Impacts of Distributed Generation from Virtual Power Plants
Markus Franke, Daniel Rolli, Andreas Kamper, Antje Dietrich, Andreas Geyer-Schulz, Peter
Lockemann, Hartmut Schmeck, and Christof Weinhardt
[email protected],
[email protected],
[email protected],
[email protected],
[email protected],
[email protected],
[email protected],
[email protected]
Universität Karlsruhe (TH), Kaiserstraße 12, 76131 Karlsruhe, Germany
Abstract
As CO emissions and sustainable energy production have entered the focus of
2
attention in politics and industry, ecologically advantageous alternatives are strongly
promoted. We address virtual power plants from an information technological,
economic and legal perspective in order to enable decentralized sustainable
generation. For the realization of virtual power plants we draw on a peer-to-peer
infrastructure with market coordination and legal coverage to manage the distributed
generation units and we focus on the combination of power and heat. Based on our
prototype for a decentralized market platform, we examine the economic and
ecological impacts of an increasing pervasiveness of distributed generation and virtual
power plants as well as their potential influence on society.
At the social level, we consider questions of local immission, but also of growing
awareness for power issues. With regard to the ecology, we expect a reduction of
overall primary energy demand resulting from reduced transmission and
transformation losses and increased use of combined heat and power plants at a local
level leading to a reduction of emissions. Finally, since local distributed generation
makes more efficient use of primary energy and long-distance transport lines can be
reduced, we expect lower costs for the complete system as well as reduced uncertainty
with regard to amortization of investments. Besides a description of the methodology
our presentation will include selected results.
KEYWORDS: Virtual Power Plants, Decentralized Energy Generation, Market Coordination,
Cost Optimization
1 Introduction
There is a continuing tendency in the energy market to employ smaller generation units for both
electricity and heating. Beyond sustainable energy sources, fuel cells for the cogeneration of locally
distributed electricity and heat are gaining importance. For examining the impact of this distributed
generation, we focus on virtual power plants (VPP) from an information technological, economic
and legal perspective. We define virtual power plants as pools of autonomous generation units
primarily for electricity and heating. Typically, they employ small to medium sized generation units
like fuel cells. The fuel cells produce both heat and electricity. While the former can only be
provided to consumers locally, the latter is in principle suitable for long-distance transfer. Still it is
intended to provide the electricity of VPPs locally since this offers additional advantages presented
in this text.
For fostering an overall balanced provision of energy within a VPP, a way of controlling and
optimizing the per se autonomous distributed units must be chosen. Since we see markets as both
capable of coping with the complexity and particularly suited for the distributed nature of VPPs, we
chose market coordination for controlling them. We examine three different scenarios of
coordination with increasing degrees of freedom. First, we consider a natural monopoly of one
energy company controlling and optimizing a VPP with all its decentralized units, coupled with a
reduction of load curve peaks via non-linear pricing on the demand side. Second, we presume
independent generators of energy that are coordinated by a central market operator. Third, we
consider a market model with bilateral contracts and a non-profit market operator for the local
distribution network.
To examine virtual power plants and their impact, we chose the methods of theoretical analysis
and simulation. For conducting the latter, we implemented the prototype of a market platform for
automated optimized trading of electricity and heating contracts in the project SESAM1 . The
prototype is based on a peer-to-peer infrastructure corresponding to the decentralized nature of
VPPs. Basing on this infrastructure, we strive to develop a market structure that supports our main
requirements for virtual power plants, namely spontaneity and self-organization. In this paper, we
focus on the prerequisites for and consequences of such structures.
The rest of this text is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the system architecture of
SESAM including the market structure, modeling technique, and the juridical component. In section
3, we take a closer look at the economic considerations of virtual power plants. We address
optimization in section 4 and conclude with summary and outlook in section 5.
2 System Architecture
The system architecture employed in the SESAM project encompasses three important aspects:
Market structure, support for legal transactions and peer-to-peer infrastructure. Of these the first two
will be detailed here. The market model for virtual power plants in the context of SESAM has to be
specified in such a way that both spontaneity and self-organization are supported. Where hierarchies
and fixed pricing schemes rely on predefined, commonly agreed-on, and long-term relationships,
markets per se deliver individual just-in-time links between participants. To further foster
spontaneity, the harmonization between different participant groups must be advanced. These
groups are traditionally divided into countries with different legal frameworks, incompatible ITsystems and last but not least different market segments with various trading mechanisms.
2.1 Spontaneity and Self-Organization in Markets
Harmonizing users in market terms means providing them with a market model they all can rely on
for a shared understanding of the market structure and a common terminology. Harmonization and
increased spontaneity, respectively larger degrees of freedom for the individual, allow and require
self-organization for the functioning of a complex system. For virtual power plants in particular, we
see larger markets after harmonization meaning a bigger choice of suppliers and less transaction or
switching costs within and between different VPPs. The market itself provides a way to organize
such systems. It can be employed as an algorithm by the central planner, it can serve as a
coordination system with a central market operator and processing of decentralized information, and
it can even truly epitomize self-organization with bilateral communication links between all
participants.
2.2 Market Model
In order to systematically derive a market model for virtual power plants that can realize all
mentioned aspects, we start with the notions of a minimal market model [1] that applies to any kind
of market. With respect to implementation, this basic model identifies the six concepts participant,
product, attribute, intention, agreement, and offer as follows:
• Participant: A participant represents an agent of any kind that takes part in a market. Market
participants submit intentions to a market.
• Product: A product can represent any good or service.
1
SESAM is a project at the Universität Karlsruhe(TH), Germany, funded by the Federal Ministry of
Education and Research (BMBF)
• Attribute: Attributes are used to describe properties of products and market participants. A
product attribute can be declared forMatching. This means that the respective attribute is
mandatory for consideration when matching the underlying intention with others.
• Intention: An intention represents the smallest closed entity of purpose within a market. An
intention is defined by two groups of products, namely the incoming and outgoing products.
Incoming products are the ones the participant wants to receive while outgoing products are
the ones he is willing to give away in exchange.
• Agreement: An agreement is always derived from two fully specified intentions that are
declared binding. It indicates that the two associated intentions match and that the respective
participants have committed themselves to exchanging the products of the involved intentions.
• Offer: Each offer contains one or several intentions and serves as a container of control data
for communicating these intentions. Its timestamp is set upon receipt of the offer by the
runtime environment. An offer can be a BindingOffer or a NonBindingOffer. Binding means
that the associated participant is committed to the precise embodiment of the offer, while nonbinding offers just deliver noncommittal information.
In order to derive our specific market model for virtual power plants (VPM), we start by taking a
closer look at the energy domain in order to identify the characteristic embodiments of each one of
the aforementioned concepts and to integrate them into the VPM.
We consider the products Electricity as well as long-distance Heating to be central to the energy
market. Furthermore, we add the product Money that is common in many markets. Accordingly, we
derive three such subconcepts from the original Product concept.
Figure 1: The MMM, including electricity, heating and money
Figure 1 comprises the introduced six concepts of the MMM. The product concept has the three
subconcepts for Electricity, (long-distance) Heating, and Money. For briefly exemplifying more
details of our approach, we add two concretized attributes to the product Money, namely
productAmount and productCurrency. As the names suggest, productAmount specifies how much
money a participant is willing to pay; productCurrency specifies the currency of this amount.
The two products Electricity and Heating both have many more attributes than Money.
Electricity, for example, contains an elaborate system of 54 price slots, an additional base rate field,
share of ecological electricity, contract duration, etc. Since the data structure is not explicitly
accessed, we omit the detailed display of all attributes in this paper for the sake of clarity.
For our prototype, we use ontologies to represent the VPM in RDFS 2 documents. Hence, every
new participant interested in joining our platform can learn the full employed market model by
receiving the VPM RDFS-document.
With this document in hands, any participant of the market can address any other participant in a
common terminology. However, the VPM aspects sketched so far only cover the market perspective.
To enrich the VPM for implementation and law-abiding application, we integrate all required
security and law aspects. Security in our context particularly encompasses digital signatures,
encryption and certificate handling for secure communication, authentication, etc. For the scope of
this paper, we presuppose this infrastructural layer and will not examine it in detail. The juridical
aspects, on the other hand, have to be explicitly elucidated and integrated as will be done in the
following subsection.
2.3 Juridical Component
In order to support a participant in changing between the supplier and the buyer role, we rely on an
agent-based contract service. We have two types of agents in the contracting process – called
contract agents – making use of a “legal mediator”. The legal mediator guarantees the legal
correctness during a contract conclusion. The contract agent consults the legal mediator during the
different steps of the workflow needed to buy or sell energy. In the virtual power plants scenario,
participants can switch the role of customer and supplier; a customer of energy and heat can become
a supplier by offering his excess production on the (local) market. The role of traditional utility
providers is limited in this scenario to providing the local distribution network and satisfying excess
demand not met by decentralized units. In addition, a utility company can possibly offer services to
the private suppliers and buyers that enable them to automatically conclude a contract.
Since in our setting, switching roles instantly is possible, it is important that the conclusion of
the contract can also take place spontaneously, i.e. with as much automation as possible. In order to
quickly obtain a legally valid contract in the highly regulated utility domain, immediate automated
legal consultation is particularly important. Consequently, the mediator can be interpreted as a kind
of personal electronic lawyer of the participant. The entire process of concluding a contract is
carried out by a contract agent. This agent’s task embeds the transaction into the internal workflow
of the energy management system on the customer’s side.
In the following, the architectures of the contract agent and the legal mediator are presented. It
can be stated that the fully automated support of the contract service results in high qualitative and
monetary advantages for buyers as well as suppliers. The quality of the final contracts with respect
to provableness and effectiveness is substantially increased. The basis for the legal mediator is the
formalization of the code of law. We borrow ideas from the domain of Artificial Intelligence (AI).
Our architecture corresponds to the basis architecture of an expert system [2]. The main criteria for
our choice of rule engine are the control of forward chaining and backward chaining. Also nonmonotonous reasoning must be supported. In order to integrate the mediator into the SESAM
framework, we chose a Java implementation. The basis of the rule engine is an ontology for legal
terms that in turn is an extension of the minimal market model ontology: On the one hand, we
extend the ontology by synonyms for the different concepts and properties. On the other hand, we
concretize concepts of the general minimal market model in order to meet particularities of
European utility regulation and national basic law. This finally delivers a comprehensive virtual
power plant market model.
In general, SESAM follows a service-based approach [3]. As explained, the core juridical
services are represented by agents. This fits into the specifications of the SESAM project for an
implementation based on peer-to-peer technology. For agents in a decentralized setting, it is
necessary that the peer structure provides a semantically rich environment. Accordingly, we based
the internal structure on the reference architecture for agents [4].
2
Resource Description Framework Schema, see http://www.w3.org/TR/rdf-schema/
For running the system, the two agent types must each be deployed for every market participant:
The contract agent assumes the task to represent the personal interests of the market participant. It
contains the personal preferences of the market participant it represents as well as the economic
criteria that should be employed. These contribute to the goals that the agent pursues. Since goal
conflicts are nearly inevitable, the conceptual challenge to handle these conflicts during the process
was answered as proposed by the BDI theory [5]. The contract agent will negotiate directly with the
contract agent of other participants.
The legal mediator – our kind of personal lawyer – cooperates closely with the contract agent
and receives requests from it. While it is reasonable that a contract agent commonly represents its
market participant it is conceivable that legal mediators can be specialized in a certain legal domain.
Therefore the legal mediators may advice several market participants and one participant may
consult several mediators. The requirements for the legal mediator differ fundamentally from those
of the contract agent. Due to strict law requirements the mediator is constructed in a modular way.
The process of systematically answering legal questions is subsumption. To enable subsumption in
an electronic environment, we modelled the required law paragraphs in rules, which are processed in
a inference engine within the legal mediator.
The juridical architecture thus allows us to flexibly represent and handle the different legal
frameworks in order to enable automatic contract conclusion between participants.
3 Economic Considerations
In this section, we discuss the impacts of decentralized power generation from a mainly economic
perspective. We consider five factors that are crucial for the success of virtual power plants as we
consider them here: Decreased need for peak load generators, decreased transmission capacity
demand, decreased transformation losses, reduced investment risk and benefits of cogeneration of
power and heat. Furthermore, certain types of virtual power plants may lead to increased use of
demand side management as shown in section 4, if the generation units are directly controlled by
consumers as intended in the more advanced scenarios.
3.1 Peak Load Generation
From the supplier’s point of view, virtual power plants represent an attractive way for reducing the
share of peak load generators in the company’s generator portfolio, thus allowing lower average
production costs. From the customer’s perspective, decentralized generation as a substitute for peak
load demand is attractive with respect to the price that needs to be paid for adequate electric supply.
However, this potential for cost reduction strongly depends on the control mechanisms of
decentralized generation units. In the first scenario with one central energy company controlling the
VPP (see section 1), optimal results can be achieved via centralized optimization and dispatching of
the decentralized units. In this scenario, central peak load generators are basically substituted by
decentralized ones. Spontaneity or self-organization do not occur here.
The two more advanced scenarios (see section 1) using market coordination are more promising
in this respect. Since dispatching is done here by a neutral local operator, or customers even have
direct control over their generation units, and all necessary information is communicated via the
price, optimization takes place locally. It is important that the technology used in the units supports
this degree of spontaneity: Since the type of units used in decentralized generation usually has short
ramping up times, spontaneity becomes possible much easier than in conventional settings. Equally,
the organization pattern moves away from a hierarchical coordination to a self-organized one that is
based on market mechanisms.
Thus, flexible price and cost structures as well as appropriate market design become vital for the
functioning of the whole system. From a technical viewpoint, the model presented in section 2
allows the exchange of offers and the conclusion of contracts. From the economic perspective, it is
equally important that the incentive structures in the market allow efficient solutions. For this, some
conditions must be met: In addition to the common conditions for market efficiency [6], the
technology and the cost structures of units used in decentralized scenarios must be compatible with
the goals set.
Concerning the costs, the following considerations should be taken into account: If, for example,
the price of a KWh produced by the cheapest decentralized unit is higher than that of the most
expensive central plant, decentralized units will not be dispatched (an exception can be justified by
the considerations in section 3.4 concerning risk premia, but here we are more concerned with short
term unit commitment problems with given investments). If, on the other hand, costs of a KWh
generated decentrally should ever drop lower than those of central base load generators, the
decentralized units should be dispatched first and would run continuously, thus replacing the cheap
but inflexible base load plants. In that case, if decentralized generation is not capable of providing
sufficient peak capacity, central peak load generators would have to be dispatched – quite not what
was intended in the first place. Of course, given the facts shown under 3.5 these are just theoretical
considerations at two extreme points.
In order to substitute central peak load generators as proposed in the introduction, variable
energy prices for decentralized units must be located between base and peak load prices.
Furthermore, an important condition is that the offers given to the market reflect real costs and are
not influenced by strategic behavior of market participants. Otherwise, big energy suppliers could be
tempted to deter decentralized competition by artificially lowering the peak prices in order to secure
the further use of their investments.
3.2 Transmission
Evidently, virtual power plants consisting mainly of units installed at the consumers’ sites also make
a contribution to take load from long-distance transmission lines. First, due to the fact that the power
is already at the desired location, transmission losses can be dramatically reduced. In typical
transmission systems, about 1-3 per cent of transported power are lost per 1000 km during
transmission.
Even more important effects occur when the market succeeds in reducing peak load demand
from central sources. Since power lines are designed to transport the maximum amount occurring
during rare peaks, large parts of the capacity lie idle most of the time. Using decentralized peak
generators, the gap between minimum and maximum required capacity on the lines connecting
power plants and distribution networks is diminished. Consequently, spare capacity is unleashed that
can be used in two ways: Further growth in energy demand is possible without the need of new
power lines or their extension. In the long term, if demand stagnates, replacement investments can
be avoided or at least reduced due to this fact.
A more steady use of transmission lines has another positive side effect: since due to a reduced
percentage reserved for peak demand, at the same fixed cost, more of the capacity is used over time,
the price for the use of transmission lines can be expected to drop accordingly. If the supplier can
effectively reduce his peak demand, he can choose a less expensive tariff for transmission line
usage.
Finally, since decentrally generated power is already in the desired location, it has a cost
advantage whose height may correspond to the price usually charged by transmission network
operators and the value of the transmission losses.
Unfortunately, these positive effects only occur with local generation. If the virtual power plant
includes a high percentage of renewable energy sources that are not at the customers’ sites but, for
instance, in an off-shore wind park or in a remote area with a high number of sunshine hours per
year, these effects will be less pronounced or even reversed. Another problem with this kind of
renewable energy sources is that they cannot be subjected to a conventional unit commitment plan
since they depend on climatic effects. Although a recent study has shown that sun and wind power
complement each other well [7], the basic problem persists.
3.3 Transformation
In order to reduce losses on transmission lines, high voltages are used on these lines. Consequently,
losses are incurred in transforming and retransforming, but these are evidently smaller than those
that can be expected on a low voltage line. Thus, long distance transmission always implies
transformation.
In an average system, transmission and transformation losses amount to 5 per cent of the energy
transported which results in correspondingly higher prices.
Analogously to the argumentation given in the last section, these losses can be avoided with
decentralized peak generation as well as smaller costs of transformation equipment. Consequently,
investment in transformation can be reduced following a similar argumentation.
3.4 Investment Risks for Generation Units
The liberalization of energy markets has brought increased uncertainty with respect to investment
decisions. When they still had a monopoly for their respective area, utilities were able to project
demand for long terms from current data. Today, fluctuations of the customer base are common and
will become even more pronounced in the future. Since big power plants require many years from
the investment decision until they are operable and usually have a lifetime measured in decades,
their construction cannot be planned on a short-term basis.
On the other hand, small, decentralized generation units require less time from planning to
operation, have shorter life times and smaller investment requirements, thus offering at least a part
of the flexibility required in deregulated markets. Already, there is a trend in Germany to replace old
plants with smaller, less expensive (in terms of fixed costs) ones. Their downside are the higher
variable costs: First, the technology in itself has higher fuel costs, e.g. gas turbines versus nuclear
power. Second, economies of scale for personnel, training, maintenance, fuel delivery etc. cannot be
realized on this small scale in the same way as with big centralized plants.
However, there is a possible way to justify these potentially increased total costs of decentralized
units: They can be interpreted in this context as a risk premium that suppliers (obviously) are willing
to pay in order to avoid long-term engagement in plants that may not be needed in a few years’ time.
3.5 Cogeneration of Power and Heat
As discussed in the last paragraph, decentralized power generation alone will always have cost
disadvantages compared to centralized units, even if it may be justified by risk reduction
considerations. This is where the biggest advantage of decentralized power generation comes into
play: The possibility of naturally combining power and heat provision.
Traditionally, the generation and distribution of heat – contrary to electricity – has always been
limited to a local level. This is due to the high losses in steam pipelines allowing only the traversal
of short distances.
Small generation units tend to have a lower efficiency than bigger ones – between 30 and 45%
electrical efficiency [8] – when used only for power generation. On the other hand, in big power
plants the excess heat from power generation is typically lost due to the fact that its transport from
the plant to the supplier is not economically feasible. Since the heat is already at the right place
when using small generation units in the consumers’ garage or basement, transport losses are
minimal when the heat is inserted directly into the house heating system. Thus, the energy normally
going to waste in centralized plants is used and serves to increase the efficiency of the system. When
using integrated units for electricity and heat, the total efficiency of the system reaches 85 to 90%.
4 Optimization for Customers and Growing Awareness for Power
Issues
For most customers, electricity is a "low interest" product. From their perspective, there is no need
to deal with load curves or tariffs because there is no benefit. Customers with high electricity
demands are more amenable to such issues and are more flexible in their demand, and usually try to
maximize synergies and cost saving potentials. Most of the small and medium sized customers,
however, have a tariff that is independent from the time of day the energy is used. These customers
pay for the energy used without any limitation and independent of the time of usage.
One goal of the SESAM project is to take advantage of the potential that lies in the demand
patterns of small customers. Such customers, however, must be motivated to change their habits and
to actually deal with "energy" as a topic. For most of these customers, a financial incentive will
make them think about and ultimately change their habits.
The first step to get a financial benefit is thus to create new - and cheaper - tariffs that at the
same time reflect the real cost structure for producing energy, e.g. higher prices at noon and lower
prices at nighttime.
Almost all of the home appliances that spend a significant amount of energy, e.g. cookers,
hairdryers or lamps, are needed at a specific time and there is no possibility to move the
consumption to a time where the price for electricity is lower. There are, however, other home
appliances that could easily be moved to cheaper time slots with their activities, e.g. washing and
drying machines since customers can rather freely decide when to turn on those devices. Some other
devices have a certain flexibility in when energy is used, but the customer is not able to control this,
e.g. a refrigerator. The refrigerator has to run when the temperature reaches a certain level. When the
temperature is low enough again, the refrigerator stops automatically. By cooling/freezing to a lower
than required temperature, the time until the next start can be extended and the start of such an
interval can be chosen freely. Despite such general possibilities, a customer will neither be able nor
willing to control manually every electric device he owns. To overcome this, there is a need for
devices that can be controlled automatically. One way to control a device is to send the current cost
for electricity to the device for such device to decide when to use energy or to have the device use
energy always at a specific time.
In the SESAM project, customers will be allowed to model their energy needs in a detailed
manner: They are able to model every single device as needed with every possible degree of
freedom, as well as limitations and constrains as desired. Dependencies between devices can be
modelled as well as additional costs as penalty for late dispatching.
Figure 2: Load curve example
Figure 2 shows an editor where a refrigerator is modelled. The solid rectangle shows the block
of energy usage, the dashed rectangle shows the possible start times and the patterned rectangle
above the solid one shows penalties that occur when the interval between two points of time is
increased. In this editor, every electric device can be modelled in a new diagram or devices can be
combined in one diagram to model dependencies. Devices modelled in different diagrams have no
dependencies and can be dispatched independently.
When the load curve is modelled, the customer can choose between 3 different kinds of
optimization and can even combine them.
The three types of optimization are:
1. For a given load curve: Find the optimal tariff in the market
2. For a given load curve and a tariff: Find the best dispatching to reduce the costs
3. Find potential customers which could cooperate to get a better tariff.
The first optimization is rather simple as it only determines the costs for every available tariff
and selects the one with the lowest overall costs.
The second optimization uses the modelled load curve to adapt to a given tariff. This is a lot
more complex than the first optimization. The complexity grows with the degree of freedom for the
devices. The outcome though will minimize the costs for the given tariff.
These two optimizations can of course be combined to find the best combination of tariff in a
dispatching plan. The complexity for such a combined optimization is rather high and can only be
calculated completely for small problems. For larger and more complex issues, heuristics are needed
which may not lead to the global optimum but will find an acceptable solution in a given time.
The degree of freedom for a single private customer is not very high and the potential financial
benefit will be rather small. To gain a greater benefit, customers can cooperate with each other and
optimize their overall energy consumption. The cooperation of customers leads to a higher overall
energy demand and could enable such customers to obtain better tariffs (i.e. industry tariffs). The
organized devices can be dispatched independently which may lead to a better load curve.
In the last optimization, the best potential customers should be found.
Figure 3: Load curve optimization
Figure 3 shows a possible scenario. In a) the costs for different times and different amounts of
energy are shown. In b), c), and d) the customers’ demands are depicted by differently filled
rectangles. In b) no customer optimizes his demand at all and use their energy as early as possible.
The overall costs are very high. In c) the customers have the same degree of freedom but optimize
independently. The resulting load curve will be the same for all customers. The overall costs are
slightly lower then in b). In the last diagram d) the load curves are optimized together which leads to
a better balanced load curve. Usually, the more the load curve is balanced, the lower the overall cost
will be, because the cheaper base load can be used in order to satisfy this demand profile.
All optimizations can be combined. In such case, the best tariff, with the best load curve, and
combined from different customers is found. The complexity of this problem is obviously much
higher than the optimizations presented above.
These possible optimizations lead to a better awareness with regard to power issues and, as a
result, to a better use of energy. Looking at the results of the optimization, a customer may find out
that besides some peaks his energy demand is so balanced that it would belong to the base load
band.
In order to gain financial benefits for base load, the consumer needs to procure his peak demand
from other sources. One way could be to run his own a little power plant – e.g. combined heat and
power plant as proposed in section 3.5 – to cover his load peaks. When the costs for such a little
plant and the base load are lower than the costs for a tariff which covers the peaks in his load curve,
this would be a feasible solution. Since a power plant also produces heat, the costs for heating could
be reduced which would lead to an additional reduction of the costs. Usually, those plants will only
be profitable when the heat is needed and used. The reduced cost for base load tariffs alone will not
be sufficient to finance the plant. Although the plant is primarily designated to cover the peaks in the
load curve, excess energy could also be sold. Whenever the price for energy exceeds the price for
turning on a consumer’s own plant it is profitable to sell the energy.
The costs for a small power plant will be too high for a single customer but in cooperation with
his neighbors, such costs may be acceptable. The customers benefit from this solution because of the
reduced costs. The energy producer reduces its costs because of its lower top load and a better
exploitation of its power plants. The following subsection sets forth an example of a possible cost
reduction through customer optimization.
Decentralized power production with small units may also have some social effects. First of all,
the awareness for power related problems is raised. The customers will try to optimize their energy
demand and electricity is no longer a "low interest" product.
Despite the change of mind some other social problems may arise: decentralized power creation
leads to stronger emission at the places where the plant is placed. Larger power plants are normally
placed offside where only emissions like CO2 have an impact on the inhabitants. Small power plants
have to be near the demand site to achieve the optimal effect (reduced transmission losses, use of the
heat). Thus, the emission – i.e., noise or dust – will have a direct impact on the neighborhood. The
emission will return as immission to the local neighborhood where the plant is placed. Because CO 2
will spread out over a large area, the emission will be the same as from a large plant, independently
of the amount of the CO emission. Therefore, CO is not a local problem and can be neglected
2
2
here.
Dust, noise, vibrations (e.g. from diesel aggregates) or other pollution will affect only the direct
neighbors and such impact must be taken into account when planning a small power plant.
Especially dust and noise can have a negative impact on the living conditions and may lower the
standard of living. It is thus not possible to place a plant in any highly populated region.
Another problem is the heat created from such a plant. In the cold months of the year, the heat
can be used for heating or warm water. Usually, such a plant will produce enough heat to satisfy the
demand. But in the summer, there is nearly no need for heat anymore. Nevertheless, the heat will be
created when producing electricity. The heat is now garbage and must be disposed of. In some
regions, it could be very difficult to get rid of the heat when everybody has produced too much to
satisfy his electricity needs.
4.1 Results for Load Curve Optimization
In this section, we will present first results obtained by applying the optimization techniques
mentioned above to a single standard load curve for a private household. The demand pattern was
taken from [9], a data set containing load profiles for standard consumers widely used in Germany.
First, we assumed that 10% of the household’s power consumption can freely be redistributed
over the day. As prices, we used the internal costs of generation in a fictive, but representative
power plant pool as could be found with one of the four big suppliers currently active in
Germany [10]. Prices for transmission and distribution as well as ancillary services were not taken
into account as these normally represent a fixed share of the energy bill and thus do not change with
the kind of optimization discussed here. The case where a consumer changes the load class with his
network operator and thus pays less for transmission is not considered here.
With this setting, if one customer optimizes his costs with a variably usable share of 10 per cent
while no optimization takes place with the other customers, the total bill decreases by more than
1.56 per cent. If the fraction of freely redistributable demand is increased to 20%, the payload
decreases by 2.69 per cent. The diminishing marginal utility of a higher percentage of freely
distributable load indicates that the relation is not linear and decreasing with the percentage. This
effect will be investigated further in order to determine the exact relation between these variables.
If the load curve optimization is employed independently by every customer, the reduction
decreases to 1.14 per cent respectively 2 per cent for each customer. The reason for this effect is
clear: When only a small share of customers optimizes the load curve, base load can be used in
times of low demand. If, on the other hand, all customers use load curve optimization, additional
plants that do not belong to the base load class have to be used which increases the cost. Although
the potential is thus a bit lessened, load curve optimization represents an interesting approach for
reducing a customer’s energy bill while using efficient plants.
Furthermore, as has been discussed in the last section, even greater potentials can be achieved by
customers jointly optimizing their demand patterns.
5 Conclusion and Outlook
In this paper, we have described the framework used in the SESAM project in order to analyze the
impacts of decentralized generation or virtual power plants. We have sketched the architecture of the
framework and the prototype with its aspects concerning market and law. Furthermore, economic
considerations for the success of virtual power plants were derived and presented. Finally, as a first
result we have presented ideas for optimizing the behavior of a participant in an energy market
where prices are time dependent, communicated to the customer and where the customer can choose
to generate a part of his own demand. First results show that optimization of the load curve, where
applicable, have the potential to lower the electricity bill of a consumer. Further cost reduction will
be achieved when the optimization integrates other customers and also takes into account the
possibility of active (peak) load reduction via local generation.
There are still many questions open that we will pursue during the coming months: How do
customers react to the new possibilities given to them? How can spontaneity and self-organization
be automated by the respective systems in order to lower the acceptance threshold of customers?
What is the probable position of traditional suppliers?
Besides these aspects, it will be interesting to also analyze the supply quality produced by virtual
power plants. Will they be more or less reliable than the generation structures that predominate
today? It is especially this criterion that is crucial for the acceptance – and thus the success – of
decentralized energy generation.
Acknowledgement: We gratefully acknowledge funding of the project SESAM by the German
Federal Ministry of Education and Research (BMBF) within the scope of the research initiative
“Internetökonomie” (Internet Economics).
References
[1] Rolli, D., Neumann, D., Weinhardt, C.: A minimal market model in ephemeral markets. In:
Proceedings of TheFormEMC. Lecture Notes in Comuter Science (LNCS) (2004)
[2] Clancey, W.: The epistemology of a rule-based expert system - a framework for
explanation. Artificial Intelligence 20 (1983) 215–251
[3] Conrad, M., Dinger, J., Hartenstein, H., Zitterbart, M.: Combining service-orientation and
peer-to-peer networks. In: Kommunikation in verteilten Systemen. (2005) 181–184
[4] Lockemann, P.C., Nimis, J.: Softwareagenten: Von den Eigenschaften zur Architektur
(software-agents: From properties to architectures). it – Information Technology 47 (2005)
28–35
[5] Bratman, M.: Intentions, Plans and Practical Reasons. Harvard University Press,
Cambridge, MA (1987)
[6] Fama, E.F.: Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. The Journal
of Finance 25 (1970) 383–417
[7] Quaschning, V.: Systemtechnik einer klimaverträglichen Elektrizitätsversorgung in
Deutschland für das 21. Jahrhundert. Volume 6 of Forschritt-Berichte VDI. VDI-Verlag,
Düsseldorf (2000)
[8] AGFW: Pluralistische Wärmeversorgung. Technical report, Frankfurt (2001)
[9] Tiedemann, R., Fünfgeld, C.: Die Repräsentativen VDEW-Lastprofile – Der Fahrplan.
Technical report, TU Cottbus: Lehrstuhl Energiewirtschaftsrecht (2001)
[10] Tietze-Stöckinger, I.: Kurzbeschreibung PERSEUS-MUM und ausgewählte Ergebnisse.
Technical report, Universität Karlsruhe: Institut für Industriebetriebslehre und Industrielle
Produktion (2004)