Murali Neel
Murali Neel
Murali Neel
*
Founder, amicus (formerly Global General Counsel, Cipla Ltd.); B.A., LL.B. (Hons.),
National Law School of India University (1996). This paper would not have been pos-
sible without research assistance from Suvajit Chakraborty and Anupama Konteti, for-
mer colleagues at Cipla Limited, and Dr. Swaraj Barooah of SpicyIP who helped with
valuable feedback on an early draft of this paper.
32 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
I ntroduction
Competition law advocates the necessity for free markets, detests monop-
olies, and aspires to create a perfectly competitive playground that benefits
consumer choice. It aims to create an ecosystem oriented towards consumer
rights, free trade, and efficient resource allocation. Intellectual property
legislation, in essence, creates monopolies. There is therefore a dichotomy
between Intellectual Property Rights (IPR) and competition policy. The
former endangers competition and the latter engenders competition.1 This
paper is focused on certain activities of players in the Indian healthcare sec-
tor which highlight the conflict between IPR and competition law. While
there is a good basis for looking to the rest of the world to understand cer-
tain fundamental aspects of IPR and competition law, the Indian healthcare
sector operates in a completely different manner from that in the US and
Europe, and we should therefore be sceptical of applying the jurisprudence
from those jurisdictions to identify and address Indias problems.
min96_e/min96_e.htm.
4
World Trade Organisation, Report of the Working Group on the Interaction between
Trade and Competition Policy to the General Council (WT/WGTCP/4, Nov. 30, 2000).
5
Department-Related Parliamentary Standing Committee on Home Affairs, Ninety-
Third Report on the Competition Bill, 2001 available at http://www.prsindia.org/
uploads/media/1167471748/bill73_2007050873_ Standing_Committee_Report_on_
Competition_Bill__2001.pdf (Last visited on Jun. 25, 2015).
6
Raghavan Committee, supra note 1.
34 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
to the use of IPRs must now be brought through the round hole of abuse
of dominant position under Section 4.7 While one can sympathise with
the emotion, this is perhaps a very narrow and cynical view since the exemp-
tion for IPR from the application of Section 3 applies only to agreements.
It is a common misconception that IPR has a blanket exemption from all
the provisions of the Competition Act. Thus, if there is an instance of an
abuse of dominant position enjoyed by an IPR holder, the Competition
Commission of India (CCI) would have jurisdiction to inquire into such
abuse.8 Exclusions from the applicability of Section 3 have been provided to
persons seeking to protect their intellectual property rights as well as agree-
ments for the export of goods. However, the CCI would still be empowered
to look into the reasonableness of the restraint while exercising intellectual
property rights.9
The relationship between IPR and competition policy has been com-
plex and widely debated, and various models exist in different countries to
address potential conflicts.10 The complexity of IPR has deepened since the
adoption of legislative reforms in many developing countries as a part of
their commitment under the WTO Agreement on Trade Related Intellectual
Property Rights (TRIPS) in 1995. While the importance of IPR in stim-
ulating inventions is widely advocated, by providing legal monopoly it also
raises competition concerns, and in certain areas like food and healthcare, it
is widely believed that diffusion of intellectual property should have prece-
dence over an incentive to invent.11 It is noticeable that the discussion about
IPR and competition law has remained focussed on patents12 with very little
thought about how other IPR like copyright, trademarks and design can
give rise to competition law issues. This paper is an attempt to look at how
7
Debolina Partap, Intellectual Competition, 5(9) Legal Era (November 2014).
8
Vinod Dall, Injunctions Sought By SEP Holders Abuse of Dominance or Protection of
IPRs?, 5(9) Legal Era (Nov. 2014).
9
Government of India Report on Competition Policy (Planning Commission, 2007), avail-
able at http://planningcommission.nic.in/aboutus/committee/wrkgrp11/wg11_cpolicy.pdf
[hereinafter Planning Commission].
10
Remedies for abuse of IPR could exist in IPR legislation and/or in competition law. In the
United Kingdom, competition law issues are addressed by the Office of Fair Trading but
also by specific industry regulators like Ofcom for the telecoms and broadcasting sector,
Ofwat for the water industry and Ofgem for the electricity sector. In the United States, it
is the Department of Justice, the Federal Trade Commission and even the State Attorney
General.
11
This is evidenced in the Doha Declaration which seeks to explain and elaborate on the nexus
between IPR and national interest. See World Trade Organisation, Ministerial Declaration
on the TRIPS Agreement and Public Health of 14 November 2001 (WT/MIN(01)/
DEC/W/2), available at http://www.who.int/medicines/areas/policy/doha_declaration/en/.
12
Raghavan Committee, supra note 1; Planning Commission, supra note 9.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 35
the Indian healthcare industry uses IPR, and to identify the competition law
issues that arise from it.
13
Micromax Informatics Ltd., In re, [2013] CCI 77; the suit was filed in relation to refusal
by Ericsson to license standard essential patents for GSM technology to Micromax. The
CCI rejected this contention and directed the Director General to commence investigation.
Ericsson appealed this CCI order and the Delhi High Court granted an interim injunction
against the investigation.
14
See infra note 58 for examples. The United States uses antitrust legislation as the basis for
measures like compulsory licenses to address patent abuse. See, for example, Federal Trade
Commission order in Intel Corporation, FTC Docket no. 9288, Final Agency Decision
(Mar. 24, 1999), and notification by the Department of Justice in the case of United States
v. A.K. Steel Corpn., E.D. Mich. 15-cv-11804. For more examples, see, James Love &
Michael Palmedo, Examples of Compulsory Licensing of Intellectual Property in the
United States, CPTech Background paper 1 (Sep. 2001), available at http://www.
cptech.org/ip/health/cl/us-cl.html. It may well be argued that compulsory licenses and
other remedies for abuse of a patent are contained in the Patent Act thereby excluding
other legislation from providing measures to counter abuse of IPR. See supra note14.
15
Offshore Holdings (P) Ltd. v. Bangalore Development Authority, (2011) 4 Bom CR 212;
Bondu Ramaswamy v. Bangalore Development Authority, (2010) 7 SCC 129.
16
Offshore Holdings (P) Ltd. v. Bangalore Development Authority, (2011) 4 Bom CR 212;
Bondu Ramaswamy v. Bangalore Development Authority, (2010) 7 SCC 129.
17
The Patent Office can revoke a patent under a post-grant opposition. Similarly the High
Court and the IPAB have specific powers of revocation. See Girnar Traders v. State of
Maharashtra, (2004) 8 SCC 505.
18
See for example, S. 115 of the Patents Act, No. 39, Acts of Parliament, 1970 (India) [herein-
after Patents Act 1970]; S. 91 of the Trade Marks Act, No. 47, Acts of Parliament, 1999
(India) [hereinafter Trade Marks Act 1999]; and S. 36 of the Designs Act 2000, No.
16, Acts of Parliament, 2000 (India) [hereinafter Designs Act 2000]. See also Girnar
Traders v. State of Maharashtra, (2004) 8 SCC 505.
36 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
There is no common theme that runs through all IPR legislation and
despite being conceptualised, practiced, and taught as one subject, they have
fundamental differences in the jurisprudential and economic basis for their
existence and how they are meant to work. For example, if a patent is not
worked, the Government can force the patent holder to license it. 24 While a
similar provision exists in the Copyright Act, 25 no corresponding provisions
exist in the Designs Act. Similarly, if a trademark is not used, its registration
lapses26 but that does not prevent its continued use.
If the IPR laws do not exclude the application of competition law, does the
Competition Act, as some apprehend, 27 provide immunity to IPR from com-
19
CBI v. State of Rajasthan, (1996) 9 SCC 735.
20
See for example, S. 13, Patents Act, 1970.
21
CBI v. State of Rajasthan, (1996) 9 SCC 735. See for example, Ss. 123, 124, Patents Act,
1970; Chapter XII, Trade Marks Act, 1999.
22
CBI v. State of Rajasthan, (1996) 9 SCC 735; Moti Lal v. CBI, (2002) 4 SCC 713 : (2002)
2 ACR 1192 (SC). See for example, S. 115(4), Trade Marks Act, 1999.
23
One could argue that S. 84 of the Patents Act, 1970 providing a simplified procedure for
issuing a compulsory license if the patentee indulges in anti-competitive practices specif-
ically allowing a competition law test refutes this. This is also supported by S. 62 of the
Competition Act, No. 12, Acts of Parliament, 2002 (India) [hereinafter Competition Act
2002] which specifically states that the remedies provided in the Competition Act are
in addition to other laws and remedies. On the other hand, those who advocate the self
contained code theory could argue that by making specific reference to competition law
in just one provision, the Patents Act, by deliberate omission, excludes the application of
competition law except in S. 84.
24
S. 85, Patents Act, 1970.
25
S. 31, Copyright Act, No. 14, Acts of Parliament, 1957 (India) [hereinafter Copyright
Act, 1957].
26
S. 47, Trade Marks Act, 1999.
27
See Debolina Partap, supra note 7.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 37
The Competition Act requires that the relevant market be identified in terms
of (a) relevant geographical market;30 and (b) relevant product market.31 A
relevant product market is assessed on the basis of the following factors:
(a) Physical characteristics or end-use of goods;
(b) Price of goods or services;
(c) Consumer preferences;
(d) Exclusion of in-house production;
(e) Existence of specialised producers; and
(f) Classification of industrial products.32
28
World Trade Organisation, Report of the Working Group on the Interaction between
Trade and Competition Policy to the General Council (WT/WGTCP/4, Nov. 30, 2000).
29
See AZ, infra note 54 and Actavis, infra note 58.
30
S. 2(s), Competition Act, 2002.
31
S. 2(t), Competition Act, 2002.
32
S. 19(7), Competition Act, 2002.
38 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
civil and military aircraft, satellites, space systems, avionics, and air and
maritime traffic control systems. A concentrative joint venture within the
meaning of Article 3 of the European Commissions Merger Regulation was
notified. In determining the relevant market, the EC decided that aircrafts
which have less than 20 seats, 20 - 39 seats, 40 - 59 seats and 60 or more
seats are subject to different type certification standards. The certification
security requirements such as crash-worthiness, systems reliability, fatigue
resistance, damage tolerance and heat release of cabin materials in case of
fire differ greatly. It was held that a 60-seat commuter is not interchangeable
or substitutable with a 30-seat commuter. Both are used on routes with a
significantly different density and their prices vary significantly. The seg-
mentation was made on the basis of physical characteristics, nature and end
use of the products.33
33
Case No. IV/M053 Aerospatiale-Alenia/de Havilland, Council Regulation (EEC) No.
4064/89.
34
United States v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co., 118 F Supp 41-233; United States v. E.I.
Du Pont De Nemours & Co., 100 L Ed 1264 : 351 US 377 (1956).
35
Mohr, D., N. Mller, and A. Krieg, The road to 2020 and beyond: Whats driving the
global automotive industry? (McKinsey & Company, 2013), available at http://www.mck-
insey.com/~/media/McKinsey/dotcom/client_service/Automotive%20and%20Assembly/
PDFs/McK_The_road_to_2020_and_beyond.ashx.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 39
could differentiate themselves with the help of design elements, new features
in infotainment, and innovations directed at safety and comfort.36 Even a
specific segment in the automobile sector is clearly bifurcated. The electric
vehicles category, for example, can be further divided in four types: bat-
tery electric vehicles, plug-in hybrids, range extenders and fuel cell vehicles.
On the other hand, non-rechargeable Full Hybrid Electric Vehicles tend to
belong to the segment of vehicles with internal combustion engines where
they play a role in improvement of fuel economy.37
36
Ibid.
37
See Heike Proff and Dominik Kilian, Competitiveness of the EU Automotive
Industry in Electric Vehicles: Final Report (University of Duisburg-Essen, Dec. 19,
2012), available at http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/sectors/automotive/files/projects/
report-duisburg-essen-electric-vehicles_en.pdf.
38
Belaire Owners Assn. v. DLF Ltd., (2011) 104 CLA 398 (CCI).
40 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
has made a final consumer choice of preferring a villa for the reasons
of family size, need for privacy, demonstration effect etc. would not
switch to an apartment for a small increase in price.39
It now seems that price is not the definitive criterion for establishing a
relevant market. There are also non-price factors that are considered when
a customer buys products. This is particularly significant when we discuss
pharmaceutical products and healthcare services where customer choice is
very limited because the decision making process for these is complex, with
the doctor, pharmacist, and often the hospital,41 exerting significant influ-
ence and excluding competing drugs that are qualitative substitutes. It may
39
Geeta Gouri, Making Markets Work Effectively in India, Experience of the Competition
Commission, (Competition Commission of India), available at http://www.cci.gov.in/
images/media/speeches/DrGG.pdf.
40
Ramakant Kini v. L.H. Hiranandani Hospital, 2014 Comp LR 263 (CCI).
41
Hospital chains often have pharmacies on their premises and patients are forced to buy
drugs and other medical supplies from these in house pharmacies. Patients are not
allowed to buy in drugs or other supplies from external sources. See Snehlata Shrivastav,
Hospitals Force Patients to Buy From In-House Pharmacies, Times of India (Apr.
24, 2015), available at http://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/city/nagpur/Hospitals-force-
patients-to-buy-from-in-house-pharmacies/articleshow/47032880.cms.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 41
C. Consumer Preferences
In Belaire, the Commission cited the example of a consumer who intends to
purchase a villa. For such a consumer, the independence, space and privacy
are factors in purchasing a place of residence. While consumer preferences,
social tastes, and behavioural trends of individuals could govern the demand
elasticity of a product, they are relevant only where there is a legitimate
choice to make. As seen in Chemistree, Actavis, AZ and Hiranandani, IPR
in the healthcare sector by its very nature may well be monopolistic and may
not, give the consumer a choice within that relevant market.
E. Classification of Products
In the pharmaceutical sector, an important distinction must be drawn
between a molecule comprising its own market, and an entire therapy area.
In the case of Kaletra, the manner of identifying the relevant market deter-
mined that AbbVie did not hold a dominant position and there were several
competing products in the same market as Kaletra. A simple example could
be of acetylsalicylic acid, more commonly known as Aspirin, an analgesic.
42
Supra note 40. Surprisingly, the Competition Commission of India had previously held in
Consumers Guidance Society v. Hindustan Coca Cola Beverages (P) Ltd., [2011] CCI 25
that a multiplex chain that served only one brand of beverages was not a relevant market
even though customers could neither bring their own beverages nor leave during a show
to buy beverages from outside. No mention is made of this case in the CCIs order in
Ramakant Kini v. L.H. Hiranandani Hospital, 2014 Comp LR 263 (CCI).
43
See Evaluate Pharma World Preview 2014 Outlook to 2020, Evaluate Group (Jun. 1
2014), available at info.evaluategroup.com/rs/evaluatepharmaltd/images/EP240614.pdf,
on the projected market share of pharmaceutical companies in the global oncology market,
the fastest growing of all therapies. Roche had a market share in 2013 of 34.3%, followed
by Novartis with 10.8% and the top 10 companies had a market share of almost 78%.
42 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
If these are the only facts, then Aspirin has several well-known substitutes
such as paracetamol and ibuprofen. However, if Aspirin is prescribed to help
prevent unwanted blood clots from forming within the body, then its substi-
tute may be clopidropel.44
44
See infra note 74.
45
History, WHO Collaborating Centre for Drug Statistics Methodology (Nov. 19, 2011),
available at http://www.whocc.no/atc_ddd_methodology/history/.
46
CCI Order in the matter of the combination of Sun and Ranbaxy, Combination
Registration No. C-2014/05/170, 14 (Dec. 05, 2014), available at http://www.cci.gov.in/
May2011/OrderOfCommission/CombinationOrders/C-2014-05-170.pdf. For an example
of an ATC-3 therapeutic classification like antiepileptics, see Case No COMP/M.4402-
UCB/Schwarz Pharma, available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/cases/deci-
sions/m4402_20061121_20310_en.pdf. See also Case No. COMP/M.7275- Novartis/
GlaxoSmithKline Oncology Business, available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/merg-
ers/cases/decisions/m7275_20150128_20212_4158734_EN.pdf. Here, treatment of ovar-
ian cancer was held to be a relevant market.
47
See infra note 59.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 43
48
The Office of Fair Trading Competition Law Guideline on the Definition of Market, S.I.
2004 (OFT403), available at https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
attachment_data/file/284423/oft403.pdf.
49
Mark Jamison, Defining Relevant Markets in Evolving Industries (University of Florida,
Department of Economics, Public Utility Research Center, Working Paper, 2014), available
athttp://warrington.ufl.edu/centers/purc/purcdocs/papers/1317_ Jamison_Defining%20
Relevant%20Markets%20in%20Evolving%20Industries%20Final.pdf.
50
Case T-321/05 AstraZeneca v. Commission, 2010 ECR II-2805: MEMO/10/294. This
action in competition law perhaps provided a more effective remedy than revoking the
patent under the Patent Act which may well have been at the end of its term.
51
The Patent Act would have, at best, allowed revocation of the patent, which may not be an
effective sanction if the patent term had expired.
52
The drug regulatory system in India works differently from that of the EU and it may well
be argued that it may not have been possible for AZ to do what it did here. However, in
Roche v. Mylan & Biocon (Delhi High Court, 2014), it was argued that the clinical trial
data submitted by Roche should not be shared with Roches competitors even though this
is the only way that generics can show equivalence with the innovator product to comply
44 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
with drug regulation. It may be argued that Roche seeking an injunction is itself anti-com-
petitive, based on AstraZeneca and the decision of the EU in Apple v. Motorola Mobility
(European Commission Press Release regarding decision on anti-competitive use of stand-
ard essential patents by seeking and enforcing injunctions Docket No.IP/14/489 (Apr. 29,
2014), available at http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-14-489_en.htm).
53
European Commission Press Release, Antitrust: Commission finds that Motorola Mobility
infringed competition rules by misusing standard essential patents (Apr. 29 2014), availa-
ble at http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-14-489_en.htm.
54
See AstraZeneca, supra note 51.
55
Case C-457/10 P, AstraZeneca AB and AstraZeneca plc v. European Commission (Dec. 6,
2012).
56
The lack of a formal patent linkage in India makes it unlikely that this situation should
arise. However, a new drug (whether or not patented) introduced in India has a three-year
head start since a generic will not be able to introduce a competitive drug during that time.
Together with courts being liberal in granting interim injunctions to patent holders, it
could be argued that there is de facto patent linkage in India.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 45
57
See Dealing with the Generic Threat, Pharmafile (Sep. 15, 2005), available athttp://
www.pharmafile.com/news/dealing-generic-threat.
58
The People of the State of New York v. Actavis PLC and Forest Laboratories LLC,
S.D.N.Y.14-cv-4624 (2nd Cir, 2015).
59
There seems to be a clear acknowledgement of the monopoly of Namenda. See Stuart
Silverman, Second Circuit Affirms Preliminary Injunction in Antitrust Suit Against Drug
Companies for Product Hopping, American University WCL, National Law Review (May.
22, 2015) available athttp://news.monster.com/a/business/second-circuit-affirms-prelimi-
nary-injunction-in-antitrust-suit-against-drug-companies-for-pr-ff8e0f.
60
The People of the State of New York v. Actavis PLC and Forest Laboratories LLC,
SDNY14-cv-4624 (2nd Cir, 2015).
61
Case No: A3/2013/0559 Chemistree HomeCare Ltd. v. AbbVie Ltd., 2013 EWHC Civ
1338.
46 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
the existing products. There are several instances of brand leaders being
displaced by late entrants to demonstrate this. While this is a very persuasive
argument in itself, the infinite life of a trademark combined with a monopoly
for a patented product in the Indian healthcare sector creates several chal-
lenges for competition law. That anyone can compete using their own trade
mark assumes that it is possible to compete which is not possible when
there is a monopoly due to a patent, especially in the pharmaceutical sector.
We have always had trademarks for drugs and they have arguably made
them more accessible, since the name Aspirin is easier to remember than
acetylsalicylic acid. Why has this suddenly become an issue? Trademark law
has come a long way and it is perhaps important for us to retrace its history
to understand how far we have come from its roots and ask ourselves if we
really want to be where we are.
While we are all taught that the origin of trademarks was for goods to be
easily identifiable with their makers originally the artisan guilds in medi-
eval England this quickly morphed into a right for the maker rather than
a protection for the consumer. There is some evidence of Harappan marks
embossed on goods traded with foreign countries such as Mesopotamia and
Babylonia. The legal recognition of the trademark as a species of incorporeal
property was first accorded by the Court of Chancery in the first half of the
19th Century. In Millington v. Fox62 , it was decided that it was not neces-
sary to establish any intention to deceive on the part of an infringer against
whom an injunction to restrain his use of another trademark is sought.
62
Millington v. Fox, (1838) 3 My & Cr 338.
63
Ramdev Food Products (P). Ltd. v. Arvindbhai Rambhai Patel, (2006) 8 SCC 726 : (2006)
33 PTC 281, 299.
64
S. 2(1)(zb), Trade Marks Act, 1999.
48 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
65
Quality is not relevant for pharmaceutical brands since all drugs having the same chemical
composition are approved before being allowed to be sold and it is a requirement of the
Drugs and Cosmetics Act that a generic is the chemical and bio-equivalent of the innovator
(patented) drug.
66
Sumat Prasad Jain v. Sheojanam Prasad, (1973) 1 SCC 56 : AIR 1972 SC 2488, 2490.
67
Glaxo Group v. Dowelhurst Ltd., 2000 FSR 529, 539.
68
But see the recent reports of Phillip Morris claiming expropriation of property in respect of
tobacco plain packaging laws of some countries, which highlights this issue once again. See
M.C. Porterfield & C.R. Byrnes, Philip Morris v. Uruguay: Will Investor-State Arbitration
Send Restrictions on Tobacco Marketing up in Smoke, Investment Treaty News (Jul.
12, 2011), available at http://www.iisd.org/itn/2011/07/12/philip-morris-v-uruguay-will-
investor-state-arbitration-send-restrictions-on-tobacco-marketing-up-in-smoke/; Aylin A.
Sahin, Philip Morris v. Uruguay: Intellectual Property Debate in International Investment
Arbitration, Berkeley Tech. L.J. (Nov. 7, 2014), available at http://btlj.org/2014/11/phil-
ip-morris-vs-uruguay-intellectual-property-debate-in-international-investment-arbitra-
tion/.
69
American Home Products Corpn. v. Mac Laboratories (P) Ltd., (1986) 1 SCC 465 : AIR
1986 SC 137, 154.
70
McAtee v. Chem Shengula, (2007) 34 PTC 298.
71
One may argue that there are families of drugs and they together with the International
Non Proprietary Names are well known amongst the cognoscenti. For example, statins
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 49
protection and become open to competition, the use of a trade name for that
drug is so prevalent that no one remembers the generic chemical name72 for
instance, acetylsalicylic acid has always been overshadowed by the brand
name Aspirin. This phenomenon of not having common names for products
does not seem to prevail in any other industry. When brand names became
common nouns like in the case of Yo-Yo (a childrens toy), cellophane73 (the
plastic wrapping material), photocopying (Xerox74) or instant photography
(Polaroid), there developed a theoretical basis for these trademarks to be
genericised. But pharmaceuticals seem to have managed to sidestep this
issue. In fact, the generics established their own pharmaceutical brands,
rather than challenge the basis for innovators to name a product and then
appropriate it to own the brand. The justification was patient safety it is
easier to prescribe and consume drugs which have simple, memorable names
than having to remember the generic chemical name.
Calpol, different trade names and marks for the same drug, paracetamol,
by one company, GlaxoSmithKline (GSK) in this case, creates significant
confusion for doctors, patients, and chemists.78 From a competition law per-
spective, it allows pharmaceutical companies to create a segmentation of the
market for analgesics, rather than just paracetamol a smaller market than
analgesics79 and justify the claim that they each have no significant market
power in the analgesics market.80 It is significant that paracetamol is covered
by the Drug Price Control Order81 and as a result, it is easily argued that by
this measure, the government has ensured that no paracetamol manufac-
turer has significant market power, thereby negating the effect of brands
causing any disruption to the working of market forces.82 This does not
however explain why patented drugs, which are very likely to have a monop-
oly, are not covered by price control in India, when a vibrant competitive
market with over 300 producers, like generic paracetamol, is. Evidently, the
economic basis for this policy of the Indian government is extremely difficult
to understand.
establishing the standard for approval of drugs and their trade names pursuant to S. 17-B
of the Drugs and Cosmetics Act, 1940: Exacting judicial scrutiny is required if there is
a possibility of confusion over marks on medicinal products because the potential harm
may be far more dire than that in confusion over ordinary consumer products.
78
There is also a brand called Krocetamol, presumably a take on both Crocin and paraceta-
mol and several variations on the Calpol brand Calpol Plus which has paracetamol and
ibuprofen, and Calpol T which has paracetamol with tramadol. These combinations are
one of the reasons cited by Indian doctors to prescribe brands rather than generic chemical
names. See K.K. Aggarwal, infra note 95.
79
While it may seem like the relevant market is either analgesics or paracetamol in India,
there are other aspects like price and substitutability that affect the definition of market.
80
It is arguable based on the views of doctors, pharmacists, and patients, on substitutability,
that combinations containing paracetamol, ibuprofen, and diclofenac for example, may be
treated as being part of the analgesics market. However, this conclusion is not supported
by the order of the Competition Commission of India in the matter of the Sun Ranbaxy
merger, supra note 46, where for example, atorvastatin and rosuvastatin were each con-
sidered as separate markets, although the family of statins all treat the same condition and
act in a similar manner and are similarly priced by Sun. Interestingly, the Competition
Commission considered spare parts for each car brand as a relevant market Shamesher
Kataria v. Honda Seil, [2014] CCI 26 , available at http://www.cci.gov.in/May2011/
OrderOfCommission/27/032011.pdf.
81
Issued under the Essential Commodities Act, 1955. It has been and continues to be the
subject matter of challenge before the Delhi and Bombay High Courts and the Supreme
Court of India.
82
See paragraph 23 of the order of the Competition Commission of India in the matter of the
Sun-Ranbaxy merger, supra note 46 for an example of this concept being accepted, with
little explanation, by the Competition Commission of India.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 51
83
The definition of trade mark was amended in 1993 to include shape of goods, their pack-
aging and combination of colours to follow global norms on trademarks. See S. 2(1)(m)
and S. 2(1)(xb), Trade Marks Act, 1999.
84
See the decision of the Court of Appeal in Nestle v. Cadbury, 2013 EWCA 1174 where
Cadbury was refused registration of its distinctive purple colour which it has used for over
a century.
85
The battle between GSK and Sandoz on the inhaler from Sandoz that competes with purple
coloured inhaler sold as Advair (the multi-billion dollar blockbuster from GSK) is being
keenly watched. GSK was granted CTM registration for the purple colour combination on
the inhaler. While a Danish court refused GSK an interim injunction, a court in Cologne
granted an interim injunction but the case was eventually settled.
86
Dr. B. Jayakrishnan, Asthma Inhalers And Colour Coding: Universal Dots, 60(578) Br J.
Gen Pract 690691 (Sep. 1, 2010), available at http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/
PMC2930224/.
87
See Aaron S. Kesselheim, et al, Variations in Pill Appearance of Antiepileptic Drugs and
the Risk of Nonadherence, 173(3) Jama Internal Medicine 202 (Feb. 11, 2013); Brady
Dennis, If Color or Shape of Generic Pills Changes, Patients May Stop Taking Them, The
Washington Post (Jul. 14, 2014), available at http://www.washingtonpost.com/national/
health-science/if-color-or-shape-changes-patients-more-likely-to-stop-taking-much-need-
ed-drugs/2014/07/14/60e687f4-0b8c-11e4-8341-b8072b1e7348_story.html. See also U.S.
Federal Drug Administration, Guidance for Industry Size, Shape, and Other Physical
Attributes of Generic Tablets and Capsules (Dec. 2013), available at http://www.fda.gov/
downloads/drugs/guidancecomplianceregulatoryinformation/guidances/ucm377938.pdf.
52 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
of a patented drug with a trade name, unique shape and colour is a potent
combination of IPR to keep competition out forever.
88
See Chemistree, supra note 61.
89
See supra note 86.
90
A similar reasoning is offered by Indian doctors to prescribe brands rather than generic
chemical names of drugs. See K.K. Aggarwal, infra note 94.
91
Case C-299/99 Koninklijke Philips Electronics NV v. Remington Consumer Products
Ltd., 2003 RPC 2.
92
See supra note 85.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 53
This reaffirms the legal basis for a trademark to be the clear identification
of the source of the goods, and no more. It also reminds us of the potential
risk of trademarks distorting competition. In the Indian healthcare context,
each brand seems to be a market in itself since doctors prescribe brands, not
drugs by their generic chemical name,94 and patients dont consider them
substitutable because they would not be able to make the decision based on
information available to them from pharmacists who are incentivized to sell
more expensive drugs.95 This is not much of an issue in the United Kingdom
or most of Europe where healthcare is virtually free at the point of use and
patients pay very little for drugs or devices, all of which are primarily funded
by a national health service. In the United States, the oligopoly of insurers
negotiates the price of drugs with pharmaceutical companies and it may well
be argued that there is a fair balance of power. Brands therefore have little
effect of distorting competition where the buyer, the national health service,
or an oligopoly of insurers, with sufficient information and choice is able to
evaluate (both on a cost-benefit basis as well as medical need) before listing
the drugs that a doctor can prescribe. There is virtually a monopoly buyer
negotiating with a potential monopolist patent holder, and the patient is
rarely given a choice of the brand of the drug. In most of Europe, the patient
is often only aware of the generic chemical name on the label of the con-
tainer printed by the pharmacist.
93
Case C-299/99 Koninklijke Philips Electronics NV v. Remington Consumer Products
Ltd., 2003 RPC 2, 30.
94
See Dr. Ganapati Mudur, Doctors in India Defy Guidelines on Generic Drugs, BMJ 347
(2013) available at , http://www.bmj.com/content/347/bmj.f4244#.
95
For a summary of the viewpoints of the various players in the Indian healthcare sector
on competition between brands, see Dr. K.K. Aggarwal, The Generic Drug Controversy,
23(9) Indian Journal of Clinical Practice 485 (Feb. 9, 2013).
96
As a part of the Drug Price Control Order, the Indian government is now requiring all
manufacturers to register all products with details of price and sales. The Competition
Commission of India relied on sales data from the All India Association of Chemists and
Druggists who do not list all sales for all drugs. Information on direct sales to hospital
54 NLS BUSINESS LAW REVIEW VOL. 1
This will help us understand the impact of various regulations on the market
and the operation of market forces. There is clear evidence of the disrup-
tion of the market by brands, especially with several combinations97 which
are used as reasons for doctors to prescribe them in clear violation of their
ethical and legal obligations.98 The natural consequence of the existence
of brand names is their promotion by the brand owners. Since the doctor,
being the decision maker, is the real customer, pharmaceutical companies
are incentivized99 to use corrupt practices to influence them to prescribe
brands, rather than the generic chemical names of drugs.100 As a result, the
elimination of protection of brand names for drugs addresses several market
distorting issues.101 Corruption creates barriers to competition for those who
are unwilling to participate in corrupt practices, and increases the cost of
doing business which, in turn, is borne by patients. The belief that regula-
tion of drug prices is an easy fix to overcome potential dominance of brands
is a misconception that is disrupting the market by creating other barriers to
competition and incentivizing brands to game the system.
chains, government, public sector undertakings, railways and defence and paramilitary
services and the like, for example, where millions of patients are treated every year are
routinely missed.
97
See supra note 78.
98
Indian Medical Council (Profession Conduct, Etiquette and Ethics) Regulations, 2002,
Gazette of India, 1.5 (Apr. 6, 2002).
99
Indian Medical Council (Professional Conduct, Etiquette and Ethics) Regulations, 2002,
6 prohibits doctors from accepting gifts. Often, to overcome this stipulation, free sam-
ples or special schemes are provided to doctors by pharmaceutical companies. An
example of a special scheme would be giving a doctor five free units for every one unit
of a drug purchased. The doctor would therefore be able to sell six units at the retail price
and make an astonishing profit without the patient ever knowing this.
100
A common definition of corruption is the abuse of public or private office for personal
gain. See Asian Development Bank, Anti-Corruption: Policies and Strategies, Description
and Answers to Frequently Asked Questions 1 (Manila, 2000).
101
See Corruption Explained, International Chamber of Commerce, available at http://www.
iccwbo.org/advocacy-codes-and-rules/areas-of-work/corporate-responsibility-and-an-
ti-corruption/corruption-explained/ (Last visited Jul. 3, 2015), for the position of the
International Chamber of Commerce; Guidance Note of the International Monetary Fund,
Role of the IMF in Governance Issues. See The IMF and Good Governance, International
Monetary Fund, (Apr. 9, 2015), available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/gov.
htm (Last visited Jul 3, 2015); Business and Governments Against Corruption: Factsheet,
United Nations Office Against Drugs and Crime, available at http://www.unodc.org/
documents/congress//background-information/Corruption/4._Factsheet_-_An_Anti-
Corruption_Ethics_and_Compliance_Programme.pdf.
2015 COMPETITION LAW & IPR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR 55
prohibition, Section 17-B of the Drugs and Cosmetics Act, 1940 can be
used to disapprove the sale or marketing of a drug or product. Since limita-
tions can be placed on the use of a mark,102 the trademark registry can very
easily restrict the use of the name for the period of the patent,103 with the
express condition that the name be then made available thereafter to every
competitor to use, so long as the source is clearly identified on the product
or packaging. Therefore, if Aspirin is a trade name for acetyl salicylic acid
during the term of the patent, the name Aspirin and the generic chemi-
cal name should be used by every manufacturer or seller (after the patent
on Aspirin expires) together with the name or mark of the manufacturer
clearly stated, in order to distinguish products of different manufacturers
of Aspirin. Similarly, the colour of pills, devices, and packaging should be
uniformly used and industry standards established so that there is consist-
ency and confusion is avoided,thereby ensuring patient compliance. With
the elimination of competing brand names, it will be easier for ethical phar-
maceutical companies to compete, and for doctors to comply with their legal
and ethical professional obligations.104
Each drug name could automatically be listed under Section 23(1) of the
Trade Marks Act105 upon patent expiry so that they become generic, instead
of being registered. The colour of the drug or device, the text on the packag-
ing, and the design elements, all of which have a functional element, should
not be allowed to be owned separately from the product. This prevents the
composition of the drug from being changed while selling it under a well-
known brand name,106 and further ensures that patient interest is not com-
promised and patients have real choice of products in a market that allows
competition to thrive.
While we can look to the West for ideas on how to regulate our markets,
we need to be very vigilant about how different India is and why we need
to be wary of blindly implementing western models of market regulation.
Instead, we should focus on leapfrogging them to avoid the regulatory chal-
lenges that they have created in the process of their learning and growth.
102
S. 18, Trade Marks Act, 1999.
103
S. 2(1)(l), Trade Marks Act, 1999 defines limitations to mean any limitation of the exclu-
sive right to the use of a trade mark given by the registration of a person as proprietor
thereof, including limitations of that right as to mode or area of use within India or outside
India.
104
See supra notes 98, 99.
105
So far, the Central Government has listed names and pictures of gods and goddesses.
106
See for example, supra note 76.