Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Deferred taxation under default risk

2019, Journal of Economics

In this article, we have used a continuous EBIT-based model to study deferred taxation under default risk. Quite surprisingly, default risk has been disregarded in research on deferred taxation. In order to underline its importance, we first calculated the probability of default, over a given time period, together with the contingent value of tax deferral. We then applied our theoretical model to a sample of 27,749 OECD companies. We showed that, when accounting for both firms with a negative EBIT and firms with a probability of default higher than 50% (over a 10-year period), a relevant percentage of firms were close enough to default. Hence, these taxpayers should not consider deferred taxation in their financial statements, for the sake of prudence. Moreover, under default, the expected present value of deferred taxes was much lower than that obtained in a deterministic context. Hence, if we look at deferred taxes from the Government's point of view, we must consider them as being risk-free loans. However, only a portion are subsequently repaid, due to default. This implies that, when a Government allows accelerated tax depreciation it should be aware of future losses due to default. So far, these estimates have been missing, although techniques do exist and are quite practical. JEL-Codes: H250, M410.

econstor A Service of zbw Make Your Publications Visible. Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Carini, Cristian; Moretto, Michele; Panteghini, Paolo; Vergalli, Sergio Working Paper Deferred Taxation under Default Risk CESifo Working Paper, No. 7057 Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Carini, Cristian; Moretto, Michele; Panteghini, Paolo; Vergalli, Sergio (2018) : Deferred Taxation under Default Risk, CESifo Working Paper, No. 7057, Center for Economic Studies and Ifo Institute (CESifo), Munich This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/180319 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. You are not to copy documents for public or commercial purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. www.econstor.eu If the documents have been made available under an Open Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. 7057 2018 May 2018 Deferred Taxation under Default Risk Cristian Carini, Michele Moretto, Paolo M. Panteghini, Sergio Vergalli Impressum: CESifo Working Papers ISSN 2364‐1428 (electronic version) Publisher and distributor: Munich Society for the Promotion of Economic Research ‐ CESifo GmbH The international platform of Ludwigs‐Maximilians University’s Center for Economic Studies and the ifo Institute Poschingerstr. 5, 81679 Munich, Germany Telephone +49 (0)89 2180‐2740, Telefax +49 (0)89 2180‐17845, email [email protected] Editors: Clemens Fuest, Oliver Falck, Jasmin Gröschl www.cesifo‐group.org/wp An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded ∙ from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com ∙ from the RePEc website: www.RePEc.org ∙ from the CESifo website: www.CESifo‐group.org/wp CESifo Working Paper No. 7057 Category 1: Public Finance Deferred Taxation under Default Risk Abstract In this article, we have used a continuous EBIT-based model to study deferred taxation under default risk. Quite surprisingly, default risk has been disregarded in research on deferred taxation. In order to underline its importance, we first calculated the probability of default, over a given time period, together with the contingent value of tax deferral. We then applied our theoretical model to a sample of 27,749 OECD companies. We showed that, when accounting for both firms with a negative EBIT and firms with a probability of default higher than 50% (over a 10-year period), a relevant percentage of firms were close enough to default. Hence, these taxpayers should not consider deferred taxation in their financial statements, for the sake of prudence. Moreover, under default, the expected present value of deferred taxes was much lower than that obtained in a deterministic context. Hence, if we look at deferred taxes from the Government’s point of view, we must consider them as being risk-free loans. However, only a portion are subsequently repaid, due to default. This implies that, when a Government allows accelerated tax depreciation it should be aware of future losses due to default. So far, these estimates have been missing, although techniques do exist and are quite practical. JEL-Codes: H250, M410. Keywords: capital structure, contingent claims, corporate taxation and tax depreciation allowances. Cristian Carini University of Brescia / Italy [email protected] Michele Moretto University of Padua / Italy [email protected] Paolo M. Panteghini University of Brescia / Italy [email protected] Sergio Vergalli University of Brescia / Italy [email protected] May 8, 2018 The authors wish to thank Vito Polito for his stimulating discussions on deferred taxation. Many thanks also go to Alberto Quagli and Amedeo Pugliese for their helpful comments. Usual disclaimers hold. 1 Introduction Book accounting di¤ers from tax accounting in most OECD countries, due to divergence between the purposes of Accounting Principles (e.g., US GAAP and IFRS) for …nancial reporting and those for tax forms. This could cause a gap between the value of assets and liabilities for book and tax purposes. As we know, this gap can depend on either permanent or temporary di¤erences.1 For instance, Poterba, Rao and Seidman (2011) …nd that, in the USA, the book-tax gap is mainly caused by temporary di¤erences generated by the intertemporal mismatch between the carrying amount of assets and liabilities for tax and …nancial accounting (regarding, for instance, depreciation). The theoretical implications of deferred taxation for corporations have been extensively studied in the accounting literature. For instance, Sansing (1998) and Guenther and Sansing (2000) demonstrated that deferred taxes have real e¤ects on corporations, whether or not they revert over time. This is because they are directly charged against corporate earnings in the income statement. Mills (2006) highlighted the importance of the book-tax gap and pointed out several implications of deferred taxation for corporate policy. For example, corporations with large deferred tax assets are likely to lobby against tax cuts, whereas corporations with net deferred tax liabilities positions are likely to lobby for tax rate cuts. Furthermore, the empirical accounting research has demonstrated that in the United States, the aggregate deferred tax balance for the corporate sector is a liability. This has increased over time, reaching about $400 billion by the end of 2004. Its main driver has been the di¤erence between book and tax depreciation.2 It is worth noting that existing literature has neglected the possible e¤ects of default on deferred taxation. As we know, if a …rm defaults, deferred taxes are written o¤. This means that a Government, that allows generous tax depreciation allowances, faces a potential loss. As will be shown, this social cost may well be relevant. In order to explain the nexus between tax deferral and default we will use a twofold approach. Firstly, using a stochastic continuous-time model, we will calculate both the probability of default within a given period and the expected value of deferred taxes. Secondly, we will apply our theoretical model to a sample of 27,749 OECD companies. As shown, if we account for both …rms with a negative EBIT and those with a probability of default higher than 50% (over a 10-year period), a relevant portion of …rms in 1 Positive temporary di¤erences generate deferred tax liabilities, i.e., taxes to be paid in the future, which increase the total tax liability of a corporation; negative temporary di¤erences generate deferred tax assets, i.e., credits against current taxes, thus reducing the total tax liability of a corporation. 2 See, e.g., Mills and Plesko (2003), Hanlon and Shevlin (2005) as well as Poterba, Rao and Seidman (2011). 2 the sample is not far from default. For this reason, these taxpayers should not reckon deferred taxes in their …nancial statements, for the sake of prudence. Moreover, under default, the expected present value of deferred taxes is much lower than that obtained in a deterministic context. If we look at deferred taxes from the Government’s point of view, we must therefore consider them as risk-free loans. However, only a portion is repaid, due to default. The structure of the article is as follows. Section 2 provides a review of the literature on deferred taxation. Section 3 develops a contingent claim model, which enabled us to calculate both the probability of default and the present value of deferred taxes. Section 4 uses a dataset of European companies to provide a numerical analysis. Section 5 summarizes our …ndings and discusses their policy implications. 2 Literature Review In this Section we brie‡y review the relevant literature on accelerated tax depreciation allowances and its e¤ects on tax deferral. To our knowledge however, nobody has yet analyzed the e¤ects of default risk on the evaluation of the (fair) value of deferred taxes. The economic e¤ects of deferred taxation on investment choices and corporate tax policy analysis were …rst analyzed by King (1974), who stressed the fact that law imposes a binding dividend constraint on corporations. Boadway and Bruce (1979) and Boadway (1980) pointed out that dividends should not exceed after-tax pro…t. Sinn (1987) suggested a slightly modi…ed constraint, according to which dividends cannot exceed after-tax current pro…t, net of (accelerated) depreciation. Kanniainen and Södersten (1995) proved that the present form of the deferred tax constraint is ultimately de…ned by the …nancial reporting rules to which a corporation must adhere. To the extent that book depreciation equals economic depreciation, the formulation of the deferred tax constraint proposed by Kanniainen and Södersten (1995) is therefore consistent with the temporary di¤erences approach currently required by a country’s GAAP. The deferred tax constraint, however, creates liquidity in the …rm as it increases cash holdings. In Kanniainen and Södersten (1995), extra liquidity is neither distributed to shareholders (due to the deferred tax constraint), nor is invested in physical capital since it arises at the margin, i.e., when the optimal capital stock has already been accumulated. Polito (2009) applied Kanniainen and Södersten’s (1995) model of the deferred tax constraint to calculate the E¤ective Tax Rates on domestic investment …nanced by retained earnings implicit in the 2008 tax codes of …ve European countries. He showed that forward-looking e¤ective tax rates are negatively biased because traditional models 3 overlook dividend constraints associated with …nancial tax incentives, such as accelerated depreciation. More recently, Polito (2012) incorporated deferred taxation in Devereux and Gri¢th (1998, 2003) and showed that the impact of deferred taxation holds whether it is assessed using a framework consistent with the "old view", the "new view" and the "neutral view" of corporate taxation.3 All these articles applied deterministic frameworks. The accounting research deals with tax deferral by focusing on several aspects.4 Some research aims to …nd whether taxation provides additional information to investors (see, e.g., Chludek, 2011, Dhaliwahl et al. 2004, and Gleason et al., Gleason and Mills, 2002). Other work looks at managers’ behavior in terms of tax aggressiveness (see, e.g., Huseynov and Klamm, 2012, as well as Klassen et al., 2016). Moreover, there are many papers that discuss the valuation of tax deferral (see Amir et al., 1997 and 2001) as well as reversal (see Laux, 2013). Finally, Schackelford et al. (2012) point out that empirical research studying the relationship between tax and …nancial reporting focuses on tax compliance and discusses some issues regarding tax uncertainty. This strand of literature has had a relevant boost due to the introduction of a new accounting rule (FIN 48) in the USA. The aim of this reform was to standardize the reckoning of uncertain tax bene…ts and to induce companies to disclose their tax reserve amounts (see Blouin et al.,2007 and Mills et al., 2010). Tax uncertainty arises from the di¢culty in applying ambiguous tax laws and anticipating the consequences of a future tax audit (Diller et al., 2016; Mills et al., 2010).5 Despite this reform, other sources of uncertainty (such as default) have still been neglected.6 Moreover, with a few exceptions (Sansing, 1998, Guenther and Sansing, 2000, Diller et al., 2017), tax experts have analyzed taxation in a deterministic context. In any case, default risk has been disregarded.7 3 See also Edgerton (2012), who compared the impact of investment tax credits and accelerated tax depreciation. He showed that the former relief has more impact on investment choices than the latter. 4 For further details see Graham (2005), Hanlon and Heitzman (2010), Graham et al. (2012). 5 Tax uncertainty combines three aspects: an investment decision, the tax compliance, and the …nancial reporting matters. Investment decision, tax e¤ects and …nancial reporting incentives can potentially interact in ways that a¤ect investment decisions (Hanlon et al. 2010). First of all, value, timing and uncertainty of tax payments a¤ect the present value of a project and therefore invest choices. Secondly, through deprecation or expensing, the investment decision will a¤ect pre-tax accounting earnings. Lastly, as pointed out by Edgerton (2012), tax policies that do not a¤ect accounting pro…t (e.g., accelerated depreciation) are less e¤ective in stimulating investment than those that increase accounting pro…t (e.g., investment tax credit). Concluding tax uncertainty is harmful for investment (Edmiston, 2004; Scholes et al., 2015). 6 So far, scholars have mainly focused on the tax compliance uncertainty (Diller et al. 2016; De Simone et al. 2013; Mills et al. 2010). 7 If we look at the main accounting principles all over the world (US GAAP as well as IAS/IFRS), 4 3 The model In order to study deferred taxation under default risk, let us focus on a representative …rm which makes an investment I at time 0.8 De…ning the EBIT (Earnings Before Interest and Taxes) at time t as t , we introduce the following:9 Assumption 1 A …rm’s investment I yields an EBIT t ; that evolves according to a geometric Brownian motion (with 0 ), where is its deterministic growth rate, is the instantaneous standard deviation and dzt is the increment of a standard Wiener process. Moreover, growth rate cannot exceed the risk-free interest rate r.10 Assumption 2 Depreciation and amortization (DA) is constant and equal to I with 2 (0; 1) : These resources are used to maintain asset I. Assumption 3 At time 0, the …rm decides how much to borrow from a perfectly competitive risk-neutral lender. Given r, C is the coupon paid to the lender under non-arbitrage. Assumption 4 Debt is not renegotiable. Assumption 5 If the …rm does not meet its debt obligations (towards both the Government and lender), default occurs, namely the …rm is expropriated by the lender. we realize that they deal with uncertainty using a "detection free-risk" approach. According to IFRIC, detection risk is "the risk that the tax authority will detect an error or misapplication of the taxation requirement and accordingly, assess additional (less) tax. Detecting risk of 100% means the tax authority will detect all such errors or misapplication" (IFRIC, July 2014). Both US GAAP and IAS/IFRS adopt the detection risk free approach. Indeed, "it shall be presumed that the tax position will be examined by the relevant tax authorities that has full knowledge of all relevant information" (ASC 740-10-25-27) and similarly "an entity shall assume that a taxation authority with the rights to examine amounts reported to it will examine those amounts and have full knowledge of all relevant information making those examination" (IFRIC 23 par. 13). Under the detection risk-free approach, two (quite restrictive and unrealistic) assumptions are used. Firstly, the tax authority have full information about current and future events. Secondly, markets are fully e¢cient. Also in the GAAP perspective no space is given to default risk. 8 For simplicity, we assume that a …rm cannot postpone its investment decision. For a discussion of this choice see Panteghini (2012), and Panteghini and Vergalli (2016). Moreover, we also assume that economic and book depreciation coincide. In doing so, we can focus on the tax e¤ects of depreciation allowances. 9 For further details on the EBIT-based models see also Panteghini (2006, 2007, 2012). 10 Notice that the di¤erence r is the well-known convenience yield (see, e.g., McDonald and Siegel, 1985). 5 Assumption 6 After default, the Government loses the deferred tax which was originally granted. Under Assumption 1, a …rm’s EBIT evolves as follows: d t = dt + dzt ; with 0 > 0: (1) t According to Assumption 2, Depreciation and amortization is proportional to the initial investment I and therefore, the EBITDA (Earnings Before Interest, Taxes, Depreciation and Amortization) will be t + I: As pointed out, the maintenance cost of the investment is equal to I: In line with Leland (1994), Assumption 3 states that our representative …rm pays a coupon C.11 For simplicity, we assume that C is not optimally chosen but rather is given exogenously.12 Moreover, according to assumption 4, debt cannot be renegotiated: this means that the …rm’s …nancial policy cannot be reviewed later.13 Assumption 5 introduces the risk of default, respectively. Given (1), it is assumed that if the …rm’s EBIT falls to a given threshold level, the …rm is expropriated by the lender (assumption 5). Moreover, according to assumption 6, default causes a loss for the Government. This assumption is of course in line with the main accounting principles.14 3.1 Taxation Let us next introduce taxation. We de…ne as the tax rate and assume that interest payments are fully deductible. For simplicity, we also assume full loss-o¤set.15 11 Given this coupon and the risk-free interest rate r, the market value of debt can be calculated in the absence of arbitrage (see Leland, 1994). 12 For a joint analysis of …nancial and investment choices with accelerated tax depreciation allowances see Panteghini and Vergalli (2016). 13 The absence of debt renegotiation simpli…es our analysis, although it does not a¤ect the qualitative properties of the model. For a detailed analysis of …nancial decisions, with costly debt renegotiation, see e.g. Goldstein et al. (2001), and Hennessy and Whited (2005). 14 For instance, according to the International GAAP 2009, (Generally Accepted Accounting Practice under International Financial Reporting Standards, vol.2., Wiley, West Sussex): “Deferred tax is an accounting model based on the premise that, for …nancial reporting purposes, the tax e¤ects on transactions should be recognized in the same period as the transactions themselves". Moreover, "[t]he tax authorities cannot demand payment of an entity’s deferred tax liability until it forms part of the legal tax liability for a future period; equally, an entity cannot recover its deferred tax assets from the tax authorities until they form a deduction in arriving at the legal tax liability for a future period.”This means that, in the event of default, deferred taxes simply vanish and cause no tax liability. 15 Of course, this simplifying assumption could be relaxed and we intend to leave these extensions for future research. 6 Here, we assume that tax depreciation allowances follow the straight-line method. According to these assumptions, a tax deduction will be ensured as long as our representative …rm continue to produce. Since we want to focus on accelerated tax depreciation, we assumed that the inequality F > holds.16 In this case, deferred tax liabilities are generated whenever tax depreciation exceeds economic depreciation (i.e., F > ). This means that our …rm can postpone a portion of the tax liability, thereby leading to deferred taxes. More precisely, a …rm must usually set a provision for the tax rate levied on the di¤erence between tax and economic depreciation, namely, ( F ). Thus the term ( F ) Idt measures the deferred tax burden in an interval dt.17 Since we aim to study the e¤ects of default, we must also take into account the lenders’ tax treatment. For simplicity, we disregarded personal taxation and assumed that the lender’s pre-default tax burden is nil. This means that, before default, the lender receives C at any time t and pays zero taxes. When however, default takes place, the lender earns t instead of C. 3.2 Default The calculation of the default threshold level of t depends on the de…nition of default. In this article, we let a company default when t does not allow to pay both taxes and the coupon. According to this de…nition, default may be triggered when the …rm’s EBIT falls to the exogenously given threshold point D . Given these assumptions, the after-tax cash ‡ow will be equal to: N ( t ; C) = (1 )( t C) + F I: (2) According to Assumption 5, if N ( t ; C) > 0, the …rm continues to operate. When however N ( t ; C) goes to zero, default takes place and the …rm is expropriated. Solving 16 Guenther and Sansing (2004) used the declining balance method to measure the bene…ts of tax depreciation allowances. The quality of results however, does not change. To show this, let us de…ne the tax depreciation rate and the economic depreciation rate under the declining balance method as and b, respectively. The present value of the tax bene…t due to tax and economic depreciation will then b b : According to our model we are assuming that r+ b: In be r+ and r+b r+b ; or equivalently our framework we focused on deferred taxation and therefore, we let the inequality F hold. In doing so, we disregarded the e¤ects of reversal, that occurs when tax depreciation is less than economic depreciation. 17 As pointed out by Polito (2009), if tax is deferred, there is some undistributed cash, which could be re-invested in a risk-free bond. For simplicity, we did not account for this extra-provision and considered this cash as a collateral that reduces the risk of default. As long as the level of risk-free interest rates is low enough, this simplifying assumption does not a¤ect the quality of results. 7 the equality occurs:18 N ( t ; C) = 0 for t D thus gives the threshold level below which default =C F I: 1 (3) Notice that the inequality D < C holds. This means that, thanks to tax depreciation allowances, the …rm does not necessarily default if t is less than C.19 It is worth noting that D is a¤ected by taxation, and in particular, given (3) we can see that: Proposition 1 The higher the tax parameters D is. F and , the lower the threshold point According to Proposition 1, we can say that when deferred taxation is allowed, there is a reduction in the threshold point D . This means that, for any t , default is delayed. Of course, this result has an important implication, in that accelerated depreciation and other causes of deferred taxation reduce the probability of default for any t and a¤ect the contingent evaluation of future events (see Panteghini and Vergalli, 2016). Given these results we can therefore calculate the probability of default over a certain period as well as the expected present value of deferred taxes, contingent on the event of default. These computations are necessary for the numerical analysis of Section 4. 3.3 Probability Let us focus on a given period [0; T ] and calculate the probability of default within time T . In other terms, we will have to measure the probability that hits D in the [0; T ] period. It worth noting that, given the inequality 0 > D , the probability of default is equivalent to the the probability of the geometric Brownian motion t reaching the critical value D within [0; T ]. Given the geometric Brownian motion (1), i we can write h 2 t + Wt : As shown in that, at any time t, the value of EBIT is t = 0 exp 2 18 In this model, for simplicity, we also assumed that the cuto¤ level of , below which default takes place, was exogenously given. Leland (1994) also analyzed a case where this threshold level was optimally chosen by shareholders. 19 It is worth noting that this default assumption causes no loss of generality. If, for instance, we assumed that shareholders can decide when to default, the threshold level would be lower. However, the new threshold would be similar to D : For a detailed analysis of default conditions see, e.g., Panteghini (2006, 2007), who shows that the quality of results does not change when an endogenously given threshold point is found. 8 Appendix A the probability of default over the [0; T ] period is therefore equal to: P T D = P[ D ( ) T D = ln ] 0 2 D ln 0 0 + p T 2 T ! ln + D 0 2 p T T ! (4) 2 and = 2 . Apart from the complexity of formula (4), which will where = 2 be used in our numerical analysis, we can say that, coeteris paribus, an increase in the tax parameters and F reduces D and hence, the probability of default. 3.4 The contingent value of deferred taxation In the absence of default (and of other uncertain events, such as those referring to uncertain tax positions), the bene…t due to tax deferral would be higher. If, for instance, the present value of deferred taxation is equal to 1 Euro, under default risk we expect that its "fair" value is less. In this Section we therefore calculate the value of deferred taxation, contingent to the event of default. As shown in Appendix B, this value, denoted by DT ( ; C), will be equal to: ( 0 = D i h 2 (5) DT ( ; C) = > D; 1 D ( F )I where is the present value of the bene…t arising from deferred taxation in r a deterministic context.20 As can be seen, if the EBIT reaches the threshold level D ; default occurs and the bene…ts from tax deferral vanish. If is higher, the bene…t is 2 measures the present value of 1 Euro contingent positive. It is worth noting that D 2 2 (0; 1), the present value on the event of default (see Panteghini, 2007). Since D of the bene…t arising from deferred taxation is lower under default risk. As shown in Appendix C we can see that: Proposition 2 An increase in both and F time reduces the contingent value of 1 Euro of deferred tax. 20 2 D , and thus increases Using the notation of footnote 16, under a declining balance method, the deterministic value of the b bene…t arising from deferred taxation would be 0: Of course, the quality of results r+ r+b I would not change. 9 Proof. See Appendix C. According to Proposition 2, tax parameters a¤ect the contingent evaluation of future events. An increase in both and F reduces D . This means that, given , default is less likely. Hence, the contingent value of 1 Euro of deferred taxation increases. 4 A numerical analysis It is worth noting that F a¤ects the probability of default. Furthermore, the higher the parameter F the more valuable deferred taxation is. In order to study both e¤ects we will run a numerical example based on the information contained in the ORBIS dataset. 4.1 Some descriptive statistics This dataset provides information on approximately 250 million companies across the world and is provided by Bureau van Dijk. Here, we focused on active manufacturing companies belonging to the NACE class, letter C, from 10 to 33. We selected companies operating in OECD countries, with a turnover of over 20 million Euros. By choosing the 2011-2015 period, we obtained a set of 33,791 OECD companies (see Table 1). Table 1: Descriptive statistics of Aggregate and % 2015 Total Assets (TAs) 21,804 Turnover 18,079 EBIT 1,368 Interest paid 192 EBIT/TAs 15.0% Interest Paid/TAs 2.1% the ORBIS population (millions of Euros). 2014 2013 2012 2011 Avg. 20,167 18,113 18,422 17,756 19,252 17,661 16,439 16,940 16,691 17,162 1,321 1,205 1,160 1,287 1,268 183 171 180 182 182 16.3% 16.5% 15.6% 18.1% 16.3% 2.3% 2.3% 2.4% 2.6% 2.3% Our analysis was conducted exclusively on companies with available data, limited to those with at least three years of data. We therefore eliminated 6,042 …rms and obtained a sample of 27,749 companies (see Table 2). 10 Table 2: Descriptive statistics of our sample Aggregate and % 2015 2014 2013 Total Assets (TAs) 19,696 18,346 16,505 Turnover 16,045 15,720 14,609 EBIT 1,183 1,148 1,055 Interest paid 185 177 165 EBIT/TAs 6.0% 6.3% 6.4% Interest Paid/TAs 0.9% 1.0% 1.0% (millions of Euros). 2012 2011 Avg. 16,800 16,261 17,522 15,061 14,882 15,263 1,003 1,129 1,104 175 177 176 6.0% 6.9% 6.3% 1.0% 1.1% 1.0% Finally, the sample was divided into two groups: the …rst one contained companies with EBIT> 0; the second consisted of companies with negative EBIT. The former (latter) group contains 87.8% (12.2%) of the whole sample. Tables 3 and 4 contain some descriptive statistics of these two groups. Table 3: Descriptive statistics Aggregate and % Total Assets (TAs) Turnover EBIT Interest paid EBIT/TAs Interest Paid/TAs of the sub-sample with positive EBIT (millions of Euros). 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 Avg. 18,510 17,164 15,394 15,623 15,032 16,345 14,885 14,531 13,451 13,839 13,595 14,060 1,228 1,178 1,087 1,084 1,137 1,143 168 160 149 159 160 159 6.6% 6.9% 7.1% 6.9% 7.6% 7.0% 0.9% 0.9% 1.0% 1.0% 1.1% 1.0% Table 4: Descriptive statistics of the sub-sample with negative EBIT (millions of Euros). Aggregate and % 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 Avg. Total Assets (TAs) 1,186 1,181 1,111 1,176 1,229 1,177 Turnover 1,160 1,189 1,157 1,223 1,288 1,203 EBIT -45 -29 -31 -80 -8 -39 Interest paid 17 16 16 16 17 16 EBIT/TAs -3.8% -2.5% -2.8% -6.8% -0.7% -3.3% Interest Paid/TAs 1.4% 1.4% 1.4% 1.4% 1.4% 1.4% It is worth noting that …rms with a systematically negative EBIT are relatively close to default, unless they can …nd additional resources. For precautionary reasons, therefore, they should not account for deferred taxation. For this reason, hereafter we will mainly focus on the positive-EBIT group of companies. Table 5 reports the relevant parameter values that will be used for our numerical analysis. As can be seen, some are derived from the ORBIS data; others are chosen 11 according to the following reasons. Since we want to focus on a long-term scenario T is set equal to 10 years.21 The tax depreciation rate is assumed to range from to 1:5 : The values of ; C and I are obtained by using the ORBIS dataset. In line with Bilicka and Devereux (2012), we used the same risk-free real interest rate (r = 5%). As regards the drift parameter , we used two di¤erent values: 0 and 0:02. The value of the investment cost I was equal to the sum between the tangible and intangible assets contained in the …nancial statements. Subsequently, it was normalized to 100, according to the ORBIS data. Finally, in line with Dixit and Pindyck (1994), we assumed that the benchmark volatility is 20%. We also accounted for a more volatile context where the standard deviation was higher (30% and 40%, respectively). Table 5: Average values used for the numerical simulation. Variable Parameters Value(s) Time horizon T 10 and 15 Tax depreciation allowance = 2 f1; 1:5g F EBIT from ORBIS Coupon C from ORBIS Tax rate 25% Investment cost I Normalized to 100 Growth rate 0% and 2% risk-free real interest rate r 5% volatility 20%; 30%; 40% We then analyzed the probability of default in our sub-sample of …rms characterized by a positive EBIT. To do so, we divided the sub-sample into ten deciles, obtained by means of the distribution of interest payments. This allowed us to calculate the number of …rms with a default probability higher than 50%.22 Table 6 shows that the percentage of distressed …rms crucially depends on the parameter values. Table 6 also shows that an increase in leads to an increase in the probability of default. This also suggests that if a …rm’s risk is higher than the average one (about = 0:2), the probability of default is higher. As regards tax depreciation allowances, we have used two values of F : 0:10 and 0:15. In the former case, no deferred taxation is reckoned, since F = = 0:1. In 21 For sake of brevity, we did not add the results obtained with T = 15. Data are available upon request. In any case, according to our theoretical framework, we know that the longer the arrival time T the higher the probability of default and the smaller the contingent value of deferred taxation will be. 22 Of course, the choice of the threshold probability of 50% is fully arbitrary. However, it allows to identify the distribution of …rms of …rms with high default risk. Obviously, if we raised the threshold level of probability, the number of …rms in …nancial distress would be smaller and vice versa. 12 the latter case, with = 25%, the yearly deferred tax is ( F )I = 1:25. In the absence of default therefore, the present value of deferred taxation will then be equal to ( F )I = 1:25 = 25: r 0:05 4.2 Results As shown in Table 6, deciles 9 and 10 contain a relevant number of …rms, whose default probability is higher than 50%. If we sum these …rms to those with negative EBIT (that is, 3385 companies, as shown in Table 4) we can say that many companies are close to default. This means that a great deal of resources might be lost by the Government. In particular, if = 0:2, the number of …rms with negative EBIT and/or with a probability of default higher than 50% is 3977 on a sample of 27,749 …rms (i.e., 14.33%). Of course if volatility is higher the number of almost distressed …rms rises. If = 0:4 the number of …rms with negative EBIT and/or with a probability of default higher than 50% is 4735 (i.e., 17.06% of the sample). Table 6: Number of …rms with probability of default higher than 50%(distribution according to interest payments) Interest paid Probability of default higher than 50% Decile 10 Decile 9 Decile 8 Decile 1-7 f 0.2 0.1 654 (27%) 211 (9%) 16 (1%) 0 (0%) 0.3 0.1 1000 (41%) 329 (14%) 21 (1%) 0 (0%) 0.4 0.1 1414 (58%) 593 (24%) 33 (1%) 0 (0%) 0.2 0.15 534 (22%) 58 (2%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 0.3 0.15 809 (33%) 85 (3%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 0.4 0.15 1213 (50%) 137 (6%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) Number of …rms for each decile = 2437; for the deciles 1-7 the total sample consists of 17052 …rms, T =10 years. Finally, if we look at the number of distressed …rms (i.e., …rms with a probability of default higher than 50%), we see that an increase in F has a twofold e¤ect: on the one hand, it increases the amount of deferred taxes (and therefore the risk-free loan ensured by the Government), on the other hand, it reduces the probability of default. This is in line with Proposition 1, according to which an increase in F delays default and at the same time increases the contingent value of deferred taxation. In order to understand this twofold e¤ect, we calculated the contingent value of deferred taxation. As usual, we focused on the sub-sample of …rms with a positive EBIT. Again, we analyzed the sample by focusing on the interest payments distribution. 13 Table 7: The contingent value of deferred taxation for deciles ratio Interest payments/Total assets f = 0:15 Interest paid = 0:00 Decile = 0:2 = 0:3 = 0:4 = 0:2 1 24.99 24.78 23.87 25.00 2 24.87 23.79 21.53 24.99 3 24.57 22.60 19.59 24.99 4 24.36 21.97 18.70 24.99 5 23.97 21.03 17.48 24.98 6 23.51 20.07 16.35 24.97 7 23.26 19.60 15.81 24.95 8 23.00 19.16 15.32 24.94 9 22.70 18.67 14.80 24.91 10 22.25 17.97 14.10 24.86 Total 22.85 18.92 15.07 24.92 obtained by using the = 0:02 = 0:3 24.99 24.97 24.89 24.82 24.67 24.45 24.32 24.20 24.01 23.74 24.10 = 0:4 24.98 24.78 24.36 24.08 23.60 23.04 22.74 22.44 22.09 21.58 22.27 As shown in Table 7, if = 0:10 < f = 0:15, the contingent value of deferred taxation not only depends on the ratio between Interest payments and Total assets (the higher this ratio, the lower the value of deferred taxation is), but also on volatility. In particular, this e¤ect has a dramatic impact on the "fair" value of deferred taxation. If, for instance, we look at …rms in decile 5, we can see that, when = 0:2 the contingent value is almost 24. This means that volatility has a negligible impact on the "fair value" of deferred taxation. When however volatility increases, the result is quite di¤erent and, with = 0:4, the contingent value of deferred taxation decreases by 27%. This e¤ect is less relevant if a …rm’s EBIT has a positive growth rate. As a result, we can see that the contingent value of deferred taxes depends on , and the starting value of EBIT. 5 Conclusion In this article, we have analyzed deferred taxation under default risk. Despite the fact that tax deferral has long been analyzed from many points of view, we have not found any work about this speci…c topic. To …ll the gap, we have therefore developed a simple continuous-time model aimed at calculating both the probability of default and the contingent value of deferred taxation. The calculation of the probability of default within a given time period allows us to check whether deferred taxes should be reckoned or not. In our view (and according to many accounting principles), …rms with a high probability 14 of default should not reckon deferred taxes because of their low opportunity of recovery. Quite surprisingly, both the existing literature on deferred taxation and the current accounting principles are silent on this point. The calculation of the contingent ("fair") value of deferred taxes allows us to evaluate the present value of the tax bene…t arising from accelerated tax depreciation, conditional on default. Again, this point is missing in existing literature, despite its importance. Since deferred tax allowances are equivalent to a risk-free loan guaranteed by the Government, we have shown how to evaluate the expected loss faced by the Government in the event of default. Our results lead to a twofold implication. The …rst regards existing accounting principles, that should consider default risk. For precautionary reasons, indeed, …rms with a high probability of default should omit deferred tax reckoning. The second implication is about the public e¤ect of default: from a Government’s point of view, deferred taxes are a considered as risk-free loans, although a relatively large portion of them are not repaid. For this reason we suggest that a Government willing to apply accelerated depreciation should also account for the expected possible loss due to the default. We have shown that techniques do exist and are quite easy to manage. 15 A Probability Let us focus on a stochastic process that follows a geometric Brownian motion. If at h i time 2 0 we have 0 > 0 then at time t > 0 we will have t = 0 exp t + Wt : Let 2 us next introduce a lower bound D < 0 and calculate the probability to hit D within D D time T . To do so we must de…ne the hitting time as follows: T = where = ( t )t 0 and t = mint [0;T ] : Given this notation the probability that t hits D in the [0; T ] period is: P D T =P D where ( ) t ln ]; (6) 0 (7) s2[0;t] and 2 ( ) t D = min f t + Wt g : 2 Using the de…nitions = P[ ( ) T 2 ; we can rewrite (7) as follows: = min f t + Wt g = min f t + Wt g : (8) s2[0;t] s2[0;t] Let us next use (6) and (8). Following Harrison (1985, pp. 11-14), Sarkar (2000, pp. 222-223) and Cappuccio and Moretto (2001, pp. 8-9) gives: P D T = P [XT = P[ B] D ( ) T 2 ln = e D = 0 Formula (4) is thus obtained. ] ln D 0 2 0 @ 0 @ 0 ln ln D 0 D 0 + p T 2 + p T 2 16 T T 1 0 1 0 A+ A+ @ @ ln ln D 0 2 p 2 p 1 T 1 T D 0 T T A A: B The derivation of (5) The value of deferred taxation can be written as: 0 [ ( DT ( ; C) = ) I] dt + e F rdt = > E [DT ( + d ; C)] D D ; : (9) DT ( ; C) is given by the solution of the following system of Second Order Di¤erential Equation, and the threshold level D is given by (3). Di¤erentiating (9) and applying Itô’s Lemma gives the following non-arbitrage condition: 1 2 2 2 DT ( ; C) + DT ( ; C) rDT ( ; C) = ( ) I: F (10) To solve equation (10), let us apply the following general function: 0 DT ( ; C) = + A1 1 + A2 2 = > D D ; ; (11) ( F )I is the present value of the bene…t arising from deferred taxation in where r a deterministic context. To solve (10) we use (11) and apply the following boundary condition (see Dixit and Pindyck, 1994): D DT ; C = 0: (12) Moreover, we assume the absence of …nancial bubbles. This means that the equality A1 = 0 must hold. Setting A1 = 0; and using (12) gives: + A2 D and thus A2 = C Given 2 D 2 = 0; (13) : Using these results in (11) gives function (5). Comparative statics D =C @ @ 1 D = = @ @ FI and 1 < 0 it is easy to show that: FI 1 FI (1 2 )2 (1 ) 2 FI < 0; D = F 1 I < 0: 17 = 1 (1 )2 (1 )2 FI Moreover, we obtain: h i 2 d D d d h 2 D d F References i = = h ( 2) | h | 2 {z D 2 >0 2 2 {z >0 D 2 1 1 i@ } @ i@ }@ D @ with @ D F with @ @ D = FI (1 )2 < 0; D = F 1 I < 0: [1] Amir E., M. Kirschenheithr and K. Willard (1997), The Valuation of Deferred Taxes, Contemporary Accounting Research, 14, pp. 597-622. [2] Amir, E., Kirschenheiter M. and K. Willard (2001), The Aggregation and Valuation of Deferred Taxes, Review of Accounting Studies, 6, pp. 275-297. [3] Bilicka K.A. and M.P. Devereux (2012), CBT Corporate tax ranking 2012, Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation, Saïd Business School. [4] Blouin J., C. Gleason, L. Mills and S. Sikes (2007), What Can We Learn about Uncertain Tax Bene…ts from FIN 48?, National Tax Journal, 60, pp. 521-535. [5] Burnham P., and L. Ozanne (2006). Distortions from Partial Tax Reform Revealed through E¤ective Tax Rates, National Tax Journal, 59, pp. 611.630. [6] Cappuccio N. and M. Moretto (2001), Comments on the Investment-Uncertainty Relationship in a Real Option Model, Note di Lavoro Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, 28.01. [7] Chludek A. K. (2011), Perceived versus Actual Cash Flow Implications of Deferred Taxes - An Analysis of Value Relevance and Reversal under IFRS, Journal of International Accounting Research, 10, pp. 1–25. [8] Collins J.H. and D.A. Shackelford (1992), Foreign Tax Credit Limitations and Preferred Stock Issuances, Journal of Accounting Research, 30, pp. 103-124. [9] De Simone L., R.C. Sansing and J.K. Seidman (2013), When Are Enhanced Relationship Tax Compliance Programs Mutually Bene…cial?, The Accounting Review, 88, pp. 1971–1991. 18 [10] Diller M., P. Kortebusch, G. Schneider and C. Sureth-Sloane (2017), Boon or Bane? Advance Tax Rulings as a Measure to Mitigate Tax Uncertainty and Foster Investment, European Accounting Review, 26, pp. 441-468. [11] Dixit A. and R.S. Pindyck (1994), Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton: Princeton University Press. [12] Edgerton J. (2012), Investment, Accounting, and the Salience of the Corporate Income Tax, Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation, WP 12/30. [13] Gleason C. and L. Mills (2002), Materiality and Contingent Tax Liability Reporting, The Accounting Review, 77, pp. 317–342. [14] Goldstein R., N. Ju and H. Leland (2001), An EBIT-Based Model of Dynamic Capital Structure, Journal of Business, 74, pp. 483-512. [15] Graham J.R. (2005), A Review of Taxes and Corporate Finance, Foundations and Trends in Finance, 1, pp. 1-124. [16] Graham J.R., J.S. Ready and D.A. Shackelford (2012), Research in Accounting for Income Taxes, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53, pp. 412-434. [17] Guenther D.A. and R.C. Sansing (2000), Valuation of the Firm in the Presence of Temporary Book-Tax Di¤erences: The Role of Deferred Tax Assets and Liabilities, Accounting Review, 75, pp.1-12. [18] Guenther D.A. and R.C. Sansing (2004), The Valuation Relevance of Reversing Deferred Tax Liabilities, Accounting Review, 79, pp. 437-451. [19] Hafkenscheid R. and C. Janssen (2009), IAS 12 Needs Methodical Approach, International Tax Review, March, pp. 41-43. [20] Hanlon M. and S. Heitzman, (2010), A Review of Tax Research, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50, pp. 127–178. [21] Harrison J.M. (1985), Brownian Motion and Stochastic Flow Systems, New York: Wiley. [22] Huseynov F. and B.K. Klamm (2012), Tax Avoidance, Tax Management and Corporate Social Responsibility, Journal of Corporate Finance, 18, pp. 804-827. 19 [23] Kanniainen V. and J. Södersten (1994), Cost of Monitoring and Corporate Taxation, Journal of Public Economics, 55, pp. 307-321. [24] Kanniainen V. and J. Södersten (1995), The Importance of Reporting Conventions for the Theory of Corporate Taxation, Journal of Public Economics, 57, pp. 417-430. [25] Klassen K.J., P. Lisowsky and D. Mescall (2016), The Role of Auditors, NonAuditors, and Internal Tax Departments in Corporate Tax Aggressiveness, Accounting Review, 91, pp. 179-205. [26] Laux R.C. (2013), The Association between Deferred Tax Assets and Liabilities and Future Tax Payments, The Accounting Review, 88, pp. 1357-1383. [27] Leland H.E. (1994), Corporate Debt Value, Bond Covenants, and Optimal Capital Structure, Journal of Finance, 49, pp. 1213-1252. [28] McDonald R. and D. Siegel (1985), Investment and the Valuation of Firms When There is an Option to Shut Down, International Economic Review, 26, pp. 331-349. [29] Mills L.F. (2006), Five Things Economists and Lawyers Can Learn from Accountants: An Illustration Using the Domestic Production Activities Deduction, National Tax Journal, 54, pp. 585-597. [30] Mills L., Robinson, L. A., and R. Sansing (2010), FIN 48 and Tax Compliance, The Accounting Review, 85, pp. 1721–1742. [31] Panteghini P.M. (2006), S-Based Taxation under Default Risk, Journal of Public Economics, 90, pp. 1923-1937. [32] Panteghini P.M. (2007), Corporate Taxation in a Dynamic World, Springer. [33] Panteghini P.M. (2012), Accelerated Depreciation, Default Risk and Investment Decisions, Journal of Public Economic Theory, 14, pp. 161-186. [34] Panteghini P.M. and S. Vergalli (2016), Accelerated Depreciation, Default Risk and Investment Decisions, Journal of Economics, 119, pp. 113-130. [35] Polito V. (2009). Measuring the E¤ective Tax Burden in the Real World, Fiscal Studies, 30, 2, 247-278. [36] Polito V. (2012). Up or Down? Capital Income Taxation in the United States and the United Kingdom, FinanzArchiv, 68, pp. 48-82. 20 [37] Poterba J.M., N.S. Rao and J.K. Seidman (2011), Deferred Tax Positions and Incentives for Corporate Behavior around Corporate Tax Changes, National Tax Journal, 64, pp. 27-57. [38] Sansing R.C. (1998), Valuing the Deferred Tax Liability, Journal of Accounting Research, 36, pp.357-363. [39] Sarkar S. (2000), On the Investment-Uncertainty Relationship on a Real Option Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 24, pp. 219-225. 21