BA Economics Mathematical Economics and Econometry PDF
BA Economics Mathematical Economics and Econometry PDF
BA Economics Mathematical Economics and Econometry PDF
ECONOMETRICS
VI SEMESTER
CORE COURSE
BA ECONOMICS
(2011 Admission)
UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT
SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION
Calicut university P.O, Malappuram Kerala, India 673 635.
271
UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT
SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION
STUDY MATERIAL
Core Course
BA ECONOMICS
VI Semester
Scrutinized by:
Layout:
Module I & II
Module III
Sri.Sajeev. U,
Assistant professor,
Department of Economics,
Government College, Malappuram.
Module IV & V
Reserved
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
CONTENTS
PAGE No
MODULE I
MODULE II
39
MODULE III
MARKET EQUILIBRIUM
66
MODULE IV
82
MODULE V
94
4th
MODULE 1
INTRODUCTION TO MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS
A definitional equation set up an identity between two alternate expressions that have
exactly the same meaning. For such an equation, the identical- equality sign read; is
identically equal to is often employed in place of the regular equal sign =, although the
latter is also acceptable. As an example, total profit is defined as the excess of total revenue
over total cost; we can therefore write,
=RC
A behavioral equation specifies the manner in which a variable behaves in response to
changes in other variables. This may involve either human behavior (such as the aggregate
consumption pattern in relation to national income) or non human behavior (such as how
total cost of a firm reacts to output changes.
Broadly defined, behavioral equations can be used to describe the general institutional
setting of a model, including the technological (eg: production function) and legal (eg: tax
structure aspects).
Consider the two cost function
C = 75 + 10Q (1)
C = 110 + Q2 .... (2)
Since the two equations have different forms, the production condition assumed in
each is obviously different from the others.
In equation (1), the fixed cost (the value of C when Q = 0) is 75, where as in (2), it is
110. The variation in cost is also different in (1), for each unit increases in Q, there are a
constant increase of 10 in C. but in (2), as Q increase unit often unit, C will increase by
progressively larger amounts.
A Conditional equation states a requirement to be satisfied, for example, in a model
involving the notion of equilibrium, we must up an equilibrium condition, which describe
the prerequisite for the attainment of equilibrium. Two of the most familiar equilibrium
conditions in Economics is:
Qd = Qs
(Quantity demanded equal to quantity supplied)
S=I
(Intended saving equal to intended investment)
Which pertain respectively, to the equilibrium of a market model and the equilibrium of the
national income model in its simplest form?
10
=f(
, Y, T, W, E)
For example, the consumers ability and willingness to buy 4 ice creams at the price of Rs. 1
per ice-cream is an instance of quantity demanded. Whereas the ability and willingness of
consumer to buy 4 ice creams at Rs. 1, 3 ice creams at Rs. 2 and 2 ice creams at Rs. 3 per ice-cream
is an instance of demand.
Example: Given the following demand function
= 720 25P
1.9 Supply function
Supply function express the relationship between the price of the commodity (independent
variable) and quantity of the commodity supplied (dependent variable).It indicate how much
quantity of a commodity that the seller offers at the different prices. Hence,
represent the
quantity supplied of a commodity and
is the price of that commodity. Then,
Supply function
=f(
11
P, I, T,
, E,
12
income will be accounted for by the sum of the increase in consumption expenditure and the
increase in personal saving. This law is known as propensity to consume or consumption function.
Keynes contention is that consumption expenditure is a function of absolute current income, ie:
C = f (Yt)
The linear consumption function can be expressed as:
C = C0+ b
Where, C0 is the autonomous consumption, b is the marginal propensity to consume and Yd
is the level of income.
Given the consumption function C = 40 + .80Yd, autonomous consumption function is 40
and marginal propensity to consume is 0.80.
1.12 Production function
Production function is a transformation of physical inputs in to physical out puts. The
output is thus a function of inputs. The functional relationship between physical inputs and physical
output of a firm is known as production function. Algebraically, production function can be written
as:
Q = f (a,b,c,d,..)
Where, Q stands for the quantity of output, a,b,c,d, etc; stands for the quantitative factors.
This function shows that the quantity (q) of output produced depends upon the quantities, a, b, c, d
of the factors A, B, C, D respectively.
The general mathematical form of Production function is:
Q = f (L,K,R,S,v,e)
Where Q stands for the quantity of output, L is the labour, K is capital, R is raw material, S
is the Land, v is the return to scale and e is efficiency parameters.
Example: Suppose the production function of a firm is given by:
Q = 0.6X +0.2 Y
Where, Q = Output, X and Y are inputs.
1.13 Cost Function
Cost function derived functions. They are derived from production function, which
describe the available efficient methods of production at any one time. Economic theory
distinguishes between short run costs and long run costs. Short run costs are the costs over a period
during which some factors of production (usually capital equipments and management) are fixed.
The long run costs over a period long enough to permit the change of all factors of production. In
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
13
the long run all factors become variable. If x is the quantity produced by a firm at a total cost C, we
write for cost function as:
C = f (x)
It means that cost depends upon the quantity produced.
Example:
- 12 + 2x
MC =
= -12 + 4x
1.14 Revenue Function
If R is the total revenue of a firm, X is the quantity demanded or sold and P is the price per
unit of output, we write the revenue function. Revenue function expresses revenue earned as a
function of the price of good and quantity of goods sold. The revenue function is usually taken to
be linear.
R=PX
Where R = revenue, P = price, X = quantity
If there are n products and P1, P2..Pn are the prices and X1, X2Xn units of these
products are sold then
R = P1X1+P2X2 ++PnXn
Eg:
TR = 100 5Q
14
TR = 300Q 5Q
TC = 40Q + 200Q +200, find profit
Profit = TR TC
= 300Q 5Q- 40Q - 200Q -200
= 100Q +9Q - 200
),
15
Or
MU =
Example: Given the total utility function
U = 9xy + 5x + y
=
=
= 9y + 5
= 9x + 1
MPC =
16
Suppose, when income increases from Rs. 100 to Rs. 110, same time consumption
increases from Rs. 75 to Rs. 80. Then the increment in income is Rs.10 and increment in
consumption is Rs. 5. Thus,
MPC =
= 5/10
=.5
Example: Suppose the consumption function is
C = 24 + .8 Y, find MPC
MPC =
= .8
1.21 Marginal Propensity to Save
Marginal propensity to save is the amount by which saving changes in response to an
incremental change in disposable income. In other words, Marginal propensity to save shows the
how much of the additional income is devoted to saving. It measures the change in saving due to a
change in income of the consumer. So the MPS is measure the ratio of change in saving due to
change in income.MPS is the slope of the saving line. Mathematically MPS is the first derivative of
the consumption function.
MPS =
Suppose, when income increases from Rs. 150 to Rs. 200, same time saving increases
from Rs. 50 to Rs. 80. Then the increment in income is Rs.50 and increment in saving is Rs. 80.
Thus,
MPC =
= 30/50
= 0.6
Example: Suppose the saving function is,
S = 50 + .6 Y, find MPS
MPS =
= .6
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
17
Suppose the production of 5 units of a product involve the total cost of Rs.206. If the
increase in production to 6 units raises the total cost to Rs. 236, the marginal cost of the 6th unit of
output is Rs. 30.(236 206 = 30 )
Hence marginal cost is a change in total cost as a result of a unit change in output, it can
also be written as:
MC =
Where TC represents a change in total cost and Q represents a small change in output.
Example: Given the total cost function
TC = a + bQ +cQ + dQ, Find the marginal cost.
MC =
= b + 2cQ +3dQ
Example: TC = X - 3 XY - Y
MC =
= 2X 3 Y
MC =
= 3Y 2Y
1.24 Marginal Revenue
Marginal Revenue is the net revenue earned by selling an additional unit of the product. In
other words, marginal revenue is the addition made to the total revenue by selling one more unit of
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
18
the good. Putting it in algebraic expression, marginal revenue is the addition made to total revenue
by selling n units of a product instead of n-1 units where n is any given number.
If a producer sells 10 units of a product at price Rs.15 per unit, he will get Rs.150 as the total
revenue. If he now increases his sales of the product by one unit and sells 11 units, suppose the
price falls to Rs. 14 per unit. He will therefore obtain total revenue of Rs.154 from the sale if 11
units of the good. This means that 11th unit of output has added Rs.4 to the total revenue. Hence
Rs. 4 is here the Marginal revenue.
MR =
Where, TR stands for change in total revenue and Q stands for change in output.
Example: TR = 50Q 4Q, Find MR
MR =
= 50 -8Q
1.25 Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
The Concept of marginal rate of substitution is an important tool of indifferent curve
analysis of demand. The rate at which the consumer is prepared to exchange goods X and Y is
known as marginal rate of substitution. Thus, the MRS of X for Y as the amount of Y whose loss
can just be compensated by a unit gain in X. In other words MRS of X for Y represents the amount
of Y which the consumer has to give up for the gain of one additional unit of X, so that his level of
satisfaction remains the same.
Given the table, when the consumer moves from combination B to combination C, on his
indifference schedule he forgoes 3 units of Y for the additional one unit gain in X. Hence, the MRS
of X for Y is 3.
Likewise, when the consumer moves from C to D, and then from D to E in indifference
schedule, the MRS of X for Y is 2 and 1 respectively.
Table1.1 Calculating MRS
Combination
Good X
Good Y
12
4:1
3:1
2:1
1:1
MRS x y
19
In mathematical that MRS x y between goods is equal to the ratio of marginal utilities of
good X and Y.
An indifference curve can be represented by:
U (x, y) = a
Where, a represent constant utility along an indifference curve. Taking total differential of
the above, we have
dx +
dy = 0
-
and
goods.
Example: Find
20
Example: Find
, U = 8x + 4y
=
=8
=
=4
=
=
=2
Units of
Labour
Units of
Capital
MRTS of
L for K
12
Each of the inputs combinations A, B, C, D and E yield the same level of output. Moving
down the table from combination A to combination B, 4 units of Capital are replaced by 1 unit of
Labour in the production process without any change in the level of output. Therefore MRTS of
labour for capital is 4 at this stage. Switching from input combination B to input combination C
involves the replacement of 3 units of capital by an additional unit of labour, output remaining the
same. Thus, the MRTS is now 3. Likewise, MRTS of labour for capital between factor combination
D and E if 1.
21
The MRTS at a point on an isoquant (an equal product curve) can be known from the slope
of the isoquant at the point. The slope of the isoquant at a point and hence the MRTS between
factors drawn on the isoquant at that point.
An important point to the noted above the MRTS is that it is equal to the ratio of the
marginal physical product of the two factors. Therefore, that MRTS is also equal to the negative
slope of the isoquant.
MRTS =
Cancel
and
=
=
So the MRTS of labour for capital is the ratio of the marginal physical products of the two
factors.
Example: The following production function is given below:
Q = L 0.75 K 0.25
Find the MRTS L K
MRTS =
=
=
= 0.75
= 0.75
= 0.75
22
=
= 0.25
= 0.25
= 0.25
MRTS =
=
/ 0.25
=3
= 3.
= 3.
= 3. (
/
/ )
=3
1.27 Relationship between Average Revenue, Marginal Revenue
An important relationship between MR, AR (price) and price elasticity of demand which is
extensively used in making price decisions by firms. This relationship can be proved algebraically
also.
MR = P (1 - )
Where P = Price and e = point elasticity of demand.
MR is defined as the first derivative of total revenue (TR).
Thus,
MR =
(1)
Now, TR is the product price and Q is the quantity of the product sold
(TR =P Q),
Thus,
MR =
23
+Q
=P+Q
(2)
)..(3)
demand.
(
). Thus
=
. (4)
MR = AR (1 - )
= AR (
Or
AR = MR
24
25
=-
For an accurate measure of elasticity of supply at mid point method may be used
Es = q q/q+q/2 pp/p +p/2
q q =q
p p =p
Therefore,
Es = q/q1 + q2 p1 + p2/p
= q/p p + p/q +q
The elasticity of supply depends upon the ease with which the output of an industry can be
expanded and the changes in marginal cost of production. Since there is greater scope for increase
in output in the long run than in the short run, the supply of a good is more elastic in the long run
than in the short run.
Example: Find the elasticity of supply when price 5 units. Supply function is given by
q =25 -4p+p
q =25 4p +p
= p/q = -4 + 2p
Price elasticity of supply = -p/q p/q
= -p/25 4p +p (-4 + 2p)
= 4p 2p/25 4p + p
Elasticity when P = 5 is 4 5 2(5)/25 4p + 5
= 20 50/ 25 20 +25
= -30/30 = -1
= -1 = 1 (numerically)
Ie, Elasticity is unit at P = 5
26
Example: When the price of refrigerator rises from Rs.2000 per unit to Rs. 2500 per unit and in
response to this rise is price the quantity supplied increases from 2500 units to 3500 units, find out
the price elasticity of supply.
(Hint: Since the change in price is quite large, midpoint method should be used to measure
elasticity of supply)
q = 3500 2500 = 1000
q + q/2 = 3500 + 2500/2
= 3000
p = 2500 2000
= 500
p + p / 2 = 2500 + 2000 / 2
= 2250
Es: 1000/3000 500/2250
1000/3000 2250/500
= 1/3 4.5/ 1
= 4.5/3
= 1.5
1.32 Price Elasticity
Price elasticity of demand express the response of quantity demanded of a good to change in
its price, given the consumers income, his tastes and prices of all other goods.
Price elasticity means the degree of responsiveness or sensitiveness of quantity demanded of a good
to changes in its prices. In other words, price elasticity of demand is a measure of relative change in
quantity purchased of a good in response to a relative change in its price.
Price elasticity =
Or
=
In symbolic term
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
27
Ep =
=
=-
Where,
Ep stands for price elasticity
q Stands for quantity
P stands for price
stands for change
Price elasticity of demand (Ep) is negative, since the change in quantity demanded is in
opposite direction to the change in price. But for the sake of convenience in understanding to the
change in price, we ignore the negative sign and take in to account only the numerical value of the
elasticity.
Example: Suppose the price of a commodity falls from Rs. 6 to Rs. 4 per unit and due to this
quantity demanded of the commodity increases from 80 units to 120 units. Find the price elasticity
of demand.
Solution: Change in quantity demand (Q - Q)
120 80 = 40
Percentage change in quantity demanded
= Q -Q/ Q +Q/2 100
= 40/200/2100
= 40
Change in price p- p = 4 6
= -2
Percentage change in price p- p/ p+ p/2 100
-2/10/2 100
= -40
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
28
Ei = Q/Q/M/M
= Q/Q M/ M
= Q/M M/Q
Let, M stands for an initial income, M for a small change in income, Q for the initial
quantity purchased. Q for a change in quantity purchased as a result of a change in income and Ei
for income elasticity of demand.
Midpoint formula for measuring income elasticity of demand when changes in income are
quite large can be written as.
Ei
29
Example: If a consumer daily income rises from Rs. 300 to Rs.350, his purchase of a good
X increases from 25 units per day to 40 units; find the income elasticity of demand for X?
Change in quantity demand (Q) = Q2 Q1
= 40 25
= 15
Change in income (M)
= M - M
= 350 300
= 50
30
= qx/qx py/py
=qx /py py/qx
Where, Ec stands for cross elasticity of X for Y
qx stands for the original quantity demanded of X
qy stands for changes in quantity demanded of good X
Py stands for original price of good X
py stands for small changes in the price of Y
When change in price is large, we would use midpoint method for estimating cross elasticity
of demand. Note that when we divide percentage change in quantity demanded by percentage
change in price, 100 in both numerator and denominator for cancel out. Therefore, we can write
midpoint formula for measuring cross elasticity of demand as:
Ec
= qx - qx/qx + qx /2 py - py/py + py /2
Example :
If the price of coffee rises from Rs.45 per 250 grams per pack to Rs. 55 per 250
grams per pack and as a result the consumers demand for tea increases from 600 packs to 800 packs
of 250 grams, then the cross elasticity of demand of tea for coffee can be found out as follows.
Hints: we use midpoint method to estimate cross elasticity of demand.
Change in quantity demanded of tea = qt -qt
= 800 600
= 200
Change in price of coffee
pc - pc
= 55 45
= 10
Substituting the values of the various variables in the cross elasticity formula, we have
Cross elasticity of demand
31
In the example of tea and coffee, above, when two goods are substitutes of each other, then
as a result of the rise in price of one good, the quantity demanded of the other good increases.
Therefore, the cross elasticity of demand between the two substitute good is positive, that is, in
response to the rise in price of one good, the demand for the other good rises. Substitute goods are
also known as competing goods. On the other hand, when the two good are complementary with
each other just as bread and butter, tea and milk etc, rise in price of one good bring about the
decrease in the demand for the two complimentary good is negative. Therefore, according to the
classification based on the concept of cross elasticity of demand, good X and good Y are substitute
or complements according as the cross elasticity of demand is positive or negative.
Example: Suppose the following demand function for coffee in terms of price of tea is given. Find
out the cross elasticity of demand when price of tea rises from Rs. 50 per 250 grams pack to Rs. 55
per 250 grams pack.
Q = 100 + 205 Pt
When Q is the quantity demanded of coffee in terms of pack of 250 grams and Pt is the
price of tea per 250 grams pack.
Solution: The +ve sign of the coefficient of Pt shows that rise in price of tea will cause an increase
in quantity demanded of coffee. This implies that tea and coffee are substitutes.
The demand function equation implies that coefficient:
Qc/Pt = 2.5
In order to determine cross elasticity of demand between tea and coffee, we first find out
quantity demanded of coffee when price of tea is Rs.50 per 250 grams. Thus,
Q = 100 + 2.5 50
= 225
Cross elasticity, Ce
= Qc/Pt Pt/Qc
= 2.5 50/225
= 125/225
= 0.51
32
income effect is negative, that is, less is demanded when income raises, Engel curve is backward
bending.
Exercises:
1. If the demand Law is given by q =
q = 20
= - 20
=
When p = 3,
q = 20/4
=5
= - 20/16
= - 5/4
Elasticity of demand
= 5/4 3/5
=
(50 3x)
1=-3
or
= - 1/3
e=
= 5/15 1/3
= 1/9
33
3. The total cost C (x) associated with producing and marketing x units of an item is given by
C(x) = .005 - .02 x - 30x + 3000. Find
(1) Total cost when output is 4 units.
(2) Average cost of output of 10 units.
Solution: (1) Given that C(x) = .005
- .02
30x 4 + 3000
- 10x1
Where x1 and x2 are the quantities of two commodities consumed. Find the optimal utility
value if his income is 116 and product prices are 2 and 8 respectively.
Solution: We have the utility function U =
-4
- 10(58 4x2)
- 580 40x2
=0
= 116x2 - 12
= 3
=3
- 40
- 29
-3
-10 = 0
+
-10 = 0
34
=3
(3
Or
Hence
+ 1)(
- 10) + (
-10) = 0
- 10) = 0
= -1/3 or
= 10
cannot be negative
= 10
= 116 - 24
= 116 240
= -124 < 0 Maxima is confirmed.
= 10,
= 58 40
= 18
= 50x 6x
6. The following production function is given:
Q=
Find the marginal product of labour and marginal product of capital
=
35
=
=
= 0.75
=
=
=
= 0.25
7. The demand function for mutton is:
= 4850 - 5
+ 1.5
+ .1Y
Find the income elasticity of demand and cross elasticity of demand for mutton. Y (income) =
Rs.1000 (price of mutton) = Rs.200, (price of chicken) Rs.100.
Solution: income elasticity =
Income elasticity
=
=
36
=
8. Find the elasticity of supply for supply function x = 2 + 5 when p = 3
Es =
= 4p
=
=
9. The consumption function for an economy is given by c = 50 + .4 y. find MPC and MPS
Here MPC = .4
MPS = 1 MPC
= 1 - .4
= .6
10. For a firm, given that c = 100 + 15x and p = 3 .find profit function
Profit function = TR TC
TR = p x
=3x
= 3x 100 + 15x
= 18x -100
11. The demand function p = 50 3x. Find MR
TR = P X
= (50 3x) x
= 50x 3x
MR =
= 50 6x
37
FURTHER READINGS
1. G.S Monga- Mathematics and Statistics for Economics.
2. D.r. Agarwal- Elementary Mathematics and Statistics for Economists.
3. Chiang A.C and K. Wainwright- fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics.
4. Taro Yamane-Mathematics for Economics.
5. R.G.D Allen- Mathematical Economics.
38
MODULE II
CONSTRAINT OPTIMIZATION, PRODUCTION FUNCTION AND LINEAR
PROGRAMMING
Constraint optimization Methods: Substitution and Lagrange methods- Economic
application: Utility maximization, Cost minimization, Profit Maximization. Production function:
Linear, Homogeneous and Fixed Production Function- Cobb Douglas Production function- Linear
Programming: Meaning, Formulation and Graphical solution.
2.1 Constraint Optimization Methods
The problem of optimization of some quantity subject to certain restrictions or constraint is
a common feature of economics, industry, defense, etc. The usual method of maximizing or
minimizing a function involves constraints in the form if equations. Thus utility may be maximized
subject to the budget constraint of fixed income, given in the form of a equation. The minimization
of cost is a familiar problem to be solved subject to some minimum standards. If the constraints are
in the form of equations, methods of calculus can be useful. But if the constraints are inequalities
instead of equations and we have an objective function to be optimized subject to these inequalities,
we use the method of mathematical programming.
2.2 Substitution Method
Another method of solving the objective function with subject to the constraint is substitution
methods. In this method, substitute the values of x or y, and the substitute this value in the original
problem, differentiate this with x and y.
Consider a utility function of a consumer
U=
+(
. We introduce a new variable called the Lagrange Multiplier and construct the
function.
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
39
Z = f(x1, x2
) + g g(x1, x2
and
and budget constraint 60 = 2x1 + x2.
U=4
F(
, =4
=4
. 1/2
-2
=4
. 1/2
=0
=0
= 60 -2x1 x2 = 0
=
.1/2
.1/2
=
=
=
Or
= 2x2
= x2
2.4 Utility Maximization
There are two approaches to study consumer behavior- the first approach is a classical one
and is known as cardinal utility approach and the second approach is ordinal utility approach
popularly known as indifference curve approach. In both the approaches, we assume that consumer
always behaves in a rational manner, because he derives the maximum utility (satisfaction) out of
his budget constraint.
Example: The utility function of the consumer is given by u =
- 10 where
are
the quantities of two commodities consumed. Find the optimal utility value if his income is 116 and
product prices are 2 and 8 respectively.
Solution: we have utility function
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
40
U = f (x1, x2) = u =
- 10 , and
Budget constraint 116 2x1 - 8x2 = 0 from budget equation we get x1 = 58 4x2
U = (58 4x2)
- 10(58 -4x2)
41
MU2 = 2x2x1
=
=
=
=
Hence maximum utility is obtained when x1 = 18 and x2 = 10
2.5 Cost Minimization
Cost minimization involves how a firm has to produce a given level of output with minimum
cost. Consider a firm that uses labour (L) and capital (K) to produce output (Q). Let W is the price
of labour, that is, wage rate and r is the price of capital and the cost (C) incurred to produce a level
of output is given by
C = wL + rK
The objective of the form is to minimize cost for producing a given level of output. Let the
production function is given by following.
Q = f (L, K)
In general there is several labour capital combinations to produce a given level of output.
Which combination of factors a firm should choose which will minimize its total cost of
production. Thus, the problem of constrained minimization is
Minimize C = wL +rK
Subject to produce a given level of output, say Q1 that satisfies the following production function
Q1 = f (L, K)
The choice of an optimal factor combination can be obtained through using Lagrange method.
Let us first form the Lagrange function is given below
Z = wL +rK + (Q1- f (L, K))
Where
For minimization of cost it necessary that partial derivatives of Z with respect to L, K and
be zero
42
=w
=0
=r
=0
= Q1 - f (L, K) = 0
Note that
and
=0
r-
=0
Q1 = f (L, K)
The last equations shows that total cost is minimized when the factor price ratio
equal the
. (1)
43
= -w + fL = 0. (2)
= - r + fK = 0. (3)
= f (K, L) Q = 0. (4)
From equation (1), we get P =
Substitute this in (2) and (3)
From (2)
w=
Substituting P =
We get
w = PfL .. (5)
Equation (3)
r = PfK (6)
Now in (5)
P = w/fL
w/r = fL/fK
44
Where: Q stands for the quantity of output, L is the labour, K is capital, R is raw material, S
is the Land, v is the return to scale and e is efficiency parameters.
According to G.J. Stigler, the production function is the name given the relationship
between the rates of inputs of productive services and the rates of output of product. It is the
economists summary of technological knowledge. Thus, production function express the
relationship between the quantity of output and the quantity of various input used for the
production. More precisely the production function states the maximum quantity of output that can
be produced from any given quantities of various inputs or in other words, if stands the minimum
quantities of various inputs that are required to yield a given quantities of output.
Production function of the firm may also be derived as the minimum quantities of wood,
varnish, labour time, machine time, floor space, etc; that are required to produce a given number of
table per day.
Knowledge of the production function is a technological or engineering knowledge and is
provided to the form by its engineers or production managers. Two things must be noted in respect
of production function. First, production functions like demand function, must be considered with
reference to a particular period of time. Production function expresses flows of inputs resulting in
flows of output in a specific period of time. Secondly, production function of a firm is determined
by the state of technology. When there is advancement in technology, the production function
charges with the result that the new production function charges with the result of output from the
given inputs, or smaller quantities of inputs can be used for producing a given quantity of output.
2.7 Linear, Homogeneous Production Function
Production function can take several forms but a particular form of production function
enjoys wide popularity among the economists. This is a linear homogeneous production function,
that is, production function which is homogenous production function of the first degree.
Homogeneous production function of the first degree implies that if all factors of production are
increased in a given proportion, output also increased in a same proportion. Hence linear
homogeneous production function represents the case of constant return to scales. If there are two
factors X and Y, The production function and homogeneous production function of the first degree
can be mathematically expressed as,
Q = f(X, Y)
Where Q stands for the total production, X and Y represent total inputs.
mQ = f(mX, mY )
m stands any real number
The above function means that if factors X and y are increased by m-times, total production
Q also increases by m-times. It is because of this that homogeneous function of the first degree
yield constant return to scale.
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
45
46
Capital
R
C
B
A
300
200
100
Labour
In a fixed proportion production function, doubling the quantities of capital and labour at
the required ratio doubles the output, trebling their quantities at the required ratio trebles the output.
2.9 Cobb Douglas Production Function
Many Economists have studied actual production function and have used statistical methods
to find out relations between changes in physical inputs and physical outputs. A most familiar
empirical production function found out by statistical methods is the Cobb Douglas production
function. Cobb Douglas production function was developed by Charles Cobb and Paul Douglas.
In C-D production function, there are two inputs, labour and capital, Cobb Douglas production
function takes the following mathematical form
Q=
Where Q is the manufacturing output, L is the quantity of labour employed, K is the
quantity of capital employed, A is the total factor productivity or technology are assumed to be a
constant. The and , output elasticitys of Labour and Capital and the A, and are positive
constant.
Roughly speaking, Cobb Douglas production function found that about 75% of the
increasing in manufacturing production was due to the Labour input and the remaining 25 % was
due to the Capital input.
2.10 Properties of Cobb Douglas Production Function
2.10.1. Average product of factors: The first important properties of C D production function as
well as of other linearly homogeneous production function is the average and marginal products of
factors depend upon the ratio of factors are combined for the production of a commodity . Average
product if Labour (APL) can be obtained by dividing the production function by the amount of
Labour L. Thus,
47
/L
=A
Thus Average Product of Labour depends on the ratio of the factors (K/L) and does not
depend upon the absolute quantities of the factors used.
Average Product of Capital (Q/K)
Q=
Q/K =
/K
/K
=A
So the average Product of capital depends on the ratio of the factors (L/K) and does not
depend upon the absolute quantities of the factors used.
2.10.2 Marginal Product of Factors: The marginal product of factors of a linear homogenous
production function also depends upon the ratio of the factors and is independent of the absolute
quantities of the factors used. Note, that marginal product of factors, says Labour, is the derivative
of the production function with respect to Labour.
Q=
MPL =
=
=
=
MPL =
It is thus clear that MPL depends on capital labour ratio, that is, Capital per worker and is
independent of the magnitudes of the factors employed.
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
48
Q=
MPK =
=
=
=
MPL =
It is thus clear that MPL depends on capital labour ratio, that is, capital per worker and is
independent of the magnitudes of the factors employed.
MPK =
=
= A
= A
=
2.10.3 Marginal rate of substitution: Marginal rate of substitution between factors is equal to the
ratio of the marginal physical products of the factors. Therefore, in order to derive MRS from Cobb
Douglas production function, we used to obtain the marginal physical products of the two factors
from the C D function.
, Therefore,
49
=
Represents the marginal product of labour and
Thus, MPL =
Similarly, by differentiating C D production function with respect to capital, we can show
that marginal product of capital
MPK =
=
=
=
MRS LK =
=
1. C D production function and Elasticity of substitution (s or ) is equal to unity.
s =
50
=1
2.10.4 Return to Scale: An important property of C D production function is that the sum if its
exponents measures returns to scale. That is, when the sum of exponents is not necessarily equal to
zero is given below.
=
Ie
by
Q' =
ie
)
Q
This means that when each input is increased by a constant factor g, output Q increases
. Now, if + = 1 then, in this production function.
Q' = g'Q
Q = gQ
This is, when + = 1, output (Q) also increases by the same factor g by which both inputs
are increased. This implies that production function is homogeneous of first degree or, in other
words, retune to scale are constant.
When + > 1, say it is equal to 2, then, in this production function new output.
Q' =
= gQ.
51
In this case multiplying each input by constant g, then output (Q) increases by g. Therefore,
+ > 1.
C D production function exhibits increasing return to scale. When + < 1, say it is equal
to 0.8, then in this production function, new output.
Q' =
=
Q.
That is increasing each input by constant factor g will cause output to increase by
, that
is ,less than g .Return to scale in this case are decreasing. Therefore + measures return to scale.
If + = 1, return to scale are constant.
If + > 1, return to scale are increasing.
If + < 1, return to scale are decreasing.
2.10.5 C-D Production Functions and Output Elasticity of Factors
The exponents of labour and capital in C D production function measures output elasticitys
of labour and capital. Output elasticity of a factor refers to the relative or percentage change in
output caused by a given percentage change in a variable factor, other factors and inputs remaining
constant. Thus,
OE=
=a
=a
Thus, exponent (a) of labour in C D production function is equal to the output elasticity of labour.
Similarly, O E of Capital =
MPk = b.
= b.
=b
Therefore, output elasticity of capital = b.
=b
52
+KAb
= Aa
+ Ab
a = 1 b and b = 1 a, we have
Q = Aa
+ Ab
= (a + b) A
Since a + b = 1 we have
Q=A
Q=Q
Thus, in C D production function with a + b == 1 if wage rate = MP L and rate of return on
capital (K) = MPK, then total output will be exhausted.
2.10.7 C D Production Function and Labour Share in National Income.
C D production function has been used to explain labour share in national income (i.e., real
national product). Let Y stand for real national product, L and K for inputs of labour and capital,
then according to C D production function as applied to the whole economy , we have
Y =
. (1)
Now, the real wage of labour (w) is its real marginal product. If we differentiate Y partially with
respect to L, we get the marginal product of labour, thus, Real wage (or marginal product of labour)
W=
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
53
=a
. (2)
54
55
Diet problems
To determine the minimum requirements of nutrients subjects to availability of foods and their
prices.
Transportation problem
To decide the routes, number of units, the choice of factories, so that tha cost of operation is the
minimum.
Manufacturing problems
To find the number of items of each type that should be made so as to maximize the profits.
Production problems
Subject to the sales fluctuations. To decide the production schedule to satisfy demand and
minimize cost in the face of fluctuating rates and storage expenses.
Assembling problems
To have, the best combination of basic components to produce goods according to certain
specifications.
Purchasing problems
To have the least cost objective in, say, the processing of goods purchased from outside and
varying in quantity, quality and prices.
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
56
To assign jobs to workers for maximum effectiveness and optimum results subject to restrictions
of wages and other costs.
2.15 Limitations of LPP
The computations required in complex problems may be enormous. The assumption of divisibility
of resources may often be not true. Linearity of the objective function and constraints may not be a
valid assumption. In practice work there can be several objectives, not just a single objective as
assumed in LP.
2.16 Formulation of Linear Programming
The formulation has to be done in an appropriate form. We should have,
(1) An objective function to be maximized or minimized. It will have n decision variables x, x
.xn and is written in the form.
Max (Z) or Min(c) = CX+ CX+. +Cn Xn
Where each Cj is a constant which stands for per unit contribution of profit (in the maximization
case) or cost (in the minimization case to each Xj)
(2) The constraints in the form of linear inequalities.
a11x1 + a12x2 ++a1n xn < or > b1
a21x1 + a22x2 +..+a2n xn < or > b2
-------------------------------------------am1 x1 + am2 x2 +.+amn xn < or > bn
Briefly written
aij xj < or > bi
I = 1,2,n
57
A=
..
x1
b1
..
X = x2
b = b2
xn
bm
Examples: A firm can produce a good either by (1) a labour intensive technique, using 8 units of
labour and 1 unit of capital or (2) a capital intensive technique using 1 unit of labour and 2 unit of
capital. The firm can arrange up to 200 units of labour and 100 units of capital. It can sell the good
at a constant net price (P), ie P is obtained after subtracting costs. Obviously we have simplified the
problem because in this P become profit per unit. Let P = 1.
Let x1 and x2 be the quantities of the goods produced by the processes 1 and 2 respectively.
To maximize the profit P x1 + P x2, we write the objective function.
= x1 + x2 (since P = 1). The problem becomes
Max = x1 + x2
Subject to: The labour constraint 8 x1 + x2 200
The capital constraint x1 + x2 100
And the non- negativity conditions x1 0, x2 0
This is a problem in linear programming.
Example: Two foods F1, F2 are available at the prices of Rs. 1 and Rs. 2 per unit respectively. N 1,
N2, N3 are essential for an individual. The table gives these minimum requirements and nutrients
available from one unit of each of F1, F2. The question is of minimizing cost (C), while satisfying
these requirements.
Nutrients
Minimum
requirements
One units
One units
of F1
of F2
N1
17
N2
19
N3
15
58
Where P1 = 1, P = 2
We therefore have to Minimize
C = x1 + 2x2
Subject to the minimum nutrient requirement constraints,
9x1 + x2 17
3x1 +4 x2 19
2 x1 + 5 x2 15
Non- negativity conditions
x1 0 , x2 0.
Graphical Solution
If the LPP consist of only two decision variable. We can apply the graphical method of solving the
problem. It consists of seven steps, they are
1. Formulate the problem in to LPP.
2. Each inequality in the constraint may be treated as equality.
3. Draw the straight line corresponding to equation obtained steps (2) so there will be as many
straight lines, as there are equations.
4. Identify the feasible region. This is the region which satisfies all the constraints in the problem.
5. The feasible region is a many sided figures. The corner point of the figure is to be located and
they are coordinate to be measures.
6. Calculate the value of the objective function at each corner point.
7. The solution is given by the coordinate of the corner point which optimizes the objective
function.
Example: Solve the following LPP graphically.
Maximize Z = 3x1 +4x2
Subject to the constraints
4x1 + 2x2 80
2x1 + 5x2 180
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
59
x1 , x2 0
Treating the constraints are equal, we get
4x1 + 2x2 = 80 .. (1)
2x1 + 5x2 = 180 (2)
x1 = 0(3)
x2 = 0 .(4)
In equation (1), putting x1 = 0, we get
0x1 + 2x2 = 80
x2 = 80/2
= 40
When x = 0
4x1 + 0x2 = 80
x1 = 80/4
= 20
So (0, 40) and (20, 0) are the two point in the straight line given by equation (1)
Similarly in the equation (2), we get
x1 = 0
0x1 + 5x2 = 180
x2 = 180/5
= 36
x2 = 0
2x1 + 0x2 = 180
x1 = 180/2
= 90
Therefore (0, 36) and (90, 0) are the two points on the straight line represent by the equation (2).
60
The equation (3) and (4) are representing the x1 and x2 axis respectively.
x2
x1
The feasible region is the (shaded area) shaded portion, it has four corner points, say OABC
The coordinate of O = (0, 0)
A = (20, 0)
C = (0, 36) and B can be obtained by solving the equations for
the lines passing through that point.
The equations are (1) and (2)
4x1 + 2x2 = 80 (1)
2x1 + 5x2 = 180.. (2)
Then (2) (1) 0 + 4x2 = 140
x2 = 140/4
= 35
Substituting the value of x2 in (1), we get
x1 = 40 35 / 2
= 5/2
= 2.5
So the coordinate b are (x1 = 2.5, x2 = 35)
Evaluate the objective function of the corner points is given below.
61
Point
x1 x2
(0, 0)
(20, 0)
60
3 20 + 4 0 = 60
(2.5, 35)
147.5
3 2.5 + 4 35 = 147.5
(0, 36)
144
3 0 + 4 36 = 144
62
So (0, 104) and (52, 0) are the two point in the straight line given by equation (1)
Similarly in the equation (2), we get
x1 = 0
0x1 + 2x2 = 76
2 x2 = 76
x2 = 76/2
= 38
x1 + 0x2 = 76
x1 = 76
Therefore (0, 38) and (76, 0) are the two points on the straight line represent by the equation
(2).The equation (3) and (4) are representing the x1 and x2 axis respectively.
X2
P
x1
The feasible region is the (shaded area) shaded portion, it has three corner points, say PNM
The coordinate of
M = (52, 0)
P = (0, 38)
N can be obtained by solving the equations for the lines passing through that point.
The equations are (1) and (2)
2x1 + x2 104 (1)
x1 + 2x2 76... (2)
Taking the second constraint and multiplied by 2 throughout the equation
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
63
0 + 3x2 = 48
x2 = 48/3
= 16
x1 x2
(0, 104)
1144
6 0 + 11 104=1144
(46, 17)
440
6 44+ 14 16 = 440
(75, 0)
450
6 75 + 11 0 = 450
64
3x1 + 4x2
Sub to
3x1 + 2x2 6
x1 + 4x2 4
x1 0, x2 0
Min C
10x1 + 27x2
Sub to
x1 + 3x2 11
2x1 + 5x2 20
x1 0, x2 0
Max Z
2x + 7y
Sub to
4x + 5y 20
3x + 7y 21
x1 0, x2 0
FURTHER READINGS
1. R.G.D Allen- Mathematical Economics.
2. Taro Yamane-Mathematics for Economics.
3. Chiang A.C and K. Wainwright- Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics.
4. D.R. Agarwal- Elementary Mathematics and Statistics for Economists.
5. G.S Monga- Mathematics and Statistics for Economics.
65
MODULE III:
MARKET EQUILIBRIUM
. (4)
66
= a-b
=
. (5)
Equation (4) and (5) describe the qualitative results of the model. If the values of the parameters a,
b, c and d are given we can obtain the equilibrium price and quantity by substituting the values of
these parameters in the qualitative results of equation (4) and (5).
Numerical Example:
Suppose the following demand and supply functions of a commodity are given which is being
produced under perfect competition. Find out the equilibrium price and quantity.
= 750 25p
= 300 + 20p
Solution: There are two alternatives ways of solving for equilibrium price and quantity.
First we can find out the equilibrium price and quantity by using the equilibrium condition, namely
=
Second, we can obtain equilibrium price and quantity by using the qualitative results of the demand
and supply model.
p=
, and q =
1. Since in equilibrium
67
=
=
=
=
III.2. Equilibrium in the Perfect Competitive Market.
In the perfect competitive market the firms are in equilibrium when they maximize their profits ( ).
The profit is the difference between the total cost and total revenue, i.e,
.
The conditions for equilibrium are
1. MC = MR
2. Slop of MC > slope of MR
Derivation of the equilibrium of the firm
The firms aims at t he maximization of its profit
Where
Profit
= Total Revenue
= Total cost
Clearly TR =
and TC =
(a) The first-order condition for the maximization of a function is that its first derivative (with
respect to X in our case) be equal to zero. Differentiating the total-profit function and
equating to zero we obtain
=
=0
Or
=
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
68
The term
is the slope of the total revenue curve, that is, the marginal revenue. The term
is the slope of the total cost curve, or the marginal cost. Thus the firs-order condition for
profit maximization is
MR = MC
Given that MR > 0, MR must also be positive at equilibrium. Since MR = P the first-order
condition may be written as MC = P.
(b) The second-order condition for a maximum requires that the second derivative of the
function be negative (implying that after its highest point the curve turns downwards). The
second derivative of the total-profit function is
=
<0
-7
+ 12X +
Find the best level of output of the firm. Also find the profit of the firm at this level of output.
First condition requires, MR = MC
TR = PX = 4X, as P = 4
69
MR =
MC =
=3
14X + 12
14X + 12
14X + 12 8 = 0
14X + 8 = 0
3X = 2, X = and X = 4
-7
+ 12X + 5)
= 4X
+7
- 12X - 5
-7
- 8X - 5
= -64 + 112 32 5
= 11
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
70
The firm maximizes its profit at the output level of 4 units and at this level its maximum profit is
Rs.11.
III.3. Equilibrium in the Monopoly
Monopoly is a market structure in which there is a single seller, there are no close substitutes for
the commodity it produces and there are barriers to entry.
A. Short-run Equilibrium
The monopolist maximizes his short-run profit if the following two conditions are fulfilled:
1. The MC is equal to the MR. i,e, MC = MR
2. The slope of the MC is greater than the slope of the MR at the point of intersection.
Mathematical derivation
The given demand function is X = g(P)
Which may be solved for P, P =
The given cost function is C =
The monopolist aims at the maximization of his profit
= TR TC
(a) The first-order condition for maximum profit
=0
=
=0
Or
=
That is MR = MC
(b) The second-order condition for maximum profit
<0
<0
71
Or
<
That is
[slope of MR] < [slope of MC]
Numerical Example:
Given the demand curve of the monopolist
X = 50 0.5p
Which may be solved for P?
P = 100 2X
Given the cost function of the monopolist
TC = 50 + 40X
The goal of the monopolist is to maximize profit
= TR TC
(i) Fist find the MR
TR = XP = X (100 2X)
TR = 100X 2
MR =
= 100 4X
= 40
(iii)Equate MR and MC
MR = MC
100 4X = 40
X = 15
72
we have
=- 4
Clearly 4 < 0
Alternative Method
The same problem can be worked out by another method.
After finding TR and TC, compute the profit function .
= TR TC = 100X - 2
(50 + 40X)
= 100X - 2
= 60X - 2
= -2
50 + 40X
50
+ 60X - 50
As per the optimization rule, we can optimize the function. At first find the first order derivative
and equate it with zero and find the critical value.
= - 4X + 60 = 0
-4X + 60 = 0, -4X = - 60
X = 15
The second order condition for the maximisation must be less than zero.
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
73
= -4 < 0
(X=15) = -4 <
Here the conditions for the maximisation have been satisfied. So the function is maximized
X = 15
at
+ 60X 50
Substitute = -2(
) + 60 (15) 50 = 400.
B. Long-run Equilibrium
As you know that, in the long run the monopolist has the time to expand his plant, or to use his
existing plant at any level which will maximize his profit.
Mathematical derivation of the equilibrium of the multi-plant monopolist
Given the market demand
P=
And the cost structure of the plants
=
=
The monopolist aims at the allocation of his production between plant A and plant B so as to
maximize his profit
= TR -
=0
74
Or
i.e,
=
(a)
=0
Or
i.e,
But
=
= MR (given that each unit of the homogeneous output will be sold at the same
price P and will yield the same marginal revenue, irrespective in which plant the unit has been
produced)
Therefore
MR =
So that MR =
, and MR =
and
= 0.25
(1)
TR = Xp = X(100 0.5X)
TR = 100X 0.5
75
MR =
= 100 X = 100 (
(2)
= 10
=
= 10
And
= 0.25
=
= 0.5
= 10
100 -
= 0.5
Solving for
and
we find
= 70 and
= 20
So that the total X is 90 units. This total output will be sold at price P defined by
P = 100 0.5X = 55
The monopolists profit is
= TR
76
) and
-C
(a)
(b)
=0
= 0 and
or
=0
; and
or
But
=
= MC =
Therefore
MC =
and
<
That is, the MR in each market must be increasing less rapidly than the MC for the output as a
whole.
Numerical Example:
The total demand function is
X = 50 0.5 P (or P = 100 2X)
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
77
or
= 80 2.5
= 18 0.1
or
= 180 10
That is
=X
TC
Solution
(1)
=
=
= 80 - 5
= 180 - 20
(2)
(3) MC =
78
The profit is
=
TC = 500
and
<
Comparing the above results with those for the example of the simple monopolist we observe that
X is the same in both cases but the of the discriminating monopolist is larger.
III.5. Price Discrimination and the Price Elasticity of Demand
As we know that, the relationship between MR and price elasticity e is
MR = P
Proof
MR =
The price elasticity of demand is defined as
= -
Solving for
then we have
.
Or
MR = P (1
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
79
Or
=
Where
= elasticity of
If
That is,
= . This means that when elasticities are the same price discrimination in not
profitable. The monopolist will charge a uniform price for his product.
If price elasticities differ price will be higher in the market whose demand is less elastic.
This is obvious from the equality of MRs
)=
If
>
, the
)>
80
1. Bernheim, Douglas B., and Whinston, Michael D.: Micro Economics, Tata McGraw-Hill
Publishing Comapany Ltd., New Delhi, 2008.
2. Chiang, Alpha C, and Wainwright, Kevin: Fundamental Methods of Mathematical
Economics, 4th Ed., McGraw-Hill Companies,2005.
3. Varian, Hal R: Intermediate Micro Economics: A Modern Approach, 7th Ed., W.W Norton
& Company, New York, 2006.
4. Simon, Carl P. and Blume Lawrence: Mathematics for Economics, 1st Indian Ed., Viva
books Pvt. Ltd, 2006
5. Koutsoyianis, A.: Modern Micro Economics, 2nd Ed., Macmillan Press Ltd., 2008.
81
MODULE IV
NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMETRICS
Econometrics: Meaning, Scope, and Limitations - Methodology of econometrics Types of
data: Time series, Cross section and panel data.
4.1 Nature and Scope of Econometrics
Econometrics means economic measurement. It deals with the measurement of economic
relationships. The tem econometrics is formed from two words economy and measure. It was
Ragner Frisch (1936) who coined the term Econometrics. The term econometrics was first used by
Pawel Clompa in 1910. But the credit of coining the term econometrics should be given to Ragnar
Frisch (1936), one of the founders of the Econometric Society. He was the person who established
the subject in the sense in which it is known today. Econometrics can be defined generally as the
application of mathematics and statistical methods to the analysis of economic data.
Econometrics is a combination of economic theory, mathematical economics and statistics.
It may be considered as the integration of economics, mathematics and statistics for the purpose of
providing numerical value for economic relationships and for verifying economic theories.
4.2 Definitions
1. Econometrics may be defined as the quantitative analysis of actual economic phenomenon
based on the concurrent development of theory and observation, related by appropriate
methods of inference. (P.A. Samuelson, T.C.Koopman, J.R.N Stone)
2. Econometrics is concerned with the empirical determination of economic laws ( H.Theil)
3. Econometrics may be defined as the social science in which the tools of economic theory,
mathematics and statistical inference are applied to the analysis of economic phenomena
(Arthur S.Goldberg)
4. Econometrics consists of the application of mathematical statistics to economic data to lend
empirical support to the model constructed on mathematical economics and to obtain
numerical results. (Gerhard. Tinter)
5. Every application of mathematics or of statistical methods to the study of economic
phenomena (Malinvaud 1966)
6. The production of quantitative economic statements that either explain the behaviour of
variables we have already seen, or forecast (ie. predict) behaviour that we have not yet see,
or both (Christ 1966)
7. Econometric is the art and science of using statistical methods for the measurement of
economic relations (Chow, 1983).
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
82
83
2. Policy Making
Various econometric techniques can be obtained in order to obtain reliable estimates of the
individual co-efficient of economic relationships .The knowledge of numerical value of these
coefficients is very important for the decision of the firm as well as the formulation of the economic
policy of the government. It helps to compare the effects of alternative policy decisions.
For eg. If the price elasticity of demand for a product is less than one (inelastic demand) it
will not benefit the manufacturer to decrease its price, because his revenue would be reduced.
Since econometrics can provide numerical estimate of the co-efficient of economic relationships it
becomes an essential tool for the formulation of sound economic policies.
84
85
86
Y = 1 + 2X + u
Where u is the disturbance or error term, or a random (stochastic) variable. The econometric
consumption function hypothesize that the dependent variable (consumption) is linearly related to
the explanatory variable (income), but that the relationship between the two is not exact; it is
subject to individual variations.
4. Obtaining Data
Estimations are possible only if data are gathered. Data can be collected either by census
method or sample method. Important sampling methods used are simple random sample, stratified
sample, systematic sample, multistage sampling, cluster sampling and quota sampling. Similarly,
data are classified into primary data, secondary data, time series data, cross section data and pooled
data. To estimate the numerical values of 1 and 2 , data is needed. Three types of data are
available for empirical analysis, time series, cross sectional and pooled data. In econometric
models, the distinction between time series data and cross section data are important. To make its
distinction clear, let us consider the following example,
Year
1999
2000
2002
2003
2004
2005
2007
2008
2010
Sales
15
14
17
14
12
14
17
14
12
A casual look into the data set gives an impression that it belongs to time series, because it
is ordered in time. But the given set is neither time series nor cross section.
Time Series Data give information about the numerical valves of variables from period to
period. The data can be collected at regular time intervals (daily, weekly, monthly, annual etc).For
a data set to be time series, there are two conditions. Data collection interval should be equal and
gather information on a single entity. The given set of data does not obey these conditions and
hence not time series. But if we are provided with sales data for a few years, with regular intervals,
on year, six months etc, definitely they constitute time series data.
Cross Section Data gives information on variables concerning individual agents
(consumers or producers) at a given point of time. For e.g. a cross section sample of consumers is a
sample of family budgets showing expenditures in various commodities by each family, as well as
information on family income, family composition and other demographic, social or financial
characteristics. When we gather information on multiple entities at a point of time, it is called cross
section data. For example, if we are gathering details of income, savings, education, occupation etc
of a group of 35 persons at a point of time, it is the best example of cross section data. In other
words, survey data are broadly cross section data. In short, time series data is gathered at an interval
of time while cross section data are gathered at a point of time. The classification of time series
87
and cross section data are important because, the use of appropriate techniques depends on the
nature of the data, whether it is time series or cross section.
Another set of data used in econometric modeling is pooled data. Pooled data, in a simple way
is the integration or mixing of time series and cross section data. But the treatment pooled data set
is little complicated. On the pooled data, all elements of both the series and cross sectional data
used. Data in real terms (i.e. they are measured in constant prices) is used. These data are plotted
in a graph where y variable is the aggregate consumption expenditure and X variable is GDP, a
measure of aggregate income.
5. Estimation of the econometric model
The numerical estimates of parameters can be found. Using this, the consumption functions can
be shown empirically. For estimating the parameters the technique of regression analysis is used.
If the estimates of 1 and 2 are respectively -231.8 & 0.7194, then the estimated consumption
functions is Y = -231.8 +0.7194x .The hat on y indicates that it is an estimate. The equation shows
that MPC = 0.72. This suggests that an increase in real income of one dollar, led on average, to
increases of about 72 cents in real consumptions expenditure.
6. Hypothesis Testing
Keynesian theory says that MPC is positive but less than one.In the e.g. used, MPC was found
to be 0.72. If 0.72 is statistically less than one, then Keynesian theory can be supported. Such
confirmation or rejection of economic theories on the basis of sample evidence is known as
statistical inference (hypothesis testing).
7. Forecasting or prediction
Forecasting is one of the prime aims of econometric analysis and research. The forecasting
power will be based on the stability of the estimates, their sensitivity to changes in the size of the
sample. We must establish whether the estimated function performs adequately outside the sample
of data whose average variation it represents. One way of establishing the forecasting power of a
model is to use the estimates of the model for a period not included in the sample. The estimated
value or forecast value is compared with the actual or realized magnitude of the relevant dependent
variable. Usually there will be a difference between the actual and the forecast value of the
variable, which is tested with the aim of establishing whether it is statistically significant. If, after
conducting the relevant test of significance, we find that the difference between the realized value
of the dependent variable and that estimated from the model is statistically significant, we conclude
that the forecasting power of the model is poor. Another way of establishing the stability of the
estimates and the performance of the model outside the sample of data, from which it has been
estimated, is to re estimate the function with an expanded sample that is a sample including
additional observations. The original estimates will normally differ from the new estimates. The
difference is tested for statistical significance with appropriate methods.
88
If the model confirms the hypothesis or theory under consideration, it can be used to predict the
future values of the dependent variable (y) on the basis of known or expected future valves of the
explanatory variable (x) For e.g. suppose the real GDP is expected to the 6000 billion in 2010.
Then the forecast of consumption expenditure can be estimated as
Y = -238 + 0.7196 (6000)
= 4084.6
The income multiplier is defined as:
M=
1
1
= 3.57
1 mpc 1 0.72
This shows that an increase of a dollar investment will eventually lead to about four times
increase in income. Thus, a quantitative estimate of MPC provides valuable information for policy
making.
8. Policy implications
Using the Keynesian consumption function as e.g. Suppose the government believes that an
expenditure level of 4000 billion dollars will reduce the level of unemployment. We can estimate
the level of income which produces the targeted amount of consumption expenditure.
4000 = -231.8+0.7194 x
x=
4000 231.8
0.7194
x = 5882 approximately
That is, an income level of 5882, given a MPC of about 0.72 will produce expenditure equal
to 4000 billion dollars.
4.9 Desirable Properties of an Econometric Model
An econometric model is a model whose parameters have been estimated with some
appropriate econometric technique. The goodness of an econometric model is judged according to
the following desirable properties.
1. Theoretical plausibility the model should be compatible with the postulates of the
economic theory.
2. Explanatory ability The model should be able to explain the observations of the actual
world. It must be consistent with the observed behaviour of the economic variables.
3. Accuracy of the estimates of the parameters The estimates of the coefficient should be
accurate in the sense that, they should approximate as best as possible, the true parameters
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
89
of the structural model. The estimates should possess properties like unbiasedness,
consistency and efficiency
4. Fore casting ability The model should produce satisfactory predictions of future values of
the dependent variable.
5. Simplicity the model should represent the economic relations with maximum simplicity.
The fewer the equations and simpler their mathematical form, the better the model is
considered.
4.10 Types of Econometrics
Econometrics may be divided into two broad categories. Theoretical econometrics and
applied econometrics.
Theoretical econometrics is concerned with the development of appropriate method for
measuring economic relationships specified by econometric models. For e.g. one of the methods
used extensively is the principle of least squares.
In applied econometrics, the tools of theoretical econometrics, is used to study some special
area of economics and business such as the production function, investment function, demand &
supply functions etc.
4.11 Uses of Econometrics
1. Econometrics is widely used in policy formulation
For eg. Suppose the government wants to devalue its currency to correct the balance of
payment problem. For estimating the consequences of devaluation, the price elasticity of imports
and exports is needed. If imports and exports are inelastic then devaluation will not produce the
necessary change. If imports and exports are elastic then the BOP of the country will improve by
devaluation. Price elasticity can be estimated with the help of demand function of import and
export. An econometric model can be built through which the variables can be estimated.
2. Econometrics helps the producers in making rational calculations.
3. Econometrics is also useful in verifying theories.
4. Studies of econometrics mainly consist of testing of hypothesis, estimation of the
parameters and ascertaining the proper functional form of the economic relations.
4.12 Limitations of Econometrics
Econometrics has come a long way over a relatively short period of time. Important advances
have been made in the compilation of data, development of concepts, theories and tools for the
construction and evaluation of a wide variety of econometric models. Applications of econometrics
can be found in almost every field of economics. Nowadays, even there is a tendency to use
econometric tools in certain other sciences like sociology, political science, agriculture and
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
90
91
(a) exogenous (b) endogenous (c) identified (d) either exogenous or endogenous
4. The starting point of econometric analysis is
(a) model specification
5. Regressor refers to
(a) independent variable (b) dependent variable (c) error term (d) dummy variable
6. In perfect linear model, we assume that regression coefficient remains..
(a) variable until some point (b) variable through out (c) constant to some point
(d) constant through out
7. In econometric models, t+1 indicates,
(a) net addition (b) current value with some fluctuations (c) expected value (d) none of
these
8. Quota sample is.sample
(a)
probability sample
judgment sample
9.
(b)
(c)
convenientsample
(d)
When a north Indian town data and south Indian data are totaled, it leads to the problem of
.aggregation.
(a)
national
(b) regional
(c) spatial
(d) heterogeneous
Answers (1) C (2) D (3) D (4) C (5) A (6) D (7) C (8) B (9) C (10) A.
92
93
MODULE V
THE LINEAR REGRESSION MODEL
Origin and Modern interpretation- Significance of Stochastic Disturbance term- Population
Regression Function and Sample Regression Function-Assumptions of Classical Linear regression
model-Estimation of linear Regression Model: Method of Ordinary Least Squares (OLS)- Test of
Significance of Regression coefficients : t test- Coefficient of Determination.
5.1 Regression Analysis
The term regression was introduced by Francis Galton.Regression analysis is concerned
with the study of the dependence of one variable (dependent variable) on one or more other
variables (explanatory variables) with a view to estimating the average (mean) valve of the former
in terms of known (fixed) values of the latter. Galton found that, although there was a tendency for
tall parents to have tall children and for short parents to have short children, the average height of
children born of parents of a given height tended to more or regress towards the average height in
the population as a whole. In other words, the height of the children of unusually tall or unusually
shorts parents tends to more towards the average height of the population. In the modern view of
regression, the concern is with finding out how the average height of sons changes, given the
fathers height.Regression analysis is largely concerned with estimating and/or predicting the
(population) mean value of the dependent variable on the basis of the known or fixed values of the
explanatory variable.
5.2 Origin of the Linear Regression Model
There are different methods for estimating the coefficients of the parameters. Of these
different methods, the most popular and widely used is the regression technique using Ordinary
Least Square (OLS) method. This method is used because of the inherent properties of the
estimates derived using this method. But, first let us try to understand the rationale of this method.
For this purpose, let us go back to the demand theory as well as the consumption function which we
discussed in the earlier chapter. Demand theory says that there is a negative relation between price
and quantity demanded certeris paribus. In the case of consumption function, there is a positive
relation between consumption expenditure and income. There are three important questions here.
1. Which is the dependent variable and which is the independent variable?
2. Which is the appropriate mathematical form which explains the phenomenon?
3. What is the expected sign and magnitude of the coefficients?
In order to answer these questions, the theory will give the necessary support. In the case of
demand equation, quantity demanded is the dependent variable, and price is the independent
variable. Economic theory does not discuss the choice between single equation models or
simultaneous equation models to discuss the relationship. So naturally we may assume that the
relation is explained with the help of single equation, that too assuming a linear relation. As far as
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
94
the sign and magnitude of the coefficients are concerned, in the equation, D = + P + U, can
take any value but preferably zero or positive. It actually shows the quantity demanded at price
zero. So chances of demanding negative quantity is very rare and hence if we get negative
quantity, it can be approximated to zero. In the case of , it can be positive or negative. But
normally it will be negative assuming that the commodity demanded is a normal good. Of course,
elasticity nature of the commodity also influences the magnitude and nature of this value.
In the case of consumption function, consumption is the dependent variable and income is
the independent variable. Whether the relation is linear or non linear, is a debatable issue. For
instance, psychological law of Keynes suggests that when income increases, consumption also
increases, but less than proportionate. So assuming that consumption and income are linearly
related is in one way, over simplification. But for the time being let us assume so just for
explanatory purpose. Regarding the sign and magnitude of parameters and . There is some
meaning and interpretation. represents the consumption when income takes the value zero, that
is, according to theory, it is autonomous consumption. Similarly, is nothing but the value of
marginal propensity to consume which is normally less than 1 and cannot be negative.
Based on the above discussed rationale and logic, let us rewrite the demand equation as D
= + P + U , where D is the quantity demanded, P is price, and are the parameters to be
estimated. In order to estimate these parameters, we use Ordinary Least Square (OLS) method.
Once we plot this on a graph, we will be able to get the deviations between actual and estimated
observations, popularly called as errors. Naturally, a rational decision is to minimize these errors.
Thus from all possible lines, we choose the one for which the deviations of the points is the
smallest possible. The least squares criterion requires that the regression line be drawn in such a
way, so as to minimize the sum of the squares of the deviations of the observations from it. The
first step is to draw the line so that the sum of the simple deviations of the observations is zero.
Some observations will lie above the line and will have a positive deviation, some will lie below
the line, in which case, they will have a negative deviation, and finally the points lying on the line
will have a zero deviation. In summing these deviations the positive values will offset the negative
values, so that the final algebraic sum of these residuals will equal zero. Mathematically, e = 0.
Since the sum total of deviations is 0, it can not be minimized as such. So we try to square the
deviations and minimize the sum of the squares. e2. Thus we call this method as least square
method,
5.3 Population Regression Function (PRF)
Mathematically a population regression function (PRF) or Conditional Expectation
Function (CEF) can be defined as the average value of the dependent value for a given value of the
explanatory or independent variable. In other words, PRF tries to find out how the average value of
the dependent variable varies with the given value of the explanatory variable. On the other hand,
when we estimate the average value of the dependent variable with the help of a sample, it is called
stochastic sample regression function (SRF).
E(Y | Xi) = f (Xi)
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
95
Where;
E(Y | Xi) is a linear function of Xi. This is known as the conditional expectation function (CEF) or
population regression function (PRF). It states merely that the expected value of the distribution of
Y given Xi is functionally related to Xi. In simple terms, it tells how the mean or average response
of Y varies with X. For example, an economist might posit that consumption expenditure is linearly
related to income. Therefore, as a first approximation or a working hypothesis, we may assume that
the PRF E(Y | Xi) is a linear function of Xi,
E(Y | Xi) = 1 + 2Xi
Where; 1 and 2 are unknown but fixed parameters known as the regression coefficients;
1 and 2 are also known as intercept and slope coefficients, respectively.
We can express the deviation of an individual Yi around its expected value as follows: ui =
Yi E(Y | Xi) or
Yi = E(Y | Xi) + ui where the deviation ui is an unobservable random variable taking
positive or negative values. Technically, ui is known as the stochastic disturbance or stochastic error
term.
We can say that the expenditure of an individual family, given its income level, can be
expressed as the sum of two components: (1) E(Y | Xi), which is simply the mean consumption
expenditure of all the families with the same level of income. This component is known as the
systematic, or deterministic, component, and (2) ui, which is the random, or nonsystematic,
component is a surrogate or proxy for all the omitted or neglected variables that may affect Y but
are not (or cannot be) included in the regression model.
If E(Y | Xi) is assumed to be linear in Xi, it may be written as
Yi = E(Y | Xi) + ui
= 1 + 2Xi+ ui
5.4 Sample Regression Function (SRF)
Since the entire population is not available to estimate y from given xi, we have to estimate
the PRF on the basis of sample information. From a given sample we can estimate the mean value
of y corresponding to chosen xi values. The estimated PRF value may not be accurate because of
sampling fluctuations. Because of this only an approximate value of PRF can be obtained. In
general, we would get N different sample regression function (SRFs) for N different samples and
these SRFs are not likely to be the same.
We can develop the concept of the sample regression function (SRF) to represent the
sample regression line.
Y =
1 + 2Xi
96
97
98
The above mentioned assumptions are really classic to regression estimations and make the
method OLS efficient.
There are a few other assumptions also used in OLS estimated. They are,
i The explanatory variables are measured without error. In other words, the explanatory variables
are measured without error. In the case of dependent variable, error may or may not arise.
ii The explanatory variables are not perfectly linearly correlated. If there is more than one
explanatory variable in the relationship, it is assumed that they are not perfectly correlated with
each other. More specifically, we are assuming the absence of multicollinearity.
iii There is no aggregation problem. In the previous chapter, we discussed aggregation over
individuals, time, space and commodities. So we assume the absence of all these problems.
iv The relationship being estimated is identified. This means that we have to estimate a unique
mathematical form. There is no confusion about the coefficients and the equations to which it
belong.
v The relationship is correctly specified. It is assumed that we have not committed any
specification error in determining the explanatory variables, in deciding the mathematical form etc.
5.7 The Method of Ordinary Least Squares
The method of ordinary least squares is attributed to Carl Friedrich Gauss,a German
mathematician. The method of least squares has some very attractive statistical properties that have
made it one of the most powerful and popular methods of regression analysis. To understand this
method, we first explain the least squares principle.
Given the PRF:
Yi = 1 + 2Xi + ui
But it is not easy to estimate PRF, we have to estimate it from the SRF:
Yi = 1 + 2Xi + ui where Yi is the estimated value of Yi .From the equation of SRF
we can write:
ui = Yi Yi
= Yi 1 2Xi
Which shows that the ui (the residuals) are simply the differences between the actual and
estimated Y values. Given n pairs of observation on Y and x SRF can be determined so that its
value is as close as possible to the actual Y. For this the least square estimate is used such that SRF
is equal to ui2
ui2= (Yi Yi)2
= (Yi 1 2Xi )2
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
99
The principle or the method of least squares chooses 1 and 2 in such a manner that, for
a given sample the error term is made as small as possible. In other words, for a given sample, the
method of least squares provides us with unique estimates of 1 and 2 that give the smallest
possible value of the error term.The sum of squared residual deviations is to be minimised with
respect to parameters. So we use little amount of differential calculus and applying the
minimization rules, the first derivative should be equal to zero and second derivative should be
greater than zero, we finally arrive at two equations, popularly known as normal equations. The
equations are,
N 1+ 2X = y
1 X + 2X2= XY, N refers to number of observations
Using these two equations, we can easily estimate the parameters. The estimators so
obtained are called least square estimators, for they are derived from the least square principle.
5.8 Properties of OLS estimate
The least square estimates are BLUE (best, linear and unbiased), provided that the random
term U satisfies some general assumptions, namely that the U has zero mean and consent variance.
1. It is linear, that is, a linear function of a random variable.
2. It is unbiased, that is,
coefficient
3. It has minimum variance in the class of all such linear unbiased estimators
An unbiased estimator with the least variance is known as an efficient estimator. In one way,
this is the gist of the famous Gauss Markov theorem which can be stated as given the assumptions
of the classical linear regression model, the least squares estimators, in the class of unbiased linear
estimators, have minimum variance, that is, they are BLUE.
5.9 Test of Significance of Regression coefficients
Before discussing the conventional tests used in econometric analysis, it is appropriate at
juncture to have little statistical theory and logic behind testing.
5.10 Statistical inferences
Statistical inferences are the area that describes the procedures by which we use the
observed sample data to draw conclusions about the characteristics of the population on from which
the data were generated. Statistical inference can be classified under two categories. Classical
inferences and Bayesian inferences. Classical inference is based on two promises. (i) The sample
data constitute the only relevant information and (ii) the construction and assessment of the
different procedures for inference are based on long run behavior under essentially similar
circumstances. In Bayesian inference we combine sample information with other prior
information.
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
100
Classical inference constitutes two steps (i) estimation and (ii) testing of hypotheses.
(i)Estimation
There are two types of estimations, point estimation and interval estimation. Let be a
parameter (mean, variance or any other moment) in a population probability distribution from
which we have drawn a sample of size n denoted by x 1, x2, x3,xn. In point estimation
is estimated as a function of these sample observations denoted by x 1, x2, this function is
called an estimator. In specific case, when the function is determined by a numerical value, it is
called an estimator of . Thus, X = (1/n)X, the sample mean is an estimator of , the population
mean and X = say, 5, is an estimate of from a particular sample. Instead of one function of x1, x2,
x3.in the point estimation, here two functions are constructed from the sample observations
and say that lies be tween two points with a certain probability. This interval estimates are
relevant in the testing of hypotheses. The key concept underlying the interval estimation is the
notion of the sampling distribution of an estimator. For example, if a sample is drawn from a
normal population with mean and the sample mean x is a point estimator of then, (x)N (,
2/n), ie, the estimator from a sample is having a probability distribution (in this case, normal with
mean , and variance 2/n). This enables us to construct the interval (X2/n) and claim that the
probability distribution of having the true value of within this interval is 0.95, using normal
probability curve. The probability that the interval X2/n, contains the true value of is 0.95.
This interval is called the confidential interval of size (confidence coefficient) of 0.95 or 95 per
cent. This means that if we estimate from repeated samples, we shall be getting all these values
within this range in 95 cases out of 100. The complement of confidence coefficient of 0.95 is 0.05
or 5 per cent. It is denoted generally by and is called the level of significance in testing of
hypotheses.
(ii)Testing of hypotheses
Let f(x) be a population density function of x with as the parameter of the distribution.
Let estimated be the point estimator obtained from a random sample of size n from this
population. Our intention is to judge the value of , the population parameter on the basis of
estimated . For example, can we say from the estimated that the value of =*, any specific
value we guess, say 15. In other words, can we say that the sample we used have come from a
population with =*. A statistical hypothesis is a statement about the value of some parameters in
a population from which the sample is drawn and is denoted by H. The hypothesis we intend to test
is called a Null or maintained hypothesis and denoted by Ho. Thus Ho: =* is the null hypothesis.
Complementary to this, we can state another hypothesis that *, which is called the alternative
hypothesis denoted by H1. In testing of hypothesis, we test Ho: =* against the alternative H1
*.
Two possibilities of making errors exist. A null hypothesis may be really true, but on the
basis of test, we may conclude it is wrong and thus reject Ho when it is actually true. The error we
commit in this process is called Type I error or error. Alternatively, a null hypothesis may be
really wrong, but we may conclude on the basis of the test that it is true and thus we do not reject
null hypothesis when it is actually wrong. This error is called Type II error or error.
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
101
The test procedure, ideally, should be such that both Type I and Type II errors are
eliminated or the probability of committing these errors is zero. We de note probability of
committing Type I error by and the probability of committing Type II error by . Now is called
the level of significance and (1-) the power of the test.
5.11 Student t or Z test:
t test is applicable to a small sample and Z test is applicable to a large sample. These tests
undergo a detailed testing procedure where we have to consider the degrees of freedom, level of
significance, the choice between one tailed test/two tailed test and so on. All these testing
procedures have already been explained above. In order to get the estimated values of t or z, there
is a short cut. In order to get the t value corresponding to intercept, just divide the estimated
intercept value by its respective standard error and also in order to get the t value for the coefficient,
just divide the estimated coefficient value with its standard error, ie, e2/(n-2)x2. If the
calculated t value is greater than the table t value, we reject the hypothesis that X and Y are
independent. If on the other hand, if the calculated t value is smaller than the table t value, we
accept the null hypothesis, ie, X and Y are in dependent
5.12 Coefficient of Determination (R2): A measure of goodness of Fit
The goodness of fit means how well the sample regression line fits the given data. If all the
observation were to lie on the regression line, it indicates a perfect fit. But this happens very rarely.
Generally, there will be some positive and some negative u i. The aim is to make the residuals
around the regression live as small as possible. The coefficient of determination R2 is a measure
that shows how well the sample regression line fits the data.
After the estimation of the parameters and the determination of the least squares regression
line, we need to know how good is the fit of this line to the sample observations of Y and X, that is
to say, we need to measure the dispersion of observations around the regression line. This
knowledge is essential, because the closer the observations to the line, the better the goodness of fit,
that is the better is the explanation of variations of Y by the changes in the explanatory variables.
Inorder to measure this, we use coefficient of determination method. Coefficient of determination
shows the percentage of the total variation of the dependent variable that can be explained by the
independent variable. In other words, coefficient of determination is said to be the explanatory
power of the model and is defined as,
R2 = 1- e2/y2 where y = Y- mean of Y
The value of R2 ranges between 0 and 1. If the value is exactly equal to 1, it is a case of
exact relation and error is zero. This is practically impossible in social science. In majority of
cases, the value will vary from 0.6 to 0.8.
5.13 Properties
1. It is a non negative quantity
2. Its limits are 0 R 2 1. When R2=1, it means a perfect fit. When R2=0, there is no
Mathematical Economics and Econometrics
102
(b) Variations
103
small sample (b) large sample (c) when sample is below 50 (d) when sample is above
50
104