Lösch, August, 1954
Lösch, August, 1954
Lösch, August, 1954
OF FLORIDA
LIBRARIES
--^w(eT.f8S/Ullli
AUGUST LOSCH
WOLFGANG
F.
ASSISTANCE OF
STOLPER
^
C."^
Copyright, 1954, by Yale University Press.
reproduced,
in
whole or
may
in part, in
not be
any form
and 108
of the U.S.
Copyright
by
ISBN: 0-300-00727-2
Published in Great Britain, Europe, Africa, and
Asia (except Japan) by Yale University Press,
Ltd.,
London. Distributed
in Australia
and
New
Zealand by Book
Tokyo
Office.
^
^
Translator's
The translator
Note
two
distinguished economists.
of
furnished a great
Wolfgang
F.
many
President's Council
in manuscript
and
valuable suggestions.
University of
under Schumpeter, in Bonn, Germany, and a close lifelong friend therehe was able to interpret some expressions peculiar to the author
that otherwise might have remained obscure.
after,
The
and
assis-
W. H. W.
Teaneck,
New
Jersey,
May, 1952
Grateful acknowledgment
is
made
to
Lyrasis IVIembers
http://www.archive.org/details/economicsoflocatOOIs
August Losch
in
Memoriam
August Losch was born in 1906. He died shortly after the end
on May 30, 1945, at least partially as the result of that
very strength of character which forbade him to make any compromises with the National Socialist regime. He never even considered taking a government or academic position in which he
would have had to swear a personal oath of allegiance to Hitler.
The willingness to accept a professorship after the war, which he
of hostilities
have not
felt free to
homeland
The Economics
yjii
of Location
grew out of a seminar paper. His first major piece of work was a
booklet about the economic consequences of a declining population,
perhaps the best discussion of the problem in terms of classical (in
the sense of pre-Keynesian) theory that exists. The subject was set
as a prize question and Losch won the contest. Because he believed
in personal freedom, including the taking of risks, he chose to pubbooklet himself, using the prize money for the purpose.
his next major work, on Population Cycles and
Business Cycles, dealt with the economics of population. Both show
all the characteristics of a modern economist who attempts to fuse
theory and facts in one indissoluble whole. The books are concisely
written; no superfluous introductions ease the reader into the subject
matter. Nor does Losch spare the reader concise reasoning or a
lish the
multitude of facts.
It may not be without interest to give the main results of Losch's
population study in some detail, since the relation of population
growth and business cycles has aroused new interest through the
Keynes-Hansen-Terborgh discussion, through the stagnation thesis
and criticisms of it, and again through the fact that the forties and
early fifties have been a period of prosperity which has also witnessed
the largest absolute increase of population in the history of the
United States.
The question whether population cycles cause business cycles
requires different answers, according to Losch, in the precapitalist
and the capitalist eras. During the capitalist era population movements are neither necessary nor sufficient to explain the fluctuations
of the economy. Nevertheless Losch establishes the fact that in
Germany industrial production as a rule increased quickly following
a population increase. Indeed, during the periods 1861-1913 and
1923-33 he finds only two exceptions to this relationship. Since the
economic development of growing nations takes to a large extent
the form of increased housing and capital equipment for the
increased
numbers
consumers' goods,
movements and
amounts of
population
rhythm
of
the
it is
Further-
more, the growth of the economy to accommodate a growing population entails smaller risks than the adaptation to changes brought
about by technological progress and the creation of new markets.
Thus, in Losch's own words, although " population growth does not
create business cycles,
it
This kind of discussion is quite familiar today. But Losch antedates the Keynesian discussion. If his contribution is formulated in
August
"^
Memoriam
LdscJi in
The Economics
used the traditional theories of location from von Thiinen on. Yet
he succeeded in bringing new insights even to so well-developed a
theory as that of the famous Thunen rings. His criticism of Alfred
Weber's location theory is essentially that voiced by Schumpeter.^
Weber's solution is in terms of partial equilibrium theory and as
such is a brilliant piece of work. But the partial equilibrium
approach means that among the other things which have to be
assumed
as given are
of
the location of markets. What remains to be accomplished, therefore, once a satisfactory solution of the partial equilibrium problem
has been
found,
is
the
approach.
own
is
precisely
when
they published their contributions. It is neverLosch was the first to present a full general
equilibrium system describing in abstract the interrelationship of
all locations. To be sure, he did not go beyond counting equations
and unknowns. But this in itself is a major achievement which,
his
ideas
in
its
had eluded
precision,
achievement
sets
Again
his
Lest
remember
that
we
it
lose patience
was over
and courage
it may be well to
dynamics was added
Walrasian system.
Losch himself has pointed out that his system of equations shares
the weakness of any general theory which is too all-inclusive to be
applicable. This was one of the reasons why he developed his theory
of economic regions. However, the theoretical framework itself is
useful for a number of problems for which it must, of course, be
narrowed down and made specific. It is surely no accident that
one of the most useful pieces of theoretical and empirical research,
to the
1,
In Schmollers Jahrbuch,
XXXIV
(1910), 1356
ff.
The Economics
of Location
the interrelationship of
all
minimum
be
as generalized as possible.
The
an
inefficient
in all goods.
To
it
a region by
differently,
means
of
AuguiC Losch
in
Meinoiiain
xi
again becomes of paramount importance. In a similar manner interregional wage differentials cannot be understood without an awareness of the structure both of a region and its relationships with the
outside world.
The Economics of Location is not easy reading. This is partly
due to the evident pressure under which it was written. In a few
places it may be because important passages from the first edition
which were omitted from the second German edition to save space
have been reinserted in the American edition in the appropriate
places. But basically it is due to the very newness of the ideas: not
enough time has as yet elapsed or professional discussion taken place
since the publication of the book to lead to simplification, a streamlining as it were, of the formulations. Losch's work opens up new
vistas and new avenues of research. No greater compliment could
be paid to it than its being taken up where Losch left off and carried
on to new formulations and achievements. The highest praise of
this book will be if in the future it can be said that the work it
has stimulated has made it obsolete.
"Wolfgang
Ann
1953
Arbor, Michigan
F.
Stolper
new
first
is
The
my
previous ones
this:
distribution in space.
young student. At
The Economics
xiv
of Location
list
of all those
who
assisted in
my
with advice, criticism, or information, or by cooperating in so many ways. For their constant readiness to help
I thank first of all my teachers, Arthur Spiethoff, in Bonn; Walter
Eucken, in Freiburg; and Joseph Schumpeter, at Harvard University.
My obligation is especially great to the Rockefeller Foundation,
which generously made possible my two trips of investigation
through all North America, and the publication of their results.
I sincerely thank, also, the Paul Stelzmann Fund, in Freiburg, for
helping me through a critical situation. To Professor Wassily
Leontief I am indebted for valuable suggestions, and mention in
gratitude at least the following others: Professors Taussig, Chamberlin, and v. Haberler of Harvard, headquarters for my American
investigation
investigations; the
sors
members
of the
summer
whom
spent a never-to-be-forgotten
Evans in Berkeley; Carver
E.
possibilities to
and
me
in
Vice-Presi-
xv
may
or blood. But
it
if
original intentions,
many
years of hard
testifies to
I
a sense of reality
and
to a belief.
and
test
my
views
on the whole may show even the American reader the economy of
his country from a new viewpoint, and thus serve in some small
degree to express my thanks for the help and hospitality experienced
there in a hundred different ways.
It was not easy for me largely to forego the attractive task of
applying what had thus been tested to our more complicated German
conditions and analyzing the pertinent facts. But apart from all
foreign studies and the wide applicability of the resulting ideas, my
youthful experiences in a little Swabian town constitute the real
background of this book. I am convinced that we rarely learn to
know any conditions as intimately as those among which we grew up.
We can judge with certainty only a small understandable and
familiar world like this, and we transfer the findings to large
problems afterward. My Swabian homeland constitutes such a
world in miniature, if any economic landscape at all can be said
The Economics
xvi
to
do
so.
To
theories gives
book
my
have
me
and
to the land of
my
of Location
my
final
so I dedicate this
August Losch
Heidenheim (Wilrttemberg)
Autumn, 1939
The favorable
my
aged
resolve to publish a
conditions prevented
new
more
clearly
my
location theory,
have at
which in the
first
least
worked out
book
The
is
My
book on money will contain more on this subject. (Because of the premature
this book has never appeared However, a lengthy article, " Theorie
der Wahrung," appeared posthumously in the Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. LXII
(1949) 35-88.-W. F. S.)
2.
F re face
Lo
''^"
Second Edition
304 and 317-324; price control officials 263, 333, and 452-507; geographers and statisticians in 365-507; sociologists in 66-91 and
223-262; and transportation specialists in pages 127, 170-191 and
440-444. Students may skip Part I, and at first the mathematics as
well. Those interested in town and regional planning will consider
especially pages
of those
who helped
to
make
the
first
edition as well as
When
I
the
first
its
my
rest,
dedication
book technically
Then,
possible
is
not to
still
apply.
my
now
powers
new method
for practicing
August I.osch
Kiel
Autumn, 1943
Contents
Translator's
Note
August Losch
in
Memoriam, by Wolfgang
Stolper
vii
xiii
xvi
xxiii
List of Tables
xxvii
I.
Location
A.
Problem
1.
2.
3.
B.
The Meaning
of the Location
Problem
Specific Locations
a.
Effects of Locations
b.
The
Areal Boundaries
5.
a.
13
b.
13
Industrial Location
7.
Theory
a.
The General
b.
Practical Execution
The Theory
Principle
Orientation
Partial
b.
Comprehensive Solution
c.
Site
(One-sided)
Comparison
a.
Reasons for
b.
The
Site
a.
Town Settlement
Town Settlement
Town Formation
and Reasons
Site of
and Cause
for
of Belt
Belts of Locations
Formation
b.
16
16
36
36
60
63
68
68
80
85
Producing Identical
Goods
8.
15
17
of Agricultural Location
a.
Theory:
6.
9
13
85
Location Patterns
90
92
The Economics
94
b.
c.
Conclusion
99
a.
II.
of Location
98
Economic Regions
A. Economic Regions under Simple Conditions
The Market Area
9.
10.
The Network
of Markets
Continuous
b.
109
114
tion
12.
Regional Networks
122
124
124
130
Special Cases
135
to
One
Another
B.
c.
Results
136
137
Difficult
Conditions
139
139
Natural Differences
178
c.
Human
191
d.
Political Differences
Differences
196
14.
211
15.
215
On
215
219
a Chaotic Interpretation
Trade
138
b.
b.
III.
135
b.
105
109
tion
11.
105
Distribution of Popula-
a.
c.
101
223
223
Description of Equilibrium
16.
17.
The
223
Divi-
sion of
226
a.
b.
The
236
Personnel of an Industry
226
Contents
c.
d.
e.
f.
g.
18.
B.
240
Conclusion
262
245
248
255
Price Gradients
263
264
Self-Regulation
a.
265
run
(The Transfer
Disturbances
Problem)
b.
265
20.
305
b.
Regulation
ucts
of
the
Distribution
Factors of Production
316
of
(The Com-
bination Problem)
c.
The
Practical
324
Value
of
Economic
Theory
IV.
357
Examples
A.
361
Location
21.
365
Locations of Production
b.
Uniform Distribution
Uneven Distribution
c.
National
a.
Boundaries
365
365
376
as
Factors
in
Location
22.
B.
The
Location of
382
Towns
389
Economic Areas
23.
395
395
a.
The
b.
402
c.
427
Individual Enterprise
24.
312
315
396
of Distance
Regional Systems
a.
431
Size of
Towns
431
The Economics
xxii
25.
Arrangement of Towns
b.
Spatial
c.
The Function
d.
Town
Towns
of
26.
27.
440
445
Frontier Regions
452
452
a.
452
b.
Product Prices
476
c.
Cost of Living
490
496
of
b.
Commodity
Space
Movement"
496
Prices
On
438
439
Plans
Trade
C.
Epilogue.
of Location
Movement
505
508
Subject Index
509
Name
517
Index
List of Figures
1.
2.
The
The
concentration of locations
11
construction of isodapanes
19
4.
5.
49
6.
50
7.
Thiinen case
53
8.
53
9.
3.
10.
of
37
45
55
in
inversion
55
11.
Potato market
56
12.
13.
Corn market
Rent per hectare during
14.
58
15.
58
16.
Size of the
its
56
56
transition
rings
producing unit in
a)
64
culture
17.
Location of crops
as a
function of
soil
products
quality
70
86
and
distance
88
tion of distance
23.
Development
of
and the
cost curves
106
circle to
110
24-26.
U7
27.
118
28.
125
29. Theoretical
without nets
30.
125
125
The Economics
i[xiv
of Location
31.
32.
The
33.
34.
128
35.
132
36.
37.
125
economic landscape
=3
k=4
k= 7
Comparison of individual
41.
c. i. f.
and
f.
o. b.
demand with
135
respect to the
140
price
demand
145
curves
149
to
f . o.
b.
corresponding total
Geometric
45.
46.
new
large-scale
economies on
size of
172
thickly
settled
and
The law
50.
New
Orleans via
possible
186
areas
53.
Economic and
54.
55.
224
57.
The
58.
60.
areas
258
268
271
304
190
204
political borders
181
184
of refraction
Nicaragua cut
56. Effects of
167
176
to
161
market
area
49.
151
154
32
134
128
127
tariff
341
341
xxv
List of Figures
61.
Member banks
62.
Bank
the
Reserve
Federal
1,
Bank
of
366
1926
366
1926
63. Principal
European
367
1921
fairs^
64. Agricultural
America (United
States, 1930;
Canada, 1931)
65.
Rotation of crops
66.
as a function of distance
382
village
Parceling of
District of
389
67. Distribution of
69.
fields
389
on
Herrenberg
400
404
71.
72.
Market area of
Market areas of
74.
Method
five
390
75. Sales
375
from a
work
clothes
of determining retail
market areas
411
woolen
413
415
418
County, Iowa
418
76.
419
77.
420
78-79.
The
oil
421
80.
England
81.
429
82.
Shape and
442
83.
The French
as a
street
425
hinterland of Geneva
The network
86.
The
of railways
88.
447
448
453
89.
446
on the American-Canadian
border
87. Price of
445
454
457
The Economics
jcxvi
90.
91.
of Location
The
United
458
States, 1933
United
States,
of shoes,
459
1936
457
agricultural workers,
laundering a man's
shirt.
United
459
1936
New
462
York, 1919-25
95. Increase
in
465
States,
478
1910-14
97.
United
100.
Westward movement
101.
Comparison
102.
The
United
States
States,
States,
1906-15
480
480
1936
488
497
31
of house rents in the
United
States
and
Canada, 1929-37
500
and
its
502
List of Tables
1.
2.
34
Classification of locations
Complete system
two
crops
39
3.
4.
System of equations
95
97
6.
Demand
The ten
7.
Calculation of n
8.
131
9.
International trade
227
5.
as a
1 1
119
119
10.
Interpersonal trade
11.
Comparative
12.
228
efficiencies
(comparative advantages)
of
the countries
229
231
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
Surplus, self-sufficient
20.
Employment per
21.
13-14.
of land
255
282
283
347
United States,
1929
368
and
deficit regions
369
Wurt-
22. Distances
United
separating
373
size
States
392
391
and distance
394
398
trades
26. Size of
399
Distance and
counties
size
of
demand
in
405
cities,
1929
407
wholesale trade, by
409
^^^ Economics
xxviii
29.
Distance and
size of
demand
of Location
410
Iowa
demand
412
30.
Distance and
31.
size of
423
430
1928
34.
35.
431
435
in
465
Texas, 1936
36. Increase in interest rate
distance,
466
Texas, 1936
481
and distance
37.
Orange
38.
prices
United
39.
States
Comparison
of
499
487
Canada
500
States
UNNUMBERED TABLES
One-to-one correspondence between international and
235
interpersonal trade
by
New
Central States
Selling cost
total cost.
dependent on distance
United
as
percentage of
397
States
number
Germany
of places in Christaller
432
system
397n.
as
percentage of deposits,
1935
470
Spread of interest rates between New York and twentyseven financial centers in the South and West, 1923-35
505
OUR EXISTENCE
in time
this rapidly
A. Systematic Presentation of
the Location
No MAN-MADE
for
Problem
we do not know
We
is
conclusive
know only
We
it would have a
Just as the first three parts of this book imply no
clear-cut separation, so classification within this as within all other
unique
place.
sections
a particular economic activity is to be found. In judging the manifold contributions to this theme it is helpful to fix their place in
the theory. Moreover, only thus can we recognize the basic problems.
1.
its
details
some
Chapter
1.
The Meaning
of the Location
Problem
The
least for an epoch. From this follow rules for the considerations
by which entrepreneurs let themselves be guided in choosing an
actual location. It is often important to know this. But it would
be dangerous to conclude that what is must also be rational since
otherwise it could not exist, and that any theoretical determination
of the correct location would therefore be superfluous. Such a
capitulation to reality is as useful as the advice of those who on
principle contradict no one: a contemptible attitude that is satisfied
to accept one's era instead of serving it. Of what value is a science
that does not observe Schiller's valiant watchword: " Live with thy
century, but be not its creature; give to thy contemporaries, but
give what they need, not what they laud "? ^ No! The real duty of
the economist is not to explain our sorry reality, but to improve it.
The
is
far
more
1.
9.
Brief.
Chapter
2.
Specific Locations
a.
The
1.
to determine this.^
his best advantage.
of production, of competition,
in the extreme.
2. Location of a Consumer.
His location depends
location of the producers and of neighboring centers of
1.
The
is
no
different.
upon
the
consump-
As in any one
individual case price can be explained by costs, so any one location can be explained
by others. The general theory of pricing must not, of course, follow this circular
reasoning, and neither must the general theory of location. In either case only a
system of simultaneous equations can properly demonstrate the interdependence.
2. J. H. von Thiinen, Der Isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaft und
Part One.
Location
tion.
the literature
aware
the
its
first case.
fi.
chosen
problem was
first
on such
simplified assumptions that his conclusion (a tendency to agglomeration) cannot be generalized. Under uniform conditions in a free
market the individual has no latitude in the choice of his location.
The problem can thus have practical importance only either during
human
itself,
only in
enough
some
latitude of choice,
and may
fight
These
among
(aa)
Effects
on Form.
3.
4.
First,
Stability in Competition,"
1.
Economic Journal,
specific Locations
produced may vary with the distance from that place. By form
may be meant intensiveness, that is, the method of
production
of
(Thiinen)
or the stage to which factory production
cultivation
local finishing is more expensive than
locally.
If
is carried out
centralized finishing, perhaps because the advantages of large-scale
production cannot be utilized so fully, but freight per unit of
consumption is less when a product is shipped in finished rather
than crude condition, then it may pay at a certain distance from
the consumer to ship frozen meat, say, instead of livestock for
slaughter. In these cases the final product always remains the same.
it is
From
this
we must
end
products such as fresh milk, cream, or butter are prepared from the
same original products, depending on the distance from the consumer. We then deal no longer with different competing forms,
but with different products the subject of the next section.
(bb) Influences on the Substance of Economic Activity. First,
the object of consumption as a function of distance. Suppose com-
peting goods are produced in the same place. Where each will be
consumed may depend on the distance from their origin.^ Consider,
zig,
5.
6.
See
1885)
p. 164.
Part One.
Location
consumption of various products to coincide in a town. These products compete for land for their cultivation. Thiinen has shown
that under certain conditions their cultivation is arranged in rings
around the market. We shall return to this problem laterJ
2.
a.
If
we wish
to
of Location
selection of a
enter
upon
particular location
The repercussions,
strictly
and it ceases
pick out one location and examine its relation
to
be
meaningful to
to
its
neighbors in isolation.
all locations.
We
longer be charted, but can be represented only by a system of equations that are insoluble in practice. The conditions that they express,
rather than the equations themselves, are of great interest indeed.
For they contain the conditions for the functioning of the whole
system and are therefore more important than all that the special
location theory has to offer in the way of realistic details. With the
general equations we encounter the other basic force that determined location: the tendency to equalization of the advantages of
the individual economic units and (in a market into which entry
is possible)
the maximization of the number of competitors.^
j8.
of
Economic Regions
specific Locations
it
can be charted.
It neglects
goods at
major
cities
arteries.
If
establishment of
quite probable that the picture would be someunlikely that it will be wholly invalidated.
Because of their importance, a separate part of this book will be
are introduced
it is
it is
b.
We
shall
now
may be reduced
up
into
to a
Part One.
iQ
Location
same
2,
Agglomeration of Locations
a.
The
Punctiform Agglomeration
why
questions
sometimes coincide,
consumers)
so unusually great, and why and where
the same. The answer must distinguish
locations for the production of similar
the production of different commodities.
Areal Agglomerations
by the
fact that
lie
close together
10. If
11.
The
is
of buyers
and
sellers,
their
behavior, and their complementarity. It was a mistake to think that the market
method and
number of buyers and
i.
e.,
the
results of price
market
market
form
sellers without their locational pattern. In general, the tradimarket forms acquire an essentially different content as soon as they are seen
geographically. But there is neither time nor space to develop this here.
tional
'^
specific Locations
may be
of
Areal
none
Restricted
Cluster
market network
^ ^ ^
True network
Belt (cotton gins)
District (coal
mines)
Place (collars)
(bakeries)
Fig.
The
I.
Concentration of Locations
whose market includes the whole of the United States. There is,
however, a third, intermediate, form. Most of the American coal
mines are not concentrated at one site, though they are restricted
to a relatively small territory. Nevertheless they do not supply
arbitrarily those areas that lack coal.
The importance
of overlapping
coal shipments
is
Thus
its
own
special
partly
on
irrational
that each
outlets."
the steel works in the Chicago area get their coal from the Pittsburgh
much
nearer Illinois
fields is
districts this
the next inner ring. Strictly speaking, therefore, rather than the entire coal field only
an outer ring
is
is
were collected
at a
The
The
situation
would be simplest
Part One.
12
Location
redistributed from
their distances
easily determined.
worth while
tliese.
districts.
centers.
is
Chapter
3.
Areal Boundaries
a.
goods.
The latter are already given with the position of all locations,
but the former must be calculated from the locations. With homogeneous goods the boundaries are sharp if buyers and sellers are
scattered and numerous, and if the center of each area is treated
as though the other centers did not exist. Otherwise the markets
overlap and the boundaries become indistinct.
b.
There are systems in which the areas for different goods are
(as in the Thiinen case)
or overlap (as in economic
provinces)
Depending on the system, we get only boundary lines
Boundary lines between both kinds of
(1) or boundary zones (2)
areal system have two things in common: Both include boundaries
separate
Part One.
14
Location
good
that;
extension.
only between major cities, and indicate the boundary area in which
" loophole " markets are found, that is, markets belonging wholly
to neither of the two districts even though both are by nature wholly
similar. They arise from the fact that where markets meet district
boundaries empty corners appear that in themselves are too small
room
made
large
is
complex
it
to other
and more
situations.
The
following pages will discuss two groups of questions concerning the choice of location seen from the standpoint of the
individual economic unit (industrial and agricultural location
theory) two problems on the agglomerations of locations (formation of towns and belts) and two divisions of the general theory of
location (of which only the locational equations will be introduced
,
on economic regions
will
be presented separately)
1.
regions have been anticipated, whose proof cannot be given until Part
II.
Chapter
a.
The
4.
preneur.
They
will share
only the formal aim, which is to choose their location so that the
utility shall be as great as possible. Whether they have hit upon
the right one can be determined only later, of course, for even after
mature consideration they will chose " with their fingers crossed." ^
L
may
is
more
restricted for
some
them
though
not the greatest possible, may result in losses to the former. Therefore they should not
simply take the locations of leading enterprises as a guide, or without further thought
attach themselves to an already existent agglomeration of their industry.
2. Here enter all those eccentricities that skeptics like to advance as examples of
the irrationality and antitheoretical nature of actual events. For instance, a producer
may frequently locate his plant so that he can pursue his favorite hobby on the side.
The preference of English businessmen and their wives for life in the south of England
than for the abler pioneers.
location that
profit,
British
industry.
entrepreneurial profit,
it is still
There are two reasons for this: the practical difficulty of determining exactly
under given conditions how good a site really is, and the fundamental impossibility of
foreseeing how these conditions will change. Dynamically there is no best location,
because we cannot know the future. What follows is therefore meant to apply to static
conditions. That the measurement of utility itself is dubious will be discussed later.
3.
The
The
scale
runs from the security of old farms, manorial estates, or mercantile establishments
inherited for generations that have seen their owners through all vicissitudes; through
virtually
for life
(rural pastorates)
through the multitude of industrial enterprises that under prudent management may
last for a few generations, or may move away or collapse at any moment; down to
itinerant folk of all sorts musicians
and
poets, scientists
who
and preachers,
all
of
whom
inventors,
the existing
17
PRACTICAL EXECUTION
b.
many
Obviously
all
irregular influences
hensible rules can be established only for the effects of the regular.
If we disregard all locally conditioned priceless utilities, the entre-
profit.
If
we
discover
a.
Nominal
As
profit
One-Sided Orientation
1.
receipts.
The
Cost Orientation
is
money
receipts
cost
and money
factors, industrial
Thus Weber
con-
demand
sidered
point of lowest
c. i. f.
The
be wholly
to
fate of List
is
is
costs
inelastic.
(cost,
insurance, freight)
economist,
vigorously
Bankruptcy does not necessarily mean the elimination of the unfit, but mainly
its dignity through its distinction from chaos
and not really through having accomplished something just or meaningful (except
perhaps the maximum of free will, though not, as was formerly believed, the maximum
4.
utility)
2.
Part One.
i8
Location
TRANSPORT ORIENTATION
1.
The
cost of
up
to
first
distance.
2.
Perforations are
made
in a
stiff
map
and markets. Threads bearing determinate weights are passed through these holes and tied together in
one knot.
The
of production.
costs
is
The problem
is
in a system of forces.
The
and
5.
let
His
D, E, and
first
easily accessible
paper
is
"
pp. 106-115.
6.
Alfred Weber,
(Chicago, 1928)
J.
Pt.
8.
Op.
p. 141.
(Tubingen,
1909)
7.
cit.,
1935)
pp. 139-145.
19
Then
to
when
only
Isodapanes.^
combination consists of the shipment of raw materials and intermediate products to, and shipments of the finished product from.
Fig. 2.
The
Construction of Isodapanes
from a certain
place.
They
one proceeds outward from the center, and follow one another
generally at increasing intervals for a graduated
port area
is
tariff.
If the trans-
truck)
9.
Palander {op.
10. Brilliantly
cit.,
p. 305)
cit.,
pp. 337-360.
lines.
Part One.
20
Location
and
so on.
The
tary units.
On
it
there
lie,
A and
of isovecture 4
around
of isovecture 6
Of
5.
number
lowest cardinal
is
it
The
sum of
4.
the
Principle of Substitution.
According to
sum
infinitesimal deviations
characterizes the
minimum
possibility of calculating
it
point,
it
this principle
While it merely
the same time the
location.^^
indicates at
Cost.
11.
A. Predohl,
liches Archiv,
XXI
"Das Standortproblem
(1925)
294-321.
The
principle
is
stated
on
p. 306.
21
greater had not the freight rate for coke from the Ruhr to Lorraine
exceeded that for the shipment of ore from Lorraine to the Ruhr."
The
poorer the ores that have to be smelted, the greater the attracHence the iron industry moves today more
and more toward the ore. A typical example of weight-conditioned
attraction toward the consumer is offered by the brewing industry.
The weight of the water added is greater than the weight lost by
tion of their deposits.
hops, malt,
The
and
fuel.
point or
of a favored
Part One.
22
Location
not only when one of the weights exceeds the sum of the others,
but also when it exceeds their resultants. The resultant for any
given weight depends on the relative positions of the points of
insertion of the weights."
Third, established lines of communication have the result that
the costs of transportation are always smallest at one of the perforations (location of raw material or of consumption) or nodes, as can
be readily seen on the mechanical model. Only at such favored
places can the opposing forces affect each other by altering the angle
of attack, whereas
The
Even where
of reloading
moved
tion becomes
more probable.
Not
secondly,
so,
when
rates are
graduated according to length of haul. Graduated tariffs favor shipment over long distances and hence favor as locations the starting
points and terminals of transportation systems
(location of
raw
ment
15.
points.^"
figure 8
lies
cit.,
we have
areas,
If
(op.
lies
p. 144)
If
a consumption
site of
refer as
site
lies
production
lies
in
an example to Palander's
one of the cross-hatched
Many
raw material
site
raw
If it
material.
the prepon-
figures
The
{op.
p. 318)
The
is
23
recent development of automobile transportation counteracts some of the factors discussed that influence the limiting special
location. It undermines the preferred position of railway stations
in general and that of favored special points in particular. The
The
locations.
2.
costs
minimum
quantities
climate, or of gifted
men who
necessary
3.
is
especially rare, of
some
special
refuse to migrate.
(aa)
Location of Lowest C.LF. Costs. As a rule the costs of
production cannot be separated from the freight cost on raw material,
and often it is not desired to separate them from the freight cost on
the finished product. In such cases they affect location only in combination with the latter, e. g., when several scattered raw materials
have to be combined, or when several sources of supply are available.
In our examples on page 18 let there be two sources for the first,
mobile raw material, for which the cost at /ij is 10 marks per ton
17.
Thus
freights,
and
the automobile
for goods
is
on which freight
Part One.
OA
whereas in remote
15 marks
A2
Location
By ordering from A 2,
is only 5 marks.
of finished product can be saved. But let
it
on every ton
the total freight per ton of finished product for the combination
F at the point of minimum transport cost be 20 marks
Ai,BF.
less than at the minimum point for the combination A2,B
pretherefore
be
A^,
would
source,
nearer
expensive
but
The more
Hence
ferred.
among
^^
among
and
sources,
the choice
production costs
In short, the most favorable location depends upon both, and
therefore
upon
total costs.^^
(bb)
many
18. Spatial
fact,
as
Ohlin has
fre-
quently emphasized, that the factor endowment of different regions varies, and that
these factors are combined in varying proportions and thus affect production in
different degrees.
result of local
differences in scarcity.
their products, the relative scarcities themselves are a result of the particular spatial
price system.
It
is
But
it
The
freight costs.
transportation.
difficulty
do
characteristics) as causes
to
human
will not
may be
far,
to total
as a theory of
movement.
Again the substitution principle characterizes the minimum point: For small
changes in location, the sum of cost increases must equal the sum of cost decreases. If
costs were known as a function of latitude and longitude, their minimum point could
be determined on principle algebraically instead of by Weber's geometrical solution.
Predohl (loc. cit.) introduced the marginal principle into the theory of industrial
location.
The
substitution equilibrium
is
cit.,
p. 314,
does not matter that equally priced amounts of means of production, whose price
may be
varies locally,
(which
may
differ in
amount and/or
value)
The
total costs
cheap labor,
of
minimum
substitution)
total costs
cost
may
With
nevertheless decrease.
and
fails
to
As soon
indicate
the best
(discontinuous
^5
the two costs is a minimum. Second, in cases that remain indeterminate in respect to production orientation, total costs permit a decision as to where, if anywhere, the special location is reached. It may,
that a factor of production is immobile but
that
it is found in several places. The condior
not irreplaceable,
only that in the case of replaceable factors
decide
tions of production
some special location may be, and in the case of more frequently
found factors certainly will be, chosen. Only total cost can decide
for example,
happen
among
location,
when
it is
total cost.
The
special location
may
by the
effect of
when
20. A.
Weber, op.
21. Occasionally
freight
and labor
made up
lines
is,
contour lines
"
is
vom
criticism
22.
vocal.
is
found on page
filr
770.)
Even with
several
of
minimum
points,
is
Part One.
26
Location
soon
Finally, orientation
by
total costs
may even
j3.
it.
1.
2.
Regard
23.
and labor
at
most
and
definite
changing their locations cannot, except for commuters, be treated as are other transportation costs. It is incurred only once and connected with the locality in question.
24.
When
all
transportation
is
be
still
may
more advantageous.
25. ".
in the absence of decisive natural factors
industries tend to be located
within easy reach of the market." Royal Commission on the Distribution of the Industrial Population (Barlow Commission) Report (London, 1940)
(Cmd. 6153) p. 48.
.
26.
at least in principle,
on
everywhere (the corresponding phenomenon with natural facubiquitous occurrence) the fact of a special location means
exist
tors
27
is
nothing;
if
is, it is
is
condition for the choice of a location. Then receipts are the governing factor. The special location is technically unequivocal only
when all buyers, or at least a sufficient number, live in one place.
2.
Orientation by Profit
Their significance
Of
profit
is
greatest.^^
course,
c.
i. f.
costs.
But a consideration
as profits
permit.
28.
(2)
right,
(1)
at the
at the
shift to the
Part One.
28
would
that
Location
strongly affected by
prices are high than
would
variability in
about a
shift
demand
demand.
shift in
Weber's
incorrect as soon
considered. His
matter.
of lowest cost.^^
Review of S. R.
29. A. Robinson has recently criticized this omission by Weber.
Dennison, The Location of Industry and the Depressed Areas (Oxford, 1939) in
,
Economic Journal, L
(1940)
267.
30. This does not exclude the possibility that isodapanes may aid in the determination of locations not only of production, but also of consumption, and of raw
(See Palander,
materials, whenever two of the three categories of location are given.
op. cit., pp. 159 ff.) In the first case, local wage differences may be taken into account,
as described above; in the other two cases, differences in f o. b. cost of materials.
.
pp. 162-165.)
In the intermediate case, the problem
(Ibid.,
may be
to include simultaneously
All isodapanes
in principle.
(i. e.,
lines of
equal freight
cost)
both kinds
lines of
combination.
i.
e.,
lines of
is
therefore not
demand upon
31.
costs
This applies
others)
Um
wirtschaftliches Archiv,
LIV
(1941), I-ll*.
This by no means excludes the incorporation into a new location theory o*f parts
of his theory which, though destroyed as a whole, nevertheless is a great achievement.
29
is
right,
But where
there
of a
is
this to
be found?
decrease according to a
simple function.32 \Ye are thus reduced to determine separately
for every one of a number of virtual factory locations the total
attainable demand, and for similar reasons the best volume of propoints outward total
cost
money
and demand
curves,
optimum
and from
can be found.
Now the procedure is no longer theoretical, however, but simply
empirical testing, since the result holds only for the locations actually
examined and cannot be interpolated. As all points in an area can
never be analyzed in this manner, we cannot exclude the possibility
that among the locations not examined there may be one that would
yield a higher return than the most advantageous of those investigated. There is no scientific and unequivocal solution for the
location of the individual firm, but only a practical one: the test
of trial and error. Hence Weber's and all the other attempts at a
systematic and valid location theory for the individual firm were
of greatest
doomed
profit,
the
location,
to failure.
For example, Weber's method could be employed in deciding between dispersed settlement of farmers and village settlement. For in this case demand is actually given as a
first approximation as far as the location, amount, and market price and the number
of products are concerned
Advocates of the
way
Thus economically
it
remains only
points and the market area as given can explain the international division of labor
by means of the minimum transport point (see W. H. Dean, The Theory of the
Geographic Location of Economic Activities [Ann Arbor, 1938], pp. 24 ff., from the
also
dissertation)
comparative
32.
cost.
Nor does a
may
change,
if
their
change
is
as great as
Part One.
^o
Location
33.
To
that
end
it is
on the
necessary to determine
cost side
cost items
industry)
we must know:
(b)
(a)
Thus
an
main
cost factors as
given place only after the cost of factors that are not particularly cheap
is
taken into
account. However, to calculate total production costs one must include demand, whose
extent often determines the height of the costs and always decides whether they can be
borne.
But, above
all,
points
more or
less in
expected sales areas should be considered, and even before that the favored points in
their vicinity.
These
If
systematic
lists
are prepared
of various sites
(supplies,
prices,
location)
and of
locations
already
appraised, the locations and possibilities of dislocation that are especially probable or
3*
model.^*
solution.
j8.
is
not incurred.^''
would
With complete
when
it
Our
for example,
prices,
direct
practical interest.
35. F. Lehmann-Lenoir, Les verreries suisses. Etude comparative de leur repartition
territorial efjective et de celle resultant de la " Reine Theorie des Standorts " d'Alfred
Weber
36.
with but one plant, since the former can draw more reliable geographic comparisons
from actual experience than if they had to rely on estimates alone.
Part One.
32
Location
including proceeds, in contradistinction to one-sided orientation by total costs. Definite technically conditioned special locations will necessarily be confirmed by profit calculations; others,
which depended on one-sided orientation, may be so confirmed.
Should production be carried on at a special location when only
factors,
more common
3,
Up
to
orientation has
may mean
had
several
meanings in the
literature
of location.
It
of location.
it
We
and possibly by
profits.^^
(3)
describes or at the
same time
(4) gives
demand
it;
if it
As well
as
(extra-economically)
33
reasons for the result of the choice. The first of these simply names
an actual situation at the source of a location factor after that factor,
but it remains an open question whether this factor is also responsible for the choice
(we shall
the source
at
for
1) .^^
But
it
that
the actual site is rational though not technically due to the factor
(We call this either " economic " or
located in the same place.
" extra-economic " restriction to a point of consumption, etc. dz
and
ds in
Table
l.)*^
40. Apart from the fact that whether or not production will pay at all depends also
on every other factor influencing profit. (See Predohl, op. cit., p. 294.)
41. As such technical restrictions are imposed mainly though not entirely by
nature, the influence of nature on the choice of a location may be briefly sketched.
The natural causes for local differences in the economic scarcity of means of production
may be divided into (1) their natural abundance, first as to the number and second
as to the extent of their sources; and (2) their technical suitability for shipment
(mobile or immobile)
According to the number of the sources of supply, production is: (1) With immobile
of production unconditionally dependent on source technically and economically
means
(one source)
conditionally dependent
(2)
(several sources)
All mobile
means
independence of their source, no matter what the number of their sources (ubiquity
through transportation)
Thus a location's technical independence of its sources predominates except where
immobile factors of production are found at only one or a few sites. Technical ubiquity
need not be economic, however, and vice versa. A locally varying economic scarcity of
factors of production can only limit still further the possibilities of a production
location that are already narrowed by technical scarcity. It cannot extend them.
In addition to influencing the choice of a location through sources and the technique of transportation, nature influences it through the technique of production,
which, however, depends not solely upon nature but also upon price relationships.
Nevertheless, nature does affect in this way the kind and relative amounts to be
shipped. (The extent of the weight loss is only one factor among others.)
42. It is clear how protean the all-too-popular concept of orientation is. When it is
said, for example, that an industry is " oriented to raw material," does the phrase
mean: (a) That in choosing a location attention need be paid to raw materials alone?
But to which of several? To the cost of its production or of its transportation? To its
quality or its quantity? Or (b) that the raw material merely plays the most important
role
among
Or
(c)
an industry that
on only
Or
(d)
do we
at this source?
refer to
If
there
Part One.
34
Location
Table
(a)
All
Partial
factors
(one-
con-
Extraeco-
sidered
nomic
sided)
Orientation
Ordinary location
(bb)
Indefi-
Technically con-
nite
sary
Techni-
(cc)
Result
2
of
choice
cally
(d,)
economi-
Explanation
cally
(c)
Special
of
location
and
of
Techni-
location
(aa)
Defi-
cally
special
and
loca-
extra-eco-
10
tion
nomically
nite
Fortui-
Economi-
cally (d2)
11
economi-
tous
(dd)
Extracally (d3)
The
up
in the text.
location
is
is
words.
always definite
(e. g.,
35
transport orientation)
a necessary
one may
with orientation by technical restrictions on production) .^3 A rational special location is always definite, but a
definite one is not always rational.
Table 1 shows the relation between orientation and special location in their various meanings. One-sided orientation need not lead
to a special location (Space 1) and special location does not neces" Techsarily presuppose one-sided orientation (Spaces 5, 6, 8-11).**
be indefinite
(as
means
profits
this remains uncertain (Space 8) unless costs (Space 2)
(Space 5) or extra-economic considerations (Space 10) are also taken
into acount with the exception of an unavoidable technical restricIn this case only will
tion at one single source of supply (Space 9)
but
43.
Transport orientation
duction
may be
is
44. For example, it does not follow from location in a market area that easy sales
determined the choice of this location in whole or even in part. In many other cases,
on the contrary, the location of consumers has a great influence on the choice of
location,
though
is
it
The
location of any particular coal mine, for instance, cannot be fully explained
coal.
fields in
have not attracted many industries nor are they worked to any great extent because of
of their unfavorable location. Although coal is widely distributed, coal mining is
rather concentrated.
tion
Hence
by raw material,"
is
" orientation by
" restric-
itself,
therefore,
it is
is
only
special location.
46.
The
do not employ,
is
this:
Special location
(a)
or (&)
or (d)
;
(c)
meanings that we
Chapter
As
The Theory
5.
far as industry
of Agricultural Location
concerned,
is
With
particular enterprise.
a.
These problems,
too,
especially joint
demand and
wage
supply, local
we
differences,^
shall
move
to
and
an
orientation that takes all factors into account. But here, too, as with
industrial location,
1.
we
shall
Preliminary Remarks
agricultural locations
enterprise
(Fig. 3)
1.
be the
site of
I,
36
33
Ordnung der
(1942)
337-373.
Landwirtschaft, Inter-
Agricultural Location
37
OD
is
Fig. 3.
let the other be more expenproduce but in return cheaper to ship (rich ore mined
The market area for the poor ore will therefore
underground)
extend from the mine to the distance OD, and only then will the
ring be reached within which it is cheaper to smelt the rich ore.^
sive to
are
now
is
purchased there
2.
Another example
is
which
cotton,
for
If
OA
is
a coal district,
the low price of electric current from a large power station erected in
and AB the loading costs of coal (i. e., costs independent of distance)
and
if
depend on
distance are lower for coal than for electricity, current will be transmitted in
vicinity
kelusu'lrtscliaft
to distant points.
(Berlin, 1934)
pp. 201
ff.
the
Part One.
38
at
O, and
AB
the
amount by which
Location
The
from
or
ship starch.
The same
figure,
on
still
another situation,
when
raised in the
OD
^.
Possible Cases
The
reasons
seen.
For
this
Independent Variables
k:
/:
Derived Variables
a
=A
TT
= p kf:
^ir a:
-^
R = rE = E {p kf) A:
m ^ p a: Highest profit
loss to
producer)
Agricultural Location
Table
39
2.
IN
Variables
Fulfill Condition
No. (m)
Crop Produced
Monoculture
Relative
Polyculture
i"^
o c
^2
Size
of
a
o
Variables
Uncon-
SomeAlways
times
Conditional
^v
Never
ditioned
Culti-
vated
Rings
together
6
E,
Ai
Pi
to
to
to
Eo
A^
P2
I
I
>
>
>
=
<
>
<
8
9
=
<
>
11
12
=
<
>
16
17
18
<
X
X
22
23
24
<
(m)
X
X
X
X
X
X
>
=
<
X
X
<
X
X
X
X
<
=
<
>
25
26
27
X
X
X
X
>
21
X
X
>
19
side
II
in-
in-
side
<
20
and II
by
side
side
1
X
X
=
<
>
13
14
15
X
X
X
X
X
>
10
<
or
II
X
X
X
>
II
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
Part One.
40
Table
tudes of the
first
Location
magni-
and
II.
Spatial Order
y.
We seek those cases where both crops are raised. Only then
does the problem of their spatial order arise. Both crops will be
grown when one yields a gieater rent per hectare at the center
of the area and the other at its periphery. The condition under
which I will yield a greater rent at the center than II is Ri > R..
This
yields:
First Condition:
< ^^'^^~^^
(I)
This
< |^
2
derived as follows:
is
R^ >R,.
substituting
0, this
becomes
Ei-pi-A:,>E2-p2- A^.
By dividing
this
becomes
Ez'
5.
This
is
p2 A2
derived as follows:
Ri
< R2.
By substitution we get
-A^<E^-{p^-kf) -A-
E^- (p.-kf)
But
at the periphery
Therefore
^1
ipi
p2 +
1^2 +
(Pi
E,pr
- E,p, +
E^p^-E,p,+
7-2
E^pr
a^ ^=
ao)
fiifla
?,
we
get:
E2
-^-A^<0
E^Az
A
^ E^p. -
iEiAz
= EJEspz
-A^<
T?
I,
,2
,2
Dividing by
{E.p.
A.) we
==
El
{E2P2
.2
get
E.p,-A,
^Ei
Aj
E2P2
j3
- A2)
(2)
Agricultural Locution
<jl
'^E,p,-A,^E,
First
(1)
we
and
establish for
(2)
be grown.
In 12 additional cases our assumption on the relative magnitudes
oi A, E, and p is not sufficient to decide between the different crops.
They leave it open whether only one or both together will be
planted. The latter will occur either when both conditions are
fulfilled or when neither is. This depends on the exact numerical
value of ^, , and p. If both conditions are fulfilled or if neither
one is, cases 10 and 18 differ from the remaining 10. Since in both
cases Ex/E^= 1, both conditions can never be met. On the other
hand, it has the same effect that for (pi p^
(a^ do)
both
conditions are unfulfilled at the same time.^ The cultivation of
both crops simultaneously is then possible as in the other 10 cases.
They can even be grown side by side in adjoining sectors within
the same ring instead of in successive rings only, as in the other
will
10 cases.
6.
(2)
To
can be
(pi
pz)
(a^-a^)
neither condition
,1
If
Ei{pi
= 2.
(1)
nor condition
fulfilled:
as
assumed
in cases 10 to 18,
therefore E^p^
it
,2
follows that
Ai = E^p^ A^.
Eipi
But condition
requires that
it
^2
(1)
^2)
Part One.
42
Location
more
side.
8.
upon
More Exact
Reasons.
distance, conditions
{p2
(1)
a^) <
{pi
a,) <
{p2
fla)
or
<
2^22
Since
m^
<
mg,
Thus crop
^iW^i
<
or
-1^12
jEimi
>
>
follows that Ei
2brings in the greater total profit
it
I
2^2
{Ej_mi)
but the
From this it
smaller profit per unit (mi)
yield 1 per unit of area is greater. The first inequality makes
certain that crop I is superior at the market; the second, that it
it
is
Derived as follows:
E2P2
since a
= A/E,
= aE;
A2
substituting in
ipi
(3)
E2
- aiEi
(3)
E^
^ E^(pi-aj)
2 (p2
E^^
*
- 2)
2(^2-0.) <i(pi-ai)
< 1(^2-^2)
same order)
Q.E.D.
(in
the
9.
A more
detailed analysis
would have
to take into
43
Asricultiiral Location
point
is
also varies with distance and with the possible freight. Near a
town, labor especially becomes more expensive and agricultural machines cheaper.
Let us sketch at least briefly the manner in which nominal agricultural wages
depend on distance from the market. Suppose that the amounts in the laborer's
budget are independent of price; that agricultural and industrial commodities can be
combined into a general commodity of which the amounts / and i are supposed to be
consumed per year. Let / be the freight per unit of quantity and distance, and pi
or pi the unit price in the town; suppose finally that the real wage is the same
/
a constant)
everywhere (/J
= + =
How
(a) ?
Na
= l(p,-af) + i{pi
-\-
af)
Whether
these, Ipi and ipi are constants, whereas af{il) depends on
the nominal wage will decrease or increase with distance from the town will therefore
depend upon whether a greater weight of agricultural or of industrial goods is
Of
distance.
consumed.
Even today agricultural goods are likely to preponderate. The urban annual consumption per capita is roughly 500 kg. of food and 400 kg. of coal. The rural laborer
receives by way of the town perhaps 60 kg. of industrial goods and 80 kg. of food (in
the country potatoes, milk, flour, and meat make up three fourths of all foodstuffs)
He uses less coal than the town dweller because he burns wood, and besides coal does
not always reach the country from a town. Thus one can count on only about 140 kg.
of urban products as against 420 kg. of rural products. Much depends upon fuel.
A second reason why agricultural wages decrease with distance from a town is that
house rents are lower because the ground
agricultural rent
itself is
cheaper
(as
third reason
is
population, which often increases with distance from the town, together with the
incomplete mobility of this surplus. Fourth, the agricultural laborer saves transport
cost and local taxes, since local services can safely be lower. In the fifth place, he has
more incidental and intangible income (land for gardening, the possibility of breeding
small animals, and a more natural way of life)
Sixth, he buys some things from
.
farmers at lower
cost.
still
example)
On the other hand, the migration of the abler inhabitants to towns,
where they can specialize according to their particular gifts, does not explain a real
difference in eSiciency wages as between town and country, though it does explain such
a differential among country dwellers in favor of the skilled trades.
for
11.
The
also:
The
total freight
is
proportional
for crop I
words:
The
is
less
gross profit
<
on crop
is
Hence
its physical yield, which influences the cost of transportation.
same distance the latter makes up a greater percentage of the gross profit for
crop I, and this difference in percentages increases with distance. The originality
greater net profit for I, therefore, shrinks more quickly with increasing freight costs
and finally drops below that for crop II.
centage than
for the
Part One.
44
2.
i?i ==
Location
R2, or
Hence
^- E,p,-E,p^-\-A,-A,
f(E,-E,)
or
/ E^mx
Eomz Y
The
distance k of the transition from the center is directly proportional to the difference in gross profits before deduction of freight
charges,
kf
If
{E^m^
to
the equation
is
written as
2^2) / (1 E2)
and the
and above production costs)
(over
per centner Thus every production spreads out until at the edge
of its ring the rising marginal cost curve intersects the marginal
revenue curve.
This differs from the usual discussion of marginal adjustments
individual firm only in that in the latter case marginal cost
an
of
refers to production, whereas here it refers to transport cost. The
two problems of the amount and the location of production are
thereby solved simultaneously. If rings I and II represent areas of
intensive and extensive cultivation of the same commodity, between
which no transition
is
dis-
This
is
reached as follows:
2^2
as a -
A/E, A
= aE;
- ipi + A^-A^
therefore
ft
_ :^2p2 ~ -^iPi +
'^i^i
~ '^^^
f{E,-E,)
E^ip.
substitiiting
we
m=
(p
~ a)
a^)
-E^{pi-a^)
E,-E,
1)
get
ft
(E.m,-E.mA
1
.
\Ei Et
^ p
_^
S.
Agricultural Location
45
of
is,
ment
I.
Cheap Product
II.
Dear Product
Fig. 4.
demand
and
for a cheap
for
on the
an
expensive product
if
und
14.
The
commodity
(I)
(II)
to almost nothing,
If
kf,
in Figure 4
reduces the
whereas
hardly
it
is
" bear
the
demand
for the
is
more expensive
cheaper one
Example: Corn
is
intensive cultivation
Riihl,
grown near the River Plate and wheat farther away, not
its yield per hectare with an appropriately
smaller (contrary to the otherwise excellent discussion by A.
is
Das Standortproblem
The
specific gravity of
goods
is
is
decisive.
On
a par with
it
the town
and
Or, which amounts to the same thing, reduction by drying, cleaning, butchering,
so on.
In wartime,
when
transportation
is
difficult,
this concentration
is
carried
Location
Part One.
^6
An Example
of
ThiXnen Rings
market
price, p, rise.
This
case 9 in
Table
2,
acre,
and
that
it
A, and
will be
a relatively small
Weight
is decreased by:
(1) Eliminating everything superfluous or less important;
shipping powdered instead of fluid milk; fruit juices instead of fruit; with rising
freight rates frozen meat rather than iced, then meat with bones removed, later canned,
e. g.,
(2)
Further processing
(bacon instead of corn; dried eggs instead of barley; butter fat instead of
oil crops)
also.
This diminution in the bulk of the same commodity in areas far removed from
is, as Englander rightly said [Theorie des Giiterverkehrs und der Frachtsdtze [Jena, 1924], p. 118), only a special case of decrease of the yield in weight per
their markets
unit of area away from the market, except that the one case concerns different kinds
ri commodities
different
A. Petersen
is
prises
correctly deduces
from
und was
sie
wirk-
(such as distilleries, dairies, sugar refineries, plants for the manufacture of starch
and the preserving and canning of food, and grain mills) may have a wholly rational
location in East Prussia, though they are far from their markets. He errs, however, in
believing that the compatibility of such intensity at a distance from the market with
the Thiinen theory had been overlooked until then. Adam Smith had already shown
that the two-fold freight charge causing low agricultural and high industrial prices
is conducive to industrial development in remote areas.
The industries employ the
heavy products of the soil cheaply on the spot and in return ship a smaller weight in
low-quality goods to markets nearby, and a smaller weight in high quality goods to
more distant markets. {An Inquiry into the Nature and the Causes of the Wealth of
Nations [London, "1811], Book 3, end of Chapter 3, where also there are interesting
observations on the dynamics of location.) A large increase in population strengthens,
whereas the scarcity of capital associated therewith checks, this tendency toward
industrialization. Example: Balkan States (see A. Losch, Was ist vom Geburtenriickgang zu halten? [Heidenheim, 1932])
17.
separate products.
as
47
AgiicnUural l.ocaliun
E
Yield per hectare
Milk
(pfennigs)
(pfennigs)
(kg.)
25
p
Market price
250
20
II
Cream
2.5
300
160
III
Butter
350
380
hence
fl,
10;
= A/E
a2=I20;
As
= 350
m== p a
hence
mi
ma
== 10;
^ 40;
II
and
and
and
* II
is
II:
III:
III:
mg
^^
between
<
30 <
30 <
100
<
250 <
100 >
250
1000: Fulfilled
750: Fulfilled
75:
Not met
III.
The producer
= 30
because of the
of milk
difficulties of
>
40
f.,
pp. 30-33.
where
been developed.W. H.
W.
Part One.
Boundary
line
between
and
E,-E,
/V
Location
III at kilometers
250 - 30
24
)-0.\
= 92
at distance k
= -
^-^
j=
pressing
cases
Interregional Trade
t,.
Of course
this relative
may be
from
rising, the
The
single
when
the price
is
depressed in this way; it falls to zero (with dismore rapidly decreasing rent on
is
enough
to
as foreign competition,
22. i?,
>
i?3;
77>21.
E, (p,
49
Agricultin-al Location
'
from far away toward the market; at first it will not be able to
compete despite its own low costs, because of high freight rates.
"^^Xi^.'^
\
\
miles
Cream [
Bulterarea
L* .-i-
t^
Domestic
Fig. 5.
Foreign
as a function of distance
Moved
rates.
For example, the quantities of Canadian exports to the United States increase
and
cheese.
Location
Part One.
50
The
rf.
Spatial
Order
of Production Systems
Coslper acre
Fig. 6.
and
But
if
24.
Here we can equate the inner ring to intensive, and the outer
meanings previously mentioned), since
among
rings to extensive,
case 2
and
case 26
= p^.
In both cases the outlay and the yield per hectare are gieater in the irtner ring, and
a moment's
alternatives
E1/E2
< A1/A2,
that
is,
commodity
if
intensity
or commodity II
is
is
is
rotation of crops
(D)
(if
a^
the
> aal
fulfilled too.
{K)
.
the
for case 2,
place of
if,
25.
(in
cultivated)
in the vicinity of a
Thus
his
market
numerical example
5^
Agricultural Location
0.
Consumption
not grouped about one center of consumption as has been assumed up to now, but about several, these select
their own sources of supply from the environment of the foremost
The rings under
producer if they are near enough (see Fig. 45)
region of many
in
a
discussion form around each new center, but
towns there is no room for the outer ones; they are displaced
toward its margin. The number of displaced rings increases with
When
production
is
the density of towns. For the inner rings the individual town is
the marketing center, for the outer ones the agglomeration of towns.
Thus with the growth of northwestern Europe more and more
ment,
first
recently by H. Backe.^^
must
with
fulfill
compared
to
(p.
is
in the
1| taler: 1,818
40.)
In fact
>
1,119)
market (1,818/1,710
<
is
(Thiinen: op.
cit.,
p.
121, 14a)
>
1,000)
the profit
1,119/1,000)
would be proportional
example would generally hold also
Since according to
this
for a
(which
as a whole.
Historical significance:
Thunen
is
market; just as List showed, in opposition to the classical writers, that free trade
profitable onjy
proved the temporally limited validity of the English theories of the time, so
is
as List
Thunen
Exceptions are explained by the fact that besides location, which has been the
sole basis of
and
freights)
reality:
,
duties
freight rates
new
situations,
and
so on.
27. See G.
I,
33
Ordnung der
(1942)
345
Landwirtschaft,"
fF.
Part One.
52
2.
Location
Technique
of Presentation
mi
<
.
<
ruz
6 and
out from a price limit pi
per hundredweight. This is the lower limit for potatoes,
for if the price sank below half that for corn no more potatoes
would be raised. At these prices there should be a demand for
exactly twice as many hundredweight of potatoes as of corn, so
that the area devoted to both will be the same.
In order to simplify Figures 7b and 7d, the demand curves have
the same slope, which involves a greater elasticity of the demand
for potatoes. The example is further clarified if the market is
regarded as a line rather than a point (like a river valley with many
Then the rings become zones, and the demand is proportowns)
tional to their breadth. We also assume hereand this will turn
out to be significant that the commodity with the higher yield per
hectare (potatoes) will be cultivated in the zone nearest the market.
This will be true, as we have seen, if rings are formed at all. Again,
the production of each commodity considered alone is supposed to
be in equilibrium; that is to say, neither potatoes nor corn yields
a rent at their respective margins of cultivation.
As for the technique of presentation, it should be noted that
the scale employed for the quantity of corn is twice that for the
quantity of potatoes, and that it is to be reckoned from the actual
boundary between I and II, whereas the town line is always the
p2 = 12
Thus, in contradistinction
shift
and the
be directly compared.
aerial
The
53
Agricultural Location
n
10
i
s
5
V -
rs^ Tn
Potatoes
Corn
Wp\
0'
1
SO
[100
M
N/
"^\
^
Fig. 7.
Xvw
Thiinen case
Thiinen rings
'
of potatoes (l)](7
0'
A'
'
Centners
K,
>^-->Y"
^^1
^^/
^,y^
J --y^
7
^^K
/?;
^^''^
b)
V;
XTr\
N^/
r-A.
r
'^^op
Part One.
r
54
I
Localio)i
now immediately
formation are
tion in
tti
gives 9.5
II
and
now
<
> 7.5 >
fulfilled
po/2 gives 2
rising for
5.75)
I.
<
(fli
The
When
= 2;
pi
= 11.5;
=1.5; p2
p^/l
on a hundredweight
the profit
substitu-
ai> pi>
3.75; substitution in p2
of potatoes
RoSz/t)
equal to half that on the same amount of corn (i?iSi
The cultivation of
final equilibrium will have been reached.
potatoes is then diminished by the area A'B'BA, total cultivation
by the smaller area C'D'DC. So far everything agrees with Thiinen's
is
theory,
case has
been so extensively
dis-
jg.
We
shall
Inversion of Rings
single assumption.
We
shall
suppose
fields
boundary
line
AB
(Fig. 8c)
now
superior
as
equilibrium really
at the
is
decided at the
boundary
as a function of
Agricultural Location
55
boundary. But according to Figure 8e, on the contrary,^" the boundary line thus found marks also the boundary between potatoes and
corn; only it appears (this boundary being assumed as given) that
at least for the moment it will be more advantageous to plant the
other crop at every point away from the boundary. To the left of
the dividing line the cultivation of potatoes, not corn, will yield
the greater rent per hectare; the reverse is true to the right of the
line.
y.
The
Fig.
9)
The
Critical
Assumption
z/'
ti
la
and
case
Fig. 9.
Ila
from
8e.
8a; le
arbitrarily,
30.
Figures le and 8e show the rent per hectare as a function of distance from a
when the position of the boundary is given.
market,
31. la
8a; \e
and
lie
from Figure
8e.
Part One.
56
Location
that would
hold,
would
mean disequilibrium.
would
prices
right,
toward
the
shift
the boundary would have to
fall, and, most important, all rents would decrease below the amount
that had induced the farmers to change. Nor would the new situalarger rent was promised for the
Now
moment. Obviously
The
all.
!!
Centners
Potatoes ^
C.
Corn
Die-hards
Fig. 11.
Potato market
hards, B'F)
Fig. 12.
Fig. 13.
EB')
loss
completion of the change (from Figure 7e) and the broken line
shows the rent that prevailed before the revolutionary change (from
Figure 8e)
All farmers between E and 7^ sociologically speaking,
the whole rural middle class or, more accurately, the entire region
of moderate ground rentwill have lost rent (hatched area in Figure
Only a few of the richest farmers (between and E) and the
10)
rural proletariat, and only on the soil at and beyond the boundary
(between F and H) ^^ will have gained.
Will the farmers between E and F, interested in preserving the
traditional order, be able to obstruct the revolutionary method of
planting by ^obstinately continuing to cultivate the original crop,
giving up a merely transitory advantage in order to acquire greater
rent in the end? The change to potatoes, profitable under all cir;
32.
is
more
Agricultural Location
57
cumstances between
and , and
to
corn between
F and H,
so
lowers the price of both that the rents of the obstinate ones fall.
Thanks to their better location, the rent of the innovators is larger
in the end.^*
Thus we
dynamic economy
3.
manner
33.
The new
13.
It
is
E and F
is
crops.
is
no
rent
34.
land
is
cultivated.
cases only
between
desirable.
It
possible exception
is
G and
B'
(Fig. 10)
and less
commodity of greater
yield per acre, but lower price, pays considerably less freight per mile.
36. In this case the fields are not only of different width, which would not be bad,
but also of different length. Only when the crop with the smaller yield per acre (com)
is cultivated farther out can its rent by the hundredweight at market be greater than
the corresponding rent for potatoes. And only when the rent per hundredweight on
corn
is
greater
for potatoes.
is
the rent per acre, because of the smaller yield per acre, equal to that
Part One.
58
1.
With equal
a subcase to No.
2.
When
when
and 18
of
Table
2,
because
get
= E2,
on the production
restriction
Location
lines of
soil (2)
Fig. 14.
Illustration of case
18 of the
Fig. 15.
rings
complete system
37. In
First, let
fields
GH. Both fields then acquire automatically the same boundary, A'B'.
(However, the length of the fields can now no longer be read off automatically from
the supply curves K^' and K2, as was still possible with Kt^ and K^. To this end it is
equal to rent
field lengths.)
demand
curves,
/,
on
K^',
and
Agricultural Location
rings
outward
parallel
sectors,
to
we
For
zones.
59
these
still
lines.
it
4.
There
still
presentation)
where a
is
of
uneven
quality.^^
Of course
in those
(rings)
2,
(b)
It is
on the
better
say, of
AB
ABDC
is
ML
38.
Any
local variation in
effects similar
Location
Part One.
6o
the better soil toward the left until at the new limit, A'B', the same
rent per hectare ensues for both crops because of the reduced
cultivation of potatoes. Calculated per centner, the potato rent is
only half that for corn, because the yield of potatoes per hectare
is twice as large. This shift raises the supply of corn by the yield
of the area A'B'BA, and the greater supply so lowers the price that
the outermost limit of cultivation
is
to
COMPREHENSIVE SOLUTION
b.
We
so far
1.
The
40.
By a somewhat
hatched.
is
Brinkmann,
near a town
extensively
is
possible
(radial differentiation)
(concentric differentiation)
("
31)
Only
to
this
the question
is
extent:
as
Upon
no longer one
minimum
exact consideration
of locating the
short as possible;
upon
for
(in
to
p.
29,
note
to fields for
transport cost)
contrast
6^
Agricultural Location
a whole. There
is
room
it fits
to plant
his
farm
consideration)
note 46.
Total profits alone are decisive; there are no additional criteria
for individual crops. Even the production system {Betriebssystem)
that would be most advantageous for the farm cannot be scientifically unequivocal, as a rule,*^ but can be determined only after
experimentation; even then uncertainty would still remain, since
innumerable combinations are possible and the choice among them
depends in general upon irregular local relationships between supply
and demand. Nevertheless, science can still be of service, as it is
in the case of the industries.
The
The
such yields a
maximum
system favorable to
it
profit,
that excludes
Part One.
62
2.
Localioji
of a Location
it,
duction, by what will yield the most profit to the farm as a whole.
The same end will naturally be sought when plans for the use of
These plans themselves
its fields have to be formulated anew.
depend upon market prices of location and supplies, and the composition and scale of output; upon the relative position of the
various fields to the farm,^^ and of the farm itself to the sales market
and to markets for the factors of production; upon the suitability
of soil and climate, and not least upon the skill of the farmer; upon
the advantages of mass production to the individual farm and to
other farms (thus also upon what is cultivated by other farms in
and, finally, upon the disadvantages of onethe neighborhood)
;
It
may, of
impossible
situations
44.
That
facilitates
*^
this
is
if
single product
Marquardt
in
This appears
the combination.
presentation
to
most
ff.)
few other
factors.
Its
further
Agricultural Location
63
c.
1.
One
certain
of the
main
industrial
neglected,
is
comparison where
resembling the agricultural can be
that in agriculture the number of production
situations
the fact
number
tion.
is
Hence
cultural,
industry
in agriculture producers
enterprises.
is
has
it
on the
less,
size of
48.
irregularly pro-
field in
order to see
how
is
Part One.
64
cost
costs.
point
if
ground rent
is
Location
included in the
desirable. ^^
Fig. 16.
Size of the
producing unit in
a) industry,
b) agriculture
49.
Neither excludes an optimal supply for the consumer, however, since the higher
costs may be more than compensated in the first case by savings in freight
production
To
This
is
is
easy to understand.
OB
In Figure 16b
let
TB
The
line,
expand
beyond O to B, at the intersection of the marginal cost curve with the price
But rent, TUOB, is a cost factor, appearing either as actual rent paid or as
interest on the value of the land. Hence by its nature rent is not a differential but
a price (see J. A. Schumpeter, " Das Rentenprinzip in der Verteilungslehre," Schmollers
The customary presentation, which makes it appear as a
Jahrhuch, XXXI [1907])
at first
line.
residual,
is
amount
For nonagricultural uses there are other values, and still others for the
rest of the land, and the price of land for industry as well as agriculture is derived
from this competition of uses. Suppose this system to be such that a farmer obtains
the area in question because he offers the most for it; then his cost curve must be
for the land.
shifted
new
upward by the rent, whose total amount is fixed. B is the low point on the
no other amount of production can support such a high rent. Chamused this new cost curve, K2, to whose minimum point the demand curve is
curve, for
berlin
first.
He
is
given
from the beginning. Thus we find tangency of cost and demand curves a criterion of
equilibrium in both branches of the economy.
51. A farm aiming at the minimum size necessary to its existence could add land
as long as there were still larger farms (unless their size depended upon the special
ability of their managers) merely because it produced larger rent and therefore could
offer a higher rental or a higher price. Hence it would buy from neighboring farms
the fields that were less favorably situated for them than for it.
,
Agricultural Location
The
65
limitation works in a
downward
direction also:
Even where
52.
The
effects of a financial
and a
real division
dis-
The
other farms.
evils
to
co-operative spirit) are therefore not necessarily associated with real division. Trouble
will arise, however,
if
it
is
to be
who
remem-
make
This
variable at
the
is
all,
optimum
size of
necessarily true:
When
technical development
On
is
not
not increase.
The
poultry.
See Priebe,
should vanish!
Location
Part One.
56
size,
minimum
to the
producers)
To return to the geometrical picture once more: As intruding
competitors in industry restrict the sales area to a point where the
demand curve shifts toward the left until it is tangent to the cost
curve, so in agriculture they restrict areas of production until the
upward and
by addition of the
curve. This is
the counterpart of the process described by Chamberlin and Robinson.^^ The only difference is that in industry, depending on the
competitive situation, the cost curve is given and the demand curve
variable, whereas in agriculture price is fixed and costs are variable.
In either case, however, the variable curve is shifted for the same
reason and with the same result, until it is tangent to the fixed
curve. In short, we find in both industry and agriculture the two
important forces that oppose one another and determine location:
a tendency to maximization of the number of producers and maximization of rent.^ The latter is well known. It remains to sketch
cost curve, displaced
ground
rent,
to the left
is
demand
2.
production
falls as
i.
e.,
The
Then
is
rises;
its
reached
more than
income is reached, for the rent could still increase if this were too high, and would
have to fall if it were too low.
56. Even when a few other differences between agriculture and industry are
examined (as in the first edition, page 55) they turn out to be of little weight, so
that in both cases the problem of location is in all essentials the same, in spite of the
different competitive situation and a few differences in degree.
,
Agricultural Locatiu7i
67
we
find periods in
new
invest-
And
finally,
when
self-confidence
of per-
more
and increasingly
government security. After such periods, when
between economic lords and serfs are open only in the
the barriers
downward
direction, confidence returns again; social tension inEconomically, too, men wish to live by their own wills
creases.
57.
Even poor
best qualified
(H.
districts often
Rohm,
"
XXVI
[1940], 430)
59 At the margin where men hesitated between dependent and independent occuincome was higher in this or that case according to whether the man was
pations, an
Chapter
A
tions.
town
is
6.
Site
(1)
a.
1.
The
perfectly
would lead
at
some
j8.
1.
In some places a
number
demand
for each
one
Reasons for
Town
69
Settlement
and
so on)
2.
.^
Production may also gravitate to one place because it is technically tied to an important source of the raw materials and intermediate products that it uses; or because it is technically tied to
consumers, as is the case with craftsmen or merchants, for example.
Or it may simply be attracted by a large labor market, a considerable
local demand, contact with government agencies, traffic junctions, or
the proximity of other towns. Such advantages, which are limited
to a few places, occur also with natural uniformity, as we shall see
later in the model of a simple system of economic areas. Locations
like these are especially rare and at the same time especially favored
The fewer possible
in systems of equal structure (see pp. 130 ff.)
market areas we assume, the larger becomes the number of goods
whose markets around their possible locations is greater than is
.
firm.
INTERNAL COMPETITION
1.
al.,
Mono-
Part One.
70
Location
among
Amount
Fig. 17.
its
appear.
Is
demand
curves?
still
valid for
all,
or will
more competitors there are, the flatter each partial demand curve
becomes; that is, the more sharply demand reacts on each price
change of a single firm. We are aproaching pure competition and
shall have reached it when the partial demand curves become so
flat that,
its
goods at a
little
Reasons for
Town
7^
Settlement
shows
(^1
rest solely
one another.
might be expected that each entrepreneur would pay every factor
of production according to its marginal product, and that this output would be the
same whether the last unit of the factor were employed by the marginal entrepreneur
or by a superior one. What more the latter was able to extract from it would have
partial
4.
to
demand
Theoretically
it
size of
the firm.
Where
the marginal worker (as seen by the individual firm) could be distinguished from other
all would have to be paid according to output, unless their greater output
was due to their own skill rather than to their position in the factory. In so far as
the former is true, it should make no difference, therefore, whether a good or a poor
worker was employed, since each would be paid according to his productivity. In
reality, the better enterpreneurs secure the better workers as well the better sites and
workers,
pay them higher wages than they could get from the marginal entrepreneurs. The
reason is that these workers need less supervision because of their personal charac-
teristics,
time (indirect
efficiency)
and quantitative
less
so that
Location
Part One.
72
now
The
total cost
curve
is
market price
rise slowly.
jumps of the aggregate supply curve show that a new factory has
become able to compete. The smaller these jumps, that is, the
smaller the
optimum
size of a firm in
The
all
portions of curves
minimum
within the relevant price intervals. From this it follows that every
producer, after having entered the total supply curve, is represented
in every portion of
it.
If all
efficient
This would
the supply curve would necessarily be horizontal (As)
exclude special profit and would correspond to tangency in the
Chamberlin process. The agglomeration of factories would then be
still greater; first, because the size of each would be less; second,
because at the lower price the demand from the original market
area would be greater; and third, because the area itself would be
enlarged. The last two effects have been taken into account in our
.
demand
curve.^
4.
own
Under
is
fixed.
which
minimize freight
competitor finds
5.
On
minimum
desirable location of
total length of
is
cost
it
al.,
Monoindus-
6.
Reasons for
Town
Settlement
The
73
'
are that
first
it is
valid only
group of objections
First, it is
hardly likely
that one duopolist will assume that his rival will not react to his
actions. As soon as this assumption is dropped we find, as
Palander has shown, " a pronounced tendency toward deglomeration." ^ If, for example, both duopolists act alike, the optimal
location for each is one sixth of the length of the whole stretch
from each end. Here is a second improbability: Why should the
two duopolists act differently if all circumstances confronting them
are identical for both? It is true that the more symmetrically the
competitors are located along our stretch, the greater will be the
own
long as they are located symmetrically. (Hotelling himself consymmetry merely " improbable," without excluding it by his
assumptions.)
The result is valid only if both rivals assume in their price policy
that they have to share the market. But this assumes a great lack
of foresight and this is the third improbability of their behavior.
Palander ^ shows that the interaction of two possible behavior pat-
as
siders
7. The mathematics will be found in Hotelling, op. cit., and in even more general
form in Tord Palander, Beitrdge zur Standortstheorie (Uppsala, 1935) pp. 232-235.
,
8.
Palander, op.
9.
Op.
cit.,
cit.,
pp. 237
ff.
p. 394.
Part One.
74
Location
terns will lead to continuous price fluctuations, and this is true even
when the firms are still fairly distant from each other, but is certainly
when
true
their distance
with the aggressor, the duopolist attacked will find it more profitable
after a certain distance to lower his price and thus either crowd the
aggressor out of the market entirely or force him to lower his price.
Hotelling does not consider this possible behavior. Such a price
reduction means that the rivals will move farthest apart, until the
The
second group of objections is directed against unlikely circumstances. First, Hotelling assumes a completely inelastic demand,
which is a rare case. Hotelling told me he would agree that with an
elastic demand there would be a tendency for the rivals to move
into the neighborhood of the quarter points. I would go even
farther: In the case of
an
elastic
demands and
The
demand an
profit possibilities.
if
are
assumed. Hotelling might salvage his argument for several competitors by abandoning the line for an area. On the other hand, for
the line and this is true also for a larger area Chamberlin shows
that more than two producers would spread out even under Hotelling's own assumptions.^" The intermediate producers are all equally
spaced from each other. If one of them moved nearer to his righthand neighbor, for example, he would lose as much area to his lefthand competitors as he gains from the one on his right. Nevertheless,
Chamberlin overlooks the fact that such an asymmetry might be
profitable for him if it were an equilibrium position. But equilibrium exists now only if the rivals are equidistant. However, even
independent of any considerations of equilibrium Chamberlin is
correct: It is impossible that more than two entrepreneurs approach
10. E.
1936)
pp. 194-196.
Reasons for
Town
75
Settlement
each other. A third producer who was located between them would
always gain by jumping over either his rival to the right or his rival
to the left. Only the producers at the ends of the stretch have an
area one and a half times as great as that of the others. As long as
they remain on the interior third point of the end portion of the
stretch, none of the rivals has any incentive to jump over them and
become an end man. To this extent one might speak of a tendency
But even
this
of
y.
4.
to producers in the
n. There
costs.
is
The growth
Pa'>'t
1^6
One.
Location
labor market.
situation:
It
is
advantageous for a
do
not coincide. Of course this alleviates not these fluctuations themselves, but their reinforcing secondary effects on enterprises that are
directly concerned, such as local handicrafts and business.
Fourth, more general reasons: The ablest members of all proand trades which are not tied down to particular places,
who therefore can live where they wish and are in general the
bearers of a conscious cultural tradition, tend to attract one another
and thus increase their achievements and their enjoyment of life.
fessions
and
of the expensive supply installations of suburban settlements, but also through the
common
12.
13.
14.
This
is
I 5.
spread out
to tax
it
would
land speculation
external economies.
(1922)
pp. 131
f.
mine, and occupations that are determined by, location. In a rough classification the
former generally include agriculture, mining, and some manufactures; the latter
Reasons for
Town
Settlement
77
or larger firms, and partly in the fact that only thus does there
arise a sufficiently large
demand
for
many
has two causes, the size of the urban population and of the
demand
demand
times what
will
it
2.
The
Chance Agglomeration
may
show
that location
when
they derive no
advantage at all from one another; when from their standpoint the
coincidence is merely fortuitous. Seen from the standpoint of the
regional system this agglomeration has three important causes: (1)
orientation by a capital city, (2) orientation by main roads, (3) the
of different enterprises
coincide even
tionships,
which
rest
on the
rela-
settlements, are such that only compartively few places offer possible
include their followers: handicrafts, service, trades, etc. But this is a very rough
approximation only, which neglects reactions on allegedly independent locations.
Nevertheless it is useful in planning the development of new areas.
15. This plays an important role, also, in the development of a downtown district
(a " city ")
which in general arises for essentially the same reasons as do towns and
,
Part One.
78
locations
for
industrial
enterprises,
Location
independently of one
another.
8.
^^
Summary
Even though the earth were a smooth and uniform sphere towns
would still arise for numerous reasons. These agglomerations of
locations
would be
partly fortuitous,
when
well,
of
number and
association
include those of
in
site
the
as
Reasons for
2.
Town
79
Settlement
We
system favored places do not appear until a location has been determined, whereas here intrinsic sources of supply are present first.
In general such sources of supply limit the number of possible
locations for a particular industry, but increase
natural system
It
is
made more
might be thought
factors.
is
it
so
difficult.
is
one of the
all
historical
the advantages of a
Part One.
go
the price.
still
But Part
III will
show
Location
may
be advisable.
b.
1.
He who
a.
The problem
on the exact
site of
on the location of
all
But the
the other
A somewhat more
fore,
combination of the other locations, and then choosing that site for
the town in whose neighborhood most optimum locations (interdependence having been considered) are situated. Even this state18.
centers,
and the
like.
fortresses,
administrative or religious
Reasons for
Town
81
Settlenieyit
would
still
Special Cases
is
the location of a
More
20.
1934)
and elsewhere.
Part One.
82
Location
harbor and the rock foundation for skyscrapers, nor by its closer
proximity to American and West European industrial areas than
any of the more southerly ports, nor by its situation at the terminus
of the Erie Canal and of many railroads, etc., but by the advantages
of numbers.
Consider first a few examples of cities whose existence seems to
have been determined to a high degree by their location. The
centers of states or of natural basins often have the advantage of
being optimum transport points in a region that cannot easily be
reduced by outside competition because it is protected by natural
or artificial tariff walls. Such points are ideal locations for consumption-oriented industries ^^ with an extended sales radius.
Leipzig, for example, possesses this advantage in double measure:
It is the approximate center of the basin that is bounded by the
Erzgebirge range, the Thuringian Mountains, and the Harz Mountains, all about sixty miles distant. It is also the central city of
Germany; almost all of Germany lies within two hundred and fifty
miles of Leipzig, or a comfortable day's journey, and conversely,
nearly the entire area within that radius is German. A third advan-
tage of
its
location
is
Upper
Silesia-Ruhr,
On
is,
in
to consumers is important.
see F. Ratzel. " Die geographische
damming
of
traffic
II, 446.
Town
Reasons for
83
Settlement
location
than
is
restricted
by a source of supply.
planted
wood
much weight
in smelting
still
to
More important
all
sources of coal, a
in production.
coal,^*
and
the large cities are concentrated in the coal districts, or the highly
urbanized zone stretching from the coal of northern France and
Belgium across the Ruhr and the lignite region through Upper
all
Silesia and far on into Poland.^^ Examples of source-oriented consumption are health resorts, many university towns, religious shrines,
and capitals.
But not much is proved by such examples. Dependence on source
does not mean unconditional restriction to a source, still less to one
particular source; for competing sources and other factors which
affect town formation become relevant. Neither does it mean that
all of the industries of a town are confined to this one source. Some
are tied to the source of supply, since they depend in turn upon
The
forces that
its
seat there.
site of a
24. Improvements in the technique of smelting have undermined this rule however,
because the amount of coal required per unit of iron has been reduced. Furthermore,
ore deposits have become more and more powerful locational attractions, as ores with
less
and
25.
less
The
concentration of towns in
rail
distance rates for coal were one of the most important factors in location and, indeed,
in the decentralization of former times. Electricity, too, which is cheaper to transport
effect.
Part One.
8^
2.
The System
As towns are
of
Location
Town Locations
economic
is
Chapter
We
Site
7.
shall limit
and Cause
of Belt
Formation
a.
Advantages of Specialization
Consider the cotton belt, the corn belt, the wheat belt, and so
in the United States. These belts produce mainly the crop
question; or, which is not the same thing, most of the crop in ques-
on
tion
is
produced
there.
Belts are
site,
source,
Chapter
5.
Among the
Differences in climate
and
(1922)
Okonomik
des land-
Sec. 7, p. 91.
1933)
p. 202.
Fart One.
86
Location
Fig.
in dollars
18.
a)
e)
g) profit
The
The
in dollars
cost, in dollars
and 2
respectively.
is
the advantage
3.
If
product
on
soils
We
the situation
would suggest
p. 252.
4.
is
costs.
The
On
pp. 87
f.
Belt.
Formation
87
area for cotton gins and presses would have to be considered because
of the small return in raw material per unit of area. Thus much
higher freight costs would result. The whole sales organization
would be more diffuse and less fully used. No single port in the
country would ship enough bales to make profitable the loading
machinery and efficient export presses that now exist in the two
southern ports specializing in the shipment of cotton.
Similarly, every other belt has its centers: commodity exchanges,
transshipment points, collecting stations, sales markets, research institutes, and so on. Other things being equal, profits decrease with
distance from these centers, either because all shipments pass through
them, or because with increasing distance their facilities can be
enjoyed only with correspondingly greater difficulty. Thus production crowds around these centers,^ whose existence may even
depend on
this crowding.*'
for crop 2.
gi^
product
5.
2,
This
is
For product 1, the second curve lies below the first; for
above it. The profits per hectare are now equal at distrue of small enterprises, which
especially
This would be represented graphically in such a way that with scattered pro-
duction the
demand curve
the
demand curve
will
it.
As soon
as
production
it
is
its
its
cost
Location
Part One.
88
tance
OB, and B
between
necessarily lies
A and
C.
The
area for
cultivation of the second product will not include the entire area,
which is
market than
especially suited to
II,
it
could
Crop
Fig. 19.
if
yet
it,
it
will
push nearer
to the
soil
quality
and distance
Disadvantages of Specialization
2.
There
specializing in
difficult subject
7.
Hence the
suitability of a location
on
less
is
(producer's price)
suitable
soil.
decided not by
site
With an adequate
summary
good example
is
from
(quality of soil)
alone,
conifer plantations at the expense of deciduous trees since the rise of industrialization.
Fir quickly produces the desired timber,
new
We
fact
et.
make
it
shift
point
B somewhat
coincide with C.
vicinity of a town.
89
Belt Formation
present purpose.
The
following presentation
is
of F.
The
to increasing specialization.
The
diversification
appear at
and
may
but
will
but
eco-
yield
an additional
profit.
Sozialokonomik, 1922)
10. See p. 88, note
11.
8.
is
possible.
Part One.
90
Finally,
it
specialization
may be concluded
of belts, never-
Location
bear.
which may be
by industrial districts, has essentially the same causes that
we have already encountered so frequently; the advantages of site
and source of supplies, of scale and association. The advantages of site
brings about industrial agglomerations independently of all natural
inequalities. Even in the ideal economic district, as will be seen
The
illustrated
later,
the
main
lines of
In the actual
As
all,
the weight of coal does not appear in the finished product, coal
coal regions.
may
attract industry,
good location
for a dense
Thus
the northerly
13.
"
12. J.
Mitteilungen,
LXXXVII
Belt Formation
The
91
advantages of
the
more do
size
The more
wise obvious.
and
because of the cost of land, transportation, and labor are often merely
sprawling cities. But just as we found it impossible to offer more
than a very general formula for a system of agricultural enterprises,
so one should not expect a demonstration of how the location of
industrial areas must necessarily be determined. There are usually
plausible reasons in favor of certain regions, of course, and the
better
tain
we know
it is
that
none of the
be overlooked.
and
more
cer-
Chapter
8.
The Problem
200
Alfred
ff.)
He
more influencing
like
or,
to
Predohl
XXI
("
the
as
Das Standortproblem in
the systems of
[1925], 304)
equations that determine the prices and distribution of production factors with respect
to
(" Preis-
But
locations.
all
and
of
all
less
units,
is
smaller, as in
Predohl
treats actually
one
only the
as given
from
first.
convincing.
But such
reflections
belief in the
fundamental impor-
93
man must
is
neglected.
The few
4.
The
was laid
interest
when
to
at first
space
is
seriously considered.
Part One.
94
a.
Location
This
as seen
trial struggle
way
The
within.
market
disappears.
We
and consumers,
for agriculture as
well as for industry, and develop the pertinent equations briefly for
the latter (Tables 3
and
The
4)
.^
1:
tageous as possible.
An
In order to eliminate
that industrial
for
If all
S",
locations but
Table
3,
is
as given, everything in
(x, y"^)
The
the equation
partial derivatives
with respect to them then hold the condition that the location p"* will be chosen at
the point of greatest profit (equation 1 Table 4)
,
Table
3.
95
Place of Production
Product
No.
p1 (x} y}); Pj
Pf (xfyr);Pi
Pi
ai, Pi
2 2
ai, ^1
PrCx^yH
Abbreviations of their
equations
Number
Site
ai
= 2a
ej, a2,
Pi
(Together)
jji;
P2
2 2
a2, ^2
dj
a2
Number
A
B
P2
(Together)
|=2A+B
b 4-q|
+ .Q
Given
d"'
Individual
/'"(n")
demand
product
for
V
V
Qf pioduct m at site q as a function
Average cost
,^
^
j^m ^
m/)
demand D"* = )i'(f',x"y"',a'"fl'"
A .
.,,;,. q^q
of production
J
= D" (tt k"") Profit on product m at site q
'^
<i)
"^
-^
S"*
of the total
"^v
<i
(7"
e'",o-,
q'"'"*
')
0-"
Urban population
Freight rate
Number
To
find
sq.
of the
km.
town
P""
of products
Number of
Unknowns
1.
tt""
2.
p"
at location P'J
in sq.
km.
3.
4.
X, y
2n
5.
a, /3
e""
+ ni + N
Sum: 4n
Now
for
(see
p.
number
8,
note
8)
Under
of independent enter-
is
economy
as large as possible,
as a
Part One.
g6
to costs. ^'^'
is
Location
possible at
all,
This condition would be fulfilled when the individual volundecided not to exhaust all possibilities of profit. Nevertheless,
there would still be room for new competitors since the areas, as
they developed under the existing conditions, could be made yet
smaller without detriment to the profitability of the industries or
tarily
reached
its
maximum.
now push
in,
If still
enterprises
all
may happen
It
ducers will
as
leave the marginal entrepreneur a profit small but within these limits
still
The
six.
enough
closely
to take
away
is
situation
is
similar when,
is
own
payment
him, which
9.
is
of interest
on
his
This gives for each of the n locations an equation of the general form
4.
tt^
k">,
The
market area that can be supplied from a location depends on the one hand on the
shape of the demand and on the other on the shape of costs within the firm. Both
are illustrated in Figure 16a; the total demand, D, within this market area as a function of
f.
o. b.
intersect at S
10.
price,
and
total
where
costs
costs, k.
The
curves
demand
when the demand
shifted demand curve
curve
is
left.
The
of tangency.
Equation
is
reached
the
is
is:
(ir^)
'
(k">)
',
or like equation
4.
97
of
regions.
Table
SYSTEM OF EQUATIONS
4.
Number of
Pertinent Equation
Equation which
Condition
1.
Maximum
profit
as^
^-
Maxi-
'2.
mum
3.
permit
Total area used
No unusual
<
Gf +
<P'^
num-
profits
ber of
Producers
4.
-^
Area
<G
Gl' -f
= X
(Dq)
as small as
condition
as-- =
o;
dTTq
possible
.5.
fulfills
dGl
Equations
2n
= G
m
n
(Dq)
akq
aG^
Boundaries
Indiff'erence lines
Sum: 4n
+m+N
They
are indifference
lines.^^'^^
locations is variable. Hence for a given shape of the area, condition 4 is supposed to
maximize the number of producers; condition 1, on the contrary, maximizes the profit
of a given
number
number
of producers.
not in general.
is
Profits
Nevertheless, the
small.
would disappear
number
of producers
also
if
made
rectangles were
sufl&ciently
for rectangles,
It is
best.
For any given point {x,y) on the edge of the industrial market area (factory
price
freight rate x distance) must be the same whether one buys from P" or Pi.
For the geometric form of the border see pp. 165 f.
12.
13.
five
equations: size
and
limits of
market
which excludes
it
to
be in equilibrium.
The
Thus
strict sense to
would appear
We
and who
receives them.
is
used,
still
and how
further.
It
efficiently;
might
or the
Location
Part One.
98
b.
The
and consumption
will
coincide.
On
a village
14.
town in its role as production center may me repreand as a center for consumption by (^, tj) The first
equations determines x and y, and | and t] can be determined by a very
The
system of
(x, y)
similar one that will not be derived here, however, in order not to linger over extra-
economic matters.
overdetermined.
from its
market areas coincide, except at the level of the economics of a self-sufficient town
where otherwise the balance of payments between town and country would not be in
differs
equilibrium.
If,
more than
cultural goods
his products.
if
the
He
optimum
it
would be
consumer were
left
latter location.
Something similar will occur in the case of a town that is a center of consumption.
too, will approach an industrial location. Thus we obtain two new best locations
for towns as producers of industrial and consumers of agricultural commodities, in
the determination of each of which the other location was taken into account. Now
the two locations may be nearer to each other, but still they do not coincide. Something similar can be shown for farmers as producers of agricultural and consumers of
It,
industrial goods.
99
by themselves is a great city, whereas the best one for the production
and consumption of products of the soil alone implies an even
distribution. This is confirmed by the distribution of populations
in earlier times and today. Formerly, when the consumption of
agricultural commodities outweighed that of goods produced by
artisans, there were many small towns. ^^ Later, when food made up
only a part of living costs, even for the workingman, there was a
tendency toward concentration in large cities. Today, thanks to
improvements in transportation, the complete separation of loca-
c.
CONCLUSION
The
significant thing in
It was to
economy, equilibrium would be possible under certain conditions,
but it is important to be clear about these conditions. ^ For the
At that time agriculture could still constitute the determining basic stratum.
Yet sometimes they do. Many ranch owners in Texas pass the week ends in
their town houses, but stay on their ranches during the week.
17. The cheaper becomes the automobile, the farther beyond the real suburbs does
the commuting area extend. Distances over forty miles are not unusual in the United
States. According to a Gallup poll, only about three per cent of American workers live
in the immediate neighborhood of their places of employment, whereas 45 per cent
15.
16.
commute
18.
either in their
own
and vacation
is
Many
persons
move from
localities of
lower wages and living costs to those where both are higher, but where the absolute
amount
places of origin
expensive
is
localities.
In the case or regional boundaries the equations themselves rather than the
single variables have been counted, as an exception, among the unknowns (see Table
19.
3,
point 5)
20. In
no other
my
significance.
Part One.
lOO
Location
as of other
this,
unknown
country.
improved, and employed to solve practical problems more precisely than with our
all, the physicist does not derive the law of freely falling
bodies from a universal formula, nor the physician his remedy from a general formula
for treatment. Still, see the gallant attempt of W. W. Leontief, "Interrelations of
archiv
21.
und Archiv
This
is
fiir
which
is
ensured by the
individual's self-interest.
These are the independent variables that affect equilibrium without its reacting
in our case, for example, the size of an area, the direction of demand, the
technique of production, and the level of freight costs.
22.
upon them:
1.
The
basic ideas for the following discussion have already been developed in
Bonn
and
my
Law and
Political
Economy
my
at the
also
in
THEORY
THE
assumption
now on
the
to
make
But no doubt
it
might
just as well
have been said that the price level between 10 and 20 degrees East
longitude and 45 and 50 degrees North latitude would have to fall,
and that between the Meridian of Greenwich and 10 degrees East
longitude and 40 and 50 degrees North latitude would have to rise.
In other words, it is highly improbable that the line dividing falling
and rising prices coincides exactly with political boundaries. Even
though it could be shown statistically that the German price index
was falling, this would prove neither that prices had fallen everywhere in Germany nor that they had fallen only in Germany.^ For
instance, it is very unlikely that the coal mines in the then Polish
Upper-Silesia would have been able to maintain their prices if
German mines a few miles away had had to lower theirs. The fact
that Upper Silesia constituted an economic unit would seem to be
more important in many respects than the fact that it was politically
separated from Germany. On the other hand, suppose large subsidy
payments to flow from western Germany toward the east. In such
a case the economic consequences would resemble those of war
indemnities to a hair. Prices would necessarily fall west of the Elbe
and
rise east of
it.
Two
arise in the
same
country.
It
probable, rather, that price changes, which according to the old theory
is
it,
In the case of small or long and narrow countries like Canada and
immediately obvious, but it holds also for those whose shape is better
countries as well.
Chile this
rounded,
3.
is
as
we
To what
But the
(pp. 302
ff.)
still
our inquiry.
Part Two.
Economic Regions
economic regions,^
Actually they
104
altered
little
regions was not examined. To give but one example: The fallacious
idea of a general price level was merely split into fallacious ideas
of regional price levels. Yet even cursory examination of the nature
that the price surface was much
country than a calm lake. Certainly all that is
included in an economic region must have something or other in
common. But it would be premature, though it is a mistake that
suggests itself in consciously logical procedures, to conclude from
this that since prices are the central phenomena in all exchange
processes, the best definition of an economic region would be a
region throughout which prices are approximately the same. This
definition is unsuitable, however, because there are no such regions;
and even if there were they would be without significance and thus
not worth our attention. In order not to fall into a similar error
we shall proceed in the opposite direction and try to discover
whether and how, under rational assumptions, an economic boundary can be expected to arise. Instead of starting from a preconceived idea we shall look first for actual differences, and not until
then for their logical common denominator.
of such a region
more
4.
like a hilly
different origins.
town,
contributed others;
territorial,
"
Das
Merkantilsystem
in
seiner
[1911], 667-688.
Chapter
Among
9.
We
first group
and of large-scale production;
in the second, those of shipping costs and of diversified production.^
In the following derivation we start from radical assumptions
in order that no spatial differences may lie concealed in what we
assume: that economic raw materials are evenly and adequately
distributed over a wide plain. Our area shall be homogeneous in
every other respect as well, and contain nothing but self-sufficient
How
can
this starting
point
Let us select any one of these farms, and ascribe to its owner
the wish to produce manufactured goods over and above his own
needs. Will he be able to sell them? The savings due to mass production will favor his enterprise, whereas transportation costs will
hamper it. How large will his market eventually be? Suppose his
neighbors are of the same stamp and live similarly, so that the
demand curve for one is typical of all. Let d, in Figure 20, be such
an individual demand curve for beer. If OP is the price at the
brewery, which is at P, those living at P will buy PQ bottles of beer.
1.
we
io6
Part Two.
Economic Regions
Thus PF
will
be the extreme
^ for beer,
and total sales
volume of the cone that would
PQF on PQ as an axis (Fig. 21)
sales radius
Quantity
^Quantity
Fig. 20-22.
demand curve
Derivation of the
demand cone
(Fig. 21)
(Fig. 22)
volume must
Its
still
The
result
is
is
given by
PF by
To
reduce to kilometers
107
Expressed algebraically,
D=^bX^ f
where
D = total
b
demand
as a function of
f.
o. b.
price p;
7r=3.14d
f{p-\-t)XtXdt.
= f(p
it
costs
mark
-\-t)
individual
demand
as a
function of price at
The
derivation
is
simple.
The volume
of a solid of revolution
is equal to the area of the generating surface times the path of its
in Figure 20 have the area
center of gravity. Let the surface
PQF
and
let
the ordinate of
its
2^/
(since according to the
f (p
-\- t)
X X
t
dt.
yoF=f
Taking into account,
f{p
+ t)XtXdt).
finally, that
as a function of the
is
-^
we
brewery
price p.^
It
different form,
P<^^i
io8
Two.
Economic Regions
brewery
MN will
4.
If
minimum
This
this capacity.
Its
can be reached only by a plant that has been built especially for
average cost curve touches the planning curve once, but otherwise
it.
to the right,
lies
plant does not produce more cheaply than any smaller or larger one the
corresponds to
its
minimum
amount
amount
that
that corresponds
to its point of tangency. This point represents the capacity for which it was built.
For since the point of minimum average costs already lies above the planning curve,
another and larger plant would evidently be more advantageous. This is easily seen
cost curve,
The planning
curve represents geometrically the envelope of the average cost curves for plants of
various
sizes.
LXX
5.
(1932)
particularly p. 244;
translated
by
Industrien, Pt.
C.
J.
Tids-
Friedrich as Alfred
The difference is, first, that this deduction is not correct, because
demand as independent of local price. Secondly, his (marginal) method
scale producers."
it
regards
different, and less suited to the Chamberlin process. And thirdly, he does not
employ this process. A further difference is didactic in nature: He starts with an
unequal distribution of natural resources and introduces agglomeration later, whereas
is
we proceed
6.
As soon
as
and so are
agglomerate, and thus
their
price
relationships
production
strictly
sites
different, too.
So, for
it
for the
speaking their
moment. See
p. 143,
But however
note
10.
demand
curves are
significant this
may
are
their
be,
near the
we must
Chapter
The Network
10.
of
Markets
a.
The deduction
Region
Size of
1.
would be relevant
form. But they are not. Even
so far
if
circular in
of breweries lying so closely together that their sales areas touched,
one or another farmer would still be tempted to start a brewery
unprofitable.^
The
honeycomb
demand curve A
will be shifted
downward.^
This procedure has become familiar for product differentiation through the work
Chamberlin {The Theory of Monopolistic Competition [Cambridge, Mass.,
1933; 5th ed., 1938]) and of Joan Robinson {The Economics of Imperfect Competition
[London, 1933]) but it holds just as well for differences in location. For those un1.
of E. H.
on the
subject, Chamberlin's
As long
(2)
as the
demand curve
These
which
is
of
special interest in the present context, will choose the location of their establishments
way
in such a
consequence of
demand
some
of the buyers.
As a
will shift to the left until they are tangent to the cost curve
and
all
surplus profits
The
disappear.
an area is larger than necessary for n producers, but not large enough for
n
1, there is a monopoly which, of course, is restricted by latent competition that may become actual if the monopoly is exploited to the full. Then comes
a struggle between the earlier and the later firms, one of which must finally succumb
however,
if
If
since there
2.
With
is
109
Part Two.
10
Economic Regions
still
Then
tt.
total
demand
the market
is
If still
MW;
the same
area.^
Fig. 23.
Development
of
2.
hexagon
Shape of Region
A.
It
is
is
curve. A', is determined by the fact that OV must equal the volume of a cone
developed by rotating the surface OABT about OT as an axis. OA again is equal to
demand
This we know from daily experience. Suppose one is to have a cake baked near
home. Nobody would carry the heavy pan of batter across the whole town, even to
the best baker. Bwfno one would mind a long trip to leave a watch for repair with
a skillful watchmaker, and one would go even outside the town to a medical specialist.
5. Diminution of a region is disadvantageous for the established entrepreneur,
because his profits disappear; it is welcome to the newcomer because then there are
more possibilities of making himself independent; and it is often advantageous for the
consumer because although the price at the plant usually rises, the average freight
4.
costs fall.
Network
of
Table
Markets
5.
DEMAND
AS A
Demand
Total
Shape of
Market Region
of
entire region
Large
circle^
Small
circle^
R2H
0.302
1.047204)
Hexagon
0.907
of
region utilized
H -0.550
0.333
H^3)
H- 0.606
H^4)
r2H (2.598-^1.580)
H -0.608 H^O
H -0.608 H^
H-0.617 H^
H-0.617 H^
r2H (2.598-^1.690)
H-0.651
equal
area
Square
Triangle
1.
R = radius
H|
H-0.651
H^
PF
in
Fig. 20.)
r
base removed
(r<R).
H = height
of
b/2
2.
Large
3.
It
is
hexagon
if
4.
The
is
demand
cone.
demand
(Individual
Fig. 20.
it
is
at
site
of factory,
PQ
in
1.)
circle,
easily seen
r
is
6. This will be assumed more frequently, for it is not only an especially convenient
assumption but an especially reasonable one. If OF, as in Figure 20, is the price at
which nothing more will be sold, and OT the amounts that would be consumed if
the good were free, then OF and a line parallel to it through T, and OT and a parallel
line to it through F, will in almost all cases delimit the area in which the demand
curve must lie. We now choose our scale in such a way that OF is equal to OT, so that
these lines and their two parallels form a square. If we draw in this square all conceivable forms of demand curves and the diagonal FT, the resulting triangles and all
portions of the possible demand curves lying within them will be congruent and
symmetrical in resepct to FT. The sum of the deviations from FT is zero. The straight
line FT is the average value of every possible form of demand curve. In all cases
where no details are known about the actual shape of the demand, the linear form is
the only well-founded assumption.
Economic Reaions
Part Two.
p,
the
volume
of the portion
^= f
We now
cut the
in such a
way
that
an equilateral
triangle, a square, or a
hexagon of
The
result
is
greatest
when
this area
that the
is
is
demand
of the
market area
not curtailed at
greatest
when
it is
all.
as a
whole
The demand
circular in form.
is
of the
But per
unit of area of the market region, the demand of the small circle,
not that of the large circle, is greatest because in the latter case the
average for the area is reduced by the small demand near the limits
for shipment. The average demand in the small circle is obviously
greater than in any polygon of equal area. But because circles
leave empty corners, the demand per unit of the entire area in the
case of the hexagon exceeds not only that of a square and a triangle,
circle.
In other words,
among
all
the possi-
required
with a triangle, and the least with a regular hexagon. The honeycomb is therefore the most advantageous shape for economic regions.^
The advantage benefits consumers as a whole, ^ whereas for the
bilities of realizing
7.
is
8.
it
The
is
to
regular hexagon
is
The
result of these
full.
is
Among
all
the corners, the hexagon retains most of the advantages of the circle.
The
size of
the
Network
Markets
of
113
it is
cut down. Yet the honeycomb shape contributes to the advantage of producers as a whole also, since it makes
neur how
his region
is
number
of independent enterprises.
how
great
the advantage of
is
is
about
instances,
triangle
is
in
circle,
if
the
its
a straight line.
greater or
It
large
An
In comparing the hexagon with the square, for instance, the boundary region
to be reckoned from the inscribed circle of the hexagon to the circumscribed circle
10.
is
of the square.
parison,
The
and the
elasticity
is less
circumscribed circle
is
of
no consequence
at
all.
Part Two.
11^
Economic Regions
for
The
size
to be fully utilized.
In
summing up
it
may be
hexagon becomes
more favorable
as a regional
possible one.^^
b.
11. I have found the hexagonal shape discussed in two places in the literature,
though without adequate proof. First, by W. Launhardt (Mathematische Begriindung
der Volkswirtschaftslehre [Leipzig, 1885], p. 181)
who assumed it only by way of
example; and recently in the admirable book by W. Christaller (Die zentralen Orte in
Siiddeutschland [Jena, 1933])
who at least advanced a general though inadequate
proof. According to Christaller the hexagonal arrangement of central sites has the
advantage " that they are neither too few nor too many, and also that no districts are
left without regular supply" [ibid., p. 69)
H. Haufe {Die geographische Struktur des
deutschen Eisenbahnverkehrs [Langensalza, 1931], pp. 14 f.) finds hexagonal networks
of transport lines most favorable for the uniform spherical surface of the earth because
with them, though not of course with the triangles into which they necessarily divide,
,
is
hexagons, like triangles but unlike squares, can cover the earth without a remainder.
Network
1^5
Markets
of
on the
influence
we
shall
now
situation
and
size of the
market
area.
This influence
proceed to examine.
and
For farmers as producers the advantages, for farmers as consumers the disadvanmay preponderate. Scattering shortens the distance from
12.
farm buildings to
fields
and
generally, also,
to the
farm buildings or
fields.
This
affects the
it
is,
(1)
the
(2)
traffic
is,
whether because of the size of loads, for example, with extensive fertilization or
naturally high yields, or because the number of trips is larger (as with cattle, schools,
churches, government offices, daily requirements in so far as these cannot be cheaply
produced in small quantities, as with goods needing a large market area; (3) the
higher the costs per mile and the more they differ for villages as against more dispersed
These
settlements.
differences,
unequivocal; inventions like the telephone and the radio encourage scattered
settle-
ments, whereas the increasing interlacing of markets favors the establishment of villages.
The
issue
is
In scattered settlements
man must
W.
Christaller,
13.
is
that
Part Two.
ii5
Economic Regions
Let b be the distance between the small market towns ^i, B2,
and so on, as we shall call the smallest places where industrial goods
are produced for sale, b corresponds to the diameter of the inscribed
circle 2p of the market area, except that p is expressed in freight
costs
and
b in kilometers or miles.
nV
1.
and
location.
The
town
its
is
nailed over
it
is
at a similar angle
toward the
right.
Network
of
117
Markets
There remains
which
nF
is
equal to
a,,
.-^
.^
X'^\/-^-\.
Figs. 24-26.
The
therefore,
= a^/H
Part Two.
ii8
Economic Regions
same kind
^'
l\
+^
1^
iV,
1^
^1
/;/'}
10
^^^J^
Fig. 27.
The
are hatched.
10 smallest
economic
13a.
areas.
The
sectors containing
by the
Those enclosed
Werner Kanzig
of
this
From
(feV3)
Z-
=r
r?,
/jth
where n
area.
is
7,
number of settlements
The general formula used by Losch has the form
number of settlements. Let the number of the area.
corresponding to the
market
figures.
many towns
Simple points
the
Network
Table
Area
No.
6.
nV
.f^
i9
Markets
of
11
= number
plied,
al/7
a)/ 4
equivalent
the
of
in
number
of
aV,
12
.f^
1)
= distance
2a
al/,2
distance
centers
diameter of inscribed
13
a|/l6
16
.f.
al/,3
nV
= necessary
of seller
2a
of
areas
circle.
shipping distance
from farthest
= distance
still
necessary
customer.
a|/l9
2a
19
21
a|/21
.fy
10
25
a)/ 25
al/7
Table
Area
No.
7.
CALCULATION OF
Area
No.
(1
1/3)2
02
(1>^
(1
.1/3)2
12
(2
1/3)2
02
12
(2
1/3)2
12
(2
1/3)2
22
11
(3
1/3)2
02
1/3)2+
(^)2
(1^^1/3)2
(1>^)2
(2K n)^
(>^)'
19
13
(2 >^ 1/3)2
(1^)2
21
16
10
(2K
1/3)2
(2^)2
25
27
15
(3>^ 1^3)2
(>^)2
37
find k
h ^ m,
ho
> m,
a.
If ho
b.
If
/z
then
fe
2m
+
1
and
2in
{hg
h)
then
k
=m
I;
and
==
(m
1)
{h^
h)
-W.
F. S.
Ecor.oniic Regions
Part Two.
120
market
and the number of settlements they contain also grow discontinuously. This, again, makes surplus profits possible. For if
sales in 32 settlements, say, were required to make a certain commodity profitable, area No. 13 with 31 settlements would be too
small. But the next area is the unnecessarily large market area 14,
with 36 settlements, so that sales must extend to 36 settlements.
The demand curve would then intersect the cost curve instead of
merely touching it, and surplus profits would thus arise in this
industry."'^^ Such moderate surplus profits are actually the rule,
for it would be pure chance if the demand curve in its jumps should
is
areas
still "
One more
14.
As a consequence of
jumps if it
Chamberlin
this discontinuity in
demand
curve
is
area
i.
its
e.,
its
left
demand
The
different questions.
borders
ment.
a market
15.
Thus whether
is
is
demand
of settlements
first
on the
not zero.
An
a discussion of which
is
distribution of chances.
The
may break
strife
out,
Among
the
first
several supply
centers.
seems to
political centers as
is
me
especially
divided
populous
districts,
places.
and
probable.
when
Political division
several
lords
is
had
to
in
(1)
It
turn toward
possible, however;
serfs
among
the same
one need
villages.
situation:
division
is
wholly improbable.
neighboring
market
areas
If
with
it
(3)
discontinuous
difiBcult.
If
that
makes
oligopolistic
Network
of
2.
181
Markets
Location at
Center of Gravity
might be established between three settlements instead of in one of the original settlements. This we shall
production
site
call
Compared with
location in a
has the disadvantage of no local demand worth mentioning, but the advantage of being nearer to the next sales points.
Hence the smallest possible value for nF is 0.58a instead of a, as is
the case with location in a settlement. Except for nV, however, the
settlement
it
two
size
of
The
two locations
is
definitely superior
would
demand.
be that the
all
if
possible
demand
curves,
it
may be
can be
shown " that, at least for the 10 smallest areas examined, location
at an original settlement entails a greater demand in half of the
cases (areas 3, 4, 6, 7, and 9) and location at a center of gravity in
the other half.^^ However, in those cases where location at the
center of gravity is more economical, its advantage over location in
a settlement is more pronounced than the reverse.
Thus whereas location sometimes appears more favorable in a
settlement and sometimes at a center of gravity, if each is considered by itself it may be presumed that when everything is carefully
,
demand would
17. The proof, though not difficuh, is too long to be given here. In any case, it is
unimportant for the development of our ideas.
18. Consequently it may happen that with appropriate location of a factory fewer
places will provide a greater demand for the same commodity. This is possible with
goods whose longest shipping distance is too short to make the demand at points on the
felt,
small area.
With
relatively
short
is
more
decisive in the
may
Part Two.
128
decrease.
This
mine the
sites of
economic
especially true of
is
other
locations, as
we
Economic Regions
capitals,
which
(2)
deter-
The
and
3.
this there
is
number
of practical reasons
at a center of gravity.
c.
REGIONAL NETWORKS
We
have seen that there is only one suitable shape for market
and only a limited number of possible sizes and situations.
Because of the restricted number, the most favorable area is uniquely
determined for every commodity.^^ One and the same area will
usually be the market for several goods, since there are more products
than regional sizes. But beyond the market area these goods need
areas,
two
and necessary
others.-"
things are
Thus with
no longer
sales
volumewill
as they are
19.
the area,
From this
demand at
20.
local
must be
number
as small as possible.
maximum
is
demand
easily possible
shipping distance.
distance, the fewer settlements will be required to achieve a certain sales volume, for
demand with
little sensitivity
increasing distance.
to shipment;
that
is,
only an inconsiderable
Network
of
Markets
123
still
to
come must
take place.
21.
What
experience.
p.
126.
On
classes of
Here
new
Chapter 11.
The System
of
Networks
a.
Market areas for the various kinds of goods resemble narrowmeshed or wide-meshed nets of hexagons that to start with can be
thrown at will over our plain. ^ Despite the resulting confusion,
every place would lie in the market area of every good.- Yet it is
worth while to bring order out of this chaos by means of a few
reflections.
we lay the nets so that all of them shall have at least one
common. Here a metropolis will arise, with all the advantages^ of a large local demand. Second, we turn the nets about
this center in such a way as to get six sectors with many and six
with only a few production sites (Figs. 28 and 29) .* With this
arrangement the greatest number of locations coincide, the maximum number of purchases can be made locally, the sum of the
First,
center in
minimum
distances
least,
and in
lines are
reduced
is
1.
With
the limitation, aheady established, that their middle points coincide with
The
situation
is
wholly symbolic.
We
and
live
all
simultaneously amidst
many
sur-
preference.
3.
This presupposes that in a number of branches the planning curve does not
See Figure 48 and the accompanying text.
fall
steadily.
4.
More
centers of the four smallest areas, whereas Figure 29 shows all regions.
124
The System
of Nclivorks
125
tance in the next quadrant not with one of the other two, which
are too near.
Once network
is
Fig. 28.
Theoretical pattern of an
Fig. 29.
economic landscape
is
no longer
free,
Theoretical pattern of an
economic landscape, but
without nets
Fig. 30.
a radius of 60 miles.
Handatlas, 8th
(From Andree's
Fig. 31.
radius of 60 miles.
{Ibid.)
ed., p. 198.)
The
and lower
Part Two.
J26
Economic Regions
Neither are the outlying environs, even within the same sector,
uniformly settled. Some localities have no production of their own
at all, whereas at other places the centers of several market areas
" cenof varying size coincide. Such agglomerations of locations, or
found
upon
are
calls
them,
tral sites," as Christaller so appropriately
(Fig.
regularity
certain
closer examination to be distributed with a
Smaller agglomerations can be found at distances of V3a, Sa,
32)
from each other; many of medium size at distances of 6a;
and
and larger ones lie 1 2a apart.^ Yet it is not true that when an equal
number of areas have their centers at two places these areas them.
2V^
selves will
possibly
be of equal
fulfill
size.
Towns
entirely different
few towns, and somewhat farther out, industrial prices rise sharply
until at last, with minor fluctuations, production sites again become
so numerous that the local price level falls (unless the index is
heavily weighted with goods having a very large sales area that can
be purchased only in the metropolis and therefore become increasingly dear with rising freight costs)
If the entire regional system has the radius L, goods for which
p is somewhat greater than L/2 can be produced only in the metropolis.^ Even locations on the borders between two regional systems
can no longer compete in such commodities. Consequently, at a
distance of something more than L/2, no new competition arises
for the metropolis. With a distance of something more than L/2,
.
locations.
On
the other hand, the distance between these pairs of possible locations
is
than the radius of the circle on which they lie. Hence they are too near together,
and a choice must be made between them. If a location in the lower sector is chosen,
The possible
its mirror image in the middle sector must necessarily be relinquished.
locations in the two outer sectors, on the contrary, are separated by the proper distanc^^.
less
6. The minimum distance between two production centers of any given size is aV3,
and every center has at least one neighbor at this distance.
7. Living costs, on the other hand, which include agricultural products, rent, and
extra expenses, and take retail markups into account, are highest in the metropolis,
at least when fuel is disregarded for reasons discussed on p. 42, note 10.
8. Such a typical metropolitan function, for example, is bank clearing at the highest
level.
The System
of
Networks
127
^\/5
Y^
7\^i
V/
V J^^^f^ I
1^
0^
^^
V/
11
>i.v
/\i.</
_
o-.te.
7i,i^
V
...
\^
s\i^:...-^j3__iz
__3oc
v/
^^>
^
?j
.i^':..t-#-:-,--
"750
Fig. 32.
The transport
The numbers
refer to the
number
of centers
which coincide
in a particular point.
all of
The
lines:
The number of centers along the heavy lines is twice or more that along
number of centers along the thin lines is approximately one and
the number along the broken lines. The difference in traffic density
a half times
P(nt.
128
Txuo.
Economic Rarions
f4
11.
1*10
1.33
23
2*8
/i,
1*t
2?.
15
25
f.|
/i
24
f9
n\
>
13
.37j^
iVy^
.i,.f
2*
16
^mq
12
,.
/..
fn/
./
fi.
ll
^*
Ipll
n/5
13
Z*^^
21/
21
15
^/
35/.
9'
26
16
32
31
''
20
1.39
'i
S'
28
IjtiZ
Z
Fig. 33.
The
Fig. 34.
numbers
(I)
of their region.
3.
towns of the next lower rank. The numerals indicate regional centers with the same
number as in Figure 33, from which this one was made by omitting all regions without
a center and two complete places of next lower rank.
The System
of
Networks
129
prices will thus rise again, since goods with a large sales radius
freight,
and
their
(uni-
upon drawing
communication,
(measured by the number of area
centers per unit of length) occurs along the sectors. Thus twelve
such main lines radiate from the metropolis; " i. e., six lines cross
in it. Elsewhere in the region there are junctions of only two or
Finally,
we
traffic
theoretically not
9.
Instead of spatial price differences tfiere are spatial differences in profits wtien a
This
is
is
it
is
too great.
The
price cones
cases.
11.
Eleven through railway lines run out from Berlin, for instance; from Paris,
including branches within a radius of about 25 miles, exactly twelve; directly from
London, twelve through highways. This orientation of main arteries toward the
metropolis was noticeable after the incorporation of Austria and the Sudetenland into
the Reich. Their main roads formerly ran toward Vienna and Prague, and good connections with the old Germany were often possible only by way of their own capital
cities.
12.
is
Munich or Nuremberg,
some 50
say,
one
miles.
Further important results are: six sectors containing few towns and six conmany are grouped about the metropolis; in its immediate environs a region
having the form of a cogwheel remains free of towns; the towns show a honeycomb
13.
taining
distribution,
main
lines of
distance; the
joQ
Part
" isolated
Economic Regions
TtL'o.
We
state."
shall
not
it is:
an economic landscape.^*
SPECIAL CASES
b.
1.
whose necessary market area is exactly as large, or because extraeconomic factors above all, political division into administrative
units influence spatial economic arrangement.
Political division
is
way
that a
and
30,
on may
so
exist,
3,
and
10,
and 12
to 29.
14. Economic empire, economic region, or economic area (in the narrower sense)
would be suitable, especially if one recalls the original meaning of regio and Gebiet:
an area of authority, according to Grimm's Worterbuch. It is, in fact, the economic
domain of the central metropolis. On the other hand, economic district, or province,
may
object to the
consider that
it
way
in
which
is
common
meaning
of the word.
ask
Geog-
them
Only by way
of
do
geographic peculiarities influence the region that has sprung out of pure space, as
with R. Hapke's more general " economic landscape " (" Die okonomische Landschaft
und Gruppenstadt
und
Wirtschafts-
geschichte, Geddchtnisschrift
fiir
would orient
all
a geographical unit in
E. ^Vinkler, "
and
Raumordnung
der Wirtschaft,"
Neue
in correspondence.)
15.
from parts of
therefore, the large region includes k centers of next smaller regions, which, however,
are
made up
of parts of
regions.
131
8.
Each Other
Size
(actual)
Regional Size,
Regional
the
Number
in
Complete System
afsi
a 1/41
ai/;;
a 1/32
a 1/42
a 1/72
19
a 1/38
ay43
a 1/73
11
24
106
.f^'
30
81
a 1/35
3^45
77
a 1/38
a 1/46
a 1/76
.^v
al/4T
a|/7T
number under
is
at the
total
number
The
of settlements in
when
/t
=3
all
places
lie
special case
efficient
where A
^3
(Jena, 1933)
pp. 63-85. Furthermore, the chance
symmetrically with respect to each of the six through
,
and thinly settled areas appear, has misled him into estabon the " communication principle " (ft = 4)
In this
arrangement the greatest possible number of important places lie on main lines of
communication. But this is true anyway (see Fig. 32) especially in a complete system
of market regions. The communication principle was one of the axioms by which
the final position of regional networks was determined. In our economic landscape
both this principle and the principle of supply are therefore united. It would
disrupt logical geometrical development if one were to suppose that cheapness,
rapidity, frequency, and extent of communication over long distances could create a
special locational advantage that would result in more industries being established
lines
and hence no
thickly
Economic Regions
Part Two.
132
about it, and above all it is probably the most that can
be attained today by conscious planning. Adapted to individual
cases it forms, furthermore, the very basis for the new organization
attractive
in the East.
O/O o\o
of/
o/o O/O
y ,-'-<o \
Fig.
/t
35.
4.
Fig.
(3)
36.
l.
o.o
O /
^v
V o\o
O/O
(2)
'"
drawn.
than otherwise would be the case; partly because they could manage with smaller
regions, partly because these regions would be narrower in the direction of the com-
Whoever wishes
to
at right angles to
it.
in
it
the
by Culemann in
his
planning
("
Zur Stadtplanung
in
is
den neuen
With
deutschen Ostgebieten," Raumforschung und Raumordnung, 1941, pp. 100-230)
larger towns it is supposed that the local demand and the demand from the environs
.
justifies
The
special case
ft
=7
is
is
divided
with twin
Kansas)
cities
among
like
He
cit.,
aptly characterizes
by the
(as is
fact,
first,
that
no
secondly, that the market regions of the places in question are cut
up
as
The System
of
Networks
2.
133
We
is
a-n
of
its
7 is, in fact, a
by political boundaries. For these conditions ft
ft
13 would be another. In the first case, however, the regional
boundaries are not as Christaller has drawn them, but as they appear in our Figure 36.
Christaller's figure is possible only because he departs from the most rational distribulittle
as possible
possible solution;
the economic principle, as he believes; rather, a few of the possible market boundaries
are at the
The complete
political boundaries.
Whenever only
the
smallest possible market areas of similar structure are taken into account despite their
slight flexibility
plicity)
(as is
Thus
different standpoint.
principle, because
=4
ft
^3
is
is
especially advantageous
from a
it
still
ft
is
the
best
according to
the
know
that I
on the
subject,
and
cases, his
at the
inquiry
same time
is
the best
a distinguished
Kutno)
own
system
is
subject,
the
(Der
isolirte Staat in
and C. Culeraann (" Aufbau und Gliederung gebietAufgabe raumlicher Gestaltung," Raumforschung und Raumordnung, 1942, pp. 249-256) recommends the rectangle because, unlike the hexagon,
through lines of communication do not cut up small regions and thus disturb local
1875], Vol. II, Pt. II, 4, p. 11),
Bereiche
licher
traffic,
as in
cut
but run tangent to them. Nevertheless, either long detours often result or else,
cities, diagonal streets are subsequently laid out, so that the regions are
many
up
als
after
all.
Economic Regions
Part Two.
134
2 t
1'
^l 10 i
all.
i5
r ^
^t
&
>4
'
7\.
'
p4
>'3
^i!
j4'
y^
2
10
iSI/ fX
^
^
y(\ X X
/
^
A
)
K Ni
-^-h
l/^5
<'*y^ )t\
-J-
2I
4
V
w
^^
>/
"y^ 5
'
--
>9
'Vil/^n
v.^
/v.
;[> p "v yr
'v
s^
i
Fig.
37.
^J
4-
/6\
y\ ^
"x
-^\>\
^\\
h^
^sj^
9y"
/'.
5r
.7
4/V
Ni^
7<r7
V
23
The
right quadrant.
it
7*
Upper
and the
numbers of the
Comparison
with Figure 32 shows the difference between quadratic and
hexagonal arrangement. In the former up to eight, in the
latter up to twelve, routes run together at one point. The
angles at which they meet are 45, 30, or a multiple
corner.
The
thereof.
agon
siderably less
why square
Thus
also,
regions are
The
less
two. But although two square road networks that are turned 45
degrees in respect to one another are superimposed, most connections
in the honeycomb road network are obviously shorter (Fig. 32)
Chapter
a.
The Network
12.
of Systems
may be
size of
The
largest neces-
Figs.
38
and
39.
landscape
is
small.
cites.
Broken
lines:
Double
landscape boundaries.
lines:
Hatched:
many towns
metropolis //i would have to give up without reason the establishment of a second metropolis, Hz. In these distant parts the advantages of agglomeration of producers at //i are no longer noticeable,
since they buy nothing more from there; secondly, the difference
between sectors rich and sectors poor in towns and the advantages
of communication associated therewith disappear progressively.
Hence a second metropolis arises at a distance of 2L from the first,
and so on, until finally the entire plain is filled with landscapes.
When these have become numerous enough, they assume the
135
Part Two.
ig5
Economic Regions
dominate over
it.
b.
greater than
To
summarize:
transgressed;
if p is less
if p
lies
than L/3,
first
cases
1.
Only
these,
is
considerably
These producers
|
export also^
These consumers
import also
These consumers
Thus where
transgression of
arise.
These producers
supply only the domestic market
become
where L/2 < p.
excess profits
a landscape
if
The Network
The
of Systems
137
and
effects of
exports,
though
it
Upon
RESULTS
So
far
and competition.
be expected th^t we shall now consider all the factors thus far
neglected, in order to derive a theory that fits reality. This sounds
good, but is humanly impossible. Were we to try, we should either
end up with equations and be forced to give up observation (visualization) and application, or else deal with an infinite number
We
shall
therefore
138
Chapter
Some New
13.
Factors
ECONOMIC DIFFERENCES
a.
Local Differences
1.
Price^
in
a.
1.
Three
possibilities are
open
to the
individual case
f.
(A)
o. b.
He
same
c. i. f.
on the
Depending on
average and from place to place. We shall now examine how they
are set, how high they are, and how they affect the entrepreneur
himself and his customers. In order to do so we must first free
ourselves completely from the notions of traditional price theory,
which regards demand as though it were concentrated at one point.
price (C)
.^-^
ability of the
demand
of
consumers
its
will
1.
dislike
(1)
up
to
makes
it
p.
The
167.
principal
size
the
profits
interests of
from differentiation.
nearby consumers.
(3)
Differentiation
(2)
(4)
Uniform
f.
contrary
generally
is
differentiation
o. b.
prices
is
to
the
generally
would be more
This should not be confused with the irrelevant technical question of whether
is, whether or not
the carrier collects the freight from the buyer or the seller; that
it
appears on the
3.
There are
bill.
several combinations
in
mind
in
what
(A
+F
and variations of
or
(basing-point system)
-f C)
The meaning
follows.
139
this.
and
should be kept
Part Two.
140
It is
close to or far
from the
paid by each;
i.
The demand
e.,
Economic Regions
to
factory, since
it
respect to the
the
f.
o. b.
demand curve
only for
all
price
vertical distance
it is based on
payment to the manubut which is of no particular
is <ii.
by the
do
and which
Amount
Comparison of individual
Fig. 40.
demand with
price
i.
o. b.
(do)
respect to the
price
(dj),
c. i. f.
to the
unit
freight
between do and
from factory to
neighboring town.
We
line,
UT,
Some New
^4^
Factors
The
determine.
is ci
are
more
UR -^ QU;
in E,
demand
of
elasticity
elasticity in C7
==
it is 3
e.
2.
>
Cl
In words:
price
is
The
(1)
more
policy for
individual
price
o. b.
>
elastic
the corresponding
>
>
(ei
place,
2) .*
and
for
(2)
o. b. prices for
f.
(C)
freight costs
(A)
costs
4.
The
or not at
reason
>
(ei
(F)
all
is
(see
" Spatial
say.
Discrimination," Review
Price
when
a market center
is
is
is
of
produced by
it is
greater.
surrounded by a
of price in the
seller
more
costs.
to
o. b.
f.
price,
c. i. f.
M. Hoover,
E.
An
if
Economic
'
falls;
2)
the
profound areal
also explains
191).
p.
effect of
why
changes in
demand
food)
and supply
demand
in the latter
in the
effect
c. i. f.
price
in agriculture
upon
it.
Thus
price
by increasing demand
than they decrease supply, whereas in industry they should decrease supply
less
less
than
industry.
In regard to the
cially of
at the
in
mining,
is
f.
o. b. price,
the
demand
though
it is
demand,
especially
elasticity relationships,
as
it
is
and espe-
At any
on the geographical
who
Only the
and the
,,
Economic Regions
Part Two.
1^2
to current
more
the
f.
o. b. prices increases
(ea
>
csl 2
o. b. prices (3
f.
> u)
> u)
-^
places.
more
elastic
(4)
>
(fi
>
c.
i. f.
it
4)
may
greater reaction
elicit a
Preliminary Study
(bb)
(2)
Demand
To
6.
Proof: If d^
nearer to
its
is
continually shifted
If
is
is
and
not falling at
With
in respect to the
by coincidence equal,
it
is
c.
more
HJ
it
smaller,
will intersect
UT
its
and
nearer and
(i. e.,
HJ's)
strongly on the
all.
demand
downward
is
to say, in the
is
demand
regional
UT'%)
(i. e.,
the
The
c.
i. f.
i. f.
price
is
elastic at the
f. o. b. and c. i. f. price)
on the contrary, if the prices are
(associated
(ei>e2)
same place
in respect to the
f.
o. b.
price
(f2>e4).
This
is
Some
i43
i^exu Factors
generally also
more
elastic,
much
the rural
demand
short of the
falls
demand
politan
(n
PQ)
is
It is
9. If,
is
demand
of
country dwellers (compared with that of a person living at the factory site) will be
less than one third, and if the individual demand curve is convex, more than one
numbers.
now, modify this result. Affluence, or at any rate
population density, decrease with distance from a town. For since farmers living away
from the city pay double freight in the manufactured products that they buy and the
agricultural products that they sell either their income will be smaller or their farms
larger than in the vicinity of a town. But even with the same income and at the same
price, especially if this is high, the individual buys fewer and fewer urban goods with
increasing distance from the town; for his demand depends upon price relationships
as a whole, and these shift more and more in favor of rural products. Consequently
third, of
10.
few
the individual
demand curve
intersection with
individual
the
demand
curve, but
demand throughout
is
rotated
The
;-axis.
to their
sales
left
about
its
special
one that
falls
more
amounts
to still less
the town. Only the decrease in population density counteracts this: More farmers with
a more even distribution then live near the town, where their demand is still relatively
large.
Since for
all
three reasons
demand in
demand
the rural
is
particularly small,
third of the
urban demand.
Economic Regions
Part Two.
1^^
The
demand
regional
is
more
elastic.
Strictly
speaking, this
statement holds only for the average form of the straight-line demand
curve; but it is therefore valid for the majority of conceivable, if not
actual, cases. It is a rule of thumb. It seems plausible because a rise
in price, for example, diminishes not only the individual demand
(the height of the demand cone), but also the number of buyers
(the radius of its base). Of course the average height of the cone
(which is the relevant magnitude so far as total demand is concerned)
is decreased by less than its maximum height (which represents the
It is therefore necesindividual demand at the center of the region)
sary, at least for the average case in which the demand is linear, that
rigorous proof of the statement be given. It is offered herewith for
the case where the market region is restricted by nothing but transport costs. In this case curve A in Figure 41 represents the total
demand." Now let d be the individual demand at the site of produc.
D the total demand throughout the sales region, and R the unit
tion,
p;
and
let
= ^
d^ <C
D ^- D\
falling prices
That
demand
individual
p' then,
on the
contrary,
the regional
is,
rising
To
= R^ -^ R'^.
That
is,
the regional
demand
demands
maximum
D -^ D' = d^ -^ d'^
freights.
If,
for instance,
11.
The
12.
In
raised
still
more general
effect of a price
a town, the
elastic
is
than
demand
is
The
terms:
change on the
total
When
is
the
local,
importance in
demand.
also.
The
demand, as is readily seen from curves A' and A in Figure 41. But
more effective is its change, even with a high price. In the
limiting case, point concentration, G coincides with F, and the effect of a division of
the town among several producers is percentually the same at every price.
regional size affect
Some New
area
145
Factors
restricted
is
this)
As
Oz
Os
TO
0,
Individual
Transport funnel
Fig. 41.
OV
Volume
Volume
OW
Volume
OJJ
Total
WA
demand
demand
demand
curves
as
O^ADT
an axis
about O^T as
an axis
of truncated cone resulting
from revolution of
as
an axis
OX
Volume
OiPQT
about
O^T
as
an axis
A'
Demand
demand
{^M'P
= O^A = EF)
as a function
of factory price ^^
A"
Total demand as a function of factory price when price and distance of competitors are given
A'"
OM'
OP
is
supposed always
is
the price, p the size of the area, which together result in equilibrium.
to
be
is,
supposed to come to O^, does not reach the value p with every factory
equation
The
more demand
price.
D -^D' = R^ -^ R'^,
absolute
13.
From
factory price
OE upward
Economic Regions
Part Two.
146
The matter is exactly the same if the radius of the market area
cannot be greater than r (or p in equilibrium) regardless of what
the possible shipping distance R may otherwise be (curve A', Fig. 41).
We let R increase slowly; that is, we let the price fall. As long as
R <i r, the given boundaries are irrelelvant. But when R becomes
greater than r, an increasingly large part of the possible demand
will not be realized because of the restriction of the region; i. e., for
this reason, too, total demand will become less elastic the lower the
,
price.^*
If,
it
is
= BH
that
an equal percentage
centually
price.
is
Now
since this
interesting; that
is
demand
in the
same proportion
individual
demand
from a factory
as the distance
(r)
The
is
The number
(c27rr)
increases
elasticity of the
on the contrary,
rises
14.
One may
demand. Yet
reach
it
in
say also:
cannot
The
less
fall
<
Some New
^47
Factors
Geographical Price Discrimination. With price discrimination the seller asks of each buyer the factory price that will yield
the highest profit. Where it does not involve too much trouble,
(cc)
price policy
is
Now how
is
The
The
factory price of
an
isolated
sales
its
Now
let
t)
P X dn
n
c
= marginal
dP'
price
'
'
costs.
is:
+ nXdP
^_ Pxdn dn
d(Pn)
dn
^_^
=
=c
c.
(P-^e), or p
c nf\n); or, more correctly, since no quantities
containing p remain on the right side of the equation,^"
15.
Only
in
(in preparation)
On
> total
costs
condition.
16.
The
Economic
derivation
is
E.
M. Hoover's
("
.
Economic Regions
Part Tiuo.
1^8
Obviously the factory price is not the same for all buyers, but
depends upon t, c, and c. We shall now discuss the influence of
these three factors
on
p,
The
to pay.
increases with
remain constant
formulation
= C+{P^e)].
[p
Distance}^''
first
when
is
and
c are constant.
does not
as a rule,
as
t.
on
this
point.)
Let ^1 be nearer the factory than An. p^ will then be greater than
pi
if
i-C
From
^2
^1
1
<^)
^1(^2
But
>^ gig
^ r-^ is
1(^2
+ + c)
(^2
^1)
The remainder
1.
of the
c)
But e.c
than one if (co^i +2^) < (ei^i
ic).
than eiC. If the inequality is to hold, t would
have to show a greater percentage increase than e. But this is highly
improbable, since e can become infinite while t always remains
finite. If in the absence of better information we assume a straightline demand curve as the average shape, e will increase more rapidly
than t. That is, the very shape of the demand curve makes it unlikely
that p will increase with t. But, in addition, even in the few cases
in which p might increase with t as far as demand is concerned,
it can actually happen only in the still fewer cases where A^ can be
prevented from buying through A-^ rather than directly from the
factory. It follows that the factory price will fall with distance as a
inequality will be
is,
less
as a rule, greater
rule.'^''^^'''^
16a.
The
17.
This
is
shown
in Figure 42 as
is
1
and
"
first
>
1,
lies
is
held
entirely
Some
N<?zv Factors
149
Elasticity.
price that
constant
t,
stretch of the
demand
curve. ^
within
quadrant
Its
the
t
P"
e
Finally,
1.
must
first
= p' -\-p".
rise at least as
with increasing
greatly, that
constant
asymptotes
are
p^c
and
l.
Since
is,
much
only
if
if
For
>
1,
as p' falls, if
is
less
less
with
to increase
e
raise the
e.
=
=
t
f (e)
and
Consequently p"
c.
But p" can increase
corresponding hyperbola
is e.
For
>
which
is
fulfilled for
2.
Fig. 42.
18.
Since the excess profits of the nearer entrepreneur are greater, therefore, than
more distant ones, the former have a greater influence on the choice of
would correspond to their demand, to say nothing of their numbers
those of the
location than
This
instances in
is
realistic.
cities.
One need
price, or in
which the
seller
many
pays at least
The
direction
it is too low.
For
< e < I, the
This would make marginal revenue, which for
< e < 1 is negative, positive again. As production increases, total costs rise and
subsidy payments fall. Hypothetically speaking, production is expanded in this case
until marginal cost equals the marginal savings in subsidy payments. For e < 1 the
is
Economic Regions
Part Tu'o.
i-o
Marginal Cost. The higher the marginal cost the higher is the
factory price which the same buyer must pay. How does a change
in c affect the spatial price dispersion, i. e., the dispersion of the
factory prices which are established for different distances? Since p'
is
made
From
follows that
and thus
e=
demand
the
{p
-\- t) -i-
{b
it
brakes
itself.
and
equation, p
p t)
-\- t
offer first
an algebraic
= [{b/a)n'\ +
h,^^ it
demand
individual
f.
price in three
o. b.
places.
distance
than maximization of
is
The
profits.
cost
maximum.
profit
21. I
doubt that the intensification of spatial price differences that has been
constant.
6 is
22.
Where
p,
t,
and n have the meaning given above, and b/a and b are the para-
total
demand curve.W. F.
S.
revenue curve,
i2
h
= 2-x
= ( _x + b)x;
b
= _x
-(-
6;
for the
""
whence by
differentiation
is
^
-f-
b.
p.
32-W.
F. S.)
J.
Some New
Factors
151
Amount
Fig. 43.
(a)
with respect to
f.
o. b.
revenue curves,
port cones.
(c)
(b) Corresponding
Corresponding trans-
Economic Regions
Part Two.
j_2
function of total sales, /', is derived from the individual marginal receipts by horizontal addition. This intersects the marginal
as a
cost curve,
hence
of
it
HG
K\
at G.
Here marginal
costs
optimum amounts
The
points of intersection
The
factory
prices, po, pi, and p2 (which, incidentally, all lie on the straight
line HPo) can be read off from the corresponding demand curves.
Finally, the corresponding delivered prices, Po, Pi, and P2, lie on doIt is easily seen that these prices differ by f/2. According to a
well-known theorem P^L, for example, is equal to AH -^2 and
p^K + f/2, and so on.
i, P^L
p^K
CH 2. Since
AH-CH =
Furthermore,
is
it
costs
more would be
is,
sold;
that
amount
sold
is
equal to
(for
example,
I)
yp_^ -^ p^C
amount, the gross
.
If
profit
WAPqL
is
the
amount
paid by buyers over and above the variable costs of production. One
third of it goes for freight paid by the buyers themselves, one third
for freight paid
profit.
24. Construction of the curves for gross profits assumes that the single buyer exerts
no influence on marginal costs.
25. A similar but somewhat simpler diagram is given by J. Robinson, op. cit., p. 183.
Mrs. Robinson treats also a simple case of curvilinear demand curve. W. F. S.
26. The sales radius, which would be represented in the demand cone by the highest
possible freight, may be shown in this so-called traffic funnel also by the greatest
amount sold per buyer the line OD'.
Some New
Factors
153
market
of the
even when
area,
On
it
is
buyer fall from OD' to zero with the distance from D'. On the
other hand, the number, n27rt, of buyers (n per freight unit) at a
certain distance (measured in transport costs, t) increases proportionately with distance. From this foUoAvs the equation for total
=dX
D* =
4^ -d
a
bola, with
h.
Therefore
Dt
d'^
its
riZ-irt.
{a
sumers
It
-=r-
This
as
2)
of
is
a para^
drawn, with
follows that
combined demand
demand
a linear
+ nZTchd.
^- ^/abirn
With
if
all
is
the
the con-
total
demand
of nearer
2.
the
factory
is
by (^1)
27.
The
otherwise
it
would be advantageous
agricultural rents.
fore differs
is
now
clear
maximum
Part Two.
154
Economic Regions
Amount
Fig. 44.
shall
29. It must be remembered, however, that interrupted hauls are more expensive
than direct hauls.
Some New
Factors
155
How
First:
hyperbola
Kq.
other delivered price than OPq. The factory price for B^ is, therefore, lower by / than that for Bq. The condition that would have to be
=*
Second:
If
is
to rise
copia must be
seen.
30. All
to greater,
demand
and
all
curves that rise above the upper limits {Ao, A^, A^,
that fall beneath the lower limits
would correspond
{Ao, A^',
A^
and
so on)
lead
lead to smaller,
Part Two.
jr6
Economic Regions
demand
of the
ticity
demand
is
subcase
increased relatively quickly.
Suppose that the group of hyperbolas
one would be
flatter
4-
Xo
2yo-f
Xo
Po^o and yo^KoPo. The scope of d is horizontally
hatched in Figure 44. In this case among others the demand curve
itself can be a straight line. Conversely, it is true that when the
demand curve is a straight line the entrepreneur always pays half
where
the freight.^^
Algebraic solution:
follows as the
c, i. f.
From
and
for Bz,
eoC
31.
The
32.
This
2^2
is
strictly true
case,
Some New
*57
Factors
Let Bo be farther away from the factory than B^. If P2 is higher,the condition under which the delivered price will not differ by
^2^1; or, if ^2 ^1
h
more than the freight is P2 -Pi
e,
It will
i)
{c
^2)
be found
straiofht-line
Application
3.
+h+ ^
{c
resulting from a
Dumping, or
more
distant
An
is,
it is
In America especially there have been many complaints about such cross-hauling. The Federal Trade Commission
has calculated that in 1928-29 it caused unnecessary freight in the
cement industry, for example, amounting to some 20 per cent of
the total production and marketing costs. ^^ Exact analysis shows,
of distance.^*
it is
It
34. Perhaps because a producer is not sure of his costs, is not acquainted with
neighboring buyers or shippers, wishes to continue accidental business relations, enjoys
exceptional freight rates that are much too low, or in transactions within the concern
certain
amount
pp. 75
f.
if
Part Two.
1^8
Economic Regions
with falling
foreign
dumping
into the
home
market.^^
As unlimited dumping leads only to pressure on prices and allround losses, the basing-point system attempts to replace it with
regulated, or limited, dumping. The simplest of its many forms is
that in which all factory prices are the same and the freight from
the basing point to the buyer is added to all. Producers outside the
basing point therefore charge their customers more or less than the
actual freight, according to circumstances. Only thus in the limiting
case can all producers compete at the same price for every buyer
They will not do so in
(quality rather than price competition)
.
reality, of course,
if,
they had to absorb more freight than would correspond to the profits
from near-by customers plus the share in the fixed costs (m)
In
addition, the permissible freight absorption will sometimes be still
.
G. Seidler, "
Competition,"
37.
1936)
The
NRA,
won
at all
by dumping,*"
it
will
Division of Review,
p. 229;
(English ed.,
p. 309.
This
is
Some New
Factors
159
On
(dd)
basing point)
and
area.
area
zuill
Uniform
Prices.
(profit plus
then the
tariff in a uniform transport area the market area will then be bounded by a hyperbola.
This includes the basing point when m and z lie between h and h/2; it becomes a
straight line that passes halfway between factory and basing point when z is equal to.
and m at least equal to, h/2, or vice versa. Conversely, if m or z is smaller than h/2,
the hyperbola includes the factory site. In the latter case, however, not only will no
freight
more
will
advantage:
see,
p.
27).
On
the size of an area supplied to special advantage: Besides the area that a factory
is willing to supply at all, that part of an area that
of interest; or,
will supply
with
less
are
than when freight is charged from the factory. The dividing line passes halfway
between factory and basing point if the price policy in both places is the same; that is,
if they either charge the same uniform f. o. b. price or if both discriminated starting
On
criminatory
f.
if
o. b. prices at
result in higher
f.
o. b.
will
site
of the
equal prices are charged from the basing point and disthe factory, the area in which charges via the basing point
prices
is
widened (provided
itself lies
z,
excentrically
m ^ h)
is
an
f.
Only
o. b.
in
an ellipsoid
more
price policy
advantageous.
41.
With
The
ellipse
uniform basing-point
price,
differ-
Producers
who
point, but toward the basing point they discriminate too strongly against neighboring
buyers.
of rising, though
Economic Regions
Part Two.
j5o
Nevertheless,
it
chosen as advantageously
as possible, or as small as
possible.**
(ee)
and
tion of old
of
new
enterprises, that
is,
efforts to
The competiexpand, or to
We
Thus C
is
is
as small as
demand
This
is
F and C
for
and Pa the uniform c. i. f. price, DPq will determine the sales and TP^ the f. o. b. price
and the marginal revenues in the individual localities (points of intersection with
EP^ gives the discriminatory factory
do, di, and do, and Uq', Ui', and u^' respectively)
prices for the case where aggregate sales are as they are with C and F. The marginal
revenues from all buyers are the same (Q, 7?,5) only with A; with T {M,R,W) and
C (A^, R, T) on the contrary, they are partly too high and partly too low to permit
an equally advantageous exploitation of the demand, and thus an equally large profit.
.
Some New
161
Factors
It was assumed in
possible prevails only in an open market.
Chapters 9-12 that the limit had been reached when the area was
so diminished that the demand curve at a uniform factory price was
tangent to the cost curve. With any further decrease the enterprise
would no longer cover its cost, unless it adopted the expedient of
Fig. 45.
form
f.
that
is,
unless
it
demanded
different
Comparison of price discrimination (0), uniprice (V), and (X) uniform c. i. f. price
o. b.
To
Thus
determine the smallest market area and the most favorable price therein,
is no longer made to intersect the current highest marginal
revenue but the lowest possible one, and thus the one that is valid for the smallest
possible number of places. It need not be the lowest absolutely, if in such a small
and
C and
F,
is
With
Part Tivo.
,(j2
in full operation
it
independent enterprises
to multiplication of
Economic Regions
is
and
their markets?
Here
C and
F,
once more to my
forthcoming " Geographie der Preise." Only this need be said here: That marginal
revenue curves should be identical is entirely consistent with the fact that the total
There would be
so
much
will be
more
same
further reduced until in both cases profits have disappeared despite price
discrimination.
sales it raises
itself.
It is
consumed. Price discrimination occurs even though its purpose is thus thwarted. The
example of monopolies almost without teeth, that
may
and
yet be unable to
make
excess profits,
because the areas that they control absolutely are too much restricted from without.
47. W. Launhardt, Mathematische Begrilndung der Volkswirtschaftslehre (Leipzig,
1885)
48.
pp. 161
ff.
H. Hotelling,
" Stability in
ff.
With geographical
and
Some Nevj
163
Factors
and
legal
Concerning
a^:
Dumping
his
own
profitability
dump, then
in a neighboring area
Concerning 03: The following holds true for price discrimination. As the aggregate
marginal revenue curve is shifted to the left with the diminution of an area, its intersection with the marginal cost curve also moves toward the left. According to whether
the new point of intersection is higher or lower than the old, the new factory price at
the geographical boundary will be higher or lower than before. In the
new equilibrium
the average costs, which generally rise with decreased sales, exceed the factory price at
Marginal
lies
costs.
the revenue in the boundary zone. Indeed, this certainly will not be the case,
and the
The
compensate one another. Together they make it possible to decrease the necessary market
area far more than without price discrimination. The diminution proceeds until the
average costs are so high above the factory prices prevailing in the boundary zone that
the deficit in fixed costs is only just covered by the surpluses in the interior.
Concerning b: How are a stable price and market to be found? The matter is not
so simple that one need only advise that half the freight be added to the costs. For
the costs depend upon the size of the area also, and this is still unknown. Following
the example of Walras with his " prix crie par hasard " in a one-point market, would
it not be possible to start from a boundary accidentally held between areal markets?
Each would then determine the most favorable starting price on the basis of his costs
and his share of the demand (A' in Figure 41) Whoever was cheaper than his competitors because of this starting from an arbitrary boundary would as a rule have to
move the boundary back until prices were equal there. It is improbable either that
the cheaper seller should retreat of his own accord, or that the boundary (like price
in the Walrasian market) should be jointly changed. Each, rather, would eagerly hope
for a market area of the most advantageous extent, no matter whether or not his
competitors were located in it; whether he would therefore have to drive them from
the market or share it with them. According to this boundary, as he imagines it, he
sets his starting price, only to find that he has begun with too large an area, since his
competitors will underbid him before he reaches that boundary. Each one, therefore,
has higher costs and smaller revenues than he calculated, so each generally lowers his
sights as to the desirable market area and usually raises the price. Each gropes his way
toward the equilibrium point where boundary and boundary price coincide. Is there
only one such boundary and boundary price? The curve of delivered prices at the
"
boundary for all boundary points on the line connecting " I " and " II " at which " I
can aim, cuts the corresponding curve for " II " only once if the boundary price changes
monotonically with shifting of the boundary which upon closer examination appears
to be the rule. When each stops struggling and cannot expect more than mere existence
where there is a strong tendency to independence stable equilibrium reigns.
.
Part Two.
i6^
2.
(aa)
Economic Regions
Effect
the most profitable market area is larger, that necessary to existence equal to or smaller than with F or C. Hence, in industries
to which there is free entry, locations will often lie closer together
their goal
is
When
c.
lose;
i. f.
but
costs
does not coincide with the basing point they move, like all plants,
toward it.^^ The more evenly all competitors in a market area share
the demand, the more nearly do the points of least c. i. f. costs for
all coincide. They agglomerate until some costs of production rise
so much because of the concentration that some plants migrate to
another point of agglomeration. Only when industries voluntarily
concentrate in a smaller market area (which will generally be more
advantageous) does there arise a tendency to disperse from the
basing point, and to settle more densely the farther they scatter.
Whether dispersion or new agglomeration is the final result, migration from the basing point is probable.^*
For the buyers in the industry whose price policy is under con53.
by
its
who
Here
is
adherents.
An
can nowhere be
(quota)
now has
,
passed unnoticed
pane diagram, especially when the prices of many production factors are geographically
leveled by rate schedules and stabilized. The minimum transport need not be at the
site of
consumption.
move from
It is
is
According
petition
to A.
R. Burns the capacity of the iron and steel industry from 1916
to 1931 rose
It
increased thereby.
Some New
165
Factors
They may be
the production
site,
but
this
likely to
is
attracted to
and
especially
be overshadowed by a
host of other factors. Policy C, like the basing-point system, eliminates not only the influence of the producer's location on prices,
but also the influence of prices on the location of the consumer.
Within the
(bb)
sales area
Effects
A comparison with
almost always results in higher
with free entry, a greater number of independent enterit is more advantageous for the entrepreneur, whereas
in lower c. i. f. prices, and so on the average favors
always
results
F
the consumer.^^ Only distant consumers fare better with A, and
better still with C, because here freight is absorbed; those living
near the factory, on the other hand, pay higher prices (see Fig. 45)
With the basing-point system and with policy C much waste through
profits and,
Thus
prises.^^
cross-haulings
/?.
is
likely,^^
which
Price Differentials
raises prices.
among
Market Areas
Different
for all
55. A. Losch,
56.
(in
preparation)
with C.
to interpret this to
c. i. f.
price
mean
is
that the
lowest with
and C, but
demand curve
F and highest
also they are
located
58.
and
This
in
is
which
easily seen,
must be a matter
is
of indifference
they order.
hyperbola.
lie
with
Part Two.
i56
important
case.
Finally,
if
Economic Regions
are curves of the fourth degree.'^ The boundary lines become still
more complicated if the straight mileage tariff is replaced by a
graduated
The
tariff.
situation
is
except that they are, so to speak, the mirror image of industrial sales
areas. If the boundaries of the latter are projections of sections of
price funnels, agricultural boundaries originate in the intersection
of price cones. Again the case of equal freight rates, but different
prices at the centers, is the most important one. Figure 46 shows the
price cone for three places, A, B, and C, and above S the industrial
mirror image. In exactly the same way that B, as an industrial place,
would be excluded from sales if the price there were equal to the
price at A plus the freight costs from A to B, it would be prevented
from supplying agricultural products if the price at B were equal
only to the price at A less the freight from B to yl.^ Just as the
is
line DG" forms the upper limit of industrial production, so
the lower limit for agricultural production at the price in B. The
larger a town, the higher the market price of agricultural products
in it. Assuming that the population of A doubled, the price of milk,
in order that the milkshed could
say, would have to rise above
increase at the expense of town B. B, too, would experience a price
increase, but by a smaller absolute amount because its population
has remained the same. Consequently the branches of its bounding
hyperbola will be more compressed: it carves out for its own needs ^
DG
AD
their vertices
that their foci lie about in the middle of the areas that they enclose.
way
demand is greatest.
59. W. Launhardt has
For then
then
already
shown
this
f.)
(Beitrdge zur Standorttheorie [Uppsala, 1935], pp. 223-230. See also his Fig. 193, p. 363).
Moreover, A. Schilling
("
from the economic front outward by the amount of the freight costs.
were on a traffic route that connected A with its hinterland.
A. Predohl (" Die ortliche Verteilung der amerikanischen Eisen- und Stahl-
which
price,
rises
60. Unless
61.
demand
for steel,
As long
(Pittsburgh)
as
(Chicago)
producer determine the price until Chicago produces enough, and more than enough.
Some New
Factors
167
woyyw
Fig. 46.
It is different
uniform
c. i. f.
If
price, different,
up
around towns
mirror image
however, from
would extend
their
to the
and
it
demand
will
have
No
at the Pittsburgh-plus-price.
its
own
Then
sales area.
established reacts
Part Two.
j58
2.
Although
Economic Regions
to
who
similar products.*'
63.
The
themselves.
difference
may
lie in
and with therp the price for the same product, vary
In the more expensive shops one pays for the
of making a number of other purchases at the same time, for their better
Retail trade margins,
equipment with
all
and so on.
most immediate neighborhood, if the factory is in a small
For in an unrestricted area most of the demand would then come from a
place.
Not
medium
necessarily the
65.
" Strength
66.
and
is
Some New
Factors
169
both for and against a manufacturer: for him because he can invade
the field of his competitors in spite of freight costs; against
more favorable
him
he cannot
keep the competition of similar goods entirely out of his home
area.^ The more unique an article is and the fewer substitutes it
has, the less does it have its market entirely to itself.*^^ But for the
same reason its market area is very much larger than if all its buyers
lived in the same place. How many sales areas overlap may be
realized from the great variety of goods carried by retail dealers.
Entrepreneurial activity also can be understood spatially. Small
improvements extend the home sales area at the expense of competitors and make it more concentrated. New or greatly improved
goods capture their market at the expense of all old goods together.
Thus the development of the automobile took place at the expense
because, in spite of his
freight position
phenomenon. The more local, national, or even racial cultures surthe more wide differences give way to harmless
of the described
memory
entirely;
67. It
but in
were
this
hard to
is
competition, as
is
real,
it is
few idiosyncrasies
They were
if
the
more do
separated as long
so often asserted.
dialects, a
of a different past;
senseless
It
seems to
the inefficient.
if
not harmful
me
that
it
Sensible though
when
inefficient
intensifies
it
off
competition for
may be
have real
to
for
often be standardized.
in relation to the producer's price, so that for this reason alone overlapping
is
restricted
narrower border region. With high-quality goods everything often depends upon
specific properties of the raw material, which then is ordered from a great distance
even though ordinary grades may be plentiful enough. Thus hundreds of German
to a
places can supply clay, but only one can furnish the clay needed for the
making
of
and subtle
larger places
Zimmerman,
"
with
less
See,
for
example, C.
by larger
and partly
to
new
customers.
Part Two.
Economic Regions
market
economic
area.
on the
If,
contrary, this was too small even for the first entrepreneur (i. e.,
intersect)
if he could not make the demand and the cost curves
as
3.
With public
had encouraged during the past century.'* Something similar is true for important raw materials.'^
But only competitive tariffs follow general rules. Next to a drop
in the level of freight rates to about 1/10,'^ differential railway rates
tion of the forests
70.
For example,
steel,
salt,
sugar,
and
so on.
Even here,
to
be
of certain kinds of coal better than others. To this extent there is still some overlapping. But the cores of the sales areas of the various coal fields are distinct.
71. Especially
sive
goods
(see
The
72.
with busy stretches, moderate distances, small shipments, and expenIn these cases the competition of the motor truck enters.
note 77)
is
generally
much
overestimated,
and the height of the marginal costs therefore underestimated. With fully employed
equipment every traffic increase must raise costs almost proportionately. It is generally
impossible to justify cheap special rate schedules of wide applicability with low marginal costs. I shall discuss this subject in more detail in another book.
73. When, in 1924, the cheapest railway kilometer for the cheapest commodity was
about 1 per cent of the most expensive kilometer for the most expensive commodity,
the one was obviously subsidized
profitable.
Sombart, Die moderne Kapitalismus, II (1919) 1143 ff.; Ill (1927) 98 f., 122.
75. Other things being equal, the use of machinery must nevertheless decrease with
the distance from coal, and so must the production of low-quality mass-produced goods
74.
W.
with distance from raw material; on the contrary, the importance of poorly paid labor
of high quality
'76.
W.
in ihrer
1940)
must
increase.
Sombart, op.
cit.,
p. 25.
II, 345.
P. Schulz-Kiesow,
industriellen Standort
und
Die Eisenhahngutertarifpolitik
die
Raumordnung
(Heidelberg,
New
Sotne
171
Factors
according to product
^^
significant
change for the location pattern since the exit of the horse and
wagon, which, like the autotruck, charged freight essentially in
proportion to weight and distance.
Local Differences in Tariffs
a.
1.
The
volume
elasticity of the
of
traffic
For
each place.
If
OP
traffic
if
volume
rate
is
of traffic
is
zero
is
of
when
would be
if
PQ
(in Figs.
Thus
If Cq, Ci, 62
The
away a place
all traffic.
volume
20 and 47)
(Fig. 47)
and
so on, are
the farther
suffices to
demand
prevent
curves for
flatter
and
77.
From
much cheaper by
important: whether
The
new production
the pound.
is
transportability of
price
the
rate
traffic
is
will bear."
The
level,
costs,
costs.
The
The
total surplus
must be
at least
Part Two.
172
Economic Regions
Volume
Fig.
47.
tiation
for
of traffic
goods
and
spatial
freight
under
free competition, the latter just covers the costs, the tariffs
lies at
tariff.
Hence
it
But
if
may
suffice.
tariff
en-
courages
naturally extends)
80.
M. Keir
("
Economic Factors
influence
on the
in the Location of
Manufac-
Academy
its
of Political
and
Social Sciences,
Sofne
New
i73
Factors
c.
upon small
differences
price.
i. f.
overlap.^-
2.
tariff.
thought
a rich ore pays less freight per unit of yield (unit of useful content)
What
is
ship the same product under different freight rates? In generAl two
things may be said. First, the product with the lower tariff cannot
be entirely excluded from sale, whatever its factory price may be.
Even though it is displaced at its own production site by anothei
article that can be made much more cheaply, with a sufficiently
large possible sales area a point is nevertheless reached at some distance where the delivered price of the product paying the lower
rate falls below that of the other.** Second, the sales area of the
place with the higher tariff will be surrounded by that of the other.
It is
factory price.
It
may
coincide.
The
the actual
p. 365.
As the result of a fairly good investigation J. Schmitz calculated that this point is
reached for the brewing industry at a sales radius of about 47 miles. {Das Standortprohlem in der deutschen Brauereiindustrie, University of Cologne dissertation, 1930, p. 61).
83.
cit.,
p. 228.
Economic Reg-ions
Part Two.
174
/3.
We
come now
to the case
where the
all.^^
tariff is raised
If
minimum
is
or lowered,
falls,
the pos-
necessary
size is decreased.^^
and
as a
85.
in
On
many
86.
tariff
operates
business almost tenfold, but certainly not the economic sales radius.
87. See D. Lardner's century-old Railway Economy
(London, 1850)
W.
p. 14.
Launhardt's paradoxical conclusion, that lower freight rates increase sales areas greatly
{Mathematische Begriindung der Volkswirtschaftslehre [Leipzig, 1885], p. 152) but
,
number
at all
of consumers
industrial sales
it
(ibid., p. 177)
(i. e.,
schaft
88.
so
(Berlin, 1934)
much
Of course
as the individual
more expensive
is
is
An example
is
maps
is
in
the extension of
in Weltwirtschaft,
p. 73.
to infinity.
89. Similarly,
and with C
upon
monopolistic industries.
and
rest
1934, p. 15,
the sales area expands for goods that are cheaper to produce but
to ship (Fig. 3)
Agricultural materials, for example, are more
quently processed at some central location.
.
fre-
the
Some New
^75
Factors
within "
"
competition, however, may now have to arise
immobile
because
at the location of the cheap factories
The new
that
is,
Launhardt has formulated this double effect of cheaper freights with classic brevity.
Reduction of freight rates decreases the importance of distance. " Mastery over space
has been extended, and all activities that were hampered in their development by
spatial restrictions have been broadened and advanced in consequence; on the other
"
hand, all that required the protection of isolation have been curtailed and enfeebled
(ibid., p.
91.
206)
now more
Thus
sharply developed.
the effects of a
Agricultural production
is
and ocean
materials,
made
freights,
it
this
had flourished
many
places.
If
for
many raw
soil
materials from
becomes thus more
by nature.
on consumption, lower freight
country plays
it is
On
93.
The
the other hand, the artificial leveling of wages nowadays raises the impor-
Economic
Part Two.
176
Regio7is
Now
increased.
A2 intersects
tt^,
profitable.
Now,
v\^/^
^
\
\
Y'
Fig.
48.
Effect
economies on
jij
^;s.
<^\^2
Amount
of
size of
new
large-scale
market area
together:
TTi
first,
at a certain
An
more
producer.
further reason
number
why many
who
find
it
may be
possible to
employ
their capabil-
ities
to a
cities;
either
lowering of prices.
95.
They belong
(3)
(1)
increase in population;
to
coal;
(4)
the exhaustion of
mechanization;
locations,
(6)
lowering of freight
rates.
These
factors
(5)
further
(3, 5)
large
and
Some New
^77
Factors
the two coincided (which certainly was not mere chance) the fate
of those worlds in miniature whose unquestioned center was a
princely residence, a small rural town, or often only a manor house,
,
At
it
all
whole that in
grasp,
its
much more
abstract.
The
at first
much more
difficult to
quiet corners remote from the metropolis but, much more important, in the metropolis itself. The unmanageable specialization in
central functions impeded not only their close touch with the rural
areas,
were
fulfilled
selected sites
cities
W.
IIIl.A (1927).
H. Ritschl, " Reine und historische Dynamik der Erzeugungszweige," Schmollers Jahrbuch, 1927. P. Schulz-Kiesow, Die Eisenbahngutertarifpolitik
in ihrer Wirkung nnf den industriellen Standort und die Raumordnung (Heidelberg,
(1922); 113.
1860.
(1919);
Tiibingen, 1922.
1940)
The expansion
many markets
of
Beginning with
on socage farms and in villages) continued by urbanization
(guilds against rural crafts) and accelerated by mechanization (factory against crafts)
(large against small enterit ended with the double-edged victory of mass production
prises) that results here and there in a reduction in the size of markets (controlled
markets and autarky)
96. The subordination of a once independent center to a larger one, or of a dependent center to a different main center, affects the central upper stratum most severely,
greater chain of developments that was, however, not free of reverses.
specialization
(handicrafts
for with
97.
it
Or accepted
it
only in externals.
that
is
98. See,
Chicago: "
for example,
The
E.
to
of
2.
Economic Regions
Part Two.
i>j8
be asked whether food grown in the very soil on which we live may
not agree with us better, and the most recent investigations tend
to favor this view.
To
Though
effect of
lower freight
economic
size.^^
areas,
rates:
under
reduction in freight
however, not their
geographical distribution.
b.
1.
remain
as
NATURAL DIFFERENCES
Local Differences
We now dismiss
they were.
in
Producti vit y
i<>^
fact
that nature
and
human endeavor
favors
unequally from place to place. Production, cultivation, or acquisition is possible, according to the manner in which she co-operates:
manufacture or building when nature supplies only resources (industry)
cultivation
when man, on
fertility (agriculture)
and
the other
collection
when
hand
increases natural
may
some rule, or may be entirely uniform over wide areas. The frequency of the first situation causes many to despair of any spatial
99. If it is desired to
it
follows that
district
where conditions of
raw materials)
(except for
incoming freight rates should not be lowered; but (where freight decrease reduces the
one area) the rates within it, or (where freight decrease increases the size of
the area) from it to the rest of the country, should be lowered.
100. Large losses or gains may occasionally be caused by the shift: losses, if necessary
size of
crowded; gains,
if
W. Zimmermann, among
others, in
1933).
Some New
i79
Factors
it
since all
if
from
use
communication.
Regular changes in natural conditions are obviously much less
disturbing,^"^ and by good fortune they are both common and
important. One need only recall the climatic changes associated
with latitude, or the fairly uniform variations in the lines of equal
precipitation over wide stretches of the earth's surface. Precipitation
is of definite importance in the United States, for example, where
it decreases from east to west; or in southwest Australia, where it
decreases toward the interior. Natural gradients such as these can
be found even in zones that appear economically uniform. Thus
harvest time in the American cotton belt varies (or shifts) with fair
regularity from early July in the south to the end of October in the
north.103
If
first
regions of
more or
less
equal
If
when
with a wholly
two regions may arise that exhibit great regularity within themselves but which are characteristically different.^"*
102. In
like
freight costs, not alternatively, like local advantages that occur without transition.
103.
cities
include
times.
104.
Miinster, Leipzig,
Economic Regions
Part Two.
i8o
Here we are
interested,
first,
First,
^"^
Riickgliederung der
The
XVI
(1939), 1-31.
and
and distance from the center of a landscape, between peace and war economy, and
often between greater and lesser population density, is equivalent to that between
more and less fertile soils. On a more fertile soil the agricultural population is always
denser and (which is not the same) the villages larger (since a small acreage is enough
to
make
possible
than do smaller
106.
They
villages.
more
the possible one. For sales areas on poor soil contain relatively
demand.
Large
bought from nearby
remains tolerable)
as that of the
more
its
approaches
much
elastic
(as
Since the
demand
to
in a
curtailment of the
area by raising prices. Conversely, however, the sales areas in the thinly settled region
enough to result in the same demand at the same factory price as sales
same goods in the other region. They, too, may be curtailed, and an
adequate demand nevertheless be achieved by a lowering of prices.
Figure 49 resolves this apparent contradiction, r^ and r^ are demand curves in a
thickly settled region {R) a^ and a^ in a thinly settled one {A). The necessary demand
in A is DE. The demand curve r^ would result in R in the same demand, DE, at the
price as in A. But the corresponding area would be larger than with the curve r^,
which lies to the left of it and which results in BC, the minimum demand necessary
in R. The same thing holds true when sales areas in A are compared with those in R.
are not large
will
supply area
Moreover, goods
distances.
Some
iSJew
Factors
Second,
if
about the same. Because of their irrational shape, such border areas
are on the whole somewhat larger than interior areas. If sales areas
in the rich region are larger, it is uncertain whether a factory on
the border will attract sufficient demand from the poor region to
fertile region.
Comparison of marand
Fig. 49.
settled
with
regions,
another case of natural differences of an areal kind is imporImagine a large region, A, and a small one, B, wholly similar
in natural features but separated by a wide uninhabited region like
a mountain range, a desert, or a body of water, or by high customs
duties in A. The essential assumptions are the differences in size
and distance. Two further assumptions are economic in character.
First, the planning curve must have a break, as in Figure 48. Thus
there must be two different production methods: large-scale and
small-scale production. Second, only B must be too small for mass
Still
tant.
production.
Under
these conditions
is
large plant.
B may
be situated in
its sales
and supply A
as well.
area,
Economic Regions
Fart Two.
xgo
of the freight.
The
situation
would
suffice to
make
Of
duties."^
approaches
it
all
the
today as
its
fantastic
customs
large
American businesses
if
"
themselves by
customs duties.^"
Uniformly operative natural factors will be more important in
general for agriculture, irregular factors for industry and mining.
But the influence of nature plays a significant role in all branches
"^
of the economy in the formation of " districts " and " belts."
in
far
disadvantages
so
This has both advantages and disadvantages:
as it encourages urbanization and causes an irrational distortion
in the shapes of market areas; advantages in so far as the external
economics that result when similar production is concentrated in
one place need not be purchased by carrying out part of this production under unfavorable natural conditions. ^^-
2.
Local Differences
in
Accessibility
Among
points
is
businesses.
European
109.
110.
dem
The
make
countries,
to the ocean.
Written before the autumn of 1939, but retained in the 1944 edition.W. H. W.
See A. Losch: Selbstkosten- und Standortverschiebungen von Genussgiltern nach
(Berlin,
1934)
(Zwischenstaatliche Wirt-
by H. v. Beckerath, Heft 4)
111. 5. W. Wilcox, Chief Statistician of the Bureau of Labor Statistics in Washington, D. C, told me that an attempt to divide Illinois into areas of similar production
showed a surprising agreement with geological structure, which went so far that regions
where corn was grown for the market, for example, were associated with a formation
different from those where it was used as fodder.
112. It would be so, for instance, if all kinds of soil were evenly mixed everywhere.
schaft, edited
Some New
i3
Factors
It is
of airplanes
113.
and the
carriers,
is
distributed
among
the various
relative size of their loads, see A. Losch, " Die Leistung der See-
114.
lines.
with
highways,
of
more
closely
is
in addition, the
If,
as
costs,
it
it
favors places
In so far as
it
it
may
truck.
cit.,
p. 94;
and Palander,
deutsche Industriekorper
seit
bahngiitertarifpolitik in ihrer
ordnung [Heidelberg,
op.
cit.,
1860 [Tubingen, 1922]; and P. Schulz-Kiesow, Die EisenWirkung auf den industriellen Standort und die Raum-
1940].)
lie
to
the Autobahnen.
more acute
railways;
i.
Autobahnen,
maps
much
to
The
Lines of equal
-greater revolution of
of C. Pirath, "Auflockerung
communication.
See
Three out
Part Two.
i84
Economic Regions
Transport Lines
Fig. 50.
The law
of refraction
and a law based on reason, which shows clearly enough that the
economic principle is not merely a human invention and does
not simply correspond with the attitude of a particular epoch.^^^
It runs through the history of natural science as lex parsimoniae:
the principle of simplest
means or
117. I
to
this
in
my
.
review of Palander
("
Beitrage zur
and admirable accoimt of H. von Stackelberg, " Das Brechungsgesetz des Verkehrs,"
fiir Nationalokonomie und Statistik, CXLVIII, 680-696.
118. On the contrary, it embraces the behavior of some men in almost all situations,
and the behavior of almost all men in some situations: when desire and aversion are
strong (one wants to attain a definite end or avoid it as far as possible pursues every
advantage or high aim; husbands his powers; avoids the unpleasant)
It is otherwise
when we live everything instead of separating means and ends; when we rejoice in
the game; surrender ourselves completely only those can do so who are free of desire
and filled with love. There are two worlds, and we are wanderers between them.
119. Others of our results, too, have their counterparts in nature. What, after all,
are the often sharply separated feeding grounds of various animal families and species,
Jahrbiicher
Some New
185
Factors
= fa\/a^ {c x)^;
=
F
F^
a minimum when
+
+
+ -^^= = Hence U sin ^ - sin a = 0,
F{x)
or ^^"
'^
smj3
-===
yj a^
-\-
= ft
{c
x)-
AE
will then be Fa
x-.
F (x)
-\-
is
y/h^-\-x-
site
of the harbor
jE.
the
If
fa
is
and
the
main direction
made
may be
as short as possible.
is
if
New
H
N
beam
and
from
number
Part Two.
i86
load of pineapples
possible.
The
is
to be shipped to
New
Economic Regions
Orleans as cheaply as
is,
the
more it resists the passage of a beam of light the more will the
beam be deflected (path I instead of path II) Exactly so, were
there no Panama Canal today, would a connecting railway be chosen
between Pacific and Atlantic ports that would be more southerly
the higher the rail tariff in comparison with the ocean freight. At
,
Fig.
51.
Schematic representa-
(H) to
New Orleans
from Hawaii
(N) via
Panama
is
stated thus:
Whether the
cost of a canal
number in
Hence the
objections to the
law in question.
However, the objections are less important here because transport
lines, with which we are now dealing, are considerably less numerous
than transport points. In the case of ocean traffic between the east
and west coasts of America, for example, it can be said, despite the
numerous harbors and innumerable points of departure and arrival,
that in the neighborhood of the Central American isthmus at least
there are only one or two transport lines. But if the traffic of the
Some New
^7
Factors
west coast of South America with Europe and with the east coast
of North America is added, there will be several lines, and for each
one a somewhat different situation of the Panama Canal would be
more advantageous. Since it would not pay to have a special canal
for each transport line (quite apart from the fact that the choice
severely limited for technical reasons) the location
of the present cut is a compromise. The higher the fixed costs of
overcoming an obstacle to traffic and the greater the number of
of locations
is
transport lines that have to surmount it, the more does the law of
refraction lose in significance. It cannot be applied to a group of
must be regarded
is,
to
as like
^.
Transport Points
Among
tance.
transport points the nodal points are of special imporThey are more favorably situated in respect to freight than
is
why
Among
and
trade.
way leading into the Bohemian and Hungarian basins, and into
south Germany. The narrower the pass and the more important
the market lying behind this natural gateway, the nearer to it will
industries with large necessary sales areas establish themselves, other
things being equal; but they will pass through
a larger market
on the other
it
only
when
there
is
side.
121.
but for
crossing the
Part Two.
jgg
Economic Regions
problem
special
different markets
to the
Hence
^^^
as possible.^^^
Palander
river port
^-*
is
problem, and
sites.
This holds true for smaller market areas, whereas a gateway merely constricts
In general, therefore, countries separated by mountain chains are eco-
larger ones.
nomically
less closely
is
a sufficient reason
why Wiirttemberg
123.
This
for instance,
is
especially important
when
is
not
much
longer than the necessary one. Furthermore, port installations are cheaper on a river.
124.
Op.
cit.,
p. 349.
Some New
i9
Factors
smaller and
the nearer part of the hinterland individual farmers, who are espefrom the railway, or own poor soil, or lack ability, will
cially far
now
The important
spatial relations
is
freight.
But
it
is
to
reality.^^
Even
if
we
neglect
125.
When
wheat
is
is
locally
may
exist
A may be above
difficulties,
many
but also partly to slight product differences and partly to the fact that
and sometimes a deficit.
on the
"
World Market
" in
Chapter
23, b, 4.
Part Two.
igo
Economic Regions
all
Then
is
Some New
Factors
191
States,
difference
if
overlapping.
Peru were
With
to get
its
it
entire supply
will only touch, but supply and sales areas will in this case overlap!
(Fig. 52.)
c.
1.
HUMAN DIFFERENCES
In pioneer industries, however, where a rather infrequent combination of characteristics is required, less able entrepreneurs may
also find a place, though they are still above average. Will the abler
producers be content with small sales areas and leave large markets
to the less skillful, who could not otherwise exist? The outcome is
as though all entrepreneurs were competing in the same market:
The well qualified extend their sales areas until at the boundaries,
which now extend farther outward than need be, the price is equal
to that at the
skillful neighbors.
sary, sales
127.
As the
general, so
capabilities of a
the special
abilities
his
can expand
it
Economic Resions
Part Two.
192
In a literal sense they are the ones with the larger sphere of influence.
Since they prefer great cities as locations wherever possible, their
sales areas will be often, and perhaps usually, above the average in
size for this
2.
The
reason alone.
Differences
in
National Character
itself also
in the
way in
which they organize their economic life. But such national differences interest us here only in so far as they operate spatially which
presupposes that the various races and nationalities are not thoroughly intermixed. Where consumption is still rigidly determined
by a common way of life (that is, where it represents a meaningful
group of needs similar for all), tribal, national, and racial differences,
like all differences between regionally confined groups, are of great
economic importance from a spatial standpoint. Then the boundaries
of a tribe or nation are at the same time the boundaries of regional
networks for whole classes of goods. Not much is altered when in
cosmopolitan periods customs and usages relax and become more
similar. But even when they do, and advertising and fashions of the
day instead of established custom attempt to determine consumption,
not all boundaries are obliterated. Many customs are determined by
the character of a landscape, by its history, and perhaps biologically
too,^^^ and can be changed only slowly or not at all.^^^ Thus a native
born entrepreneur can judge more accurately what compromise
with the prevailing fashion will be possible. His solution and his
advertising will correspond more closely with the national or tribal
character, and up to a certain point national boundaries will still
remain economic boundaries.
128. Heredity and landscape affect national character in part directly, in part
through tradition, which also is largely determined by historical chance. For the
influence of landscape see W. Hellpach, Geopsyche (5th ed., 1939)
129. Conversely,
United States
is
how
differences in character
little
its
to a
European
visiting the
first
in consumption, even
sight.
One
American is nature's master and shapes it, rather than allowing it to shape him. This
imposing uniformity (as Ratzel has put it) is one of the sources of America's wealth.
If there were as many cultural differences there within the same space as in Europe,
cheap mass production would be finished. Earnings at least would fall, though psychic
income need not. Incidentally, it is just this economic and cultural uniformity that
makes the strong political position of the individual states so little dangerous to the
Federal Government. Nevertheless, even in the United States the heyday of the
regional
is
only beginning.
So7ne
New
Factors
193
But production,
too,
is
largely influenced
by the individuality of
producers, even when they do not work exclusively for their own
needs. What is produced will naturally depend in great measure
upon the special skill of a people, though it cannot be said simply
Characteristic skills
a priori, since, for example, they often require a suitable task for
Thus
their development.
some
by no means objective
It
is
criteria
differently.
it
is
They
react differently
environment. The
to their human,
diversity of production of a people is determined by how far they
can resist a general leveling. The more they can do so, the less
will they specialize one-sidedly in goods for a larger market.^^^
They will neither simply accommodate themselves to an unfamiliar
demand nor be satisfied with goods that are fashionable elsewhere.^^^
Such loyalty to the native and indigenous has enormous advantages,
do
as they
130.
often
to their natural,
work
real
ff.
and 236
ff.
those of larger
Ability varies
among
the citizens
faster,
The
131.
among
meaning of European
zation.
132. It
is
may
alienate a people
from their
soil.
wood
in the con-
struction of furniture, fruit that has never been seen to ripen, clothing that
for a different climate,
travel
among
cultural
might do
not
is
prepared, a thousand things that are possible against the background of a cosmopolitan
attitude when
all
this
life
of a people,
it.
it
is
difficult
For there
is
to
little
sense in ordering a multitude of goods from afar simply because they are cheaper or
more attractive, as long as one has not found in some way or other a place in one's
world pattern for their individuality, their origin, and their producer. One's horizon
must widen with the expansion of markets. But it would be far from right to hold
that this expansion of markets intrudes upon a people like fate from without. They
themselves decide whether it shall take place at all; it depends on them whether they
are ready for
Of course
to hasten
it.
it.
it
would be
The enormous
dawn
production as
of capitalism
was
only possible because we were willing, on the whole, to accept standardized products
reason
why
possibility
surface.
she has
more
goods. For
Part Two.
,Q^
Economic Regions
far transcending the diminution in economic risk,"^ for it is conducive to a more harmonius development of human nature. The
individual will have to specialize everywhere, but it makes a great
difference whether in his sphere "* there are only associates who
specialize in the same field, or whether he is surrounded by men
who live for him the other possibilities that he has had to forego^^^
that is, whether his horizon constitutes a complete whole.
The expansion
diminish
risks
(see E.
Willeke,
Arbeitskraft
risk con-
itself.
large
Sozialokonomik (2d
ed., 1923)
Vol.
II, Pt.
1.
Some New
Factors
195
property ^" resulting from free divisibility and deliberate policy ^^*
these were not due to chance. Whoever considers thoroughly the
particular nature of the products and production; the highly valuable specialties that can be made only by unusually well-trained
and adaptable workers who like to tinker and experiment; whoever
considers the energetic yet sound business policy that clings to easily
understood and controlled conditions and to enterprises seldom
exceeding the capital and labor resources of one family ^^^ (just as
Wiirttemberg itself in many respects resembles a large family which
has contributed greatly to the easing of social tension and encouraged
the use of native products)
whoever considers
all
"
Grundlagen
fiir
und
economy
Krisenfestigkeit
Wirtschaftskunde,
to
der
(1936)
See also the great atlas of P. Hesse et al., Landvolk und Landwirtschaft in
den Gemeinden von Wurttemberg-Hohenzollern [Kartenwerk) (Stuttgart, 1939); and
several contributions in Weltwirtschaft, 1934, No. 11/2.
138. Ever since 1848 the Zentralstelle fiir Gewerbe und Handel (the present Landesgewerbeamt) fulfilled certain functions of a regional planning office in an exemplary
manner, more recently under the farsighted leadership of Ferdinand von Steinbei'
139. According to 233 official American studies, the largest enterprises are seldom
the cheapest; it is generally the medium-sized and often the small ones (G. J. Stigler,
American Economic Review, June, 1942, Pt. 2)
As for agriculture in Wiirttemberg,
281-298.
the
number
note 53)
The
is
(money
in
p. 65,
1934 amounted
Baden
in Schleswig-Holstein to 88,
und Grosse
and
in
when
is
13.)
In any case, depopulation of the Swabian villages would affect the vitality of industry
through the
loss
himself, typical in so
depopulation
much
is
many
ways,
came
as a peasant
may change
favor-
Part Two.
!<)()
Economic Regions
POLITICAL DIFFERENCES
d.
1,
a.
States
1.
which
its
(Die Wiirttembergischer
Preiser
140. E.
by
their subdivisions
2.
p. 79)
Similarities
capital
as centrally as
Wirtschaft
toward
oriented.^**
ah Vorbild
possible,
[Stuttgart,
1937],
it
for
is
and
Thus
it is
mediate condition
144.
may be
an example.
normal
temberg
as
The Swabians
The
German
language
Some New
Factors
197
out the whole area and that local locational advantages are not
everywhere the same.
3.
equal
common
size is
to both states
The
districts
size of states
and market
areas,
po'^ver.
If
The former
The influence of centers always grows less toward the periThe capitals and their immediate surroundings differ more
sharply from each other than do the border regions. Just as we
7.
phery.
station
Bavarian because they are oriented toward Munich both politically and culturally; this
especially true of teachers and clergymen, who are so important in the evolution of
is
a language.
145. F. Ratzel, Politische
146. Ibid., p. 282.
p. 221.
Economic Regions
Part Two.
jqg
Thus
political
and economic
Dissimilarities
/3.
They
more
1.
are not
2.
so easily
rigid than
economic boundaries.
changed.
daries.
like
economic boun-
oases,
for this.
On
make
same time concrete units that " collide in space " and
to whom distance therefore means something. On political frontiers
two organizations meet, and often two nations large and in certain
and are
at the
whom
distance changes
little
or nothing.
With
changes.
147. Especially since the two political principles that are so important to world
trade balance of power and differentiation between war and peace were abandoned
(See W. Euken, " Staatliche Strukturwandlungen und die Krisis
after World War I.
des Kapitalismus,"
WeltzvirtschaftUches Archiv,
XXXVI
[1932.],
297-321, particularly
p. 309.)
148. See
Grenzen "
149.
W.
Ratzel, op.
cit.,
p.
451;
in der wissenschaftlichen
Sulzbach,
Rationales
Gemeinschaftsgefiihl
und
wirtschaftliches
Interesse
(Leipzig, 1929)
150.
and
Thus
tariffs at
List's
Some New
Factors
199
The
4.
goals of
If
those for states are arranged in a descending order as follows: continuance, power, Kultur, prosperity, this order must be exactly
Political
human
nomic landscapes
may be
than
if
On
which are
151. In the
belongs because of
artificial
its
situation.
is
state
The
is
entire state
becomes a market by
assured by protective
tariffs
it
an
and made profitable by
itself,
Part Two.
200
Economic Regions
traffic,
as
is
traffic,
especially
common among
country
folk,
2.
Economic Areas
as Basis
We shall begin our investigation by sketching at least the influence of an economic area on the state, and conclude with a more
minute analysis of the inverse relationship. It need hardly be men152.
Thus
tariffs
The
length-
ening depends partly upon the tariff level and partly upon the way in which duties
The effect
are collected (a frontier can be crossed only at certain designated points)
.
town
is
similar.
Some New
Factors
201
Empire in
Size
make
interest
The
(free trade)
reason to enlist
to
do
so increases.
154. See
M.
(Leipzig, 1930)
Rostovtzeff,
,
Next
GeseUschaft
und
Wirtschaft
im romischen Kaiserreich
2 vols.
cit.,
pp. 356
ideological
and
ff.
homogeneity, the fact that its economic disis undoubtedly the most important cause
of the tenacious cohesion of the British Empire.
(See A. Losch, " Die Leistung der
156.
tances are
to
much
its
shorter than
its
racial
geographic
schaftliches Archiv,
XXXIX
(1934)
1/12, p.
3.
Part Two.
o,,^
Ecoiioinic Regions
It
3.
A political
it is
hard to
frontier
cross.
is
This
an economic boundary
is
regularly true
when
it
also
when by nature
Though
it is
is
which
is
cheaper, though not quicker, than if the stream were solid land.
But there is no doubt that on the opposite bank the sale of many
medium
shipping distances is made extraso the wider the river and the
158.
This
refers
to natural boundaries.
all
trade
impossible, nor does every natural obstacle have to be turned into a political frontier.
Thus
It is sufficient
its size
suitability of
its
opinion Solch asks too much of natural boundaries in his otherwise admirable
work (J. Solch, Die Auffassung der " naturlichen Grenzen " in der wissenschaftlichen
In
my
Some New
203
Factors
dates itself to the economy. On the other hand, it shifts the necessary
foreign trade as much as possible to easily safeguarded markets, and
here the economy has to adjust itself to the policy of the state. Only
4.
BY State Boundaries'^"
Larger market areas are always transformed along political frontiers, and all areas are changed where the borders represent merely
man-made obstacles to trade. We can classify these changes into:
first, destruction of locations or their removal away from a boundary,
What has already been sketched in comparing political and economic boundaries may now be supplemented. '^'' Figure 53 shows
at the left a few typical situations at the border of economic landscapes; at the right, at the border of two countries. The relative
position of the regions on either side of the landscape varies,
depending on their size and other factors. Since they are oriented
toward different centers, they do not necessarily dovetail with each
other. The political boundary, on the other hand, necessarily cuts
through the regular networks of market areas unless
coincide with an economic boundary.
159.
When
Nutzen
vision
it
is
economically
profitable.
zuirtschaftlicher Grossriiume
of
(in
See
p.
339,
it
happens
and Losch,
to
Wesen und
.
The
pro-
Some raw material obtainable only beyond the frontier may suddenly acquire significance, or an invention may be made there that may be more threatening than any
lack of raw material, which often can be made synthetically or for which a substitute
There will never be absolute safety in any region smaller
must also be considered that as the space grows in size more
defensive measures are needed and more means of defense provided, for larger empires
have to reckon with more powerful adversaries. The development of one great space
starts that of another. All depends upon which increases more rapidly the need for
the means of security, or their supply.
160. For transformation within states especially through the enormously important
can frequently be found.
itself.
It
The
ff.
paragraph and the next four paragraphs are from the first
German edition of Die rdumliche Ordnung der Wirtschaft, which were omitted from
the second edition to save space. Ed.
160a.
rest of this
Part Two.
204
Economic Regions
eti
Fig. 53.
Economic and
political borders
and
7.
off
now
its
left,
face
Soi7ie
New
Factors
>
These derived
area,
next higher
number
if
the surplus
good in question
to
is
sufficiently
move
into the
size class,
of areas.
^}j 165
is
added
surrounded by a region of especially numerous overmay be consolidated, more enterprises can exist here than at any other point along the border.
162. The enterprise locating at the border will select that side of the border where
the empty space is larger; or, if it is not much smaller, where higher tariffs com161.
Such
lapping and atrophied market areas. But, as the pieces of three regions
size.
H. Chamberlin shows the same thing for a boundary beyond which there
are no more markets (The Theory of Monopolistic Competition [Cambridge, Mass.,
163. E.
Adjustment
product concerned to
when
rise to
number
the surplus
is
large
enough
is,
size,
for all
but too
not
This
much
reaching
less
it.
is
is
than half the radius of the landscape, without the possible sales distance
Ptirt
2o5
Two.
Economic Regions
prevent market areas from extending beyond them, industries occupying gaps are still less common and market areas still larger. The
number of unobtainable products is greater, too. For example, the
The
kind and
up
when low
added
to the
purchase price than when these charges are high. Second, there must
be added to the customs duties all the annoying formalities at the
border, which cause many small enterpreneurs to give up all foreign
trade.
third,
and
when
number
between a
is
the technically
of border crossings.
seller
and
his
The resulting
customers
is
relatively
13.
is
large
an Adjoining State
enough
there
is
industry
B.
If
166.
is
B were
to introduce a high
its
the special
The
which typically have a short sales distance, is calcuon wholesale goods from the much lower middleman's price. This makes no difference to the ultimate consumer if the retail margin
on either side of the border is the same percentage of the purchase price inclusive of
167.
tariff
on
retail goods,
tariff.
Some Xru'
207
Factors
may be
The
country
is
doubly harmed:
it
loses
openings for
its
y.
Economic Width
Boundary
of a
is
cit.,
p. 331, Fig.
may be
83
and
able to export.
If
S equals
text.
P''*
2o8
Ecnnomic Regions
Two.
maximum
(1)
The width
but
boundary is
scapes,
of a
boundary
is
The
(2)
all
effect
economic land-
of an economic
felt
5.
^''^^
These are economic areas that exist only because there are states,
and hence, as a rule, coincide with these states. Most important is
the area over which an economic order based on politics extends.
quite conceivable that every state may have its own special
In the face of such fundamentally different political beliefs the world-wide acceptance of
It is
no means
a fore-
When
state frontiers
agricultural products also are artificially diverted from their natural markets.
This
is
hardest for the farmers concerned, but affects those economic landscapes as well that
have been deprived of their natural boundary zones. Even a large state benefits only
to a limited degree from this diversion. Because of increased agricultural supplies
the per capita income of the inhabitants of its central economic landscape is higher
than if state frontiers and economic boundaries coincided; but the per capita income
in the
The
boundary seam, and that of all citizens of the state taken together,
boundary thus appear in agriculture exactly as in industry.
is
lower.
costs of a
is
therefore
more important
H. von Beckerath,
" Politische
und
" Politik
und
tariff policies.
Wirtschaftsverfassung," ibid.,
LVI
(1933)
258-276.
LVI
(1932);
Some New
The
is
209
Factors
second profound
effect that
may
originate from a
country
its
entire
advantageous for such a landscape to rise to statehood, so the damage is at least reduced when a state develops into
an economic landscape. This assumes three things above all: first,
that political boundaries represent a great artificial barrier to trade;
area. Just as
it is
nomic importance;
economic landscape
is
of great eco-
an
share a
common
is
We
political fortune.
may
exert
upon the
and the
It is wise, also,
ment
enemy
is
risky.^^^
is
this state,
175.
associated,
It
is
in
many
form of
premium
risk against
that
is
to
which there
is
is
so closely
on
capital.
rate.
no insurance.
(Jena, 1936).
178. Similarly
make
had
effects that
reached at
first
boom with
industry
to
Economic Regions
Part Two.
210
also.
still
to
many
laws,
and
so on.^^^
Finally, in
porarily a
many
homogeneous economic
monetary system
seen in Part
to create regions
The
III.
area.
is
is
The power
normally but
of a
common
slight, as will
be
period and since the last crisis was exceptional. Most tariffs, too,
do not even approach the creation of a national market, or even a
network of purely domestic market areas. As a rule they curtail
only the tips of areas that extend over a boundary. Moreover, there
will be pointed out below some further limitation of the old thesis
that production factors are less mobile internationally. If it was
wrong formerly to underestimate the importance of political factors
in developing economic areas, we should not forget today, on the
other hand, that this is, after all, but one influence among several.
179.
The method
of
computing taxes
affects,
example,
for
the
construction
of
automobiles.
180.
181.
XXXII
(1930)
For the
many
trade barriers
between individual states in the United States see Works Progress Administration, The
Marketing Laws Survey, Comparative Charts of State Statutes Illustrating Barriers to
Trade Between
States
(Washington, D. C, 1939)
Chapter
14.
effects of
individual factors
were examined. This chapter will discuss all the different factors
that work together toward the same end: to limit the extent of
narket areas.
It is a
many
will
is
But where freight costs are of little importance, competition by itself would hardly influence the limitation of market
areas and the distribution of production sites. Locations would not
have to maintain a certain distance from one another, and all
market areas would overlap everywhere. Even competition can
exert its limiting effect only by way of freight, or other factors that
operate similarly. Here it is immaterial whether these factors work
by raising prices to the consumer or by lowering the profits of the
competition.
producer.^
to the former.
(a)
distance,
Transport
costs.
and naturally
The
freight rate
a point
is
In such cases the argument that freight costs are insignifithe ground. One thinks here of retail stores, laundries,
breweries, and the like that deliver by motor truck or messenger boy.
With increasing distance from a producer the density of habitations
and the demand of individual customers drop, partly because outside of large cities the density and buying power of the population
decrease and partly because, even with a constant freight rate and
for all the reasons still to be given, both this particular producer's
proportionate share of customers and the inclination of individual
customers to buy become smaller. As a consequence the time of
the motor truck or of the messenger boy is less and less efficiently
employed with increasing distance, and there remains only a choice
is
zero.
cant
1.
falls to
und
first
used by V. Furlan,
"
Curves for
Die Standortprobleme in
(1913).
Economic Regions
Part Two.
212
Among
higher freight
rates.
ance and
and unloading, since these are fixed
costs.
Time
(b)
costs.
whom
a distant factory
is
not a reserve
as loss of
Selling costs.
The
distance.
a market
too
Business
little
is
also greater.
risks.
attention
is
Idiosyncrasies.
of their
so on.
Thus
own
the
to the character-
and
neighborhood are not
demands
of a
more
distant
so easily met.
2.
articles.
It
may
even determine location, as E. M. Hoover has shown in his admirable study of the
shoe industry. Location Theory and the Shoe and Leather Industries
Mass., 1937)
3.
(Cambridge,
p, 176.
According to German law, payment has to be made at the domicile of the buyer
213
Extent of business.
a business entails
after a certain point,
minimum
costs, iDut
it
makes
eventually.
itself felt
(g)
average
Hindrances
to trade.
Sooner or
most goods
The
difficulties
of the
more
distant connections.
its immediate costs, distance plays a role
individual and that presupposes thorough
is
men
no longer served
directly,
more
hold large or
can be done only at the
expense of native individuality. Even the proportion of Catholics
in Europe decreases, by and large, with their distance from Rome.^-^
It is
difficult to
as a rule it
Not
narrow
ring.
Mohammedan
Similarly,
among
the people
lie at
the
world.
5. In the field of sociology compare: the sphere of marriage, migrating supply areas
(examples in Bevolkerungshiologie der Grosstadt, edited by E. von Eikstedt [Stuttgart,
Part Tivo.
214
Economic Regions
6.
The
of any
tlieir
own
limits.
Chapter
necessary to
in Reality
SPATIAL ARRANGEMENT
a.
The two
Economic Regions
15.
of both
a complete picture.
1.
Market Areas
2.
Since market areas for the same product overlap, as has just
said, strictly speaking they can no longer be compared with a
been
They
more
carelessly flung
1.
Based
in
are
part on
Economic Journal,
my
(1938)
like
The
down.
lecture,
,
71.
essential properties of a
"The Nature
of
Economic Regions
Two.
Pai^t
2i6
3.
Regional Systems
It
is
often spatially
Spinning mills in the United States are concentrated in the eastern part of the
cotton belt.
3.
One
of the two
The
other
is
is
then to establish
trade with
its
own
economic landscape.
4. O. Schiller ("Die Landschaften Deutschlands," Allgemeines Statistisches Archiv,
XX [1930], 24-41) even goes so far as to maintain that in Germany only the following
cities are morfe or less autocrats in their economic landscapes: Berlin, Stettin, Konigsberg, Breslau, Munich, Vienna, and Stuttgart.
5. Hence they often show extraordinary fluctuations in population. The gold-mining
town of Cripple Creek, in Colorado, for instance, had 45,000 inhabitants in its heyday,
and only
But after the depreciation of the dollar the old mines became
and the population rose quickly to 7,000. (C. Goodrich et al.,
Migration and Economic Opportunity [Philadelphia, 1936], p. 271.)
4,000 in 1930.
Economic Regions
217
in Reality
major
may depend
also
upon
the hierarchy of
administrative areas.
190.)
In the
6.
last case
similar extent; not accidentally, but because these goods represent a meaningful com-
bination.
supply region for cotton gins had a radius of roughly 5 miles, but with their improvement and with better roads the most advantageous size of the supply area increased.
But
this
more advantageous
size of
is
up on
new
cotton
more cotton than those in the old cotton area. (E. S. Moulton, " Cotton Producand Distribution in the Gulf Southwest," U. S. Department of Commerce, Domestic
Commerce Series No. 49 [Washington, D. C, 1931], p. 46)
8. Only the cotton of the Southeast is spun near by, as a rule, which gives rise to
third
tion
many
2i8
P^''^!'
Two.
Economic Regions
whereas in another
case,
it
economic and
political
4.
We
market
10.
MMARY
the matter
9.
SU
more
clearly
and regional
we may speak
systems.
Or
of markets, belts,
to impress
and
districts.
(op.
cit.,
p. 37),
the rival Rhenish-Westphalian centers, thus obtaining a larger economic lanscape that
is split through the center.
On the other hand, see Isenberg, " Zur Stadtplanung in
den neuen deutschen Ostgebieten," Raumforschung und Raumordnung, 1941, pp. 141 f.
How clearly the supply regions for individual partial centers can be separated is
seen in the simple example of the twin cities St. Paul and Minneapolis. Even when
their economic functions in general are at all similar, the regions they control are
clearly distinguished. The hinterland of Minneapolis stretches toward the west, whereas
the more easterly St. Paul commands the east. (See M. L. Hartsough, The Twin Cities
as a Metropolitan Market [Minneapolis, 1925], p. 13. The case of Leeds and Bradford
is similar.
(Stamp and Beaver, The British Isles [London, 1937], p. 573.)
12. Yet, according to K.
Haushofer (" Grosstadtprobleme der Monsunlander,"
Archiv fiir Bevolk., 1942, p. 268) Japan is made up entirely of cells having about the
same shape, and the size of a district; small river drainage basins with urban centers
,
" that
Economic Regions
219
in Reality
The members
of
series
this
complicated, increasingly
ingly
uncommon
self-sufficient, but,
unfortunately, increas-
too.
ON
b.
No
doubt the
CHAOTIC INTERPRETATION
spatial
emphasis on
interpretation
No
may be confirmed by
matter
the
how widely
facts, it is
a chaotic
the long
the reality of the factual. Dangerous because our idea of reality is one
of the factors that shape the future. Had only obstacles to the operation of logical
the
its
dawn
and natural
of capitalism, this
great achievements.
It
it.
Part Two.
220
The
and
roots of anarchy?
despair, a parasite
poral nature of
may
Economic Regions
all
human
But there
it
is
on which
one another and cause tensions but do not destroy
each other's roots. The economic sphere is simply added to the
many other spheres of life that overlap, neither dominating nor
merely tolerated.
geographical, geological, political, racial, religious, and so
interfere with
A. Description of Equilibrium
Chapter 16.
Six Cardinal
THEME
OUR
Seen from
is
of
Labor
man
the standpoint of
it
is
and place.
the problem of the
2.
3.
The problem
The problem
The problem
less
of choice of
an occupation.
of the cooperation of
men
in an enterprise.
(the emigration
G.
The
(the developmental
town)
Here we
discuss only the nature, not the cause, of the division of labor.
In the
would be our old familiar trio: site, supply, and volume; that is,
natural differences in and advantages of mass production or, as Ohlin and Iversen
express it, a lack of mobility and divisibility. A historical treatment would have to take
final analysis the cause
latitude,
nomic
areas.
upon which
is
will
have
to
It forgets,
it
223
Part Three.
224
Trade
The
general at
Fig. 54.
The mathematical
is
infinitely
more impressive
as a solu-
all
We
shall
do
well to recall from time to time the limited validity of our precise
formulas, in order not to overlook the fact that they merely help us
do not provide one.
Even the most carefully considered conclusion is only an experiment after all. It is like shooting when we are neither certain of
the target nor able to test how close we have come to it. In the
last analysis, of course, we say that we have been aiming at the
highest utility, and many believe themselves able to measure it.
But to balk at words would be petty. Utility may signify the general
good as well as personal happiness, and efforts may be directed
toward it either from a sense of duty or by inclination. ^ And yet
we have agreed upon a vague word that any critic will be able to
pick to pieces! The real difficulty in all measurements of utility
2.
But in every
InLerrelaled Problems
,S/x
lies
225
we have no
is.
We
we
live
without inter-
Chapter
The
17.
Six Cardinal
a.
THE OCCUPATION OF
PERSON
What does any given person produce? Official occupational guidance should assign to each one the activity in which he could best
serve the interests of the state. But as long as the state allows free
choice in the matter everyone selects the occupational that he likes
best among those available to him. In so far as his liking depends
upon earnings, there are two ways of deciding on an occupation.
One is the marginal view, as it corresponds to the Walrasian method
of describing equilibrium.
1.
members
(2)
The
in any particular industry that their marginal products are proportional to their wages.
This
'
The
Six
227
tn
lO
(U
1-1
Pri
ings)
.1
-0
ra
so
CO
00
T3
eTr;
r-^
un
oi
10
oi 't
1-J
(u
r-.
"c f^
X!
LO
rj
Tt-_
CO
ti
T-C
T->
T-J
in
in <s
<
T-^
pq
-^
c 2 ^-^
t
-G
n
O '^J ~ -' ^
" S c c
o >^
*j ::;
- ..
nj
fj
U
cu Oh i: Si 3
5
rt
a,
ti
rr 3 3 D,S^5^3
rd
u -S 2 '-<
^ .t;
^ g
"
3 u u ti il I
fi
ti -C
T3uSoc<uti
,,
o ;>
<u
" 2 O
*j tJD 3
V si
c
-g .. o ^ O ^ bO J
.^ 3 ^
I
S-.
CO in
-^ '^'
8 s;;;
^
d
1-^
bD bO bo
TD
""
i3 J3
13 IS !S
in
rt
V
bo
G
LO
II
v-J
^
d
CN
reichs)
^
fe
>-
S C
td
^
Natio
'^
rn
'5
-.2
Hh
u^^ ^ >
Self-s
r-
,-<
r-^
CO
CO
rO
t-h'
rt
G "^ -"
o
ij jj S "
o;^ 3 g
T-H
Z3
1-H
in in
Tj;
in
(^
1-1
T-^
CO
CO
CO in
in
CN
1--
T-;
T-H
in
1-1
<U
'>
1-1
in
Cv]
,-i
<
cO
T-H
it)
3 p c
Ol
>,
Q
u
PQ
<
>
C
o
ducti'
'^
recoi
.2
't!:
i!
,
'-'
^a
.3
'
>-
rt
I-
^
^
6-6
r-
."
-n
-o sS
^.
-5
*j 13 TS
o u
3
> S
ddd
-'SS>
>
.'-'
X!
Si
--
XI
rt
Oj
<U
>-<
>s
5
c
3.-C'
--
^H
>-
.2 r'
OJ
3
Oh u
3
a T3
O gr
(U
<U
H ^
cfl
,^-s
"^
C-
S 3
^
*j
rt
bx)
t
>
-^^
iH
C
2
'
xi
xT
IH 4J
n
QJ
g u
X!
}:!
S
^
<2
*"
o 3
SP
p
c
..
* O
i3
0)
3 3
'^
>-
to
IJ
Oh
rt
tH
3 t3
U _
ri
'^
a 3
CTJ
Oh
-S 2
.- -3
Tl
t:
.3
O 3
CTJ
u
c
O
01
O 3 d 3
3
cj
O
be
Xi
Oh
cu
^
-
C.
3
^
2 S
a -^^ 3
_
3 g
u U
S -^
a> .a
rt
x;
-w
ns
is
?
2 ^2 "
s^
-s.^
^^-3
cu
y
>
"^
'G
;3
cn
00
ii c 1:
3 j3
,,
o e <U
O
<J
o
i2
"5
Ti-
0-
>-i
oj
.r
"^
Si
C ^
T-^
.ti
6 S
C 3
.5
CO c^
<D
(N (N
2 b 2
o ,.
j3
in
I-*
-D
a
B
CI
" 3
djr^jdd
T^
0'
Di
i_(
d^d"^.
;>-
OJ
?;
c
^ lj
V
^
CO <N
T-c
sO
<6
Oi
dt
r^
^ o
.5 -^
.3 X5
a:
^d
p
dd
CO
T^ d
d
22 d
cO CN
00
^s-P
ojecti
73 .y
^3
00 Cn CN
^__^
i-t
T3
^ 3
o o.fq c
>>
tio 3
^ OJ <u _<J
s
'-'
S-H
CO
00
3 3 ?
.5
C d
3 w
CM
(NJ
r- "^
<
cs
-5
CO
CO
CO
CO
ction
Ph
tL]
<u
1 1 ^ Hh^-S
'"'
(iH
s^
C4
2^
bo
0000
0000
r-J
in
rly
(U
Th ts
franc
VO
t^
S
y_,
Show's
^
(U u
-^
3 Oh
with
b
W
Q
x:
dollar
1-;
13
;S
"S
bO
shillin
in
i-i
3^
11
0000
d d
u.y
"
3
J
iJ
o c i^
" " P ;?
3 o
fi
,
^^V.
o g
u^ScuoS--Tj
i-i
j3
.2
0-,
QJ
^r3
.2
>^M-,;_.-^^"flOt>Di>P33.ti
II
II
5?
U-l
(U
i2
*-
c3
g 2
4J
e^
a,
3u-S-S>4;o-
.2
M X!
^o
tJD
C C C C
3
o U
w d i
.3
'
-^
0000
0000
^ 0000
^
S
^
0000
t^>
J3
-C
(U
Cv
U-t
OJ
X>
_>- Oh
- 'b
cut3 a
ra
>
ii
c^
^-I
a
3
j=
"i
lU
r3
QJ
IH
3
w
bo
:a;
Trade
Part Three.
228
^O
^
r^
r- (M
(Nl
fsl
^^
^
Tj-
(S
rH
CO
-^^
r^'
<si
"-^
<N
v^ith
fsl
CSl
-* CO
'* T-
ooo
Labor
IT)
Prices
CS4
^^^
CO
T-^
^"
O O
^
q
CO
of
(Cents)
P9
oO
CO
r00 tN so
CO CO (N
00 t^ CO
(N
CM -^ CO
->
CM
in
CM 00 CO
LO r~ U-)
cO CO CO
SO r^ in
in
00
so
so
so
^o
o
r~ in in
00 so
oo SO
o
o
OS Cs
Oo
Division
Potential
<
.-<
CSJ
Hourly
i5i
o^
Wage
(Cents)
oo
\o
r-.
o\
-^
O
ddd
so so
T-H rt lO
CO r- CO
00 * CO
rH
O
OO
in CM
ddd
in in co
csj rsi CO
csl
ddd
0.10
0.11
0.11
Oi
for
oi
oi
unit)
0.020
0.025
0.025
0.013
0.050
0.033
0.010
0.012
0.016
0.012
0.033
0.014
3 -2 S
^ [^
H ^ H
,"*
per
Self-consumption
CNj
o
CO
Oo
T-I
CN CO
Production
uO
Q
<
(Hours
1.00
0.16
o
o
oo
q
q
in CM
0.25
csi
in
(N
--I
OO
qq
(N
csi
dJ
oo
o
so
iri
r-~
2.50
1.00
o
q
CM in
so CM
-^ T^
0.16
<
so so
Csj
<t
in CM in
-^ CO
so so
O
in
r^
ddd
T-1
CTs
CTs
oo
o
LO ^ ^
in
t^ cs CO
o
o
00 so
Oo
oo
o
CO
00
00 in CO
in CM in
00 in in
oO
<U
J'
<->
"O
(U
U U
H-,
^)
r-~
(Units)
CO
Hourly
Production
P^
ddd
PQ
<
1)
so
fsj
T-I
T-J
SO SO CS
(6 d> d>
T-^
so *_
ddd
dd
oo
d
T-I
^d
Tt-_
Tt CO
in CM in
ddd
ddd
Tt
so 00
T-;
ddd
<i-_
sq
0C3
>-;
T-I
q Cs
^dd
in
-^
di
csi
CO
ddd
^'
00 so
>
j3
00
r-~
CO
dd
ddd
^C
00 in CO
<6
dd
'
o
T-I
<4-l
3
a.
in (N in
00 in in
3 P-!
c
dd
ddd
ddd
CM in CO
00 ^_ in
I-~
P5
O
T-^
so
(World
<
Productivity
5o
record
Objective
CM
."
X!
CTs
in
r^
(J
a,
00
r-_
dd
ddd
ddd
CO CA
ddd
1 I
1
S O
t? -^
Ti
o '^
o
tu
si
1)
-s
li,
<U
l-i
3 O
**-
ni
oa
^1
o
B
B
o
.a
<
5 ^
a
3 C
o g
<
a-
3
3
2 S
a,
CL,
<->
O,
Oh
(U
3-5
C
fe.S
i:
"
"^ -
Tlie Six
229
influence
him
II
III
IV
II
100
80
90
90
100
125
37
25
100
57
131
43
100
500
100
100
100
167
50
166
100
1000
100
950
125
100
112
112
80
100
30
20
175
100
20
100
20
20
60
100
30
99
10
100
10
95
IV
*
265
333
100
66
70
40
100
30
100
500
100
100
200
333
100
333
100
1000
100
950
Calcula ted
2.
In
frc
75
111
400
500
232
133
233
100
100
500
100
100
61
10
105
10
100
89
100
100
150
100
101
30
100
9.
The Principle
my judgment
250
Country IV
III
111
89
100
100
III
II
Country
Country
of Comparative Cost
Of course
its
among
individual persons
is
ff.)
But
so far
it
exhaustively enough.
" Wo gilt das
2. The following is based upon my article on comparative cost,
Theorem der komparativen Kosten? " WeltwirtschaftUches Archiv, July, 1938. (The
Part Three.
ago
Trade
will be familiar to
connection.
this
Development
of the Principle
An
edge
3.
is
elementary knowl-
assumed.
The
if
absolute prices,
i.
e.,
The change
price level has the function of restoring equilibrium in the balances of payments.
numbers and
(comparative)
in order of their
With
and
in the
into real
magnitude.
(absolute)
Only
cost
this
mechanism
differences
in
trans-
sufficient
Tlie Six
231
decided what goods enter into trade between the two countries.
Only for commodities lying between the two lines is it true without
limitation that both countries will import them from other countries.
As
even
for exports,
two.
this
12.
11
and
III
(column
4,
ORDER OF COMPARATIVE
ADVANTAGES^
I
f^.B
ti
II
II
III
F
III
II
IV
III
IV
IV
a.
countries.
Table
line 2
12)
for example.
between
Line
lies
exports food
Trade
Part Three.
232
which goods enter international trade can be determined, from which follows the hypothetical proposition that if the
dividing line were given it would sharply separate imported and
sary sequence in
The
the half-knowledge
goods on the farther side
of the line would all be on the list of imports but would not exhaust
From this follows the little that is definitely known about the
it.
trade relationships between any two countries: That they do not
exchange the goods between the dividing lines but import them
from this and other countries. Whereas everything is known in the
second case, once the dividing line is given, in the third case even
the lines separating two countries provide only partial information
exported products.
that
if
all,
as to
/?.
Now
compare trade between countries and trade between perwhat concepts of interpersonal trade correspond
to those with which we are already familiar from international trade
For this purpose we must proceed as though
(Tables 9 and 10)
country (column
4.
is
2)
be
set
From
up
it
scale of
is
The
and
between these two alone what they will exchange with one another, in which
and with what probability. Other countries and the rate of exchange so
interfere with the system as to make it possible to say in advance only that the order
in which goods are exchanged between two countries, which is fixed by the size of
comparative advantages, can be interrupted but not jumbled.
costs
direction,
5.
The
following
endeavored
margin
firm.
("
also
Wo
derivation
assumes
that
efficiency
remains
constant.
to
gilt
das
" Weltioirtschaftliches
have
at
the
in the
Archiv,
The
Six
.,
233
(Column 4
of
Table 9 contains in
column
10,
4)
sterling
The
5).
level of the
this into
sum
credits; that
is,
of their debits
their balance of
the others.
sole difference is ttiat tfie excfiange rate does not give tlie international wage
working hour directly, but only after the introduction of an intermediate link
(the hourly wage in national currency)
7. See G. von Haberler; Der internaiionale Handel (Berlin, 1933)
p. 102; English
6.
for a
edition (1936)
p. 133.
Part Three.
20J
Trade
way
The demand
for
limits
takes longer to reach the point where the demand for its goods
exceeds productive capacity and drives its exchange rate upward,
until the foreign demand for its still remaining special products can
be satisfied by the domestic supply of hours of work required to
produce them. Sooner or later this point must be reached. Hourly
wage and exchange rate will finally become so high that the balance
it
8. There are exceptions; for example, among sparse populations. There the hourly
wage is so adjusted that the sum of the activities possible at this wage just fill the
working time of a man. Consider the versatility of the rural artisan, or the combination of innkeeping with agriculture; a sharp separation of occupations would be
undesirable in rural districts. Secondly, the wish to be continuously employed forms
for
The
Six
235
typical example of
requires no lowering of " domestic prices."
transfer by a simple shift in buying power without change of price!
It is based upon the relative insignificance of the individual in the
whole economy.
The
INTERPERSONAL TRADE
INTERNATIONAL TRADE
Rates of exchange
International prices
Barter terms (relation of export to
import price)
National price system
National price level
Gold import
The
Wage
level
in a stocking)
= import
question,
to prices
of goods)
Capital export
Export
Hourly wages
Efficiency wages
Real wages (relation of wages
Part Three.
236
Trade
What
same function.
But the choice of an occupation does not depend entirely on
money income, as we have been assuming up to now, or even upon
the utilities that this income will buy. On the contrary, to these
more or less variable utilities there must be added all those imponderables that are associated with various occupations and usually
For a man aims at the
appear as fixed utilities (or disutilities)
exactly the
highest total utility, not at the highest purchasable utility, but the
making
money
calculus.
When
b.
1.
The Personnel
What have
the
members
of an Occupation
common?
aptitudes that
quality of work.^
common
characteristic
(at least
concerned) is not
restricted to members of a particular occupation. The particular
ability may be found outside the occupation to a greater or lesser
degree. It can therefore be at most a necessary characteristic, which,
moreover, hardly need be mentioned. It is never a sufficient characteristic. Is not the relevant question for the members of an occupation how quickly the job can be done, rather than whether it can be
as far as native ability to
9.
It
a definite type of
is
textile worker,
The
done
at all?
What
is
the exact
237
meaning
ductive " in
it,
who
who
or
are " relatively most proare " comparatively superior " ? In no case
who
is
This leads
to
men
only,
where
is
"
correct
most
skillful subjectively
when he
(J.
sees
"
in special
sozialen Klassen
12.
What
are as efficient as
men
feminist movement.
not to
efficiency.
in
But
it
many
Otherwise
it
is
irrelevant
is
in
to time,
The
Part Three.
238
Trade
more generally, when one leaves the money for the utility
As against outsiders, the members of any given occupation
Still
calculus:
have only one thing in common: they find their highest satisfaction
in it."
is
for a
comparatively superior to
an activity
another in which she
contrary,
marginal worker
is
in
The
Six
239
^^
entrepreneur is interested chiefly in the wage per unit
kindness
of output, the worker only in his hourly wage. Mistaken
toward labor has made the latter into the wage; that is, the price
of the worker's output. Payment by time instead of by output has
"
revolutionary results: AVith a piece wage there are no " better paid
occupations, because there is no basis for comparison. The wage
for making a coat cannot be compared with that for making a pair
of shoes. Uniform hourly wages for tailors and cobblers do not
The
when they
The picture
exist
The others join the ranks of the unemployed. Only wage schedules
make marginal workers economically significant; that is, marginal
in the sense of the least productive workers, not in the sense given
above of those that are readiest to leave or to enter an occupation.
Only
in the case of
wage schedules
is it
engaged in a more lucrative occupation are objectively more productive in it than all in less lucrative ones. The situation differs
fundamentally from barter, where it need not be true that those
who objectively or subjectively excel in a task will actually perform
When wages are determined in a free market that occuit also.
pation will be chosen that will lead to the highest earnings when
efficiency and piece rates are taken into account. With an hourly
wage schedule that occupation is chosen in which output times the
piece rate is at least equal to the established hourly wage and which
offers the highest hourly wage of all. (This is true only when wages
are determined in a free market.) Of course, it is not necessary that
output times the piece rate should equal any of the existing time
rates. This will then result in the army of unemployed that muddled
philanthropists are never tired of creating.
connected with the organization of the firm;
exceeded
its
optimum
size
or
is
for
Though
standpoint of industry.
It will
it
become
degrees of efficiency until the value of the marginal product equals the wage paid for
all
it.
Except in so far as production results in costs that depend simply upon the
lapse of time or upon the duration of the production process. Then he also is interested in work tempo and hence in the hourly wage of the individual worker.
15.
Part Three.
240
2.
The Personnel
Trade
of a Firm
Who
produce independently as master craftsAt the least it implied that the combination
men,
dealers, or farmers.
upon
many
occupations
but upon different possibilities for production, which depend on combinations with other factors of production possible at any moment. These are a function of the degree
of utilization of the capacities of a plant at any given time. Thus
the choice of an occupation by employed workers depends still less
upon mere aptitude than does that by the self-employed. On the
contrary, the common output of persons in different occupations, as
are not even conceivable)
oping aptitudes.
c.
THE LOCALITY OF
PERSON
Where does any given man produce? This time we shall invert
our customary procedure and trace our answer step by step from
special to
1.
more general
solutions.
The Locality
a.
of
Employed Workers
on one
wage level.
The
Six
241
1.
is
in fact a dangerous
inter-local equalization of
If
2.
where he found a
livelihood,
and
all
would work
as the
mere existence
(as little as
expenses in
work with
for
better food,
work
clothes, carfare,
and
so on.
But
return.
But
local inequality of
we have
seen.
fi.
16.
Mutatis mutandis
this
as
they are
Only
in statics
is
profit
be recovered.
is
Pai^t
242
Three.
Trade
in various places.
But our total satisfaction does not depend solely upon what we
can buy in various places with the income available at a given time.
For besides purchasable goods unique things that are without price
influence our location; those individual characteristics of places and
people that cannot be interchanged, all those imponderables of
production and consumption that often mean incomparably more
to us than the economic process proper. For this reason potential
real wages for the same worker, unlike the wholesale price for the
same product, may differ from place to place by more than his
travel costs.
y.
Equal
Satisfaction
We wish to maximize neither our money wage nor our real wage,
but our total utility. This, too, differs interlocally for individuals
by far more than traveling expenses, for it makes an enormous
difference whether we were born in a place or have to move there.
Migration means relinquishing much that, like friends, can be
replaced only after a long time; or never, like one's native place.
We cannot take landscape and people with us. And seldom do we
become as attached to new surroundings as if we had grown up
18. In his admirable study L. B. Zapoleon
(" International and Domestic Commodities and the Theory of Prices," Quarterly Journal of Economics XLV [1931], 443)
expresses the opinion, however, that local differences in the style of living nowadays
show more in the relative amounts in which goods and qualities obtainable everywhere are bought, than in the existence of different products that can be obtained
only locally.
19. On the other hand, those local differences in custom to which one adapts oneself
simply in order not to seem queer can no longer be included in the concept of real
wages.
20.
R. Wilbrandt,
Vom Leben
der Wirtschaft,
P. I
(Berlin, 1937)
The
243
a part of them.
22. If a
localities,
movement
person could divide his working hours and his free time
(after
among
several
deduction of traveling
loss of his
Hence the
23.
utility
abrupt
rise at the
hagen, 1942],
24.
border of a
district or country.
We may
go a step further and assume that individuals are not free to choose
Then
p. 354.)
where they
will be
most useful
to
it.
there are no longer limits to the interlocal differences in personal utility. Instead,
the individual
is
so situated that in
no other
locality
would
does not take place until local differences in utility are greater than travelling expenses.
Only a modern gypsy can apply the same rule to goods and to himself. But differences
in the mobility of stable persons, gypsies, and goods are evidently differences in degree
only, even where movement between countries is concerned. Whoever starts with the
assumption that labor is internationally immobile is dealing with a limiting case.
26. Utility for the individual can be compared between localities at a given
moment, when he really is one and the same, provided we interpret his choice of
locality as though he had decided in favor of the greater utility. But interpersonal
utility comparisons are something entirely different. This would be an interpretation
of a formal principle of explanation as an actual force, which does not become any
more real because men believe in it and calculate real wages and set up wage schedules
in conformity with it. Worship does not transform an idol into a god.
Trade
Part Three.
244
8.
From
all that
Conclusion
it
follows,
first,
human
to
that exists
when we
pass
we proceed from
we have done
here.
When
gives a
with the special case it is soon covered over by the more general
solution, and then appears merely as an error on the road to truth.
Secondly, as universally valid spatial differences in utility do not
exist in a free economy, there is also no limit for spatial differences
in nominal or real efficiency wages. All wages remain unique and
incommensurable in
space,
distribution of persons.
He
will select
it
so that
nowhere
else
does he feel enough better to make up for the cost of moving and,
if necessary, the loss of familiar surroundings.
2.
An
money but
law of
profits,"^
and
-^
incomes
27. In other words, wages may lie arbitrarily above the minimum of existence, but
an entrepreneur's profit cannot exceed the enterpreneurial income by an arbitrary
amount without bringing counteracting forces into play.
28. That is, through the wrong choice of a location it can fall below the minimum
The
245
men and
THE OCCUPANTS OF
d.
Who
LOCALITY
upon what
is
" locality."
meant by
or a precise meaning.
may be understood
It
like
New
group of locations
York, or one single spot
as a
^^
^
like Macy's.
of existence
more
easily tiian
is
incom-
In a double sense:
a vertical direction
employed
Of course even
[a)
(multistory buildings)
{b)
artificial increases in
is
still
The extremely
difficult
problem
of size of the individual lot remains, which recalls the problem of " product differentiation,"
and the
difficulty of
"
product
way the
"
is.
One might
ground could be
But a discussion of basic principles
must not employ such an institutional pons asinorum. Or one might assume infinitely
small plots of ground together with a prohibition of sabotage; that is, no one would
be allowed to withhold his land as the " key piece," but would have to surrender it to
if
made
the highest bidder. In this case, however, the question of the production or occupants
of such an infinitely small plot
plots.
in
in
Part Three.
246
Trade
1.
and residence.
Localities
when
loss
necessary.^-
those
of a
case, in
is
this:
in
for settlements
same purpose; different men and different proddo not always compete for exactly the same combination or areas. This means
that the assumption that the prices of all remaining lots remain constant becomes
impossible, and we can say nothing more about the occupants or the production of
one locality alone, but can only determine the distribution of persons in general. Thus
our subject cannot even be discussed unless all rivals compete for the same combination
of areas, however this combination may be determined. Such a combination we call a
endless ways with other areas for the
ucts
locality in
its
more
restricted sense.
31.
level
(e. g.,
through the
32.
The
common
be found in special
characteristics of
why
its
a given
1-26.)
even
less
who move
number
The
Six
247
areas such as
particularism, or chauvinism.
Localities
2.
Who
prepared
in
it.
He who
First,
is
with
utility here.
tion
revenues of
all locations, as
The
all
locations except
entrepreneur in order of the total utility that they will afford him.
If the location to be disposed of is to be at the upper end of the
series, that is, if it is to assure at least the same utility as the next
best, its price must not exceed a definite calculable amount.^* The
price may even have to become a subsidy, especially if the revenues
to be obtained from this location do not even cover the remaining
costs. The various entrepreneurs may now be arranged in order of
the highest price that they are ready to pay for the location in ques-
The one
When we
at the
try to
the highest gross profit here (proceeds before deduction of the cost
33.
is
and
of rent based
on
show
a certain place
total utility.
depends
Trade
Part Three.
2^8
utility so
this
(before subtracting the cost of the lot)
greater elsewhere, yet provide a smaller net profit because
of a disproportionately greater outlay for space. Yet even the net
profit may be higher somewhere else, for it does not by itself deter-
may be
mine
total utility.
was
exclude
sufficient to
the same.
we
restricted our-
The
money
profits,
the
mechanism
is
in principle
1.
THE INDUSTRY
Localities
a.
The
in
IN A
LOCALITY
Correct Solution
profits
can no
longer be excluded, for the returns to the entrepreneur need no longer he equal.
case then
amounts
to a
normal one.
The
The
Six
249
everything
more
In any given
neighboring competition leaves room.^^ It is the difficult task of
those authorities who must plan and develop cities or countries to
decide which particular industries should locate in a particular place.
The practical procedure may be imagined about as follows: First,
the chief production advantages of the locality in question, and next
the main cost factors for the various enterprises are determined,
from which appear the industries for which the local cost advantages will be most advantageous. So much for supply.
As for demand, it would have to be determined which were the
industries whose nearest competition was unusually far distant, and
whether the intermediate demand would be adequate. If both
favorable production conditions and a satisfactory distance from
competition exist, an undertaking of the type considered would
have a good chance. Cases are much harder to find in which neither
favorable conditions for production nor a particularly favorable
competitive position are manifest, yet where an enterprise might
nevertheless succeed in the end against neighboring competition.^^
The most difficult thing of all is to discover how the industries that
are to be attracted will themselves reciprocally alter the bases of
calculation; particularly at what price level the final equilibrium
will be reached.
Whether neighboring production sites will leave room for a new
factory depends upon more than competition from similar firms.
As a rule the product of one locality differs in quality as well as
packaging and the like from similar products of other localities.
locality
clearly:
On
the whole
it
is
somewhat
different
is
and
characteristic article
obtainable only there, and the real question is whether it can hold
its own against all other possible similar or entirely different goods
that consumers would otherwise purchase. Whether the individuality of a locality can be maintained, whether the products peculiar
to it will find an adequate market, whether it can obtain the consumer's goods peculiar to it at such prices that a sufficient number
of people will remain attached to it these are the questions that
must be answered.
36.
That
touch.
The
is,
demand
must be included
curves at least
in the
planning
curve.
37.
localities
but of
sales
is
Part Three.
250
p.
THE INDUSTRY OF
1,
Trade
COUNTRY
political
differences,
inhabitants
econortiic
and
localities
landscapes at most)
localities
any advantages in
from the
gifts of
on the
On
common
that
least the
here.
38. Depressed areas whose workers do not wish to migrate (see p. 326, note 13)
should change over to something wherein their greatest comparative advantage lies.
See A. Robinson's review of S. R. Dennison's The Location of Industry and the
Depressed Areas (Oxford, 1939) in Economic Journal, L (1940) 26.
,
39.
it
The
is this:
Only
in
less to
countries also;
perhaps when these are small, widely separated, and very dissimilar islands, and differences in the size and utilization of enterprises do not play too important a role.
to a
is
few countries.
The
avoided by dividing
it
difficulty of
into a finite
number
of discontinua.
The
251
Six
Antwerp
to
New
York,
say.
freight costs to
the domestic harbor, which are added to the ocean freight, are often
higher, and always as different as can be for individual points of
origin and destination. Because of these local variations in supply
prices
differ
everywhere.
It
movement
that the
long run.*^
But this means that countries simply do not show the economic
uniformity postulated by the principle of comparative cost; hence
The problem of
it is illogical to apply the theorem to them.^*-*''
determining the production of a country must be solved in some
other way.
Wo
In the
first
place,
it
is
often does not hold for individuals either, since in general a long period
objections.
For example,
it
is
known.
is
it is
practically
and
means not
theoretically
Wo
gilt
das
all,
Theorem der
difficult
time in international
Since this prejudice regards countries, though incorrectly, as units the principle
^<J^'
2r2
2.
Three.
Trade
COUNTRY
'^^
itself.
is
its
refutation.
And
so long as
Nevertheless, this
way
is
unnecessarily complicated.
The
47.
all
trade diminishes with the increasing size of a country. For example see
"
Herberts,
J. H.
Importance du commerce exterieur dans I'economie frangaise," in L'Activite co-
nomique
(Paris, 1937)
p. 6.
or even sufficient condition for the exchange of goods can be seen, on the one hand,
from our model of economic areas in which trade is carried on despite an equal dis-
The
Six
253
Consider for a
moment
the market areas are large in comparison with countries and if their centers are perhaps even concentrated in a narrow space, as is true of many natural resources,
certain countries will be typical exporters and others typical im-
On
country.
if
2.
Localities
in
The
is
to
where
shall they
from
this question,
be situated. ^^'^^
First,
industries
that lie close together at the center of the free space, or even overlap.
sites,
and not
all
when
that could
competitive
bidding begins to increase land prices and to raise costs. Thus the
number of industries exceeds the number of available sites at first,
49. It
and choice
of site
it
We
is
use
not tenable in a
is
strict sense,
a favorable locality
if
it
however
no
offers
we do not
assume the prices of all lots except one as given (in conformity with the procedure
in section d, 2, but only the prices of all except a few. This broader formulation makes
50.
the processes
still
51. In practice
locations.
An
clearer.
one
will
have
to be content
is
generally impossible.
Trade
Part Three.
254
many
come
with an
to grief
way
that
but one buyer remains for each site. Even with relatively few
sites and competitors the determination of this equilibrium price
presents a difficult mathematical problem (calculus of variations)
No simple solution exists for the problem of who shall acquire
individual sites and at what price, and who shall be completely
finally
eliminated.
This
is
must
satisfy: It
price of 4,
and
b,
which
gets I at a price of 2.
Industry
c,
on the
would be still
Table 13 shows that at price 2 for site I industry a achieves a net
profit of 2 on it, whereas industry b achieves a net profit of only 1.
industry a
it
more
also that
52.
fulfills
it is
anywhere
else,
Thus within
is
a bilateral monopoly.
but
II.
See R. Triffin,
172.
The
Six
Price
Net
of
and
a, b,
c,
II
II
and
Site
for sites I
Table 14
a
Price of Site
f.
II
Chooses Site
II
II
lor
I
or II
II
II
T
II
II
II
II
II
II
II
Industries
a.
in
The Regional
General
Basis
Rules of
p.
Strictly
speaking
Thumb
all
locations
are
dependent.
53.
The
Summary
No one
and the others
interdependent.
I.
Part Three.
256
Trade
within
itself.
choice
among
many
system.
bound
tionally
centers,
The
it.
We
in practice
Here we
tion,
thumb
Examples
The
Six
will
be offered only
if
257
explanation.
The importance
of source is obvious in the distribution of popuboth Europe and the United States.^* Why is the
population of the North American continent concentrated in the
northeastern part of the United States? ^^ The most important
reason is the climate: too cold in the North, too hot in the South/^
too dry in the West. Then the soil: on the whole it is poorer in
the West than in the Middle West and the East, and often below
the requirements for grass, not to mention grain.
Climate, soil quality, and man co-operated to produce the result.
In the South some of the soil is very good even today, an example
of the fact that a natural factor alone is of no great significance.
Natural resources are not unequivocally on the side of the Northeast, though they may give it a slight advantage. ^^ Its situation in
respect to communications, on the contrary, is unusually favorable.
in
lations
It lies
We
54.
of their industries.
The
north and another through Washington to the south (somewhat further south
to the
The
56.
the same
soil,
the
as the industrial
population that
to historical reasons.
math
The
is
is
due partly
its
War, which manifestly broke the backbone of the South, did not
But a more important reason was that most of those who
did come in were accustomed to a northerly climate, in which they were more efficient
and, perhaps most important of all, in which they felt better. In this case the influence
of climate probably makes itself felt through consumption rather than through
of the Civil
production.
57. In
freight)
the South
iron
and
(ore
steel
market is so unfavorable that factories cannot reach their optimum size, at least near
Duluth. See A. Predohl, " Die ortliche Verteilung der amerikanischen Eisen- und
Stahlindustrie," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv,
58.
Which
XXVII
(1928), 286
329*.
ff.,
when immigrants
and
arrived from
at first
remained
there.
59.
freights to
the East Coast despite the different distances, the time costs such as interest can
be saved over the shorter northern route.
on
still
Part Three.
258
Trade
Of course artificial measureseconomically determined discrimination of freight rates to the disadvantage of its great rival,
the Mississippi Valley have strongly emphasized the natural advantages of the Northeast.
The belt of strikingly dense population that stretches slightly
southward from the English industrial areas across northern France
and Belgium, southern Holland, the Ruhr, central Germany, Saxony,
Upper Silesia and the neighboring parts of Bohemia and southern
Poland, into northern Rumania and the Ukraine, where it turns
like
rather
politically
than
Inhabitants per
square kilometer
Over 100
Fig.
60-100
25-50
1-25
55.
about 1930.
(After
Goode and
others.)
area,^
is
chiefly attributable to
how
regularly the population density falls off with distance from this belt, especially
toward the north. In the south the pattern is distorted by, among other things, a
second densely populated belt that runs up the Rhine Valley and continues on the
other side of the Alps
down
According to Haufe this belt was very thickly settled even before the days of
On the relative
industrialization {Die Bevolkerung Europas [Berlin, 1936], Map 1)
61.
locations of industry
"
Regionale
and
LIV
one another,
(1941)
292.
see O. Schlier,
The
Six
259
London,
Be
it
reality,
tifically
exact emphasis
2.
on boundless interdependence.
The
In General
1.
The Individual
62.
factors
63.
get
down
it
become.
This
is
Enterprise
The
number
Technical progress
may
of producers.
and
The
size of
first
The
have disproved elsewhere the solution given by the theory of comparative cost:
where the comparative advantage for its type of production is greatest." (" Wo gilt das Theorem der komparativen Kosten? " Weltwirt65. I
"A
f.)
Part Three.
25<)
Trade
it
The
utility.
scope for this subjective choice of a location is objecmost it may cost profits and the entrepre-
neurial
wage.***^
amount
limited.
offered
(3)
is
limited.
When
(2)
When
five cases:
(1)
When
number of producers
entry their number is small
that new entrepreneurs can
the
who
smoothly, the pressure of potential entrepreneurs always tends toward the elimination of profits and a condensation of locations
accordingly. In this case an enterprise is established simply where
it can exist. Its existence depends primarily also upon the location
of neighboring enterprises that compete either for sales or for factors
of production. If a new bank, say, is to be founded, a gap in the
already existing bank network must be found that will assure an
adequate supply area of deposits on the one hand, and an adequate
SPECIAL CASES
are valid only in the rare cases in which their very restrictive assumptions are fulfilled.
1.
A factory chooses the locality with lowest freight costs. This
assumes that production costs are the same everywhere, and also
that the number and demand of consumption centers are unchangeable. If their number is variable the total freight or the average
66.
True
in a free
scarcity;
(F.
(3)
Machlup,
and
"
(4)
(1)
profits
261
If
become more
the
sales
number
distant, as to
make
the
new
location
more favorable
prices
2.
its
higher freight
costs.
upon
their
power
of attraction.
Local-
(I)
and
filled
68.
individual enterprise
is
demand
as follows:
Is
p. 23, these
ful-
include
supplies.
of this
curves intersect)
The
particular
Part Three.
262
CONCLUSION
g.
The
necessity
division of labor
and
is
inclination.
Trade
By
necessity
when producers
(person or
as possible;
is,
number
number of
the constant
of pro-
groups.
ducers can be collected into a smaller or larger
If Malthus were right, if man, like the lower animals, continued
to multiply so rapidly that each individual would be just able to
exist,^^ there would be no such difference. But because man restrains
his multiplication his income rises above the minimum of subsistence
It is
(profits
precisely the
In contrast
71.
Of course
the
minimum
its
individual
who
are only
Chapter
18.
Price Gradients
by the
costs of distance.
make up
The
(2)
If a
may
arise
among
(3)
Price dif-
Landscape and world gradients apply to goods of different producers; market gradients affecting industrial products apply to goods
of the
at
most equal to
the costs of distance in the broad sense, which also includes trade
1.
Here
der Preise
lished
it
(in
is
what
is
discussed at length in
my
Geographic
monograph)
263
B.
The
up
1.
dismiss as insoluble a third traditional task; to calculate the gains from inter-
national trade.
2.
results are
summarized
in
my
article, "
264
Chapter 19.
a.
Self-Regulation
We
trade.
shall discuss here these aspects of price fluctuations for
the most important subjects and the spatial constructs that are used
as a frame of reference in international trade.
1.
Individuals
Let us
for the
start
work
of the cobbler
On
is
385-402.
S65
Port Three.
o(35
Trade
amounts are
Of course he may be more free with his money, less careful about
his purchases, shopping in more expensive stores and there paying
higher prices even when they do not correspond to better quality.
The
landlord
may have
phere of prosperity:
more
freely,
and
Jung
will
He
is
be most severely
with distance.
One day a
new
more
rent, spends
deposits
more
in the bank.
affected, since
even club
loyalties
and puts
reparations:
weaken
to
Jung
unilateral
must be made. His " import of goods " and his " export
of capital," both of which he will decrease with a sigh, will most
likely bear the chief burden; he will spend less and be able to save
less. But in addition pressure will be exerted upon the whole level
of high prices that surrounds Jung. Forced by necessity, he will
again buy more carefully; he will bargain with his landlord, and
transfer
later.
267
Self-Regulation
2.
Factories
demand
change.
<x.
Price
Waves and
How
They Spread
We
Part Three.
268
Trade
the scarcity of imports will raise prices in B'2 also, though not quite
so high as in B\, since the special cause operating there is absent.
" focus of infection " for
B'z, on its part, now constitutes a new
inflation
its
is
shoes.
^;
^i
Fig. 56.
(3.
The
on market areas
Price waves always move away from their point of origin. Each
consecutive temporal and spatial link in the chain of purchasingpower transfers is necessarily farther removed from the starting point
than the preceding one. For a recipient of increased purchasing
power
source
will turn
269
Self-Regulation
goods in the opposite direction from that city, because nearer Stuttgart they encounter the still stronger price-cutting competition of B.
y.
As the
The Damping
of Price
its
Waves
different reasons.
1.
Not only
with distance.
is
products
3.
is
But only
to
at large.*
and
The
industrial
truth of this
finishing trade.
4. B.
Barfod (Local Economic Effects of a Largescale Industrial Undertaking
[Copenhagen and London, 1938], p. 44) calculated that in Aarhus 45 per cent of consumption expenditures (dwelling up to 85 per cent, clothing 30 per cent, food 25 per
cent) was retained as local income. According to Isenberg (" Zur Stadtplanung in den
neuen deutschen Ostgebieten," Raumforschung und Raumordnung, 1941, p. 137) in a
,
German
agricultural region
up
to 60
who
calls
are not
For economic regions in which industry and agriculture are intermixed it would have to be considerably higher. According to the same
author (ibid.. Vol. 6, p. 18)
29.3 per cent of German productive workers were
employed
27.1
world markets)
is
divided
among
If
the rest
these groups
it
and
forestry,
and
and communications)
with distance.
demand
of a
Part Three.
270
Trade
becomes
B grows
still
clearer
as the
its
point of origin,
IN
PURCHASING POWER
Assume
is
the
man who
and so on,
and Ci, jEi, Gi, and so on, are consumers, and the rest are producers
of one product each: B, of shoes; D, of bread; F, of butter, and so on.
additional 1,000 marks' worth of shoes from B^.
C, E, G,
Suppose that a unit of each product cost initially 1 mark. Now let
disturb the equilibrium. Let the chain of trade connections be as
in the figure. Thus D, the baker, for example, would have supplied
C and perhaps E also, but he would have supplied neither A nor F.
Such a selective chain is the rule in reality where imperfect com-
petition prevails.
By paying
1,000
a customer of B.
271
Self-Regulation
Now
As the demand
for
his shoes suddenly increased, B^ raised his price to 1.5 marks. C,',
whose income has not gone up, will no longer buy 1,000 marks
worth as before, but only 500 (so that B^ will sell 667 units to A
and
.333
units to C,)
for the
goods of Di, which so far have not risen in price. By joining D/s
long-established customers with an additional 500-mark demand,
he drives jDi's prices up also, though by less than A Avas able to do
with his additional purchasing power of 1,000 marks from B^, and
so on.
CO
CO
ca
CO
Fig. 57.
transfer in goods
and an
elasticity of
In this way it comes to pass that with distance from the center
of origin both the fall in purchasing power and prices (starting
with B) and the increase in purchasing power and prices (starting
with jBi) will flatten out.^
5.
This conclusion
is
were equal
to
I,
demand
or B^ would suffer
If
another, an elasticity of
B and
demand
elasticity of
is
all
no matter how
demand
is
conceivable;
(if
each represents
he
failed to
Part Three.
272
3.
So far
entirely
Trade
on
as a substitute.
several sellers,
and
reality
new
from
Thus
customers.^
the
4.
The
its
origin because
wave
it
to flatten
divides.
In
the two price waves approach one another, they flatten out
The End
of the Price
Waves
Whereas local price differences are very great in the first economic period, the fall in prices widens and flattens out in the
succeeding ones. It must be remembered, however, that so far as
the causes of this phenomenon (discussed under 1 to 3) extend,
the sum of the increases or decreases in purchasing power remains
the same, even though it is divided among more and more persons
by partial shifting. This is the law of the conservation of purchasing
power. Thus, though the total fall in purchases from B, say, was
1,000, he suffers a loss of only 500 marks and through a price cut
shifts the further loss of 500 to D, who in turn absorbs 200 marks
of it and passes on a loss of 300. The sum of the amounts absorbed
)
is
(500 + 200 4-90 + 40 +
exactly 1,000.
The shift from
-
movement of
upward with B, downward with B^. At best B could shift the entire loss to D; at the worst, B^ would have
to transfer all the profits to D^, until at last profits and losses reached Z and were
equalized there. The effect of a combination of different elasticities is still more com-
prices
may be
Cournot's point)
still less
interesting.
Self-Regulation
273
7.
Thus B has
C, even
though
shifted
at a loss,
when he
preceding one.
from
less
is
over as far as he
Z.
still
Then he
enters
he had in the
affects one of his
as
concerned.
we
Here two
situations
P'^^^
274
Three.
Trade
where, however; that is, there must be one or several places where
diminished and increased purchasing power balance one another
without altering prices.
Besides this there is still another possibility, more probable at
first: That Z)i and Fa, with their combined additional purchasing
power of 300 marks, will become new customers not o Z, but of D,
and the price drop
in place of E. The series will then stop with
will no longer reach F, H, and so on. Consequently their demand
from Z will not decrease, which equalizes Z's loss of an additional
demand from D^ and F^ previously assumed. In other words, these
two simultaneous possibilities of a link between chains of price
increases and price decreases mean that those who gain in purchasing power, either as a simple result of its shift (through Z) or
after a preceding price change (in the case of D, for instance)
demand what the persons with reduced purchasing power have
given up. Both are typical examples of the real transfer, which is
achieved when decreased and increased purchasing power meet
somewhere.
The
spatial distribution of these two forms of transfer is imporAt first those persons or places with decreased purchasing
power dp and those with increased purchasing power ip may be so
far apart that no equalization occurs at all. But as the waves of
purchasing power spread dp and ip move closer together. At first
only their largest supply and market areas overlap slightly, and the
shift in demand from ip to dp of those few in the region of overlap
tant.
Z can
little.
At
much
changed.
last
Self-Regulation
275
Economic Landscapes
3.
The economic
is
exposed throughout.^^
This important function of economic
price fluctuations
(of
capitals,
to
the transfer of
their
economic
becomes
still
more
when
clear
it
is
money
therefore, there
If,
is
any
logic at all in
who
structs
Countries
4.
Do
11.
This
is
point in a wave
12.
may become
the center of a
which every
to
new wave.
is
no organized landscape
at
all.
its
its
own
When
areas or
its
particular circle of
is
must be dispersed here and there. This need not mean its complete dissipation, for
the arming of a fort, say, may at first chiefly benefit one single factory somewhere in a
it does mean an irregular geographical distribution,
which of course may suffice to rob it of the cumulative cyclical effect which otherwise
would occur in the course of interregional trade.
Part Three.
376
Trade
approximately with economic regions, either fortuitously or by compulsion, what has already been said of them holds here also. Has
the state as such, not as an economic area, additional significance?
a.
Currency
international trade.
first
important characteristic of
is
whether differences
I.
large
created that
would
procuring the
money would
still
face the
problem of
which are
is
later nullified
by a reaction.
(aa)
Preliminary Transfer. The preliminary transfer is brought
about by a further price movement, which is added to that caused
by a shift in purchasing power.
13. I shall call a medium of payment that
wise restricted group " local money."
is
Sclf-Regidnlion
277
First:
price drop,
its
An
amount to be
transferred in credit money, whereas they themselves have to remit
in monetary reserves." There is first the local bank, which receives
amount
the
in
its
own
serving as regional
bank, which has to change its deposits into notes; finally, the central
bank, which receives notes and has to pay out gold. Suppose a
payment of
And
many
on the
will
notes,
be created.
If
which sent 1,000 marks in notes to Berlin, has shrunk even more.
It must reduce the amount of deposits by 10,000 marks, either by
raising its rediscount rates or by direct curtailment of credits. Consequently prices in Wiirttemberg fall ten times more than if there
were no deposits, and in Germany twice as much as if there were
no bank notes. This true shifting of the price level occurs only
with credit creation; that is, with a hierarchy of different kinds of
money, whereas in a region with a uniform currency the price waves
started by a shift in purchasing power necessarily suffice for transfer.^^
The change
to bring about.
some time
passes
threatened.
15. For example, a transfer of reserves with the local Federal
Reserve Bank from
one commercial bank to another within the same Federal Reserve District. W. F. S.
16. Not only money rates, but all prices must have
at least the same tendency; not
merely some,
as with price waves. In this case the change in the price level
instead of only a fictitious average, as with price waves.
is
a reality
P^^f^
2y8
Trade
Three.
deposits
one another slowly, the areas of falling and rising price levels meet
This
almost instantaneously (at least with neighboring countries)
goods,
which
probably
transfer
of
considerable
and
rapid
causes a
takes place chiefly in the border regions. We shall disregard the
capital movements that also are released and assume that 700 marks
in gold and 300 in merchandise are transferred at first, which must
be paid when the German payment comes due.
.
The
Paris
and
17.
Thus
Final Transfer.
no further influence on
prices in
Only mathematically
is
the French
price
level
German
price level.
slightly
money by
1,000 marks;
and
vice
279
Sclf-Regululion
The
(cc)
Reaction.
transfer.
2.
Where
local
from complete
Additional local
accepted money.
credit creation.
The
local
Trade
Part Three.
28o
maintained.
Suppose once more that 1,000 marks are to be sent from Stuttgart
to Paris. (I) If transfers are made in hoarded gold and the receiver
hoards it in turn, no price fluctuation will be necessary.^" (II) If
the local money is 100 per cent covered by gold in both countries,
but this time the amount owed has to be withdrawn from circulation, both price waves due to the shift in purchasing power will
be started; the immediate payment, however, will likewise be made
at first almost entirely in gold, into which the local money accumulated by the debtor can be converted without further trouble.
(Ill) If there is a 10 per cent bank-note coverage behind deposit
money and the bank notes in turn are fully covered by gold, we
have the typical case of intranational trade, already described above,
Now the local money can no longer be
simply converted into gold; on the contrary, gold shipment reacts
tenfold
on the amount
of deposits.
To
money must be
other.
Whereas
in the
first
case 1,000
at least 800,
it
is
now
With
20.
This
is
of the creditor.
true only
immediately true when gold flows from the hoard of the debtor to that
If it flows from the hoard of one to that of another bank of issue it is
when both
power by
their
credit policy.
21. It
is
therefore
no meaningless caprice
of the currency
281
Self -Regulation
the fact that all, or at least the created, means of payment of the
one banking area are invalid in that of another bank.^* Thus there
with low reserve ratios have to resign themselves to wide price fluctuations. This
is
the
mean only this) so that the physically diminished gold reserve will regain its
former nominal value and the amount of local money can thus be left unchanged, the
actual reserve ratio is the same in both cases. We must accustom ourselves to the idea
that the individual features of the old-fashioned gold standard, such as fixed reserve
(See my article, " Die
ratios and exchange rates, do not necessarily go hand in hand.
can
Lehre
1)
(no reserves)
23. The difference appears especially in the difficulties of transfer. When a creditor
country buys nothing from a debtor country in spite of an enormous drop in the
exchange rate, the latter cannot pay if the debt exceeds its gold supply, but its economy
alone.
With
crisis.
It is clear that
and the
smaller the reserve ratio, the greater are their secondary deflationary effects because
the fewer the installments that can be paid at first out of the supply of international
means of payments, the more the gold drain alters the amount of local money. The
more inflexible the reserve ratio, here more quickly the secondary effects begin to
appear, but they are avoidable with variable exchange rates and thus not to be
ascribed to the currency difference itself. Only for fixed exchange rates does F. W.
Meyer {Der Ausgleich der Zahlungsbilanz [Jena, 1938], p. Ill) correctly make the distinction that the gold cover may be insignificant for restraining the creation of money
but that for international payments, on the contrary, its size must be appropriate to
Moreover, even with the old-fashioned gold standard,
thanks to fluctuations between the gold points, price fluctuations will be replaced at
least in small part by fluctuations in the exchange rate, an advantage that would be
the gravity of the disturbances.
XXXII
[1930], p. 75)
of the
countries, but
Part Three.
282
Trade
of gold,
and
.^^-^^
Table 15
Preliminary Transfer by
Construction of Currency
Deposits
Gold cover
Note
(fractional)
Gold
Price
of notes
circu-
reserves
movement
movement
lation
by notes)
Gold
II
Excess
Immaterial
100%
No
Zero
currency
III
100%
IV
99-1%
Yes
!>Yes
Zero
Paper currency
These
differences lose
some of
are; that
is
to say,
it
The
with dissimilar
District.
of issue.
sole
This was the case also with the notes of the Bavarian and Wiirttemberg banks
The
deposit
money
of a
bank
is
Thus American
bills,
and
to
its
customers.
value
as well, are
usually accepted at face value throughout a rather wide zone along the border,
and
the coins, in particular, of both countries are so similar that they can be used in slot
less
harmful.
There
is
a second
and
higher than with a lower gold cover. For this reason a high gold cover
able with fixed exchanges.
is
more
favor-
Self-Regtilatjon
The
283
sharper and
In brief, the more
uniform the currency, the more slowly preliminary transfer in goods
shift in price levels in the first case is therefore
lasting.
takes place."
Creditor and Debtor Countries Have Differently Constructed Currencies. When the degrees of cover are unequal, the
actual shift in price levels and the effect on each country, varies
with the degree of cover.-^ Table 16 shows, first, what we have
already seen in the last section: That the higher the gold coverage
with one participant in a transaction, or even with both, the larger
the portion of the resulting payment through gold movement alone.
(bb)
Table
16.
Gold Shipment,
Marks from
Note
Coverage in
Gold,
Explanation:
The
10
10
40
30
40
10
40
10
50
40
Column
Column
Price
Price
Fluctuation
DiflFerence
A toB
A
2:
The
3:
over
-20
-26
+20
7
50
44
8
-16
+30
41
+ 10
+ 12
28
200
260
300
490
500
-12
its
31
gradation,
is
arbitrary.
of the participants
(cases 2
and
effect
27. In
ratio. ^^
our former example it took place slowly outward across the Wiirttemberg
were valid on both sides. Beyond the national frontier it
differences in
may
cause a change
on the upswing,
in the other of
hardly 1,000
if it is
amount
of notes in one
if it
is
in a depression.
This among other things explains the slight reaction of prices in gold movements in the United States and France, where the actual, if not the legal, gold coverage
of notes is very high and, in addition, deposits in central banks have to be partly
29.
Part Three.
284
Trade
It forms a cushion against the effects of cyclical changes originating abroad and of international capital movements. It moderates
deflationary crises and inflationary upswings, though in return it
case
original situation
(=
100)
A would
stand
enough
to cause
covered by gold.
The
it is
is
far
debtor (Case 2) who receives large shipments of gold, but the one
In addition this gold should
that has a debtor also with a high coverage (Case 5)
above that of
its
whence
it first
came.
gold,
285
Self-Regulation
and therefore the smaller the price and comfirst, the longer will these movements persist
before the preliminary transfer has been completed entirely in goods.
the gold shipments
modity movements
at
7iot
made good
in the reaction.
But
A and B must
supposed
to
common
with Lutz,
F.
W. Meyer ("
XLIX
Devisenbewirtschaftung
[1939], 415-471)
als
the thesis that the gold standard could no longer function today because,
things, countries often
considerations.
endeavor
neue Wah-
among
movements out
other
of cyclical
In other words, they act as though their reserve ratios were consider-
Now
prices
need
compared with those of the creditor and in contrast with the prevailing view,
than if gold movements could affect the credit structure (see Table 16)
fall less
tion)
is
it
policy of sterilization
becomes dangerous only when it attempts also to neutralize the shift in purchasing
power proper (not only its multiple effect on the credit structure) that is, when it
tries to prevent the origin of the waves of purchasing power that bring about actual
;
transfer.
Part Three.
286
much
Trade
and
With
Summary.
different
3.
effect.
Our train of thought carries such wide implications, yet corresponds so little with the traditional view, that it may be good to
apply it to a few important examples.
(aa)
Do
the Whole?
Does
foreign exchange
Does it shift the
Mean
Injury
to
The
old theory of
and
tionably
final one,
it
is
would have
to
by drawing in
German discount
who are not
also those
concerned in it; that is, all those within the sphere of influence of
the Reichsbank, not only those situated in the Stuttgart wave of
falling prices. It worsens the barter terms of trade also for those
who either have already shifted their share in the loss of purchasing
power to others or who, with a uniform currency, would have had
nothing at all to do with the transfer. But we now know that this
Self-Regulation
287
deterioration
later
spread
it over a longer
period of time. Prices in Wiirttemberg have to remain lower for a
longer time, though the decline is less. Nevertheless, even in case
B they are still below German prices as a whole: (a) because of
decreased purchasing power, and [h) because of a restriction in
bank credits consequent upon the decreased circulation of notes due
to this decline in purchasing power. This restriction in bank credits
is in addition to the general national restriction, which is associated
with a reduction in the gold reserve.
The Extent
(cc)
of
the Preliminary
Transfer.
For various
34.
As a
rule,
the world)
35.
the
more
For so far
as deposit
money
exists
all
about half
and compensatory.
still
remains to
Trade
Part Three.
288
provide the debtor bank with additional foreign exchange until the
date of settlement.^ If we disregard capital movements because
they merely postpone the problem, the debtor must bring about an
export surplus of the size of the payment. This may be done by
decreased buying (his imports) as when he keeps a smaller stock
on hand; restriction of his enterprise; relinquishment of plans to
enlarge his factory, and the like; and by increasing his exports.
The former lowers wages and the prices of imported goods; the
,
latter,
of
Applied
(Paris)
to
its
demand
it
for foreign
raise the
demand
is
often
one of these
exports may automatically cause a decrease in imports. See H. Backe, Urn die Nahrungsfreiheit Europas (Leipzig, 1942) p. 75.
for
even in a
final transfer of
Selj-Begvlation
289
between a mere " advancing wave transfer " and a final equalization of
and decreased purchasing power (concluding, or final, transfer of goods in
the narrow sense) and, (2) in both cases between such a transfer within and beyond
guish:
(1)
increased
currency boundaries.
Example: obligatory clearing credits. See my article, " Die Lehre vom Transfer
Nationalokonomie, CLIV (1941), 400 f.
40. This recalls the procedure employed with the reparations payments, except that
then the tribute money collected by the Reichsbank did not have to be sterilized upon
which everything depended.
41. If payments are repeated at sufficiently short intervals the waves become a continuous price drop. The price differential around health resorts during their season,
for example, is of this type. The high prices in such places result not only from the
influx of purchasing power, however, but also from the fact that their season is very
short. It is also important that production for their own consumption, like that in
towns populated by rentiers is comparatively small, so that their supply areas have to
be greatly extended during the season.
39.
neu
Part Three.
2()0
Trade
The interjerence subsequently reduces the extent of the preliminary transfer of goods, and consequently also the reaction.*^
level.
Transfer Aid Necessary? When the legal or economically advisable reserves are fully used in the creation of notes
or deposits, the bank authorities cannot chose whether or not to
co-operate in the preliminary transfer. With a reduction of the
reserve they must raise the discount rate. If, on the other hand,
*^
the reserves are sufficient, so that both central banks can sterilize
the gold movements, the situation is exactly as with a purely metallic
currency: The preliminary cash transfer is not, nor need it be,
associated with any sort of transfer of goods. It is accomplished
Is the
(dd)
CLIV
(1941)
391
Nationalokonomie,
f.
43. See my article " Um eine neue Transfertheorie. Zur Verteidigung der alten
Lehre durch Fritz Meyer," Jahrbiicher fiir Nationalokonomie, 1943, pp. 23-25, a reply
to Fritz Meyer, " Eine neue Transfertheorie? " Archiv fiir Wirtschaftsplanung, I (1941)
171-180.
44. It
is
the discount rate, but not to prevent price waves by open market operations. Moreover,
it would be a mistake to believe that the effect of an influx of gold on purchasing
power can always be compensated by issuing government bonds instead of bank notes.
If the economy wants more money, credit will be created to the limits of possibility,
the bank discount rate will rise and attract foreign money, more gold will flow in,
and it will become increasingly difficult to counteract its effects by issuing more bonds,
291
Sdf-RegulalioTi
sums the
essentially
We
them
with Fig. 57. Then it is probable that the debtor will bear a transfer
burden. For he has bought at a higher price from the creditor B3,
though more cheaply from his former supplier B, as set forth above,
and he will reduce his own prices in order to raise the additional
amount. Conversely, the creditor will make a transfer gain, which
will be limited, however, by the fact that his increased demand
makes the services of his workers and sellers more expensive. The
change in the selling prices of those chiefly concerned diminishes,
though in small measure, the losses or profits of their sellers in so
far as these in turn buy from them. Even for those chiefly concerned, this business connection means too little for the change in
purchasing power of their workers and sellers to be noticeable at
first. With time, of course, both will shift part of their loss or gain
45.
The
business
is
how
It
it.
is
closely
and
elastically
Part Three.
2()2
Trade
who made
distance,
is
The
equal to the
loss
German
frontier remains to
Buyers in the Germ-an frontier ring gain from Germans,
sellers in the preceding ring, whereas sellers lose to
that is, to buyers in the French frontier ring. Thus in
situation at the
Germany
others,
whole a transfer
there
is
be
clarified.
is, from
Frenchmen,
that
the
German
loss results,
price.
One more
corrected.
46.
The
because
it
old theory recognized only this loss at the fiontier, and overestimated
confused the
losses
tlie losj
Moreover,
it
it
final losses.
293
Self-Regulation
but only
with a
loss
and
The
smaller such a
community
is,
the
more
at first affected
by a
transfer,
movements
(gg)
Depreciation.
].
even when caused by only a part of it. Suppose that upon repayment
of a large loan by a Berlin firm to a London banking house, the
Reichsbank prefers depreciating the exchange rate by 20 per cent
to a sharp increase in the discount rate. As soon as the preliminary
transfer has been completed the exchange rate goes up again to its
former level, and even higher during the reaction. If the Reichsbank
wished to maintain the lower rate, German prices would have to
rise instead. When through depreciation one aims merely to avoid
such price fluctuations, it is wrong to adhere forever to the lower
rate of exchange.
Let us compare exchange depreciation to facilitate transfer with
the results of a depreciation to revive the economy. If a 20 per cent
is assumed in both cases, the price levels will eventually
by 20 per cent in both. But what will happen before matters
have gone this far is decidedly different. (1) According to extent:
With transfer the price level rises in the reaction by as much as
40 per cent, but with a depreciation for cyclical reasons never by
more than 20 per cent. (2) According to direction: With transfer
the calculated price average falls at first because of the wave of
lower prices, and again later when the reaction subsides (from 40
whereas with a cyclical revival
to 20 per cent above the old level)
depreciation
rise
47.
in
Aj^
Z?i
is
demand
is
in different proportions,
Part Three.
294
Trade
Geographically:
(3)
The manner
in
which the
rise
accomplished
to be examined more closely in the case
of a depreciation for cyclical reasons. Depreciation lowers domestic
prices at first compared with those abroad. The foreign, and with
it the total demand increases; so, too, do prices therefore in both
domestic and foreign currency. But they do not rise uniformly.
As a rule, though not necessarily, the smaller exports were before
depreciation relative to domestic sales, the less important will be the
increase in foreign dem.and and the less prices need rise in consequence. For this reason the price rise, and with it the revival is
regionally quite different at first, but with time it is diffused from
the region and the branches of business first affected, to all equally.
At last, if we disregard secondary cyclical effects, all prices except
interest rates will rise in the same proportion as the rate of exchange
has been lowered.
This second phase is hard to demonstrate in concrete cases,
because it appears so late that new events distort the picture again.
The first phase, however, is well shown by the example of the
American depreciation. In 1935, as compared with 1932, the year
preceding the depreciation, the prices of such typically domestic
goods as fuel and furniture rose least, the former by 4^ per cent.^^
Industrial goods of which a few were exported rose more: e. g.,
textiles by 29 per cent. The greatest increase was shown by agricultural products with a high export quota; cotton, for example, of
which more than half the crop is exported, rose in price at New
Orleans by 87 per cent.^^ The still greater increase in the case of
wheat, almost none of which was exported, was caused by failure
of the harvest.^" Measures to limit the acreage under cultivation
also played a role, though not a decisive one.
Hence depreciation benefited most America's great depressed
area, the cotton-raising South Avhich, conversely, had been hardest
hit earlier by the depression. The situation of the cotton grower
was naturally communicated to the prices of the goods he used, but
not in such a way as to change them immediately and uniformly
throughout the whole United States; on the contrary, they reacted
most strongly first at the seat of the cause. Thus up to 1932 the
retail prices of food had fallen 33 to 37 per cent below those of 1929
of the price level
is
48. See
49.
50.
U.
is
enough
S. Statistical
S.
341.
295
Self-Regulation
they had fallen in the cotton belt, i. e., the South Atlantic, East South
Central, and West South Central States, by 35 to 39 per cent. Conversely, in the industrial area in 1935 they were 15 to 20 percent and
in the cotton belt 20 to 22 per cent above those of 1932."
The same
result
New
(Boston, Buffalo,
(Atlanta, Houston,
10 per cent in the latter.^It must not be forgotten, however, that the export quota merely
determined the rate at which the prices of various goods eventually
adapted themselves equally to the depreciation. With transfer, the
it
is
Germany
by loss of purchasing
power (spreading outward from Berlin in our example) is greater
by the effects of this loss. But even within the Berlin economic area
countries in the part of
In the
Even
first
later,
affected
when
is
being trans-
from U.
pp. 8-9.
52. Calculated from U.
Bureau of Labor
Statistics.
S.
Bureau
of
S. Statistical
Labor
Statistics,
384,
Part Three.
2g6
Trade
out as
it
prices as a
Munich
Berlin as
rise at
as representative of the
above.
it
than equalizes it. This last difference in price levels persists, even
though between changing regions, until the wave has receded from
Germany.
From
all this it
first raises
and then lowers the German price level on the average; but that
within Germany, within its great economic areas, within individual
small market areas, and even within single enterprises something
entirely different takes place. ^^
The
difference
started in Berlin.
is
Munich
conceals. But, to
return to our starting point, it shows above all that a depreciation
due to a transfer works quite differently from a depreciation to
differences
is
to
Self-Regulation
297
1,100 marks for 1,000 francs. On the other hand, with the higher
exchange rate that results from the passing of the ebb in purchasing
power across the border, 1,100 marks might now correspond perhaps
to 1,300 francs. An ebb in purchasing power of 1,300 francs and a
tidal wave of only 1,000 francs would then meet in France.
But as a rule events do not occur in this way. The fate of the
true Stuttgart ebb in purchasing power of 1,000 marks and of the
additional Stuttgart exchange loss of 100 marks is different. The ebb
is locally limited, whereas the corresponding increase in purchasing
power ^* among exporters, who export more, and importers, who
import less, is distributed throughout all Germany and raises the
price level everywhere.^ Exchange profits and losses are similarly
distributed spatially and the Stuttgart loss is generally indistinguishable from the others. It is decisive that the small waves of ebb
and flood that arise everywhere in Germany because of the altered
great
and the
wave has
just
begun
its
course,
(hh)
Does It Make Any Difference in What Currency a Debt
Payable? Whether in that of the creditor or the debtor? It is
obviously immaterial for the countries concerned whether the
creditor or the debtor starts the fluctuations in price level or exchange rate in the process of changing one currency into another.
With a fixed exchange rate it makes no difference to either, but with
Is
makes or
money
loss.
receives
^^
payment
in foreign
54. It does not leave Germany, as would be the case with a fixed exchange rate
through the shipment or the destruction the money.
55.
On
56.
This
the average
is
it
does not
rise, if
to
the ebb
is
who would
desire
payment
movements because
it is
in a currency that
it
holds especially
risk involved.
With paper currencies,
added to the general reasons why capital is less mobile
than within countries. But on the whole one can agree with Ch. R. Whittlesey (" Internationale Kapitalbewegungen bei gebundener und freier Wahrung," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv XLIV [1936]) that the restraining effect of free exchanges on the international movement of capital has been greatly exaggerated in the past.
capital
of the exchange
ParL Three.
2q8
Trade.
for instance.
with which the local production of goods does not keep pace. Trade
with the outside world must first be established. In the beginning it
is very much harder and more expensive to import goods than to
export gold. As the flood of purchasing power is not equalized by
an ebb it is gradually distributed rather uniformly throughout the
world, and may lead to a world-wide boom. For otherwise than with
a normal transfer, prices will rise everywhere and permanently.
Equalization of the Balance of Payments. Price movements are never necessary for mere equalization of the balance of
payments, because since every claim must be paid, deferred, or
canceled, it is always equalized. Only when the equalization is to
be brought about in a certain way, that is, otherwise than through
(kk)
balance of payments constitute an ordering, even though but temporarily effective, force.
Comparison with the Old Transfer Theory. ^^ The difference between the two views appears clearly in the different
(11)
57.
58. See
my
p. 288,
note
critical discussion of it
37.
("
fiir
Nationalokonomie,
299
Self-Regulation
first
suffice.'"
Both camps have confused the preliminary and the final transfer.
shift in purchasing power (which of course generally leads to
price waves even when creditors now wish to buy in addition what
debtors forego) does indeed suffice for the final transfer. For the
success of the preliminary transfer in goods, however, an artificial
shifting of the price level is necessary, but its effects are later
annulled by a reaction. The advocates of the old school thought
statically, and neglected space. For them the results of a loss of
purchasing power, and of a rise in the discount rate, were, equally,
a lowering of the " price level." They had no real notion of the
movement of a change in purchasing power in space and time.
They could not recognize, therefore, the fundamental difference
between the preliminary and the final transfer, which is ultimately
caused by the varying strength and proximity of the two price
movements. The crests and troughs of the two price waves are too
ill-defined and too far apart to result in the rapid transfer of goods
that with different currencies is required to complete the transfer
of money. Only for this reason does there occur the preliminary
transfer of goods, which can be brought about only through a shift
in the price level. The prompt effect of a discount policy, and
especially ^^ of the exchange-rate mechanism, depends, besides their
influence on the movement of capital, upon the fact that they bring
the two opposite regions nearer together by jumps, since in point
The
1943,
pp.
19-28)
Nationaldknonomie, CLIII
[1941], 727-734.
59.
60.
my
I,
too,
article,
LIV
"
first
group on
this point.
[1930], 1103.
and without
somewhat slower
effect of a
affects
movement
in the
Three.
Pd'ft
aoo
first
Trade
to the
national frontier.^^
Because the central bank cannot wait until the wave of purchasing power reaches the frontier it simply anticipates the effects
of this, in so far as they are of importance to it, by changes in the
discount rate, for these effects are the same in both cases: Goods
in a broader sense, of the
flow mainly from the border region,
one country into that of the other. Even with a shift of the general
price level the international equalization is thus completed at the
border, to which are then added domestic transfers between the
interior and the border region.*^* But apart from this, price waves
^^^
and the
one.
ft.
Tariffs
^^
62.
power
The
is
principle
equalized.
What customs
is
duties
mean
to
commodities trade,
Furthermore,
its
equalization
power
loss
is
more important
purchasing power approach one another in space, or the deeper or higher they are
countries,
are
exceptions.
64'. The direction in which these domestic transfers move is the reverse of that taken
by price waves. They begin at the border and progress gradually toward the interior.
65. It follows from our theory that customs duties affect the frontier zone most and
and
Compare
is
and
147
elasticity
3f>i
Self-Regulation
political risk
means
to international
movements
of capital.
One
could easily imagine a tariff policy that would not make transfer
more difficult, but rather facilitate it by simply taking the place of
discount policy. If the receiving country lowers and the paying
Reviewing our
results,
shift in the
Summary
we
find
that
frontiers generally calls for greater price movements than a corresponding transfer within a country. This is due to the following
causes:
1.
may
With
2.
among
connections.
Usually the
obstacles,
these sharper
price
reaction.
67.
rise
of
Trade
Part Three.
202
5.
When
is
what
around
phenomenon.
69. It
is
as
if
anticiapting
its
arrival,
is
not
its
Self-Regulation
his
home
303
cross
particular direction, even before they have reached its center. Nevertheless, it is at least probable in the case of sufficiently large and
own
frontiers.
6.
The Globe
here in open space. This merely reduces the problem of its fate
to insignificance, however, instead of solving it. What happens when
not a thousand, but a thousand million marks are transferred? The
decrease in purchasing power rolls onward, farther and farther
around Berlin. Long after equalization has occurred in the West,
0.7r
away from
this
0.7r divides
the population
eccentrically.
Large areas of
into halves)
its
own country
are farther
Part Three.
304
Trade
(2 --'>=
Fig. 58.
also,
among
occur, in so far as
is
that with
are propagated.
71.
The
B and
B^,
lie,
QP^iQi on which
The broken
3^5
Self-Regulation
1.
Equalization by Migration
So
far
we have
and demand may be due to changes in taste, the exhaustion or discovery of resources and countries, protracted unilateral payments,
increased
tariffs,
increase,
technical
would have
interest,
restricted his
72. It
problem of the
now found
itself,
and
great
enough
to
Part Three.
joG
Trade
74.
men
Naturally
it
is
known
in a general
and industries to places where they can make a greater profit or at any rate
costs. But in this connection such knowledge is too general.
75. For examples see the maps in National Resources Committee, The Problems of
a Changing Population (Washington. D. C .,1938) pp. 93 fl.
livelihood,
cover their
Save
when
by a sufficiently large
number. Then, perhaps, there will be with wages, as with prices of goods, some scope
within which they can vary from place to place without causing greater migrations.
In such cases one may speak of an upper, or inward, migration point and a lower, or
76.
outward, migration point for local wages, though not with the same precision as in
the case of
homogeneous goods.
307
Self -Regulation
risk,
continue until wages and interest are everywhere equal once more.
in neither the old nor the new equilibrium.
Results of Migration
2.
It is possible,
for the
movement
movement
of goods.''^
of factors
As experi-
fact,
the lender.
in the
as well.
and the
real question
is
is
is
a loss in population.
The
movements
opposite
is
it is
not so
much
that there
is
new demand
from the emigrants' country, as that part of the emigrants' demand and part of the
demand created by exported capital is retained by the emigrants' country. What is
new is merely that this demand now comes from abroad, and hence leads to export.
79. The more so since the prices of exported goods may very well rise. For on the
one hand emigration reduces the supply of goods produced in the emigrants' country,
and on the other increases the demand for them from the immigrant country, as has
already been set forth above. That is, the supply curve is displaced toward the left
may
easily
be
much
higher.
new equilibrium
price
Part Three.
3o8
Trade
upon many
things: It
ther migration depends upon how much of their income those who
were left behind have received from those who migrated ( a per cent)
and how much from elsewhere (b per cent). The remainder of their
income consists of consumption of their own products or exchange
themselves (c per cent). Hence a -{- b -\- c = 100. The emimay continue to buy something from their former suppliers
per cent), who depend to the extent of about (a -f b) per cent on
among
grants
(!
(a
-\-
original
b)
is
number
The
multiplier
is
then 100
-f-
40
2.5.
That
is,
every
mark
of original
income
that craftsmen derive from farmers raises their income by a further 1.5 marks through
trade among themselves to a total income of 2.5 marks. Not that the total national
income has increased by that much (Keynes's error) A rise of one mark in original
income in B^ results only in an additional 1.5 marks of the total national income being
shifted there, just as those remaining there are not simply unemployed but are
.
39
Self-Regulation
3.
a.
Consequences
classical
about
it.
difficult.
Assume
What
first,
and the
inter-
1.
Comparison between
Places: It
is
Wages
rise,
compared)
be sure,
to
where workers leave and fall in the places to which they migrate.
If it were certain that migration occurred only from places of low
to those of high piece rates, wages would become more nearly equal
interlocally, the easier and therefore the more common migration
becomes. But the money wage, or even the real wage, may be lower
at the destination of the migrant because he wishes to increase not
his purchaseable, but his total utility. In this case, wage differences
would be increased by migration.
Comparison over Time: In a region of decreased purchasing
power, wages not only tend to fall in comparison with a region of
increased purchasing power, but tend to fall absolutely also, in
comparison with previous wages. Matters remain thus as long as
frictional resistance or the prohibition of migration prevent a fresh
distribution of labor.^^ Of course migration must not be expected
unemployed only
Moreover,
as
is
cit.,
at their
former
site,
easily seen, or
even to think of
it
and
at their
sum
former wage.
of an infinite series,
do Barfod
(op.
and the author of " Zur Stadtplanung in den neuen deutschen Ost(Raumforschung and Raumordnung, 1941, pp. 100-230)
In other respects
gebieten "
both
it is
82.
internaticnalen
nomie,
II
(1930)
"
161-199.
Part Three.
oio
Trade
said, for
more from their earlier level, the smaller the extent of migration.
Hence the degree of the mobility of labor permits conclusions only
on the extent to which wages differ in time, not on the extent to
which they differ in space the very question in which we are most
interested in the present connection.
2.
Do
political
flow of goods?
3.
We
BE
DEPOPULATED WITH
FREE MIGRATION?
The
classical
Self-
Regulation
311
born elsewhere.
is it
j8.
Even had the classical writers been correct, it follows from what
has been said that the results of difficulties in the international
movements of the factors of production are neither sufficiently
important nor characteristic enough to justify preserving the strong
and unique position of international trade in the theoretical structure.^* But were the classical economists correct at all? Is it not
true that in their time, and throughout the reign of their theory,
no particular obstacles to international migration existed, though
there might have been hindrances to migration within countries?
Often enough national frontiers created no special difficulties for
migration, but merely adjusted themselves to these. In fact, countries even promoted migrations through their customs duties. Do
such special hindrances as prohibition of migration or love for the
fatherland operate any differently in principle from the usual curbs:
and
For the solution of the transfer problem, for example, though not for
is completely irrelevant.
its
" for
origin
Trade
Part Three.
31-
4.
The economy
adapts
movements
movements of proproblem, the latter a problem
itself to brief
disturbances by
them.
c.
The
WHAT REMAINS
able,
is
To
inter-
And
is
difference in currencies,
completely overlooked so
expected that prices in different parts of the same country will shift
in opposite directions.
3*3
Self-Regulation
The
classical view,
respect to the
movement
In cases where the source of the disturbance was not too far from
the center of the country, it described the change in price level
accurately for the period preceding the reaction. But even within
these limits the price level after all is only an average of organic
differences, among which the wider movements predominate at first,
though the smaller but essential movements prevail in the end.
Everything depends upon separating price waves from real shifts
in the price level, for their functions are entirely different. Transfer
is
if
confused.
among
reasons for this view are easily seen. There was a wish to derive principles
from simple cases that were at least roughly applicable to English conditions.
Working with whole countries offered the one possibility of verifying these principles statistically. Finally, the results for zvhole countries were of greater interest than
those for their parts; first, because practical decisions on such problems as free trade
or protection depended on these findings; second, because the main interest of the
classical writers was not in individuals or parts, or even structure, but solely in the
functioning of the whole. They differed from their opponents, who also emphasized
the whole, only in the fact that these latter could not understand how the whole could
be built on the utility instead of on the sacrifices of the individual; on his freedom
rather than on his restraints.
85.
at first
Part Three.
34
countries,
national trade.
Trade
outmoded
subsidiary assumption of uniform mass phenomena. As a consequence countries can no longer be regarded as economic units. We
now think of them in all their diversity and expanse rather than as
mere points. We take space seriously.
Chapter 20.
The
and
self-regulation
as a third
Its critics
good in
itself,
might reflect,
and as such constitutes a part of the national income.
This is the first reason why judicious regulation from without
(" intervention ") may be advantageous in principle. But, though
a free equilibrium may not be the best possible one, it is not
therefore arbitrary but reasonable after its fashion if only men
act in accordance with nature and logic. The automatic spatial
organization of the economy, for example, shows a quite acceptable
pattern on the whole, even from extra-economic standpoints, but
now and then the result can be improved by intervention.^ A second
type of meaningful regulation from without attempts not to create
a situation better than that arising from the free play of forces, but
to bring this situation about at a lower cost; that is, to facilitate
adaptation.
at least
1.
more
accurately, or
self-regulation.
2. J.
M. Keynes,
is
for
example
("
For even perfect functioning of the free play of forces guarantees only that
everyone will achieve his greatest attainable utility for every given constellation of the
other forces.
It
does not guarantee that the general welfare, or perhaps even the
circumstances by a
judicious alteration of the grouping from without. This should be possible, especially
when unwholesome forces are able to participate in the free play. On the other hand,
not many cases can be imagined in which an unwelcome situation could develop from
the perfect co-operation of
wholesome
forces.
Pari Three.
3i(i
a.
Trade
1.
The former
opposition
is
prevent permanent
shifts.
undesirable.
We
The
perfectly.
which we
sterilization
of gold
movements
moderates
in particular, to
be sure,
but at the expense of the other participant. If not only the unnecessary changes in price level but also the essential price waves are
compensated, and if this occurs on both sides, the transfer of goods
is
made
actually
shifts in prices, to
impossible.
Secondly, the
movements
in
If a
to.
tariffs,
it
themselves.
may
Men and
especially affected
effects.
If
country
it
start a
movement
by customs
duties, since
may come
much
is
protected or
in the protected
(Canada)
economy
that have to
317
Facilitation of Adaptation
2.
a.
By Monetary Policy
1.
Monetary policy
is
the chief
to
is,
and partly
fall
which are
later
to a cyclical
downturn. To this extent even short-run fluctuations are still influenced by a policy decision that was made far in the past a decision
as to the monetary standard.
A purely local standard (paper currency) leads, in the form of
fluctuations in the rate of exchange, to short but severe price jumps;
an approximation to a world currency (gold standard with a high
gold coverage) on the other hand, leads to small but protracted
,
4.
We
start
with an old-fashioned gold and paper currency; thus the exchange rate
and fluctuating
when
when with
change.
is
We
shall speak of a
is
in the other.
freed, or with a
We
is
say that
changed;
paper currency
factors
Part Three.
3i8
Trade
valid.
But only rich countries can afford these advantages, for they
require a great store of gold and exceptional renunciation of credit
creation as we see it realized in the United States. For poor countries, on the other hand, and especially those with great disturbances
in the balance of payments, a paper currency is incomparably more
suitable than a gold currency with low coverage. If a high coverage
were always more advantageous (for which there seems much to
be said at first) it would of course repay a poor country either to
borrow gold or at least to accumulate an interest-bearing fund of
foreign exchange. No doubt only psychological inhibitions or undervaluation of future advantages as compared with present sacrifices
stand in the way. It is true, furthermore, that a high gold coverage
develops its full advantages only in company with a small extent of
credit creation. But as this would mean other disadvantages for a
2.
Within what
how
far
legal coverage.
Regulation
pom
Without
319
On
the contrary,
it
can
more with an
rate
of deflation.
Now
They
and
movement; that is, prevent it from affecting the price level. The
gold movements will, of course, be increased thereby. Conversely,
the debtor country will reinforce the effects of the smaller gold
movement on prices with a discount rate above normal, and the
creditor country with one below normal. But this is only rarely
Thus the sterilization of gold will facilitate the preliminary transfer of goods, that is, will distribute it in time; the enhanced
effectiveness of gold will accelerate it.
intended.
The secondary effects on short-term capital movements will accentuate the difference between these various possibilities in the case of
gold movements, and weaken them in the case of price fluctuations.
When gold is sterilized fewer credits flow from the creditor country
to the debtor country; this necessitates a still greater flow of gold.
With increased effectiveness of gold the discount policy brings about
still
movement
policy of sterilization
is
therefore
Part Three.
poQ
Trade
more important
for
Case
2:
3:
5.
If
on the amount
the cover
and limitation
is
of credit
United
States,
and scope
it
does not
make much
by
F.
(1941), 174
f.
Meyer,
"
"
LIV
Archiv
Wirtschaftsplanung,
3.
The
321
preliminary
effects of slight
countries)
so
ment and
let
all
(case 2)
that only
two
in
1931,
when
front
first
to
7. In case 3 an attempt
exchange by using all gold
will
be
made
at first; that
to
is,
damp
also variable.
Part Three.
322
Tariff Policy
p.
tariff
Trade
would
facilitate a transfer
3.
a.
A boom
Full Employment.
under an
Thus
(b)
is
old-
the country
tariffs,
but a
system of import and export duties or other regulatory measures aimed at a flexible
exploitation of marketing possibilities.
of Germany's transfer burdens
("
3^3
Now
credit creation
is
slowed
down
in
the past.
3.
Autarky.
The
Again
F.
W. Meyer,
has generalized unique situations without dealing with business-cycle theory, and has
applied them to large economic areas as though this were a matter of course.
"
Devisenbewirtschaftung
[1939], 415-471;
als
(See his
XLIX
der Aussenwirtschaft,"
ibid.,
Part Three.
324
Trade
Methods
/3.
self-regulation,
The Course
y.
of
Managed Transfer
Lack of space prevents repetition of what I have shown elsewhere for each single phase of transfer: That despite interesting
differences in details the essential process with free and managed
is the same.^^
In both cases final transfer takes place
by the equalization of waves of purchasing power, whether these
appear as price waves or, with price control, as waves of employment.
In both cases final transfer must be preceded by a preliminary
transfer, and the chief medium in both is the movement of money,
goods, or credit, even though these may differ partly in their importance and in their reasons. In both cases, finally, the results of this
preliminary transfer, which are in many respects alike, are again
eliminated after completion of the final transfer.
equalization
b.
Either the
new
situation
is
N ationalokonomie
CLIV
"
(1941)
394-402.
This
fact
is
is
to
Die Lehre
(1940), 401;
everything
LIV
(1941)
312-348.
overlooked by
all
those
who do
CLIV
how to
Nationalokonomie,
not understand
apply price theory to the new forms of currency and foreign trade, and hence with
seek for errors in the theory instead of in themselves.
much ado
remain
as
it
325
new developments
are to be
prevented (1).
Impediments to Adaptation
1.
a.
The economic
so far that
its
an entire economic
all
of
down
new
any
What
Trade
Part Three.
226
cases, at least
abandon.^^
ticular, creates a
museum, which,
sums
for
combinations
12. I
the
its
is
amount
of psychic utility.
individual
is
if
and
it is
social
income
amount
as
possible to speak
The
Social
number
and national
interests
of contented philosophers,
The
so tenaciously to their
landscapes and their occupations that they are ready and able to
sacrifice solely in
reason,
is
make
order not to lose their connection. This solution, born of loyalty and
to equalize
wage
new depressed
economic
a voluntary
areas everywhere.
it
sensible
many
systematically for a
327
new and
J3.
is,
to
promote adaptation
it.
Prevention of
New
Combinations
1.
TRADE BARRIERS
change in foreign trade may result in undesirable dislocations of domestic production, which can sometimes be avoided
by tariffs and so on. These changes may be undesirable:
lasting
1.
If consumers gain less than producers lose. This amounts to
an objection against the argument for free trade. To the best of
my belief, it has been proved so far only that the division of labor
(that is, free trade) between two persons raises the physical income
of each when their abilities in the production of two goods are
comparatively different. A larger amount of both products is then
If
physical
of exports that
15.
"While
it is
may not be
so agreeable to them.^^
if
more
(in
Then
there
is
they had continued at their old one (otherwise they would not
Part Three.
328
Trade
nobody
this choice
is,
There
good extra-economic reasons for preventing the greater specialization of productive forces by means of
customs duties and so on: (a) because in the end it is more advan2.
are
still
a few
tageous for a people to develop their capabilities in many directions; ^^ (b) because materials for defense must be produced at
home, in so far as they cannot be procured from reserves or from
spheres of influence abroad; (c) because it may be politically
undesirable to have foreign countries profit more by free trade than
the
home
country.
It will
3.
into a
change)
it is
customs
duties.^
PROHIBITION OF MIGRATION
2.
As with
sliding-scale
free trade,
off
than
if
Economic Journal,
1938, p. 636.)
in
(L.
Robbins,
vir-
tually coincide.
17.
edition (1936)
pp. 221
(Berlin,
1933)
p.
162;
English
ff.
18. Naturally this argument is true only within certain limits. Complete autarky
would condemn almost any people to poverty and impotence.
19. In most cases, of course, a tariff to help over a period of adaptation, like an
infant industry tariff, will be most likely to benefit a nation as a whole only if new
enterprises would be profitable even though they themselves had to bear the cost of a
changeover or of development. (For exceptions see von Haberler, op. cit., pp. 207 ff.;
ff.)
329
men
or capital
The Facilitation
2.
a.
One
in
of Adaptation
practice
is
facts,
the
it is
made
difficulty
There
is
would be
factors.
on
still
bureau to furnish
opened up locations,
more important than information on single locational
of great assistance
especially desirable
and
central
easily
Trade
Part Three.
330
man
thus can never be found for all times. All that can be expected of
even systematic examination is an approximation. But suppose that
a better location has been found. Removal to it encounters diffi-
culties,
Our
in
lies
Its
frequent
One more
new
When
the
file
leader
is
tion.
The
first settlers
in the
start is especially
important in coloniza-
which they arrived, because the interior has not yet been opened
up. Seen from the standpoint of the history of the development their
choice of a location is wise, but it is wrong in respect to the final
at
outcome. That is, it has the unfortunate end result that the country
is never settled uniformly. An unduly large part of the later immigrants will also settle near the harbor (New York) not only because
,
may be
sites if
its
individual units
may be
33"
economy-
last detail.
motivation. First
measures
that
is
(1)
we
own
and then
their concrete
form in respect
way
immediate
nature of these
to
an objective
(2)
There most of the immiand a large part of the population in general have collected. (W. Madje,
Uruguay, Volkwerdung und landwirtschajtliche Erschliessung eines ilberseeischen
21.
grants
Munich
dissertation, 1937.)
Part Three.
332
Trade
should be
facilitated.
react
Factors
2.
Making
for Dispersal.
Three
at a suitable distance
their
23.
Not because
but in spite
of,
controlled
competition
economy the
control measures
is
als
contributions of Eucken,
of completeness
it
25. I
26.
"
In addition to this
to,
(com-
(Berlin,
1942)
Special attention
und
to p.
196, note
to
the
142.
Leistungs-
called to
is
strict
super-
be a solution that
Public monopolies are even harder to evade; they can crush potential
more easily, need be less afraid of interference from above, and feel
often the cost-lowering lash of the struggle for profits.
competitors
less
this
edited by G. Schmolders
aiislese,
itself favors
Der Wettbewerb
of
cost
of,
Die
still
Wahl
of sponlancous decentralization.
See
Z.
G. Dorner,
Industrieanlagcn
und
XIX
(1941)
27.
des Slandortes
A good mayor
is
fiir
41, 45.
its
growth.
333
is
in general controlled
y.
The
state
With
question
is
among
The Ruhr was the
small towns,
many would,
of course,
price of the
Many
World War
deficiencies
in
German economy
were
encouraged.
after
created
in
this
way,
Many new
agglomerations
depressed
extravagantly
Part Three.
334
We
Trade
economic suitability of a
First,
the
most significant advanimportant.
location as especially
investigated.
are
examination
tages of the area under
ment.
1.
industries
The
fuel,
typical
possibility.
4.
With
Sales.
The
first
of location
in the
manner
3.
Enhancement
of the Result
In the third place, the state can compel certain new combinations,
its intervention becomes truly creative. This is a rational
course when the measures adopted aim at achieving for a given
and here
31.
H. Metzdorf,
scfmftsforscItun(r,
32.
XVI
"
Raumordnung und
Agrarpolitik,"
Landwirtsrhaft
itn
Vierteljahrshefte ziir
Wirt-
(1941-42), 119.
nordlichen Kalifornien
Pfeifer,
(Leipzig, 1936)
p. 40.
nation, area,
greater than
335
or industry,
would be
few
we can
It is
discuss
connection.
Advancement
a.
A people can
of a People
by fuller utilization
encouragement of
progress; better distribution of national income and national wealth;
more normal distribution of the population; a more reasonable
proportion between working hours and free time; elimination of
first,
much harmful, inferior, and useless production; regulation of production and consumption in order to encourage easier and more
complete success of the economically rational; and so on. Second,
by increasing these resources at the expense,^^ or at least with the
help, of other nations. Here belong plundering, subjugation (reparaexpulsion (from the home country or from
tions, enslavement)
foreign markets) development (education of backward peoples and
opening up their territories) exclusion of competing peoples, and
duties that are borne by foreign countries or at least improve terms
of trade. ^* We select for discussion three stages of spatial expansion.
,
1.
those
who
value?
Pkmdering
^^
the soil
may provide
and
of a country
its
33. See J. J. Spengler (" The Economic Limitations to Certain Uses of Interstate
Compacts," American Political Science Review, XXXI [1937]) who believes that all
,
state
intervention that does not merely help economic laws to prevail can achieve
G. von Haberler, Der internationale Handel (Berlin, 1933) pp. 215 ff.; English
A. Losch, " Ein Auseinandersetzung ijber das Transfer[1936], pp. 290 ff.
problem," Schmollers Jahrbuch, LIV (1930) 1093-1106 (typographical errors corrected
34.
edition
in
LV, 192)
35.
On
f.
On
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv,
varieties
LVII
of colonial
(1943)
first
edition
Miihlenfels,
Trade
Pail Three.
gog
who
still
common
In
raising of
Consequently
it
is
difficult for
ff.
develop them as quickly as can large nations with but few possessions overseas.
38.
This has
C. Gini
("
also
been proved
statistically
W.
Sulzbach
("
ff.,
334
ff.)
is
Die
Zukunft des
overly skeptical
on
of the
337
is
In
Sombart
special
cases,
of
course,
political
weakness
German economy
may
in
itself
favor exports.
it,
and
The
profitable.
association
of
capitalism
not
essential,
though
Part Three.
338
Trade
European might. Though the course of events could not have been
wholly arrested, it could at least have been delayed.*- It is small
comfort that overseas industrialization benefited Europe also, that
it increased the purchasing power for her goods, and at most merely
changed the commodity composition of the exports: more machinery
instead of finished goods, more quality goods instead of massproduced articles.
It is true that the proportion of overseas trade to the total trade
of Europe changed but little immediately after World War I. In
1910 38 per cent and in 1930 40 per cent of all European imports
came from overseas, while in 1910 as well as in 1930 31 per cent of
to countries outside
Europe
{Statistisches
Jahrhuch, 1931, p. 95*) Power and welfare are not absolute, however, but relative to that of others. They diminish in Europe, even
though they may increase absolutely, when countries outside it grow
powerful and rich still more rapidly.*^ European foreign trade has
declined proportionately, though not absolutely. In 1910 Europe's
share in world imports was 66 per cent and in 1930 59 per cent; her
share in world exports declined from 60 per cent in 1910 to 53 per
cent in 1930.** This means that the world outside Europe carries
on increasingly more trade with itself.*^ No longer do all roads
.
formerly.
wirtschaftliches Archiv,
LIV
(1941)
is
no longer
so logical
is
as
338
ff.
43. In
'
'
XXXVII,
45.
no.
(1933)
War
II is said to
converge on Europe.
and Europe
339
The world
is
just
its
leadership,
be right!
on whether
restrictions on
is,
economic area
is
In addition
it is
essential to distinguish
the country at the geographical center whose market areas are most
expanded by the removal of internal barriers, from the frontier
all are curtailed by the increase of
outward barriers. The connection between the formation of a large
economic area and the stabilization of economic development is not
so simple as has been represented by some of those with no knowl-
edge of cyclical
relations.*^
economy
nineteenth century
licher Grossrdume.
f.
This has always been done within the sterling area. (A. Losch, " Verrechnung
und Goldwahrung ein Vergleich," Die Bank, August 21, 1940.) To this extent the
49.
Keynes plan
50.
offers
For the
nothing new.
rest,
is
partly a
matter of no consequence, and partly raises the same problem that would exist also
Part Three.
340
Trade
borders.
its
More than
it
is
cannot be said
clear that the advantages
this
of large
Unions.
3.
its
wealth not by
ship,
duties
the frontier or
succumb
entirely.
The
my
51.
The
first
world economy.
Losch,
"
Archiv,
LIV
Weltivirtschaftliches
[1941], 312-348.
52. The abolition of tariffs was incomparably easier a hundred years ago, when the
German Zollverein was formed, than it is today, because most industries still had very
short sales radii. In the main, therefore, only enterprises near a frontier suffered from
the competition of an adjoining country. After a union has been formed, prices will
drop more sharply in the country with higher duties. First, because the prices of
imported goods will be perceptibly reduced; and, second, because the resulting import
surplus (= loss of purchasing power) depresses domestic prices.
From
demand
53.
the
a definite price
onward
former frontier)
curves of those enterprises with the lowest delivered price at the frontier
the demand and cost curves lies lower when the latter
Figure 48)
This is shown in Figure 59, where A^' is the new
demand curve and P' the new equilibrium point. The market area within the frontiers
of the old state may be curtailed or extended, but the sales must extend into the other
is
not broken
(as in
member
of the union if prices are to fall. In Figure 60 the limits of the market area
before the formation of the economic union are represented by a continuous line,
those of the new one by a broken line. If Eastland had previously collected duties of
HK
arc
HJK.
34'
Westland
Fig.
59.
Fig. 60.
Eastland
tariff
when
produce their export goods more cheaply, whereas their increased demand is apt to
make imports more expensive (if it affects them at all) These countries gain less per
unit through free trade, but because by specializing they can produce and exchange
to
more
in
all.
suffices to
States pursues a protectionist policy, the barter terms of trade will be in the neighbor-
hood
of 10 cars to
lOJ^
chemicals.
With American
around
With American protection the United
mass production,
4|^
chemicals.
it
will
Germany
change
to
free trade
and Germany
With American
United States exchanges 145 chemicals for 100 cars, thus gaining 45 chemicals compared with their no-trade situation. Germany gains only 5 chemicals, on the other
hand, since she could produce 100 cars in the same labor time as 150 chemicals. The
cars in the
o<2
Part Three.
Trade
is
it
and
attitudes!
almost
all
^'^
at least in agriculture,
to
many
enough
Is it
to
Furtherance of a Country
remove the
much
less
^"^
with the
she specialized in car production and free trade prevailed, compared with the fact that
she can
now exchange
ten times as
many
cars
although at a
less
favorable price?
Even though the German barter terms of trade (per unit) have deteriorated, her gain
from free trade (namely, 125 chemicals: 150 30 -f 5) is incomparably greater than
(Of the gain of 125 chemicals, 120 are due to increased
the American gain of 45.
productivity which free trade, compared with autarky, makes possible, while 5 chemicals
are due to the gains from trade proper. Expressed in chemicals, the productivity under
autarky would be only 30.) [Translated from the first German edition, pp. 196-197.]
55. Instead of many villages becoming too small for local industries.
56. Thus, by increasing the amount of capital the Italian policy of the HohenstaufEen Emperors was a precondition to settlement of the East. See Dannenbauer, in
Festgabe
57.
state.
state
fiir
For
The
Haller.
many
was ready
that the
years
its
its
main
to
interest of
in
It is
more understandable
territory or,
under certain
343
That
is, is it
the conditions under which reality comes nearest to the ideal result
of the free play of forces without a long detour (2)
this ideal case still show defects?
1.
Or
does even
It is
We
common
good.
First,
respects
it
all
human
The
at
it
it
any given
tiinc.
the land.
is
But
On
it
is
that
it
may
be raised
men were
may be
less
by forcing persons to work in places or at occuhappy but produce more in physical terms.
of forces
Part Three.
^^
it
Trade
In the
first
place, economically
is
actually
the
moving van
To
common
60. Most of the large Canadian cities, for instance, lie surprisingly near the
American border. This is mainly because of climate and the natural routes of
communication.
61. This has been shown with the utmost clarity by G. von Haberler, Der internationale Handel (Berlin, 1933), pp. 138-139; English edition (1936), pp. 183 ff.
345
it
better, or
the
if
plant.
new
is
If
assumed
the
location
is
new machinery
In retrospect,
the
new
machinery
replaced by
is
it
turns out
means
so cheaply as
had
been assumed
originally,
improvement, still greater in comparison with the original condition, had arrived. Not to be able to wait, always to want the best
machines at the moment (not only technically, but economically
best) to react instantly to every change in locational factors, merely
decreases profits in some cases, but in others it means real private
and social loss. The latter is more probable the less superior is the
second machine or the second location to the first. ^,
Z.
Hence
it
is
not at
all
a tax
Part Three.
346
Trade
interest
What
to
Spatial Organization in
the competition
in
[1937],
Raumforschung und
"
..
Table
Method
for
77.
347
Goal
No.
More
healthful
I-IV
life
Higher earnings.
Fostering of Kultur
.
Military protection.
V-VII
uvwz
a r s
Method
for
a
a c n V
a y z
Methods
materials
dz
life
g ix
m-p
w
be
be
powers
Increase
industrial areas
Conservation of productive
n p-r
d f i-m
power.
Ownership of homes
Ownership of land^
11
12
13
14
15
16
of productive
Auxiliary Methods
DI
I
I
areas'*
Decentralization^Intimate contact
17
18
1-7
8-10
Recreation
V VII
Avoidance of unneces-
4-7,9-11
19
VII
VII
sary roads
Avoidance of traffic jams
More assured basis for
12-19
52
20
business planning.
size of enter-
20-22
prises
23-26
II
III
III
IV
III
VII
VII
21
Adequate
Encouragement of small
enterprises
Elimination of unprofitable
nonagriclutural
enterprises
Encouragement of old
nonagricultural enter-
hkl
hkl
27/8, 30
Introduction
of
new
nonagricultural enter-
VVI
V
VVI
VI
More self-sufficiency*.
More protected settle-
AC
III
VII
Spatial communities
Diversification of busi-
VII
ness possibilities
Full use of public
CII
Encouragement of poor
31
provementsj
Test economic
tions
1
1
1
regions.
49/50
4,51
2,8,16,53
3
q
q
3, 5,
27
Methods
Encouragement of independence
Autonomy of units of manageable
size
(p.
239)
suitability
of loca-
Increase
amount of land'*
41
42
43
44
Influence precipitation'^
Influence warmth"
Utilize industrial gases*"
45
46
47
Education
48
49
50
Influence migration"
Protect national monuments
Foster pattern of settlement
General partial protection of nature^"
Separate local and through traffic^'
Encourage obvious central points
5,34
Individual
ah
w
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
stallations*
Increase sales^
32
in-
Decrease costs*
47/8
Specialization
in
nonagricultural
enterprises*
Full-time employment* (see p. 164,
footnote 1)
Consolidation of landed property*
Obligatory licensing for new enterprises*
Merging of old enterprises*
Elimination of submarginal enterprises*
Discontinue subsidies
ment
26
27
28
29
30
Improve quality
Survey possibilities of technical im-
D VI
D
D
27/8,31/5
36/7, 46
4, 37/40
37,41
37, 42/4
45/6
Prevention of damage.
Soil conservation
Water conservation
Control of climate
Increased productivity.
Regulation of size of
population
.
24
25
25/6
prises
VVII
22
23
1,3,27/29
prises
VII
Individual Methods
(continued)
No.
51
52
53
(1) Closed to new nonagricultural enterprises, building (urban parks, good farm land), cultiva(danger of wind erosion), alteration (preservation of wild life, etc.). Zoning is in general
an important measure in the organization of space. (2) For example, by free divisibility. (3) Thus
permit no factories, warehouses, squares, etc., to intrude on the edge of a town between the residential quarter and the open country. (4) By accurate calculation of the costs of distance (see pp.
ff.), organization of the market, protection of a region, exchange of customers; knowledge of
neighboring associates, and promoting the maintenance of inventories. (5) With small enterprises:
promote small-scale technique (small motor, for instance); tax adiantages. With old nonagricultural
enterprises: rationalization of the enterprise and the industry (standardization, regulating the working
up of national resources); foreign models; cheap raw materials (geological research, reclamation of
waste). With new nonagricultural enterprises: reduction of freight and taxes and other rewards for
an adaptable choice of location. (6) With small enterprises: development of a demand for quality,
public orders. With old enterprises: dissemination of knowledge of their existence (by common
vation
Trade
P^rt Three.
348
and their quality (by expositions). With new enterprises: public orders, curbs on
importation.
(7) Encourage research, publish the results; instruction, advice, study of foreign
achievements. (8) Infant industry tariffs, temporary tax exemption, establishment of public installations (roads, electricity, water, railway station).
(9) For example, admit political and religious
refugees (Huguenots). (10) Important in fighting many pests. (11) Protection against wind and
erosion, equalise precipitation, sanctuaries for insectivorous birds (A. Seifert, Die Heckenlandschaft
fOdal, 1942], pp. 323-333). (12) Protection against drifting and erosion (woods, hedges, protective
planting, and perhaps prohibition of plowing), against leaching (suitable fertilizers), and against
building on good arable land. (13) Irrigation and drainage. (14) By dikes, clearing, and improvement. (15) For example, requiring licenses for large consumers, equalization of peak demands for
various regions.
(16) Encourage rain: fnrestation, facilitate evaporation from open water (slow
and shallow flow), rainmaking by cannon fire and seeding clouds. Prevent rain: clear forests, rapidly
flowing or deep water, cause rain to fall over the sea, eliminate the rainy season (the plan to widen
the English Channel, which is supposed at the same time to moderate the climate of northeast
Europe. See A. Jaumann, " Gelenktes Klima," Deutscher Volkswirt., 1942, pp. 972-974), hail
rockets. (17) Locate industry to windward [sic\; keep exhaust gases (carbon dioxide, iodine) in the
(18) For
country with ventilators (Kaserer, Berichte iiber Landwirtschaftl, n. s.. Vol. XXVIII).
example, time rates, not piece rates, for the finishing of expensive products that are easily spoiled
indenturing,*
attract
by free
increase
immigration
instance,
by
For
(investigations of Refa)
(19)
land for settlement (United States), expectation of independence, tax exemption, supplying of public
protective
Protective
animals,
so
on.
service (dwellings), beautifying of landscapes, and
(20)
planting, protection of picturesque landscapes as distinct from protection of whole regions (closed
areas). (21) Also in urban traffic. Direct through traffic past center of town. (22) Parallel where
possible by the size of the locality and enterprise. The best relation of agglomeration and dispersion
from the standpoint of aerial defense varies. (23) See, for example, F. Reichert, Das Gleichgewicht
der Geschlechter im Heiratsalter (Berlin, 1942).
advertisinK)
Spatial
(bb)
Organization ab ovo.
left entirely to
If
the development of a
magnitude and
its
Raumordnung; and many monographs. Valuable data for reorganization are provided
by the District Maps of the Reichs Bureau for Spatial Organization, which indicate
statistically
comparisons
illustrates
Furthermore, Bohnert
the re-
(ibid.,
1943,
pp. 79-84) has developed careful plans for a rural reorganization of Wiirttemberg
(for my objections see pp. 65, 66 f., 115, 195, 234, and elsewhere), though they are
much
too radical.
first
is
referred to
(Raumforschung und Raumordnung, II [1938], 13 ff.). Most of its proposals result directly from a comparison of
the real with the theoretical pattern; for instance, the plans for through highways,
consolidation of farms, and a more even distribution of population and industries.
For this purpose the regions where more, or fewer, or the already existing number of
inhabitants seemed desirable were outlined on maps. The most important preliminary
the plan for the spatial organization of Wiirttemberg
were
to
be more thickly
War damage
settled.
facilitates reorganization.
impetus to the order of spatial planning, and three commissions published reports:
Royal Commission on the Distribution of the Industrial Population (Barlow Commission)
Report,
tralization;
(Cmd
6153)
(London, 1940)
(Cmd
6378)
flE.
special Ministry of
349
The
First:
If a
country
is
ment
How
first
The
[a]
Plan.
The
first
and
greatest difficulty
We know
only
its
is
to get a clear
general outline:
The
national defense. ^^
The
66.
theorie
und Raumwirtschaft,"
in
say
main
as
Gedanken zu einer volksorganischen Standortlehre," Raumforschung und Raum(Hamburg, 1937) H. WeigI, 385 ff.; G. Schmolders, Wirtschaft und Raum
mann, Politische Raumordnung. Gedanken zur Neugestaltung des deutschen Lebensraumes (Hamburg, 1935) and others. In our sense, also M. Pfannschmidt, Standort,
"
ordnung,
Part Three.
350
We
optimum
Trade
size of the
" space
"
mathematical space
";
that
is,
approach of equal rank? For the practical significance of the theory of space see W. Christaller's excellent article, " Raumtheorie und
Raumordnung," Archiv fiir Wirtschaftsplanung, Vol. I (1941). Compare H. Meinhold's
review of the first edition of this book in Die Burg (Krakau, 1942) p. 360. He who
speaks about experience wants to convince those of like mind, but he who deals with
the measurable aims to convince all by his arguments. It is another matter when, at
research with
its
result, as a scientific
the completion of his work, an investigator's findings for which he has paid dearly
are
too,
when he who
actually
shapes space blends the ponderable and the imponderable into one artistic whole.
67. In this case, advancement of a country, it would be determined not by the
highest per capita income but by the highest total income, which would presuppose
a somewhat larger population. From a military point of view one would even have
is, all income that is above the subsistence
and could therefore be used in case of war or renounced. The latter means that
the labor concerned would be freed for military service. In case of war the total
available excess income is augmented when capital goods are not replaced, and by
other possibilities which temporarily increase the efficiency of the war economy. A.
Losch, Was ist vom Geburtenruckgang zu halten? [Heidenheim, 1932], Heft 2, 7th
Without
Regulatioti from
351
situation
when
is
so simple that
it is
is to be settled anew,*
of
the
settlement
can be taken
the
structure
benchmarks
for
and
where
conditions
similar and
agricultural
region
are
from an old
play
of market
whose system of locations came about by the free
forces. Then it may be hoped that the copy also will stand the
crucial test of functioning by itself as soon as it is left alone. Exact
as
plan
68.
is
Or
is
a creative act.
is
to
eastern territories.
missioner
7/n
(rural
development)
in
Reichskommissar
fiir
Neues Bauerntum, 1942, pp. 281-286, which contains an excellent survey; the compilations, Landvolk im Werden, edited by K. Meyer, 1941, and " Struktur und Gestaltung der zentralen Orte des deutschen Ostens," Reichsarb. fiir Raumforschung, 1941;
and the extensive bibliography in Raumforschung und Raumordnung and in Neues
Bauerntum.
69. It
is
way
that
all
older country.
70.
(blacksmith)
its
(dairy), in the small town (veterinarian), in the county seat (slaughter house), and so on.
Within the 1938 borders of Germany in 1933 there were 62,000 smiths, 12,000 dairies,
7,500 veterinarians, and 527 slaughter houses in about 50,000 communities, of which
46,000 had populations of less than 2,000. Depending on its nature, every pursuit,
therefore, requires a population of different average size. But these figures do not
necessarily provide benchmarks for a new settlement if the number of customers varies
greatly in consumption habits from region to region. In planning the start, moreover,
(especially upward) that a given
it is impossible to change the size of a population
nonagricultural enterprise ^vill need according to its development, desired income,
consumption standard, and so forth. In this case the typical location of a particular
business may be a community of higher function, unless all villages are planned to be
Part Three.
.2
ff.)
Trade
its
main
outlines
We
to arise,
much more
Even when the plan was originally good it may become antiquated by unforeseen development. (3) Gradual putting into effect:
The plan shows the final goal, but settlement of a country seldom
takes place in a moment. During the state of transition the population distribution will differ entirely from its final distribution,
tions:
may become
necessary.
and within
The latter determines the largest size of the market area, the former the
minimum number of its inhabitants. (See J. Umlauf, " Der Stand der Raumordnungsplanung fiir die eingegliederten Ostgebiete," Neues, Bauerntum, 1942, p. 284.) The
consumers.
locating of nonagricultural enterprises whose necessary sales radii extend beyond the
planned area is a risky business. Unlike smaller ones, these cannot be guaranteed
survival by keeping competition out unless they are monopolies or enterprises supplying
the state.
71.
The same
where there
is
as little
natural landscapes.
72.
Of course
it
modern formation
of artificial landscapes,
of location
is
353
is
Two
on the
not;
it is
free to
employ or
not.
To
the
first
belong:
See
Raumordnung, 1941, p.
74. Where this rigid
increased responsibility
150)
test
is
enterprises
(Raumforschung und
is
lacking
an
power degenerate into
planning includes power
,
let his
do the senseless. Here is an example from my own experience that could hardly
have turned out worse if the settlement had grown entirely without plan. In a small
town where a few steps used to take one into extensive woodlands and fields of waving
grain, one must now pass through miles of ugly human projects before seeing the
beauties of nature spread out before him once again. The most beautiful spots have
to
489-496)
(See
.
to the eye
and the
forester
Part Three.
354
Trade
and industry. The situation and central point of a system of economic areas may even be first determined by a political actnamely,
the founding of the capital; our ideal case of a uniform plain is the
best example of this. There are many instances of the attraction
exerted by a capital. Thus Stuttgart, a capital, has far outstripped
Cannstadt, though the latter is more favorably situated from the
standpoint of traffic; and even after industrialization the towns in
Wiirttemberg that are seats of higher administrative units {Ober-
amtsstddte)
districts.
Where government
progressed.
traffic network: In our ideal economic region a
route had to be arbitrarily established in addition to
the capital, before the position of the system was unequivocally
determined. Indeed, an economic region owes it very origin to the
advantages of a capital and busy main traffic arteries. It is for this
reason that the laying out of administrative and traffic networks is
such a powerful means in the spatial policy of the state. As soon as
the main traffic arteries and their tariff schedules are given, the rest
of the economic region, the feeder lines and the rural towns, can
main
traffic
be established.
thus providing a framework of capitals and main highways
actual settlement the state has already exerted a powerful
before
By
75.
Points
colonization.
of
crystallization
Thus
New
A Marketing Atlas
York, 1931], p.
vii.
1850
421)
it is
76.
easy to see
how
first
settled
Regulation
influence
Without
fro>ri
355
the surveying
Encouragement
facilitate
Compare
e. g.,
"
Urban
appioximately eight miles apart with loading platforms four miles. These centers
for
supplies."
110 to
"
78.
The
arrangement of the
traffic
network. Yet
is,
when
first
Office
and when
it determined this in advance. According to the classic account of Friederici the actual
end result depended upon whether the squatters who occupied the land or buyers who
wished to get possession of it won in the end. Then, too, the tendency to give everyone
an equal amount of land, with or without payment, came into conflict with the enormous allotments to individuals or companies (not always with the condition of later
subdivision among settlers)
In New England complete new settlements were planned
with considerable success, in the South with but little; in the West everyone lived for
.
In any case,
according to plan.
is
Friederici,
Turner, TJie Frontier in American History [New York, 1921]. Meynen and
Lebensraumfragen Europdischer Volker, edited by K. Dietzel [Leipzig, 1941],
278-292. Pfeifer, Geographische Zeitschrift, 1935, pp. 138-158, 361-380.
301.
F. J.
Pfeifer in
II,
it
(G.
Part Three.
3^6
Trade
The entire plan of the state is thereby put to the test. As explained
in 2, encouragement consists in the promotion of all ordering and
especially of all liberating forces, but, in the settling of new counHere a preliminary
tries, above all in anticipating the result.
determination of possible locations for settlement and their opening
up through public installations (water, power, traffic connections)
facilitates choice by colonists and entrepreneurs.^^ Correction of
the preliminary rough plan by the introduction of finer details
occurs only with time, when free initiative no longer needs to be
encouraged.
Restriction of private initiative:
The
and other
In order to protect
to provide
for necessary corrections in the results of a free organization of space,
the common will of the citizens is influenced also by measures of
the nature indicated in Table 17. When applied to a new country
they are appropriately changed, and they perfect the result in comparison with mere self-regulation.
centers,
and otherwise
The
79.
settlement of whole regions at a time has the advantage that public installa-
Lokator
United
If
States;
factories.
the agricultural advantages associated with a low population density do not out-
357
With
means urbanization.
y.
Encouragement
an Industry
of
Again the principal methods are education, payment, and comOnly through education can the whole economy be
promoted together with the particular industry concerned.^ Compulsion, as practiced by mercantilists, for instance, where the state
provided workers and customers to young industries, means disguised
payment, borne in this case by those who had to deal with the industry in question. Overt payment appears in the form of lost subsidies
(direct subsidy and protective tariffs) or of productive subsidies
The latter are designed to
(infant industry or temporary tariffs)
pulsion.^"
c.
We
employed
in
in
The amazing
industry,
possibilities are
dem Krieg
als
of the
Wurttemberg linen
in the 1860's
(Berlin,
1934), pp.
112-114
(Zwischen-
Part Three.
958
Trade
here the quarrel between deists and theists will be recalled) though
the correct policy almost always begins at the roots, and not with
consequences. Finally, theory need not await the slow and inaccurate
operation of the economic mechanism, but can anticipate the results
is
required.
model
life.
The
great rules of
much
as
thumb
cases.
this elaboration
lost in details,
is
because
down
it
much more
simplifies;
it
is
intricate cases.
Theory
is
not useless
useless only
simplify
Where could
beliefs of the
85.
"
liche
Theorie.
(Ibid., p. 82.)
'
descriptive
W. F. S.]
'
German
is
on the
theory on the basis and
rests
359
and
Not
is
in explaining that
nature and
the creator,
lies
THEORY
reality
1. Most radically, perhaps, through a widespread tendency in the United States, and
most dangerously through Keynes, whose General Theory of Employment, Interest,
and Money (London and New York, 1936) is really based on phenomena of decadence
in the economy.
365
^fl^^
364
Four.
Examples
actual.
reality for
and liberty.
As investigations on the economics of space are still relatively
few and scattered despite an awakening interest in all countries, it
was important to assemble as much material as possible, and I have
therefore drawn to a considerable degree upon foreign writings in
belief in reason
addition to
2.
"
The
my own
extensive studies.
[reprinted (with
minor
alterations)
in.
Memorials
to
compared with the United States, for the shorter distances there are
and a greater density of population. Between Berlin and Stuttgart
there are more things upon which the imagination can linger than there are between
New York and Kansas; and more people, with all their various characteristics, are
crowded in between the two German cities and withdraw the south from the immediate
role in
offset
Europe
by higher
as
costs
interest of Berlin,
A. Location
Chapter 21.
a.
1.
Locations of Production
UNIFORM DISTRIBUTION
N ON AGRICULTURAL ENTERPRISES
A map
of the banks in
of such a distribution.
am
of the 99 counties
1.
cement industry
up
W.
G.
Holmes
"
Cement
mills
began
American
to spring
2.
(Plant Location
[New York,
'
'
size."
1930], p. 17.)
States,
365
Map
154)
1910
(Paullin
and
Part Four.
366
final
example. Figure 63
is
map
of the great
own
European
Examples
fairs.
We
something
shows that
district as
Fig. 61.
* '
:v
Member banks
Iowa, on January
in
-_*i.Vi>**
L*
1,
/. :. ;. :
m,
(University
1926.
V
^>v
Map
of
Bank
of Chicago,
Chicago, Bureau
of
5.)
-J
Fig. 62.
Bank
locations
in
counties of Iowa
Variations are
number
in
Maps
much more
notice-
and the distribution of the more numerous cattle markets, shown on a map in the
same article,^ is more regular. The reader is referred also to maps
of the Russian tractor stations, dairies in Iowa,* American cotton
gins,^ and daily papers in Indiana.
3.
4.
5.
U.
S.
of cases,
A. Allix,
Department
of
Series
p. 56.
6.
U.
S.
Department
of
of Distribution,
I,
3G7
f.acattons of Pioduclinn
ments, ice cream plants, brickyards, breweries, and hotels; but above
individual cases.
Fig. 63.
Principal
Geography of
Fairs,"
European
fairs,
1921.
(After A.
Allix,
"The
p. 503.)
Sometimes
this
refineries
are either distributed throughout the beet-growing district or, in so far as they refine
cane sugar, concentrated at three ports of entry. Similarly with gristmills. Some
German cement works are scattered throughout central and southern Germany, whereas
others concentrate near coal mines. Consider also the locations for natural
carbonated waters.
and
artificial
Table
18.
[ndustrics with
more than
1,000 plants.
Of
NumIndustry
Production
value
ber
of
added
plants
mil-
total
production
the following
percentage
was
produced
dollars
Consump-
in
regionsjregions
in per in per
cent of cent of
Self-
their
Artificial stone
Ice
cream
Planing mills
Bakeries
Beverages
Artificial ice
10
Furniture
11
Structural steel
12
13
14
15
16
17
Boxes
Abattoirs
Potteries
Confectionery
Printing and publishing.
Dyes
19
Natural stone
Canneries
20
Butter
21
Grist mills
Electrical
22
machinery
con-
duc-
sump-
tion
tion
52
59
740
235
54
72
135
288
111
180
61
12
17
14
18
12
12
1,347
1,753
1,881
2,997
3,527
4,022
Jewelry
31
Women's
clothing
8,082
32
33
34
35
36
Silk goods
Spinning and weaving mills
Furs
1,281
Shoes
Automobile parts
products
hats
Total
461
213
178
11,524
8,605
3,778
1,482
1,249
1,277
1,749
2,021
12,712
1,063
1,888
1,341
1,154
12,915
1,293
1,536
Turpentine
21
669
3,691
goods
61
1,851
1,802
1,108
Book binderies
Men's clothing
Women's
49
45
50
42
28
42
33
28
25
25
172
258
789
167
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
Wood
32
39
37
40
57
47
43
48
66
59
68
59
2,438
3,150
4,849
20,785
5,154
4,110
171
522
232
134
69
56
78
62
60
35
56
19
16
13
18
15
11
24
24
51
61
16
51
54
25
18
36
24
57
51
40
46
54
17
49
57
41
24
19
28
16
27
27
24
44
78
66
74
79
13
14
17
20
13
58
53
48
83
56
34
48
52
26
36
46
38
54
43
35
47
32
44
17
41
53
36
25
33
15
18
23
and
apparatus
Woven
their
pro-
18
tion ofjtion of
Pro-
duc-
surplus deficit
in
lions of
Examples
Fart four.
3i)8
1,491
2,855
1,636
1,183
1,329
72
461
443
451
681
854
98
98
775
319
626
101
74
73
79
84
12
45
33
38
39
30
26
27
29
23
14
24
20
15
23
26
4
23
12
10
4
710
26
14
15
12
4
15,858
65
15
11
11
16
10
11
16
19
81
76
85
79
79
82
96
23
17
ca.
39
17
31
16
21
17
j
23
16
21
ca.
30
60
a. " Regionally " (that is, in the producing state) there was consumed (production
of the self-sufficient states -\- local production of the deficit states -j- local consumption
of the surplus states) in per cent of the total production. For the method of calcula-
tion
employed
see
Table
19.
Locations of Production
369
income.^ Samples showed that using the share in retail sales would
have given substantially the same result. If consumption was not
more than 20 per cent above or below production, the state concerned was placed in the self-sufficient group. If consumption was
more than 20 per cent below production, it appeared as a surplus
state; and if consumption was more than 20 per cent above production, the state was entered as a deficit state. The results for all
the investigated nonagricultural enterprises together are reproduced
in
Table
19.
Table 19
Regionally
Production*
Consumption
65
18
17
25
18"
57b
Surplus region
Regions of
self-sufficiency
Deficit regions
100
a.
b.
c.
cient
consumed
production as
per cent of total
production
25
18
17
100
eo"
Thus 60 per
provided
cent of
all
state that
When
it.^
1
to 25, including 70 per cent of
70 per cent of it locally. This is
far more than might have been expected from the usual descriptions
of the concentration of industry. For example, 74 per cent of all
it
shoes are
8.
made
in
Represented with
New
sell
sufficient
to
be sure, but
local
und Raumordnung,
f.)
Part Four.
370
Extmples
We
and consumption
tion
of
conclude:
(I)
The produc-
To this conclusion it
astonishing nor generally true, since in order to limit the
of nonagricultural industries investigated
we have
number
the
first
place
that there
is
it is
number
virtually
of regional connections.
Thus
is
relatively small.
many
important
10.
One
county town,
say,
how much
fiir
F.
of the
retail
workmen, beverages,
the inhabitants of a
is
spent there
(from
for housing,
money spent by
electricity,
gas,
water,
fuel,
furniture,
products as flowers, green vegetables, eggs, butter, milk, potatoes, meat, and so on,
make up more than half of the total. Even a world capital like Berlin with
enormous environs carries on more than half of its trade, calculated by weight,
with the province of Brandenburg. (Ausschuss zur Untersuchung der Erzeugungs- und
Absatzbedingungen der deutschen Wirtschaft. 1. Unter ausschuss. 2. Arbeitsgruppe.
Das Wirtschaftsleben der Stddte, Landkreise und Landgemeinden [Berlin, 1930], pp.
certainly
its
94
ff.)
Locations of Production
to them.
may be
these
of factories."
is
made
Thus our
371
Only
is
as perfect as in industries
their
demand
with thousands
larger.
into account
traffic
it
is
routes,
much
higher,
West of
and Canada has been omitted from our
If these
of retail trade
uneven.
Part Four.
p^2
Examples
"
nonagricultural enterprises are luidely spread out in space. " Belts
disdisturb our theoretical economic geometry much less than
" do, for example. This greatly strengthens the impression
tricts
that the spatial distribution of most nonagricultural enterprises
'
corresponds very
xuell,
second objection might be that the Census of Manufactures, upon which our investigation is based, does not cover all
nonagricultural production. Enterprises with an annual production
of less than $5,000, auxiliary production of retail shops, the building
(2)
When
many
as
(3) It might be urged in the third place that the fact that
production and consumption in a state are equal still does not
prove that a large part of its products is not exported and a large
part of its consumption imported. For instance, the two most
important wood-producing regions in the United States, the Northwest and the Southeast, supply one another because the former
produces only soft and the latter principally hard woods. Yet
experience shows that specialization and overlapping seldom go so
far. As a rule a whole scale of qualities is produced everywhere,
so that at most their ranking differs from place to place. And even
though the sales radii are often very long, those regions near a
market are nevertheless of most importance because of the thinning
out of markets with distance, which will be discussed later. On the
other hand, a difference between production and consumption may
be only apparent and due to the fact that, though income or retail
sales may be good average measure of consumption, they may not
always be so in the individual case. On the basis of such a calculation the South would have a surplus of artificial ice and the North
would have to bring it in, whereas it is perfectly clear in this case
that the requirements of the South are above, and those of the North
below, the average. Accordingly this third objection should lose
much of its significance when everything is taken into consideration.
LocaOons
of
Production
373
(4)
it
of products
size.
" domestically,"
so
theless to such a
as a single state.
Although none of the four objections discussed has proved decisive, it cannot be denied, of course, that despite its extent our
investigation of half of American nonagricultural production is after
all only an incomplete means of determining the site of every single
location and its market an impossible task for one investigator
alone.
Consequently this study provides a strong presumption
rather than a rigid proof of an agreement between reality and the
essential features of the theoretical outline.
Table 20.
EMPLOYMENT PER
;
'
Building industry
Other local requirements
Supplying district needs
berg
Ruhr
Reich
38
32
31
24
86
94
96
94
126
21
147
150
39
12
13
165
92
113
98
261
207
Wuerttem-
26
39
East
Prussia
32
32
30
INHABITANTS
30
30
26
Nonagricultural superstructure
1,000
244
size
and
size,
nonagricultural production
is concerned, is
upset especially by the fact that the large states are mainly agricultural whereas the
small ones, where a real need for outside products would be expected, have many
different industries.
14.
To
be found in part in
schafilicher
"
Die Tragfahigkeit des deutschen Ostens an landwirtin Struktur und Gestaltung der zentralen
p. 29.
Pari Four.
y^
Examples
Agriculture
2.
At
first
sisrht
very uneven,
if
The
still
basic agricultural
more important.
Its
network
itself is still
to
15.
much
Arkansas
(35
per cent)
by the
On
more
of Agriculture, Value of
Locations of Produclion
37f
ratio of agriculture
to
economy
the
in general.
The
difference
between Rhode Island and the state of Missouri, for instance, shrinks
from 1 34 to 1:2. Above all, the transitions are much more
crradual and reorular, so that differences within single economic landscapes can often be neglected. On the whole, the agricultural
population thins out from East to West on the one hand, and from
the center toward the North and South on the other (Fig. 64) .^^
:
Fig. 64.
States,
1930;
Canada,
Dominion Bureau
1931).
Statistical Abstract
of the
culture.
As
is
17.
But
distribution
is
far
it is still
West have
is,
For
exceptionally sparse.
particularly small.
is
all states
in
which
less
is
less
the higher
its
proportion of the
state's
population.
18.
In the comparatively thickly settled .South, for example, the slight inclination to
to
Examples
Part Four.
376
more
Similarly, distance
intensive agriculture.
b.
1.
When
is
rather
UNEVEN DISTRIBUTION
was chosen.
more
An
readily, of course,
answer, too,
is
more
why
readily
per hectare.
Relation of physical yield of various crops to the proportion of total production of the
U. S. supplied by New England, Middle Atlantic, and East North Central States
Yield per
HECTARE
100 KG
Share of the
Northeast
Cotton
1.7
Rye
Wheat
8.0
21
9.4
27
37
39
Oats
11.5
Corn
12.8
32.0
,May
Potatoes ....
73.8
41
47
O. E. Baker's map: "A Graphic Summary of the Number, Size and Type
and Value of Products," U. S. Department of Agriculture, Miscellaneous
Publication No. 266 (Washington, 1937) p. 6.
20. See
of Farm,
Locations of Production
377
whereas but
industries,^!
is
little
what
it is
in reality.
It is easier to
more
clearly
glass,
maps
See the
in Meyer's
(Leipzig,
1938)
pp. 26
fF.
Standortsthcorie
lished by
Amt
For a lucid description of the locations of larger groups of nonagricultural enterprises see M. Pfannschmidt, Raumordnungs- und Siedlungsfragen. Handworterbuch der
23.
Betriebswirtschaft
ff.
Another American example is the partial migration of the shoe industry from
New England toward the Middle West, so well described by E. M. Hoover in Location
Theory and the Shoe and Leather Industries (Cambridge, Mass., 1937)
An unpub24.
Part Four.
3^8
the
new
location.
In the
first
two
new
American
Civil
War
were attracted to
most important direct
factories
cases the
Examples
in the third,
apparently,
World War
suitable
utilization
more
even of poorer
ones.
The freeing of the slaves and the prostration of the entrepreneurial spirit in the defeated and ruined South after the Civil War
created an army of cheap labor that became still more attractive
power of the trade unions in New England, the
former center of the cotton goods industry. In addition, some freight
costs were saved in so far as the finished product remained in the
South. 2^ In addition there were lower taxes and building costs and
cheaper power, and in general a relative price drop in the South
due to the tariff. Finally, the invention of air conditioning made the
South independent of the New England climate, whose humidity
after the increase in
The
migration took
so cheap
of English industry.
25.
all
three times as
much.
in freight costs
Predohl, " Die Siidwanderung der amerikanischen BaumwollindusXXIX (1929) 106-159; 66*-80.
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv,
Locations of Production
379
and
so rich at
that
first
it
und
War
I,
when
the
coal
and toward
ore.
war
3 tons of
Die ortliche Verteilung der amerikanischen Eisen- und Stahlindustrie," WeltXXVII (1928) 286 f.
Technical developments have caused changes in location again and again,
28. "
wirtschaftliches Archiv,
29.
wood
(charcoal)
been exhausted.
30. The advantage of the Lorraine iron foundries over those of the Ruhr lay in
lower production costs and closer proximity to the markets of southern and western
Germany.
31. See F. S. Hall, " The Localization of Industries," U. S. Department of Commerce,
Twelfth Census of Manfactures, 1900, Pt. I, pp. 190-214; H. Schumacher, " Die Wanderung der Grossindustrie in Deutschland und in den Vereinigten Staaten," Schmollers
et
al..
Part Four.
gSo
Examples
These migrations away from coal and the seacoast together with
the long-run decline in coal exports,^^ and in part the exhaustion
of good fields,^^ did more than the great depression to create the
distressed areas of
Scqtland,^*
London
In the
of a regional
area,
Agriculture
2.
cities,^^
32. Prestige
exports went to half of the world, but each coal district supplied
freights
on bulk goods.
deep as American on
and to have longer galleries. (J. Lubin and H. Everett, The British Coal
Dilemma [New York, 1927], p. 130.)
34. See H. J. von Schumann, Standortsdnderungen der Industrien in Grossbritannien
33.
the average,
seit
dem
J.
tribution
(London, 1940)
and
others.
35. Thus the commissioner for the distressed areas was right in advising that they
produce mainly for their own needs, and buy domestic products whenever possible.
(First Report of the Commissioner for the Special Areas [London, 1935], p. 80.)
Though it is difficult for countries to shift part of their burden of unemployment to
other countries because of doubtful methods and foreign reactions, the attempt may
C.
(See
Hasenclever, Arbeitslosigkeit
und Aussenhandel.
Eine theoretische Studie, insbesondere iiber die Wirkung von Zollen auf die Arbeitsand especially G. von Haberler, Der internationale
losigkeit, Kiel dissertation, 1935)
;
Handel
36.
H. Backe,
Um
ff.;
ft.)
(Leipzig, 1942)
p. 57.
Decken has shown for the supply area of Hamburg, from an examination
of which Thiinen had derived his theory, that on the whole his theory is still valid,
though natural and human differences are more strongly in evidence today because of
37.
H.
v. d.
3^'
Locations of Production
were clearly still cultivated more and more extensively outward from the village (manured land, open pastures, open wood" With increasing distance from the economic
lands, and woods)
center, the village, the constructive force that developed a cultivated
landscape from a natural landscape lost its intensity " (p. 63). Today
village
the increasing degree of intensiveness has further blurred the differences. But where distances are considerable, as in the Birkenfeld
area, arable land is still divided in two: the inner field /, with a
three-year rotation of crops
less
six-year rotation, in
is
stable
five- to
dis-
These lines
it required the same time to haul a load of manure.
The longest time to a
he called " manure-isochrones " (Fig. 65)
field within the area / was 50 minutes, to a field within area A,
2 hours. Thus twice as many loads could be carted daily to /, and
heavier loads as well, since / was lower, as could be carted to the
more distant A. In addition to the time required for hauling, the
.
lower freight
rates.
zur
Vierteljahrshefte
("
XVI
Wirtschaftsforchung,
The
(1941-42), 220-232.)
physical
falls
schnapps.
Thus
may be
intensiveness
may
even differ at the same distance (extensive cultivation of grain and intensive production of butter in the fourth ring lie beside, not behind,
(Wagemann's
"
one another)
law of alterations
")
That
is
intensive-
therefore not
convincing.
38. "
There
is
much
greater compulsion
to
production
site
Thiinen, Der
plays a role
when
they encircle a village, because the fraction of the same total expense
represented by the cost of hauling varies with the distance of the fields from the village.
Part Four.
982
Examples
relative cost
on animals and
Roads
Combined
Ihree-field rotation
to the fields
Area
Fig. 65.
manure
of five-field rotation
Bonn, 1936,
im Landesteil Birkenfeld,
dis-
p. 89.)
c.
common, and
least
in remote areas
on the German-Swiss
Locations of Production
383
or branches to Germany, and the reasons for establishing them precisely in the border region. During the past century the decisive
factor in most cases was the saving of German customs duties. This
was shown, for example, after the entrance of Baden into the German
Zollverein, and after Germany's adoption of a protective tariff in
the late 1870's, by a blossoming-out of industry in Upper Baden;
and shown
several Swiss
frontier zone
40. Incidentally,
from place
("
Beitrag
to place
zum
des Deutschen
interlokalen Steuerbelastungsvergleich,"
No.
upon
Reichs,
1932,
4,
p.
123)
location.
On
Part Four.
384
Examples
large
number
By
made them
it
was
decide to go to Canada.
42. The statements in this and the following paragraph are from H. Marshall et al.,
Canadian and American Industry, a Study in International Investment (New Haven,
1936).
Locations of Production
385
Canadian market
ment
to attract
enough and susceptible enough of developthe superior American industries and the great
is
large
stream of capital that seeks investment. Nevertheless, there are converse cases. One is the dairies on the American side of the border.
As the American ad valorem duty on butter was much higher than
that on milk, especially in the 1920's, whereas with milk the freight
was more important, the farmer on the Canadian side found it more
profitable to send his milk to the United States, where it was made
into butter near the line. Only at a certain distance from the border
did Canada ship butter rather than milk.
When
is borne in
mind, the opposition of economic interests to a union with the
United States is easy to understand. In 1937, to be sure, the
Canadian Prairie Provinces examined the question whether a customs union with the United States would be advantageous for them.
The industrial center of the Middle West, especially Chicago and
Minneapolis, lies nearer to them and therefore, because of its greater
market, could supply many goods more cheaply than could the factories of Ontario or Quebec. So far the calculation is certainly
accurate. In the absence of a boundary line most of Alberta, Sas-
Part Four.
o85
Examples
Nova
it
also separates
Scotia
The
American
market.**
American wheat
the
owe
areas,
43.
American
coal
467; also
is
Scotia's
Affairs,
VII (1928-29)
454-
(Halifax, 1936?)
45. There is much talk, too, of a cultural similarity between the two countries.
But the European observer who arrives in Victoria from Seattle, say, or in Ottawa
from Washington, or in Montreal from New York, is impressed by the different
atmosphere. Life suddenly seems more placid, more orderly, more like that in Europe.
And that the United States would defend the Dominion in case of need is the exact
opposite of a reason for their union. This would lose Canada the help of England
without this being necessary to secure that of the United States. In short, we should
do better to compare the relation between the two countries not with that between
Germany and Austria, but with that between Germany and Switzerland: a good yet
reserved neighborliness.
Locations of Production
387
goods to the value of $100 may be brought in duty free every three
months. At the time to which the following statistics refer this was
not yet in effect, but because of the extensive traffic across the border
it was relatively easy to smuggle in small things like clothing or
tobacco. It might therefore be assumed that certain articles known
by everyone to be substantially cheaper in the neighboring country
would appear with unusual frequency in the retail trade of places
along the border. This is actually the case. Anyone strolling through
the streets of a small Canadian border town is amazed at the number
of fur and china shops, of tailors and jewelers. Signs in show windows explain: " Canadian prices are lower on blankets, furs, knitted
ware, English china, linens." The stroller will be struck, also, by
the many hotels, where Americans pass their forty-eight hours if they
must. Other kinds of business he will miss entirely.
In order to get an exact picture of retail trade along the border
I compared sales in the large Canadian town of Windsor just opposite
Detroit with those in near-by London, Ontario, which is about as
large, though farther inland. The retail sales per capita in Windsor
in 1930 were as follows, expressed as percentages of the corresponding
London
sales in
(calculated
Statistics,
Dry goods
Tobacco
55 per cent
65 per cent
Millinery
Shoes
Metal Goods
Total
96 per cent
sales
Jewelry
Custom-made clothing
Furs
The
differences are
still
more
striking
between Niagara
Falls,
The
explanation
is
that cotton
is
largely
em-
388
Part Four.
Examples
ployed for women's wear and wool for men's, and that the latter
Thus a
is cheaper in Canada and the former in the United States.
sell
in
Windsor
for
say,
would
English
cloth
that
$55,
coat made of
FurtherDetroit,
across
the
river.
in
just
might cost as much as $85
more, northern Canada provides very cheap furs; and Canadian
duties on diamonds and English porcelain are not so high as the
American. This explains the extensive purchases in Canada by
Americans.
Conversely, Canadian women prefer to buy their clothing, shoes,
and hats in the United States for the additional reason that they
regard English fashions as outmoded. The men, on the other hand,
bring in mainly American cigarettes, since they cost one fourth less
though normally subject to very high duty. If such conditions are
peculiar in degree to the Canadian-American border, they are more
or less typical in kind of all frontiers.
Chapter 22.
The Location
of
Towns
perfectly
is
realized
as
in
the
50/an
Fig. 66.
(see
Fig. 67.
Distrubtion of towns in
England, 1910, by
from one another
size
(see
and distance
Table 23)
some
and with it
and the kind of crop raised.
main
Manu-
Part Four.
390
Examples
It might therefore be
City, 1930])
our most general findings on the distribution
of settlements would be confirmed in lowa.^
If one measures in Figure 32 the minimum distances ^ separating
the common centers of a given number of areas, for example those
between the points upon which from three to five regions center,^
an especially frequent [modal] value will be obtained about which
the less common ones are grouped. Thus for every size of town
there is a typical, though not even theoretical unequivocal, distance.
facturing Trends in
expected that at
Fig. 68.
Iowa [Iowa
least
from Chicago
in millimeters
(1
mm = 4.95 km)
b)
Distance separating
Though
it
is
true that
size.
minimum
many towns
in the
all
the
unfavorable locations.
the distance in each case to the next point of equal value.
2.
That
3.
examples
if
is,
is
small, there
the centers of three, four, or five regions were each measured separately.
The Location
of
Towns
3'J'
Table 21
IN IOWA, 1930
map
Distance
mm.
mm. =
in
1
0.85 km.)
0-
of Places with
300-1,000 11,000-4,000
Inhabitants
1- 2
3- 4
4- 5
5- 6
6- 7
13
7- 8
8- 9
23
32
65
53
54
45
24
11-12
12-13
13-14
14-15
15-16
16-17
17-18
18-19
19-20
20-21
21-22
22-23
23-24
24-25
25-26
26-27
27-28
28-29
29-30
30-31
31-32
32-33
33-34
34-35
35-36
36-37
37-38
38-39
39-40
of Places
0- 5
2- 3
10-11
Number
with 4,000-20,000
Inhabitants
9-10
mm.
mm. =
in
(1
0.85 km.)
2
Distance
Number
1
1
2
6
19
11
6
7
9
13
15
13
7
5
5-10
10-15
15-20
20-25
25-30
30-35
35-40
40-45
45-50
50-55
55-60
60-65
65-70
70-75
75-80
11
11
4
8
6
9
3
3
39
8
1
4
10
9
5
2
5
2
2
2
2
2
2
Distance
Number
of Places
cm.
(1 cm. =
8.5 km.)
with 20,000-100,000
Inhabitants
in
0- 5
5-10
10-15
15-20
20-25
415
15
4
2
11
392
Part Four.
o
o
o
o
o
o
o
Examples
(S
WH
CM
CN
w
C
Ci
A
2
G
Q
UX
H
13
<u
<
JS
C "
W 4)
-d
eg
CO
3
w S
> to
"d
C G
rt
PS
00
r'"
c
o" -
H
<
H
bo 6h
e
s
d9
"
PS
"^
M
-
<N
CN
ca
CM
'"'
.!2
13
<f
c^
CN
^'
'i-
IS
"'S
rt
u
G
PS
O C
H^
.St3
t4-l
o
V
iz:
nl
OT
G
^
3;ho
O
B
D
00
CN
CO
CM
O)
.^^>^. ,-^>V^^
c;n
T-H
00
06
vO
.-.^^V^-,
-^>K_^.
s
"1 G
CM
-2
.fcj
to
o"
-s
<
S
S
G
03
CO
rt
or^-<i-Tj-^o\T-ioocs
00
00
CO
th
-^
00
00
o
o
o
-H-o
^O.
S
3
^".s
-G
"t^
|*
rt
c 13
3
Ji
aj
Ab SbO
u
n
1^
rt
^ g
M
52
"H
Cn
00
t---
u
G
w
(U
o
o
o_
"^
in
CM
,-,^>..^-.
^^
S.2
.2
CN
<N
00
1-'
to
,^
so
so
in
l3*
S
a
-G
Sfi
to
CM
<
>
o
u
(U
<TC
c^)
cy
III
sio
6
3
03
(N
\0
00
so
r~-
CM
10
rO
00
lO
M
c
5
'"
.G
&
"
u
G
-^'
CSl
a;
__^
r*
4>
G
^
a;
1-
S-.
^
H ^>.
O "-S
^ C S
H 1-^
<
w
G
ii
-a
"(3
m OCM^^O00CM^-T^vO^CMT-lO1-H^
-*
SO
CO
so
o
o
^"
f^
(M
G
a
cvi
<
w
C/3
r/l
o
u
bJ3
u
U
^
<
r^
ocNfMcor--ooT-iT-i,-i
1^
SO
CO
rj
w c
G
>.
13
3
cr
i->
>1
-
S
rt
" C
.3
to
-o
1^
lis
'C
0^
tfl
^ s
.M
'"'
a
3
CO
CMLD'.-HtNTt-ooO^
LO
tH
IT)
bC
rO
M
G
-^'
<u
t^
>
.2 :s
;g -0
u
G a ^ s
a a: a-^
m
eg
r^ CO
'^
p3
T-1
v-i
'^ CM
CM
in
(1
I^
C?\
CO
cm"
.c
G c i= O
O .CO
04
I
2 o
.s
^ ,3
S
,^;
,r
4j
rt
csi
t3
in
<u
&
""
t)
11
Disi
CM
iS
"O
CO
r-1
.rt
-S
'IS
>5.
S.2 ^
nj
XI
CO
1
-*
;5.G
CL,
r-<{Mro-^ir>vot~~cocsO^-icsicOTfij-i\ot^ooa\0
^T'7'7'7'^T'7'7'7'~;^
Oi-icMco-^invor^oocNO't-icgcOTtiosor^cocN
,
u
U G
>-
4.95
<
"3
<3
u X
3 C
i-i
i*<
iS
The Location
of
Towns
393
them
(Fig.
an increase of the
This
have assembled the places
with 1,000 to 4,000 inhabitants^ in a strip running westward from
Chicago for some 400 miles, that is, about to the western boundary
of Iowa, and about 80 miles wide, its northern edge being a prolongation of the northern boundary of Illinois and its southern edge
lying an equal distance south of Chicago. These places were arranged
in groups according to their distance from Chicago, and the average
minimum distance from places of equal or larger size was then
calculated for each group. It is manifest that this increases with distance from Chicago. But it can be further seen that in Iowa, about
50 to 140 millimeters on the map from Chicago, the average distance
is at the same time the typical one when this state is considered by
itself further proof for the uniformity of conditions there.
Variations in the typical distance between towns in two neighboring districts suggest differences in fertility. Thus the curve for
the small towns in the Texas cotton area had two peaks. This is
because a strip of fertile soil, the Black Belt, runs across the state,
and the towns on it lie twice as close together as elsewhere. English
towns are separated by typical distances of their own (Fig. 67 and
results in
is still
more
clearly
shown
in Fig. 68.
Table 23)
Here only the table is given; its interpretation will come later.
Several other examples are to be found in the literature, though to
the best of my knowledge none have been statistically verified.
According to K. Biicher (Die Entstehung der Volksiuirtschajt [1st
ed., 1893], p. 49) there were in Germany at the close of the Middle
Ages a round 3,000 places with city privileges, which in the south
and west were separated by four to five hours' travel, and in the
north and east by seven to eight. ^ All in all, a regular distribution
of towns throughout the world is extraordinarily common.
4.
5.
According to the
map
of
M.
Jefferson, "
note
7.
Some Considerations on
the Geographic
Provinces of the USA," Annals of the Association of Arnerican Geoaraphers, VII, 3-15.
6. For the distribution of large villages in Hungary see L. deLagger, " La plaine
hongroise," Annates de Geographic,
(1901)
44.
map
of
Part Four.
394
Table 23.
Airline distance from the next equally large or larger town on the
M. Jefferson, loc. cit. See also Fig. 67.
Number
Distance
mm.
mm. =
in
(1
"10,000""
20,000100,000
4.35 km.)
1910
map.
of Places with
100,000500,000
500,0002,500,000
Inhabitants
2
2- 3
79
38
20
13
4
4
3- 4
4- 5
92
58
33
13
16
5- 6
6- 7
7- 8
7
2
4
2
0-
Examples
1- 2
8- 9
9-10
10-11
11-12
2
1
Total
Average distance
162
233
39b
2.1
2.6
6.5
40
14.5
the map.
34
mm.
Among
c.
distance of 24-25
mm.
with a
B. Economic Areas
Chapter 23.
The United
States
is
an examination
of market areas.
There
is
mainly by the Department of Commerce, schools of business, individual scholars, economic institutes,
and planning boards.^ Their methods differ. The most useful seems
to me the utilization of business books and of statistics of freight
traffic, as well as the direct questioning of consumers in areas of
retail trade. On the other hand, the atlases produced at great expense
by a few advertising firms among others, but in one case even by
the NRA itself, which are supposed to indicate the " natural trading
areas " of the United States, are hard to employ scientifically.^ The
principles for such a partitioning (traffic conditions, the region in
which newspapers circulate, sales radii for retail businesses, turnover,
number of inhabitants, income levels, and so on) and the products
for which it is supposed to hold true (groceries, or even retail goods
in general) are too numerous for such " market areas " to have any
precise meaning.
investigations
on
this subject,
1.
At the federal
level:
Resources Committee)
2. The
Company
J.
W. Thompson
Shopping Areas [New York, 1927]) is still fairly useful. The towns
in which large department stores are situated are shown on a map, and boundaries
between them drawn in such a way that the distances from them to each of the
neighboring centers is the same. But this procedure considers only transport costs,
not differences in price or variety, or competition by smaller department stores.
(Retail
395
Part Four.
3g6
Examples
a.
1.
Erroneous Estimation
agree
on one
point:
retail dealers
They ship
have
too jar at a
loss.
market areas excessively.
"
Many
marginal
revenue,
The geographic marginal cost exceeds the
manufacturers permit field sales operations to penetrate too far into
unprofitable territory." ^ " Many small manufacturers have made the
error of seeking national distribution at great expense only to find
that a greater volume of business at much smaller cost could be
secured within a few miles of the plant." * " Too much territory is
being covered. It seems practically certain that a greater profit could
be made within a restricted territory." ^ " The broad generality, that
distributors should warehouse a reserve stock for retailers within a
radius of economical distribution and convenience of service is
generally followed. In the striving for sales volume it has been easy
to lose sight of the sales expense attaching to sales made beyond the
economical radius of distribution." In Germany, "A calculation of
individual cost items
showed that many beer storehouses that
been
established
lengthen
the sales radius did not repay their
had
to
expanded
their
high
cost,
What causes the loss in sales to too distant buyers? First, too
high shipping costs. ^ Williamson investigated a grocery store in a
metropolis that delivered to homes free within a radius of almost
seven miles. The yearly turnover of a quarter of a million dollars
just about corresponded to the demand of families living within
3.
International Magazine
A Marketing
4.
W.
F.
This
(Washington, 1929)
p. 14.
where freight
W.
S.
is
Department
(Washington, 1930) p. 2.
Millard, Analyzing Wholesale Distribution Costs, U.
of
Commerce,
Studies, No.
(Washington, 1928)
S.
Department
p. 2.
of
(This refers
H. Fezer,
"
Brauereien
als
pp. 1038-1040.
8.
more apt
to be disregarded:
Wirtschaftsheft
8, p. 8), it
{a)
397
Dependent on Distance
6.2
Advertising
Postage, telephone, telegrams
0.2
10.1
Packer
Packing material
3.1
0.1
1.5
Yd
~uJ
a.
J.
W.
Millard,
The Wholesale
Grocer's Problems, U.
(Washington, 1928)
S.
Department
and
(see
column
{b)
The
(Rhenish-Westphalian
egg
limestone (Ruedersdorf)
Pordand cement
(Berlin)
Potatoes (yellow)g
Lead
(f.
o. b.
German
source)
salt,
Germany)
7.90
12.85
16.80
12.50
213
103
20
10
8.1
3.9
17.
12.50
16.80
16.80
13.10
4.10
16.80
25.60
25.60
25.60
27.40
36.20
40.30
40.30
74
78
53
3.4
6B1
5.2
F
F
31
10
20
20
20
0.9
27
15
13
20
30
30
30
30
40
50
50
2.5
F
B
bri-
quettes)
Lump
Commerce,
Soft
of
p. II.
per cent for shoes, 24 per cent for grain, 34 per cent for coke and
milk,
Shipping Costs
Freight
as
21.50
31.80
42.70
51.80
63.00
175.50
201.10
299.20
738.10
762.70
1,970.
3,216.70
4
5
2
1
4.1
3.6
11
B
F
0.9
D
D
D
0.4
21 S
1.5
1.3
0.5
0.2
A
A
0.2
Examples
Part Four.
398
From
it is
them.
It is
somewhat better
to
and
An
to the customer.
business
showed how
earned by distant
little is
sales.
Table 24.
Selling Cost
Saies According to
Distance of
Distance Zones
in Miles
II
To
500
500-1000
1000-1500
G A
80
16
71
94
18
95
5
1500-
II
which
of
Total
Customer
II
D G A
D G A
Ib
73
18
31
41
27 11
36
8
32
50'
10
19
24
25
32
25
14
21
77
16
2
21
26
29
24
27
29
27
20
19
C D
4
5
11
!
13
16
13
19
Selling Cost
Profit
of which
Distance of
Customer
(Estimate")
Freight
in Miles
II
II
G
To 500
500-1000
1000-1500
1500a.
11
7
12
12
Weighted average
3
3
C
2
4
4
4
c
- 2
- 3
-1
-1
-20"
18
-11
3"
D
7
3
5
-11
The
500 kilometers (15-ton cars), (c) b as percentage of a. (d) Freight for each
additional 10 kilometers in pfennigs per ton. (e) d as pro mille of the price at
500 kilometers. (/) Class of freight rate or special rate respectively (1943)
(g) Calculated from the average delivered price.
9. Distribution Cost Problem of Manufacturing Confectioners, U. S. Department of
Commerce, Distribution Cost Studies, No. 10 (Washington, 1931) p. 12.
,
399
less
policy of the
first
The
expenses
from
be canvassed, or the nearer
district to
IN
Dyes6
Hardware''
Radiol
Groceries^
in Miles2
All costs
All costs
75
75-150
150-250
250-500
15.1
8.3
4.4
9.2
4.3
5.1
16.0
11.7
5.6
4.6
10.0
7.3
4.4
13.0
9.1
4.9
Sales
Radius
V
/
Expenses
for
salesmen
500-3
18.6
U.
19.3
7.1
5.9
21.7
4.2
4.2
A.
W^orld
S.
1.
2.
all
all
firms
4.6
whose
particular zone.
3. Firms that deliver within a radius of more than 500 miles but do not deliver
over the entire United States.
4. Source: U. S. Department of Commerce, 15th Census of U. S. Wholesale Distribution, Radio Sets, Parts and Accessories (Washington, 1932) p. 25.
5. Source: Idem, Wholesale Distribution, Groceries and Food Specialties (Washington, 1933)
(Wholesale houses with annual sales of between $100,000 and
p. 77.
,
$300,000.)
6.
7.
Source: Idem,
1932), p. 32.
1933), p. 50 (No.
1).
distant areas.
10.
Part Four.
4(K>
Examples
The
underestimation of distance,
Germany, are
^^^
JLT
/_
g^
,^__
-J
""
/^*
J.
>
/I
.^
....
tarn
II
.M
-^
-1
^*
ikm
'i
'
'''-
'--
from the farm of 206 km. Buildings are on the largest parcel. (After MunHdusern [Berlin, 1934], p. 9.)
of
simply to
the working day of the peasant is spent uselessly
overcome the distance to individual places of work " ^^and this
.
much time uselessly spent on the farm itself. (A. MiinDer Arbeitsertrag der bduerlichen Familienwirtschajt [Berlin,
included
zinger,
1929], p. 826.)
Nor
11.
will
They correspond
to the
und Raumordnung,
home and
f.,
4^1
Thus many
lected.
fields
men
themselves.^-
Consolidation of Areas
2.
When
distance
is
is,
they
An
much
So
so,
me on
One
held that
freight,
it
played no role at
all in
upon
their business.
which
after all
declined to
limits
where
it
could be supervised.
The
other entrepreneur,
(6)
more,
(c)
To
center
who produced
exactly
To round them
it
(a)
To make
them on
their
more compact.
centers. Of
farmlands when
areas
economic
course the last aim cannot always be achieved; for example, not for
the village is the center of settlement. Remaining exclaves are improved, at least in
shape and
size.
There
is
much
to
off of lands.
W.
Commerce
S.
Department
of
P^^t Four.
402
Examples
The
towns."
b.
1.
man,
less
it
will not
Though
the German insurance centers are scattered, all the companies insure
which resulted in an excess of representatives, agencies, and regional offices
(Rath, " Der Raum als Kostenfaktor in der europaischen Privatversicherung," Wirtschaftsdienst, 1942, pp. 938 f.)
but had the advantage that the risk was distributed.
During the war this scattering proved to be advantageous, especially in the case of
mortgage credit, since otherwise one single bombing attack might have wiped out a
good part of the collateral. To this extent the nature of insurance differs widely from
15.
everyivhere,
Rath
it
is
really typical.
(Organisationsform
So far as
am
und
aware, no
pp. 15-17.
1942. pp. 235-241.
1940, Pt.
I,
20. Enterprises without market areas are very uncommon. In the main they are
businesses that are " oriented toward passers-by " (R. Schmidt-Friedlander, Grundziige
einer Lehre
vom
some
403
illustrations
on the
size
and shape
of
market areas
for various
differences in popu-
II:
and
Adequate investigations on
Nevertheless
only a few selections can be mentioned here. At least the work of F. A. Fetter (The
Masquerade of Monopoly [New York, 1931], pp. 287 ff.) on the influence of freight
upon the market areas of the American steel industry may be cited, as well as A.
Predohl's excellent
made
in "
map
Weltwirtschajtliches Archiv,
Stahlindustrie,"
Regul
also to R.
("
XXVII
(1928)
285
Reference
may be
on a
in quality;
mine and
E. Scheu's
to
who
map
freight rates,
to J. D. Black (Introduction to
all
sizes
and
in
the highways,
finds
among
good.
is
He
other things that supply areas for large markets overlapped more than
Kamenz
[Dresden, 1937])
which proves,
(Die Stadt
this
subject see A.
Allix
("
The
Kamenz
in
drawn
from a considerably larger area than those of other physicians (Map 11). Finally,
R. E. Dickinson (" Markets and Market Areas in East Anglia," Economic Geography,
April, 1934, pp. 173-182) has written on agricultural markets in the English counties
of Norfolk and Suffolk. The widening of the areas, and the dying out of superfluous
centers, are interestingly shown.
22. U. S. Department of Commerce, Fifteenth Census of the United States, Wholesale Trade in Paints and Varnishes [Washington, 1932], p. 18. According to a questionnaire sent to 3,000 wholesale grocers, market areas increased in the following order:
(I) widely known trademarked articles, (2) specialties, (3) brands of the wholesalers
Part Four.
404
Examples
For one and the same product the variation in areal size is
On the other hand, this variation is often more
significant than it might seem if only the number of firms is considered, and not their volume of business as well. The number of
firms naturally decreases with an increase in the size of the market
area, but their importance often increases. An example of this is the
therefore less."
WOO
500
75 1S9 250
/li!es
1V0S
Fig. 70. Size of wholesale market areas by goods, 1929. For legend
and sources see Table 26. For areas smaller than the United States,
but more than 500 miles in radius, the highest value for the radius
was assumed to be 1,000 miles. For wholesalers who supplied the
entire United States the radius of the market area was estimated at
1,500 miles.
Firms with a
than 75
concerned.
No.
7,
(J.
W.
Millard, U. S.
Department
lapping of areas
markets,
Series
The
over-
1927], vi.)
manifestly greatest in the third case, because the qualities are most
compare.
difficult to
23. It
is
of
Territories [Washington,
happens,
(t/.
S.
also, that
Department
Commerce, Problems
of
Trade
in Paints
States,
Whole-
4"5
and
These variations
are explained not only by the different importance of freight and
selling costs but also by the height of the fixed costs and, on the
offices
Table
Percentage of firms with at most the regular sales radii given in the table
Sales radius
in Miles
75
-150
-250
-500
500
-
U.
S.
A.
World
The
area has a
74
87
93
49
67
82
93
96
99
100
97
99
100
100
maximum
radius of
62
71
83
90
94
99
100
46
66
79
89
97
98
100
21
36
58
37
48
74
93
73
84
94
98
100
99
100
Specialties, p. 77)
b.
c.
p. 32)
d.
(idem.
The Wholesale
1933], p. 50)
Economic
much
relatively simple
Part Four.
Ao6
size of the
it is
Examples
theoretically
may be
about
500 miles.^^ For wholesale furniture dealers it would probably be
It is given as embracing 50 to 200 counties
less than 200 miles.
The retail dealer's market area includes 5 to 65
{ibid., p. 25)
counties, according to the size of the towns {ibid., p. 47)
Besides market areas for different goods, a comparison of the
market areas of different cities for the same goods is instructive
Here again we find considerable differences in size,
(Table 27)
which may depend partly upon differences in market structure, but
probably in part also upon a varying power of individual centers
to attract qualified entrepreneurs. Even where the size is apparently
about the same (both national and frontier centers often do considerable exporting) the underlying causes may be very different.
normal
[furniture] factories
set at
The
must be distinguished.
length
Weight is obviously more important for the wholesale dealer, with his lower
and longer average distances, than for the retailer, for whom the cost of shipping
by freight to the customer is less both absolutely and in relation to the price. For
corresponding observations in the hardware business see W. A. Bowers, U. S. Department of Commerce, Domestic Commerce Series No. 52, Hardware Distribution in the
27.
prices
p. 32.
In
fact,
expand farther by overlapping when the freight rate is low in relation to the price.
28. W. A. Bowers, U. S. Department of Commerce, Domestic Commerce Series No.
76,
p. 3.
SIZE OF
Table 27.
whose
Businesses
407
CITIES, 1929
Radio2
Groceries^
Over
Over
500
500
<
<
Sales Radii in Miles
1;
a
u
in
in
in
IT)
Centers on
boundary
Buffalo
National
New
centers
Seattle
York.
Chicago
40
47
28
12
5
13
19
28
24
11
51
San Francisco
regional
Denver
centers
Atlanta
100
Compressed
Boston
regional
Pittsburg
47
69
Los Angeles
26
52
17
10
24
54
4
1a
in
(M
in
in
446
in
in
CM
in
<
16
17
47
30
49
34
23
20
2
19
18
26
7
12
67
12
26
34
18
76
24
53
2
12
49
36
22
13
54
14
15
44
20
41
22
33
36
34
12
10
22
22 28
4 21
49 47
67
30
75
21
26
27
34
23
40
23
13
38
26
5
51
23
c
3
p.,
42
10
60
Far
reaching
en
in
CM
in
<
*-
a
P
in
65
12
centers
Hardware*
PaintsS
Centers on
Seattle
boundary
Buffalo
24
28
National
New York
centers
Chicago
18
13
8
3
8
7
25
23
Far
San Francisco
reaching
Los Angeles
regional
Denver
centers
Atlanta
32
20
2
17
Compressed
Boston
regional
Pittsburg
24
25
2
40
57
7
10
6
33
21
21
44
24
17
70
25
33
10
15
10
28
14
16
4
45
31
5
65
18
16
21
11
18
29
2
35
2
7
centers
U.
S.
Distribution, Groceries
4oB
Part Four.
Examples
the strip were wider the sales radius would probably shrink. The
ideal location of San Francisco, almost in the middle of the strip,
is clearly apparent; its sales radii considerably exceed those of Los
Angeles, which is pushed into the corner, as it were. Denver has
no rivals for a long distance because the market on the broad plateau
of the Rocky Mountains, with their natural resources hardly yet
is still more restricted than that on the half-desert of
the western prairie, which forms the other half of Denver's market
opened up,
area.
Atlanta,
is
though partly very poor region, and has near-by competitors. It falls
in the group with large market areas only because Florida, the
southern tip of its market area, is of such great length. The second
group is hemmed in by large adjacent centers. An extensive local
demand and the demand from a vicinity that is similar in many
respects predominate here.
Some data on Germany also are available. Before the war the
average, not the maximum, shipping distance by rail for carload
lots was, in miles:
potatoes,
137^.
(b)
Entering: milk,
(a)
3^;
Distribution: bricks,
pumice
therein per 1,000 inhabitants, the so-called occupation index [" Besatzziffer "] (method 2)
is a clue to the relative extent of a market.
For relative sizes in new settlements see F. Rechenberg, Das Ein,
W.
Christaller, "
Die Verteilung der nichtlandwirtschaftlichen Bevolkerung im Hauptdorfbereich," Neues Bauerntum, 1942, pp. 139145; and "Die Verteilung der landwirtschaftlichen Bevolkerung im
Landkreis," Neues Bauerntum, 1942, pp. 169-176. [According to
his page 169, Christaller used method 1.] For size relationships
29. Methods of preservation such as the deep-freezing of fish and the pasteurizing
of milk have greatly extended the markets for quickly perishable goods, potentially
and often also in practice.
30.
The
be found in
districts will
4^9
within the Reich, see G. Isenberg, " Die Tragfahigkeit des deutschen
Ostens an landwirtschaftlicher und gewerblicher Bevolkerung," in
Struktur und Gestaltung der zentralen Orte des deutschen Ostens
(Leipzig, 1941), pp. 21-28 (longer lists in each case). Christaller
classifies nonagricultural enterprises according to the following market areas: village, environs of a main village, environs of a country
town, and county. Isenberg includes all these together as providing
for local requirements, in addition to
that
2.
An
investigation
of
wholesale
trade
in
appliances
electrical
Table 28.
0- 50
5.8
0.8-16
50-100
100-150
150-200
200-250
2.7
0.4-9.7
1.6
0.1-7.1
1.6
0.0-7.1
0.4
0.0-1.1
IN
9,
in
c.
The
range of
its
variations, in dollars.
provide
show that the concen-
f.)
Part Four.
410
account.
still
come
29.
With
Examples
increasing
purchases.^^ Thus it may be said that the richer one is the more
does one buy in larger and more distant centers, whence it follows
that the extent of a place's retail market areas increases with the
size of the place.
(See Iowa State Planning Board, Retail Trading
Areas, Series I [Des Moines, 1936], No. 7, 7a)
On the other hand,
.
the larger
outside
is
it.
Table 29.
53
12
15
38
49
11
100
53
82
54
25
100
94
82
75
58
Montrose
Donnellson
Mediapolis
Winfield
Wayland
11
The inhabitants of these villages with a population of 500-1,000 made the given
percentages of their purchases in the nearest town (Burlington, pop. 27,000 or Fort
Madison, pop. 14,000)
Iowa State Planning Board, Retail Trading Areas, Series
(Des Moines, 1936) No. 7, pp. 5b, 5c.
.
a.
b.
c.
d.
Furniture.
Men's clothing.
But of course
The
from a
city,
would
W.
The overlapping
important than its extent
much
less
suggest.
J.
For two thirds of those questioned, distance decided the place in which to buy
less than one fifth
were influenced by widely assorted stocks {Iowa State Planning Board, Retail Trading
31.
when
6, 7a,
and No.
7,
4a)
4)1
summarizes in a
Ui = /B
i \
form
^ IE
\ "
where
t/i is
the sales of
town
in the
of
2.
and n are
still
N=
tance.
is
aproximately
2.
He offers
and n
they are too unequal, the market area of the smaller town will be encircled
It
town
probably
is
is,
relatively higher
same
effect.
BO>AC
Sliding-scale tariffs
limited choice in the small town and the curves represent travel costs.
it
is
have the
in B,
Between
it
is
more
E and
better to
pass through
A
Fig. 71.
33.
According to
W. Krzyzanowski
established a similar law, but I could not find the passage in question.
that great systematizer developed
many
ideas
In any case,
on the settlement system of a country
Bau und
Examples
Part Four.
412
Thus
Columns 3 and 4 give bank localities, simiand for every group the percentage of localities in
one bank had business relations with the great
which
least
at
Table 30.
Retailers Dealing with
Chicago Wholesalers,
1930, by Distance
Sales of Detroit
Bank Locations
Per Cent
Miles
Per Cent
400
400- 800
800-1200
1200-1600
55
25
10
30
1600-
40
61
200-400
400-600
14
13
12
600-
Miles
-200
News-
by-
100
Per Cent
Miles
5
25
25- 50
50- 75
75-100
40
24
11
8
The
Chicago banks.
from the
results
and
New
YorJc
is less
Columns
it.^^
in favor of Chicago
and 6
of
Table 30
34. E. Scheu's " law " (" Der Einfluss des Raumes auf die Giiterverteilung. Ein
wirtschafts-geographisches Gesetz! " Mitteilungen des Vereins der Geographen an der
Universitat Leipzig, No. VII, 1927, pp. 31-37) according to which the sale of goods
from a producing area decreases as the cube of the distance, is much more primitive
,
in comparison.
35. See
also
Districts in the
map
United
of banks with
deposits
in
413
McKenzie delimits
p. 83)
in the Detroit area. (McKenzie, op.
city economic landscapes according to the center from which most
cit.,
Market area of a house in Kansas City (X) for (a) fine woolen
and work clothes. (U. S. Department of Commerce,
Distribution Cost Studies No. 7, Problems of Dry Goods Distribution
[Washington 1930], pp. 16 and 21.) Counties with negligible sales are left
Fig. 72.
out of consideration.
In conclusion
The
States.^"
51,
Part Four.
^1^
Examples
green vegetables, and ice cream are stocked hardly at all, and
and articles of high quality are not profitable. In theoretical terms, their supply and demand curves do not intersect. Thus
there remain only a few popular articles that are produced in
quantities and have long possible shipping distances. But even these
cannot be carried by special establishments because sales would not
be large enough, so a sort of " mixed " business prevails. As even
fruit,
specialties
The Shape
of
Market Areas
We
First,
Denver, is two and a half times as far from Kansas City as is St.
Louis to the east. Secondly, the West is more thinly populated. In
the third place, it is naturally more expensive for a place halfway
between St. Louis and Kansas City to buy clothing from the East
through Kansas City than through St. Louis. The border of the
market area therefore lies nearer to the former. It is established by
the fact that here the longer but cheap long-distance haul from
New York, say, to Kansas City plus the shorter but expensive local
transport from Kansas City costs as much as the shorter long-distance
haul to St. Louis plus the longer local transportation from St. Louis."
37.
The
more evident
in western Kansas.
There
the smaller market areas resemble narrow strips that stretch far toward the west along
the transcontinental railroads; there are no lines running north and south. But the
center that supplies these areas lies near the eastern border. See a map of the market
areas for department stores in Salina or Great
p. 67)
Bend
(J.
W. Thompson
Co., Retail
4*5
is to be seen in Figure 73, though here the boundary lines are only approximately accurate. Goods for centers 3 to
5 come from the northeast in carload lots, and are distributed in
Something similar
small lots from these centers to their market areas,^^ which have
their greatest extension toward the southwest. The coastal points 1
(Houston) and 2 (New Orleans) on the other hand, receive their
,
1.
Houston;
Washington,
1932.)
also
fit
38. The pattern of the movements of goods is reminiscent of a nest of rockets. First
the emissions of production centers, which from wholesale centers divide anew {in a
backward direction also!) to " burst " finally in the retail centers. Whether or not
,
middlemen are profitable depends very much upon whether the carload freight rate
is far enough below the rate per unit unless it is purely a commercial agency. Domestic
transportation does not differ in principle from international transportation, which
my research group and I have begun to investigate at the Institut fiir Weltivirtschaft.
In the meantime see H. Lofke, " Ursachen und Umfang des Transits," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv,
LV
(1942)
Part Four.
4i6
pattern.
The
fact that it
is
St.
Louis
lie
Examples
on the edge
may be advantageous
to go
of
St.
for the
Panama Canal
the entire
Were
it
not
for
W. Zimmermann
cites
and ocean
1937
freight
of 6,250 miles.
From
the
opposite viewpoint, water routes are of vital importance to places that are far from
Hence the greater part of the foreign trade of the Balkan countries, even
is carried on by sea.
40. A hundred years ago New York and New Orleans exported equally large
amounts of good's. The enormous supply area of the Mississippi would provide an
a market.
with Germany,
important natural advantage for the latter, if only it were controlled. (See S. A
The New Orleans Trade Area, University Bulletin, Louisiana State University,
Caldwell,
slightly
statistische Studie
417
auf
Staaten
von Amerika," Vierteljahrshefte zur Konjunkturforschung, Sonderheft 25 [Berlin, 1932], pp. 10, 26.)
It is also very important that the cheap water route through
the Suez Canal connects Europe and eastern Asia much more closely
than does the Trans-Siberian Railway. In an instance cited by E.
Steinhagen *- the railway was eleven times more expensive than the
Canal. Thus Russian markets, like those of the American Middle
West, are caught in the pincers.
The methodologically admirable investigations of Cornell University and of the Iowa State Planning Board are well worth attention.
The books of sellers, upon which all investigations hitherto mentioned have been based, are inadequate for the delimitations of retail
trade areas. The Cornell method of interrogating almost every
farmer is ideal, but expensive. The results are entered on maps and
boundary lines drawn in such a way that contested areas are excluded.
This gives a celarer picture than that obtained when the overlapping
of market areas is taken into consideration. See Figure 74 (after D.
Sanderson, Rural Social and Economic Areas in Central New York,
Cornell University Agricultural Experiment Station, Ithaca, Bulletin
614, 1934, p. 9)
42.
Der
The
recognizable today.
The
typical county
is
The
and the
acres.
first settlers
so prevalent in
Iowa
is
its
inhabi-
still
clearly
is
acres)
typical
Thus
there
farm
still
another with
would be
county, or
Government
Part Four.
4j8
Examples
on the
investigations
o
*/
.^<^^
i 0/
,V-
+
+
jf oo
^'
"-:
++
-_.
of determining retail
The
dots.
in
Town
"
+ +
Method
typical of
Fig. 74.
much more
market
areas.
buy
are represented
boundaries of the uncontested sales area of
line, those of neighboring competition by broken lines.
by a continuous
Fig. 75.
Des Moines,
I,
No.
6, Fig. 4.
1936.)
and
its
419
accompanying
text.
among
retail
trade areas for various goods. Figure 76 shows also, on the one hand,
the connection between the agricultural areas that supply the town
with eggs, poultry, milk, and so on; and, on the other, the market
areas for its retail dealers. This is easily explained. The farmer
who takes his agricultural products into town for sale makes small
purchases at the same time. It is different with cattle for slaughter,
which go directly to Chicago as a rule, unaccompanied by the farmer;
thus there is no return flow of retail buying in Chicago.
..^P-
Women's clothes
and highways) to
Fig. 76.
first
area
(Ibid.)
Part Four.
420
subject.
That
to
Fig. 77.
is
typical of so-called
is
Examples
(their small
boundary between the supply areas for Shanghai and Hong Kong). (After
Deasy, Economic Geography, 1940, p. 265.) For English coal see K. Dietzel,
ed., Lebensraumfragen europdischer Volker (Leipzig, 1941), p. 285.
4.
The wheat markets are a good example of a complicated overlapping of regions, on the one hand, and of regions naturally
important in themselves on the other. At first glance the statistics
create an impression of inextricable confusion. Every exporting
country seems to send wheat everywhere, and every importing
country to buy everywhere. In speaking of a " world market " for
wheat, should we have nothing more in mind than this universal
and closely knit fabric? Figure 78 shows the farthest boundaries of
their market areas for the four great exporting countries in the
harvest year 1928-29, the last before the extensive transformation
of markets through
44.
Balkan
states
export
much
in 1928.
421
Figs. 78
and
79.
The
The boundaries
hatched
lines;
are represented by
Figure 79:
superiority)
45.
broken
Dominant
.
areas
lines.
(those
Practically
in
South of Bahia the importation of wheat from the United States was negligible.
Part Four.
422
one can
may
and
Examples
These
difficulties of
growers are thus not surprising, since they are forced to such a great
extent to fight for a place in the contested areas or even in the
unquestioned markets of other surplus countries. Boundaries are
constantly shifting, to be sure, depending on the result of the harvest,
the changing structure of ocean freights, and changes in consumption
and recently, above all, in trade policies. But this is more true for
the boundaries of the whole area than for those of its uncontested
core.
We
turn
now from
and
do they arise? First, through
Although shipments from the four supply areas
the core regions to the contested ones,
seasonal factors.
How
continue throughout the year, they vary in amount with the season.
They
in the
another chronologically.
is
due
may
get
to the
Table 31.
423
Imports,
Million
Bushels
Importing Country
1928-1929
Canada
United
Argentina
States
Australia
Denmark
Norway
347
,.
Portugal
Greece
15
Jamaica
British West indies
China
Japan
2
1
37
34
64
52
66
78
53
87
95
67
66
24
19
29
16
18
11
11
18
29
13
Uruguay
Spanish Guinea
French Africa
Spain
France
Belgium
A rea
Ireland
Gibraltar
West Africa
61
62
25
31
14
29
54
15
19
15
of United States
5
38
11
Predominance
62
97
91
Cuba
97
Haiti
British
Venezuela
Ecuador
Bolivia
Panama
Nicaragua
Costa Rica
San Salvador
Guatemala
Mexico
28
20
13
15
Alaska
Philippine Islands
Turkey
Egypt
Sudan
South Africa
New Zealand
Netherlands East Indies
10
19
27
42
26
16
100
100
89
85
90
66
35
Brazil
25
17
91
95
72
100
80
98
100
97
100
100
72
100
87
10
12
90
87
100
60
58
100
100
31
20
43
17
12
56
15
50
55
13
16
Contested Areas
Germany
Holland
Sweden
Finland
Italy
43
37
38
44
33
50
45
39
63
7
3
48
Honduras
Colombia
Peru
Chile
British
38
'
40
49
41
12
12
38
44
Part Four.
424
Examples
Series
show
The example
two market
European purchasing
The
area.*^
The same
thing
is
The
Thus
is
or-
world's imports of peanuts in 1937 went to Europe; 87 per cent of the copper; 79 per
cent of the hides; 78 per cent of the corn; 76 per cent of the wool; 73 per cent of the
hand,
it
is
4*5
Fig. 80.
England
as a corner
market
at the center of
Tons on March 7,
Empire Shipping, 1936, Admiralty BR 84, London 1936.) The map
the same time the main routes for world trade. On the other hand, the
on the corresponding map for November, 1937 (BR 135) is curiously wide.
(After British
shows
at
scattering
All small islands that might be mistaken for ships have been omitted.
Railway freight to the two ports, and the ocean freight from both
of them to Europe, are the same,*^ so that on the whole, their supply
and market areas are probably identical. This holds also for the
two ports on the northwest coast, Seattle and Portland. But as the
wheat belt here lies closer to the ports, its nearest parts divide into
distinct supply areas for the two ports.
The great dividing line between the Atlantic and the Pacific
ports, which in Canada runs aproximately between Alberta and
Saskatchewan and continues in the United States between Idaho and
Wyoming, is more important. It must not be thought of as rigid,
47.
is
circles
stand for a
number
of practically
equivalent ports.
to
Part Four.
^26
Examples
however. Though railway freights change but little over the years,
ocean freights change all the more.*^ Hence there are wide areas
on either side of the approximate line from which grain is shipped
now to the west and now to the east. Price differentials of only a
fraction of a cent may decide the direction, even when the destination is the same: Liverpool. True, the westward route by way of
Vancouver and then through the Panama Canal is almost twice as
long as the direct eastward one, but most of the former is a cheap
ocean route whereas in the second case three quarters of the total
freight cost goes merely to transport the wheat over expensive rail-
way and
much more
Dominion Bureau
of
1936], p. 175.)
Hence
fifth to
49. In July, 1935, for example, the freight on wheat shipped from Vancouver to
England was hardly higher than that from Montreal, whereas often it is twice as high.
But because the freight from the West Coast to Europe remains higher than that from
the East Coast throughout all fluctuations, the price of wheat on the West Coast must
always be lower than that on the East Coast.
50.
The
fact
that land
routes are so
Germany
to sell
its
much more
and southern Germany were importing wheat from overseas, which could be sent by
ship as far as Mannheim. (See A. Kuhner, Die wirtschaftlichen Beziehungen zwischen
Wilrttemberg und dem Reich, Munich dissertation, 1926, pp. 26 f.) The German tariffs
could shift the central dividing zone between east German and foreign wheat; but they
were not high enough to force the east German surplus and the west German deficit
together. Indeed, the system of import certificates worked rather in the opposite
direction. Only with the recent market organization has inland transportation increased
in importance, though governmental price regulation provided for regional price
differences only up to 12 per cent in the economic year 1938-39, for example. The two
extremes were parts of Silesia on the one hand, and the Saar District on the other.
See Reichsgesetzblatt I for July
certificates
-W. F.
S.]
may be found
1,
1938.
in Haberler,
[A discussion of the
The Theory
German system
of import
ff.
4^7
can be exported for a few weeks only, but during this short period
Fort Churchill is numbered among the chief export harbors.
The supply areas for New York and the neighboring American
ports on the one hand, and for Montreal and other Atlantic ports
in Canada on the other, cannot be separated, since almost all wheat
follows the same route at first through the Great Lakes, and usually
not until it reaches Buffalo is the final decision made as to whether
to ship it on to New York through the Erie Canal, or through the
Welland Canal to Montreal. This depends mainly upon the differences in ocean freights at the moment. A great deal of American
wheat is shipped through Canadian ports, and much Canadian
wheat, generally one fifth to one third, through American ports.
Buffalo, therefore, is a gateway, one level above the ports in the
hierarchy. In contradistinction to the eastern ports, the supply area
is sharply divided between Canadian and American ports on the
West Coast, partly because these draw from widely separated wheatgrowing districts, partly because these districts lie relatively near
them, and partly, too, because cross-connections are less numerous.
As wheat shipments from a supply area stream into a port from
many directions as though into a narrow gateway, so they divide
again in the wide market area of the port as soon as they have passed
through.
Both areas show in turn a definite structure. A hierarchy
'^^
of smaller
and
same
This has already
role for their submarkets as the port for the whole. '^^
been discussed. Thus even in the case of the single product alone,
wheat, there are many kinds of area: growing, supply, and market
areas together with their subdivisions; areas for the cultivation of
summer
c.
as
would have been more correct to determine the market areas for Montreal,
New Orleans, and so on, but the necessary time was lacking.
52. See also L. B. Zapoleon, U. S. Department of Agriculture, Bulletin 594, Geography of Wheat Prices (Washington, 1918) pp. 14 f.
51. It
New
York,
Part Four.
428
Examples
(1928, rail)
In
Germany
therein are included in the gross receipts of the public transportation systems, which in Germany were 11.8 per cent and in the
numbers
income, and all costs of distance together account for 20 per cent
and 30 per cent.
Obviously their wide expanse destroys a large part of the advantages that the United States (and Russia) enjoy by virtue of their
natural abundance. Single examples show this vividly. In 1930 long
hauls in the United States transported about 5| times as many tonmiles as in Germany. The enormous cost of quickly overcoming
the vast distances in the United States is shown by the proceeds
5.8
0.9
billion in Germany.^^
2.
An
trade
it
Further-
more, it differs too much in size from the other countries. Even so,
however, enough discrepancies in size still remain to disturb the
comparison, which is upset further by the facts that distances between countries are expressed as air-line miles between their capitals
and that the difference between land and ocean freights has not been
53.
Raiunforscrmnfr
Verkehrswirtschaft
the present author.
Landwirtschaft.
54.
und Raiimordming,
366.
I,
C.
Pirath, Die
Grundlagen der
(Berlin, 1934)
Internationale Landiuirtschaftliche
costs
Rundschau
distance
of
,
in
pp. 249-273.
I,
XXXIII
exporting see
(1942)
363.
Kapferer-
considered.
is
On
429
Germany
The
share of
in the imports
with distance.
do not
Fig. 81.
two
cases.
The two
Germany
in Bulgarian
Despite the distance of these countries this share was very large,
most probably because of shipments of tobacco, which made up
about half of these exports to Germany. What is true of single
European countries ^^ is also true of Europe as a whole. In 1928
55.
in 1928,
and
56. In 1932
countries,
Part Four.
430
Table 32.
Examples
Czechoslovakia
Denmark
Austria
Hungary
Lithuania
Switzerland
Sweden
Norway
Latvia
France
175
225
331
381
25
33
20
27
27
13
22
22
'?n
T'
51
394
406
438
475
18
34
24
14
481
519
531
23
544
550
41
58
18
13
14
26
11
31
21
England
581
638
Yugoslavia
Estonia
Finland
656
688
750
838
850
900
1150
1181
1456
1500
Italy
Ireland
Bulgaria
Albania
Greece
Spain
Portugal
Iceland
14
30
37
10
12
26
16
12
71
?R
4
9
10
13
13
27
7
n
'
Distance from Berlin to the capital of the country in question in air-line miles.
Germany's share in imports, as per cent of total imports of the country in
question (Statistisches Jahrbuch filr das Deutsche Reich, 1931 (Berlin) pp. 90* f.)
c.
Germany's share in exports, as per cent of total exports of the country concerned
a.
b.
(sources as in b)
European
trated
and
on neighboring
51 per cent.
areas.
mainly ocean
frontiers, for
reasons that are easily explained: Italy, 24 per cent and 18 per cent. Great Britain,
is
only a border zone along the United States; 61 per cent of her exports went
United States in 1932, and 41 per cent of her imports came from there.
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv in which I developed theoretically the
importance of distance in international trade contains an analysis of France's trade
with her colonies that conclusively supports my theory. About 75 per cent of exports
from Algeria go to France, but only 20 per cent of those from Indo-China. " Distance,
to the
The numberoOf
more than any other fact, decides in what measure colonies will contribute to the riches
of the mother country." (R. Maunier, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, L [1939], 272.)
Chapter 24.
Regional Systems
a.
The
number
is
smaller.
Table 33
Number
Size-class
of Regions
of
Settlements
per Region
Number
of
Regions of
This Class
for k
Size-class
Number
of Places
This Class
729
243
2
3
4
81
486
162
54
27
27
18
81
243
729
5
6
of
Places of
The largest region, which includes all 729 places, has one center
and the three next smaller, with 243 each, also have one center
apiece, though one of these is identical with the center for the
largest region. Consequently the number of towns in size classes
1. A rather good but much shorter presentation by O. Schlier
("Die Landschaften
Deutschlands," Allgemeines Statistisches Archiv,
[1930], 24-41) should be mentioned
also. He shows how the influence of great cities affects the various levels of life and
XX
Class
431
own market
area.
Part Four.
432
Examples
6-0 is equal to the difference between regions of the same and the
486 (see Table 33) The
next higher size-class: that is, to 1, 2
actual number agrees well with this theoretical number over wide
areas, as Christaller has shown. ^ Thus in the regional system of
Nuremberg
(Christaller, op.
cit., p.
Size-class of place
Theoretical number of places
Actual number of places
The
199)
18
10
23
54
60
162
105
486
462
measure of agreement is shown only in the accomto be sure, which explains any deviations with
geographical, political, and other pecularities individually, at least
for all places in the higher size-classes. The virtue of the book lies
chiefly in this penetrating examination of single cases. Consequently
full
panying
text,
In regions
with the same structure, at least in those whose regional networks
(as with ^ == 0) cannot be " rotated," the centers of equally large
market areas are themselves equally large if one assigns each center
to the largest area supplied by it. Otherwise than in complete
systems, every center always coincides with the same combination
of smaller centers (Fig. 34, p. 128)
Hence the regional centers can
3.
Assume
characterized by A
=3
Since in
the
Germany within
the
is
about 2\ miles.
to
would have on the average a region with a radius of something over 1.06 miles, which would mean a separation of 2.2 miles. Then, according to
Table 8, the theoretical distance separating the various types of places would be as
183,200 square miles, each
follows:
Theoretical
Type
Size- Distance,
class
Miles
Example
of
Place
2.5^
1
4.4
Village
7.5
Rural town
13.1?
22.5 \
38.8
Many
local
examples
County town
Provincial capital
117.5
Regional capital
Munich-Nuremburg 124.4
203.1
350.0
595.0
State capital
Sectional capital
10
67.5^
National capital
miles
There are important actual examples for every type. But obviously they are adequate neither for a comprehensive explanation of European reality nor for verification
of the theory. They illustrate only orders of magnitude in what may be an important
special case.
Regional Systems
433
be divided into
those regions
size-classes that
and contain
size-classes of
economic
functions.*
From
must be a number of
town
typical
determinable as
number of towns as a function of their size.^ He announced his
classification of towns by this method in Die zentralen Orte in
Siiddeutschland (Jena, 1933) p. 65. But I cannot see that he really
succeeded, except in two classes of places that he called A and K
places, and that actually correspond with certain agglomerations
shown on the curves on his page 326. The classification developed
on pages 150-155 was not further explained. He may have arrived
at it by arranging a number of places according to their functions
and then finding that most places in a group fell in a definite sizeclass, which was thereupon regarded as typical for places with this
function. But one can hardly speak of a clustering of the places
about any representative central value within the size-class, save for
the two exceptions mentioned. Such agglomerations, if they exist
at all, would be concealed by the fact that the number of places
falls rapidly with increasing size. As long as we do not know the
law governing this decline I do not see how one could eliminate
it in order to disclose possible hidden agglomerations.
As a classification of towns cannot be achieved statistically, only
three courses remain open. To classify them by direct observation
of towns with different functions, as Christaller apparently did; to
derive the classification from a regularity that is independent of
what is to be proved (Pareto's distribution formula, perhaps) or,
finally, to obtain it by trial and error. In the last case we have one
of the theoretically derived regional systems only if the actual
pattern corresponds with the theoretical in more than one respect.
Then, in the absence of other reasons, towns can always be so
classified, of course, that their real number is equal to the theoretical
number in every size-class. But only when it appears further, per,
4.
In the general system, on the contrary, a place need not be larger, the greater
the size of
its
largest area.
He measured
computed
size
" centrality,"
not by the
based on the
of a specially
cities Schlier's
method, which, using statistics of occupation, counts the " central stratum," is probably
(" Die zentralen Orte des deutschen Reichs," Zeitschrift der Gesellschaft fur
better.
Erdkunde zu
ff.)
Part Four.
4g^
Examples
haps, that the actual distance separating these town types from one
another is the same as the theoretical distance can it be assumed that
Table
(see
131)
8, p.
such
size-classes
numbers
actual
6.
The
hexagons
7.
On
value
ft
classified first
counted
all
the places in
distances
4.
Only
The
apart.
frequencies
in
the
holds for
I really
mum
It
individual size-classes
theoretically
corresponded
were required to make the corresponhave made these in order to provide a perfectly clear starting
point.
8. The deviations would be still less if the the theoretical value of each size-class
had been derived from the actual value of every preceding one, instead of always from
the highest
9. "
class.
The Courbes
'
des Populations.'
Parallel to Pareto's
1931])
who added
to
Laplace's law of absolutely equal effect a similar law of proportionately equal effect.
(1939)
pp. 203-227.
Institut.
Jahrbuch,
Regional Systems
435
Table 34.
REGIONAL SYSTEMS
IN IOWA.
Centers
Size-class
Number
of
regions
Theory^
Distance apart*^
Reality
Theory'^
Reality'
5.6
61 5
154
153
11.2
10.3
39
22.4
23.6
44.8
5'
39
10
2-3
89.6
49.6
94.0
6e
0-1
4d
179.2
regions
Law
for
Places
Size-
Theory*"
7
Reality
Theory"*
1,800
7,200
28,800
size''
Reality*
10
44 7
8 19
205
204
3
4d
51
51
13
12
5<J
6"
= 1
Lowest
Minimum
Number
class of
for k
115,000
460,000
1,950
7,500
34,800
94,000
size-
class*
11
180-1,000
1,000-4,000
4,000-20,000
20,000-60,000
60,000-200,000
200,000-800,000
a.
b.
In miles.
Population.
Because of the small number of settlements in these size-classes, greater deviations
are to be expected. If Davenport is placed in class 4 instead of in class 5, in class
4, column 10, 34,800 must be replaced by 37,600; in column 11, 20,000-60,000 must
be replaced by 20,000-75,000; in class 5, column 5, 94 by 102.5; in column 8,
3 by 2; and in column 10, 94,000 by 111,000.
Iowa has no city of this size-class, but it lies between Minneapolis, Kansas City,
Omaha, and Chicago, the first three of which fall in this class. Their average
population is 490,000 and their minimum distance apart 236 miles.
Modal value; average value for class 5 only (because of the small number of
cases). Class 1: The distances, which incidentally correspond to size 2a in Table 8,
p. 131, were measured first (see p. 434, note 7) for settlements with 300-1,000
inhabitants, and the values so found were entered above in the table. A new
calculation, with the inclusion of places having 180-300 inhabitants, would have
taken much time, but random sampling showed that the result would not have
c.
d.
e.
/.
g.
h.
size-class. Pareto's law, established for individual towns, thus holds also for the whole classes of towns, one more reason for
regarding as representative the arrangement of classes that was chosen.
The values actually obtained for class 1 were the starting point for the calculation
Part Four.
AoQ
That
is,
-^=
a,
Examples
change in
to the
x.
formula
y
given above, a
found
for a
is
whole
which we are
in
interested.
This
is
England
(0.99 in
(1.03 in
the
number
of towns
falls
to
minimum
if
increase fourfold.
The
the
number
population must
system to reality.
G. K. Zipf [National Unity and Disunity [Bloomington, 1941])
gave Singer's discovery a simpler form. When the towns of a country
are arranged according to size, the nth town will have 1/nth the
population of the first. If the serial number (n) of a town is multiplied by the number of its inhabitants, the product will be the same
for all towns: that is, equal to the population of the metropolis. The
test works for Germany to the extent that of her 104 largest towns
in 1933 the product for the 25th to the 104th was without exception
between 5 and 6 million (Statistisches Jahrbuch fur das deutsche
p.
11.
For the 7
largest places
it
was always
The importance
of Berlin
as
To
number of places with the minimum popuColumns 7 and 9 are calculated from these
two numbers. The assumption that each successive number should be exactly four
times, or \, as large as the preceding one is arbitrary, but practical. The places in Iowa
should be grouped in such a way that either the minimum size (column 10) or the
frequency (column 8) of the groups corresponds with the theoretical value. The
11.
lation 447
start with,
(819
is
819
the
assumption mentioned
is
sum
is
given as the
of
column
3)
can be employed and no new one becomes necessary. Consequently the perfect corre-
Regional Systems
437
scapes
if,
as Singer
likewise
Thus
is
in regions of the
is
the total
number
for a
of settlements.
1
the following
relations:
Size of region
Size of landscape
Serial
Thus
also, for
Serial
example.
Population of metropolis
economic landscape
Population of subcenter
Size of its region
Size of
not for the general system, at least for similarly constructed regions.
For the present it must remain undecided whether the question is
merely to discover a statistical method of making these agglomerations evident; ^- or whether differences in fertility, ability, and so
on are great enough even in a state as uniform as Iowa to effect
such a dispersion of town sizes that it conceals all agglomerations in
this way. In this case only a classification of towns geographically
and by individual size-classes, but not according to their dispersion
within these classes, would correspond with the norm. Or, finally,
whether size is influenced by still other factors, which underlie
Pareto's law of distribution but do not enter into our theoretical
if
pattern.
The
however, by another
^^ separating towns
increases with their size, not only in regions with the same structure
but generally, as is evident in Figure 32 (p. 127). The distance apart
theoretical system
From
point.
this
it
is
fully confirmed,
Let
it
be called
a.
The
is
equal.
12. The few agglomerations mentioned by Christaller become clearer when the
places are arranged according to " centrality " (see p. 433, note 5) instead of populations.
13.
That
is,
size.
,o8
t'li^l
Examples
Four.
but also that there is a typical distance for every size. This cannot
be given even theoretically by one single value, however, except
for regions of similar structure (Table 8) but only by a frequency
curve such as we have already met with in Figures 66 and 67."
Such curves provide an interesting comparison between a region
in which the assumptions of our theoretical deduction (similarity
of natural conditions) are approximately fulfilled and a country in
which they are manifestly not fulfilled. The frequency curves in
Figure 66 are typical for the American Middle West, and correspond
perfectly with expectation. In England, on the other hand, where
,
the towns cluster in the five coal districts and around London, the
differences are
much
less,
Towns
between
over a uniformly
found.
b.
As
we found
The
dispersion in Fig. 66
we
is
upon
actual
we
already know.
15.
as I
This
am
taller,
aware.
op.
cit.,
For Munich, Regensburg, and Wiirzburg, for instance, see W. ChrisFor Berlin. O. Schlier,
Die Landschaften Deutschlands,"
p. 256.
*'
XX
(19;]0)
39.
For Paris:
M.
loxva State
P.
Meuriot, Des
p. 60.
I,
Regional Systems
439
is
actually true
many
45 per cent of
48 per cent of
53 per cent of
81 per cent of
Of
to-wns,
hatched in Figure
30,
included
more than
1,000 inhabitants.
(there would be twelve according 'to theory) firstand federal highways that run out from Indianapolis, ten
the most part through the thickly settled sectors, and eight
the thirteen
class state
pass for
of these
c.
We
know from
is
is
more
for
than for
Moines,
its
its
1936),
Minnesota
interests us here
its
general results
details.
p.
For Minnesota:
11.
1905-1929,"
Bulletin 269, p.
which
11.
University
The
cause
is
of
C.
Minnesota,
Agricultural
Experiment
in
Station,
a central town, so that agglomerations of such enterprises with long sales radii cannot
lie
the
in
16. C.
738
638
In towns
529
406
709
637
857
619
R. Hoffer,
"A Study
of Agriculture, Agricultural
1928.
Part Four.
4^0
More than
United
States
Examples
number when
most farmers
live
it is
on separate
farms rather than in villages, were asked: (1) the location of their
banks, and where they bought: (2) clothing, (3) furniture, (4)
groceries, and (5) hardware. It appeared that not even half of their
business was transacted in the same town (chiefly by farmers living
near a large one)
purpose.
indis-
criminately from one to the other, however, but had their regular
places for
banking
purchase of clothing,
men's clothing,
bank, physician,
third order was: church,
groceries, furniture,
for services was:
fruit,
TOWN PLANS
many
respects towns are miniature copies of economic landThey, too, are composed of market areas for merchants and
workmen and of supply areas for offices and various enterprises, but
also for parks, transport points, and so forth. The advantages of an
agglomeration of locations at the center ^^ determine also the plan
of a town and the most suitable course for the main traffic routes.
Similarly, and especially in the case of retail trade, smaller agglomerations of locations are found in the suburbs, ^^ which correspond
In
scapes.
17. It is
and
town,
but with broad sidewalks; and lower and farther apart toward the outskirts. At the
center cluster the buildings most frequented by both inhabitants and outsiders for
widely different purposes: markets, post
office,
town
hall,
and
others.
the community.
Only constantly
Today
there is a
tendency to have the centers of towns and even villages too scattered and disconnected;
but
building of a town
is
who have
business to transact.
The
und Raumordnung,
London provides
Regional Systems
this
perfect as in cities
Such an arrangement
is less
often seen in smaller towns. First, disthe time saved by radiating streets of
make
to
10,000
through
19.
2.
The concept of an
and squares predominate
21.
ideal
town blossomed
first
Part Four.
442
its
Examples
consequence.^^
The advantages are the simplicity of the system, easy orientation
toward street crossings, and adaptability to the right-angled shape
of houses. In order to avoid the corresponding disadvantages of the
star-shaped arrangement, the individual angles of the star must be
conspicuously different; at the center there must be a large island
around which
traffic rotates,
and
number
of
street intersections; the single sectors must not be built over as far
as their points, for on the one hand this obstructs the view of traffic
emerging from neighboring streets, and on the other makes too
noticeable those departures from the right-angled ground plan that
But when
these
to
be laid out
if
every nonagri-
at a simple crossroads.
center,
Fig. 82.
Shape and
street
+ =
tions according to
which
in the
sharp corners.
Regional Systems
443
In the
large city,
contradistinction to
its
H.
successful
length.
25.
Whereas through
railroad
is
best
traffic is
minimum
it
requirements,
is
situated.
where the
Freight stations
should be distributed on the radially emerging tracks, along or on the other side of
which factories may be located. Switch yards, freight depots, and other extensive
installations should be in the outer districts.
For
than radial
There, in contradistinction
to the heart
traffic,
Example
1;
see also
diamond-shaped
feeder streets.
See also B.
innerstddtischen
Verkehrs
Part Four.
444
nung, 1941,
Examples
und Raumord-
p. 65).-^
Even on a
dull uniformity.
As
town, and this to the metropolis (Fig. 46, p. 167), so suburban centers
toward the more influential city. Even in individual houses the most important room and its window may be
situated with respect to a view (of interesting traffic). In small places
such imperceptible deviations from symmetry, associated perhaps
with a slight rotation or moving forward of selected buildings, may
not only create a compact and dynamic street pattern but also greatly
also are diverted
effec-
27. In
28.
of 1935.
some
There must be no perfunctory or
affected enlivening, as in so many modern settlements. This is one of the
reasons why
so few modern village or town plans are satisfying. The problem of our
large cities
in particular can seldom be solved today by the principles, and still less
often by the
practical purpose, or by an assured artistic result.
to
Chapter 25.
Frontier Regions
The
political
immediate natural
boundary separates it
same difficulties
the
exactly
creates
This
supply and market areas.
farmers in
French
the
for
as
for the Swiss businessmen of Geneva
Figure 83,
in
hatched
Geneva,
its environs. Thus the hinterland of
almost completely from
Fig. 83.
The French
hinterland of Geneva.
The
its
dotted
line,
broken
"small" zone,
was excluded from the French customs area, partly by State Treaty
when Geneva became Swiss again after the Napoleonic Wars, and
partly by a voluntary decision of France when Savoy became French
in 1860. Matters remained so until 1914 and 1923 respectively. In
1932 the Hague Tribunal decided that the former state of affairs
" small " zone imposed upon
be restored, at least in respect to the
Switzerland whose customs
hand,
other
On
the
1815-16.
France in
since
1849, was to facilitate
coincided
had
and political frontiers
During the first four
zone.
this
from
products
the importation of
445
Part Four.
446
new
Examples
it
increased tenfold.
Fig. 84.
upon
The
its
The importance
of
B was
so
reduced
by the boundary of the Corridor that it lost even two places that had
remained German to competing Freystadt. (After W. Volz and H. Schwalm,
Die deutsche Ostgrenze. Unterlageyi zur Erfassung der Grenzzerreisungsschdden [Leipzig, 1929],
Map
la.)
The Canton of St. Gallen, and the upper Rhine Valley in particular,
now suffers severely under the compression that resulted from extension of the German exchange regulations to Austria. The Canton
of Ticino also
1.
2.
it
is
is
between
Italy
44'i
Frontier Regions
clearly
is
shown
is
restricted to a
few gateways.
Canadian wheat provinces and the United States only eight railways
approach it closely!
cross the line, though nearly two dozen branches
undulating, along
slightly
but
or
fiat,
Yet the terrain is perfectly
the Rocky
toward
West,
the
Even
to
almost the entire border.
Mountains, where the
hills
become
higher,
many
rivers flow in a
north-south direction and thus offer natural traffic routes, but for
312 miles not one single railway crosses the line! This supports the
general belief, which must be relied upon here in the absence of
this border,
statistics, that the small border traffic is insignificant on
CANADA
Saskatchewan
larroad
Havre
Montana
\^
Fig. 85.
5^
The network
North Dakota
of railways
and lawful trade in particular. The only exceptions are the few
gateways and these, of course, are the center for market areas of a
special kind, which often reach exclusively into the neighboring
country. Here large quantities of articles are sold that can easily
be smuggled, or that make it worth while to spend two days as a
" in the neighboring country, after which purchases up to
"
tourist
a value of $100 monthly can be brought in free of duty. But regular
purchases of goods with a short sales radius are uncommon.
One who enters the frontier city of Detroit by way of the wide
pasture lands of Ontario will hardly believe that after the tariff
had been increased during the Great Depression practically not a
single drop of Canadian milk was sent there, whereas previously
New
it
far as
Part tour.
448
Examples
mined.
The
it
lies
goods
capital
affects
same
way.
Fig. 86.
The
at a
bank
in
El Paso.
Reserve Districts in the United States, 63rd Congress, Second Session, Senate
When
1914], p. 149.)
an international boundary
is
recent exarnple
3.
dem besonderen
Frontier Regions
449
sources of supply.
Thus
its
Upper Baden
whole
series of reasons
and
so
on
(see
W.
some
respects, at least
it
is
intersection,
it
According to E. Waldschiitz
deutschen Grenzgebiet, Frankfurt dissertation, 1928, p. 39 f.) more than half the enterprises in the frontier zone were still Swiss in 1922; 80 per cent, indeed, in the food
industry and 100 per cent in the tobacco industry.
6.
p. 317, Fig. 2.
Examples
Part Four.
,{^o
(L. Dedi,
flexibility in the
wage
op.
rate,
cit.,
105)
p.
Insufficient regional
on
traffic
led
{Die
My
presentation
deutsche
[Leipzig, 1929])
is
Ostgrenze.
Institut fiir
Traffic
Silesia
The
eastern
among
present
[1944]
Upper
Silesia's
principal
trade
is
northward, to regions
that
were
und Raumordnung,
Frontier Regions
451
almost entirely by the boundary, lost nine tenths of its market area
(see map, Fig. 84)
and its population fell in consequence from
2,314 in 1913 to 1,792 in 1933. Before World War I the market areas
of the industries of the Grenzmark stretched toward the east, because
toward the west they encountered the vigorous competition of Berlin
and other great cities. The new boundary therefore cut them off
,
from the largest part of their market area, and many enterprises had
to be closed down. Extensive agricultural areas, too, lost their
natural sales center. Thus instead of near-by Danzig, Eastern Pomerania supplied Stettin, three times as far distant, and a large fraction
of East Prussia surpluses became valueless if they could not be processed to something lighter (for example, the converting of potatoes
On
new boundary
Upper Silesia. As the
German market was almost closed to them and the Polish market
alone was inadequate, this coal made its way to Scandinavia, thanks
into starch, fodder
and
so on).
miners.^
effort
is
made
9.
effects of a political
See R. Regul, " Die Wettbewerbslage der Steinkohle," Vierteljahrshefte zur Kon-
junkturforschung, Sonderheft 34
(Berlin, 1933)
G. Wende, Die Ausrvirkungen der
Grenzziehung auf die oberschlesische Montanindustrie (Stuttgart, 1932)
;
10.
"
From
this
it
is
On
this
subject
Handelsvertragen
see
(Vienna,
to
R.
effects of
customs frontiers,
be sure.
Riedl, Die Meistbegiinstigung
1928),
18,
pp.
124
in den europdischen
Boggs-Bowman, International
(Geneva zone)
and Baumgartner, Grenz-
94-106;
also
C.
Chapter 26.
We
The
Trade
cases in
and wide.
a.
1.
Spatial Variations
in
Land Prices
to
be highest
453
city,
and
to fall for
Fig. 87.
(From R. Klopper
(see
H.
v.
Thiinen,
Der isolirte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschajt und Nationalokonomie [Waentig edition, Jena, 1921], p. 103). The price summits
for every town and, in regions with the same structure for the next
lower places belonging thereto, lie on regional price gradients, of
which the steepest is the economic landscape gradient. Across section
therefore shows the following patern: Prices of land are highest in
1.
According to a
map
great regularity.
Part Four.
454
Examples
Department
of Agriculture, Value of
in 1935.
Map
(After P. Hesse
9.)
1920-2456
1135-1919
568-1134
-567 and
less
2.
Land
in Chile
about 1897 was almost dearer by 300 pesos with every additional
(1/3 of a square mile) approximately (K. Karger,
455
2.
The
Wages
Space
in
goods and
is
is
the
exactly the
capital.^
marks higher
disregarded
in 1928
if
areas with
(correlation coefficient
something
like
lAOfl
Valparaiso)
3.
The
size of
The number
form.
of
distance.
The same
Pirath, Verkehr
und Landesplanung
thing
is
true of regional
all cases
when weaker
Part Four.
^k6
As with land
The
the market.
Examples
und
Statistik,
casual workers in
by
1.
2.
10,000-25,000 inhabitants
25,000-50,000 inhabitants
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
On
50,000-100,000 inhabitants
100,000-200,000 inhabitants
200,000-500,000 inhabitants
500,000-1,000,000 inhabitants
Over 1,000,000 inhabitants
is
0%
2.
5.4%
5.8%
8.5%
13.9%
14.2%
30.9%
towns.
4.
memorandum)
Preisgefiilles
(unpublished
457
Hourly
wage
EIID50-54
155-59
160-64
365-69
170-74
175-79
80-84
1
185-89
190-94
Reichspfennigs
Fig. 89.
wage
1941.
Fig. 90.
The
Stuttgart
commuting area
ah Industriestandorte
travel
Stutt-
Part Four.
458
Examples
number
of points given.
Fig. 91.
dollars.
directions,
all
to reach their
highly industrial
New
Of course
these
money wage
they reflects only the smaller productivity of the Southern worker; nor do they affect
him
6.
that
The
is,
it
($1.10)
and
Seattle
($1.73)
is
real;
holds despite the use of sole leather of the same quality and heels of the
same brands.
Fig. 92.
459
Fig. 93.
see
Table
column
column
1936.
h.)
(For source
i.)
hand
4^0
Part Four.
On
Examples
NRA
7.
Many
of
of Labor, Bulletin
Labor that pre-code differences should not have existed, and proceeded so zealously
them that few, if any, of its policies upset business inter-relations and
to eliminate
NRA
Ind.,
1937),
p. 154.
9.
Wages
because labor
is
less
The
small towns.
a real difference,
is
4^1
did not assume greater proportions. Yet even so the effects were
apparent. Employment in the cotton-spinning mills ^^ of New
England and the wood industry of the West increased much more
than in the South {N.R.A. Hours, Wages, and Employment under
the Codes [Washington, 1935], p. 58)
Interest
3.
still
less
Space
in
SPATIAL DIFFERENCES
I.
To
The
the
European
Facts
IN
obvious,
politicians
11.
time
cent.
Between the middle of 1932 and the middle of 1933 77.8 per cent of all spinning
to the share of the South, whereas in 1933-34 its share had fallen to 73.7 per
Conversely, the share of the North rose from 20.2 per cent to 24.1 per cent.
fell
J. J.
wrote in similar vein. Chiefly as a result of government action the hourly wage of male
textile workers rose in the North from July to August, 1933, by 45 per cent, and in the
South by 67 per cent; for the women by as much as 56 per cent and 100 per cent. See
A. F. Hinrichs, "Wage Rates and Weekly Earnings in the Cotton-Textile Industry,
1933-34," Monthly Labor Review, March, 1935, p. 6.
Part Four.
4f)a
Examples
toward the end of May, 1931, when the rate of the Federal
Reserve Bank in New York was 1| per cent and that in Minneapolis
S^ per cent.
greatest
2.
SPATIAL DIFFERENCES
IN
2000
7000
Fig. 94.
from
The
New
3000
York, 1919-25.
The
rates
were lowest in
New York
That
(7 to 8
(1^ to 3
per cent)
(around New
York) 5.45 per cent in the Middle West (around Chicago) 5.99
per cent in the South, and 6.49 per cent in the Far West. Going
4^3
detail,
we
discover a
phenomenon
that
we
its
This
and the tendency of the interest rate to rise with distance from New York, are shown with special clarity in Figure 94.
Twenty financial centers are entered on the abscissa according to
their distance from New York by rail, and on the ordinates are
arranged the average interest rates on six principal varieties of bank
cent)
.^^
final decline
loans in 1919-1925."
Differences
all
with
dis-
tance from the dominant banking center, but no data have been
up
compared
with total outstanding bank loans of all sorts. In the first six months
of 1936 and for central reserve city banks the ratio was: New York,
Calculated after F. C. Mills {The Behavior of Prices [New York, 1927], p. 184)
As most statistics on regional differences in interest
have not been published in recent years, it is often necessary to go back to old data.
12.
who
in
Part
^.().j
I-
our.
Examples
14.
The
The
rate of interest
where
on
10 per cent
agri-
anyway on
all
same
customeis because the long-term total profit on the business connection in question,
it
same type
of loan
is
shall
may
be (Riefler, op.
arise because,
more
cit.,
p. 87)
On
the
from
But
distance of
some 63
miles.
Interest rose
large parts of the Dallas area lie near the St. Louis
from
8.4
per cent at a
areas,
because
which on
465
0/0
16
15
1
If
1
13
12
e-"^
11
10
^ A/ \ .J
/
"^ _^
s/> u
A,
x?=
20
60
60
IW
120
100
160
Miles
Fig. 95.
Table
35.)
achieved,
is
when
the
under consideration
Table 35.
is
Cent according
to Distance
Distance
in miles
Houston
from
Nearest of
the four
locations
0-10
10-20
20-30
30-40
40-50
0-40
40-80
80-120
120-160
160-200
6.9
7.0
7.6
7.6
;
'
7.3
9.3
8.2
8.7
9.1
9.6
10.2
9.6
8.6
'
'
9.0
10.1
1
10.5
11.0
10.7
11.3
11.0
a. Arranged according to distance from the original data of the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation. I am deeply indebted to Dr. Donald Thompson, who made
this valuable material available to me.
Port Four.
466
Examples
In several cases the interest was found to be above 2.5 per cent, the
legal rate. I was unable to determine the causes for these
fluctuations, and therefore offer the result with reservations.
maximum
Table 36.
Interest
Deposits
in Per Cent
0-20
20-60
60-100
100-140
140-180
180-200
SPATIAL DIFFERENCES
3.
The
on
Time
1.60
2.19
2.24
2.34
2.70
2.74
IN
BOND INTEREST
rate of interest
on long-term debts
New
(local
enterprises)
debtors
New
York. Most
main they lie
of those in
east of the
The
We
17.
York, 1937)
and so on.
;.
.
4^7
The
a
list
Moody
{op.
cit., p.
a6) gives
falls
in this order.
But
and the
yield rises,
Moody
of the Mississippi
should be more or
less
Finally, the
coupon
New
Of
York.
issue
them
at
its
neighbor, Vermont,
Mississippi
had a coupon
offer at least
4^ per cent
The
states that
had
to
bank and
Mississippi
states
on
itself,
east
from
New
cent.
Part Four.
468
Examples
and then
interest rates in
/?.
1.
We
The Explanation
^^
wide regional
from the
all
from
great financial centers of the Northeast, above
New York.
But now this must be explained in detail. This we shall endeavor
to do, not in general terms but by using the example of the East-
differences in interest
depend upon
first
that
the
differences in distance
West
Why
is
the
demand
West?
Why
and
of capital in this
at the
agricultural losses.
18.
Although
seems to
me
this
what holds for other prices holds for it also, to repeat the explanation
and in a form more nearly adapted to the special case of interest.
19.
The
all prices it
reader will soon notice that most arguments can be applied also to dif-
Germany.
arguments have been taken from the extensive work of
(Twenty Years of Federal Reserve Policy [Cambridge, Mass., 1933]) and
an admirable study by W. W. Riefler (Money Rates and Money Markets in the United
States [New York and London. 1930])
Others are based on my own investigations and
20. Several of the following
S.
E. Harris
personal inquiries.
469
West
at the
economy
West
money
finds
of the
banks
to the
its
less
of the
lent
way
to
New
its
centers
21. In the middle of 1935, for example, the total loans (including bills of exchange)
by banks in the East amounted to 41 per cent of the deposits, in the Middle West and
Mountain States to only 29 per cent. (Comptroller of the Currency, Annual Report for
1935 [Washington, 1936], pp. 102 ff.)
22.
The legal
demand
cent for
reserve ratio
deposits.
is,
of course, highest in
The
cities
is
Chicago: 13 per
10 per cent,
and
lowest,
on hand was 0.8 per ecnt, 1.25 per cent, and 2.25 per cent of
(Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board for 1932
[Washington, 1933], p. 269.) When we consider the fact that the smaller and more
distant banks maintain additional balances also with larger banks and banks in the
financial centers as a reserve, it turns out that they actually have a higher reserve ratio
than New York banks.
is
23.
Expenses of
116
f.)
24. In
bank averaged
States $200,000.
Pr( Four.
^yo
The
Examples
credit,
p. 108)
cit.,
losses of
The
and
in the
costs, the
West
to 0.75
higher rediscount
interest differential,
toward the West to equalize the difference. The various causes have
common denominator: the higher cost of loans toward the West
to both debtor and creditor. Again there appear the direct costs of
greater distance, which may also take the form of a greater loss of
time. Thus a country bank in the middle of Mississippi can obtain
an emergency loan from a larger bank in Memphis in three days,
a
25.
According
to the
{ibid., p.
678)
general expenses
first
Up
Salaries
1.64
0.65
Other expenses
1.15
0.41
Unpaid loans
0.80
1.35
0.44
0.66
1040
5700
Net
Absolute in dollars
0.40
0.25
0.27
0.49
1,110,000
to
47'
whereas
unless
it
it
with eastern surpluses lent out temporarily in the West, the possibility of sudden recall must always be reckoned with. For the eastern
27.
op.
cit.,
and elsewhere)
p. 75
first class,
for
whom
may
therefore be distinguished
is
(Riefler,
variously high.
It is
market for first-class bills and the great New York banks. It is highest for small enterprises, whose credit is good only at one local bank. Thus a certain class of customers
and banks always deal with one another. The larger both are, the more distance loses
in importance. J. P. Morgan is as well acquainted with General Motors, although it is
a thousand miles away, as
is
transactions)
From
this
German
discus-
paid too little attention to regional differences in risks. Their regional credit policy
was too regular, their personal policy too irregular. From this a special purpose for
regional banks, as middlemen between medium-sized deposits and medium-sized credits
on an agricultural basis followed. In order to equalize the risks the only problem was
to locate them in such a way that the borrowers should be engaged in different pursuits;
or, if it was desired to root out the evil entirely, to bring about a more balanced
development of individual economic lanscapes. Regional banks have the advantage
over the large banks that during the depression medium-sized credits proved to be more
liquid than large ones.
1933], II, 172.
Tagblatt.
May
Also
my
3, 1932.)
"
P^'i't
j^2
creditor there
which
is,
in addition to the
also exists
more or
less
Four.
we have
Examples
seen,
the
stormy and uncertain. Information and credit bureaus may compensate partly for this lack of personal knowledge, but they cannot
make up
for
it
entirely.
Huey Long,
later assassinated.
The
reaction, of course,
is
still
own
28.
countries;
No
is
The
banks.
their customers.
risk,
even
if
by distance.
That they put up with
in turn
29.
it
is
partly a cause
and partly
According to Untersuchungsausschuss
in
II,
filr
473
many
industries there,
journeys,
is
the
West are
large
not equalize
it.
up in the West
must be described in detail, to meet the objection that an explanation by distance alone is too simple. It is now easy to see that in
the final analysis almost all ^^ the factors cited depend upon distance.
The
which lent them out again locally for the most part, or at least in
the Reich as a whole, exclusive of Berlin, this proportion was
approximately one half, in Berlin one twentieth (on the other hand, almost two thirds
of all deposits went to the large banks)
31. See also F. S. Hall, "The Localization of Industries," U. S. Department of Com-
and
credit unions,
in
I,
pp. 211
ff.;
M. Keir, "Economic
American Academy
PEP
and
and others.
and Economic Planning) Report on the Location of Industry
{Political
(London, 1939) p. 9.
33. Among independent factors the fixing of legal maximum rates of interest might
be mentioned. These in turn, however, adapt themselves to the independent interest
,
differential.
in the East
As a rule they are higher in the South, and especially in the West, than
per cent in New York, for example, and 12 per cent in New Mexico).
(6
In general they are very high, but can be circumvented by additional credit terms.
P^^^ Four.
474
Examples
and
as a
and more
fertile,
its
to agriculture.
Simi-
risks to agriculture
and
upon long
influence upon
distance from the sea. But even when these chance historical and
geological factors are disregarded, the number of inhabitants, indusits
trialization
(especially in the
diversification of the
economy
form of
large-scale industries)
and
edge even in a theoretical system. To these indirect effects of distance upon interests are to be added all the direct effects, which
need not be repeated. Whoever is still in doubt need only imagine
New York shifted from its eccentric position to the middle of the
continent in order to be convinced how greatly this would lower
the rate of interest in the West.
2.
much
smaller in the
This is possible
only because the discount rate is not in close touch with the market
rate, as it is in Germany. The causes are institutional and political.
Purely economically, the readiness of individual Reserve Banks to
rediscount is determined by their available capital (and thus finally
by their gold reserve, which sometimes can be increased by rediscounting through other Reserve Banks) whereas the demand of
member banks to rediscount could be thought of as determined by
profits (difference between the discount rate of the Reserve Banks
and that of member banks) by necessity (exhaustion of their own
means) and by competition (difference between the discount rate
of Reserve Banks and that of outside banks)
Discount rates originating in this way may differ regionally by at least as much as the
discount rate of a Reserve Bank in the cheapest financial center
differs from the considerably higher rate ^* of interest on loans
between ordinary banks. For example, if the discount rate in New
York is 2 per cent and member banks there will not lend to other
banks at less than 3 per cent, the Reserve Bank in Atlanta can
immediately fix its discount rate at 3 per cent without having to
fear that its member banks will turn to New York.'^ Indeed, it can
United
market
interest.
34. It
is
only slightly below the rate that other customers pay. See Riefler, op.
cit.,
p. 92.
35. For the lower rates in the impersonal open market compete only for the most
important banks with the Reserve Bank discount. If a bank can obtain means still more
475
go even beyond 3 per cent, because not all its member banks can
borrow in New York at the lowest rate, or borrow at all, and because
in any case borrowing is associated with higher costs.
But the Reserve Banks have not used their gold reserves to the
limit, and therefore have never been interested in an effective discount rate that would facilitate international transfers. Nor was
the Reserve discount very effective as a business cycle policy, partly
because of the objective market conditions and partly because of the
Reserve Banks themselves. Because of the abundance of American
capital, the creation of credit does not play such an important role
as it does in Germany, and there is a smaller need for notes since
payment by check is widespread, so that the point at which banks
have to rediscount if they wish to extend their credit still further,
is reached later.
Thus the Reserve Banks do not exert very strict
control over their member banks through the discount rate, and
try to make up for this by changing reserve requirements ^^ and by
open market operations."
Furthermore, this abundance of capital leads member banks to
reduce their securities holdings at a favorable price during an upswing, when money is tight, rather than to call immediately on the
Reserve Banks for help. These arguments, however, apply entirely
to the rich Northeast only, whereas it is impossible to escape the
impression that the Reserve Banks in the capital-hungry West and
South often do not promote the creation of credit to a degree that
would be actually possible. Only too often they are restrained by
regulations and principles that appear to have grown out of conditions in the Northeast, and hence are not suited to the West and
South. The prohibition of rediscounting from motives of profit
seems to me especially open to criticism. For the Reserve Banks
do not want member banks to rediscount bills that they have
extended at a high rate of interest, with their Reserve Banks at
cheaply in the open market,
it
Within certain
New York
this
Reserve Bank.
requirements.
37. I
doubt their
When
efficacy.
the
sell
Government
example, to reduce the liquidity of the banks, the question is, especially
when the banks themselves are supposed to be the buyers, whether they are disposed to
securities, for
make an investment
fall
ment
them
If
the latter
is
make
industrial
buy no Govern-
obligations;
refrain,
Part Four.
^^5
their
Examples
(Riefler, op.
further the already limited effectiveness of their discount rate.^^ On the other hand, this slight effectiveness of discount
rates allows a discount policy that would not be tenable with more
restrict still
Low and
discount rates
member banks
will deal
more
become
effective,
It is
we have deduced
PRODUCT PRICES
tell
Hence
rates in the
above.
40
good
will
be large or small. At
first
means
40.
The moment
is
at
477
one
cheaper and the freight therefore higher in proportion to the proThen the following, say, are mentioned as examples
of the first group: ore, coal,*^ iron; wood, paper; bricks, cement; ^^
oil and salt,*^ as well as potatoes, hay, animals, and fruit. Typical
of the second group would be jewelry, watches, tobacco products,
is
ducer's price.
drugs, clothing,
also
is
not most
shipping distance
For instance,
it is
shorter for paper than for books, for iron than for machinery,
and
if
cases, the
is
shorter.
and
finally, in
f.
o. b.
prices plus freight, whereas with finished products the retail prices
include selling
costs,
localities.
Thus
at
first
reflections.
1.
Agricultural Products
a.
The geography
Wheat
("Die riiumliche Ordnung der Preise in Europa," Wirtschaftsring, 1941, pp. 205-207),
the European continental gradient for groups or averages of single prices at the opening
as
high as in Bulgaria.
In 1931-1933 the freight on cement in the United States, for instance, amounted
on the average
Urdahl and L.
to 1/3,
J.
NRA,
Division of Review, Work Materials, No. 65, 1936, pp. 59, 71.
Economic Survey of the Bituminous Coal Industry under Free Competition and Code Regulation," ihid., No. 69, I, 34.)
According to some sources,
August 13, 1940, salt prices in Mexico varied between 95 and 230 pesos per ton. On
Industry Code,"
F. E. Berquist, "
the whole, regional price differences are said to be great there during the rainy season
difficulties in transportation.
in
Part Four.
478
is
still
Examples
well worth
He
statistics for
wheat
files
of the
Department of Agri-
96.
Spatial pattern of
prices in the
been released
maps
These do not
connections
difficult,
which diminished
44. Geography
of
Wheat
Prices,
U.
S.
Department
of Agriculture, Bulletin
594
to a
map
statistical
cents,
of wholesale prices.
Zones are given, not lines of equal price, partly for the
way or the other to the nearest five
entire zones.
same over
479
farthest
is
therefore,
is
the supply areas for the Pacific and Atlantic exporting ports.
the
main
prices rise
p. 16)
and
Here
Along
costs
(Zapoleon, op.
cit.,
region.
But however
this
question
is
of,
and a
buy wheat
price!
is
of the
same
quality,
at the
same
"
p.
Potatoes
to
Trans-
Part Four.
48o
Examples
Fig. 98.
plus regions.
United
Bureau of Labor
States,
Statistics.)
Dominion Bureau
+ = sur-
of Statistics;
481
Colorado has increased since World War I. The low price around
Florida is a result of large imports from Cuba and Bermuda. That
around the Canadian province of Saskatchewan requires special
examination, because its potato production, though considerable,
is nevertheless low in proportion to the population.
For the rest,
the isotims, which had to be derived from comparatively few price
data with due consideration of transport conditions, naturally represent but a rough interpolation."*^ Even at the best they constitute
only a sound, yet for that very reason a useful and important,
presumption.
y.
Oranges
Distance from
Los Angeles in
Cents'
miles (rail)
16.0
Los Angeles
25.7
26.8
27.6
San Francisco
Salt Lake City
21.2
31.9
33.5
35.0
36.9
From
a.
El Paso
Portland (Oregon)
Denver
Omaha
Minneapolis
Chicago
470
780
820
1220
1370
1930
2280
2430
price of oranges.
48.
The
smaller price cones simply disappear in the interpolation, yet they are often
Thus in the Minneapolis supply area differences in producers' prices
highly significant.
up
(L.
to 66
F.
per cent, according to distance, have been showrn to persist over long periods.
Farm Crops in Minnesota, University of Minnesota,
Southeast of this area Florida controlled the market, while northwest of it California
was in possession of more than two thirds. {U S. Department of Agriculture. Carlot
.
Unloads of Certain Fruits and Vegetables in 66 Cities and Imports in 4 Cities for
Caimda 1936 [Washington, 1937]). Chicago and New York are similar "corner
markets " for oranges, as northwest Europe is for wheat.
Pfl^*
^82
nearer to
example,
it,
prices
it
is
Four.
Examples
California.
to
For
Jacksonville
as to
8.
may
Milk
for
milk
be especially large
is
and
irregular.
e.
would be wrong
It
to dismiss the
50. See
1934)
pp. 54
Prices
for
fat
(A Study of Fluid
2.
483
NONAGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Homogeneous Goods
a.
NEWSPAPERS
1.
New York
itself;
the city; for 5 cents in Boston, 220 miles distant; for 6 cents in
sidering
its
lies
falls
upon
the single
copy.
AUTOMOBILES
2.
The
its
rates prevailing
3.
CLOTHING
Summer
Information
it is
kindly
supplied
by
Mr.
S.
du
Brul,
of
the
General
Motors
Corporation.
54.
The buyer
more than
its
all
market value
as part
payment.
from the
East,
were something
like
found that
towels,
Thus
in the
which came
In
another case the conditions under which a mail-order house would deliver in the West
were less favorable, and the assortment included more expensive qualities.
Part Four.
i^^
Examples
In the present instance Palm Beach suits were not to be had at all
in remote San Francisco, according to reports of the Bureau of
Labor
Statistics.
4.
study that
is
Similar Goods
some
Economiques
et
Sociales, Paris,
1936)
Herberts, Paris.
58.
Hence
F. C. Mills' calculations of
also useless.
485
Even an orderly
task.
be
Hence
so on.2
when production
also
59. Where this was not already known it was obtained from business directories
(Thomas, Register of American Manufacturers, 1932-33 edition; Canadian Trade Index,
1936) and American Census of Manufacturers or the statistics on production of the
Dominion Bureau of Statistics.
60. Thus, in all stores investigated, a certain package of aspirin cost 12 cents in
Jacksonville, whereas in Mobile an identical package cost 15 cents. For another brand
the prices were 10 and 15 cents respectively; the difference, that is, was much greater
than would be caused by the insignificant difference in freight, since both places are
almost equally distant from the production center. New York. Similarly, the great
difference between the price for spectacles in New Orleans ($9.00) and Los Angeles
($15.50)
is
apparently genuine;
may be cheaper
level.
it
is
in the country
of origin.
61.
For example, in November, 1932, the prices of 19 important foods were 10 per
(C. Boehm, " Zur Frage
cent higher in the west end of Berlin than on the north side.
4A
[1937],
and vegetable prices were higher in the outskirts than at the center of
the city, because it cost more to transport goods from the great central market to the
shops; because the population density was down and sales were accordingly fewer; and
p. 460.)
Fruit
because competition was farther away. Extraordinary price differences prevailed in the
November
18, 1930,
onions of
und Gemiise
62.
These
medium
West
supplies.
New York
The
(in 1935
from $.70-$1.10
in the
Examples
Part Four.
^85
the smaller price funnels around a single factory simply drop through
the wide meshes of the including network. This is true of mattresses,
where, in addition, quality
for instance (Table 38, column /)
,
When
a raw material (shoemakers)
nevertheless wholly out of line, further investigation, wherever possible, has generally shown a difference in the
quality of the product or in business methods, or perhaps special
dries)
occasionally a price
is
1.
SOAP
63.
On
the Pacific Coast, along which only a narrow but very long strip
is
made
at the
strip,
and
is
populated,
the south: Seattle, $1.30; Portland, Ore., $1.42; San Francisco, $1.47; Los Angeles, $1.55
..
487
TabU
LOCAL DIFFERENCES
IN
38.
PRICES IN THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA,
1936
1
g
59
60
56
59
56
58
57
58
55
60
56
58
73
61
60
57
58
62
61
68
67
63
68
64
47
Boston, Massachusetts
Portland, Maine
Buffalo, New York
New York City, New York
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
Pittsburg, Pennsylvania
Scranton, Pennsylvania
Chicago, Illinois
Cincinnati,
Ohio
Cleveland, Ohio
Detroit, Michigan
Indianapolis, Indiana
Kansas
City,
Kansas
Minneapolis, Minnesota
Saint Louis, Missouri
Baltimore, Maryland
Washington, D.
Norfolk, Virginia
Richmond, Virginia
Atlanta, Georgia
Savannah, Georgia
Jacksonville, Florida
Birmingham, Alabama
Mobile, Alabama
New
Orleans, Louisiana
64
70
66
54
Memphis, Tennessee
Houston, Texas ...
Denver, Colorado
Los Angeles, California
San Francisco, California
.
59
59
62
Portland, Oregon
Seattle,
Washington
Montreal, Quebec
Toronto, Ontario
Winnipeg, Manitoba
Regina, Saskatchewan
Saskatoon, Saskatchewan.
Calgary, Alberta
Edmonton, Alberta
Vancouver, Brit. -Columbia
.
50
47
94 91 1.21 45
1.60 97 93 1.17 25
1.63 100 85 1.32 25
1.41 72 89 1.13 39
1.38 80 66 1.13 30
1.56 89 74 1.16 32
1.56 69 68 1.23 40
1.34 67 73 1.15 36
1.75 69 89 1.13 33
1.51 67 102 1.18 29
1.48 68 98 1.17 40
1.62 73 86 1.11 36
1.99 89 83 1.15 24
72 99 1.17 25
1.
1.74 73 92 1.12 38
1.53 65 88 1.28 39
1.68 68 96 1.18 35
1.81 72 96 1.23 28
1.96 84 86 1.31 36
1.65 68 74 1.20 20
1.70 78 92 1.19 22
1,05 28
1.51 72
1.66 70 69 1.10 24
1.86 67 60 1.14 24
1.96 71 76 1.17 32
1.74 69 82 1.24 30
9.5
1.30
11.0
1.40
10.8
1.29
12.3
1.12
11.3
1.34
10.8
1.54
13.1
1.16
12.3
1.51
13
19
17
16
16
16
15
14
15
20
15
13
12
15
11.5
1.24
11
1.12
1.50
1.56
91
1.19
31
11.8
1.47
13.2
1.17
10.5
1.15
12.6
1.10
13.8
1.21
12.2
1.25
14.8
1.31
12.2
1.25
13.7
1.18
13.1
1.25
12.9
1.31
16
17
16
15
13
15
10
12.3
1.15
11
12.4
1.36
11
9.0
1.23
12.6
1.27
12.3
1.62
13
15
15
16
15
14
1.86
71
1.73
1.68
1.57
1.83
1.83
1.87 87
2.00 79
2.00 117
2.00
2.00 150
2.18 97
2.00 100
2.25 79
1.59
1.49
1.59
1.68
1.49
1.43
1.52
1.44
45
39
42
21.2
23.7
41
21.0
42
46
20.7
41
20.9
56
44
50
36
45
29
33
44
39
37
46
43
34
39
32
46
28
33
35
46
32
40
50
44
50
19.8
19.8
19.0
22.0
18.3
23.6
19.7
22.7
21.0
20.7
26.8
20.4
22.4
27.9
26.3
27.8
24.2
22.6
24.1
23.0
25.1
22.5
19.1
28.3
22.7
24.0
17 32
17 39
18
15 35
15
16 35
15 35
16 36
cakes of 6
(U.S.A.) or laundry soap (Canada). Price ^o^ 10
(less sales tax in U. S. A.). Uther
cents
in
each
ounces
(Canada)
(USA) or 8
Kingston. Ont.. 49; Port
Canadian cities: Halifax. 51; St. John, 50; Quebec, 47;
B.C., 52.
Arthur. 50; Nanaimo, B.C.. 51; Prince Rupert.
quality (more detailed descripMen's cotton shirts with attached collars, medium
of production are New
centers
chief
The
tax.
sales
less
In dollars
tion added)
York. New Jersey, and Pennsylvania.
cents
detailed statement)
Cotton work shirts with collars (according to more
The Canadian surplus area is Quebec. In the United
A.)
U.
Kitchen soap
States production
S.
is
divided especially
among
Examples
Part Four.
488
as well as
cities:
d.
Bed
sheets,
dollars
81
X 99
(less sales
The production
inches
tax in U.
center
(according to
S.
A.)
The
is
more
states
6.
Price in
production area.
/.
Motion
g.
Glasses.
pictures.
varieties described in
h.
of heels, in dollars
i.
I.
detail, in dollars
Laundering a man's
k.
more
Resoling and heeling men's shoes. Sewed, best quality leather, well-known brand
C,
shirt
with
collar.
20.
Haircut. Adults, cents. Other Canadian cities: Halifax, 32; St. John, 28; Ottawa,
25; London, Ont., 35; Medicine Hat, Alba., 35; Nelson, B. C, 50; Trail, B. C, 50;
Prince Rupert, B. C, 50; Victoria, 35.
Mattresses, according to more detailed statements. Price in dollars (less sales tax).
Labor
Statistics,
Fig. 99.
production centers.
(Sources: see
Table
38,
489
Z.
TEXTILES
distance
would
textiles,
64. For men's cotton pajamas. The prices refer to pajamas that were deliberately
chosen because of their comparable quality (according to the Canadian special inquiry
November 1, 1936).
65. The same is true of cement, of which British Columbia imports a rather large
amount by rail. {Economic Council of British Columbia, The Trade of British
Columbia with Other Canadian Provinces and with Foreign countries, 1935 [Victoria,
of
1937], p. 97.)
following
cities,
49"
Part Four.
Examples
(2,880
the freight for the entire stretch from Montreal
to Vancouver
falls to only $3.27 because of the competing
water route.^^ As a
second factor there may be added more the risk than
the
miles)
volume
of
COST OF LIVING 68
c.
1.
General Principles
With
67.
easily in
The
19321, pp 10 26)
East Coast belongs in part to the market
area of northwest Europe for Ponland
"^ xriJinduu
cement
68
also
(zbzd.. p. 28)
it
will
..
T'
^".P"""P^^ ^^^y
P^r.
m'/h
TtI share neither view.
art ill
that
1
be assumed at
first
-"
ed.
The
"^^
49^
lawas,
conversely, a deflation of
when
It is different
have
fallen.
dislocated,
More
some
up because
the price
of the cheaper
and fewer
now be
them
least,
69.
The
third case, in
Paasche index
rises
rises, is
certainly impossible.
important.
falls,
remains
possible,
uncertain,
but especially
Part Four.
^Q2
Examples
The
procedure
is
the same
2.
Statistics
The Reich Statistical Bureau (Direccompared the living costs for German officials abroad
by methods a or b, and the International Labor Office established
for 14 European cities by methods b or c the costs of living that
correspond to those of a worker in Detroit.^^ As it was soon found
that many articles bought by the Detroit worker were not obtainable
a)
Subjective Comparisons:
tor Jacobs)
70.
71. Internationales
utility in the
United
States.
(Geneva, 1933)
("The so-called
Ford Inquiry.)
493
much
{ibid., p. 33)
fiir
schiede
und
ihrer
Bedeutung
fiir
pp. 185-189.)
Nevertheless
(food)
it
wide price differences (rent, heat) the expenditures, were not so great
example, Arbeitswissenschaftliches Institut, Jahrbuch, 1937, p. 86)
73. How differently regional variations may be viewed according to income level is
illustrated by a little incident. I asked the American Consul in Vancouver (Canada)
in the case of
(see, for
Part Four.
4y4
Examples
much
affected
by
which
inflation.
The
found in each (!) added the unweighted figures (!) ^* separately for
and heat, weighted only these three groups among themselves with constant (!) weights, and took the result to be interlocally
comparable indices of living costs. Wrongly, since according to this
method living costs may be greater not only where prices are high,
but also where people live extravagantly because they buy a better
quality of product. At best, only the indices for housing are usable.
In 1938 the International Labor Office compared the retail prices
,
food, light,
for
them
which
Group
(see
As
countries.
of footnote 74
74.
The
end
(above)
of equal size
in
Nordmark,
forschung, Wochenhericht, 1937, pp. 162-166.) In 1937 the Schleswig-Holstein household smoked 87 cigars, 350 cigarettes, and b\ pounds of tobacco; the Berlin household,
141, 1,421,
p.
45.)
and
To
1^ respectively.
requirement
(in reply to
is
consumption that
is
common
I,
105
ff.)
to
all
(1939)
places
Price Levels
ment
i)i
against
Space
all
495
gate of needs varies not only with changes in relative prices, but also
75.
own
(Rompe)
is
As far
as
drinking
concerned,
is
life
is
more
expensive in the South than in the North, even with equal prices, and in the North
cheaper in the country than in the city (see p.492, note 70.)
.
76.
is
it
fulfills
it
economy and
Chapter 27
a.
1.
Schaffle
crisis of
1857:
"With
devastating
1.
Gesammelte Aufsdtze,
II,
23-24, 42.
496
497
n
w\t
9
Fig. 100.
Westward movement
The
figure gives
period
main
is
traffic
5,
was
most rapidly in
The economic
by these influences from
this direction.
Part Four.
^q8
Examples
Ruhr
district,
upward by
more
strongly,
in Stuttgart."
2.
"
pp. 188
3.
f.
The
advance.
more slowly do
price
movement*
499
Table 39.
Food
Industrial
Seaports
cities
a
o
H
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935
1936
1937
Basis:
102
126
102
125
162
180
188
216
163
139
144
140
147
157
153
147
152
147
102
117
150
167
172
204
159
136
138
135
148
152
147
161
188
193
208
152
152
156
154
172
176
171
165
163
167
169
162
144
126
112
110
103
104
109
117
116
126
129
125
129
125
137
130
130
134
139
U.
>
S
o
o
a
141
153
144
157
145
130
110
106
161
153
141
116
113
96
101
98
105
108
108
109
107
113
118
113
114
117
116
120
120
91
99
94
100
101
102
103
101
108
111
106
108
113
113
112
115
S. A.,
Rents
_J
Automobile
Industrial
cities
cities
"3
a
o
o
-a
Seaports
cities
o
a
c
o
u
c
a
C/3
98
108
137
173
181
195
139
142
143
145
158
152
151
145
146
150
152
150
126
118
112
102
96
100
100
103
110
117
115
113
119
116
121
120
121
130
127
200
151
131
129
129
141
141
140
135
141
142
151
144
124
105
98
89
104
124
156
182
195
211
149
149
144
>
101
116
151
170
181
216
161
121
111
136
132
130
136
147
142
137
144
142
149
138
126
101
95
151
171
172
170
159
159
166
164
157
138
98
81
90
91
91
96
105
115
112
123
126
124
127
124
133
133
128
134
139
84
84
89
90
93
95
93
99
95
97
97
96
99
103
104
99
106
109
109
114
114
December, 1914
= 100.
101
94
99
105
103
104
103
101
105
109
121
128
147
161
165
171
176
179
178
175
173
169
167
166
165
162
156
150
140
129
120
115
113
112
112
112
113
113
114
117
117
118
119
126
100
102
112
119
130
151
165
172
176
176
171
165
165
164
164
165
165
171
171
171
173
173
159
144
144
144
147
147
147
159
159
159
167
167
170
170
173
Canada, 1914-15
Automobile
94
102
122
132
147
166
178
188
98
95
99
144
161
181
176
172
164
163
164
164
174
161
171
171
171
158
155
154
152
152
150
148
144
137
125
115
108
103
100
99
99
100
101
101
102
103
105
107
108
109
191
190
173
173
176
176
177
177
162
156
145
145
150
156
156
163
163
163
163
163
163
172
172
179
84
79
91
126
158
188
201
200
190
191
192
193
192
190
190
189
189
189
189
178
178
152
152
130
126
120
120
120
124
124
124
124
130
130
146
146
152
-a
Q
102
117
133
139
153
188
196
189
202
205
198
195
187
179
178
177
178
173
160
145
131
118
101
89
84
86
93
96
100
109
111
114
116
117
125
127
131
100
104
109
117
128
144
156
154
160
166
169
169
169
162
162
163
163
161
161
158
158
126
105
105
92
98
98
98
105
113
113
113
113
113
117
117
117
= 100.
S. A.,
The
my
disposal by Mr. C.
W.
for
Part Four.
Examples
Table 40
National Price Increase after Devaluation of the Currency in
Canada
U.
(June, 1931
U.
S.
Hamilton, Canada
Toronto, Canada
A.
100)
Rent
Food
Rent
82
83
114
87
90
87
93
90
102
106
91
75
80
108
87
84
86
108
79
81
70
127
85
86
67
107
94
Food
Buffalo,
S.
96
Seattle,
U.
S.
Vancouver, Canada
Detroit,
U.
S.
Windsor, Canada
of 1921,
110
100
1
5^
60
so
JJ
-\
\\
70
s.
of
J.
J.J
^
/
f
y.
\
\
SO
60
*,
'/
V**
U. S. A.
1
'A
192930 37 32 33 3f 35 36
C A N A D A
1
1330 31 32
33 3V 35 36 37
501
cities
(Fig. 101)
The
2-
We
suspected.
Its
in regions
when
it still
of tariff policy.
this
4.
J.
Wheat
(Washington, 1918)
Prices, U.
p. 25.
S.
Department
of Agri-
Pari hOiir.
5oa
Exam^iles
War.
From
the century.
1820
The
30
The ratio of price levels in the North and South in the United States and
dependence upon tariff policy, 1820-1935. a) Level of American industrial prices
(L. Myers and M. R. Cooper, Cotton Statistics and Related Data [Washington, Department of Agriculture, 1932], pp. 3-5) relative to the price of middling upland cotton
in New York (pp. 7-9. The 1861 ratio is set at 100. b) Customs receipts as percentages
of dutiable imports. (Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1891, pp. 15 ff.; 1936,
Fig. 102.
its
p. 436)
War years, partly because tariff revenues had decreased in consequence of the preceding depression, and partly because Government
expenditures had increased enormously. This period, too, is well
characterized by curve b. The fall between 1900 and 1920 was
caused, in addition to the relaxing of the protective tariff particularly in 1913,
by the
6.
The
try tariffs
War
many
rates
1897
and
were
energy of the protectionists was weakened because most of the infant indusfulfilled their purpose in the meantime. (See F. W. Taussig, The Tariff
had
[New York,
1922].)
5"3
tendencies of the
tariff policy.
What
irony of fate!
tariff
The
tected industry!
industry of
tariff wall,
also
made more
less
favorable locations
than those parts of the country that depend on exports and have to
make up for their lessened chances of exporting, brought about
through the tariff, by lowering prices. Thus before the Civil War
the cotton industry of the South "was insignificant absolutely, and
declining in addition. After the war and up to the turn of the
century, that is until the protective tariff reached its then highest
point, cotton spinning and weaving mills moved from the North
to the cheaper South at a constantly increasing rate.* From 1850 to
7.
is
But this artificial proby freight rates was less than the tariff protection.
8. In 1859 the average wage of the industrial worker in the South was only 12 per
cent under the wages in the North, but in 1869 it was 45 per cent below these. (C. Hecr,
freight rates that favor
tection
it,
Examples
P^^i Four.
C04
1860 the share of the states south of Virginia in the total production
of cotton goods had further decreased by 53 per cent; in the decade
1860-1870 it rose by 15 per cent, in the decade 1870-1880 by 36 per
cent, in 1880-1890 by 70 per cent, and in 1890-1900 by nearly 100
per cent. In the following period, up to 1920, the price level in the
South rose in comparison with the North, as we have already seen;
and wages especially increased more in the South than in the North;
the rate of growth of the southern cotton industry fell correspondingly to 35 per cent between 1900 and 1910 and to 34 per cent
from 1910 to 1920. After World War I there were fresh orgies of
the South became cheaper, and
tariff protection (1922 and 1930)
the rate of growth jumped back again to 41 per cent between 1920
,
and 1930.
This interpretation is strengthened by the development of wages
and cost of living. If the 1901 level is set at 100, the wages of cotton
workers in 1920-21 ^ at 335, were higher than those of industrial
workers, at 315." From 1922 onward they dropped below these
until, in 1932-33, the levels were 106 and 245 respectively. Thereafter they rose again more sharply (up to 1934-35 by 18 per cent
At the end of 1920 living costs in
as compared with 13 per cent)
five cities of the Northeast whose records go back furthest (Boston,
Portland, Buffalo, New York, Philadelphia) were 95 per cent above
the level of December, 1914, and in five southern cities (Jacksonville,
Norfolk, Sanvannah, Mobile, Houston) 98 per cent. Conversely, in
.
middle of 1933 to the end of 1936 duties fell again, and living costs
in the South went up by 11.7 per cent and in the Northeast by only
9.1
per cent."
The
difference
is less
for
labor than
for unskilled.
9.
L.
U.
11.
Calculated from U.
S.
Statistics
(U.
S.
Department
p. 95.
(Washington)
S.
Bureau
of
Labor
it
is
Statistics,
Changes
in Costs of
Living
b.
On
505
bank credits (cusYork was 6.08 per cent; in eight other cities
of the Northeast, 6.25 per cent; and in twenty-seven western or
southern cities, 6.29 per cent. From November, 1927, up to the
date mentioned it rose by 1.73, 1.43, and 0.73 per cent, and then
fell until the end of September, 1931, by 2.15, 1.77, and 0.97 per
cent. These figures are typical. Tlie cyclical fluctuations are regularly greatest in New York, the chief financial center, and least in
October
tomers' rate) in
30,
New
The
result, as
is
boom and
roborates
The
end
of a
this.
The
bank
credits
1:
5.88
5.19
5.15
4.69
4.67
4.60
4.53
4.49
4.47
4.22
4.02
3.33
2.70
2:
0.26
0.75
0.55
1.03
0.94
1.11
1.07
1.13
1.11
1.17
1.54
1.84
1.99
in
to
New
Row
magnitude.
row
shows by
how much
according
financial
West.i3
The
on
is
simple: the
rely
be the rates; the tighter the reserve position of banks throughout the rest of the country becomes, the more reserves and surplus
liquid funds must they withdraw from New York. In times of
plentiful money New York absorbs these excess liquid funds from
will
the
tariff
of attributing
all
is
But
this.
do not wish
The most
me
rather to be
its
its
its
prices, contrary to the ruling opinion, are especially flexible precisely because of
if
high
inward migratons thus again in central markets. (G. Pavlovsky, " Zur
Frage der raumlichen Ordnung der Landwirtschaft," Internationale Landwirtschaftliche Rundschau, Vol. I, No. 33 [1942], p. 357.)
in regions of
13.
Annual Report
years).
Examples
Part Four.
f-oQ
frequently.
The same thing is true of the discount rate of the Reserve Banks.
In July, 1928, for example, when the most frequent rate was 5 per
cent, the regional spread amounted to but 0.5 per cent. By May,
1931, the most frequent rate had fallen to 3 per cent, and at the
same time the regional spread had gradually risen to 2 per cent.
Nevertheless, and especially after what we have said about the slight
connection between American discount rates and market rates, it is
pertinent to ask whether they really play the same role as the discount rates of European central banks, say, in facilitating transfers.
To anticipate: Despite the similarity in technical function between the Federal Reserve Banks and the European central banks,
disturbances in the balances of payements between Federal Reserve
districts in the United States are more easily overcome than corresponding disturbances between the countries of Europe. The causes
lie partly in the political unity of the United States, and partly in
its special history. Its enormous gold holdings, which it owes to its
position as creditor nation, to
of gold sterilization (and thus,
minimize the
its
protective
among
effect of international
tariff,
and
to
its
policy
payments on American
prices)
exceed the
lesj-al
minimum,
between them
at first at the
14.
Fund
Generally no gold
is
made
unneces-
same way and, finally, expensive hoards of monetary gold could be abolished
and replaced by credits in an international clearing house, such as London was before
World War I. (A. Losch, " Verrechnung und Goldwiihrung ein Vergleich," Die
Bank, August 21, 1940.) The gold points would thereupon coincide and there would
be practically no further scope for fluctuations in the rate of exchange, just as today
the price for payments between any given place in the United States is the same.
sary in the
507
movements
(that
is,
in
its
still
favor,
so to speak,
avoid
dominant bank of
It is
district-wide price
15.
movements.
December
23, 1913.
5o8
Part Four.
Epilogue.^
On
Examples
Space
familiar with not more than its innermost circle. Depth must be
bought with narrowness. Space creates and protects us in this limitation. Particularity is the price of our existence.
To let this space-conditioned particularity grow without letting
the whole run wild that is political art. For me one of the happiest
results of my study is to be able to show for the spatial organization
of the economy that the free initiative of normal men produces
results that in general are wholly desirable, politically as well as
economically, provided only that man can build on rational conditions. Because the powerful forces of spontaneity, if rightly guided,
are an ally to national economic policy, this is saved the superhuman
task of planning everything down to the very last detail. The mighty
1.
He who
all,
than
set
down
Subject Index
1
.:
Table
n.:
footnote
Aarhus, 269n.
Barcelona, 493
Basel, 449
"
Agglomerations,
343n.;
areal,
6,
10,
lOff.,
90;
15,
149n.,
chance,
77;
164,
dis-
and economic
discrimination on,
wheat
belt, 386,
425
Bermuda, 481
of, 380f.
Besatzziffern.
Albania, 430T.
Algeria, 430n.
Black
Texas
494
s. a.,
392
Boundaries,
German-Polish,
13, 384;
Canadian-American,
384f.,
Arkansas, 374n.
Athens, 441n.
ments
450f.;
446f.;
13,
Ger-
168; pay-
prices
at,
market
between
251;
and
Austria, 430T.
twin
Autarky, 323f.
Boundary region,
Autobahnen, 183n.
width
136f.,
of, 207f.
181, 448;
424
Breslau, 216n.
Bank
Bank
clearing, 126
British
509
Honduras, 423T.
demand
competition
153n.
names
b.
Appalachians, 35n.
Arbeitswissenschaftliches Institut,
Bolivia, 423T.
Australia,
179,
85ff.,
ports,
in,
The Economics
of Location
British
West
Africa, 423T.
British
West
Colonization, 330
Budapest, 187n.
Colorado, 481
504
Bulgaria, 429, 430T., 477n.
and
322f.;
wars, 209;
capitals,
transfer
to
large
transfer through
applicable
economic
areas,
339;
spatial
tries
232-236;
wheat
market,
421T.,
xiv, 480;
Cannstadt, 354
470;
321,
(exports,
formation
Eastern
in
and
Cardiff, 416n.
Germany,
US,
international,
126,
134,
on
216n.,
342,
350,
354, 354n.
transfer,
276f.;
Customs unions,
340f.; possible
American-
Canadian, 385f.
Chemnitz, 444
11,
494;
Cotton, gins,
504;
Chicago,
492f.,
493,
sites,
490ff.,
Carpathians, 258
Central
295.
imports,
Western United
4I6f., 424n.
movements
coun-
occupation,
many
Corn market,
flow)
of
applied to
Capital
impedi-
327f.
of factors, 310
choice
to
and formation
275;
Canada,
312;
of
problem,
new combinations,
"
economic
with
ments
82,
166n.,
354,
37 In.,
378,
Dakotas,
374n.
Danzig, 451
Chile, 423T., 454n.
11,
424n.,
379,
477;
380,
501
380n.,
attraction
of,
386n.,
83,
403n.,
90,
258,
Colombia, 423T.
Colonial policy, 193n.
westward movement
of,
496ff.
Discount
Distance,
importance
underestimated,
Subject Index
bank
of
401n.;
396f.,
from
locations
District,
Exchange
182, 372
12,
Exchange
Chicago, 412
Division of labor, 223f., 264, 265
importance of
Expenditures,
Export industries,
Duluth, 257n.
Extra-economic
Dumping,
157f., 163n.,
234
375,
325,
136, 204,
each
toward
and
square, 134;
states,
other,
135f.;
196-210
8,
of,
168f.,
in
with
theory
434f.;
of,
lOlff.
vs.
Deposit
Insurance
Corporation,
464, 465n.
European
415f.,
compared
differentials,
461f.;
of Kansas City,
regional,
143f.;
and
size
300;
volume of
of
local
of region,
141f.;
in,
and
difficul;,
substitute
Egypt, 423T.
geographic
316,
328f.,
of,
of
416, of St.
dustrial
international mi-
305f.,
prevention
309f.,
est
Ecuador, 423T.
Elasticity:
251,
of,
gration
Federal
173,
premiums, 301n.
252f.;
Factors of production:
relation
269,
35, 302f.
205, 448;
local,
traffic
with
tance, 428ff.
258,
283n.,
403n.,
429n.,
430T.,
Electrification, 379
tion
of
England,
424n.,
339n.,
337,
430T.,
444,
of
wheat
imports
of,
423T.
location
of,
244-245,
248;
and
loca-
tion,
Free entry,
330
Comparative
toms unions
Freight
396n.;
72ff.,
83n.;
293f.;
goods,
Cus-
334,
and agglomeration,
rates,
170-178,
graduated,
171-
discriminatory
different
lowest, 260;
River, 416
Estonia, 430T.
depreciation,
for
cost,
cost. Tariffs,
in
Exchange
source
260
8,
see also
Freight
Entrepreneur,
367n.;
403n.;
of sugar refineries,
Freystadt, 446
American
Cialveston, 425
The Economics
Gateways,
ISSn.,
187n.,
187,
189n.,
191,
Institut
400,
416,
422,
426n.,
number
428,
427,
of medieval
cities,
43 If.,
Gold
problem
Gold
484
et Sociales,
and
movements,
capital
305f.;
Gibraltar, 423T.
standard,
Recherches Eco-
Scientifique de
nomiques
trade, 337f.
16ff.
Gold
and foreign
of, 445f.
Georg-Weierbach, 381
397,
Industrialization
251, 447
Germany,
of Location
318f.;
see
also
Transfer
506
for,
within Texas,
464f.; of state
movement
468f.;
in
466f.;
and
reasons
space, 505f.
324f.;
compulsory,
334f.;
into
transfer
process, 316f.
Ground
rent, 247f.,
259n.
Inheritance, division of land through, 65n.
Guatemala, 423T.
Institut fiir Weltwirtschaft, xiv
Maschinengenossenschaft,
International
400,
criticized,
402n.
trade:
and
interpersonal
312f.;
theory
and
Haiti, 423T.
Heidenheim, 455n.
business
Heilbronn, 454
cycles
in,
496f.;
Hennigsdorf, 379
Hohenstauffen, 342n.
Isochrons, 443
Hong Kong,
Isostants
420n.
= lines
of
minimum
transport
cost, 28n.
Isovectures, 19, 20
Italy, 258n., 423T.,
430T.
Iceland, 430T.
371n.;
Illinois,
Import premiiyiis,
man)
Jacksonville, 504
Jamaica, 423T.
426n.
Japan, 423T.
Joint production in agriculture, 60
India, 420n.
392
Indianapolis, 125, 371n., 438, 439
Indifference curves, 225
Indo-China, 430n.
Kamenz, 403n.
Kansas, 414n., 425, 458, 479
Subject Index
513
Kentucky, 371n.
Land grabbing,
348
339f.
names
See
Latin America.
of individual
countries
481;
Germany,
in
Latvia, 430T.
"Law
sizes
and
110,
182, 248;
Lithuania, 430T.
in
US,
395ff.,
Littoria, 442
420fr.;
Locations
banks,
36.5f.,
fairs,
315ff., 346f.
(actual)
365f.,
370;
distribution,
distribution,
37 In.;
consumer,
to
close
367, 403n.;
366,
regular
even
4l7ff.;
371;
of
of farms, 374ff.;
irregular
365f.;
8,
agricultural,
36ff.;
interdependence of
256;
all
loca-
343;
influence
nature,
of
33n.,
256f.;
98f.; at
of ports,
121f.;
188;
center
sticki-
shift of location to
historic
forces,
256,
changes in pattern,
386,
Mecklenburg,
63f.,
wheat,
259
Maximum
420r.;
(theory)
for
oil,
of, 124ff.
Locations
tung
automobile,
377;
for
system
Location policy,
shape
355n., 417;
133f.,
of,
Liverpool, 426
of,
square,
211ft.;
Leipzig, 82
130f.;
128,
networks
408f.;
109ff.;
Leeds, 218n.
401,
259,
330,
352n.
Middle West.
See
Minneapolis-St.
Paul,
218n.,
385,
403n.,
Minnesota, 439n.
Mississippi, 374, 416
392
Mittelgebirge, 258
Mortgage
credit, 402n.
Motorization, effects
siderations, 344
Mountain
individual
of
435T.n.
Location triangle, 18
names
states
States,
of,
183n.
412
Munich,
Nationalization, 332n.
Luxemburg, 430T.
New
New
Maggi, 384
Manitoba, 386
415,
416,
416n.,
425,
427n.
New
81, 82,
330
The Economics
514
New
Zealand, 423T.
Niagara
Falls,
Ontario, 387
Nicaragua, 423T.
Nordhorn, 453
between
bution
diflBculty of
Nova
Scotia, 386
260,
NRA,
460, 460n.
403;
115f.;
location
236-240;
(Besatzziffern)
distribution
408
of towns,
392
179;
311,
209;
375;
irregular
density
180n.,
of.
485n.
cycles, viii,
of a declining population,
effects
viii
Open market
US.
176n.;
Omaha, 435T.n.
Orient, 407n.
17,
261;
23,
minimum
by gross receipts,
27ff.;
transport
mechanical model,
23;
by
18,
profits,
technical,
locations, 32f.;
US
(actual)
Prices
426,
449,
shifts
products,
of
501f.;
in,
spatial
US and
129n.;
in-
369T., 473n.
333;
180n.,
of
188,
land,
253f.;
lowest
tions.
265f..
price
282;
waves.
267ff.;
16,
with credit
Petroleum, 424n.
prices
296
in
creation.
the large
movements.
and
in
Pianos. 416
uniform
270f.;
changes of
277;
delivered
Pennsylvania, 378
Peru, 423T.
spatial
Location of Industry,
at
434f.
Report on
295.
Paraguay, 423T.
(Political
movement
US
regional differences
476ff.;
Palmanova, 441n.
Panama, 423T.
Panama
regional
PEP
distribution,
257n., 258n.,
in,
in
and passim.
Oklahoma, 425
Paris,
increase
of
optimum
115n.;
agriculture
of
350;
effect
women's, 237n.
240ff.;
settlement,
scattered
of,
Occupation indices
226f[.;
to, 226;
cost, 229f.;
432, 436
Occupations, choice
occupations,
marginal approach
size,
of,
of, 99,
Norfolk, 504
Nuremberg,
of Location
f.
the small.
o.
Subject Index
159.;
515
uniform
c.
price,
i. .
140;
price
189n.;
com-
500T.
discrimination, 147-159
Product differentiation,
168f.,
cost,
397f.
Shanghai, 420T.
differences,
spatial
211;
Silesia, 426n.,
Situation
456
from orientation)
distinct
(as
33
Reaction.
Refraction,
law of
184f.;
limitation
of,
individual countries
^
186
Regensburg, 438n.
Regionalism, 504n.
Springfield,
346ff.
of
supply,
produc-
9,
455;
505
498
Substitution equilibrium,
Suchard, 384
Sudan, 423T.
Retail sales,
354
Reparations, 266
Reserve ratio,
111.,
20f.,
24n., 29n.
Rhode
Ribbon Development
Richmond, 412n., 461
Risks,
212,
402n.,
Act, 444n.
469ff.;
and
distance,
Rothenburg, 333n.
Rubber, 424n.
Ruhr, 21, 218, 258, 333n., 373T., 379n.,
424n., 498
district,
300,
386;
201, 206,
41 In.,
Canadian,
384,
and regional
386;
infant
on market
American, 202,
501;
area,
St.
322,
300f.,
Saar
200n.,
Tariffs,
426n.
406,
distribution
496;
of
towns,
392, 393
Thomas
Thunen
process, 379
rings,
ix,
13,
14,
51,
62n.,
380;
conditions for
boundary between,
emergence,
Savannah, 504
ample,
Scrap, 379
40ff.;
46ff.;
44ff.;
milk-cream-butter ex-
applied
to
production
52ff.; effect
5i6
The Economics
Time
212, 257n,
costs,
Bureau of Mines,
Agriculture,
National
395;
210n., 493
Towns: formation
of,
178,
of,
as
389f.;
the
390f.; attraction of
246n., 406;
15,
179;
68ff.,
size
function of distance,
function
more
of,
gifted into,
126,
178, 275,
43 Iff.; size of
Canadian,
344n., 386
flag,"
336
291f.
316f.,
276-278,
transfer,
279,
282,
with
reaction
299;
transfer,
and terms
speed
282-
187ff.,
Wage
differentials,
240-244,
243n.,
Wages,
19, 182
efficiency
piece
wages,
237n.,
239,
309;
real
493
inelastic
Unemployed, 239
States, 283n., 364; agricultural sub-
456ff.;
see
also
and towns
Bureau of the
wheat
names
190, 420ff.
SOI
385,
Census,
xiv, 295n.;
388,
499T.,
Wisconsin, 354n.
Wurttemberg,
WiJrzburg, 438n.
Yugoslavia, 430T.
387,
SOOT.
Wyoming, 425
of individual states
Bureau of Labor
in-
Warthegau, 456
States:
334,
Ukraine, 258
United
170n.,
326n.,
wages correspond to
423T.;
99n.,
309f.,
Turkey, 423T.
421ff.,
499T.,
Westphalia, 393n.
exports,
43n.,
25,
306,
Troy, N.Y., 11
wage
498,
384
395ff.;
493n.,
tion, 356ff.;
326n.,
United
450n.
187
Transport surface,
Administration,
wages, 305
427f.
Transport points,
276f.,
of,
of trade, 285
285;
279,
Committee, 306n.,
Progress
Villiger,
of
454;
Venezuela, 423T.
506f.;
376n.,
demand compared
"
Department
374n.,
Resources
Works
Upper
xiv;
295n.,
of Location
Name
T.:
Aereboe,
F.,
Table
Index
n.:
89
footnote
W.,
Christaller,
xiv,
104n.,
114n.,
115n.,
409,
440n.;
431ff.,
criticism
of
system,
433
Baker, O.
E.,
376n.
Cournot,
(Ottawa)
Baumgartner, 451n.
v.,
208n.
Deasy, 420T.
Decken, H.
Dennison,
Bohm,
25n.
Earhart, 472
W.
415T.
A., 406n.,
Economist, The
Brinkmann, C, 104n.
Brinkmann, T., 60n.,
Edwards,
Bromell,
(London)
498
A., xiv
Eggers, 21n.
85n., 89
Eikstedt, E.
R., 409
J.
403n.
E.,
Bowers,
Doxiades, 441 n.
Bohnert, 348n.
v.,
380n.
d.,
Boggs-Bowman, 45 In.
Bortkiewicz, L.
S.
Dickinson, R.
332n.
F.,
v.
J.
132n., 133n.
Dannenbauer, 342n.
Dean. W. H., 29n.
Beaver, 218n.
Beckerath, H.
70, 272n.
Culemann, C,
xiv
H.
v.,
213n., 246n.
Ellis,
Buchman,
S.,
322n.
Englander, O.,
Bulow,
F.,
349n.
Eucken, W.,
Bums, A.
Evans, xiv
R., 164n.
8,
45n., 46
Caldwell,
Carr. G.
S.
J.,
A., 416n.
424n.
Cauchon, 443n.
Chamberlin, E. H.,
74,
108n.,
109n.,
112n..
120n.,
205n.,
340n.
57
The Economics
5i8
Florence, P.
369T.
S.,
Isenberg,
195n.,
xvii,
269n.
218n.,
Friedrich, C.
G.,
of Location
C, 223n.
Iversen,
18n.
J.,
Garey, L.
F.,
481n.
Garver, xiv
Jefferson, M., 392, 393n., 394
Gillman, 90
Kann,
Goodrich,
Kapferer-Schwenzner, 428n.
C.,
216n.
Haase, A., 85
Haberler, G.
346n., 348n.
F.,
xiv,
v.,
Keynes,
M.,
J.
S.,
S.
107n.,
E., 294n.,
Hartsough, M.
L.,
Kuhne,
468n.
G., 403n,
Kulmer,
218n.
Hartung, 446n.
A., 426n.
Lane,
Launhardt,
Heberle, 174n.
C.,
J. J.,
461n.
W.,
503n.
Lehmann-Lenoir,
Lenschow, 171n.,
Heiser, 346n.
Leontief,
Herberts,
J.
List,
Herrenberg, 400
P.,
F.,
9,
18,
F.,
W. W.,
Friedrich,
31
336n., 355n.
ix,
xiv,
17n., 51n.,
141n.,
Lowe, 490
Lubin,
L., xiv
6, 72ff.,
162
International Magazine
^x
J.,
380n.
A., 355n.
W.
198n.
H.
76,
461n.
Horn, Charles
lOOn.
195n., 454
Hinrichs, A.
7,
Isard,
104n.,
Koster, xvii
379n., 473n.
Hansen, Alvin,
Harris,
331n.
J.,
Hall, F.
Innis,
315n.
130n.
R.,
Haring,
Hesse,
308n.,
Hapke,
Heer,
251n.,
viii,
491
Company, 396n.
McGregor, xiv
McGuire, C.
E.,
Machlup,
260n.
F.,
xiv
Name
Index
519
120n.,
166n.,
162,
173n.,
183n.,
184n.,
MacPherson, L.
G., 378n.
Paullin, 365n.
Marquardt, H.,
62n., 63n.
Powell, xiv
Mellerowicz, 369n.
Meuriot, M.
Puttkammer, W.,
Meyer,
F.
P.,
438n.
Rath, 402n.
Ratzel, F., 82n.,
K., 35 In.
192n.,
198n., 201n.,
197,
443n.
Meynen, 355n.
Rechenberg,
Miksch,
L., 332n.
Millard,
J.
F.,
W.
J.,
Riefler,
W.,
Rist, Charles,
484n.
Robinson,
Robinson,
J.,
66,
Rohm,
H., 67n.
Rompe,
Muhs, H.,
xvii, 346n.
Meyer,
403n., 490n.
378n.,
495n.
xvii, 346n.
Neue
Neupert, 393n.
New
Schaffle, 41 In.,
Niemeyer, 443n.
496
Odum, H. W.,
504n.
Ohlin,
x,
B.,
ix,
24n.,
Schiller, Friedrich,
103,
104n., 223n.,
Palander, T.,
ix,
18,
19,
Schlier,
22n.,
28n.,
73,
O.,
177n.,
183n.,
218n.,
258n.,
The Economics
520
Thiinen,
45,
173n.
J.,
H.
J.
Schmoller, G.
104n.
v.,
Triggs, H.
Schneefuss, 187n.
92n.,
62n.,
E.,
5,
7,
9,
8,
104n.,
130,
13,
36,
133n.,
Schneider,
ix,
v.,
of Location
107n.,
108n.,
Turner,
443n.
J.,
F. J., 355n.
Uebler, 440n.
Schumacher, H.,
Schumann, H.
Schumpeter,
ix,
xiv,
J.,
380n.
A.,
J.
380n., 501n.
J.,
Umlauf,
21, 379n.
J. v.,
Uhlig,
64n., 237n.
Vance, R.
504n.
B.,
Viner,
Schwenkel, 352n.
108n.
J.,
Wagemann,
Siebrecht, 402n.
H. W.,
Singer,
Walras,
150n., 434f.
414
Spengler,
xiv, 335
J. J.,
Spiethoff,
Arthur,
ix,
xiv,
343n.,
358n.
Stackelberg, H.
v.,
18,
164n.,
19,
24,
20,
179n.,
186,
382, 383
Stamp, 218n.
Steinbeis, F.
v.,
Wilcox,
Stewart, xiv
Stewart, Mrs.
G.
S.,
J.,
Winkler,
195n.,
W., 182n.
W.
E.,
F.,
396
130n.
S.
Williamson,
xiv
195n.
xvii, 453n.
Swabia,
9.
453n.
Stigler,
5,
92n.,
Weh, Max,
198n., 202n.
Sombart, W.,
163n., 226
ix,
29,
ix, x, 92,
Weber, Alfred,
Solch,
H., 381n.
Wright, 365n.
196, 492
Young, xiv
Taussig, F. W., xiv, 502n.
v.,
5 In.
Zapoleon, L.
B.,
242n.,
427n.,
478,
479,
490n., 501n.
Zeuthen, 120n.
223, 416n.
Date
Returned
Due
FEB 2 4
tQ<
^FEI^feiaafe
.^lA.
Due
Due
Returned
UI^IVERSITY OF FLORIDA
lEbE DM3TEEflS