HOUSING COOPERATIVES: POSSIBLE ROLES IN HAVANA’S
RESIDENTIAL SECTOR
Mario A. González Corzo
Over recent years, much of the debate surrounding
the present and future state of Havana’s (and Cuba’s)
housing sector has centered around the legal and economic issues related to restitution and compensation
for confiscated properties, and strategies to stimulate
much needed investment in this vital sector of the
economy (e.g., Ashby, 2004, 2005; Driggs, 2005;
Clark, 1999). Other experts and scholars (e.g., Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2000; Coyula and Hamberg, 2003; Pérez Villanueva, 2000; Padrón Lotti,
1998) have focused their attention on the relationship between the importance of historic preservation,
the desperate need to alleviate Havana’s housing crisis, and economic efficiency, while addressing the
monumental task of rebuilding the city’s basic infrastructure during the process of transition. However,
with few exceptions (Coyula and Hamberg, 2003),
affordability by the less privileged sectors of the population, and the potential role of housing cooperatives in promoting sustainable affordable housing,
has been excluded from this debate.
Historically, housing cooperatives have been used to
stimulate capital formation and improve the quantity
and quality of affordable housing in major urban
centers like New York and Paris (Sazama, 1996).
This property form provides economic incentives
and social opportunities for individuals interested in
controlling their environment and improving the
quality of their lives. Given Cuba’s tradition of cooperative-based “self-help housing,” and relatively high
rates of homeownership, housing cooperatives represent a viable alternative to improve the quantity and
quality of the country’s urban housing, particularly
in Havana.
This paper describes the possible roles of housing cooperatives in the transformation of Havana’s residential sector. The first section of the paper provides a
summary of current conditions in Havana’s housing
sector. This is followed by a discussion of the principal characteristics of housing cooperatives and the
factors that determine their value. The last section
analyzes the potential roles of housing cooperatives in
the transformation of Havana’s residential sector and
the challenges ahead.
CONDITIONS IN HAVANA’S HOUSING
SECTOR
Despite the influx of foreign investment into tourism
and commercial real estate projects during the 1990s,
conditions in Havana’s residential sector have continued to deteriorate. According to official statistics,
there were 586,768 housing units in Havana in 2001
(INV, 2002). See Table 1. Out of these, an estimated
64%, or 375,532 units, were considered in “good”
condition, compared to 50% in 1990; 20%, or
117,354 units were in “fair” condition; and the remaining 16%, or 93,883 units, were in “poor” condition (INV, 1990; INV, 2002). An estimated
60,000 dwellings needed to be repaired in 2001
(INV, 2002). Experts believe that some 1,000 dwellings suffer partial or total collapse every year in Havana due to lack of repair, tropical storms and hurricanes, or a combination of both (INV, 2000;
Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2002).1
167
Cuba in Transition
·
ASCE 2005
Havana’s substandard dwellings include more than
7,000 ciudadelas and cuarterías, and 186 barrios insolubres (Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2002). In 2001,
there were 60,757 tenement units in 6,932 buildings
in Havana, representing 10.35% of the total housing
units in the city, and housing 205,564 residents, or
9.4% of the total population (INV, 2001; Coyula
and Hamberg, 2003). In addition, there were 21,552
units in shantytowns, providing shelter for an estimated 72,976 residents, or 3.3% of Havana’s population (INV, 2001; Coyula and Hamberg, 2003). See
Table 2.
Table 1.
Condition
Good
Fair
Poor
Total
Havana: Housing Conditions,
2001
No. Of Units
375,532
117,354
93,883
586,768
Percentage
64%
20%
16%
100%
Table 2.
Housing Type
Tenements
Shantytowns
Shelters
Havana: Substandard Housing,
2001
Year
2001
2001
1997
Units
60,754
21,552
2,758
Population
206,564
72,986
9,178
% of Total
Population
9.4%
3.3%
0.4%
Source: INV, 2002; Coyula and Hamberg, 2003.
between 40% and 50% of all housing units in these
neighborhoods, where 80% of all existing units are
80 years old or older (Padrón Lotti, 1998). In addition to Habana Vieja, Centro Habana, and Atarés,
large concentrations of substandard housing are also
found in the peripheral municipalities of Arroyo
Naranjo, San Miguel del Padrón, and 10 de Octubre
(Coyula and Hamberg, 2003). Although residents in
tenements account for a relatively small share of Havana’s population, their dwellings tend to disproportionately suffer from overcrowding, disruptions in
access to basic services, and deteriorating physical
conditions.
Population density, household size, and occupancy
ratios provide another indicator of conditions in the
housing sector. In the case of Havana, as in most major cities in the developing world, there seems to be a
positive correlation between the presence of substandard housing and population density.
Source: INV, 2002; Coyula and Hamberg, 2003.
Most of Havana’s substandard housing is located in
the inner city municipalities of Habana Vieja, Centro
Habana, and Atarés. These areas are also characterized by high levels of population density and a disproportionate number of tenement buildings. In
1997, tenement buildings represented somewhere
For instance, in 2000, Havana’s (top five) most
densely populated municipios were: Centro Habana,
39,457 inhabitants per square kilometer; Habana
Vieja, 24,496 inhabitants per square kilometer; Diez
de Octubre, 19,643 inhabitants per square kilometer;
Plaza de la Revolución, 14,437 inhabitants per square
kilometer; and Cerro, 13,695 inhabitants per square
kilometer. See Table 3. This compares with Havana’s
overall population density of 3,013 inhabitants per
square kilometer (Coyula and Hamberg, 2003).
Combined, these municipalities represented 36% of
the city’s total population in 2000. Also, in 2001,
these municipalities reported two of the highest per-
1. According to Coyula and Hamberg (2003), there were 5,381 partial or total collapses in Havana during the 1993–1996 period. By
contrast, in 2000 alone, the city lost some 4,064 units due to partial or total collapses or derrumbes.
168
Housing Cooperatives
Table 3.
Havana, Population Density, 2000
Municipality
Arroyo Naranjo
Boyeros
Centro Habana
Cerro
Cotorro
Diez de Octubre
Guanabacoa
Habana del Este
Habana Vieja
La Lisa
Marianao
Playa
Plaza de la Revolución
Regla
San Miguel del Padrón
CIUDAD DE LA HABANA
Area
(sq. km.)
83
134
4
10
66
12
127
145
4
38
21
36
12
9
26
727
Population
12/31/1999
196,157
183,768
157,827
136,946
74,124
235,718
106,742
182,353
97,984
124,293
137,999
184,715
173,239
43,222
155,234
2,190,321
Inhabitans/sq. km.
12/31/1999
2,363
1,371
39,457
13,695
1,123
19,643
840
1,258
24,496
3,271
6,571
5,131
14,437
4,802
5,971
3,013
% of Total
12/31/1999
9%
8%
7%
6%
3%
11%
5%
8%
4%
6%
6%
8%
8%
2%
7%
100%
Source: www.geohive.com; Sitio del Gobierno de la República de Cuba, www.cubagob.cu
centage of housing units in “poor” condition (INV,
2002).2
By the mid 1990s, average household size ranged
from 2.9 in Centro Habana and Cayo Hueso, 3.3 in
Habana Vieja, 3.6 in Malecón and San Isidro, and 3.9
in Atarés (Coyula and Hamberg, 2003). Similarly,
the average floor space per person in most tenements
in Havana was estimated around 10 square meters,
and 39 square meters per unit (Coyula and Hamberg, 2003). When compared to other cities in the
developing world, Havana’s average household size
may appear relatively small; however, overcrowding
has increased significantly since the “Special Period.”
During the 1980s, the city received a steady annual
flow of 10,000 to 12,000 internal migrants (Scarpaci,
Segre, and Coyula, 2002; Clark, 1999). See Table 4.
This figure increased to 13,000 in 1993, and 17,000
in 1995, reaching a total of 28,000 by 1996 (Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2002; Clark, 1999). The majority of these migrants, popularly referred to as palestinos, originate from various parts of Eastern Cuba,
and often come to Havana in search of better employment opportunities and consumer goods (Clark,
1999). In April 1997, the government approved Decree Law No. 217 to reduce the flow of internal migrants into Havana. It is estimated that as a result of
this measure, some 22,000 inhabitants had migrated
from the inner districts to the city’s edge by 1999
(Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2002). Although exact
figures do not exist, some observers believe that the
annual flow of internal migrants has subsided to
9,000 to 12,000 (Pérez Villanueva, 2000).
Table 4.
Annual Migration Into Havana
Year (or Period)
1980–1989
1993
1995
1996
1997–Present
Internal Migrants
10,000 to 12,000
13,000
17,000
28,000
9,000 to 12,000
Source: Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2002; Clark, 1999; ONE 2002.
In addition to overcrowded conditions, many housing units in Havana have difficulties when it comes
to access to water and electricity. It is estimated that
17.5% of the residents in shantytowns do not have
access to water inside their units, and 25.6% do not
have their own sanitary facilities (Coyula and Ham-
2. According to a report compiled by the Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda (INV) in 2002, the number of housing units considered in
“bad” condition in Centro Habana ranged between 7,000 and 8,000, while the number of units in similar conditions in Habana Vieja
ranged between 16,000 and 18,000.
169
Cuba in Transition
Table 5.
·
ASCE 2005
Cuba: Cement Production, 1989–2001 (million metric tons)
Year
Output
1989
3,759
—
1993
1,049
-72.09%
1994
1,085
3.43%
1995
1,456
34.19%
1996
1,438
-1.24%
1997
1,701
18.29%
1998
1,713
0.71%
1999
1,785
4.20%
2000
1,633
-8.52%
2001
1,324
-18.92%
2001/1989
% Change
-64.78%
Source: ONE, BCC, CEPAL, 2000–2002.
berg, 2003). In Habana Vieja, between 30% and
40% of residents have to carry water to their dwellings; more than 25% of the existing units lack exclusive use of a bath or shower; 6% do not have toilets;
and 15% share toilets located outside their units
(Coyula and Hamberg, 2003; Morales, 1996).
In many parts of the city, the water distribution system is unable to satisfy the needs of the population
despite impressive statistics.3 Havana loses approximately 30% of its municipal water supply due to
leaks and decaying infrastructure, and limited pumping capacity severely restricts the availability of water
in many parts of the city (Driggs, 2004).
Although virtually all residents have access to electricity, inconsistent electrical service, characterized by
the infamous apagones or blackouts, is a common occurrence. Interruptions in electrical service became
more frequent during the peak of the economic crisis
of the 1990s, as the Cuban government began to
modify its power plants to use domestically produced
petroleum (Driggs, 2004). Domestic petroleum is
high in sulfur content, which is very corrosive and requires frequent plant shutdowns for routine maintenance (Driggs, 2004). These shutdowns result in
more frequent blackouts and service interruptions
(Driggs, 2004).
Finally, despite ambitious plans and efforts, Havana’s
housing sector continues to be affected by growing
deficits. Although official plans called for the addition of 400,000 dwellings to the existing stock between 1996 and 2000 at the national level, with new
construction accounting for 250,000 units, and rehabilitation efforts accounting for the remaining
150,000, actual results during that period fell below
projections (Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2002; Gomilla, 1996). Between 1997 and 1999, the number
of new dwellings built in Cuba reached a total of
141,400, or 43% below the projected target (Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2002). This shortfall in production was attributed to several factors. First, the
productive capacity of the construction sector fell
short of demand, particularly as the result of lower
cement output (Table 5) and reduced worker productivity; second, plants that once produced heavy
prefabricated panels were not converted to facilitate
the production of lighter building materials; and
third, the construction of utilities necessary to support new housing structures fell behind actual completion (Scarpaci, Segre, and Coyula, 2002; Coyula,
2000).
In addition to these difficulties, the present state of
Havana’s housing sector can be attributed to several
3. According to the Instituto Nacional de Recursos Hidráulicos (National Institute of Hydraulic Resources), 98% of the urban population receives water service; 83% enjoy a direct connection within their homes; and 14.8% have “easy” access to water (i.e., can access a
water source within 300 meters of their homes). See Driggs, 2004, and Pan American Health Organization (PAHO), 2000.
170
Housing Cooperatives
factors. Ordinary Cubans have little or no access to
capital sources to finance home repairs and improvements.4 There is also a limited availability of building
materials. Although the purchase, sale, and transfer
of residential units are technically legal, such transactions are severely restricted by existing regulations.
These limitations have hindered the potential private
development and have contributed to the expansion
of an informal real estate market. These factors have
contributed to one of the most pressing socioeconomic problems at the present time: the need to
transform Havana’s housing sector and address the
city’s housing crisis.
One way to accomplish this objective, given the legacy of socialism in Cuba and legendary entrepreneurial spirit of Cuban people, is to facilitate the development of housing cooperatives. Housing cooperatives
offer several advantages over alternative property
forms, such as cost sharing, and professional management. In addition, they stimulate investment and
capital formation by providing prospective homeowners and investors with powerful economic incentives, tax advantages, and the potential of future capital gains. Finally, the development of housing
cooperatives can result in positive economic externalities through the creation of additional employment
opportunities, higher tax revenues for the municipal
government, and the multiplier effect associated with
increased investment and consumption.
PRINCIPAL CHARACTERISTICS OF
HOUSING COOPERATIVES
Housing cooperatives differ from other property
forms in several ways. First, owners in housing cooperatives own shares in a corporation rather than a real
or tangible asset. These shares give the owner the
right to occupy the corresponding unit (or apartment) for a pre-determined period of time, usually
99 years. The owner makes a monthly “maintenance” payment to the cooperative corporation,
which includes his or her share of the underlying
(building) mortgage payments, real estate taxes, and
the operating costs of the building. In the United
States, Internal Revenue Service (IRS) Section 216
allows the tenant-shareholder in a cooperative corporation to take a deduction for his or her proportionate share of the real estate taxes and interest payments
made by the corporation (Zachter, 1989).
If the buyer in a cooperative borrows money to finance his purchase, the mortgage obligation that he
assumes is secured by a pledge of his shares in the cooperative corporation. From the point of view of the
lender, shareholders in a cooperative bear a portion
of the risk that other shareholders may default on
their obligations to pay their share of the corporation’s expenses. This risk is often mitigated by giving
the cooperative the legal right to place a lien on the
shares of an owner for unpaid maintenance; however,
even with this provision lenders still face the risk that
the sale price may be too low to compensate the corporation for its losses.
Cooperatives typically protect existing shareholders
by placing restrictions on the approval of applicants.
In some cases, the cooperative’s board of directors requires a buyer to pay a minimum of 20% or more of
the total purchase price as down payment, regardless
of the minimum down payment approved by his
lending institution. In addition, most cooperatives
also require buyers to meet a specific financing ratio,
which limits their monthly personal debt, maintenance, and mortgage payments to a specified percentage of pre-tax income. The restrictions imposed
by cooperatives are not only limited to financing.
Some cooperatives do not allow pets, place strict limitations on subletting, and require written board approval for updates and improvements to individual
units. Generally, these restrictions effectively reduce
demand for units in the cooperative building.
This reduction in demand typically has an adverse
impact on the relative values of cooperative units
when compared to alternative property forms such as
condominiums and townhouses. Some potential
4. However, according to the website of the Banco Popular de Ahorro (BPA), that institution provides home improvement loans to ordinary citizens. The terms of these loans are: minimum balance, 300 pesos; annual interest rate, 9% (fixed); term, 120 months (or 10
years); and loan to value (LTV) ratio, up to 90% of the amount borrowed. Source: http://www.bancopopulardeahorro.com
171
Cuba in Transition
·
ASCE 2005
buyers may also avoid buying shares in cooperative
buildings because they do not want to disclose their
financial situation to the building’s board of directors. In some cases, cooperatives that limit the
amount of debt financing or leverage that potential
buyers can obtain to purchase shares may cause individuals with limited financial resources to pursue less
restrictive forms of home ownership.
Determinants of Value
When buying shares in a cooperative, the bundle of
attributes that the consumer purchases includes the
unit and neighborhood characteristics, as well as a
proportionate share of the common elements in the
cooperative building (e.g., the roof, hallway, driveway, onsite laundry room, concierge, doorman,
swimming pool, gym).5 This means that the total value of the cooperative unit is equal to the sum of its
sale price and the unit’s share of the services offered
by the common elements. However, calculating the
value of a unit’s share of the services provided by the
common elements can be difficult because they are
not typically sold separately in the open market.
This limitation can be addressed by calculating the
present value (PV) of the stream of periodic (monthly) maintenance fees that the unit’s owner must pay
to cover the cooperative’s operating expenses. Because cooperative maintenance fees usually cover
payments for the underlying mortgage and property
taxes, these expenses need to be subtracted from the
monthly maintenance payment for valuation purposes. For most cooperatives the portion of the monthly
maintenance that is tax deductible is usually known.
This facilitates the calculation of the non-deductible
portion, which provides a good estimate of the
monthly maintenance amount allocated to operating
the common areas. The present value (PV) of the
non-deductible portion of the monthly maintenance
fees can be calculated as follows: 6
1) PVmaint =
Mth _ fee
1/12(i − g )
(1)
Where:
Mth_fee = Monthly non-deductible portion of the
monthly maintenance fees for cooperatives;
i= the annual discount rate; and
g = the expected growth rate
Most cooperatives report the outstanding balance on
their blanket mortgage at one point in time. As a result, we also need to calculate a unit’s proportionate
share of the outstanding blanket mortgage balance
each time the unit changes hand using the following
equation:
2) Mbal _ unit = Mbal
Shares _ unit
Shares _ total
(2)
5. Schill et. al. (2003) used a hedonic regression model to estimate and compare the determinants of value for housing cooperatives and
condominiums in New York City. In its most simplistic form, the hedonic regression model developed by Schill et. al.(2003) can be expressed as follows:
V int = α + βχΧ int + βwWn + ρIt + βcCin + εint
Where:
Vint = the logarithm of the value of housing unit i in neighborhood n at time t
Xint = a vector of property-related characteristics
Wn = a series of census tract fixed effects
It = a vector of dummy variables that take a value of one in observations for partments in year t
Cin = the ownership type (condo or cooperative)
βc = the differential effect of ownership type (holding all else constant)
εint = an error term with the usual properties.
6. The average yield on a one-year U.S. Treasury Bill during the observation period provides a good approximation for the annual discount rate (i). Similarly, the average inflation rate during the observation period can be used to represent the expected growth rate (g).
172
Housing Cooperatives
Where:
Mbal= outstanding balance of the underlying mortgage
Shares_unit= the number of shares allocated to a particular cooperative unit
Shares_total = the total number of shares in the cooperative building
Therefore, the value of a cooperative unit is:
3) Vcoop = Pcoop + PVma int + Mbal _ unit
(3)
The value of a cooperative unit is also determined by
property-specific characteristics (i.e., the unique
characteristics of the cooperative building and the
unit being considered). Building-specific characteristics include design features, number of elevators, year
constructed, building lot size, number of stories, type
of exterior, fuel type used, zoning regulations, presence of doorman, concierge service, total number
units, number of sponsor/investor units, and parking
type. Unit-specific characteristics include square
footage, unit design and distribution, number of
rooms, number of bathrooms, location within the
building, floor, balconies or terraces, ceiling height,
etc. In addition to these characteristics, other key aesthetic externalities such as presence of a water view,
the appearance of nearby improvements, and the
quality of landscaping in the neighborhood as factors
that influence the value of residential properties
(Bourassa et al, 2003).
HOUSING COOPERATIVES: POSSIBLE
ROLES IN HAVANA’S HOUSING SECTOR
Given their unique features and relatively simple valuation, housing cooperatives can contribute to the
transformation of Havana’s housing market in several ways.
Improve the Quantity and Quality of Housing
Housing cooperatives represent a viable alternative
for individuals wishing to enjoy the benefits of homeownership without the hassles associated with it,
and can make significant contributions to the improvement of the residential housing stock. Since
their residents own them, housing cooperatives offer
economic incentives and social opportunities for individuals interested in controlling their social environment and improving the quality of their lives
(Sazama, 1996). Because owners pay for their corresponding share of the benefits offered by the common areas, they have a vested interest in maximizing
the utility or satisfaction they receive from their use
or consumption. Housing cooperatives provide owners with powerful economic incentives to maintain
and improve the physical conditions of their units
and their common areas. This enhances the cooperative’s financial stability and contributes to its future
viability.
Stimulate Private Investment and Capital
Formation
Like other real estate purchases and investments,
buying a unit in a housing cooperative provides potential owners and investors with an opportunity to
take advantage of the benefits of leverage. Leverage
allows potential homeowners or investors with limited funds to acquire properties of substantial value.
The disadvantage of leverage, however, is that it represents increased risk exposure.7 Some examples of
such risk are a temporary decline rather than increase
in property values, or a loss of employment, which
could make it difficult for homeowners or investors
to continue to meeting installment payments (Benke
and Fowler, 2001). The use of leverage reflects the
traditional risk-return relationship: higher levels of
leverage can result in greater potential rates of return,
but also represent greater levels of risk (Benke and
Fowler, 2001).
As financing opportunities become available, particularly for individuals with limited resources and income, the economic advantages of homeownership
and investing in real estate assets increase substantially. Although relying on leveraged financing to buy a
home or acquire an investment property may increase the borrower’s overall debt burden, the ultimate outcome is the acquisition of a tangible asset,
7. Leverage in the context of personal real estate purchases or investments is defined as the ability to use a relatively small cash down
payment to obtain (or control) property of substantial market value.
173
Cuba in Transition
·
ASCE 2005
which could generate future cash flows or could be
converted into cash at some future point in time.
The development of investment products (e.g., conventional and non-conventional mortgages) that allow individuals to take advantage of the benefits of
financial leverage could serve as a powerful incentive
to stimulate capital formation and alleviate Havana’s
housing crisis.
Positive Externalities
The development of cooperative housing projects
could also provide employment opportunities in areas such as construction, management, maintenance,
household services, and retail. New employment opportunities in the formal sector could provide an alternative to employment in the underground economy, and contribute to a cooperative’s financial
stability and long-term viability. In addition to new
employment opportunities, the development of cooperative housing projects also has the potential of
increasing Havana’s tax base. This can be accomplished by providing tax incentives to facilitate their
development and designing and building spaces that
include ancillary facilities such as retail shops, restaurants, and storefronts to meet the needs of local residents. The development of “mixed use” cooperatives
(i.e., cooperatives occupied by both residential and
commercial tenants) can contribute to the city’s tax
base in the form of additional property taxes and taxable consumer spending. A portion of these tax revenues could be allocated to the improving and maintaining Havana’s infrastructure and providing
additional social services, resulting in positive externalities.
The Challenges Ahead
Property Rights: The transformation of Havana’s
housing sector, regardless of the type of property
form used, will require the expansion and guarantee
of private property rights, the elimination of existing
restrictions on homeownership by ordinary citizens,
and the liberalization of the real estate and construction markets.8 The importance of property rights in
this context cannot be understated because property
rights are the sine qua non of residential housing market development in both advanced and developing
economies.
A well-established system of property rights also facilitates the conversion of assets into fungible capital,
and constitutes a fundamental requirement for capital formation. According to de Soto (2000), a formal
system of property rights
begins to process assets into capital by describing and
organizing the most economically and socially useful
aspects about assets, preserving this information in a
recording system—as insertions in a written ledger or
a blip on a computer disk—and then embodying
them in a title. A set of detailed and precise legal rules
governs this entire process. Formal property records
and titles thus represent our shared concept of what is
economically meaningful about any asset. They capture and organize all the relevant information required to conceptualize the potential value of an asset
and so allow us to control it. Property is the realm
where we identify and explore assets, combine them,
and link them to other assets. The formal property
system is capital’s hydroelectric plant. This is the
place where capital is born (pp. 46–47).
In most countries property rights are defined or assigned through a formal legal system, or by less formal mechanisms such as customs or traditions. Two
areas of property law that have a direct impact on the
development of real estate markets are contract law
and land use regulation. Contract law deals with the
system that defines and facilitates the transfer of real
property and property laws allocate those rights, and
settle disputes and disagreements (Malpezzi, 2000).
Research by Miceli and Sirmans (1997) shows that
substantial efficiency gains are possible when countries institute systems that create official property registers and provide some form of private insurance or
public guarantee to back property rights. Regardless
of its level of economic development, a nation’s
property market is said to be a well-functioning if the
process of price discovery is complete and contributes
8. Article 2 (Law No. 65) specifically limits homeownership to a primary residence and a secondary (summer or “rest”) residence. This
law strictly prohibits legal ownership of more than two residences.
174
Housing Cooperatives
to the reduction of the risks involved in purchasing
and financing real estate assets (Bertaud and
Renauld, 1997; Malpezzi, 2000). Price discovery is
simplified and its costs are reduced when the required institutions for efficient property markets,
such as property registration and insurance service
providers, mortgage lenders, and real estate brokers,
are present and encouraged.
Financial Intermediation: The transformation of
Havana’s (and Cuba’s) housing sector will also require the development of a competitive residential
mortgage market. At the present time, the Cuban
government serves the as the sole financial intermediary in the residential real estate market by providing
personal loans (instead of mortgages) through the
Banco Popular de Ahorro (BPA). The personal loans
provided by the BPA allow borrowers to finance one
hundred percent of their purchases, permit joint applications, and can be paid using automatic salary deductions. However, since they are personal loans,
rather than mortgage loans, borrowers are not allowed to use their real property as collateral. It is estimated that the recapture rate for housing loans ranges from 97 to 99 percent, and most commonly used
terms are as follows (Hamberg, 1990):
•
•
•
•
•
Detached house or second floor walk-ups—
interest rate, 3%; term, 15 years.
High rise buildings—interest rate, 2%; term, 20
years.
Mountain rural cooperatives—interest rate, 2%;
term, 25 years.
Other rural cooperatives—interest rate, 3%;
term, 30 years.
Self-help housing—interest rate, 3%; term, 10
years.
To facilitate the transformation of the housing sector, other participants (both domestic and foreign)
should be allowed to offer various types of financing
to existing and potential homeowners. Under this
scenario, lending decisions would be based on the
borrower’s credit (or risk) profile and history, and the
lender’s cost of capital and tolerance for risk. This
transformation will also require the development of a
market for mortgage-backed securities (MBS), collaterized mortgage obligations (CMOs), real estate in-
vestment trusts (REITs), and other types of financial
derivatives. The development of a market where
these financial instruments could be easily traded can
inject much needed capital and liquidity into the system (Buckley, 1996; Renaud, 1999).
Unsettled Property Claims: The third challenge
that needs to be addressed consists of unsettled property claims. There are scenarios under which this
highly sensitive issue may eventually be addressed
(Ashby, 2004). One possibility is for claimants to receive substitute restitution, by which they would be
granted another property of equal value to the one
originally confiscated by the government. Compensation could also take the form of cash payments to
individual claimants equal to the fair market value of
their respective properties. Another scenario is for the
government to make a lump sum payment to an entire class of claimants, from which qualified individuals would receive payments. A final possibility is for
compensation to take the form of redeemable vouchers, debt securities, or shares in privatized business
firms.
CONCLUSION
Despite the influx of foreign investment into tourism
and commercial real estate projects during the 1990s,
conditions in Havana’s residential sector have continued to deteriorate. By the end of 2001, more than
90,000 housing units were considered in “poor” condition, and an estimated 60,000 were in urgent need
of repair. The city’s sub-standard or slum housing included more than 7,000 ciudadelas and cuarterías,
and 186 barrios insolubres, providing shelter to more
than 90,000 inhabitants. Experts believe that some
1,000 dwellings suffer partial or total collapses every
year due to poor maintenance, years of neglect, and
the severity of tropical storms.
Although the majority of habaneros have access to
electricity in their homes, service interruptions have
become an almost daily occurrence, causing food
spoilage and intensifying the effects of summertime
heat waves. In the inner-city municipality of Habana
Vieja, more than 30% of residents have to carry water to their home, and more than 25% of the existing
units lack exclusive use of a bath or shower. Finally,
it is estimated that 25% of the residents in the shan-
175
Cuba in Transition
·
ASCE 2005
tytowns located in the city’s peripheries do not have
their own sanitary facilities, and 17% lack access to
water inside their units.
The current condition of Havana’s housing sector
can be attributed to several factors. First, ordinary
Cubans, with the exception of those receiving generous remittances from abroad and those with substantial hard currency earnings, have very little access to
funding for home repairs and improvements. There
is also a limited availability of building materials in
state-owned stores. Finally, and perhaps more importantly, most transactions involving residential properties are strictly regulated by the state.
Historically, housing cooperatives have been used to
stimulate capital formation and improve the quantity
and quality of affordable housing in major urban
centers like New York and Paris (Sazama, 1996).
This property form provides economic incentives
and social opportunities for individuals interested in
controlling their environment and improving the
quality of their lives. Given Cuba’s tradition of cooperative-based “self-help housing,” and relatively high
rates of homeownership, housing cooperatives represent a viable alternative to improve the quantity and
quality of the country’s urban housing, particularly
in Havana.
The development of housing cooperatives can also
create positive externalities associated with new em-
ployment opportunities and additional tax revenues.
By creating additional employment opportunities in
the formal sector, housing cooperatives can provide
an alternative to employment in the underground
economy. The development of housing cooperatives
can also increase Havana’s tax revenues. Part of the
resulting tax revenues can be used to improve the infrastructure and provide additional social services to
the city’s residents. Finally, housing cooperatives
have the potential of bringing investment into the
housing sector, and stimulating capital formation
through increased private homeownership.
However, three principal challenges remain in the
near term. First, the transformation of Havana’s
housing sector will require the elimination of existing
restrictions on homeownership, the expansion of private property rights, and the development of an efficient system of property records. Second, this process
will also require the presence of independent intermediaries capable of offering various financing options to potential homeowners and investors, and the
development of financial markets where diverse financial instruments could be exchanged. And third,
unsettled property claims should be addressed during
the early stages of transition to reduce the uncertainties associated with restitution, compensation, and
pending litigation.
REFERENCES
Ashby, T. (2004). “Cuban real property: Current
laws and future prospects.” Real Estate Law Journal, 33, 123–153.
Benke, W., and J. M. Fowler (2001). All about real
estate investing. 2nd Ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Bertaud, A., and B. Renaud. (1997). “Social cities
without land markets.” Journal of Urban Economics, 41, 137–51.
176
Bourassa, S. C., M. Hoesli, and J. Sun (2003). The
price of aesthetic externalities. Retrieved Dec. 15,
2004, from http://www.fame.ch/library/EN/
RP98.pdf.
Buckley, R. M. (1996). Housing finance in developing
countries. New York: Oxford University Press.
Clark, J. (1999). The housing dimension in Cuba’s urban crisis: Havana as a case in point. Retrieved on
December 15, 2004, from http://www.amigospais-guaracbuya.org/oagjc005.php
Housing Cooperatives
Coyula, M. (2000). “La arquitectura habanera en el
2000 vista desde el futuro.” Revista Bimestre Cubana, 87, epoca 3, #12, pp. 200–209.
Coyula M., and Hamberg, J. (2003). Understanding
slums: Case studies for the Global Report: 2003:
The case of Havana, Cuba. Retrieved Jan. 17,
2005, from http://www.ucl.ac.uk/dpu-projects/
Global_Report/cities/havana.htm
De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere
else. New York: Basic Books.
Driggs, E. (2004). “Deteriorating living conditions
in Cuba.” Cuba Transition Project, University
of Miami. http://www.futurodecuba.org/.
Gomilla, S. (1996). Informe Nacional de Cuba. Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda (INV). La Habana:
Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda.
Hamberg, J. (1990). “Cuban housing policy.” In S.
Halebsky and J. M. Kirk (Eds.), Transformation
and struggle: Cuba faces the 1990s (pp. 235–250).
New York: Oxford University Press.
INV, Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda (1990). Control de Fondo de Viviendas. 1990. La Habana:
Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda.
Miceli, T., and Sirmans, C.F. (1997). “Torrens vs. title and transfer insurance: An economic analysis
of land title systems.” Illinois Real Estate Letter,
10, 81–88.
Ortega Morales, L. (1996). “La Habana: Barrio de
Atarés.” In H. Harms, W. Ludeña, and P.
Pfeiffer (Eds.). Vivir en el “centro,” Viviendas de
inquilinato en metropolis Latinoamericanas. Hamburg: Technical University.
Pan American Health Organization (PAHO)/CEPIS. (2000). Assessment of drinking water and sanitation in the Americas. 2000. Retrieved on February 15, 2005, from http://www.cepis.opsoms.org
Padrón Lotti, M.T. (1998). “Experiencia participativa en un proyecto de rehabilitación en la Ciudad
de La Habana.” In R. Dávalos Domínguez and
A. Basail Rodríguez (Eds.). Desarrollo urbano:
Proyectos y experiencias de trabajo. La Habana:
Universidad de La Habana.
Renaud, B. (1999). “Financial markets and the financing of social housing: The view from developing countries.” Urban Studies, 36(4), 755–
773.
INV, Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda (2000). Boletín Estadístico Anual. 2000. La Habana: Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda.
Sazama, G. (1996). A brief history of affordable housing cooperatives in the United States. Storrs, CT:
University of Connecticut Department of Economics Working Paper Series.
INV, Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda (2001). Boletín Estadístico Anual. 2001. La Habana: Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda.
Scarpaci, J. L., Segre, R., and Coyula, M. (2002).
Havana: Two faces of the Antillean metropolis.
Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
INV, Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda (2002).
Control de Fondo de Viviendas. 2001. La Habana: Instituto Nacional de la Vivienda.
Schill, M.H, Voicu, I., and Miller, J. (2003, Sept.
15). The condominium v. cooperative puzzle: An
empirical analysis of housing in New York City.
Retrieved November 30, 2004 from http://
law.nyu.edu/realestatecenter/
Malpezzi, S. (2000). Tales from the real side: The implications of urban research for real estate finance
in developing and transition economies. Retrieved
December 15, 2004, from http://wiscinfo.doit.wisc.edu/realestate
Zachter, M. (1989). “Cooperative housing corporations: Current tax issues.” The CPA Journal Online.
177