Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing in The Presence of A Strategic Retailer
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing in The Presence of A Strategic Retailer
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing in The Presence of A Strategic Retailer
Abstract
1. Introduction
Manufacturers of most consumer goods sell their
brands to consumers through common independent retailers (e.g., supermarkets and convenience stores for
grocery products, department stores, specialty stores
for consumer electronics, sporting goods, etc.). There
has been substantial theoretical research on such channel structures (e.g., McGuire and Staelin 1983, Choi
1991, Lee and Staelin 1997). This stream of research has
analyzed the optimal behavior of channel members under alternative assumptions about vertical strategic interactions between manufacturers and retailers. Researchers of the new empirical industrial organization
(e.g., Kadiyali et al. 1996, 1999) have studied the competitive interactions between manufacturers (horizontal
strategic interaction). Decision support systems for promotion planning make assumptions about the pricing
rules used by retailers (e.g., Silva-Risso et al. 1999 assume constant margin, Tellis and Zufryden 1995 assume category-profit maximization). The appropriateness of such assumptions for any specific market is an
empirical question. Our goal in this paper is to empirically infer (1) the vertical strategic interaction (VSI) between manufacturers and retailer, (2) the horizontal
strategic interaction (HSI) between manufacturers simultaneously with the VSI, and (3) the pricing rule
used by a retailer.
The approach in this paper is particularly appealing because it can be used with widely available scanner data, where there is no information on wholesale
prices. Researchers usually have no access to wholesale prices. Manufacturers have access to their own
wholesale prices, but usually have only limited information on competitors wholesale prices. In the absence of wholesale prices, we derive formulae for
wholesale prices using game-theoretic solution techniques under the specific assumptions of vertical and
horizontal strategic interaction, demand functional
form, and retailer pricing rules. We then embed the
formulae for wholesale prices into the estimation
equations.1 While our empirical illustration is using
1
scanner data without wholesale prices, the model itself is easily applicable to the situation where wholesale prices are available by using the derived formulae for wholesale prices as additional estimation
equations in the model.
Relationship with Previous Research
For a quick overview of the relative contribution of
this paper, we compare related papers in the literature in Table 1.
Several papers in the new empirical industrial organization (NEIO) tradition have attempted to infer
competitive interactions underlying pricing behavior
among manufacturers (HSI) using national-level data
(for example, see Roy et al. 1994 and Kadiyali 1996).
In these papers, retailer behavior is not modeled. One
justification for this is that the focus is on competition
at the national level. Furthermore, any particular retailers strategic behavior will be lost in the data aggregation across retailers, and hence, is irrelevant for
the level at which the analysis is done.
Because manufacturers do tailor their marketing
mix to local market conditions (Manning et al. 1998,
Nichols 1987), NEIO researchers have recently
shifted their focus to analyzing HSI among manufacturers in local markets using scanner data. But
at this local level, retailer strategic behavior can
have a significant influence on a manufacturers
price-setting behavior. Therefore, retailers interaction with manufacturers (VSI) needs to be accounted for. A further complication when using scanner
data is that wholesale prices are unavailable to the
researcher. As a result, to analyze manufacturer
wholesale-pricing behavior, the wholesale prices
need to be inferred from the data.
Kadiyali et al. (1996, 1999) infer wholesale prices
by making a simplifying assumption about the VSI.
They assume that the retailer is nonstrategic and
charges an exogenous constant margin. This assumpshares) based on the parameters of the demand model (which are
assumed to be completely known with no econometric error). An
econometric model, however, is used to estimate the parameters of
the demand model assuming that the observed market shares and
retail prices are an outcome of optimal firm behavior conditional
on the underlying parameters of the demand model.
245
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
Manufacturer-Retailer
Interaction
Demand Functional
Form
Wholesale
Price Information Available
Estimated
NA
NA
Linear
NA
Estimated
Bertrand assumed
Bertrand assumed
Manufacturer Stackelberg
Vertical Nash
Manufacturer Stackelberg,
vertical Nash, and retailer Stackelberg models
(with Bertrand among
manufacturers)
1. CV estimated
2. Manufacturer Stackelberg, vertical nash, and
retailer Stackelberg models (but with Bertrand
among manufacturers)
Manufacturer Stackelberg,
vertical Nash
Constant margin
Category profit
Category profit
Linear
Logit
Linear, estimates LAAIDs without structural pricing equations
No
No
No
Category profit
No
Yes
No
Cannot separately
identify from reaction to retailer
Estimated
246
Retailer Pricing
Rule
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
247
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
In summary, we choose from the following strategic interactions and demand models:
(1) Vertical strategic interaction: manufacturer
Stackelberg and vertical Nash;
(2) Horizontal strategic interaction: Bertrand, tacit
collusion. We also estimate a continuous conjectural
variation (CV) parameter6;
(3) Retailer pricing rule: category-profit-maximization, brand-profit-maximization, constant markup;
(4) Demand functional form: logit, multiplicative.
Section 2 describes the model. Section 3 describes
the data, the estimation procedure, and the results.
Section 4 concludes with a discussion of limitations
of the model and suggestions for future research.
2. Model
Figure 1 represents the schematic model of the market
that we analyze: Two manufacturers sell through a
common retailer to consumers. Consumers make
their choices after observing the retail prices. In the
manufacturer Stackelberg models, the manufacturers
choose wholesale prices first; the retailer chooses retail prices after observing the wholesale prices. In the
vertical Nash models, the manufacturers and the re-
248
Figure 1
tailer choose their prices simultaneously. Manufacturers choose their wholesale prices simultaneously. In
the figure, one-sided arrows represent sequential decisions and double-sided arrows indicate simultaneous decisions. The two main assumptions embedded in the figure are that (1) there are two
manufacturers in the market and (2) that manufacturers sell through one retailer. We justify both of
these assumptions below.
ASSUMPTION 1. There are two manufacturers in the market.
We focus our empirical analysis on the two largest
brands in the yogurt and peanut butter categories.
This is reasonable for our purposes because the two
largest brands have a very large market share (82%
for yogurt and 65% for peanut butter). Other brands
have relatively low market share of less than 10% in
this market. Private labels have a minuscule market
share in these categories in these stores. Hence, the
use of private labels for strategic purposes is not a
serious issue as in the studies by Kadiyali et al. (2000)
and Putsis and Dhar (1999). While it is possible to
extend model development to additional brands,
solving for the optimal vertical strategic reactions becomes computationally cumbersome.
ASSUMPTION 2. Manufacturers sell through one retailer.
The primary effect of this assumption is that we do
not model any effect of retail competition. This may
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
i 1, 2,
(1)
249
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
the intrinsic attraction of brand i, and it is the unobservable (to the econometrician, but observable to
the firm and the consumer) component of utility. U it
is the average utility across consumers for brand i in
period t. We assume that ijt follows an i.i.d. Type-I
extreme value distribution, leading to the logit model.
To allow for the market share of the two inside
brands to expand and contract over different periods
with the choice of the marketing mix, we allow for
nonpurchases (through an outside good) denoted by
i 0. We normalize the utility of the outside good to
zero across periods. That is, we assume U0t 0.9 The
market share for each brand is given by
exp(Uit )
sit
1
exp(U )
2
k1
i 0, 1, 2.
(2)
kt
i 1, 2. (3)
Equation (3) is the demand-side estimation equation. The term it serves as the error term in the estimation equation. As discussed in Besanko et al.
(1998) and Villas-Boas and Winer (1999), these error
terms can capture the effects of manufacturer advertising and consumer promotions that we do not explicitly model in this paper.
Modeling the different correlations in ijt between the inside goods
and the outside good using a nested logit model would lead to a
richer and more flexible formulation. However, this prevents solving
for the supply-side estimation equations in closed form.
250
p1t
st
p t
s1t
p
2t
s2t
p1t
s2t
p2t
1t s1t (1 s1t )
2t s1t s2t
1t s1t s2t
,
2t s2t (1 s2t )
(4)
where it dp dit fp f it pi .
The Multiplicative Model. The multiplicative demand model was
fii fij dii dij
qit a i pitbii p bij
jt f it f jt dit djt .
For estimation, we used the log-log model, by taking the logs of the above equation on both sides and
adding a normal additive error. The derivatives with
respect to price for the multiplicative model are well
known.
Retailer Model
We derive the pricing equations for the retailer under
different types of VSI for the logit model. For the multiplicative model, the equations can be derived similarly.
For the category-profit-maximizing retailer the objective is to maximize category profits in period t.
Since consumers who buy other than the two brands
that we analyze may contribute to retailer profits, we
assume that the outside good gives a constant contribution to retailer profit. Denoting the margin from the
outside good as m0, the retailer objective is given by
Rt [( p 1t w1t )s1t ( p 2t w2t )s2t m0 s0t ]Mt ,
(5)
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
i 1, 2.
(6)
Because the retailer is a follower in the manufacturer Stackelberg games, the retailer does not incorporate manufacturer reactions when choosing retail
prices. In the vertical Nash game also, the retailer
does not incorporate manufacturer reactions, due to
the simultaneous nature of the game. Hence, the firstorder conditions and the pricing equations are identical for both the manufacturer Stackelberg models
and vertical Nash models.
For the retailer maximizing category profits, the
first-order conditions imply
[]
[]
s2t
0,
p it
(7)
Substituting the price derivatives from (4) and solving the first-order conditions give us the retail-pricing
equation
1
s
s
1t 2t
1t
1t s0t
2t s0t
p w 1
p1t
w1t
2t
Retail
price
2t
2t
m.
s1t
s
2t
1t s0t
2t s0t
(8)
(1 s1t ) 2 (1 s2t )
(1 s1t )(1 s2t ) (s1t s2t ) 2
pt
wt
2t
(1 s2t ) 2 (s1t s2t )
1t (1 s 1t )(1 s 2t ) (s 1t s 2t ) 2
2t
(1
s2t
2t
(10)
Wholesale
price
Retail margin
w1t
2t
2t
w1t
2t
w1t
2t
(11)
Retail
margin
wt
p 1t
w 2t
p2t
w1t
Wholesale
price
Retail margin
[]
2t
Retail
price
Rt
s
0 sit ( p it wit ) 1t 0,
pit
p it
w1t
Wholesale
price
i 1, 2.
p1t
Rt
s
0 sit ( p 1t w1t m0 ) 1t
p it
p it
( p2t w2t m0 )
p w
1t (1 s1t )
1 s
s
p2t
w2t
1t
2t
s1t 10
.
1 s2t
(12)
1t
(1 s1t ) 2 (s1t s2t )
(13)
251
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
p t
1
wt
0
0
.
1
(wjt cjt )
(14)
w1t
pt
wt
p 1t
w 2t
p2t
w1t
1m
p2t
w2t
0
.
1m
sjt p1t
sjt p 2t
0,
p 1t wit
p 2t wit
i 1, 2;
M
sit p 1t
sit p 2t
it
sit (wit cit )
wit
p 1t wit
p 2t wit
st
j i,
w p (w c ) 0,
p t st
t
(17)
where
(15)
1 1
1
j i,
(16)
252
0 1
1
M
it (w it c it )s it M t (w jt c jt )s it M t F it ,
i 1, 2;
p s
t t
wt p t
st ,
(18)
p s
t t
wt p t
st
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
pt
Retailer Margin
s1t
s2t
1t 1t 0 2t s0t
1t (1 s1t )
2t (1 s2t )
Vertical Nash
Category profit maximization
s1t
(1 s1t )
1t
1t s0t
s2t
2t s0t
m0
s1t
s2t
2t s0t
1t s0t
2t
Vertical Nash
Brand profit maximization
1t
2t (1 s2t )
st
Wholesale Margin
rt .
(19)
Retail
margin
pt st
wt p t
m0
s1t s2t
2t s0t
1t s0t
2t
Manufacturer Stackelberg
Brand profit maximization
Manufacturer cost
ct
ww m
1t
2t
Model
pt
Manufacturer Stackelberg
Category profit maximization
1 s s
Manufacturer Stackelberg
Brand profit maximization
1t
2t
s1t
1 s2t
(1 s1t ) 2 (1 s2t )
(1 s1t )(1 s2t ) (s1t s2t ) 2
Vertical Nash
Category profit maximization
10 01
Vertical Nash
Brand profit maximization
10 01
1 0 m
w
1t
(1 s1t ) 2 (s1t s2t )
(1 s2t ) 2 (1 s1t )
0
1m
253
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
pt ct
11 s2t ( pw12t sp21t pw11t sp 11t )]/Dett }
1
s
t I
1m
pt
st (1 m).
Hence,
r 2t 2t ,
pt ct (1 m)
where
st .
(21)
is
pt 0 t
(20)
254
st
I
p t
s
t t I
pt
st ,
(22)
i 1, 2.
(23)
sit
sit pjt
itM
0 sit ( p it wit )
0,
p it
pit
pjt p it
i 1, 2;
j i.
st
I ( p t wt ) 0,
pt
(24)
where
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
1
21
12
1
and the operator denotes element-by-element multiplication of a matrix and I is the identity matrix. We
can interpret the ij terms as the measure of coordination in pricing across brands by the retailer. Therefore,
pt wt
s
t I
p t
st .
(25)
3. Empirical Analysis
Data
We do our analysis on the yogurt and peanut butter
categories on two EDLP stores from two different regional chains in a suburban market.12 These stores
happen to be the two largest in this market. The data
are for a period of 104 weeks during 19911993. In
the yogurt market, we analyze competition between
the two largest brands, Dannon and Yoplait. Together, they constitute about 82% of sales in this category in this market. In the peanut butter market, we
analyze competition between the two largest brands
in the market: Skippy and Jif. Together they constitute about 66% of sales in this category. The next
largest national brand has less than 10% of market
share in both categories in these stores. Private labels
have a very small market share in these stores.
Because store-level data do not provide any information on the share of the no purchase alternative,
12
These stores claimed to be EDLP. We verified these claims by comparing the variance of prices between these self-professed EDLP
chains and self-professed high-low chains in this market. As expected, the price variance in the EDLP chains is about half of that
of high-low chains. Furthermore, consistent with Bell and Lattin
(1998), EDLP chains had a lower average price than the high-low
chains.
we follow BGJ in using information from the household-level data to compute the share of no purchase. Assuming that the panel is representative of
the universe of consumers, BGJ take the share of no
purchase as the proportion of store visits by the panelists in the data that did not lead to a purchase in
the category.13
Estimation
Our estimation equations are the demand equations
in (3) and the pricing equations in (20). As discussed
earlier, details such as consumer promotions and advertising are not available in scanner data and are
unobserved by the researcher and therefore captured
by the demand error terms jt. However, manufacturers, retailers, and consumers have information on
these, and therefore they affect the manufacturers
and retailers choice of prices and the consumers decision to buy. Villas-Boas and Winer (1999) and BGJ
offer evidence that this is indeed true. We do the same
variation of the Hausman (1978) test that BGJ use and
find price is endogenous. We use lagged price as an
instrument in conducting this test.
Because features and displays are also strategic decisions made by the retailer, theoretically they should
be considered endogenous. Putsis and Dhar (1999)
found that features and displays are indeed endogenous. We test for endogeneity of features and display
in two ways. First we follow Villas-Boas and Winer
(1999) and look at the correlation between estimated
residuals (using both three-stage least square (3SLS)
and full-information maximum likelihood (FIML),
where only price was treated as endogenous and feature and display were treated as exogenous) and feature and display. The correlations were not significant
(p values .2), indicating that there would be no
endogeneity bias if feature and display were treated
as exogenous. One may note that in our demand
model, we allow for interaction effects between price
and feature and between price and display. This in13Because multiple purchases in a store visit are fairly common in
the yogurt category, in this category we also reweight store visits
by the number of purchases made during the visit in computing
the no purchase share. The results, however, are not very sensitive
to the reweighting.
255
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
teraction variable was crucial in eliminating the endogeneity bias problem.14 The second test we do is a
variation of the Hausman test. We estimate two models with price treated as endogenous using 3SLS: (i)
with feature and display as endogenous and using
instruments (lagged feature and display) and (ii) with
feature and display as exogenous. If feature and display were indeed exogenous, then both models would
be consistent, but the first models estimates would
have a higher variance because it is an instrumental
variable method. However if feature and display were
endogenous, only the first model would be consistent.
If q denotes the vector of parameters to be estimated,
1 V
2)1(q1 q2),
then the test statistic (q1 q2)(V
where V is the estimated covariance matrix, is distributed as 2(#q) distribution, where #q is the number of parameters in the vector q. We find that the
null hypothesis of exogeneity cannot be rejected (p
.17).
This endogeneity of prices, however, implies that
we still need to use an instrumental variables estimation procedure. Furthermore, errors across the
supply and estimation equations are correlated due
to price. We therefore need to use a simultaneous
equation instrumental variables estimation procedure
such as FIML or 3SLS. The major advantage of FIML
estimation is that we do not need to provide instruments for prices, because the optimal instruments are
generated within the estimation procedure. To compute the optimal instruments in FIML, however, we
need to make the normal distribution assumption on
the error terms. That is, we assume that 1t, 2t, 1t,
2t are assumed multivariate normal. In 3SLS there is
no need to make the multivariate normal assumption,
but we need to provide instruments. We prefer FIML
in this paper, because formal tests for nonnested
models (Vuong 1989) are available using likelihood
estimates.
14We briefly explain the intuition for why modeling the interaction
can help in eliminating the endogeneity bias problem. Let y1 x11
x22 x1x23 be the true model. Suppose x1 is endogenous,
but x2 is not. Instrumenting x1 will eliminate the endogeneity bias,
but suppose we only fit the model y1 x11 x22 1, then 1
x1x23. In this case we will find that cov(1, x1) 0 and
cov(1, x2) 0. Therefore, it will seem that both variables are endogenous if we do not include the interaction term.
256
Note that we cannot use FIML if we do not have the same number
of endogenous parameters and equations.
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
Manufacturer
Interaction
Tacit collusion
Bertrand competition
Store 1
Store 2
Store 1
Store 2
196.90
247.27
240.66
212.96
()
205.19
(2.259)
202.38
(2.028)
208.25
(2.643)
207.29
(2.529)
203.66
(2.040)
208.25
(2.643)
266.78
(6.558)
204.39
(2.147)
211.03
(2.949)
()
298.29
(2.101)
292.19
(1.972)
321.17
(2.529)
309.35
(2.318)
249.9
(2.030)
309.35
(2.318)
318.84
(2.489)
310.93
(2.347)
325.85
(2.608)
()
289.24
(2.734)
259.44
(1.700)
288.82
(2.722)
297.95
(2.969)
271.11
(2.164)
288.82
(2.722)
266.78
(2.005)
291.55
(2.798)
303.71
(3.114)
()
265.47
(2.132)
257.41
(1.961)
275.28
(2.322)
280.95
(2.426)
269.08
(2.204)
275.28
(2.322)
277.74
(2.368)
301.75
(2.772)
307.85
(3.821)
Note: The Vuong test statistic is with respect to the best-fitting model (with the highest log-likelihood).
257
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
Intercept (Dannon)
Intercept (Yoplait)
Feature
Display
FeaturePrice
DisplayPrice
Price
Marginal cost (Dannon) outside
good retail margin
Marginal cost (Yoplait) outside
good retail margin
Store 2
Parameter
SE
Parameter
SE
2.740
2.920
2.580
2.122
4.378
0.800
6.364
0.563
0.473
0.939
2.227
1.356
3.447
0.633
4.870
6.170
2.750
0.950
3.230
0.230
10.060
4.539
4.616
2.479
4.078
3.883
6.507
7.669
0.495
0.617
0.349
1.783
0.639
3.445
0.678
9.180
7.490
7.110
2.290
6.080
1.890
11.310
0.337
0.042
8.100
0.281
0.050
5.620
0.457
0.045
10.250
0.428
0.053
8.060
Intercept (Skippy)
Intercept (Jif)
Feature
Display
FeaturePrice
DisplayPrice
Price
Marginal cost (Skippy) outside
good retail margin
Marginal cost (Jif) outside good
retail margin
Parameter
SE
Parameter
SE
10.414
10.523
3.470
14.400
4.942
12.544
10.539
1.538
1.528
4.303
2.327
4.985
2.284
1.326
6.770
6.890
0.810
6.190
0.990
5.490
7.950
9.504
9.616
8.807
5.023
8.066
2.944
9.049
2.162
2.142
2.376
2.970
2.221
2.895
1.831
4.400
4.490
3.710
1.690
3.630
1.020
4.940
0.718
0.054
13.220
0.798
0.082
9.760
0.714
0.056
12.870
0.771
0.086
9.020
258
Store 2
The author notes that Lee and Staelin (1997) show that Stackelberg
leadership leads to greater profitability (and therefore implies greater power) only in the case of demand models characterized by VSS.
The power balance argument the author makes holds only because
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
259
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
Table 7 CV Estimates for the Logit Model: Category-Profit-Maximizing Retailer and Constant-Margin Retailer
Store 2
Yogurt
4.293
0.286
0.640
5.420
4.601
0.537
1.289
6.462
1
2
1
2
Peanut Butter
Store 1
Store 2
Store 1
Store 2
0.122
0.154
0.232
0.252
0.126
0.149
0.262
0.232
0.151
0.399
0.297
0.454
0.147
0.316
0.204
0.693
Store 2
11.026
2.488
2.328
10.505
8.755
2.583
2.118
8.370
4. Conclusion
In this paper, we empirically inferred the VSI between manufacturers and retailers and the HSI be19
Since FIML does not converge for the CV models, we use 3SLS
for estimation.
260
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
261
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
p1t
1
1 s1t p1t
s1t p2t
1 2 s0t
w1t
s0t
1t p1t w1t
p2t w1t
s1t
1t
1 s1t p1t
s1t p2t
2t p1t w1t
p2t w1t
s1t p1t
s1t p2t
s2t p1t
p2t w1t
p1t w1t
1t w 1t
s2t
2t
s2t p2t
.
p2t w1t
.
w1t
(1 s1t s2t ) w1t
(1 s1t s2t ) w1t
(A1)
Similarly,
p2t
s1t
p1t
s2t
p2t
.
w1t
(1 s1t s2t ) w1t
(1 s1t s2t ) w1t
(A2)
Solving (A1) and (A2) for p1t /w1t and p2t /w1t, we have
p1t /w1t 1 s1t and p2t /w1t s1t. By symmetry, p2t /w2t
1 s2t and p1t /w2t s2t.
These reactions are summarized in Equation (12) of the paper.
p1t
1
s1t p1t
s1t p2t
1 2
1t
,
w1t
1t (1 s1t ) 2
p1t w1t
p2t w1t
p2t
1
s2t p1t
s2t p2t
2
2t
.
w1t
2t (1 s2t ) 2
p1t w1t
p2t w1t
Substituting the share derivatives with respect to prices from
Equation (5), we get
p1t
s1t
p1t
2t s1t s2t p2t
1
,
w1t
(1 s1t ) w1t
1t (1 s1t ) 2 w1t
(A3)
p2t
1t s1t s2t p1t
s2t
p2t
.
w1t
2t (1 s2t ) 2 w1t
(1 s2t ) w1t
(A4)
Solving (A3) and (A4) for p1t /w1t and p2t /w1t, we have
p1t
(1 s1t ) 2 (1 s2t )
w1t
(1 s1t )(1 s2t ) (s1t s2t ) 2
and
p2t
1t
(1 s1t ) 2 (s1t s2t )
.
w1t
2t (1 s1t )(1 s2t ) (s1t s2t ) 2
By symmetry,
Appendix
p2t
(1 s2t ) 2 (1 s1t )
w2t
(1 s1t )(1 s2t ) (s1t s2t ) 2
p1t
2t
(1 s2t ) 2 (s1t s2t )
.
w2t
1t (1 s1t )(1 s2t ) (s1t s2t ) 2
262
and
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
References
Agrawal, D. 1996. Effect on brand loyalty on advertising and trade
promotions: A game theoretic analysis with empirical evidence. Marketing Sci. 15(1) 86108.
Allenby, G. M. 1989. A unified approach to identifying, estimating
and testing demand structures with aggregate scanner data.
Marketing Sci. 8 265280.
, P. Rossi. 1991. There is no aggregation bias: Why aggregate
macro logit models work. J. Bus. Econom. Statist. 9(1) 115.
Armstrong, M. K. 1991. Retailer response to trade promotion: An
incremental analysis of forward buying and retail promotion.
Unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of Texas at Dallas, Dallas, TX.
Bell, D., J. Lattin. 1998. Shopping behavior and consumer preference
for store price format: Why large basket shoppers prefer
EDLP. Marketing Sci. 17(1) 6688.
Berkowitz, E. N., R. A. Kerin, S. W. Hartley, W. Rudelius. 1999. Marketing, 6th ed. Irwin, McGraw Hill, New York.
Berry, S., J. Levinsohn, A. Pakes. 1995. Automobile prices in marketing equilibrium. Econometrica 63(4) 841890.
Besanko, D., D. Dranove, M. Shanley. 1996. The Economics of Strategy.
John Wiley and Sons, New York.
Besanko, D., S. Gupta, D. Jain. 1998. Logit demand estimation under
competitive pricing behavior: An equilibrium framework.
Management Sci. 44(1) 15331547.
Boulding, W., R. Staelin. 1995. Identifying generalizable effects of
strategic actions on firm performance: The case of demandside returns to R&D spending. Marketing Sci. 14(3) G222G236.
Bresnahan, T. 1989. Industries and market power. R. Schmalensee,
R. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization. North Holland, Amsterdam, The Netherlands.
Bucklin, R. E., S. Gupta. 1999. Commercial use of UPC scanner data:
Industry and academic perspectives. Marketing Sci. 18(3) 247
273.
, J. Lattin. 1992. A model of product category competition
among grocery retailers. J. Retailing 68(3) 271294.
Carlton, D. W., J. M. Perloff. 1994. Modern Industrial Organization.
Addison Wesley, Reading, MA.
Chevalier, M., R. C. Curhan. 1976. Retail promotions as a function
of trade promotions. Sloan Management Rev. (Fall) 1932.
Chintagunta, P. 1999. Investigating category profit maximizing behavior at a retail chain. Working Paper, University of Chicago,
Chicago, IL.
Choi, S. C. 1991. Price competition in a channel structure with a
common retailer. Marketing Sci. 10(Fall) 271296.
Christen, M., S. Gupta, J. C. Porter, R. Staelin, D. R. Wittink. 1997.
Using market-level data to understand promotional effects in
a nonlinear model. J. Marketing Res. 34(3) 322334.
Cotterill, R. W., W. P. Putsis. 2000. Testing theory: Do assumptions
of models of vertical strategic interaction of national and store
brands meet the market test? J. Retailing
,
. 2001. Do models of vertical strategic interaction for na-
263
SUDHIR
Structural Analysis of Manufacturer Pricing
This paper was received October 7, 1998, and was with the author 19 months for 4 revisions; processed by Scott Neslin.
264