options are. Mass media are
basically treated in one of three ways. The print media is virtually unregulated;
428 Regulatory Tasks for the Future
in the United States and Europe, free speech governs. The main restrictions are
the prohibition of libel, the protection of privacy, and some protection from
obscenity. Other countries have similar, though usually somewhat more restric-
tive, free-speech protection. Private broadcasters and cable operators are treated
somewhat differently. They require licenses and franchises to operate and are
subject to certain obligations, such as, in the United States, the fairness doc-
trine, the must-carry rule, and so on. They still enjoy significant free-speech
rights; in particular, they are able, to a large extent, to determine what will be
shown on their medium. The third type of treatment is common carriage. This
is the traditional way for telephone carriers to operate. That is, any user, and
any form of content, as long as it is lawful and as long as it pays the regular
price, will be carried over the telephone network.
The question now arises, how should the telephone carriers' increasing mass
media role be handled: Should it become something akin to a second cable
television system (i.e., with the powers of selecting and programming many of
its channels and excluding others)? This would give an unprecedented gate-
keeper role over mass media to private or governmental organizations with
considerable market power. Instead, telephone organizations' role as mass me-
dia carriers should be governed by the conduit and nondiscrimination principles
of common carriage, which is the traditional way that telephone carriers have
provided services in the past.5
It is important to distinguish conduit, or transmission, functions from content
functions involving information provision or modification. This is the most ba-
sic way to distinguish common carriage from publishing.
Whether or not telephone carriers offer program services does not affect the
validity of common carriage principles. Common carriage applies only to a
communication carrier's provision of conduit services. If a conduit provider is
also permitted to offer content, the basic principles of common carriage are not
reduced; On the contrary, they are even more important, because otherwise the
carrier could keep its content competitors out, or discriminate against them.
There is a simple way to summarize common carriage. All electrons and
photons are created equal. (In 1990, the New York State Public Service Com-
mission established the first U.S. rules to this effect, drafted by the author,
denying telephone carriers censorship rights for lawful messages, or the ability
to institute discriminatory access arrangements for information providers or lis-
teners.) In the United Kingdom, on the other hand, under traditionalist pres-
sure, the regulatory agency Oftel established a censorship board and other forms
of control. Most countries also permit or require various forms of content dis-
crimination.
4. Financial Interconnectivity: Protecting the Viability of the Core Network.
Clearly, an expanded, upgraded, and enhanced network utilizing the best tech-
nology requires significant capital investment. A competitive network system
may drive prices not only to costs but to marginal costs, making it impossible
to cover fixed costs, let alone to have monopoly profits to support upgrades.
Furthermore, as discussed, there may be a problem of investing in a critical
mass (i.e., in generating externalities) when the risk is borne by the initiating
Regulatory Tasks for the Future 429
network but the rewards are shared by others through the mechanism of inter-
connection. Finally, a technologically dynamic environment means shorter eco-
nomic lives for equipment, requiring faster amortization. It is therefore a chal-
lenge for future policy to structure arrangements such that adequate investments
in the network are available in a decentralized environment.
5. Social interconnectivity: establishing new mechanisms of redistribution.
The pluralistic network will make it increasingly difficult to maintain the tra-
ditional system of internal transfers from one class of users to another. But this
does not spell the end of transfers as such. There is still ample possibility and
opportunity to subsidize some categories of service for reasons of social policy
or regional development, or for the positive benefits that new subscribers pro-
vide to existing users. One type of support mechanism is a "lifeline" program
to insure access by the poor.6
A new mechanism to finance desired subsidies and end the primary reliance
on the PTTs and their customers would be to establish a "universal service
fund" with contributions by all network providers, instead of the present sys-
tem of internal transfers. Such funds could be raised through various access
charge mechanisms, or, more neutrally and efficiently, through a value-added
tax on communication services.
6. Informational interconnectivity: privacy protection. The new telecommu-
nications environment raises privacy problems. Privacy issues, in effect, are
the flow of information beyond the intended recipient. Privacy protection in
telecommunications is not a new issue. In the past, manual operators and party
lines all created their own problems. The first patent for a voice scrambling
device was issued in 1881, only five years after the invention of the telephone.7
Relatively strong expectations of privacy developed in time. Today a new gen-
eration of privacy problems has emerged. The reasons include:
a. More and more transactions are conducted electronically.8
b. It has become easier and cheaper to collect, store, match, and redistribute
information about transactions and individuals.9
c. The number of carriers and service providers has grown enormously, leading
to an increasingly open network system in which information about use
and user is exchanged across companies.
d. Transmission conduits increasingly include unsecured portionsfor ex-
ample, because of mobile communications.
Concern with electronic privacy has led to different policy approaches. In Western
Europe, attention to privacy issues has led to data protection laws and the
establishment of institutionalized boards and commissions that have often im-
posed fairly rigorous restrictions on data collection and data flows. This is
discussed in Chapter 37 on transborder data flows. In the United States, the
approach has instead been based on a variety of ad hoc federal and state legis-
lation.
The policy challenge is to structure a more flexible approach: a framework
in which the user would have several hardware and software "privacy options"
of service.
430 Regulatory Tasks for the Future
match the global scope of networks. The openness of the evolving network
system will not stop at the national frontiers. In the long run, telecommunica-
tions will move beyond the territorial concept, and the notion of each country
having full territorial control over electronic communications will become
anachronistic. Communications are becoming distance insensitive. Rerouting,
arbitrage, and the establishment of communications "havens" become easily
possible. This undermines attempts to set rules administratively for prices and
service conditions. No country can be a telecommunications island anymore.
The more interrelated countries and economic activities are, the less likely it is
that there are stable solutions to separate policies. Moreover, instabilities in
one country affect the entire system. It becomes increasingly difficult to control
all the elements in such a complex matrix of interrelations (See Chapter 40).
This means conceding a greater role to international bodies, while recognizing
their limitations, and similarly conceding a greater role to the coordination powers
of markets.
Conclusion
432
The Pluralist Network 433
This has begun with the private networks of large users. These private net-
works, some of whose operation and administration require hundreds of skilled
technicians and managers, even where they usually rely on the infrastructure of
the regular carriers, have emerged in developed countries. These activities are
spearheaded by private firms, but are pursued also by nonprofit and public
organizations. Similarly, users with common interests and activities have begun
to interlink through private value-added networks such as SWIFT.
Examples for actual or potential group networks are those of (1) advertising
agencies linked to media firms and printers; (2) chemical manufacturers and
environmental protection agencies; (3) insurance firms, hospitals, record rooms,
police departments, and so on; or (4) of automobile manufacturers, dealers,
suppliers, and shippers.
In some instances these networks will have special performance features that
distinguish them from the general "public" network. In the first example just
cited, network bandwidth must be high to permit transfer of high-resolution
graphics. In the second example, the usefulness of the network may be in
supporting software and databases. In many instances, such as the third ex-
ample, it is probably the price of intercommunications that drives the arrange-
ment. In the fourth example, the standardization of transactions may be the
primary advantage.
Most users are likely to participate in several networks. Furthermore, such a
pluralist network arrangement does not mean separate transmission links for
each subnetwork at every point. It will often make sense to transport the traffic
of several low-volume users part of the way on the general network until the
point where there is enough aggregate traffic to branch off. The economics of
sharing are not abolished. But they must prove to be superior as a matter of
choice, not imposed by a legal requirement. Hybrid arrangements like virtual
networks are therefore likely to be popular.
The earlier observations suggest that no specific event undermines a Euro-
pean PTT's role; instead, the aggregate of challenges will lead to the "tipping
of the monopoly." Restrictions in one area are interconnected with others; con-
versely, liberalization in one field is hard to contain. Thus, equipment liberali-
zation leads to the demand for new services, such as value-added networks,
which in turn creates pressures for resale opportunities. It is unlikely, given the
nature of PTT organizations, rapid technological developments, and resultant
market pressures, that they will be able to put out every fire, man every ram-
part, and seal every dike successfully. At the same time, a partial liberalization
also provides opportunities for the traditional telecommunications authorities,
and they may seize them for the temporary advantage, though change will
undermine their exclusivity in the long term.
The conclusion is that European telecommunications will, in the short run,
experience a push by PTTs to extend and defend their monopoly position and
to expand in the direction of new services and equipment operations. However,
long-term forces are at work that are likely to lead in time to an unraveling of
the monopoly system. These factors, in combination, make it unlikely that the
PTTs will maintain the present extent of their monopoly control.
434 The Pluralist Network
Network of Networks
The network system of the future is one of great institutional, technical, and
legal complexity. The network environment will consist of an untidy patchwork
of many subnetworks, serving different geographical regions, customer types,
user groups, categories, and service, with no neat classification or compartmen-
talization possible. It includes a hodgepodge of participants, governmental and
private, national and regional, general and specialized, narrow and wideband,
terrestrial and satellite, tiny and vast, domestic and multinational. The Ameri-
can experience demonstrates the long-range instability of structural regulation,
such as compartmentalization of the telecommunications sector along different
functional and geographic dimensions and the assignment of market segments
to different carriers. This is due to the overlapping and ever-changing nature of
services, the inability to define clear boundary lines, and the incentives for
participants to breach restrictions. Hence, the future telecommunications net-
work environment will have carriers engaged in multiple functions, though there
will be no shortage of official attempts to establish order.
will nor the political support. Yet there is need for regulatory oversight of the
rules under which networks and users interrelate in the future, as detailed next.
To bridge this tension will be one of the central challenges for future policy.
Gradualism
As the earlier discussion of interconnection of old and new networks demon-
strates, it is not necessary to cut one's links to other participants. Multiple
networks need not lead to multiple telephone sets on the desk. This is not more
necessary than having multiple currencies if there are several banks in a coun-
try. In the situation of multiple networks, the functioning of the network fed-
eration depends on rules of interconnection. Such rules are being structured in
regulatory approaches of open network architecture (ONA) in the United States
and of open network provision (ONP) in Europe. Such arrangements provide
additional impetus for new networks in that they permit the gradual establish-
ment of a new network. They also permit a wide range of options between a
full and separate physical network, and the use of an existing network in dif-
ferent and innovative ways, somewhat apart from the general "public" user-
ship.
The concept of gradualism inherent in open network architecture is impor-
tant. Many advocates of the traditional shared network system believe that the
demands of pluralism could be met by a flexibility for software network op-
tions, without altering the exclusivity of the physical network of the traditional
monopolist. This is wishful thinking. Granted, to permit software networks on
a transmission monopoly is a correct first response to the emerging pressures.
However, it is unlikely to be adequate in the long run. Soon users will want to
supplement transmission offerings with additions to satisfy their preferences in
terms of technology, control, and economics. The exclusive network cannot be
the superior solution in each instance, particularly if it has to follow political
mandates, or if it cannot bargain individually on prices.
The Pluralist Network 437
The traditional public system may be losing its exclusivity, but it is gaining the
flexibility of moving into new activities. The experience of British Telecom,
Sweden's Televerket, the semi-independent public system of the STET group
in Italy, and of the Telefonica group in Spain indicates strong tendencies of
dominant carriers to expand vertically into equipment and manufacturing, even
internationally. These tendencies are similar to the developments in the United
States, where the scope of activity of the AT&T successor companies is stead-
ily increasing. Such new horizons are an attraction to the PTTs as they consent
to the loss of monopoly; for policymakers, they raise regulatory issues on how
to deal with the substantial economic power of independent PTTs now renamed
PTOs, but with market power intact.
The traditional public network system operated with the obligation of universal
service, that is, virtually any interested customer had to be served, regardless
of location. In a pluralist network system, the question is whether universal
service obligations apply to all participants. The answer is likely to be differ-
entiated. For some of the more specialized services, the obligation will not
exist. But for "basic" service, it will continue, and the definition of basic is
likely to expand. The boundary line is likely to be an ongoing issue of policy
discussion.
Internal Subsidies
Transnationalism
Preface
1. There are, of course, semiofficial volumes in which various countries' PTTs report
about themselves, but these reports are neither analytical nor probing.
3. Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
441
442 Notes
9. For simplicity, utility is expressed in monetary units. Then u(P,n) = P(n) + u(n)
10. Heal defines it, similarly, as
1. The author served as a member of the Advisory Board for the selection.
2. NYNEX data, see Noam (forthcoming).
3. New York PSC data, see Noam (forthcoming).
4. Encompasses all U.S. carriers; translated for new telephones from data on access
line using 1975 ratio. Sources: Telecom Factbook, 1986; FCC, Statistics of Commu-
nications Common Carriers, 1945, 1955, 1965, 1975, 1985.
5. This classification extends those of Ergas (1989).
1. Residential penetration is not the entire story. In public (i.e., coin) telephones of
several European countries, Switzerland had the highest density (8.90 per 1000 popu-
lation). Densities are substantially lower in the rest of Europe. In the United States, the
corresponding density is 7.18, to which figure one must add the many private coin
telephone networks that have mushroomed since liberalization of this sector. In New
York State in 1988, privately owned coin telephones amounted to an additional 20
percent of those operated by the telephone companies, suggesting a density of 8.6 per
1000 population. The OECD countries apart from Switzerland and Japan have substan-
tially lower densities. See Table 32.2.
7. Germany
1. In a letter to a colleague in both the party and the Reichspost, Ohnesorge rhapso-
dized in 1931 about Hitler, then still in the opposition:
Notes 443
Dear God, what luck that the country has been blessed with a man of such stature!
. . . He is the only, the last great German! And everything is right as he approaches it
and as he wishes it. ... Haase, dear Haase, when finally the marching steps of the
battalions will sound again through the streets of Berlin! Both of us are still young!
Then we will march, too, unyielding, unrelenting to wherever Adolf Hitler wants [Na-
gel, 1937, p. 24].
Such sentiments, expressed also publicly, had not slowed Ohnesorge's career in the
Reichspost during the Weimar Republic; he was promoted to considerable responsibil-
ity, including being in charge of the Reichspost's priority project of transition to auto-
matic exchanges.
2. In 1972, Germany's high-technology exports had been a respectable 26.3 percent
of the six major countries. However, by 1983, this share had fallen to 17 percent. The
French share in the same period declined from 11.1 percent to 8 percent, Britain's share
from 13.8 percent to 10 percent, and Switzerland's share from 3.5 percent to 3 percent.
In contrast, the non-European countries improved their situation significantly. Japan's
market share almost doubled from 13 percent to 25 percent, and that of the United States
rose from 32.2 percent to 37 percent, amounting to more than one-third of the total.
Furthermore, the market as a whole increased sixfold, from $8.4 billion in 1972 to $54
billion in 1983. In telecommunications, Germany's share fell from 22.8 percent to 14.5
percent: in electronic tubes and transistors, from 17.4 percent to 11 percent (Bundes-
bank, Annual Report, 1983).
3. It also invested extensively in America and acquired 20 percent of the American
company Advanced Micro Devices (AMD), a company that second-sourced Intel and
Zilog microprocessors. It also bought 100 percent of Microwave Semiconductor, 80
percent of Litronix, and 60 percent of Advanced Microcromputer (AMC). Through Corning
Glass it established the successful optical fiber venture Siecor and acquired the floppy
disk operations of Perkins-Elmer. Siemens also formed joint ventures with Intel and
Westinghouse, in 1988.
4. Today the Bundespost's record of service in the rural population is often used to
support the argument for its monopoly. According to the Bundespost, the Bell System
in the United States concentrated on the lucrative urban areas to the disadvantage of less
profitable and more sparsely populated areas: "A telephone connection in structurally
weak areas is either not offered at all, or even today is offered more expensively and
maintained or provided technically less accomplished than in urban regions" (DBF,
1981, para. 96a). In fact, rural telephony in the United States is often cheaper than an
urban one. In typical farm states such as Iowa and Kansas, the percentage of house-
holds having telephones in 1987 was even higher (95.1 percent and 95.2 percent,
respectively) than the national average of 92.4 percent (Federal-State Joint-Board,
1988), and a high 96 percent of all American farms had telephone service in the
same year (Rural Electrification Administration, 1988). This was despite the signifi-
cantly lower density of population, particularly in the American West, as compared to
that in Europe. Population density in the state of Wyoming is 12.4 inhabitants per km 2 .
In comparison, density in Germany is 246 inhabitants per km 2 ; in the United King-
dom it is 233 per km 2 ; and in France, 100 per km 2 . In some instances, the technical
quality of independent rural telephony has not been as high as that in urban areas,
but it is often better, too. In 1985, the average residential flat rate for unlimited local-
call service was $13.80 per month in urban U.S. areas and $10.15 per month in rural
areas.
5. The Bundespost planned for a natural evolution from ISDN to broadband ISDN,
444 Notes
with a structure suitable for higher-speed applications like television or video telephony
(Ohmann and Armbruster, 1986; Armbruster, 1986).
6. A study undertaken by the Deutsches Institut fiir Wirtschaftsforschung (DIW) in
1980 found that for each additional billion DM in investment in telecommunications
beyond the existing 10 billion, 21,000 to 22,000 jobs would be generated if such in-
vestment continued (Schnoring, 1982). However, another study, commissioned by the
Ministry of Economics in 1983 and carried out by the IFO Institute and looking at the
period 1983-1990, found that an additional billion DM a year in telecommunications
investment would result in only 4000 additional jobs per year. This is not an impressive
figure; it means that for each new job, a new and ongoing investment level of DM
250,000 ($134,000) per year would have to be maintained.
7. To ascertain the efficacy of this system, the FCC also asked that AT&T and eleven
public utility commissions determine whether network damage has occurred. They con-
cluded that there had been no negative effects on the network or physical impact on
personnel.
8. The interest of private households and business customers in various new features
of telephone service and equipment grew dramatically. There was a demand, approach-
ing two-thirds of all businesses and residences, for detailed specification of billings.
Such billings are not normally provided (Schulte, 1982, p. 322, Table 12B).
Another common U.S. service, call-forwarding, began to be introduced in Germany
under the name of GEDAN only in the 1980s. But the basic rate for this service was
between DM 133 and DM 160 ($71 and $85) per month. Cost for call forwarding in
New York is, for businesses, $6 per month after an initial installation fee of $54; for
residences it is $4 per month after an initial fee of $15.50. (Frequently, the initial
installation rate is cut or dropped to attract usage.)
9. It should be noted, however, that although Wagner advocated public ownership of
the railroads as essential, another eminent German institutionalist economist, E. Sax,
argued that a form of private enterprise could fulfill public tasks just as well (Sax,
1887). Wagner's views, however, won in the political sphere.
9. France
1. Although the DGT installs and maintains customer equipment, authorized inde-
pendent installers and their subcontractors can also provide such services. There are
about 500 primary installer authorizations in the country, employing about 15,000 peo-
ple (Voge, 1986).
2. The digitalization of central office switches permitted the introduction in 1983 of
itemized billing (at a separate charge), conference calls, call forwarding, free-phone
(800 service), and call waiting (Bruce et al., 1985).
3. When the agreement expired in 1990, Thomson won a France Telecom contract
for broadband switches and CGE's Alcatel made defense electronics one focus of a new
division (Boult, 1990, p. 10).
4. The reorganization was also believed to help French telecommunications exports
by avoiding head-on competition between two suppliers for international contracts. For
example, in the case of major Egyptian telecommunications contract, CIT-Alcatel bid
against Thomson and Siemens. The merger eliminated the potential for such intra-French
competition.
5. In the United States, Alcatel's sales efforts began in 1984 and resulted in orders
for several dozen of a U.S. switch version, the E-10-5, primarily for small independent
telephone companies, such as the Clay County Rural Telephone Cooperative in Indiana,
rather than to the Bell Operating Companies (Telephony, 1985, pp. 32-33). For equip-
ment other than local exchanges, Alcatel's customers in the United States were MCI
and AT&T for multiplexing systems. Having adapted ITT's System 12 switch, Alcatel
reentered an American central exchange market that ITT had abandoned in 1986 when
adapting the System 12 proved too expensive and time-consuming.
In 1990 Alcatel pulled many of its operations out of the United States except for
cable television and SONET transmission equipment development (Roussel, 1990d).
1. Until 1987, when the zones were redrawn, the small call areaswith an average
of 31 square kilometers versus 2673 square kilometers in the United Kingdom (Dabbs
et al., 1982)allowed for untimed local calls. After 1987, only two charging zones
remained. Areas for local and long-distance calls were extended and local calls became
timed.
2. The PTT is required to meet performance standards in "reserved" services and
has lowered rates for several services since the reform,
3. To enhance its position as the dominant supplier in the newly liberalized value-
added services market, PTT Telecom acquired 45 percent of a Dutch networking firm,
Impact Automation, and began negotiations with France Telecom and the DBP Telekom
about an international consortium (Schenker, 1989, p. 8).
11. Belgium
I . Although it opposed the loosening of its own monopoly, the RTT was not above
benefiting from the opportunities presented by the liberalization of others. After an
agreement between the U.S. carrier MCI and the Belgian Post Office, the PTT became
the major entry point to Europe for the American alternative long-distance carrier.
446 Notes
2. In Turkey, BTMC has a particularly large contract, which includes the transfer of
technology and manufacturing expertise to the Turkish equipment producer Teletas in a
turnkey arrangement.
3. Also, under its guidelines for the licensing of VANs providers, RTT granted ap-
proval to five service providers: GEIS, Sabena, SITA, SWIFT, and Infonet. However,
the licensing process was criticized because the requirements for VANs providers were
unclear and because the RTT's 95 percent ownership of Infonet's Belgian operations
could result in preferential treatment (Tutt, 1990, p. 15).
13. Switzerland
1. Part of the telecommunications profits are used to subsidize the postal services
within the PTT. Swiss mail service is excellent, but partly at the expense of telecom-
munications users and network quality. Transfers in 1983 were more than SFr 600
million; in addition, about SFr 90 million, or 3 percent of value added, were transferred
to the general federal treasury (Knieps, 1985b, p. 19).
14. Austria
1. Unlike many PTTs, the Austrian PTV does not operate broadcast transmission
services, though it distributes broadcast programs to transmitters and cable networks.
2. In 1984, a reduced-cost phone service (Service 660) was introduced in which
recipients pay part of the tariffs for received calls. Starting in 1985, the PTV in con-
junction with Radio Austria initiated a text mail and data service "Telebox," which
attracted about 2100 subscribers by 1988.
3. ITT Austria was a successor to Czeija & Nissel, Austria's first telephone equip-
ment firm, which was at one time partly owned by AT&T and which exclusively sup-
plied large manual exchanges from 1896 to 1913.
4. There are claims that Austria was the first place in Europe with a transistorized
computer, the "Mailiipferl" (Smith, 1984, p. 14).
15. Sweden
16. Finland
I . In 1989, Motorola filed a patent suit against Nokia related to cellular handsets.
Nokia held 16 percent of the U.S. cellular equipment market (O'Dwyer, 1989b, p. 8).
Notes 447
The suit was resolved out-of-court, with Nokia and Korea's Tandy Corporation signing
a license agreement favorable to Motorola (O'Dwyer, 1989a).
20. Ireland
1. Its first operator was a boy who was dismissed for playing marbles while the
switchboard was idle.
21. Italy
1. Since 1984, broadcast teletext has been offered under the name of Televideo. The
FT administration also provides public bureaufax service with facsimile equipment in-
stalled at post offices; paging (Teledrin); electronic mail teletex (since 1985), and a slow
scan video system useful for traffic control and surveillance.
1. Some of the joint East-West ventures would not have been possible had not the
Coordinating Committee for Multi-Lateral Export Control (CoCom) moved in June 1990
to relax certain trade barriers against exporting telecommunications technology to East-
ern Europe, especially those that have demonstrated that they have ended "intelligence
cooperation" with the Soviet Union (Datapro, 1990). As a result, high-speed fiber op-
tics as well as data equipment (up to 9600 bps), analog mobile interface equipment, and
small digital PABXs could be sold to Hungary, Poland, and Czechoslovakia, though
not to Romania, Bulgaria, and Soviet Union, which were identified as more problematic
from a strategic perspective (Woollacott, 1990).
2. This section owes much of its information to Campbell (1988).
3. In Minsk, Kiev, Barabinskii, Erevan, Akhtyrskii, Perm, Sverdlovsk, Taldom,
Tashkent, Ufa, Kaunas, and Navlinskii and in Estonia (under that republic's control)
(Campbell, 1988, pp. 83-84).
1. The E.G. also faced disagreements among member states on satellite policy and
spectrum management. Tensions over service development especially in the area of
VSATs led to the postponement of the E.C.'s Blue Paper on satellite policy in 1990
(Roussel, 1990). Frequency coordination problems beyond the scope of CEPT's Radio-
communications Committee led the B.C. to call for a European Frequency Research
Institute to allocate spectrum for mobile services.
2. In order to satisfy the various national demands for participation, they were ex-
traordinarily complex in structure and acronyms. ESRO was headquartered in Paris,
while its two main technical centers were located in the Netherlands (ESTEC) and in
Germany (ESDAC, later ESOC). Other centers were ESLAB in the Netherlands, ESRIN
in Italy, and ESRANGE and ESTRACK in Sweden.
448 Notes
1. For example, Siemens produced computers during the 1960s under licenses ob-
tained from RCA, but was left in the lurch when RCA abandoned its computer business.
Siemens then joined Philips and CIT to form Unidata, a joint computer venture that
faltered in the mid-1970s. After the failure, Siemens entered into an arrangement with
Fujitsu for the manufacture of IBM plug-compatible machines, but the Japanese backed
out in 1985. In 1974, Siemens acquired an unsuccessful joint computer venture of AEG-
Telefunken, which also produced specialized mainframe computers under license from
RCA.
In Britain, the major computer manufacturer has been ICL, which has had some
success in mainframes, but less in the market for smaller units. Its overall market share
declined throughout the 1970s.
2. With the onset of integrated circuit technology, the role of the American govern-
ment as a purchaser of electronic components, until then a major factor, began to de-
cline. In 1960, public procurement of semiconductors was $258 million, 48 percent of
the total. By 1973, it had fallen to $201 million, 6 percent of the total U.S. sales (Levin,
1982). In 1987, because of the military buildup, government procurement (military and
civilian) had risen again to about $1.2 billion, or 12 percent of domestic sales (Semi-
conductor Industry Association, 1988, communication).
3. Capital markets in America, and to a lesser extent in Japan, were vastly more
active than their European counterparts, with the exception of London after the liberal-
ization of its trading practices. For the first ten months of 1985, for example, the turn-
over on U.S. security exchanges was $755.9 billion. In Japan, it was $267.1 billion. In
Britain, capital market turnover was only $48.8 billion, in Germany $29.7 billion, in
France $10.2 billion, and in Italy $3.8 billion (The Economist, 1985, p. 77). By 1990,
total turnover was greatest in Japan ($2,313 billion), followed by the U.S. ($1,542
billion), Germany ($661 billion), the U.K. ($379 billion), France ($65 billion) and Italy
($36 billion) (NYSE, 1990, communication).
4. In Germany, capital investment in private entrepreneurial operations also devel-
oped only slowly. An OECD report found that "Germany has long stood out by the
virtual absence of venture capitalism, in contrast to the dynamism that its small and
medium-sized firms display" (OECD, 1985, p. 31).
5. In absolute terms, support levels for the French plans were small: for the first
five-year plan, funding was $140 million; and for the second five-year period, $263
million.
6. A hierarchy of procurement preferences was established: top priority was given to
French companies, and lowest to imports to France. This system tended to exclude some
of the firms that produced the most advanced designs of chips, and thus restricted French
computer manufacturers at times from the use of the newest technology.
7. The Micro-Electronics Support Scheme, for example, provided only 12 million
of research and development money to British microelectronic manufacturers, mostly to
established firms such as GEC, Ferranti, and Plessey. Similarly, the Advanced Com-
puter Technology Project provided a tiny .8 million per year to British semiconductor
manufacturers between 1976 and 1979. During that same period, the Component Indus-
try Scheme distributed about 20 million (Malerba, 1985). Subsequently, the govern-
ment increased its support by contributing a quarter to a third of R&D expenditures and
a quarter of total necessary investments. The Micro-Electronics Industry Support Pro-
gram (MISP), the Micro-Electronics Application Project (MAP), and the Electronic
Component Industry Scheme (EC1S) were all launched in 1978. Also, the memory com-
Notes 449
ponent firm Inmos was created through the National Enterprise Board. Britain even
provided support to foreign companies that were domiciled in the United Kingdom.
8. International joint ventures often present difficult problems in practice. In addition
to the obstacle of incompatible products, problems include selection of the physical
location, the operational language, the composition of management, and labor sensitiv-
ities. The collaborative effort of Siemens, ICL, and Bull to develop fifth-generation
supercomputer technology was launched with a French director, English as the lan-
guage, and a shared R&D lab located in Germany. For the same reasons that firms like
to see duplication of efforts reduced by joint ventures, trade unions are suspicious of
such efforts. They are fearful of employment reduction and of the ability to deflect the
effects of strikes in one country.
9. One of the consequences of joint venturing is that it leads toward greater stress on
standardization. In March 1984, the twelve leading European computer and commu-
nication firms agreed to draft common standards for the interconnection of their prod-
ucts. In 1985, six European computer manufacturersSTC, Nixdorf, Siemens, Olivetti,
Philips, and Bulljointly determined to base their future computer systems on AT&T's
Unix operating system and to develop software for such uses. In 1986, they further
agreed to collaborate on OSI interconnection standards. Membership was open to other
European firms, but non-European companies (i.e., American and Japanese) were ex-
cluded.
1. This meant that the majority of the large business centers could now be served
directly by an international record carrier, rendering Western Union unnecessary for the
domestic leg of international transmissions. At the same time, the IRCs were required
to unbundle their rates into separate charges for terminal equipment, transmission, and
local access and to interconnect so that customers could use one telex machine to access
all IRCs.
To permit Western Union to offer international communications services, the FCC
had to overcome the opposition of the IRCs, which feared that Western Union would
provide far stronger international competition than domestic competition because of public
recognition of its name and the large number of telex machines already operating in the
United States. Although the U.S. Court of Appeals, 2nd Circuit, overturned this deci-
sion in 1980, the International Record Carrier Competition Act subsequently amended
the Communications Act of 1934 to permit Western Union IRC service. At the same
time, the legislation permitted the IRCs to provide domestic record service.
2. Although there are a number of technical objections to this proposal, none of them
is particularly convincing, considering the sophistication of telecommunications tech-
nology. Another objection is that multiple codes would impose an extra cost on the
PTTs. This extra cost, however, could be compensated by payments from the carriers,
which would benefit from access.
3. Prior to the advent of communications satellites, the FCC focused on authorization
for and ownership of submarine cable facilities. It scrutinized applications for these
facilities to decide whether their need justified an increase in a carrier's rate base. The
commission's close review of the applications resulted partly from the fact that invest-
ments in international submarine cables were quite large in comparison to investments
in most domestic facility applications.
AT&T, the IRCs, and other carriers used these cables and were at least theoretically
subject to rate base regulations and thus sought to obtain ownership interests in these
facilities, in the form of "indefeasible rights of use" (IRU). The FCC concluded that it
was impossible to audit the IRCs and that no benefits would flow from rate regulation
of the industry. The carriers sought ownership interests in order to expand their rate
bases and to realize certain benefits under the U.S. tax code. The IRUs still exist, and
the ownership interests in addition to the PTTs' interests have added new parties to the
negotiating process.
4. Following enactment of the Comsat Act, the FCC developed various policies to
establish and protect Comsat's role as the U.S. signatory and monopoly U.S. provider
of international satellite service. A key component of this role was the construction and
operation of these stations. Comsat and the U.S. international service carriers, AT&T
and the IRCs, would own and operate stations jointly through a cooperative Earth Sta-
tion Ownership Committee (ESOC). This approach gave Comsat the major role in earth
station management as well as in investment decisions and allowed Comsat to bundle
earth station costs with space segment costs in setting rates.
Following pressure from various carriers and users, the FCC proposed a more liberal
international earth stations policy in 1982. Carriers and users wanted Comsat to separate
out charges for its space segment (satellite) and earth segment (earth station), and they
also wanted the option of building their own lower-cost earth stations at sites with
efficient access to Intelsat. In 1984, the FCC authorized international earth stations
(Frieden, 1983).
Not surprisingly, the competitive pressures that led to modifications of policies re-
Notes 451
CCITT adopted a numbering plan that permits a multivendor system in the United States,
and also accommodates in PTT countries alternative providers of databases and local
area networks (Schiller, 1984).
3. Between the transmission line and the user, two sets of network termination equip-
ment exist, known as NT1 and NT2. NT1 provides the subscriber functions such as test
loops, power feedings, timing, multiplexing, and synchronization. The network termi-
nation point T is located between NT1 and NT2. NT2 equipment is more sophisticated
and provides functions of switching, multiplexing, and protocol handling by equipment
such as PBXs, local area networks, and terminal controllers.
4. The original American telephone companies' position had been to go with T as
the demarcation point; this point had to be defined by the CCITT Study Group, which
had thought in terms of an integrated rather than separated NT1 and NT2. PTTs can
integrate them if they wish to do so; and the German Bundespost's elaborate graphic
representation of ISDN architecture omits even an acknowledgement of point T's exis-
tence.
5. Going one step further, the German telecommunications equipment industry com-
missioned a report on ISDN by another former head of the governmental telecommuni-
cations department, Franz Arnold. That study was, if anything, critical of the Bundes-
post's ISDN and cable television plans as too timid. Arnold called for a "national
effort," which would include private and public funds, in which ISDN was a first step
in the right direction. This would provide German export industry with future potential,
which the present traditional copper-wire-oriented technology does not offer. For such
support, public funds must be available to reduce private risk (Muller-Sachs, 1984, pp.
6-7). In pursuit of goals, the Bundespost took an administrative leadership role in the
CCITT Study Group XVIII, which was chaired by one of its officials, Theodore Irmer,
who subsequently became the head of the CCITT itself. The DBF was also the first
PTT administration to announce a tariff structure for ISDN.
6. An operational framework for a CEI was reached in March 1986 by three major
firms with diverse interests: Pacific Bell (carrier), IBM (equipment supplier), and Tym-
net (value-added provider).
ing a one-day Transpac failure. However, CEPT challenged the survey, claiming that
96 percent of calls were completed successfully in 1989. The CEPT figures measured
only X.25 and not dial-up access (Schenker, 1990b).
4. The SCC also stores the message and relays it to the addressee. The RPs and
SCCs interconnect with leased lines since both the sender and receiver are encrypted so
that it is impossible to control which banks communicate with each other. The RPs
cannot communicate directly with each other, but must go through the SCCs. The lines
between the RPs and SCCs are doubled as insurance against lines failure, and the SCCs
also have back-up installations.
5. SWIFT supplies users with the necessary hardware and software through its sub-
sidiary STS SWIFT terminal services, with equipment by IBM, DEC, NCR, Burroughs,
and others. About 70 percent of the member banks opt to purchase SWIFT equipment
over equipment supplied directly by computer products vendors.
36. Videotex
1. SEAT is the official "publisher" of on-line information with its main product
being the Pagine Gialle Elettroniche (Electronic Yellow Pages). SEAT has data from 1
million Italian firms classified into 1400 categories. The system allows companies to
include technical and commercial data on their products, yet had only 25,836 users in
1987. Of the user sessions, 39 percent were to access PGE, 11 percent made use of
teletourism services, and 42 percent were on Amadeus, a real-time credit rating and
financial facts service aimed at business users. The PGE system developed by SEAT
runs on two simple commands, cerca (find) and mostra (show). Other services offered
by SEAT include Mastermail (electronic mail), Banca dati Tributaria (home banking),
teletourism, and an Official Airlines Guide. These services are generally not used much
beyond corporate applications. In 1990, there were 100,000 terminals in use, and SIP
had invested only 100 billion lire ($1 million).
lished information in one's possession, no one else could take it and publish it. This
was similar to a trespass and conversion action.
6. Justice Louis Brandeis, in a famous dissent, wrote of "the right to be left alone
the most comprehensive of rights and the right most valued by civilized men" (Olm-
steadv. U.S., 1927).
7. On the history of privacy, see Posner (1981); Simmel (1906); Westin (1967);
Seipp (1978). In the United States, privacy is a nonpartisan issue. The Privacy Act of
1974 was cosponsored by Senators Edward Kennedy and Barry Goldwater.
8. In the extreme, private information is so valuable to an individual as to make him
a target for blackmail. See also Brown and Gordon (1980) for an economic perspective
from the FCC.
9. In an information-based society and economy, the incentives to acquire informa-
tion are continuously increasing. See Posner (1981, pp. 231-347) for the most compre-
hensive discussion of the economics of privacy.
10. Another indication is provided by a survey conducted by American Express among
its card holders, which showed that 90 percent felt that mailing list practices were
inadequately disclosed, 80 percent felt that information should not be given to a third
party without permission, and more than 30 percent believed federal legislation was
needed to restrict the use of lists ["Privacy Study Reveals Lack of Consumer Confi-
dence," Direct Marketing, December 1988, p. 8, in McManus (1989)]. It should be
noted that American Express makes extensive use of the data it has accumulated on its
cardholders. According to Fortune, the company computers "maintain and update weekly
a profile of 450 attributessuch as age, sex, and purchasing patternson every card-
holder" (Newpert, 1989, p. 82).
A 1988 survey by the Massachusetts Executive Office of Consumer Affairs of the
main consumer complaints found them topped by telemarketing and promotional mail-
ings (Marchocki, 1989, p. 47; McManus, 1989, p. 82).
11. "Pac Bell backs off selling lists," Alameda Times Star, April 16, 1986, p. 16,
as cited in McManus (1989).
41. Regulatory Tasks for the Future: Interconnectivity in the Pluralist Network
1. The New York State Public Service Commission established, as the first state,
principles of ONA (Noam, 1990); it was also the first to establish collocation (NYPSC,
1989; NYPSC, 1990c).
2. In the United States, the fundamental 1934 Communications Act, for example,
defines it in a totally circular fashion. Section 153(h) states that "a common carrier
means any person engaged as a common carrier for hire. . . . "
3. The origins of common callings arose from the medieval custom of carrying on
business at stated periods in fairs within defined market areas. Fraudulent commercial
practices were prohibited and disputes were settled by the steward of the fair with the
assistance of the other merchants.
4. Western Union Telegraph Co. v. Call Publishing Co., 181 U.S. 92, 98 (1901).
5. These are part of the questions that the New York Public Service Commission
addressed. After public comment, the commission adopted common carriage principles
of content-neutrality-nondiscrimination and separation of content and conduit func-
tions. Issues include line-drawing problems. For example, are supplementary or subsid-
iary functions such as the signaling channel and network management functions part of
common carriage? Or is the central office affected, which is an issue in collocation? Or
billing and collection services, which are important to VANs?
Another kind of a question is whether common carriage and private carriage can
coexist in the same entity, or in the same service. For example, can a carrier be a
common carrier to users at one end of a communications link, but a private carrier to
the user at the other end?
Similarly, there is the question of how market power or monopoly should enter into
common carrier issues. Or the questions of what would qualify as legitimate distinctions
between classes of users, or what forms of prior subscription may be used for "adult"
programming.
6. New York State has a $1 per month lifeline plan, with installation spread over a
year to be $2 per month (NYPSC, 1987).
7. There is evidence for telephone wiretaps by private parties and individuals ten
years after Bell's patent (Westin, 1967). The New York Police Department tapped tele-
phones since at least 1895. In 1916, this led to a scandal about listening in on private
conversations of Catholic priests and to those of a law firm involved in competition to
J.P. Morgan & Co. for World War I munitions contracts (Seipp, 1978).
456 Notes
8. For example, in 1962, the U.S. federal government had 1030 computer central
processing units; in 1972, 6731; in 1982, 18,747; and in 1985, over 100,000 (Linowes,
1989).
9. In the past twenty years the cost of access to a name on a computer-based mailing
list has come down to about one thousandth of its earlier cost.
References
Dallmeyer, Martin. 1977. Quellen zur Geschichte Des Europdischen Postwesens 1501 -
1806. Bern: Verlag Michael Lassleben, Kallmiinz, vol. 1.
Ministry of Communications. 1990. Political Agreement on the Telecommunications
Structure. Copenhagen. June 22, p. 2.
Schulte, Josef. 1982. Endgeratekonzeption im Fernsprechdienst der Deutschen Bundes-
post. In Telekommunikation in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, ed. Dietrich
Elias. Heidelberg: R. V. Decker's Verlag, G. Schenck, pp. 319-48.
Stephan, Heinrich. 1859. Geschichte der Preussischen Post von ihrem Ursprunge bis
auf die Gegenwart. Berlin: Verlag der Koniglichen Geheimen Ober-Hof buch-
druckerei, (R. Decker).
Wolf, Thomas. 1983. Akzeptanz und Kosten des Schnurlosen Telephons, Neue Ziiricher
Zeitung. October 26.
457
458 References
3. Network Tipping: The Rise and Fall of the Public Network Monopoly
Allen, David. 1988. New Telecommunications Services: Network Externalities and Critical
Mass. Telecommunications Policy 12(3): 257-71.
Aronson, Jonathan, and Peter F. Cowhey. 1988. When Countries Talk. Cambridge,
MA: Ballinger.
Barnes, J. A. 1954. Class and Committees in a Norwegian Island Parish. Human Re-
lations, 1.
Baumol, William J., John C. Panzar, and Robert D. Willig. 1982. Contestable Markets
and the Theory of Industry Structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Boissevain, J. 1979. Network Analysis: A Reappraisal. Current Anthropology, 20.
Bott, E., 1971. Family and Social Network, New York: Free Press.
Buchanan, James M. 1965. An Economic Theory of Clubs. Economica 32(125): 1-14.
David, Paul A. 1987. Some New Standards for the Economists of Standardization in
the Information Age. In Economic Policy and Technological Performance, ed.
P. Dasgupta and P. L. Stoneman. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dumey, Richard. 1983. Telecommunications and the BT Case Competition Rules. Un-
published Speech at Antitrust Luncheon. Commission of The European Com-
munities, Directorate General for Competition, Brussels.
Economides, Nicholas. 1989. Desirability of Compatibility in the Absence of Network
Externalities. American Economic Review 79(5): 1165-81.
Elmaghraby, Salah E. 1970. Some Network Models in Management Science. New York:
Springer.
Hardin, Garrett. 1968. The Tragedy of the Commons. Science 162 (December 13).
Hayashi, Koichiro. 1988. The Economies of NetworkingImplications for Telecommu-
nications Liberalization, paper presented at the IIC Conference, Washington,
D.C., September.
Heal, Geoffrey. 1989. The Economics of Networks. New York: Columbia Institute for
Tele-Information. Working Paper Series.
Huber, Peter. 1987. The Geodesic Network. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing
Office.
Kami, Shlomo. 1986. An Analysis of Electrical Networks. New York: Wiley, pp. 1-4.
References 459
Klingman, David J., and J. Mulvey eds. 1981. Network Models and Associated Appli-
cations. New York: Elsevier.
Knox, Robert. 1830. Elements of General Anatomy, Translated from Inst. edition of
Beclard's Anatomy by D. A. Beclard. Edinburgh: Maclachlan & Stewart, p.
214.
McGuire, Martin. 1972. Private Good Clubs and Public Good Clubs: Economic Models
of Group Formation. Swedish Journal of Economics 74(l):84-99.
Mueller, Milton. 1988. Interconnection Policy and Network Economics. Paper presented
at Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, Airlie, Virginia, October
31.
Noam, Eli M. 1986. The "New" Local Communications: Office Networks and Private
Cable. Computer Law Journal 6(2).
. 1988. The Next Stage in Telecommunications Evolution: The Pluralistic Net-
work. Paper presented to the International Telecommunications Society, New
York: Columbia Institute for Tele-Information Working Paper Series.
Richardson, Jeremy John, Gunnel, Gustafson, and Art Jordan. 1985. In R. A. W. Rhodes,
Power Dependence, Policy Communities and IntergovernmentalNetworks.
Colchester, Essex: Department of Government, University of Essex, Wivenhoe
Park, pp. 6-8.
Rothenberg, Jerome. 1976. Inadvertent Distributional Impacts in the Provision of Public
Services to Individuals. In Public and Urban Economics, Ronald Grieson, ed.
Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Schelling, Thomas. 1978. Micromotives and Macrobehavior. New York: W. W. Nor-
ton.
. 1969. Models of Segregation. Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation.
Shepherd, William. 1983. Concepts of Competition and Efficient Policy in the Telecom-
munications Sector. In Telecommunications Today and Tomorrow, ed. Eli M.
Noam. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Tiebout, Charles. 1956. A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures. Journal of Political
Economy 64(5): 414-24.
Tullock, Gordon. 1971. Public Decisions as Public Goods. Journal of Political Econ-
omy 179(4): 913-18.
Woroch, Glenn A. 1990. On The Stability of Efficient Networks. Waltham MA: GTE
Labs. Mimeo.
Zacharisen, W. M. 1932. The Atomic Arrangement in Glass. Journal of the American
Chemical Society 54(10): 38-42.
4. Forces of Centrifugalism
Elton, Martin, ed. 1991. Integrated Broadband Networks: The Public Policy Issues,
Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Ergas, Henry. 1989. International Telecommunications Accounting Arrangements: An
Unsustainable Inheritance? Paper presented at Colloque Villefranche-sur-Mer.
June 1-3.
FCC. 1945. Statistics of Common Carriers. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Print-
ing Office.
. 1955. Statistics of Common Carriers. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office.
. 1965. Statistics of Common Carriers. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office.
. 1975. Statistics of Common Carriers. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office.
. 1985. Statistics of Common Carriers. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office.
Guerard, A., G. Lafarge, and C. Pautrat. 1979. Les Regions dans la Course au Tele-
phone. Economic et Statistique 117 (December):37-49.
Ito, Yoichi. Historical Review of Japanese Telecommunications Policies. In Pacific
Basin Telecommunications, ed. Eli Noam and Seisuke Komatsuzaki, forth-
coming.
Komatsuzaki, Seisuke. 1986. The Economic Impact of Informatization. In KEIO Com-
munication Review 7(March): 13-24. Tokyo: Institute for Communications Re-
search.
Nagai, Susuma. On the Deregulation Process in Japanese Telecommunications. In Pa-
cific Basin Telecommunications, eds. Eli Noam, and Seisuke Komatsuzaki, and
Douglas Conn, forthcoming.
Nambu, Tsuruhiko. A Comparison of Telecommunications Policies for Deregulation. In
Pacific Basin Telecommunications, eds. Eli Noam, Seisuke Komatsuzaki, and
Douglas Conn, forthcoming.
Noam, Eli M. 1986. The "New" Local Communications: Office Networks and Private
Cable. Computer Law Journal 6(2): 247-82.
. Divestiture Plus V and the Coming Regulatory Agenda. In New Regulatory
Concepts, issues, and Controversies, ed. Harry Trebing, forthcoming.
Nora, Simon, and Alain Mine. 1980. The Computerization of Society: Report to the
President of the French Republic. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Pfeiffer, Giinter, and Bernhard Wieland. 1990. Telecommunications in Germany: An
Economic Perspective. New York: Springer-Verlag.
Piore, Michael J. and Charles F. Sabel. 1984. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibili-
ties for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books.
Pool, Ithiel de Sola. 1990. Technologies Without Boundaries: On Telecommunica-
tions in a Global Age, ed. Eli Noam. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Porat, Marc U. 1978. Communication Policy in an Information Society. In Communica-
tions for Tommorrow, Policy Perspectives for the 1980s, ed. Glen O. Robinson.
New York: Praeger.
Schiller, Dan. 1982. Business Users and the Telecommunications Network. Journal of
Communication 32(4): 8497.
Schulte, Josef. 1982. Endgeratekonzeption im Fernsprechdienst der Deutschen Bundes-
post. In Telekommunikation in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, ed. Dietrich
Elias. Heidelberg: R. V. Decker's Verlag, G. Schenck, p. 321.
References 461
Steckel, Marie-Monique, and Marc Fossier. 1990. France Telecom: An Insider's Guide.
Chicago: Intertec.
Strassman, Paul. 1985. The Information Payoff: The Transformation of Work in the
Electronic Age. New York: Free Press.
Telecom Factbook. 1986. New York: Television Digest.
AT&T. 1976. An Econometric Study of Returns to Scale in the Bell System. Bell
Exhibit 60, FCC Docket 20003 (Fifth Supplemental Response), August 20.
Baumol, William J., John C. Panzar, and Robert D. Willig. 1982. Contestable Markets
and the Theory of Industry Structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Brock, Gerald W. 1981. The Telecommunications Industry: The Dynamics of Market
Structure. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Chrust, Steven. 1985. MCI Communications Corporation. New York: Bernstein Re-
search.
Dobell, Rodney A., et al. 1972. Telephone Communications in Canada: Demand, Pro-
duction, and Investment Decisions. Bell Journal of Economics and Management
Science 3(1): 175-219.
Federal-State Joint Board. 1988. Monitoring Report of the Federal-State Joint Board.
CC Docket No. 80-286, 87-339.
Fuss, Melvyn, and Leonard Waverman. 1977. Multi-product Multi-input Cost Functions
for a Regulated Utility: The Case of Telecommunications in Canada. NBER
Conference on Public Regulation. Washington, D.C., February 15-17.
Mantell, L. 1974. An Econometric Study of Returns to Scale in the Bell System. Staff
Research Paper. Office of Telecommunications Policy, Executive Office of the
President. Washington, D.C., February.
Meyer, John R., Robert W. Wilson, M. Alan Baughcum, Ellen Burton, and Louise
Caoulette. 1980. The Economics of Competition in the Telecommunications In-
dustry. Cambridge, MA: Oelgeschlager, Gunn & Hain.
Nadiri, Ishaq and Mark Schankerman. 1981. Production, Technological Change and
Productivity in the Bell System. In Productivity Measurement in Regulated In-
dustries, ed. Thomas Cowing and Rodney Stevenson. New York: Academic Press,
pp. 219-48.
OECD. 1990. Committee for Information, Computer and Communications Policy. Per-
formance Indicators for Public Telecommunications Operators. DSTI/ICCP/TISP/
89.10. February. Paris: OECD.
Schulte, Josef. 1982. Endgeratekonzeption im Fernsprechdienst der Deutschen Bundes-
post. In Telekommunikation in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, ed. Dietrich
Elias. Heidelberg: R. V. Decker's Verlag, G. Schenck, pp. 319-48.
Shepherd, William. 1983. Concepts of Competition and Efficient Policy in the Telecom-
munications Sector. In Telecommunications Regulation Today and Tomorrow,
ed. Eli Noam. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, pp. 79-120.
6. Policy Directions
Nora, Simon, and Alain Mine. 1980. The Computerization of Society: Report to the
President of the French Republic. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
7. Germany
Jason, Chris. 1985. Mercury Dials the Right Number. Financial Times, October 2,
p. 4.
Jones, Phil. 1989. UK Frees Leased Line Resale. Communications International, July,
p. 5.
Journal of Commerce. 1983.
Laws, Malcolm. 1989. U.K. Vendors Target New Network Niche. Communications
Week International, July 26, p. 1.
Littlechild, Stephen. 1983a. Deregulation of UK Telecommunications: Some Economic
Aspects. Economic Review 1(2): 29.
. 1983b. Regulations of British Telecommunications Profitability. London: De-
partment of Industry.
Locksley, Gareth. 1982. The EEC Telecommunications Industry: Competition, Concen-
tration and Competitiveness. Brussels: Commission of the European Communi-
ties.
. 1983. Europe and the Electronics Industry: Conflicting Strategies in Positive
Restructuring. West European Politics 6(2): 128-38.
Lynch, Karen, and Dawn Hayes. 1990. Telepoint Operators Refocusing. Communica-
tions Week International, July 16, p. 11.
Manning, D. 1988. Telecommunications in the United Kingdom. In European Telecom-
munications Organizations, ed. James Foreman-Peck and Jiirgen Miiller. Baden-
Baden: Nomos.
Maremont, Mark. 1989. British Telecom Is Getting Less British All the Time. Business
Week, August 14.
Monopolies and Mergers Commission, The General Electric Company, PLC, and The
Plessey Company. 1986. PLC: A Report on the Proposed Merger. London: Her
Majesty's Stationery Office.
Morgan, Kevin. 1987. Breaching the Monopoly: Telecommunications and the State in
Britain. Working Paper Series on Government-Industry Relations. No. 7. Uni-
versity of Sussex.
Noam, Eli M. 1982. Towards an Integrated Telecommunications Market: Overcoming
the Local Monopoly of Cable Television. Federal Communications Bar Journal,
34(2): 209-57.
. 1985. Video Media Competition. New York: Columbia University Press.
. 1986. The "New" Local Communications: Office Networks and Private Cable.
Computer Law Journal 6: 901-42. New York: Columbia University Press.
Official Journal L360. 1982. Congressional Record, U.K. December 21, p. 36
Oftel. 1985a. British Telcom's Price Changes. Oftel press notice. December 16.
. 1985b. Professor Carsberg Congratulates BT for Achieving Call Box Target.
Press release. April 20.
. 1988. Chatlines and Other Message Services. Statement from Professor Bryan
Carsberg. July 19.
. 1990a. Director General of Telecommunications Publishes Sixth Annual Re-
port. June 27.
. 1990b. PCN Licenses. Oftel News, March.
Purton, Peter. 1989. Slow Progress of VANS. Communications International, July, pp.
27-32.
. 1990. Old Player Returns to UK Telecom. Telephony, March 26, p. 14
Raggett, R. J. 1986. Racal Vodaphone Fights for Its Share. Telephony, April 28.
Redux, Huber. 1989. BT Ventures Proliferate as International Markets Complicate.
Telecommunications, September, pp. 57-58.
468 References
9. France
Alletier. 1973. Die Telegraphenstation Koeln-Flittard, Eine Kleine Geschichte der Na-
chrichtentechnik. Rheinisch-Westfaelisches: Wirtschaftsarchive zu Koeln.
Arlandis, Jacques and Laurent Gille. 1989. Performance Under Different Regulatory
Regimes: A Comparision of British Telecom and France Telecom. Montpellier:
IDATE.
Attali, Jacques, and Yves Stourdze. 1977. The Birth of the Telephone and Economic
Crisis: The Slow Death of Monologue in French Society. In The Social Impact
of the Telephone, ed. Ithiel de Sola Pool. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 97-
111.
Aurelle, Bruno. 1986. Les Telecommunications. Paris: Editions de la Couverte.
Benedetti, Marino. 1983. Telecommunications Services: Policy in Europe. Paper pre-
sented at the European Institute of Public Administration, Maestricht/Valkerburt.
Bertho, Catherine. 1987. Origins of the Organization of Telecommunications in France.
New York: Columbia Institute for Tele-Information. Working Paper Series.
, et al., ed. 1984. Histoire des Telecommunications en France. Toulouse: Edi-
tions Eres.
, and Michelle Nouvion. 1986. In Les Telecommunications, Bruno Aurelle. Paris:
Editions de la Couverte.
Bienaim, Jean-Pierre, and Michel Picaud. 1984. Telecommunications et le IXeme (ninth)
Plan. Revue Fran^aise des Telecommunications, January 19, pp. 35-41.
Bonan, M., Dominique Roux, and Jean Michel Delbarade. 1985. L'importance de Tele-
communications sur la Croissance Economique. Paris: Universite de Paris-
Dauphine.
Boult, Raymond. 1989. Users Back PTT Split. Communications International, October,
pp. 13-14.
References 469
Pautrat, Charles. 1984. La Nouvelle Structure Tarifaire. Revue Franfaise des Telecom-
munications, January, pp. 127-34.
Petersen, Thane. 1989. A New CEO Is Taking Bull by the Horns. Business Week, July
17, p. 80.
Pierrand, Jean. 1984. Thomson Voit Grand pour ses "Micro." Le Monde, April 23.
Quatrepoint, Jean-Michel. 1984. CIT-Alcatel n'a Fait qu'une Perce Limite sur les Marches
Europeens. Le Monde, May 15, pp. 20-21.
Rice, Valerie. 1989. It's Now or Never for Europe's Biggest Chip Makers. Electronic
Business 15(August 7): 16.
Roussel, Anne-Marie. 1989a. French Clarify VAN Regulation. Communications Week
International, May 15, p. 13.
. 1989b. French Revision. Communications Week International, May 29,
p. 22.
. 1989c. The Top 25. Communications Week International, October 24, p. CIO.
. 1989d. Quiles Offers Reform Plan. Communications Week International, No-
vember 13, p. 13.
. 1990a. French Reform Still Hotly Debated. Communications Week Interna-
tional, April 9, p. 3.
. 1990b. Reforms Gaining Ground. Communications Week International, May
21, p. 3.
. 1990c. French Senators Want More Reform. Communications Week Interna-
tional, June 18, p. 13.
. 1990d. Report Warns of Foreign "Invasion." Communications Week Interna-
tional, August 13.
Schenker, Jennifer. 1989a. Bull Reorganizes in Aftermath of Merger. Communications
Week International, February 6, p. 13.
. 1989b. New Minister on the Spot in France. Communications Week Interna-
tional, July, p. 24.
. 1989c. Users Combat French Initiative. Communications Week International,
November 27, p. 2.
. 1990. Transpac Ready to Branch Out. Communications Week International,
January 29, p. 2.
Scientific American. 1983. Special Issue on French Telecommunications. October.
Simon, Jean-Paul. 1990. Aftermath: Deregulation in France in the Eighties. Paper pre-
sented at the 18th Annual TPRC, Airlie VA. September.
Steckel, Marie-Monique, and Marc Fossier. 1990. France Telecom: An Insider's Guide.
Chicago: Telephony.
Stephan, Heinrich. 1859. Geschichte der Preussischen Post von ihrem Ursprunge bis
auf die Gegenwart. Berlin: Verlag der Koniglichen Geheimen Ober-Hofbuch-
druckerei (R. V. Decker).
Telecom France. 1990. Revue Franqaise des Telecommunications. International Edition.
April.
Telecommuncations Reports. 1990. National Assembly Approves Government Plan to
Separate France Telecom, Postal Service. May 28.
Telephony. 1985. A Partnership in Progress. February 11, pp. 32-33.
Tully, Shawn. 1989. Europe Goes on a Telephone Binge. Fortune, August 28.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1939. Cited in Telephone and
Telegraph Statistics of the World, January, 1938, American Telephone and
Telegraph Co. Comptroller's Department, Chief Statistician's Division. Wash-
ington, DC: Government Printing Office.
References 471
Dabbs, P., J. J. E. Swaffield, C. M. Aust, and I. Sarwar. 1982. Going Dutch! British
Telecom Journal. Spring.
de Pous, Victor. 1988. Dutch Privacy Bill Again Delayed. Transnational Data and
Communications Report. December, pp. 6-7.
. 1989. Dutch Data Protection Act in Force. Transnational Data & Communica-
tions Report. December, pp. 21-22.
Forden, Sara Gay. 1990. AT&T-Italian Joint Venture Targets and U.K., Greece, Por-
tugal, Spain Markets. The Wall Street Journal, July 28, pp. A3E, 3.
Hayes, Dawn. 1989. Suppliers Split Over GSM. Communications International, Sep-
tember 18, p. 1.
Hins, Wouter, and Bernt Hugenholtz. 1986. The Law and Economics of Transborder
Telecommunications: Report on the Netherlands. Hamburg: Max-Planck Institut.
Holcombe, A. N. 1911. Public Ownership of Telephones on the Continent of Europe.
Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
ITU. 1990. Annual Telephone Statistics. Geneva: ITU.
Kingdom of the Netherlands. 1981. Facts and Figures: Transport and Communications.
Amsterdam: Ministry of Foreign Affairs.
Lablans, Peter. 1989. Privatization of the Dutch PIT: New Telecommunications Op-
portunities. Telecommunications Business 1(3): 61-66.
Malerba, Franco. 1985. The Semiconductor Business. Madison: University of Wisconsin
Press.
Montgomery, Page, Lee Selwyn, and Paul Keller. 1990. The Telecommunications In-
frastructure in Perspective. Economics & Technology, Inc. March.
Netherlands PTT. 1985. PTT in Motion. Amsterdam: Netherlands PIT.
Philips, Frederik. 1978. Forty-Five Years With Philips. Dorset, UK: Blandford Press.
Prokesch, Steven. 1990. Philips Sees $1 Billion Loss in Reorganizing 2 Divisions. New
York Times. July 3, pp. D1-D2.
PTT Telecommunicatie. 1983. The Dutch Telecommunications Service in Brief. Am-
sterdam: PTT Telecommunicatie.
Schenker, Jennifer. 1989. Dutch PTT Enters Datacoms Market. Communications Week
International. October 16, p. 87.
. 1990. Judging the PTTs. Communications Week International. July 16, pp.
Cll-12.
Staple, Gregory. 1990. The Global Telecommunications Traffic Boom. London: IIC.
Tagliabue, Paul. 1987. New York Times. January 15, p. F8.
Transnational Data and Communications Report. (TDR). 1989. Equipment Approval
Row Mars Start of Dutch PTT. February, p. 3.
472 References
11. Belgium
Belgian National Committee for the World Year of Communications. 1983. Belgian
Communications Technology, November.
Cheeseright, Paul. 1985. Key Decisions Still Awaited. Financial Times, January 14,
p. 8.
Euro-Telecom News. 1987. Belgium. 1(10).
ITU. 1990a. Annual Telephone Statistics. Geneva: ITU.
. 1990b. European Digital Mobile Telephone Network: Belgium Chooses System
Suppliers. Telecommunications Journal 57(3): 191.
Kellaway, Lucy. 1990. Don't Ring Us. ... Financial Times, June 18, p. 4.
Miiller, Jiirgen. 1988. Telecommunications in Belgium. In European Telecommunica-
tions Organizations, ed. James Foreman-Peck and Jiirgen Miiller. Baden-Baden:
Nomos, pp. 87-102.
Pichault, Frangois. 1985. La Telematique dans le Cadre Reglementaire et Institutionnel
de la Belgique. Courier Hebdomadaire, CRISP, December 6.
Poullet, Yves. 1989. The Belgian Telecommunications Case. Presented at FNRS Inter-
national Conference on Telecommunications. Brussels. January 20.
RTT. 1985. Current Situation and Development of Telecommunications in Belgium.
Telecommunication Journal, pp. 52, 191.
. 1987. Belgium Telecommunications. Brussels: RTT.
Schenker, Jennifer. 1990. Judging the PTTs. Communications Week International, July
16, p. C13.
Tutt, Nigel. 1989. A Question of Balance. Communications International, August, pp.
21-26.
. 1990. Belgium Belies Status as Netherlands Reforms. Communications Inter-
national, July, pp. 15-19.
U.S. Department of Justice. 1987. The Geodesic Network: 1987 Report on Competition
in the Telephone Industry (The Huber Report). Washington, D.C.: Government
Printing Office. January.
References 473
12. Luxembourg
13. Switzerland
14. Austria
15. Sweden
Dabbs, P., J. J. E. Swaffiekl, C. M. Aust, and I. Sarwar. 1982. Going Dutch! British
Telecom Journal, Spring.
Evagora, Andreas. 1990. Privatization Proposed. Communications Week International,
October 1, p. 10.
Gilhooly, Denis. 1990. Swedes Opening Resale Market. Communications Week Inter-
national, June 4, p. 1.
Gleiss, Norman. 1983. Connection of Privately Owned Equipment. Tele, XXXVI(21).
English edition.
Gustafsson, Karl Erik. 1987. Televisioneren studie i branschutveckling. Kristianstad:
Raben & Sjogren.
Heimburger, Hans. 1931. The State Telephone System 1881-1902. Gothenburg.
Holcombe, A. N. 1911. Public Ownership of Telephones on the Continent of Europe.
Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
ITU. 1990a. Annual Telephone Statistics. Geneva: International Telecommunications
Union.
. 1990b. Swedish Telecom Introduces Information and Entertainment Service.
Telecommunications Journal 57(4): 258.
Krzywicki, John. 1990. Japan and Sweden: Comparative Regulatory Frameworks. Cam-
bridge Strategic Management Group. Presented at the Telecommunications Re-
ports Price Caps Pre-Conference Seminar. July 13.
Ministry of Transport and Communications. 1987. Telecom in Change. Stockholm.
June.
Mitchell, Bridger M. 1983. The Cost of Telephone Service: An International Compari-
son of Rates in Major Countries. Telecommunications Policy. March.
OECD. 1985. Report to the Committee for Information, Computer and Communications
Policy. Special Session on Telecommunications Policy. Paris.
. 1987. The Swedish Telecom Market. Report No. 1437. Unpublished paper.
Paris. May.
. 1989. Telecommunication Network-Based Services: Policy Implications. Paris.
. 1990. Committee for Information, Computer and Communications Policy. Per-
formance Indicators for Public Telecommunications Operators. DSTI/ICCP/TISP/
89.10. February. Paris: OECD.
O'Dwyer, Gerauerd. 1990a. Nordic Free Market Looms. Communications Interna-
tional, April, pp. 5-6.
. 1990b. Televerket to Face Appeal. Communications International, June, pp.
6-7.
Qvortrup, Lars. 1989. The Nordic Telecottages. Telecommunications Policy, March,
pp. 59-68.
Satellite Communications. 1988. Comvik Receives Permission to Transmit to North
America. December, p. 8.
Siemens. 1985. Study on National Tariffs Worldwide.
Swedish Telecommunications Authority. 1987. Facts About Televerket: 1987. Farsta:
Televerket Information Unit.
Telephony. 1984. A Commitment to Quality. October 7, p. 7,
. 1987. Ericsson Divests Office Equipment Firm. October 26, p. 26.
Televerket. 1983. Organization and Operation of the Swedish Telecommunications Ad-
ministration. Stockholm: Televerket.
. 1984. Annual Report. Stockholm.
. 1989. Who Represents Europe? Paper presented at Assessment 1989. Luxem-
bourg. May 11.
476 References
16. Finland
17. Norway
18. Denmark
Barnes, Hillary. 1987. Low-Cost Calls. Financial Times, October 19, p. 29.
Feldman, Mark B., and David R. Garcia. 1982. National Regulation of Transborder
Data Flows. North Carolina Journal of International Law and Commercial Reg-
ulation 7(1): 1-25.
Green, Jeremy. 1989. The Unconventional Ways of Danish Comms. Communications
International, November supplement, pp. 29-32.
NKT. 1987. NKT at Telecom 87, October.
OECD. 1982. Committee for Information, Computer and Communications Policy.
Background Report: Denmark. Unpublished report for Special Session on the
International Implications on Changing Market Structures in Telecommunica-
tions. Paris.
Olsen, O. Jess. 1988. Deregulation and Reorganizationthe Case of Danish Telecom-
munications. Memo 4. Copenhagen: Institute of Economics, University of Co-
penhagen.
Pedersen, Mogens Kuhn. 1987. The State and Telecoms Policy: Convenient or Con-
trived? Unpublished paper.
. 1988. The Danish Telecommunications Equipment Industry. Paper presented
at European Association for Research in Industrial Economics, Rotterdam. Au-
gust.
P&T Directorate General. 1988. Liberalization of the Rules Governing Text and Data
Transmissions on the Danish Telecommunications Network. June 21.
Qvotrup, Lars. 1984. Cable Television: Public Infrastructure or Private Business, Cable
Politics in Denmark. Le Bulletin de I'Idate: Le Prix des Nouveaux Medias
17(October): 173-79.
TeleDenmark. 1987. Strongest Growth Is in International Telecom Traffic.
Transnational Data and Communications Report. (TDR) 1989. Europe Achieving
Telecom Reforms. October, pp. 6-8.
Williamson, John. 1990. Danes Buy Back Local Telcos. Telephony, April 2, p. 16.
478 References
19. Iceland
Eurodata Foundation Yearbook. 1987. London: Eurodata Foundation.
ITU. 1990. Annual Telephone Statistics. Geneva: ITU.
OECD. Committee for Information, Computer and Communications Policy. 1990. Per-
formance Indicators for Public Telecommunications Operators. February, DSTI/
ICCP/TISP/89.10. Paris: OECD.
Post and Telecommunications Administration. 1986. Telecommunications in Iceland.
Tomasson, Olafur. 1990. Iceland. Telephony, January 22, p. 54.
20. Ireland
21. Italy
Antonelli, Cristiano. 1988. The Emergence of the Network Firm. In New Information
Technology and Industrial Change: The Italian Case, ed. Cristiano Antonelli.
Dordrecht: Kluwer.
References 479
22. Spain
Bradsher, Keith. 1990. Allure of Spain's Phone Company. The New York Times, March,
p. D12.
Burns, Tom. 1985. ITT's Redundancy Plans Unacceptable, Says Spain. Financial Times,
October 1, p. 2.
de Moragas, Miguel, Rosario de Mateo, and Emilio Prado. 1987. Spain. Electronic
Mass Media and Politics in Western Europe, ed. Hans J. Kleinsteuber, Denis
McQuail, and Karen Siune. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, pp. 251-72.
The Economist. 1985. Hello World, Madrid Calling. May 25.
. 1990. Please Try Again. May 12, pp. 71-72.
Eurodata Foundation Yearbook. 1986. London: Eurodata Foundation.
Financial Times. 1989. Nynex Sees Gibraltar As Its Telecoms Showcase. October 5.
ITU. 1990. Annual Telephone Statistics. Geneva: ITU.
Lopez-Escobar, Esteban. 1985. Spain Telecom's Monopoly. Intermedia, July/Septem-
ber, pp. 3-4.
Manning, Dorothy, Diego Bader von Jagow, James Foreman-Peck, and Jiirgen Muller.
1988. In European Telecommunications Organisations, ed. James Foreman-Peck
and Jiirgen Muller. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
MarTech Strategies, Inc. 1983. Telecommunication Policies in Ten Countries: Prospects
for Future Competitive Access. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
Martinez, Miguel. 1990. A Digital Missing Link. Communications International, Feb-
ruary, pp. 18-20.
Morgan, Jeremy, and Charles Mason. 1990. Argentina's Entel Deal Postponed as Banks
Struggle to Meet Terms. Telephony, August 20, p. 8.
Purton, Peter. 1989. What the EC Is Trying to Achieve. Communications International,
July, pp. 28-29.
. 1990. Nineties May Be Fiesta for Spanish Telecoms. Communications Inter-
national, February, pp. 15-17.
Ryser, Jefferey. 1988. Getting South America's #!*% Phones to Work. Business Week,
April 18.
Taylor, Robert. 1990. Ericsson Offshoot Wins Spanish Telecoms Order. Financial Times,
July 6.
Telefonica. 1990. 1989 Annual Report Madrid: Telefonica.
References 481
23. Portugal
24. Israel
Bainerman, Joel. 1988. Israeli Upstarts Target Niches. Communications Week Interna-
tional, November 7, p. 24.
. 1989. The Pragmatic Approach. Communications Systems Worldwide, Septem-
ber, p. 50.
Eres, Beth. 1989. Status and Trends in the use of Computers and Telecommunications
in Israel. Interdisciplinary Center for Technological Analysis and Forecasting,
TelAviv University.
Hai, Shaul. 1988. Israel. Telephony, January 22, p. 62.
Israel Statutes. 1982. 7060: The Telecommunication Law. Jerusalem. August 22.
ITU. 1990. Annual Telephone Statistics. Geneva: ITU.
Louisson, Simon. 1987. After Three Years Success Still on Hold for Bezeq. Jerusalem
Post.
TRC. 1990. Market Report. Bezeq-Israel. World Telecom Daily. February 26, pp. 15-
19.
482 References
25. Turkey
26. Greece
Efstathiou, James. 1990. Greece Going Digital. Communications Week International,
September 17.
Eurodata Foundation Yearbook. 1984. London: Eurodata Foundation.
ITU. 1990. Annual Telephone Statistics. Geneva: ITV.
Kotsonis, Stefan. 1990. "Greek Telecoms Shake-up" Communications International
December, pp. 14, 16.
OECD. 1990. Committee for Information, Computer and Communications Policy. Per-
formance Indicators for Public Telecommunications Operators. DSTI/ICCP/TISP/
89.10. February. Paris: OECD.
OTE. 1985. Annual Report 1984. Athens.
. 1985. Telecommunications Statistics in Greece '84. Athens.
Schenker, Jennifer. 1990. Judging the PTTs. Communications Week International, June
12, pp. Cl-16.
. 1990. The Soviet Telecom Challenge. Eastern Europe and Soviet Telecom
Report 1(6).
Communications International. 1989. December, p. 12.
Datapro. 1990. Datapro Reports on International Telecommunications. New York:
McGraw-Hill.
Dellin, L. A. D., ed. 1957. East Central Europe Under the Communists: Bulgaria.
New York: Fredrick A. Praeger, pp. 369, 383-84.
Dixon, Hugo. 1988a. UK Group in Soviet Pay Phone Venture. Financial Times, July
5, p. 3.
. 1988b. UK Digital Telecoms Switch for Moscow. Financial Times, October
18, p. 6.
. 1990. The Paranoia Eases. Financial Times, April 19.
Eastern European and Soviet Telecom Report (EESTR). 1990a. Hungarian Telecom:
Catching Up With Europe, 1(3).
. 1990b. Polish Telecom: New Directions, 1(4).
The Economist. 1990. Sorry, Reformer, the Line Is Dead. July 21, p. 2.
Fidler, Stephen. 1990. Western Companies Hold Lifeline for Eastern Europe. Financial
Times, April 17, p. 4.
Financial Times. 1987. October 19, p. XXIV.
Frank!, Judy. 1989. The Telecoms Glasnost. Communications International, July, pp.
39-41.
Gilhooly, Denis. 1989. Hungary Heralds Telecoms Reform. Communications Week In-
ternational, October 30, p. 1.
Goodhart, David. 1989. Siemens to Modernize Soviet Telephones. Financial Times,
August 3, p. 3.
Gulyaev, Yuri V. 1990. Directions in Telecommunications Policy in the USSR. Paper
presented to the International Telecommunications Society. Venice, Italy, March.
Hayes, Dawn. 1990. Cellular Network Proposed for Baltic. Communications Week In-
ternational, June 18, p. 18.
Kelly, Tim. 1990. Telecommunications and Eastern European Economies. Paris: OECD.
Lakicevic, Ognjen, ed. 1970. A Handbook of Yugoslavia. Belgrade: Beogradski Graficki
Zavod.
Lewis, Patrick. 1976. Communications Output in the USSR: A Study of The Soviet
Telephone Systems. Soviet Studies, July, pp. 406-17.
Major, Iva. 1980. The Progress of the Hungarian Telephone. Hungarian Academy of
Sciences: Institute of Economics Series, 17.
Nulty, Timothy. 1990. Considerations in Telecom Investment in Eastern Europe. Wash-
ington, D.C.: World Bank.
Pearce, Alan. 1990. A Capital Question. Network World, April 30.
Poland: A Handbook. 1974. Warsaw: Interpress, pp. 276-77'.
Popescu, Virgil. 1990. Romania. Bucharest: Ministry of Communications.
Pronay, G. 1990. Freedom of Speech. IEEE Review, July/August.
Purton, Peter. 1990. Western Firms Plan Baltic Service. Telephony, June 11, pp. 16,
20.
Rocks, David. 1990. Hungary Grants Second Cellular Net. Communications Week In-
ternational, June 4, p. 7.
Satellite Communications. 1990. July, p. 9.
Schenker, Jennifer. 1990. Upgrade in Czechoslovakia. Communications Week Interna-
tional, July 2.
484 References
Selin, Ivan. 1986. Communications and Computers in the Soviet Union. Signal, De-
cember, pp. 91-95.
Skendi, Stavro. ed. 1956. East Central Europe Under the Communists: Albania. New
York: Frederick A. Praeger.
U.S. Department of State, Advisory Committee on International Communications and
Information Policy. 1990. Eastern Europe: Please Stand By. Washington, D.C.:
U.S. Department of State.
Woollacott, Emma. 1990. Relaxation on a Sliding Scale. Communications Interna-
tional, July, pp. 32-33.
Aronson, Jonathan, and Peter Cowhey. 1988. When Countries Talk. Cambridge, MA:
Ballinger.
Butler, Richard. 1989. ITU Plenipotentiary Conference: Closing Address. June 30.
Codacovi, Lawrence. 1989. WATTC: Impact on Services. Transnational Data and
Communications Report, June-July, pp. 18-20.
Codding, George A., Jr. 1984. Public Access to International Organizations: the ITU.
Intermedia 12(6).
. 1990. The Nice ITU Plenipotentiary Conference. Telecom Policy, April, pp.
139-50.
, and Anthony M. Rutkowski. 1982. The International Telecommunication Union
in a Changing World. Dedham, MA: Artech
Cowhey, Peter S., and Jonathan B. Aronson. 1985. The Great Satellite Shoot-Out.
Regulation, May-June, pp. 27-35.
Dougan, Diana Lady. 1987. The High Stakes Game of International Standards Setting.
Washington D.C.: U.S. Department of State.
Drake, William. 1988. WATTC-88: Restructuring the International Telecommunication
Regulations. Telecommunications Policy, September, pp. 217-23.
. 1989. The CCITT: Time for Reform? in Reforming the Global Network. Lon-
don: International Institute of Communications, pp. 28-43.
Gibbons, Roger. 1989a. Surveying Europe's Standardization Scene. Communications
International, November, pp. 25-31.
. 1989b. European Standards. Communications International, December, pp. 19-
22.
Gilhooly, Denis. 1989. Finland's Tarjanne Elected ITU Head. Communications Week
International, June 26, p. 41.
. 1990. CEPT Faces Up to Its Changing Role. Communications Week Interna-
tional, March 12, p. 13.
Le Boucher, Eric. 1984. Europe des Telecommunications S'Organise. Le Monde, Jan-
uary 21.
Lynch, Karen. 1990. U.S. Turnaround. Communications Week International, October
29, p. 4.
Northern Telecom. 1980. Nature of the Telecommunications Industry Throughout the
World. Submission to the Canadian Restrictive Trade Practices Commission. May.
Official Journal L360. 1982. Congressional Record, December 21, p. 36.
Quander, Peter. 1982. Internationale Zusammenarbeit? In Telekommunikation in der
Bundesrepublik Deutschland, ed. Dietrich Elias. Heidelberg: R.V. Decker's Verlag,
G. Schenck, pp. 375-90.
References 485
Rutkowski, Anthony M. 1982. The U.S.A. and the ITU: Many Attitudes, Few Policies.
Intermedia 10(4-5).
Satelllite News. 1990. Execs Spar at Philips Satellite IX Conference. March 19.
Schenker, Jennifer. 1989. CEPT Revamping Rates. Communications Week Interna-
tional, February 6, p. 1.
Scherer, Joachim. 1985. Telekommunikationsrecht und Telekommunikationspolitik. Baden-
Baden: Nomos.
Schnurr, L. E. 1988. The Single European Act: Towards an Open Market in 1992.
Essex: Essex Institute of Higher Education.
Warden, Becky. 1990. The Curtain Rises on a New Satellite Generation. Communica-
tions International, July, p. 5.
Whitehouse, Bob. 1989. "IT in the ITU" Says Dr. Tarjanne. Communications Inter-
national, October, pp. 20-23.
. 1990. CEPT Accedes Under Siege. Communications International, April,
p. 6.
Aronson, Jonathan David, and Peter F. Cowhey. 1987. When Countries Talk. Cam-
bridge, MA: Ballinger.
Cane, Alan. 1985. Producers Pin Hopes on New Alliances. Financial Times, June 24,
p. 3.
Dang-Nguyen, Godefroy. 1986. A European Telecommunications PolicyWhich In-
struments for Which Prospects? ENST-Bretagne. August.
The Economist. 1985. Privatization: Everybody's Doing It Differently. December 21.
Ellul, Jacques. 1964. The Technological Society. New York: Knopf.
Ergas, Henry. 1985. Exploding the Myths About What's Wrong. Financial Times, June
26.
Etheridge, James, 1983. Center of Controversy. Datamation 240(June): 31-34.
de Jonquieres, Guy. 1990. Shadows Over the Sunrise Sector. Financial Times, July 25,
p. 12.
Knieps, Giinter, Jiirgen Miiller, and Carl Christian von Weizsacker. 1981. Die Rolle
des Wettbewerbs im Fernmeldebereich. Baden-Baden: Nomos, 1984.
Levin, R. C. 1982. The Semi-conductor Industry. In Government and Technical Prog-
ress: A Cross Industry Analysis, ed. R. R. Nelson. New York: Paramount Press.
Malerba, Franco. 1985. The Semi-conductor Business. Madison: University of Wiscon-
sin Press.
Miiller, Jiirgen. The Benefits of Completing the Internal Market for Telecommunications
Equipment in the Community. Research on the Cost of Non-Europe. Fontain-
bleau: INSEAD. vol. 1.
OECD. 1985. Committee for Information, Computer and Communications Policy. Ven-
ture Capital in Information Technology. Paris: OECD.
Palmer, Michael, and Jeremy Tunstall. 1990. Liberating Communications: Policymak-
ing in France and Britian, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Wiegner, Kathleen. 1985. Europe Fights Back. Forbes, August 12, p. 82.
Wiles, Peter. 1960. Will Capitalism and Communism Spontaneously Converge? For-
eign Affairs, February.
Colby, Laura, and Richard Hudson. 1989. AT&T Learns Right Choices for Europe.
Wall Street Journal, February 2. p. 27.
Davis, Bob. 1988. FCC Orders Phone Companies to Report Yearly Purchases of For-
eign Equipment. Wall Street Journal, February 26.
References 487
Baumol, W. J., J. C. Panzar, and R. D. Willig. 1983. Contestable Markets and the
Theory of Industry Structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Besen, S., and L. Johnson. 1986. Compatibility Standards: Innovation and Competition
in the Broadcast Industry. Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation.
David, P. A. 1984. Understanding the Economics of QWERTY, or Is History Neces-
sary? Mimeo. Stanford University.
Digital NCTE Decision. FCC Docket No. 81-216.
Farrell, Joseph, and Garth Saloner. 1985. Standardization, Compatibility, and Innova-
tion. Rand Journal of Economics 16(1): 7083.
. 1986a. Standardization and Variety. Economics Letters, January.
. 1986b. Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product Preannounce-
ments and Predation. MIT Working Papers, No. 411, February.
References 489
36. Videotex
Booker, Ellis. 1989. Vive le Minitel. Telephony, August 8, pp. 23-25.
British Business. 1981. CCITT. 1980. Study Group VII. Recommendation S.100. Lon-
don: Crown Publishing. January.
Clavaud, Richard. 1984. Le Destin Incertain de Minitel. L'Expansion, April, p. 37.
Darmon, Jacques. 1985. Le Grand Derangement: La Guerre du Telephone. Paris: Edi-
tions Jean Claude Latles.
The Economist. 1989. Highwired Society. August 9, p. 55.
France Telecom. 1990. Teletel Meets with Worldwide Success. Revue Franc,aise des
Telecommunications, No. 12 (April).
France Telecom News. 1990. Minitel Penetrates French Business. Winter.
Howkins, John. 1985. Communications in Finland. Intermedia, 10(4-5): 48-49.
492 References
Kramer, Richard. 1991. Misapplying the Model: The French Minitel and U.S. Video-
tex. New York: Columbia Institute for Tele-Information Working Paper Senes.
Neue Medien. August 1985.
Roussel, Anne-Marie. 1989a. Italians, French, Purchasing Videotex. Communications
Week International, March 12, p. 6.
. 1989b. Minitel Gets New Terminal. Communications Week International, April
17, p. 52.
. 1989c. France's Minitel Shows Major Losses. Communications Week Interna-
tional, July 10, p. 14.
. 1989d. France Telecom Rebuts Teletel Drain. Communications Week Interna-
tional, August 14, p. 8.
, and Mark Rockwell. 1989. Minitel Spreads Beyond France. Communications
Week International, June 12.
Sichel, Bertha. 1983. How the French Are Using Videotex. ITP Report, No. 1 (Spring-
Summer): 23.
Telematique News. 1987. 1987 Minitel Statistics: January to June. Fall.
Thomas, Hilary. 1988. Mintel USA. Mimeo. November.
Tonnemacher, Jan. 1982. The New Media in West Germany. Intermedia 10(2).
Tydeman, John, et al. 1982. Teletext and Videotex in the United States. New York:
McGraw Hill.
Vedel, Thierry. 1987. New Media Politics and Policies in France from 1981 to 1986:
What Is Left? New York: Columbia Institute for Tele-Information Working Pa-
per Series.
Woollacott, Emma. 1990. Small Screen Services. Communications International, Feb-
ruary, pp. 41-43.
Anderla, G. 1983. The International Data Market Revisited. Report to the Second Sym-
posium on TBDF. Paris: OECD. October.
Botein, Michael, and Eli M. Noam. 1986. U.S. Restrictions on International Data
Transmission by Telecommunications Networks. New York: Columbia Institute
for Tele-Information Working Paper Series.
Cass, Ron, and Eli Noam. 1990. Services Trade and Services Regulation in the United
States. Rules for Free International Trade in Services, eds. D. Friedman and
E. J. Mestmacker. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Commission of the European Communities (CEC). 1990. Concerning the Protection of
Personal Data and Privacy in the Context of Public Digital Telecommunications
Networks. June 5.
Consultative Committee on the Implications of Telecommunications for Canadian Sov-
ereignty (CCITCS). 1979. Telecommunications in Canada. Ottawa: Information
Canada.
de Pous, Victor. 1989. Dutch Data Protection Act in Force. Transnational Data and
Communications Report, December, pp. 21-22.
Fauret, Jacques. 1989. Privacy in the New Europe. Transnational Data and Commu-
nications Report. November, pp. 17-18.
Feketekuty, Geza, and Jonathan David Aronson. 1983. The World Information Econ-
omy. Background Paper of the George Washington and McGill Universities'
References 493
Roche, Edward M. 1984. New Agency on Technology Takes Flight. The Independent
10(4).
Sauvant, Karl P. 1986. Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in Data Services. West-
view Special Studies in International Economics and Business. Boulder, CO:
Praeger, Westview Press.
Seipp, David John. 1978. The Right to Privacy in American History. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard Program on Information Resources Policy, pp. 78-83.
Simmel, Georg. 1906. The Sociology of Secrecy and of Secret Societies, American
Journal of Sociology 11: 441, 446, 450.
Simitis, Spiros. 1985. Data Protection: New Developments, New Challenges. Trans-
national Data and Communications Report 8(2): 95-96
Sixth Report of the Data Distribution Registrar, 1990. London: Her Majesty's Stationery
Office, June.
Transnational Data and Communications Report (TDR). 1983. European Data Base
Searches Chapter Than Using US. 6(8): 423.
. 1986. OECD Weighs Future Telcom Policy Role. 9(1).
. 1989. Protection of Personal Data Used for Employment Purposes. March, pp.
26-29.
Turn, Rein, ed. 1979. Transborder Data Flows: Concern in Privacy Protection and
Free Flow of Information. Washington, DC: American Federation of Information
Processing Societies, vol. 1.
Warren, Samuel D., and Louis D. Brandeis. 1890. The Right to Privacy. Harvard Law
Review 4: 193,196.
Westin, Alan. 1967. Privacy and Freedom. New York: Atheneum.
Wigand, Rolf T. 1985. Transborder Data Flow and Its Impact on Business and Govern-
ment. Information Management Review 1(2).
Piore, Michael, and Charles Sabel. 1984. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities
for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books.
41. Regulatory Tasks for the Future: Interconnectivity in the Pluralist Network
497
498 Index
Office equipment manufacturers, 24 PBX (private branch exchange), 46, 74, 76,
Office of Management and Budget (OMB), 77, 305, 373
398 in Belgium, 180
Oftel (Office of Telecommunications) (United in Denmark, 227, 228, 308
Kingdom), 106-9, 112, 115-19, 121, in Finland, 215
124, 129-32, 321, 428 in France, 140, 152-53
Ohnesorge, W., 71 in Germany, 85, 86, 91
Okavana, Jun, 233 in Iceland, 231
Olinet, 248 in Israe!, 266
Olivetti, 98, 239, 248-50, 308, 317, 318, 325 in Netherlands, 172, 176, 177
Olivetti-Bull, 159 in Norway, 223
Olsen, O. Jess, 225, 226 in Portugal, 261
Omnitel, 188, 250 in Russia, 287
On-line databases, 379, 402-4 in Sweden, 205-7
Ontyme, 131 in Switzerland, 190
Open network architecture (ONA) concept, 39, in Turkey, 268
60, 364-67, 372, 415, 426, 435, 436 in United Kingdom, 124-25
Open Network Provision (ONP), 145, 182, in Yugoslavia, 280
306-8, 365-67, 372, 436 PCI, 372
Open skies policy, 301, 335 Pearce, Alan, 274
Open Systems Interconnection (OSI) model, Pebereau, George, 154, 155, 158, 328
116, 365, 413 Pedersen, Mogens Kuhn, 225-28
Optical switched-star cable systems, 53 Penny Post, 15-17
Orbita-Molniia satellite system, 284 Pentaconta system, 152
Organic Law of 1959 (France), 143 People's Republic of China, 110, 209
Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Peres, Shimon, 263
Development (OECD), 24, 171, 210, Perier, Denis, 388
213, 216, 230, 244, 267, 280, 293, 302, Perry, Charles R., 19
339-49, 363, 393-94, 402 Persians, 7
Orion Telecommunications, 335, 337 Personal networks, 119-20, 408
Orkla Borregaard, 222 Peru, 7, 325
Osterreichische Post und Pervyshin, Erlen, 287
Telegraphenverwaltung (PTV), 196-99 Petersen, Thane, 162
OTC, 288 Pfeiffer, Giinter, 45, 90, 98
Overcapitalization, 49, 58, 108, 328, 354-55 Pharos, 21
Phase E review, 330
Philips, Anton Frederik, 172
Pacific Telesis, 98, 250, 256 Philips, Frederik, 172, 173
Packet-switched networks, 143, 144, 171, Philips, Gerard, 172
182, 188, 211, 217, 222, 227, 228, 236, Philips (company), 24, 75, 119, 148, 152,
242, 249, 268, 271, 280, 286, 351, 371- 154, 156-57, 161, 169, 171-74, 176,
72 177, 183, 196, 256, 271, 279, 308, 317,
Pactel, 119, 121, 330 318, 325, 326, 383
Paging services, 145, 213, 218, 236, 268 Phillips, C., Jr., 427
Paliadent, 266 Phonepoint, 119, 163
PanAmSat, 300, 335, 337 Photovideotex, 384
Panzar, John C., 27, 29, 57, 354 Piano Europa, 244
Papandreou, Andreas, 270-72 Picaud, Michel, 146
Papandreou, Vaso, 271 Pichault, Frangois, 182
Pasok party, 272 Pierrand, Jean, 154
Patents, 40 Piher Semiconductor, 256
Patterson, Paul, 339 Pinhasi, Raphael, 266
Pautrat, Charles, 141, 143 Piore, Michael, 49, 408
Paxnet, 227, 228 Pipe, G. Russel, 393, 394, 402, 403
Payphones, 131, 268, 349 Piquet, Jacques, 192
514 Index
Scherer, Joachim, 83, 90, 298, 300 308, 315, 316, 318, 319, 325, 326, 328,
Schiller, Dan, 45, 350 329, 340, 374
Schlumberger, 162 Siemens-Nixdorf Information Systems, 77
Schneider, Friedrich, 192, 193 SIFRANET, 265
Schneider industrial group, 160 Sigismund Augustus (king of Poland), 277
Schon, Helmut, 363 Signetics, 173, 317
Schrack, 197-99 Silicon Valley, 47, 314
Schulte, Josef, 45, 78, 89 Simitis, Spiro, 404
Schulte-Braucks, Reinhard, 306 Simonsen Electro, 223
Schwarz-Schilling, Christian, 79, 93, 96, 98 Sims, Calvin, 119
Scientific-Atlanta, 125 Sindelka, Josef, 198
Scott, John Dick, 72 Singapore, 110, 163, 314, 320
SEA, 160 SINTEL, 253
Sears, 391 SIP. See Societa Italiana per 1'Esercizio
SEAT, 248, 390 Telefonico (SIP)
Securicor, 118 Sirm, 242
Seita, 148 Sitter, R., 266
Selenia-Elsag group, 248 Skendi, Stavro, 282
Selwyn, Lee, 171, 197 SKF, 395
Servan-Schreiber, Jean-Jacques, 314 Skyggnir earth station, 231
Service dispatch, 378 Slovenia, 280
Service economy, 44, 48 Smart Card, 316
Service quality interconnectivity, 430 Smau, 244
SESA, 144, 153 Smith, Adam, 12, 31, 49
SET, 240 Smith, Diana, 261
Seven Years War, 12, 13 Smyth, Eleanor C., 17
Sevres porcelain works, 148 Snow, Marcellus S., 89
SFT, 146, 152 Soares, Mario, 261
SFT-Ericsson, 151, 152 Social Democratic party
SOB, 318-19 in Belgium, 180
SGS, 154, 162-63, 248, 319 in Denmark, 226
Shapiro, Carl, 355 in Germany, 78, 92, 95, 396
Shared-tenant services, 46, 366, 410, 432 in Portugal, 261
Shas party, 266 Social interconnectivity, 429
Shaye, 119 Socialist party
Shearson-Lehman-Hutton, 98 in France, 146, 147, 149-50, 152-53
Shell, 119, 169 in Italy, 243
Shenda telephone company, 110 in Portugal, 261
Shepherd, William, 29, 57 in Spain, 255
Sichel, Bertha, 386 Social optimum size, 33-34
Siemens, Carl Friedrich von, 74 Social Partners (Austria), 196, 197
Siemens, Georg, 70-74 Social subsidies, need for, 5556
Siemens, Heinrich, 72 Social welfare, 41
Siemens, Sir William Carl, 72 Societa Finanziaria Telefonica (STET), 154,
Siemens, Werner, 69, 70, 72 163, 239-43, 288, 321, 390, 437
Siemens-Albis, 188, 192, 193 Societa Generale di Telefonia, 240
Siemens & Halske, 71-77, 82, 83, 85-88, 90, Societa Generale Italiana de Telefonia e
91, 95, 98, 100, 102 Applicazione Elettriche, 240
Siemens & Schuckert, 72, 74, 75 Societa Italiana per 1'Esercizio Telefonico
Siemens Brothers, 72 (SIP), 61, 239, 241-47, 249, 250, 326,
Siemens (company), 24, 27, 69, 70-72, 124- 390
26, 138, 139, 151, 152, 156-58, 161, Societa Telefonica della'Alta Italiana, 240
162, 173, 181, 183, 197, 198, 199, 217, Societe Anonyme de Telecommunications
218, 227, 228, 231, 245, 246, 260, 261, Radioelectrique et Telephonique (SAT),
268, 271-73, 276, 278, 279, 282, 288, 148, 152, 155
Index 517
Societe Europeenne des Satellites (SES), 184, See also ISDN (Integrated Services
185 Digital Network)
Societe Franchise du Radiotelephone (SFR), Standard Radio and Telefone AB, 324
145 Standards Promotion and Applications Group
Societe Generate de Belgique, 157, 181, 249 (SPAG), 303
Societe Generate de Telephone (SGT), 136, Standard Telefone og Kabelfabrik (STK), 223,
137 324
Societe Grammont, 139 Standard Telephone and Radio (STR), 187,
Societe Industrielle du Telephone (SIT), 138- 192, 193, 324
40, 151, 152 Standard Telephone & Cable, Lid. (STC),
Society of Telecom Executives (United 111, 119, 124, 126-27, 324
Kingdom), 105 Standard Telephone Company (STC), 324
Socotel, 152, 155 Stanhope, John Lord, 14, 15
Sofia Telecommunications Plant, 280-81, 287 Stanley, Kenneth, 331, 339
Solana, Luis, 254, 255 Staple, Gregory, 128, 244, 331, 339
Somitomo, 338 Stapley, Barry, 124
Sony, 119, 173 Star network architecture, 120
Sorman, Guy, 150 State, U.S. Department of, 323
Sotolec, 155 State Agency for Telephone Services (ASST)
South Korea, 314, 320, 326 (Italy), 239, 240, 242, 243, 249
Southwestern Bell, 349, 389 State regulatory commissions (United States),
Sovam Teleport, 285 323
Sovereignty, 402 Stationary cellular radio, 52
Space development, 311 Steckel, Marie-Monique, 45, 143, 144, 148,
Spain, 139, 163, 209, 251-57, 330 163
electronics industry in, 252 Steenbergen, T., 175
equipment industry in, 255-56, 308, 321, Steenbergen Commission, 175-77
324, 326 Stenbeck, Jan, 210
international service in, 341, 344 Stentor, 223
postal service in, 252, 253 Stephan, Heinrich, 4, 10-14, 17, 69-70, 72,
telegraphy in, 252-54 133, 294
telephony in, 25, 251-54 STET. See Societa Finanziaria Telefonica
telex in, 252-54, 308 (STET)
value-added services in, 253, 373 Stette Commission, 221
vertical integration in, 321 STIPEL, 240
videotex in, 254, 389 Storno, 226, 227
Spare-parts service, 378 Stourdze, Yves, 137
SPC switches, 171, 172, 206, 216 Strassman, Paul, 44
Special drawing rights, 333-34 Strategic private networks, 51
Specialization, 49-51 Stromberg-Carlson, 125
Special Telecommunications Action for Strowger system, 73, 103, 124, 139, 151,
Regional Development (STAR), 234, 188, 256, 260
310 Stuebing, Heinz Volkmar, 80
Spence, A. M., 358 Suard, Pierre, 158, 246
Sp-1 system, 152 Submarine cables, 19, 110, 127-28, 135, 153,
Sprint Networks U.S.S.R., 285 179, 187, 241, 247, 258, 265, 289, 294,
Staatsbedrijf der Posterijen, Telegrafie en 334, 336-38
Telefonie, 170 Submarine Lightwave Cable Company
Stage coach postal service, 16, 17 (SLCC), 337
Standard Electrica, 258, 260, 321, 324 Subnetworks, 39, 43, 377, 407, 425, 435
Standard Electric Kirk A/S, 324 Subsidies for network start-up, 3941
Standard Electric Puhelinteollisuus, 218 Supply-oriented perspective, 28
Standard Elektrik Lorenz (SEL), 75-77, 82, Supraregulation, 420-22
83, 85-87, 90, 102, 324, 326 Swaffield, J. J. E., 170
Standardization, 27, 358-59, 425-26, 433. Swarttouw, Frans, 174, 175
518 index
Unequal user size, 38-39 telephony in, 3-5, 46, 47, 49, 56-59, 61-
Ungerer, Herbert, 366 62, 71, 112-13, 140, 349
Unidata, 15 value-added services in, 115, 369-70, 380
Unified Automated System of videotex in, 374, 383, 390-91, 409-10
Telecommunications (EASS), 284 United States International Trade Commission,
Uniformity in regulation, 421-22 329
Uniform Settlements Policy, 333 United Telecommunications, 372
Unilever, 169 United Telekom (UT), 278
Uninet, 372 United Telephone Company (Ireland), 232
United Kingdom, 52, 103-32 United Telephone Company (United
cable television in, 53, 120-21 Kingdom), 19, 20
cellular telephony in, 118-20 Unite!, 119
data protection in, 396-97 Universal Communications, 223
duopoly review, 113, 132, 361 Universal Postal Union (UPU), 297
electronics industry in, 47-48, 104, 318 Universal service, 35, 36, 45, 55, 56, 64,
entry barriers in, 26 111, 115, 323, 429, 437
equipment industry in, 104, 115, 123-27, UNIX-based systems, 227
317, 320-21, 324 Unlisted telephone numbers, 400
international service in, 339, 344 URA 2G system, 153
ISDN in, 129 US Sprint, 209, 285, 332, 333, 348, 410
PBXs in, 124-25 USTT, 325
postal system in, 14-17 Ustwer, 192
radio in, 295 US West, 119, 121, 276, 279, 288, 330, 349,
satellite communications in, 128 389
telegraphy in, 17-19, 127-29, 294
telephony in, 19-22, 25, 103-13, 117-18, Vail, Theodore, 4
128-32, 140-42, 209 Value-added networks (VANs), 5, 6, 28, 51,
telex in, 121-23, 129, 298, 305, 332, 337, 56, 107, 111, 113-17, 303, 308, 369-
422 81, 433, 434
Thatcher government in, 48, 63, 104, 105 basic packet transmission, 371-72
value-added services in, 113-17, 372 in Belgium, 182
vertical integration in, 320-21 conceptual framework for, 370-71
videotex in, 128, 316, 320-21 in Denmark, 228
United Kingdom Telegraph Company (UKTC), in France, 144-45, 164, 372
18 generic services, 370, 373-76
United Nations Center on Transnational in Germany, 372, 373
Corporations, 394 in Greece, 273
United Nations Intergovernmental Bureau for in Ireland, 236
Informatics, 394 in Israel, 265
United States in Italy, 372, 373
cellular telephony in, 329 in Netherlands, 175, 177, 372
containment of equipment industry in in Norway, 222
Europe, 323-25 in Spain, 253, 373
data protection in, 398, 402-4, 429 specific applications, 376-80
deregulation in, 23, 62, 65 in Sweden, 373
electronics industry in, 47, 315-17 in United Kingdom, 113-17, 372
European exports to, 327-30 in United States, 115, 369-70, 380
European interpretation of Value-added tax, 74, 429
telecommunications policy of, 322-23 Valvo, 173
international services, 331-36, 338-40, 344 VAN Infonet, 144
International Telecommunication Union and, van Rosenthal, C. Jansen, 310
295-96 Vasseur, Frederic, 151
ISDN in, 361-63 VCRs, 173
open network architecture in, 364-66, 436 Veblen, Thorstein, 312
satellite communications and, 299 Vedel, Thierry, 56, 386, 387
522 index