Kuo-Ping Chang : Model-Free Option Prices
Kuo-Ping Chang : Model-Free Option Prices
Kuo-Ping Chang : Model-Free Option Prices
Kuo-Ping Chang*
First version
Second version
June 2014
August 2014
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2459464
* Department of Quantitative Finance, National Tsing Hua University, Kuang Fu Rd., Hsinchu 300,
Taiwan, E-mail: [email protected].
ABSTRACT
In this paper, I have used simple arbitrage argument to derive a dozen of model-free option price
properties. In addition to deriving the Greeks under model-free framework, the results show that first, in
contrast to the traditional view, a European call (put) option for a non-dividend-paying asset can also be a
European call (put) option for any other non-dividend-paying asset, and every non-dividend-paying asset
is also both a European call option and a European put option for any other non-dividend-paying asset.
Second, in some cases the time value of the European put option can be negative, and adjust the exercise
price of an option can decrease or even erase the time value of the option.
Theorem under the binomial option pricing model to examine these properties.
Key words: the Greeks, the time value of option, the Arbitrage Theorem.
1. Introduction
Start from the seminal work of Black and Scholes (1973), various option price properties have been
derived under the Black-Scholes-Merton and binomial option pricing models. Up to now, there are only
a few model-free option price properties developed in the literature.
under model-free framework, the results show that first, in contrast to the traditional view, a European
call (put) option for a non-dividend-paying asset can also be a European call (put) option for any other
non-dividend-paying asset, and every non-dividend-paying asset is also both a European call option and a
European put option for any other non-dividend-paying asset.
the European put option can be negative, and adjust the exercise price of an option can decrease or even
erase the time value of the option.
A call option gives its owner the right to purchase an asset (the underlying asset) for a given price
(the exercise or strike price: K ) on or before a given date (the expiration date: T ).
owner the right to sell an asset for a given price on or before the expiration date.
date. Because American options have more choices, they are more valuable than European ones.
The following are some important properties of options.1
Property 2.1
Consider two portfolios at t 0 , where the underlying asset is one share of a non-dividend-paying
stock, and the simple risk-free interest rate between t 0 and t T is r :
Portfolio A: one European call option c with exercise price K , and cash
K
deposited in a bank;
1 r
Properties 2.1-2.3 and the call option part of Property 2.5.1 are the same as in Merton (1973).
Portfolio B: one European put option p with exercise price K , and a share of the stock S 0 .
On the expiration date t T , both portfolios give exactly the same payoff: Max[ST , K ] . Thus, the
costs of the two portfolios at t 0 must be the same:
K
S0 p .
1 r
(1)
Equation (1) is called the put-call parity. Suppose Equation (1) doesnt hold:
Case 1: At t 0 , c
K
S 0 p . Then an investor can immediately get net profit by adopting the
1 r
K
from a bank; and (ii) buy one share of the stock
1 r
and one put option. At t T , if ST K , the investor obtains zero profit by letting the put option
expire, selling the share of the stock to the holder of the call option at the price K , and giving K to the
bank. If ST K , the investor obtains zero profit by exercising the put option and giving K to the
bank.
Case 2: At t 0 , c
K
S 0 p . Then an investor can immediately get net profit by adopting the
1 r
following strategy: (i) short-sell one share of the stock and sell one put option; and (ii) buy one call and
deposit
K
in a bank. At t T , if ST K , the investor obtains zero profit by using cash K from
1 r
the bank to exchange for one share of the stock from the holder of the put option, and then give back one
share of the stock. If ST K , the investor obtains zero profit by using cash K from the bank to
exercise the call option, and then give back one share of the stock.
From equation (1) it is easy to find that since call and put options are rights, i.e., their values cannot
be negative, we have the following lower bounds for European call and put options:
Property 2.2
c S0
K
K
S0 .
and p
1 r
1 r
If at t 0 , c S 0
K
, then an investor can immediately obtain net profit by short-selling one
1 r
share of the stock, buying one call option, and depositing cash
K
in a bank. At t T , if ST K ,
1 r
the investor obtains zero profit by using cash K from the bank to exercise the call option, and then give
back one share of the stock. If ST K , the investor can obtain net profit: K ST 0 by getting K
from the bank and spending ST to buy one share of the stock from the market, and then giving back that
share of the stock.
If at t 0 , p
K
S 0 , then an investor can immediately obtain net profit by borrowing cash
1 r
K
from a bank and buying one share of the stock and one put option. At t T , if ST K , the
1 r
investor can obtain net profit: ST K 0 by selling that share of the stock for ST and giving K to
the bank.
If ST K , the investor obtains zero profit by exercising the put option and giving K to the
bank.
Property 2.3
c .
At
K
K
S p , and if S K 0 , we will have C c S
S K , i.e., the
1 ( r / 2)
1 ( r / 2)
market value of the American call option must be greater than the gain of exercising the call option. For
example, suppose that at t 0 , an issuer issues an American call option with K $102 .
At
t T / 2 , if the stock price is S $105 , then the American call options value C must be greater
than $3 ( S K ) . If C cannot be sold at a price more than $3, it will mean that no one (including
the seller) in the market believes that the stock price at t [T / 2, T ] will be greater than $105. This is,
of course, contradicts the previous assumption that at t T / 2 , S $105 .2
Property 2.4
In the put-call parity, if c p , then K S 0 (1 r ) , i.e., the exercise price must equal the
c
c
p
p
0 (or
0) and
0 or (
0) . Also,
K
K
K
K
The difference in the values of two otherwise identical European options cannot be
K
and
1 r
K
, where K K 'K , c c'c and p p' p .
1 r
K
K'
K ' K
S 0 p and c'
S 0 p' , we obtain: c'c
p' p .
1 r
1 r
1 r
K
1 r
K
.
1 r
Note that equation (1), the put-call parity, is also a restatement of the Modigliani-Miller capital
structure irrelevancy proposition (i.e., the market value of the firm is independent of its capital structure).
In
K
K
where
is the riskless debt. At t T , if the
1 r
1 r
For an underlying asset, the relationship between the forward price F0 and the spot price S 0 is: F0 S 0 (1 r ) . For
example, suppose at t 0 , S0 $100 and r 2% . Then the seller of the forward contract will ask for at least $102, i.e.,
she will want: F0 S 0 (1 r ) . However, the seller cannot sell at a price more than $102. This is because the buyer of the
forward contract can always turn to the spot market to buy one unit of the underlying asset at S 0 $100 . Without default,
spend $100 at t 0 is equivalent to spend $102 at t T .
equityholders pay K to the debtholders, then the equityholders can have the firm, ST .4
cannot be negative, we must have:
Because debt
K
p and hence, 0 c S 0 . If at t T the equityholders
1 r
need to pay more to the debtholders to have the firm (i.e., K K 'K 0 ), then at t 0 , c 0 ,
p 0 and 0 S0 S0 S0 c
p imply: lower equity value, higher debt value, no
1 r
Property 2.5.2
K
.
1 r
c
c
p
p
0 (or
0) and
0 (or
0) .
r
r
r
r
(i) At t 0 , from S0 c
p , if only r increases ( r r'r 0 ) and other factors
1 r
(including S 0 and K ) remain constant, then the firms debt value will decrease, i.e.,
K
K
K
K
p'
p , and 0 S0 S0 c'c
c
0.
r
K
K
K
p
, and risky debt is:
1 r
1 r
1 r
p
K K
K
K
0 .
remain constant, we will have: 0
p' p . Thus,
r
1 r' 1 r 1 r' 1 r
K
K
Because
K
K
K
K
and c
.
1 r' 1 r
1 r' 1 r
Property 2.5.3
c
c
0 (or
0) .
S0
S0
At t T , if S T K , then the equityholders will not pay K , and the debtholders will have the firm S T .
At t 0 , from S0 c
p , suppose only S 0 increases ( S 0 S ' S 0 0 ) and other factors
1 r
Then S 0 c p , and:
c
p
0 ) and p 0 (i.e.,
0 ). This is impossible since S 0 0 . If
S0
S0
this case holds, it will mean that increasing the market value of the firm will make both equityholders and
debtholders suffered.
Case 2: c 0 (i.e.,
c
p
0 ) and p 0 (i.e.,
0 ).
S0
S0
market value of the firm increases), the equity value will decrease, the debt value will increase, and there
will be some wealth transferring from the equity to the debt.
the debt is riskless, i.e., S 0 c
no effect on the debt.
K
, S 0 0 only increases the equity value: c S 0 0 and has
1 r
c
p
0 ) and p 0 (i.e.,
0 ).
S0
S0
c
p
0 ) and p 0 (i.e.,
0 ). This means that S 0 0 will benefit
S0
S0
Property 2.5.4
c p
c p
(or
) for any x S 0 , r, K .
x x
x x
c p
c p
c p
and
.
u u
d d
In the finance literature, the intrinsic value of an option is defined as the maximum of zero and the
value the option would have if it were exercised immediately. For a call option, its intrinsic value is
Max[ S K , 0] . For a put option, its intrinsic value is Max[ K S , 0] . The time value of an option
which arises from the time left to maturity is defined as the difference between option value and intrinsic
value.
Property 2.2, c S 0
K
and hence, TV c 0 .
1 r
From
Even without changing the expiration dates, issuers of European options can adjust
For S 0 K , if the exercise price increases from K to K ' , i.e., K K 'K 0 , and S 0 K ' ,
TV c
0
K
TV p
0
K
K
, and K 0 implies c 0 and p 0 .
1 r
(ii) For S 0 K , if the exercise price drops from K to K ' , i.e., K K 'K 0 , and S 0 K ' ,
TV p
0
K
TV c
0
K
K
, and K 0 implies p 0 and c 0 .
1 r
(iii) For S 0 K ,
if K K 'K 0 , TV c c'( S0 K ' ) c (c'c) ( K ' K ) c K 0 and
and
TV c
0
K
TV p
0;
K
TV p
0,
K
and
Property 2.7.1
TV c
0.
K
almost surely ST K , then p 0 , and the European call option price is: c S 0
From Property 2.2, we know c cannot be less than S 0
K 5
.
1 r
K
. For example, a firm provides its
1 r
employees a stock option (a European call option) with K $10.2 , S 0 $200 , r 2% , and T is one
month. It is very unlikely that after one month, the firms stock price will be less than $10.2. Thus,
this call options price at t 0 should be: c S 0
an investor can sell one call option, borrow
$1 ( 191
K
$190 . If not, say, c $191, then at t 0
1 r
$10.2
from a bank, and buy one share of the stock to earn
1 2%
10.2
200) . At t T , ST K , say, ST $100 , the holder of the call option will spend
1 2%
$10.2 to exercise the option, and the investor will obtain zero profit by giving the share of the stock to the
holder and paying $10.2 to the bank.6
almost surely ST K , then c 0 , and the European put option price is: p
K
S0 .
1 r
Here c is also the value of a forward contract on the non-dividend-paying underlying asset. Suppose there already exists
a forward contract with K as its delivery price. Then, the value of this forward contract f at the current time, i.e., at
t 0 , is f ( F0 K ) /(1 r ) , where F0 is the forward price if both parties negotiated at the current time. Combine this
equation with F0 S 0 (1 r ) , the relationship between the forward price and the spot price, we get f S0 K /(1 r ) .
6
In the Black-Scholes option pricing model, the European call option price is:
where
d1
ln(
S0
2
) (r
)T
K
2
, d 2 d1 T .
T
K
S 0 . For example, issuing a European
1 r
month, the stock price will be more than $204. Thus, the put options price at t 0 should be:
K
S 0 $190 .
1 r
If not, say, p $191 , then at t 0 an investor can sell one put option,
$204
204
) . At
in a bank to earn $1 ( 191 10
1 2%
1 2%
t T , ST K , say, ST $100 , the holder of the put option will exercise the option, and the investor
will obtain zero profit by transferring $204 from the bank to the holder and giving back one share of the
stock.
Property 2.7.3
From Properties 2.7.1 and 2.7.2, the Greeks for the European call and put options are:
c
1
p
1
c
K
p
K
p
c
0,
0,
0;
0.
1 0,
1 0 ,
2
K 1 r
K 1 r
r (1 r )
r (1 r ) 2
S0
S0
Property 2.7.4
From Property 2.7.1, c S 0
K
, the time value of the call option is:
1 r
TV c c ( S0 K ) S0
From Property 2.7.2, p
TV c
r
K
r
0.
( S0 K ) K
0 , and
K
1 r
1 r
1 r
K
S 0 , the time value of the put option is:
1 r
TV p p ( K S0 )
TV p
r
K
r
0.
S0 ( K S0 ) K
0 , and
K
1 r
1 r
1 r
the time value of the call option will disappear, and C c S 0 , i.e., the call is like a transferrable
restricted stock. These results and Property 2.6 show that, in addition to time, other factors can also
Since American call and put options can be exercised on or before the expiration date, their time values must be
non-negative.
Property 2.8
(i) For any two non-dividend-paying stocks with the same current share price S 0 , and the same
European call options exercise price K and expiration date T , suppose K is very small relative
to S 0 and T is short so that at t T almost surely ST K .
option prices at the current time must be the same: C c S 0
K
;
1 r
(ii) For any two non-dividend-paying stocks with the same current share prices S 0 , and the same
European put options exercise price K and expiration date T , suppose K is very big relative to
S 0 and T is short so that at t T almost surely ST K . Then, these two stocks put option
prices at the current time must be the same: p
K
S0 .
1 r
The above results show that an assets call or put option can directly be used as another assets call
or put option. This finding challenges the conventional view that an option must be derived from or
dependent on some specific underlying asset.
distributions) of the two underlying assets are irrelevant in pricing these options. To price these options
all we need are: K , r and S 0 , where K is determined by the issuer of options, r is determined by
the economy, and S 0 is influenced by both the economy and the individual company. This indicates
that an assets current price S 0 may reflect not only the assets past information but also the markets
expectations about the assets future performance.
Property 2.9
If c S 0
K
is a European call option for a non-dividend-paying asset, then it can
1 r
K
S0 p where t 0, 1, 2,..., T , and m is the risk-free interest rate in
(1 m)T
each period. If K is very small relative to S 0 and T is short so that at t T almost surely ST K , then p 0 , and
8
c
K
0 . If K is very big relative to S 0 and T is short so that
, and
T
T
(1 m)
p
K
0.
at t T almost surely ST K , then c 0 , and the European put option price is: p
S0 , and
T
T
(1 m)
the European call option price is: c S0
K
S 0 is a European
1 r
put option for a non-dividend-paying asset, then it can also be a European put option for any other
non-dividend-paying asset.
For example, suppose asset As European call option has K $10.2 where S 0 $200 , r 2% ,
and T is one month. It is very unlikely that after one month, asset As unit price will be less than
$10.2. Thus, the call options price at t 0 is: c S 0
K
$190 . If another asset Bs unit price
1 r
is $50, then we can let the underlying asset be four units of asset B, and this c $190 can also be asset
Bs call option.
Suppose asset Es European put option has K $204 where S 0 $10 , r 2% , and T is one
month. It is very unlikely that after one month, asset Es unit price will be more than $204. Thus, the
put options price at t 0 is: p
K
S 0 $190 . If another asset Fs unit price is $50, then we can
1 r
let the underlying asset be 0.2 units of asset F, and this p $190 can also be asset Fs put option.
Property 2.10
European put options for any other non-dividend-paying asset (including itself).
For example, suppose that for two assets, the first assets current unit prices is S 01 $200 , and the
second assets current unit price S02 $198 . Then S 02 can be written as:
(i) a European call option for one unit of the first asset: S 02 S 01
K
, where K $2.04 , r 2% ,
1 r
K
(0.1) S 01 , where K $222.36 ,
1 r
K
, where K $2.0196,
1 r
K
(0.1) S 02 , where
1 r
3. The Arbitrage Theorem and Properties of the Binomial Option Pricing Model
Chang (2012) has introduced the Gordan Theorem/the Arbitrage Theorem (see also Bazaraa et al.,
1993, p. 47).
System 2:
Ax 0
for some x R n
Atp 0
1
1
In System 2 of the Arbitrage Theorem, the vector p (which is not the same as the probability
measure in the real world) is usually termed as the risk neutral probability measure, and pi , i 1, ..., m ,
can be interpreted as the current price of one dollar received at the end of period if state i occurs.
If
the matrix A has rank m (i.e., the matrix has m independent rows), the risk neutral probability
measure p will be unique.
results.
Example 3.1
Assume a one-period, two states of nature world with no transaction costs. There are a money
market (Security 1) which provides 1 0.25 dollars at time one if one dollar is invested at time 0 (i.e.,
the risk-free interest rate is r 0.25 ), and two other securities (Security 2 and Security 3) with current
prices $4 and $500, respectively, which at time 1 provide:
In incomplete markets, assets may not be replicated, but with no arbitrage (i.e., System 2 of the Arbitrage Theorem has a
solution), they are still priced by the same (which may not be unique) risk neutral probability measure.
750
S 02 4
S 03 500
2
250
Security 2
Security 3
That is, at time one, when Security 2 provides $8, Security 3 will provide $750; and when Security 2
provides $2, Security 3 will provide $250. In this case, the two securities are not governed by the same
risk neutral probability measure (i.e., System 2 of the Arbitrage Theorem has no solution):
Security 1 :
Security 2 :
Security 3 :
1
1.25 (1 ) 1.25;
1 0.25
' 1 / 2
1 1
1
S 02 4
8 2 ; p'
1 0.25 2
2
1 ' 1 / 2
" 3 / 4
1 3
1
S 03 500
750 250 ; p"
1 0.25 4
4
1 " 1 / 4
S 01 1
i.e., we cannot find a vector p
, 0 1 , such that System 2 holds:
1
0
0 .
0
By System 1 of the Arbitrage Theorem, there must exist arbitrage strategies: e.g., at time 0, we can
short sell one share of Security 3, buy 60 shares of Security 2 and invest $260 ( 500 4 60) in the
money market, and at time 1 we can get net profit:
x1
1.25 1(1 0.25) 8 4(1 0.25) 750 500(1 0.25) 55 0
1.25 1(1 0.25) 2 4(1 0.25) 250 500(1 0.25) 60 = 195 > 0 .
1
When investors adopt this strategy, the time-0 price of Security 2 will go up and that of Security 3 will go
down. In equilibrium (with no arbitrage), the time-0 prices of the two securities will adjust to the point
2 / 3
that they all are priced by the same risk neutral probability measure, say, p
,
1 / 3
Security 2 :
Security 3 :
S 01 1
1 2
1
1.25 1.25
1 0.25 3
3
S 02 4.8
1 2
1
8 2
1 0.25 3
3
2
1 2
1
S 03 466
750 250
3 1 0.25 3
3
or
8 4.8(1 0.25)
2
750 466 (1 0.25)
3
2 4.8(1 0.25)
2
250 466 (1 0.25)
3
0
2 / 3
1 / 3 0 .
Since, in the above equation, the rank of the matrix is 2 (which equals the number of the states of the
2 / 3
nature), the market is complete, and the risk-neutral probability measure
must be unique. Also,
1 / 3
any security can be replicated by other two assets:
(1) Replicate Security 2s time-1 payment: At time 0, spend $4.8 (or short-sell one share of Security 2)
2
to buy n 0.012 shares of Security 3 and borrow $0.8 ( 466 0.012 4.8) from the money
3
market, and at time 1, we can get:
$8
750
(
1
0
.
25
)(
4
.
8
466
n) if the time - 1 price of Security 3 is $750
3
(2) Replicate Security 3s time-1 payment: At time 0, spend $466
3) to buy n 250/ 3 shares of Security 2 and deposit $66
market, and at time 1, we can get:
2
(or short-sell one share of Security
3
2
2
250
( 466 4.8
) in the money
3
3
3
Example 3.2
Assume a one-period, two states of nature world with no transaction costs. There already exists
two assets: a money market with the risk-free interest rate r 0.25 , and a contract (Contract A) with
time-0 price $10, which at time-1 is worth $16 if the economy growth rate is more than 3% and $6 if the
growth rate is less or equal to 3%. Now, suppose that another contract (Contract B) promises at time-1
to pay $60 if the growth rate is more than 3%, and $20 if the growth rate is less or equal to 3%. Then,
what will the time-0 price of Contract B be?
16
60
S 0B ?
S 0A 10
8
20
Contract A
Contract B
1.25
16
The money markets time-1 payment vector
and Contract As time-1 payment vector
1.25
8
are linearly independent, and the number of the linearly independent vectors equals the number of the
states of the nature. Hence, by System 2 of the Arbitrage Theorem, the market is complete, and with no
9 / 16
arbitrage, there exists a unique risk-neutral probability measure p
:
7 / 16
Money Mark et :
Contract A :
or
S 01 1
1 9
7
1.25 1.25
1 0.25 16
16
S02 10
1 9
7
16 8
1 0.25 16
16
9 / 16
7 / 16
0
0 .
Money Mark et :
Contract A :
Contract B :
S 01 1
1 9
7
1.25 1.25
1 0.25 16
16
S 0A 10
1 9
7
16 8
1 0.25 16
16
S 0B 34
1 9
7
60 20
1 0.25 16
16
(2)
or
60 34(1 0.25)
20 34(1 0.25)
0
9 / 16
7 / 16 0 .
Money Mark et :
Contract A :
Contract B :
S 01 1
1 9
7
1.25 1.25
1 0.25 16
16
S 0A 10
1 9
7
S 0B 34
1 9
7
(2)
That is, Contract A can be shown as a European call option c $10 for Contract B, where the exercise
price K is $44 if the time-1 price of Contract B is $60, and $12 if the time-1 price of Contract B is $20.
Contract B, on the other hand, can be shown as a European put option p $34 for Contract A, where
the exercise price K is $76 if the time-1 price of Contract A is $16, and $28 if the time-1 price of
Contract A is $8.
In the following, I will use the Arbitrage Theorem to examine the properties of the binomial option
pricing model.
Assume a one-period, two states of nature world with no transaction costs. There are a money
market with the risk-free interest rate r , and an asset (a stock) with time-0 price S 0 which at time-1
provides S 0 u (u 1) if the economy is good, and S 0 d (0 d 1) if the economy is bad.
The
S0u
1 r
money markets time-1 payment vector
and the stocks time-1 payment vector
are
S0 d
1 r
linearly independent, and the number of the linearly independent vectors equals the number of the states
of the nature. Hence, by System 2 of the Arbitrage Theorem, the market is complete, and with no
arbitrage, there exists a unique risk-neutral probability measure p
. Suppose also that there are
1
one European call option and one European put option based on the same stock with exercise price K :
cu M a [xS 0 u K ,0]
pu M a [xK S 0 u,0]
S0 u
S0 u
S0
c?
S0
p?
S0 d
cd M a [xS 0 d K ,0]
S0 d
pd M a [xK S 0 d ,0]
Asset :
Security 3 :
Security 4 :
1
(1 r ) (1 )(1 r )
1 r
1
S0u (1 ) S0 d
S0
1 r
. (3)
1
Max( S0u K , 0) (1 ) Max( S0 d K , 0)
c
1 r
1
Max( K S0u, 0) (1 ) Max( K S0 d , 0)
p
1 r
1
From equation (3), we can derive the following properties for S 0 u K S 0 d .10
Property 3.1
S0 p
Put-Call Parity.
1
S0u (1 ) S0 d 1 (1 ) ( K S0 d ) 1 ( S0u K ) K
1 r
1 r
1 r
1 r
K
.
1 r
Property 3.2
(i) c
1
( S0u K ) 1 S0u (1 ) S0 d 1 (1 ) S0 d 1 K
1 r
1 r
1 r
1 r
S0
1
K (1 ) S0 d S0 1 K (1 ) K S0 K S0 K .
1 r
1 r
1 r
This indicates that for any American call option C , even if S 0 K 0 , it wont be exercised.
(ii)
1
(1 )( K S0 d ) 1 S0u (1 ) S0 d 1 (1 ) K 1 S0u
1 r
1 r
1 r
1 r
S0
1
S0u (1 ) K S0 1 K (1 ) K K S0 .
1 r
1 r
1 r
Property 3.3
Suppose c p , i.e.,
1
( S0u K ) 1 (1 )( K S0 d ) .
1 r
1 r
Security 2 :
Security 3 :
Security 4 :
Security 5 :
S 01 1
1 3
1
1.25 1.25
1 0.25 4
4
S 02 48
1 3
1
75 15
1 0.25 4
4
S 03 68
1 3
1
100 40
1 0.25 4
4
c9
1 3
1 3
(75 60)
(100 85)
1 0.25 4
1 0.25 4
p9
1 1
1 1
(60 15)
(85 40)
1 0.25 4
1 0.25 4
where the same call and put option price: c p $9 can be dependent on Security 2 ( S02 ) with
10
K
K
and p 0 . For K S0u S0d , p
S0 and c 0 .
1 r
1 r
or
dependent
on
Security
( S03 )
with
K S 30 (1 r )
Let K K 'K 0 and other factors other factors (i.e., u, d , S 0 and r ) remain
Property 3.4
constant.
Then
c c'c
i.e.,
1
( S0u K ' ) 1 ( S0u K ) 1 ( K ' K ) 0 ,
1 r
1 r
1 r
c
K
0 , and c
because r 0 and 0 1;
K
1 r
p p' p
i.e.,
Property 3.5
1
(1 ) ( K ' S0 d ) 1 (1 ) ( K S0 d ) 1 (1 ) ( K ' K ) 0 ,
1 r
1 r
1 r
p
K
0 , and p
because r 0 and 0 1.
K
1 r
c p
c p
0 and
0.
u u
d d
(i)
S0
1
(1 r ) d (1 r ) d
[ ( S 0 u ) (1 )( S 0 d )] ,
' . with
1 r
ud
u'd
and
p'
Then from
1
[(1 )( K S 0 d )]
1 r
1
p' p p
p' 1 '
[(1 ' )( K S 0 d )] , we have:
0.
1 and
1 r
u'u u
p 1
c p
(1 )
'
(1 ' )
(c'c) ( p' p)
( S 0 u' K )
( S 0 u K )
( K S0 d )
( K S 0 d )
1 r
1 r
1 r
1 r
(ii) Let
1
' ( S0u' ) (1 ' )(S0 d ) 1 ( S0u) (1 )(S0 d ) S0 S 0 0 .
1 r
1 r
d d 'd 0
Then
1 '
c
u (1 r ) u (1 r )
1
u d'
ud
or
'
With
c'
1
[ ' ( S 0 u K )]
1 r
and
1
c' '
c'c c
[ ( S 0 u K )] , we obtain:
1 and
0.
1 r
c
d 'd d
c p
(1 )
'
(1 ' )
(c'c) ( p' p)
( S0 u K )
( S 0 u K )
( K S0 d ' )
( K S 0 d )
1 r
1 r
1 r
1 r
Property 3.6
1
' ( S0u) (1 ' )(S0 d ' ) 1 ( S0u) (1 )(S0 d ) S0 S 0 0 .
1 r
1 r
Even without changing the expiration dates, issuers of European options can adjust
TV c
(1 ) ( K ' K ) 0 and
TV TV 'TV p' p
0.
1 r
K
p
TV p
1
TV p TV p 'TV p p'( K ' S0 ) [ p ( K S0 )] ( K ' K )
0
1 0 and
K
1 r
1
TV c
( K ' K ) 0 and
TV TV 'TV c'c
0.
1 r
K
c
(iii) For S 0 K ,
if K K 'K 0 ,
TV c
K
1 r
and
TV p TV p 'TV p p' p
p
1
(1 ) ( K ' K ) 0 and TV 0 ;
1 r
K
if K K 'K 0 ,
TV p
1
TV p p'( K ' S0 ) p ( p' p) ( K ' K ) ( K ' K )
0,
1 0 and
K
1 r
and
Property 3.7
TV c TV c 'TV c c'c
c
1
( K ' K ) 0 and TV 0 .
1 r
K
Every non-dividend-paying asset is also a European call option and a European put option
1 3
1
1
Money Mark et (Security 1) : S 0 1 1 0.25 4 1.25 4 1.25
1 3
1
S 02 48
70 30
Security 2 :
1 0.25 4
4
1 3
1
S 03 50
75 25
Security 3 :
1 0.25 4
4
1 3
1
c6
10 0
Call Option :
1 0.25 4
4
1 3
1
p6
Put Option :
0 30
1 0.25 4
4
where
(i) c can be a call option for Security 2 (with K $60 ) or Security 3 (with K $65 ). Also, p can
be a put option for Security 2 (with K $60 ) or Security 3 (with K $55 ).
(ii) One share of Security 2 is:
(a) a European call option for two shares of Security 3 where K $80 if the time-1 share price of
Security 3 is $75 , and K $20 if the time-1 share price of Security 3 is $25 ;
(b) a European put option for one share of Security 3 where K $145 if the time-1 share price of
Security 3 is $75 , and K $55 if the time-1 share price of Security 3 is $25 .
One share of Security 3 is:
(a) a European call option for two shares of Security 2 where K $65 if the time-1 share price of
Security 2 is $70 , and K $35 if the time-1 share price of Security 2 is $30 ;
(b) a European put option for one share of Security 2 where K $145 if the time-1 share price of
Security 2 is $70 , and K $55 if the time-1 share price of Security 2 is $30 .
4. Concluding Remarks
In this paper, I have used simple arbitrage argument to derive a dozen of model-free option price
properties. In addition to deriving the Greeks under model-free framework, the results show that first, in
contrast to the traditional view, a European call (put) option for a non-dividend-paying asset can also be a
European call (put) option for any other non-dividend-paying asset, and every non-dividend-paying asset
is also both a European call option and a European put option for any other non-dividend-paying asset.
Second, in some cases the time value of the European put option can be negative, and adjust the exercise
price of an option can decrease or even erase the time value of the option.
Theorem under the binomial option pricing model to examine these properties.
REFERENCES
Bazaraa, Mokhtar, Hanif Sherali and C. M. Shetty, 1993, Nonlinear Programming: Theory and
Algorithms, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York.
Black, Fischer and Myron Scholes, 1973, The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, Journal of
Political Economy 81, 637-654.
Chang, Kuo-Ping, 2012, Are Securities Also Derivatives?, American Journal of Operations Research 2,
430-441.
doi: 10.4236/ajor.2012.23051.
Also in http://ssrn.com/abstract=987522.
Merton, Robert, 1973, Theory of Rational Option Pricing, The Bell Journal of Economics and
Management Science 4, 141-183.