Samuels PDF
Samuels PDF
Samuels PDF
3 August 2004
T
o what extent do the institutions of presidentialism allow voters to hold governments accountable?
Powell and Whitten (1993) suggested that voter capacity to sanction is strong when clarity of
government responsibility for outcomes is clear, and vice versa. I argue that clarity of responsi-
bility functions differently under presidentialism and that presidentialism generates particular forms of
accountability. In general, electoral sanctioning is weak in nonconcurrent elections, which do not occur
under parliamentarism, but is stronger in concurrent elections. In concurrent executive elections the
clarity of responsibility does not attenuate the economys impact on the vote. Yet in concurrent legislative
elections both partisan and institutional variables diffuse responsibility for economic performance. Thus
under many common institutional and partisan formats, voters sanction presidents to a greater degree
than legislators for the same phenomenon. These findings elucidate the conditions under which we
might observe accountability similar to what we find in some parliamentary systems or a more uniquely
presidentialist dual democratic legitimacies of the kind Linz (1994) imagined.
he degree to which voters can hold elected offi- ability by enhancing identifiability and allowing vot-
1
Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy August 2004
follows what Susan Stokes calls the normal economic be. This suggests that (to some degree at the least) they
voting research program. In this approach, voters ought to attempt to convince voters that they share
use the past performance of the government to predict a personal and political affinity with their successor-
future performance and see the government as respon- candidate.
sible for that performance (Stokes 2001, 13). Schol- Voters can reward a successful presidents party by
ars believe that voters capacity to reward or sanction electing his or her partys successor, or they can pun-
elected officials declines when they cannot discern re- ish the incumbents party by electing a rival partys
sponsibility for government performance. Powell and candidate. There is therefore no reason why voters
Whitten (1993) thus argued that voters are more likely could not hold political parties as a whole and pres-
to punish or reward incumbents for the state of the idential governments as a wholeeven those popu-
economy when clarity of responsibility for outcomes lated by term-limited politiciansaccountable in a ret-
is high. Given the separation of powers under presiden- rospective voting fashion. Thus while many problems
tialism, a pertinent question is therefore whether clar- inhere in the accountability relationship between cit-
ity of responsibility affects voters capacity to reward izens and governments, these problems are not lim-
or sanction presidential governments, in both executive ited to presidential systems, nor should we simply
and legislative elections. assume that presidential governments are necessarily
The theory of retrospective voting (Fiorina 1981; worse than other forms of government in terms of
Lewis-Beck 1988) suggests that electoral accountabil- accountability.
ity occurs because voters retrospectively judge whether Aggregate economic voting studies typically assume
governments have acted in their best interests and then that some voters consider national economic condi-
reward or sanction them appropriately. Yet several fac- tions before the election as part of their vote decision.
tors might hinder voters ability to sanction elected Voters attribute reward or blame to the incumbent gov-
officials. First, voters might not be able to punish in- ernment for those conditions, and as a result the vote
cumbents if no viable alternative exists (Anderson shifts. Yet electoral accountability declines when voters
2000; Manin et al. 1999). This problem is not limited cannot discern responsibility for government policy,
to presidentialism, and in the analysis I include only and voters are more likely to punish or reward the
competitive elections. Second, incumbent politicians incumbent government for the state of the economy
might strategically conceal information about policy if clarity of responsibility is high, and not if clarity of
responsibility. This is also a problem everywhere, and responsibility is low (Powell and Whitten 1993).
we can reasonably assume that voters in presidential Two related reasons explain this dynamic. The first
systems can potentially sanction governments, at least highlights incumbents strategic actions. All incum-
as much as they can anywhere else. In any case, it is bent governments tend to lose votes (Nannestad and
unreasonable to assume that incumbents facing com- Paldam 2002). Powell and Whitten surmised that in-
petitive elections conceal all information; instead, we cumbents know this and thus prefer to diffuse politi-
should test to see whether partisan and/or institutional cal responsibility, for example, by blaming those with
factors mediate the connection between economics and whom they might have shared control of government.
elections. A countrys institutional and/or partisan makeup can
Third, citizens will be able to sanction governments help politicians diffuse responsibility, or it can com-
only if politicians desire (and are eligible for) reelec- plicate such activity. The second factor emphasizes
tion or care about who succeeds them to office. Manin, voters ability or willingness to gather information:
Przeworski, and Stokes (1999, 48) suggest that limits on As institutional or partisan complexity increases, vot-
presidential reelection thus restrict voters capacity to ers will have greater difficulty discerning actual re-
hold governments accountable. Limits on reelection do sponsibility for government output, independently of
impede voters from rewarding or punishing a particular whether politicians attempt to diffuse responsibility or
individual incumbent president (or legislator), but they not. Regardless of which factor weighs more heav-
do not impede voters from sanctioning the incumbents ily, lower clarity of responsibility should insulate in-
party. In presidential systems, the vote for or against the cumbents from the factors that cause them to lose
party of a term-limited president or legislator is nec- votes.
essarily a judgment of both the individual incumbent
and the incumbents party. Manin and coworkers sug-
gestion assumes that incumbent presidents do not care
PRESIDENTIALISM AND CLARITY
about their legacy, have no interest in the continuity OF RESPONSIBILITY
of their policies, and do not care about their partys Perhaps clarity of responsibility and thus voters capac-
success once they have left office. Yet last-term presi- ity for sanctioning in presidential systems depends on
dents care about their place in history and, thus, care factors that scholars have identified for parliamentary
about their performance in office. Moreover, since their systems.6 Or presidentialism could affect how voters
legacy is profoundly shaped by who succeeds them to hold governments accountable in particular ways. For
office, they also care about who that person turns out to
6 Powell and Whitten (1993) argued that incumbent party or coali-
may not appear. Still, this does not mean that incumbents are not tion cohesion and the type of committee system are important for
responsive to voter sanction and do not try to change their policies clarity of responsibility. Information on those variables is unavailable
to avoid additional future sanctions. for most of the countries in this study.
2
American Political Science Review Vol. 98, No. 3
example, Manin, Przeworski, and Stokes (1999, 47) im- nonconcurrence should attenuate the impact of na-
ply that presidentialism obscures government respon- tional factors on the vote because (all else equal)
sibility generally and that coalition and divided gov- it focuses voters and candidates energies on local
ernments under presidentialism are particularly bad factors and candidates personal qualities, including
for accountability. In contrast, Persson, Roland, and but not limited to any potential incumbency advan-
Tabellini (1997) suggest that the separation of powers tages due to constituency service. In nonconcurrent
institutionalizes conflicts of interest between branches legislative elections we also tend to observe relatively
of government and thus encourages relatively greater less national party organization involvement and rel-
information revelation than parliamentary systems, atively more influence of local or regional political
which should aid voters efforts to discern policy re- messages.
sponsibility. A similar logic should hold for executive elections.
A few single-country studies support the notion that Nonconcurrence frees presidential candidates to cam-
differences exist in terms of voters ability and/or will- paign on entirely individualistic bases, meaning that the
ingness to sanction members of the same party who oc- election result will depend relatively more on voters
cupy different branches of government, such as Lewis- perceptions of the candidates personal qualities and
Beck (1997) on France and Erickson (1989, 1990) on relatively less on their partisan connections. That is,
the United States, but no cross-national research has we have reason to believe It might not be the econ-
yet confirmed or refuted these findings.7 How do voters omy, stupid in nonconcurrent presidential elections,
in presidential systems think about blame and reward? because national policy factors ought to matter rela-
Do they focus exclusively and always on the president, tively less.
regardless of who controls the legislature? Are leg- Another institutional factor that might mediate clar-
islators in some partisan or institutional environments ity of responsibility, in legislative elections, is the elec-
more or less likely to feel the brunt of the voters wrath? toral rule. Under presidentialism voters cast separate
Several factors might sharpen or blunt clarity of ballots for legislative and executive elections. Unlike
responsibility and thus voters propensity to reward in parliamentary systems, this offers the opportunity
or punish incumbents in presidential systems. The for substantially different dynamics to drive executive
most important factor is unique to presidentialism and legislative elections. The primary factor is whether
and is institutional: the electoral cycle, or the concur- the electoral system encourages or discourages local-
rence or nonconcurrence of elections. Others (see es- ism and/or individualism, giving legislators the choice
pecially Shugart 1995) have noted that the electoral whether to run with or against their president
cycle plays a key role in executivelegislative rela- and/or party (Carey and Shugart 1995; Shugart 1995).
tions. Here I suggest that it also mediates the ac- When the electoral rule for legislative elections encour-
countability relationship between voters and elected ages localism, the state of the economy should matter
officials. relatively less, all else equal. In contrast, when the rules
Concurrent elections under presidentialism most re- nationalize legislative campaigns, the economy should
semble elections under parliamentarism. When exec- matter more clearly and consistently.
utive and legislative elections are held simultaneously, Two other variables that we also find in parliamen-
candidates for executive and legislative elections have tary systems merit discussion. The first is coalition gov-
strong incentives to coordinate election campaigns, in ernment. Coalitions tend to obscure any one partys
order to benefit from campaign economies of scale, responsibility for government output (Anderson 1995,
coattail effects, and organizational advantages. That is, 2000). As in parliamentary systems, governing in coali-
concurrent elections tend to encourage a team effort, tion might insulate incumbent presidents or legislative
whereby politicians employ their national party orga- parties from the factors that might otherwise affect
nizations and national partisan messages to get out the vote swings for or against them. A contrast of vote
vote. This associates copartisans from both branches swings lends credence to this notion: Presidents who
of government in voters minds and encourages voters governed in coalition were relatively more insulated
to hold them accountable for the same things. Conse- from losses, losing on average 4.68% (N = 21), com-
quently, in concurrent elections voters have relatively pared to average losses of 6.31% (N = 54) for pres-
greater incentives to hold both branches coresponsible idents who did not govern in a coalition. A similar
for the economy, all else equal. result obtains for the legislative elections: Parties in
In contrast, when either executive or legislative coalition lost an average of 0.92% (N = 32), while
elections are held nonconcurrently, national policy is- parties that governed alone lost an average of 3.59%
sues such as the economy should matter relatively (N = 71).
less. For legislative elections, following the literature Second, minority government might insulate pres-
on U.S. congressional elections (e.g., Erickson 1990), idents and legislative parties from vote swings due to
economic performance. In unicameral presidential sys-
tems, minority government occurs when the presidents
7 Remmer (1991, 2001) is the only scholar who has explored the links
party or coalition does not control more than 50% of
between economics and elections in a cross section of presidential the seats in the single legislative chamber. In bicameral
systems. However, Remmer was not interested in the impact of po-
litical institutions and explored economic voting in Latin America
systems, minority government occurs when the pres-
generally. Moreover, she did not explore the impact of economics on idents party or coalition does not control more than
legislative elections. 50% of the seats in both chambers. When parties divide
3
Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy August 2004
control over the branches of government, the incum- growth in year t 1 if the election was held in the
bent president can claim that all parties must share first six months of the year, and the change in GDP
responsibility for poor performance. Several studies growth in year t if the election was held in the last
confirm that minority parliamentary governments suf- six months of the year.11 I call this variable Economy.
fer smaller losses than majority governments (e.g., If the economy matters generally in presidential sys-
Powell and Whitten 1993 and Strm 1990). As with tems, this variable should have a positive and significant
coalition governments, minority presidential govern- coefficient.
ments also appear to insulate incumbents from losses. If clarity of responsibility diffuses or accentuates
Presidential parties running a candidate following a economic voting effects, we should observe variables
minority presidency lost on average 5.00% (N = 51), in multiple regression analysis that substitute for, de-
compared to average losses of 7.68% (N = 24) for crease, or wipe out the impact of the economy on vote
candidates following a majority president. However, it swings. The logic of the argument suggests that the ef-
remains to be seen whether the economy drives these fect of economics on elections is interactive with clarity
differences. of responsibility variables (Powell and Whitten 1993).
The factors explored thus far permit us to place Thus if the economy matters in general, we expect a
presidential systems on a continuum. At one end elec- positive and significant coefficient on Economy (all
tions are nationalized and always concurrent, and at else equal), and if another variable blurs the impact
the other end legislative elections are localized and of economic fluctuations on the vote, we would expect
often not concurrent with the executive election. In a negative and significant coefficient on the interacted
the real world, Costa Rica might fall on one end of term Economy OtherVariable when that variable is
the continuum while Colombia fell at the other end, added to the equation. The impact of the economy
and the United States would fall somewhere in the on the vote would then be the sum of the coefficient
middle. The question remains whether such variables on Economy plus the coefficient on the interacted
affect clarity of responsibility for incumbents in either variable.
branch of government. As per the discussion in the previous section, I ex-
plore the impact of the following independent vari-
ables: Concurrence, Electoral Rules (for legislative
CLARITY OF RESPONSIBILITY AND elections only), Coalitions, and Minority President, all
ECONOMIC VOTING: ANALYSIS operationalized as dummy variables. I enter each vari-
able directly and in an interacted term (with Economy).
I test the impact of clarity of responsibility and eco- The dependent variable in all regressions is the abso-
nomic conditions on elections in 23 presidential democ- lute percentage change in vote for the incumbent pres-
racies, defined as those in which both branches of idents party from the previous election. In the models
government are directly elected for fixed terms and for executive elections, the dependent variable is the
in which the head of government is not accountable vote change in the executive election, and in the models
to the legislature (Siaroff 2003).8 I employ aggregate for legislative elections, the dependent variable is the
economic and electoral data. I included a case if the vote change in the legislative election. In all models, I
country had had at least two consecutive democratic employ ordinary least squares regression with robust
electionsand if political and economic data were standard errors.12
available. This resulted in a sample of 75 executive In all regressions I also included two control vari-
elections and 103 legislative election.9 ables: the incumbent partys proportion of the vote
Scholars of economic voting typically employ one of in the previous election (Previous Vote), which should
the following three variables as the indicator of eco- have a negative impact because parties tend to lose
nomic performance: GDP growth, inflation, or unem- votes after being in office; and a dummy variable
ployment. I employ the percentage change in real per indicating whether or not the incumbent president
capita GDP growth (World Bank 2003).10 Following is running for reelection (Reelection). This variable
Pacek and Radcliff (1995), I use the change in GDP should return a positive coefficient because incumbents
running for reelection have advantages in terms of
8 I include cases from Siaroffs Category 2 as well as Category 6,
name recognition and organization relative to other
which functions essentially like Category 2. As Elgie (1999, 11)
notes, regime classification varies from one writer to another, but
the only case on which I differ from Siaroff is Bolivia, which Siaroff 11 Quarterly figures are unavailable for most countries in the sam-
classifies together with Switzerland. Despite a quirk in Bolivias ple. Other operationalizations could provide more nuance, but data
constitution, it functions as a pure presidential system. See Inter- limitations restrict my ability to conduct such tests. For example,
American Development Bank 2002; personal communication with because the time series is relatively short for most of these countries,
John Carey and Octavio Amorim Neto. I cannot explore the impact of shocks relative to long-term trends
9 Appendix 1 contains a list of the countries and elections. I explore (cf. Palmer and Whitten 1999).
differences across regime types, incorporating pure and semipresi- 12 I do not employ models with country dummies because of the
dential systems as well as parliamentary systems, in other work. numerous cross sections relative to the overall sample size in the
10 Unemployment information is unavailable for most of the coun- data set (with 23 cross sections I have an average of three executive
tries in the sample. As for inflation, the expectations about the impact elections and four legislative elections per country). I ran a series of
of inflation are far less clear than for that of GDP growth, supporting regressions with country dummies, and although some of the dum-
the use of the latter over the former, because it is unclear whether mies were significant, their inclusion did not substantially alter the
voters respond to the level or direction of inflation. results.
4
American Political Science Review Vol. 98, No. 3
5
Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy August 2004
6
American Political Science Review Vol. 98, No. 3
7
Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy August 2004
8
American Political Science Review Vol. 98, No. 3
to the expectations generated by Table 4, which con- presidentialism. The results confirm neither the most
trasted concurrent and nonconcurrent legislative elec- optimistic views, expressed most clearly (if only at
tions and found that the relationship between the an abstract level) by Persson, Roland, and Tabellini
economy and the vote was significant in both types (1997), nor the most pessimistic, perhaps expressed
but both weaker and less robust in nonconcurrent by Linz (1990, 1994). In many ways the findings echo
elections. Shugart and Careys (1992) suggestion that the sep-
Finally, I examine the impact of the other clarity of aration of powers can engender different forms of
responsibility variables in Table 6. Recall that I argued representation and accountability than parliamentary
that nonconcurrence tends to reduce the impact of systems.
national party organization and campaign messages. Clarity of responsibility and thus voters capacity to
Thus the influence of all national-level partisan factors sanction elected officials work in particular ways under
ought to be relatively diminished in nonconcurrent presidentialism. When elections are nonconcurrent,
elections. The results are clear: In contrast to the re- a situation that cannot occur under parliamentarism,
sults in Table 5, none of the interacted variables are sanctioning for the state of the economy is weak. In ex-
significant in Table 6, indicating that no other clarity ecutive elections this lack of a connection between the
of responsibility variables mediate the impact of the economy and the vote came somewhat as a surprise, but
national economy beyond the electoral cycle.20 the relatively weak relationship in legislative elections
To sum up, the results for legislative elections in followed theoretical expectations and research findings
Tables 46 indicate that the economy matters in on U.S. elections. Because about one in five executive
both concurrent and nonconcurrent legislative elec- elections and two in five legislative elections around the
tions, although it has a greater impact and matters world are nonconcurrent, these results support some
more clearly and consistently in concurrent elections. observers concerns about overall accountability under
Moreover, the results indicate that partisan and in- presidentialism.
stitutional clarity of responsibility affects the rela- In contrast, concurrence enhances voters capacity
tionship between the economy and the vote in con- to reward or sanction government officials for the state
current elections but that the evidence for such a of the economy in presidential systems. These results
connection is much weaker in nonconcurrent leg- qualify Linzs critique of presidentialism based on his
islative elections. In addition, when we compare the notion of dual democratic legitimacies. Despite the
impact of the economy in executive and legisla- formal separation of powers, institutions that promote
tive elections (compare against Tables 1 and 3, e.g.) close electoral linkage between the executive and
we can infer that voters reward or sanction presidents legislative branches can generate unified democratic
more than legislators for economic performance.21 legitimacy. Ceteris paribus, when elections are con-
These results leave us with the following: In concur- current voters treat the incumbent executive and his or
rent executive elections, the economy affects the vote, her legislative supporters as a team and judge them as
regardless of the clarity of responsibility. Yet in noncon- such.
current executive elections, the economy never mat- However, the all-else-equal clause is essential, be-
ters. In concurrent legislative elections, the economy cause in concurrent elections legislative fragmentation
affects the vote, but partisan and institutional variables and localizing electoral rules can affect the degree
mediate that connection. The economy also affects the to which voters hold both branches accountable for
vote in nonconcurrent legislative elections, but rela- the economy. This implies the following: Under single-
tively less so than in concurrent legislative elections, party majority government with concurrent elections,
yet neither partisan nor institutional variables mediate voters in presidential and parliamentary systems will
that link. These findings tend to support my argument not differ much in their capacity to sanction or reward
about the particular way in which the electoral cycle governments. However, even under concurrent elec-
affects clarity of responsibility and thus accountability tions, when we see multiparty coalitions (for exam-
in presidential systems. ple), clarity of responsibility and thus voters ability to
sanction incumbents function differently under pres-
identialism and parliamentarism. Under parliamen-
CONCLUSION tarism, as Anderson (1995, 2000), Powell and Whitten
This paper elucidates the conditions under which elec- (1993), and others have argued, partisan and institu-
toral sanctioning is more or less likely to occur under tional variables tend to diffuse clarity of responsibility.
Under presidentialism, the same phenomenon occurs
in concurrent legislative elections but not in executive
20 The negative and significant result on Electoral Rules indicates
elections. This separates the degree to which voters
that candidates from the presidents party obtain a higher percentage
of the vote when the electoral rules localize competition. This
sanction executives and legislators and means that
occurs because localizing electoral rules allows candidates to insulate executives in many presidential systems are subject to
themselves from national trends and base their campaigns on the relatively greater sanctioning or rewards than legisla-
personal vote and the incumbency advantage. tors, a situation that cannot by definition arise under
21 Regression analysis that pooled all elections, however, did not
parliamentarism.
statistically distinguish between the effect of the economy in execu-
tive and that in legislative elections, although the sign of the dummy
Presidentialism generates distinct forms of account-
variable distinguishing executive from legislative elections was in the ability. The electoral cycle most clearly affects this dy-
predicted direction. namic, but electoral rules and party system features
9
Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy August 2004
also mediate voters ability to sanction incumbents. in ways that parliamentary elections cannot. Thus al-
Under a limited set of conditions presidentialism can though the state of the national economy matters rela-
approximate parliamentarism, and we would expect tively little in nonconcurrent legislative elections, and
to see a similar form of government accountability national clarity of responsibility variables do not af-
in both types of systems. But the collective, respon- fect this relationship, local variables may systemati-
sible parties, policy-oriented sense of accountability cally affect the vote and thus promote accountability
that is rooted in normative political theory can oc- (for example, whether voters can recall the incum-
cur under presidentialism only under these limited bents name or the extent to which they credit
conditions. When such conditions are not met, and the incumbent with providing constituency service).
when the electoral and party systems separate the The degree to which presidentialism allows both na-
bases for selecting members of each branch, we have tional and local accountability simultaneously merits
a more clearly distinct presidentialist dynamic. For exploration.
example, even when elections are concurrent, vot- Yet if one disputes Shugart and Careys suggestion
ers are often likely to sanction incumbents in both that separating the bases for electing the executive and
branches of government to different degrees, depend- legislative branches can be a normatively good thing
ing on institutional and party-system factors. And for democracy because it permits different forms of ac-
when elections are nonconcurrent, national factors countability, and instead holds to the Linzian view that
matter relatively little in both executive and legislative both branches should generally be held accountable
elections. for the same things, then the results here reinforce the
For legislative elections at least, Shugart and Carey conclusion that the core problem of for government ac-
(1992) suggested that nonconcurrence and/or localiz- countability under presidentialism is the potential lack
ing electoral rules can be a normatively good thing of electoral linkage between the president and his or
because there is nothing prima facie wrong with the her legislative contingent. Party-system and other insti-
idea of giving legislators an opportunity to campaign tutional factors shape the strength of this linkage, so
on their constituency service and voters an opportu- the findings in this paper thus reinforce the critical
nity to base their vote on local rather than national role that institutions and party-system configurations
concerns. In this way the institutional separation of can play in shaping democratic performance. Future
purpose under presidentialism (Samuels and Shugart research ought to explore these differences in more
2003) can enhance representation and accountability detail.
APPENDIX 1: CASES
Country Electionsa
Argentina 1983PL, 1985L, 1987L, 1989PL, 1991L, 1993L, 1995PL, 1997L, 1999PL
Benin 1995L, 1999L
Bolivia 1985PL, 1989PL, 1993PL, 1997PL
Brazil 1989P, 1990L, 1994PL, 1998PL
Chile 1958P, 1961L, 1964P, 1965L, 1969L, 1970P, 1973L, 1989PL, 1993PL, 1997L, 1999P
Colombia 1974PL, 1978PL, 1982PL, 1986PL, 1990PL, 1991L 1994PL, 1998PL
Costa Rica 1962PL, 1966PL, 1970PL, 1974PL, 1978PL, 1982PL, 1986PL, 1990PL, 1994PL, 1998PL
Cyprus 1981L, 1985L, 1991L, 1996L, 2001L
Dominican Republic 1986PL, 1990PL, 1994PL, 1996P, 1998L
Ecuador 1979L, 1984PL, 1986L, 1988PL, 1990L, 1992PL, 1994L, 1996PL, 1998L, 2000P
El Salvador 1989PL, 1991L, 1994PL, 1997L, 1999P, 2000L
Guatemala 1991PL, 1995PL, 1999PL
Honduras 1981PL, 1985PL, 1989PL, 1993PL, 1997PL
Korea 1987P, 1988L, 1992PL, 1996L, 1997P, 2000L
Malawi 1994PL, 1999PL
Mexico 1994PL, 1997L, 2000PL
Nicaragua 1991PL, 1996PL
Panama 1994PL, 1999PL
Paraguay 1989PL, 1993PL, 1998PL
Peru 1985PL, 1990PL
United States 1962L, 1964PL, 1966L, 1968PL, 1970L, 1972PL, 1974L, 1976PL, 1978L, 1980PL, 1982L,
1984PL, 1986L, 1988PL, 1990L, 1992PL, 1994L, 1996PL, 1998L, 2000PL
Uruguay 1966PL, 1971PL, 1984PL, 1989PL, 1994PL, 1999PL
Venezuela 1963PL, 1968PL, 1973PL, 1978PL, 1983PL, 1988PL, 1993PL, 1998PL, 2000PL
Note: More cases are listed here than are included in the regressions. None of the first elections in any time series are included because
there is no t 1 information on the Previous Vote variable for the first. Thus the total number of cases included in the regressions equals
the total number of cases listed here minus the first cases in every countrys series.
a P, presidential; L, legislative.
10
American Political Science Review Vol. 98, No. 3
11
Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy August 2004
Remmer, Karen L. 2001. Elections and Economics in Contem- Debate. In Presidentialism and Democracy in Latin America, ed.
porary Latin America. Presented at the meeting of the Latin Scott Mainwaring and Matthew Shugart. New York: Cambridge
American Studies Association, Chicago. University Press, 1254.
Samuels, David, and Matthew Shugart. 2003. Presidentialism, Siaroff, Alan. 2003. Comparative Presidencies: The Inadequacy
Elections, and Representation. Journal of Theoretical Politics of the Presidential, Semi-Presidential and Parliamentary Dis-
15 (January): 3360. tincion. European Journal of Political Research 42: 287
Shugart, Matthew S. 1995. The Electoral Cycle and Institutional 312.
Sources of Divided Presidential Government. American Political Stokes, Susan. 2001. Introduction. In Public Support for Market
Science Review 89 (June): 32743. Reforms in New Democracies, ed. Susan C. Stokes, New York:
Shugart, Matthew S., and John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assem- Cambridge University Press, 134.
blies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. New York: Strm, Kaare. 1990. Minority Government and Majority Rule. New
Cambridge. York: Cambridge.
Shugart, Matthew S., and Scott Mainwaring. 1997. Presidentialism World Bank. 2003. World Development Indicators [CD-ROM].
and Democracy in Latin America: Rethinking the Terms of the Washington, DC: World Bank.
12