Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
DOI 10.1007/s10657-006-5671-4
Institutions and contracts: Franchising
Etienne Pfister · Bruno Deffains ·
Myriam Doriat-Duban · Stéphane Saussier
C
Springer Science + Business Media, Inc. 2006
Abstract This paper investigates a new dataset of franchise networks in nine countries in
order to assess whether and to what extent do institutions influence the practice of franchising. Our regressions relate the structure of franchise networks (the rate of franchised units
as opposed to corporate units) to individual parameters supposed to reflect the extent of
moral hazards on the franchisor’s and franchisee’s sides and, more specifically, to various
institutional parameters of the franchisor’s country, namely, the legal tradition, the level of
procedural formalism, the constraints imposed by labour regulation and the effectiveness of
trademark protection. While agency theory parameters seem to perform rather badly in this
international setting, institutions such as trademark protection and labour regulation have
more explanatory power: greater trademark protection encourages franchising and the impact of labour regulation is mostly positive, depending on the type of labour regulation that
is being considered. The effect of legal tradition and formalism seems negligible once these
parameters are taken in.
Keywords Franchising . Institutions . Contracts . Legal systems
JEL Classification D23 . F23 . K12
1. Introduction
A franchise is a contract between two agents where one (the franchisor) sells the right to
use a trademark, a finished product and, quite often, some know-how and business methods
to another (the franchisee), in exchange for a combination of fees. This contractual form is
E. Pfister
CREDES-University of Nancy 2 and TEAM-University of Paris I
B. Deffains ()· M. Doriat-Duban
CREDES-University of Nancy 2
e-mail:
[email protected]
S. Saussier
ADIS-University of Paris XI and ATOM-University of Paris I
Springer
54
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
distinct from a vertical integration or from an employment contract because the franchisee(s)
is the only residual claimant and has a large independence from the franchisor (in terms
of price fixing, for instance). Yet, franchising goes beyond straightforward sales contracts,
because of their long term focus, of the know–how transfers that are implied and because of
the many provisions (territorial exclusivity, tied sales, quality controls, etc.) that a franchise
relationship can entail. Thus, the franchise contract is a hybrid organization form in the sense
of Williamson (1991) and several theoretical and empirical papers have sought to analyse
the tradeoff between franchising and company ownership, mostly on a within–country basis
(Brickley and Dark, 1987; Lafontaine, 1992; Brickley, 1999; Lafontaine and Slade, 2001;
Pénard et al., 2004).1 By using a dataset of 546 networks distributed over nine countries, we
can expand this literature into an international setting, trying to evaluate why some countries
exhibit a higher rate of franchising.
In explaining these international differences in franchising, our focus will be on the institutional framework, an issue that has been largely overlooked so far. Indeed, the economic
analysis of franchising has mainly focused on incentives and monitoring issues (Lafontaine
and Slade, 2001; Pénard et al., 2004). While the results that have been provided so far form
an interesting and rather coherent set of results, there are still some puzzles to be solved. For
instance, the few empirical works that have tried to explain the franchise mix were far from
conclusive as only a small part of the observed variance in the franchise rate was explained
by the regressions (Lafontaine, 1992; Lafontaine and Shaw, 2004; Scott 1995; Pénard et al.,
2004). Many empirical studies also mention the coexistence of franchised and companyowned units within chains, a phenomenon labelled as “dual distribution” (or “plural form”
or “contract mix”), a strategy which is not directly rationalized by agency-based models.2
Another puzzle is that the franchise rate differs so much between countries. For instance,
our dataset indicates that the franchise rate is higher in Germany, where 78% of the downstream units are franchised out than in the United States (whose franchise rate is of 60%).
Few empirical papers have addressed these stylized facts, even though some hints have been
given here and there. For instance, it is generally assumed that foreign networks should
include more franchised units because controlling remote corporate units would prove too
difficult. Note however that the issue here is that of distance, not of distinct international
settings, and the same logic applies to the distribution of franchise units within the same
national territory. A more convincing approach has been heralded by Brickley et al. (1991),
who observe that the rate of franchising in the American States is highly variable and is lower
in States with a legislation precluding the termination of franchise contracts. More generally,
1 Some papers have also looked at the determinants of contractual provisions, especially royalty rates (Mathewson and Winter, 1985; Lafontaine 1992; Lafontaine and Shaw 1999; Scott 1995; Brickley, 2002).
2 Most of the agency-framework literature refers to dual distribution as a transitory strategy. For instance,
firms can operate some units directly either to signal their quality to potential franchisees (Gallini and Lutz,
1992; Lafontaine, 1993) or to credibly commit to protecting the value of their brand name (Scott, 1995).
Therefore, the extent of company ownership should decrease as the network ages because signals and credible
commitments are less and less needed. Other explanations focus on the capital, information or managerial talent
constraints faced by the franchisor, which lead him to franchise out some of his units. Once, these constraints
are overcome, the rate of franchising should diminish (Oxenfeldt and Kelly, 1969; Caves and Murphy, 1976;
Norton, 1988; Minkler, 1990). Yet, the empirical studies contradict both of these approaches for the franchise
rate turns out to be rather stable over time (Lafontaine and Shaw, 1999, on US and Canadians chains, Pénard
et al., 2003 on French networks). More recent explanations present dual franchising as an efficient and
persistent organizational form and emphasize the complementarities between corporate and franchised units,
including innovation incentives (Bradach, 1997; Lewin-Solomon, 1999), organizational learning (Sorenson
and Sorensen, 2001), better management control (Lafontaine and Shaw, 2004), or brand name development
(Bai and Tao, 2000)
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
55
the role of institutions in coordinating the economic activity has received an increased attention ever since Coase (1960)’s seminal contribution. A large sample of papers has recently
documented how differences in institutional frameworks help explain diverging patterns of
economic activity. Unemployment and growth, for instance, seem to be significantly related
to labour regulation and protection of property rights, respectively (Knack and Keefer, 1995;
Henisz, 2001; Botero et al., 2002; Falvey et al., 2004). Foreign direct investment, trade,
licensing and joint venture practices, among others, have all been linked to national institutions governing, notably, corruption, political and economic freedom, and the protection of
intellectual property rights (Smith, 1999, 2001; Yang and Maskus, 1999; Oxley, 1999; Wei,
2000; Disdier and Mayer, 2003). In these and other papers, differences in national institutions
affect the respective profits associated with each organizational structure, which lead each
firm to adapt its organizational strategy to the set of institutions it is confronted to.
This paper prolonges this analytic framework by applying it to the case of the trade–off
between franchising and corporate units. Our focus will be on general institutions, such
as legal traditions, procedural formalism, labour regulations and trademark laws and enforcement, rather than on laws specific to the franchising practice. First, such laws remain
largely underdeveloped in most developed countries and may vary from State to State in
federations. Second, using “broad” institutional parameters should have greater implications
for the general understanding of contracting behavior: beyond franchising, our results can
have resonances for other types of contracting practices such as outsourcing or licensing.
Third, these broad institutional parameters have been shown to influence several (mostly)
macroeconomic factors such as growth, unemployment, or the development of the financial
markets. Looking at their influence on more microeconomic behavior such as franchising is
rarer and it might be of interest to explain how and why do these institutions impact on the
macroeconomic aspects of the economy.
In Section 2, we briefly present the institutional framework that will be taken into account
in our regressions of the franchise rate. Section 3 describes the sample and our dependent and
independent variables. Section 4 proceeds to the empirical analysis and Section 5 concludes.
2. Institutional framework and franchising practices
At the core of franchising practice lies a contract which is supposed to impose obligations
on the franchisor and his franchisee(s). By this contract, the franchisee usually agrees to a
payment scheme and to several provisions, including exclusive dealings, quality standards,
conditions of contract termination and so on. Likewise, the franchise contract stipulates the
duties of the franchisor, including know–how transfers, management assistance, territorial
exclusivity, advertisement expenditures and so on. Inevitably, both parties may try to cheat on
their partners, for instance by playing down the turnover made thanks to the franchised trademark, by refusing to disclose some strategic know–how and, more generally, by exploiting
the unavoidable incompleteness of the contract. These incentives to cheat will be determined,
in part, by the effectiveness of contract enforcement, which, in turn, derives from the efficiency of the judiciary (Anderlini et al., 2001). Therefore, the institutional framework serves
to reduce the uncertainty associated to individual transactions characterized by some degree
of incompleteness (North, 1990). The laws are meant to provide the parties with rules and
safeguards that cannot be circumvented.
In such a context, behavior of the economic agents should be significantly influenced
by the laws themselves (Posner, 1998) as well as by the effectiveness of their enforcement
(Shavell, 2004) and their complexity (Kaplow, 2000). In particular, some aspects of the
Springer
56
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
organizational choices of firms, such as franchising, can be explained by characteristics of
the institutional framework (Hadfield, 1990). More precisely, this paper relates franchising
to three distinct institutions :the legal tradition and procedural formalism of the judiciary, the
extent of labor regulation and the effectiveness of intellectual property rights (IPR). In this
section, we briefly review how each of these could affect the incentives to franchise.
2.1. Franchising, legal traditions and the procedural formalism of law
In ensuring that fundamental rules as well as contract specific provisions are respected by
the parties, an effective judiciary can exert an important influence on how parties trade-off
different institutional designs such as franchising versus corporate units. Djankov et al. (2003)
have outlined important differences among countries in the quality of their courts, which
may help explain variance in the franchise rate across countries. Part of these differences
can be explained by differences in revenues, education, or deficient incentives structures
for the participants to dispute resolution (judges, lawyers and the litigants themselves), but
much attention has focused on the legal tradition of countries and, more specifically, on the
procedural formalism of law.
Though their distinctions often look overestimated, Common Law countries are usually
separated from Civil Law ones. The Common Law tradition is characterized most clearly
by the importance of decision making by juries, independent judges and the emphasis on
judicial discretion rather than on written codes. Oppositely, Civil Law is characterized by
less independent judiciaries, the relative unimportance of juries and a greater reliance on
procedural codes. Within this latter group, a distinction is often made between the French
civil law—which was transplanted to much of Western Europe (Belgium, Holland, Italy
and Spain for instance), Northern and Central Africa and Latin America, some parts of
Asia—and the German tradition, which became accepted in much of Western Germanic
Europe, including Austria and Switzerland, as well as in Japan, Korea and Taiwan.3 As
demonstrated through several empirical studies, countries of different legal traditions use
different institutional mechanisms to control the economic activity. For instance, civil law
countries exert a stronger control of the labour market (Botero et al., 2002), provide less legal
protection to shareholders (La Porta et al., 1997, 1998), have a tighter control of entry in
economic activities (Djankov et al., 2002) and resort to more formalized procedures of dispute
resolution (Djankov et al., 2003). In turn, we might expect these institutional differences to
alter the organizational behavior of firms and their network structure in particular.
The notion of procedural formalism is central to this pattern. Ideally, any dispute could
be resolved by a third party relying on fairness grounds only. Lawyers, written submissions,
procedural constraints on evidence, appeals, arguments, or even the law itself would be
barely needed here and dispute resolution would be fast and costless. Yet, in reality, all
juridictions sidestep from this model by heavily regulating their activity: mandatory (and
often professional) judges and lawyers, codified collection and presentation of evidence,
regimented dispute course, legally justified claims and decisions, and so on, testify of the
degree of formalism present in the modern exercise of law, which may still differ from
one country to another and, in particular, from one legal tradition to another. For instance,
3 The German tradition differs from the French one in that it makes a lesser use of codification. This is due
to the more pragmatic conception of justice of the historical German tradition, represented by Von Savigny. It
also derives from the late unification of Germany, which allowed a variety of influence on the judiciary, from
the French Civil Law to Common Law.
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
57
Djankov et al. (2003) find confirmation that Civil Law countries regulate dispute resolution
more heavily than Common Law countries.
Whether and how formalism affects the organizational structure of firms is much less
known, however. According to Djankov et al. (2003), higher procedural formalism results
in longer dispute resolution, lower enforceability of contracts, and lower consistency of the
system. Clearly, greater formalism at the country level should entail a lower propensity to contract out some operations because the regulation of in–house operations can be done through
authority, thus by-passing costly and long disputes. Simultaneously, however, greater formalism is also meant to reduce the risk of subversion of the judiciary by the powerful (through
corruption for instance). Greater formalism can also impede the economic actions that one
party may take against another to tilt their respective bargaining positions. In that view, formalism provides a guarantee of equity to potential franchisees, which could encourage greater
franchising. Because such concerns have been left unattended by the empirical literature so
far, the regressions in Section 4 will try to propose some preliminary results on this topic.
2.2. Franchising and labour regulations
Labour regulation has mainly been established to protect the interests of workers and to
guarantee a minimum standard of living to the population. It takes on three distinct forms:
employment law, industrial and collective relations laws, and social security law. An extensive literature has considered how labor regulation (including minimum wages, flexibility,
working hours) affects the level of unemployment or of productivity gains (Nickell and Layard, 1999; Kugler, Jimeno, and Hernanz, 2003) but fewer papers have examined how it
modifies the organizational structure of firms and the franchising practice in particular.
Intuitively, greater labour regulation (in terms, for instance, of workers’ health and safety,
minimum wages, work hours, rights to unionize, layoff policies, and so on) should reduce the
short-term profit of companies, which should lead them to try escape the burden of regulation,
for instance by decreasing their labor to capital ratio. Other strategies can be used to escape
the constraints of regulation. For instance, firms may avoid locating in states or countries
where labour as well as other types of regulation (environmental for instance) are more
constraining (see Holmes, 1998, or List and Co, 2000, among others). Botero et al. (2003)
also find that greater labour regulation is associated to a larger unofficial economy. The paper
will seek to expand these results on the link between labour regulation and economic activity
by considering how labour regulation might affect the organizational structure of firms and,
in particular, whether it influences the practice of franchising.
The costs of regulation (per employee for instance or per unit of output) are said to
be disproportionately smaller for larger firms, thanks to greater financial strength and to
scale, scope and experience economies (Crain and Hopkins, 2001). For instance, internal
financing can help larger firms to invest in capital or in organizational changes to comply
with the regulation in a more effective fashion. Provided such investment is largely a fixed
cost, it should get more profitable as the size of the firm (number of employees or total
output) increases. Smaller firms may also be exposed to greater competitive pressures so that
any increase in costs could prove detrimental relative to the foreign competition. Finally,
larger firms are more likely to use regulation as a stimulus to modernisation. Some recent
evidence of these considerations has been provided in the case of intellectual property rights
regulation :smaller firms often complain about the high costs of patents (in terms of deposits
and enforcement) and are also more frequently constrained by the patents of other, often
larger, competitors (Cohen, Nelson, and Walsh, 2000; Lerner, 1995). Indeed, their smaller
size prevents them from investing in R&D to circumvent rival patents while their low size
Springer
58
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
and lack of experience prevents them from benefiting from scale and experience economies
in the patent deposit and enforcement process. Other evidence has been provided in the case
of greater product safety (Viscusi and Moore, 1993). Following such views, we might expect
franchisors to be less prone to franchising in countries where the labour regulations are tight,
provided that they are of a greater size than their franchisees. Basically, maintaining the sales
departments in–house results in productive and administrative efficiencies that would make
franchising particularly costly.
This argument can be criticized on at least two grounds. First, although the proportion of
corporately owned units suggest that franchisors are of a greater size than their franchisees,
this is not systematically the case. Second, the relationship between firm size and the costs
of regulation seems to depend on the type of regulation that is considered. The few studies
that have considered the case of labour regulation indicate that the costs of labour regulation
increases with firm size or, at least, are rather low for small firms (Edwards, Ram, and Black,
2003). For instance, small firms are often explicitly exempted from certain types of labour
regulation, such as those related to collective matters (unionization or strikes for instance).
Some issues administratively dealt with through labour regulation in large firms can also be
more adequately be handled face-to-face in small businesses, as are maternity leaves or working hours. Thus, larger firms (and franchisors in particular) may seek to delegate the burden
of labour regulation to their smaller franchisees who can be either exempted altogether, or in a
position to deal with these issues in a more effective manner than a large corporation would do.
Overall, therefore, the impact of labor regulation on franchising remains largely ambiguous.
2.3. Franchising and intellectual property rights (IPRs) protection
How intellectual property rights influence corporate strategies has mostly been studied in
the case of patent protection. Several cross–industry or time–series samples have been used
to investigate how differences in patent protection affects R&D investment (Sakkikabara
and Branstetter, 2001; Arora, Ceccagnoli, and Cohen, 2003). On an international setting,
concerns have focused on how national differences in patent protection, measured through
surveys or through a qualitative index (Ginarte and Park, 1999; Ostergard, 2000), may explain international trade flows (Maskus et Penubarti, 1995; Smith, 1999) or foreign direct
investment and location choices (Lee and Mansfield, 1996; Smarzynska, 2004).
In this framework, one intuition that may be linked to the setting of this paper is that greater
patent protection should facilitate licensing practices and enable the patentee to capture a
greater share of cooperative surplus. For instance, Ferrantino (1993) as well as Yang et Maskus
(2001) find that the license fees perceived by American firms in different foreign countries are
positively correlated with the level of patent protection offered in the partner country. Oxley
(1998) also notices that alliances formed with foreign firms located in a country where patent
protection is low often involve some form of quasi-integration (such as greater shareholding
participation) :hence, stronger property rights can facilitate pure market–based mechanisms.
Note though that the effect of patent protection is not systematically significant: for instance,
Bessy, Brousseau, and Saussier, (2001) do not observe any relationship between the structure
of licensing contracts and the level of patent protection. Another concern hinges on whether
greater patent protection also increases the number of licensing contract, beyond increasing
the total license fees earned by a patent owner.4
4 Indeed, greater patent protection could enable a licensor to earn greater licensing revenues with a lower
number of license contracts.
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
59
To what extent does this intuition apply to the case of franchising practices ? First, greater
trademark protection should indeed translate into a higher franchise rate. As the protection
increases, competition from infringers decreases and the franchisee should be willing to pay
higher sums to use this trademark. Better trademark enforcement also reduces the risk of
opportunism: for instance, absent effective trademark protection, a franchisee can imitate
inappropriable know-how and use it to produce a counterfeit product. On the other hand
however, low protection and greater risk of infringement may also be conducive to franchising :indeed, a franchisor would rather franchise his trademark and be paid low franchise fees
than be merely imitated with no compensation in return. By legally entering the network, the
franchisee is spared the hassle of lengthy legal procedures and may gain access to specific
know-how. This paper should provide some empirical guidance as to how these different
trade-offs are resolved.
3. Data and variables
Section 1 briefly presents our dataset. Section 2 lists our independent variables related to
moral hazards and other individual-level parameters. Section 3 considers the institutional
variables that will be included in our regressions.
3.1. The dataset
Our empirical analysis is based on a database constructed from the Forby’s Guide survey
made in 2003. Initially, 946 franchise chains operating in 17, mostly developed, countries
are covered but the number of firms used in our regressions will however be more limited.
First, not all of these firms provided useable information on the (national) franchise rate of
their network. Second, non-responses to some of the questions used as independent variables
further reduce the size of the sample. For instance, for a large number of firms from the initial
sample, we were unable to compute the total (including foreign units) number of units in their
franchise chain. Neither have we found a reliable index rating the efficacy of trademark law
and of the enforcement of intellectual property rights in the United States, so that regressions
that include these parameters will be run on a more restricted sample. Third, in several cases,
the number of observations per country was much too small to credibly capture any country
effect, so that we chose to drop these observations altogether. All in all, the final sample
consists in 546 franchise chains.
Our dependent variable will consist in the rate of franchising within the national network,
as data on the franchise rate in other countries than that of the franchisor were too poor to
be exploited. Hence, the franchisee’s country is always the same as that as of the franchisor.
Table 1 presents the number of observations by country of origin5 and the mean franchise rate
in that country. The average rate of franchising is of 72% but displays important international
differences:the highest rates of franchising can be found in Switzerland, Germany and Great
Britain, while Canada, Belgium and the United States display the lowest rates of franchising.
The franchise rate found for France is grossly equivalent to that found by the French Chambers
of Commerce, i.e., 66%. On the other hand, our franchise rate for the United States is less
than that found in other empirical studies such as Lafontaine (1992) or Lafontaine and Shaw
5
Indeed, the franchise rate could be calculated only for the nation state, but not for the foreign countries in
which the franchise chain was also operating :though it made a distinction between the national units and
the foreign ones, the Forby’s Guide survey did not compute the number of franchised and in-house units by
foreign country.
Springer
60
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
Table 1 Summary statistics
Source: Forby’s Guide Survey.
Country
Franchise rate (N )
Germany
0.78 (284)
Austria
0.65 (34)
Belgium
0.56 (9)
Canada
0.44 (9)
Spain
0.63 (6)
United States
0.60 (82)
France
0.65 (72)
Great-Britain
0.77 (41)
Switzerland
0.78 (9)
Total
0.72 (546)
(2004), who observe a franchise rate of 78%. One explanation relates to the composition
of the sample :depending on firm and industry characteristics, the propensity to franchise a
unit can be highly variable. In the regressions, these elements will be controlled for by the
inclusion of individual parameters, mostly related to moral hazard concerns, and industry
dummies. Country–level parameters will consist in variables related to the legal frameworks.
3.2. Measuring moral hazard
The intuitions brought forward by the theory of contracts are relatively straightforward to
interpret in empirical terms and much work has been made in that direction already (Pénard
et al., 2004). Basically, the structure of the franchise chain is supposed to be related first
to agency problems between the franchisor (the principal) and the behavior (level of effort)
of his agents (the franchisees and/or his corporate units), then to the fulfilment of some
commitments (training, assistance, quality control) by the franchisor.
3.2.1. Controlling the behavior of the corporate units and of the franchisees
When the downstream partner provides important inputs in the sales process, the upstream
producer might prefer to delegate these operations to independent franchisees if he cannot
adequately control sales units within the corporation. That way, downstream sellers should
be provided with the adequate incentives to exert maximum efforts, especially if the contract
involves only a fixed, upfront, franchisee fee. Conversely, however, there are some settings
where even independent franchisees can be led to adopt an opportunistic behavior towards the
franchisor. For instance, in a context of non–repeat purchases, they may choose to sell low–
quality products, thereby free–riding and in fact ruining the franchisor’s trademark. Therefore,
very valuable trademarks may not be franchised out and corporate units might be preferred in
contexts of non–repeat purchases. Bercovitz (1999), Brickley et al. (1991), Minkler (1990),
Brickley and Dark (1987) and Norton (1988) have confirmed that the franchise rate increases
with various proxys of geographical distance between the corporate center and the sales units
(distance is used here to indicate higher costs of controlling corporate units). Minkler and Park
(1994) also find that the proportion of franchised units is inversely proportional to the value
of the trademarks owned by the franchisor (measured through the ratio of stock market and
book values of the firm). Finally, Brickley and Dark (1987) also note that the franchise rate
is lower in industries characterized by non–repeat purchases, but later works have presented
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
61
more ambiguous results (Brickley et al., 1991; Lafontaine, 1995). More problematically,
concerns related to the franchisee’s moral hazards are unlikely to affect the franchise rate
if they can be dealt with through provisions in the franchise contract, such as territorial
exclusivity, exclusive dealings and so on, whose effectiveness are partly determined by the
institutional framework.
To assess the extent of opportunistic behavior by downstream units, we will use data on
the competences required from the franchisees. Basically, as these competences increase, the
franchisee is expected to provide more valuable inputs and the upstream unit might prefer a
franchise contract to obtain the right level of efforts from him. A behavior involving several
competences could also be difficult to contract on or to control, so that delegation to an
independent unit should provide better incentives. Three distinct variables will be used:
r A dummy variable indicating whether any specific qualifications are required from the
franchisee. If no qualification is required, it is highly probable that the input provided by
the franchisee is of low relevance to the performance of the franchised units :internal control
should be easier, low–powered incentives could be sufficient and franchising should be less
frequent;
r Whether the franchisee is required to have some salesman experience. If so, we may expect
his efforts to significantly influence the performance of the outlet;
r Qualifications. This variable is defined as the arithmetic sum of eleven dummy variables
indicating the extent of the qualification or experience requirements demanded by the
franchisor to the potential franchisee. Higher values for this indicator plausibly signal
greater reliance on the franchisee’s efforts, higher control costs, high obstacles to in-house
contracting and a need for high-powered incentives. Franchising should then be more likely.
Note that there are other explanations that are compatible with a positive relationship
between the franchise rate and the competences required from the franchisees. For instance,
it could be argued that highly qualified personnel are more difficult to find within the
corporation (Scott, 1995; Sorenson and Sorenson, 2001). A negative relationship could also
be found if the requirements act as a selection or as a rationing device (Lafontaine, 1992).
From a resource–based view, it could also be inferred that personnel as well as productive
tasks involving several competences should be kept in–house :greater control within the firm
should prevent these competences/personnal from spilling over the rest of the industry. Even
from a transaction cost approach, arguments could be found to justify a negative relationship
between the level of competences required from the franchisee and the franchising rate.
Indeed, as the number of competences involved in the franchisee’s task increases, writing
a franchise contract over them gets more and more costly, and an internal contract might be
preferred. The case for this negative relationship is even stronger if the competences are regarded as specific: the franchisee is unlikely to develop them unless he has some commitment
(or “hostages”) from the franchisor in the form of a standard, long–term, labour contract for
instance.
3.2.2. Controlling the behavior of the upstream unit
The upstream producer is also expected to perform some tasks that may not be adequately
contracted such as controlling the behavior of the downstream sellers or transmitting intangible know-how. As the extent of these tasks increases, pure market-based relationships may
lead to opportunistic behavior. For instance, the franchisor may refuse to transmit some useful
know–how or may practice insufficient control of franchised units. Alternatively, the franchisee might use the know-how that is being transferred as a bargaining chip to renegotiate
Springer
62
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
the contract. In such settings, corporate units should be more frequent because franchising
yields important transaction costs. Along these lines, the following variables were extracted
from the Forby’s Guide survey :
r The extent of training provided by the franchisor. The Forby’s Guide survey lists ten
areas (including seminars, quality assessment, sales technics, etc.) where training may be
provided by the franchisor. Our variable is the arithmetic sum of the resulting ten dummy
variables, and a greater value should be associated to a lower franchising rate.
r The extent of management assistance provided by the franchisor. The Forby’s Guide survey
lists eighteen areas where some management assistance (including organisation, benchmarking, human resources management, etc.) could be provided by the franchisor. Our
variable is the arithmetic sum of the resulting eighteen dummy variables, and a greater
value should be associated to a lower franchising rate.
r The number of units using the trademark. Indeed, trademark value should increase as the
number of people using it expands; we may also expect that as the network grows, the task
of the franchisor in outing the less performing units is increasingly difficult and yet crucial
as more customers will be served. The franchising rate is thus expected to decrease as the
number of units within the network increases.
r The number of years the franchisor was active in the industry without resorting to franchising (divided by the total number of years in business). This variable is supposed to
reflect the difficulty and cost of developing the franchise package. Clearly, as the costs and
obstacles to franchising increase, the franchise rate should decrease. On the other hand, if
building a franchise network has proved difficult, the commitment by the franchisor not to
cheat on his franchisees is likely to be more credible.
Again however, it should be stressed that specific contract provisions as well as an adequate
structuring of licensing fees could alleviate much of these moral hazards problems provided
that contract enforcement is effective enough. For instance, higher variable fees should provide the franchisor with the incentives to control his network and to transmit the required
know-how. Provisions restricting contract termination by the franchisee or preventing him
from being employed or franchised by competitors should also constrain his behavior.
3.2.3. Other variables
We introduce a few additional variables that are not directly related to the agency framework
but that still have been used by several empirical papers in a complementary fashion:
r Age of the network. When a trademark has been successfully franchised for several years,
the franchisor no longer needs to signal the value of his network to potential new franchisees,
which should make franchising easier. On the other hand, an older network may no longer
need some outside capital to expand, so that the proportion of franchised units should be
lower. Finally, older trademarks may have more value and transferring them to a franchisee
could prove very risky.
r Financial support. The extent of financial support may signal relatively low capital constraints on the franchisor’s side. According to Caves and Murphy (1976), the resort to
franchising should be less frequent then since the franchisor is able to invest in–house to
expand the firm. Several empirical facts run counter to this argument, however :for instance, the franchise rate does not seem to decrease with the age of the network (Pénard
et al., 2003; Lafontaine and Shaw, 1999; Bercovitz, 2000) and franchisors often provide
some financial support to their franchisees. Financial support will be measured by the
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
63
Table 2 Summary statistics
Variable
N
Mean
Std. dev.
Min.
Max.
No specific competence
546
0.23
0.42
0
1
Salesman required
546
0.71
0.49
0
1
Qualifications
546
5.30
2.25
0
11
Management assistance
546
11.02
3.52
0
18
Training
546
7.41
2.37
0
10
Total number of units
546
358.99
2208.23
1
29500
Proportion of years
out of franchising
546
0.29
0.29
0
1
Financial support
554
5.52
3.11
0
12
Tied sales
546
0.44
0.49
0
1
Age of the network
546
12.88
10.68
0
90
Source: Forby’s Guide Survey.
arithmetic sum of twelve dummy variables indicating whether the franchisor has provided
any specific financial support (ranging from credit counselling to outward credit) to his
franchisees.6
r Tied sales. In some franchise networks, the franchisees cannot substitute away from the
franchisor’s product. In this case, selling inputs to franchisees can be another form of
royalty on output. While the extent of tied sales can vary between networks, the dataset
proposes only a dummy variable to account for these contractual arrangements. This dummy
variable may have a negative impact on the proportion of franchised units for tied sales
make franchising more similar to company ownership, thus diminishing the advantages of
franchising over company ownership.
r Industry dummies. Our regressions include a set of 24 industry dummies designed to capture
sector specific effects (such as the frequency of transaction or the level of risk borne out
by the franchisee), but at this level of aggregation, these variables merely serve as control
parameters and no particular proposition can be related to them.
Some summary statistics for these independent variables are presented in Table 2.
3.3. Measuring the institutional framework
The legal framework is apprehended through four types of indicators.
3.3.1. Legal traditions
We will make the usual distinction between Common Law (United States, United Kingdom,
Canada) and Civil Law systems (France, Belgium, Spain, Germany, Austria, Switzerland).
6
The total number of units as well as the age of the network can also interpreted as a proxy for the financial
strength of the franchisor.
Springer
64
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
Another dummy variable is added to control for the influence of the German legal tradition
which characterizes Germany, Austria and Switzerland in our sample.7
3.3.2. Procedural formalism
In itself, the legal tradition exerts a very uncertain and unknown influence on franchising.
As the works of Djankov et al. (2003), Botero et al. (2002) and others have shown, the legal
traditions condition the type of institutions the country will be endowed with, which, in turn,
will encourage or discourage franchising. The procedural formalism of law, which is said
to be higher in Civil Law countries, can promote the internalization of the sales operation.
To measure formalism, we use the data collected by Djankov et al. (2003). These data are
initially defined on the formalism associated with two specific disputes, i.e., eviction and
check collection, but the authors suggest these conflicts are typical of how default on private
contracts are solved by the courts in a given legal environment. Four indicators will then be
separately used in our regressions:8
r Professionalism. This index measures whether the resolution of the case relies on the work
of professional judges and attorneys, as opposed to other types of adjudicators and lay
people. The index takes into account the assignation of the case to a general juridiction
court, whether legal representation is mandatory and whether the judges could be considered
as professional. This variables goes from 0 to 1 as the professionalism of the judiciary
increases.
r Written procedures. This index measures the written or oral nature of the actions involved in
the procedure, from the filing of the complaint to the actual enforcement. It is calculated as
the number of stages carried out mostly in written form over the total number of applicable
stages, and runs from 0 to 1, where higher values mean higher prevalence of written
elements.
r Legal justification. The index measures the level of legal justification required in the judiciary process. Hence, it assesses whether the complaint should include references to the
applicable laws, legal reasoning or formalities that would normally require legal training,
whether the judgement should mention the legal justification of the decision (articles of
the law or case-law) and whether judgements should be based on law only (as opposed to
equity concerns).
r Formalism. This (broader) index is meant to capture the general level formalism in the
judiciary, reflected on by the extent of professionalism, written procedures, legal justifications, statutory regulation of evidence, control of superior review, engagement formalities
and independent procedural actions. The index ranges from 0 to 7, where higher values
denote a greater extent of formalism.
3.3.3. Labour regulation
The third aspect of the legal framework that we seek to integrate in our empirical investigation
is the stringency of labour laws. Again, how the regulation of employment conditions affects
7 There does not seem to be wide differences in the laws applied to franchising in common and civil law
countries. Yet, some tiny differences can sometimes be meaningful. In Germany, for instance, the franchisee
can break the contract and be reimbursed of his investments until one year after the conclusion of the contract,
unless the franchisor has explicitly specified otherwise. Lack of information on that particular consideration
has resulted in several legal conflicts.
8
See Djankov et al. (2003) for details.
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
65
the practice of franchising is very ambiguous. On the one hand, larger firms can be better
placed to cope with some aspects of labour regulation. But on the other hand, small firms are
sometimes explicitly exempted from some of the provisions in labour regulation. Thus, we
will use several indicators separately to account for this heterogeneity, all of which are taken
from Botero et al. (2002) :
r Obstacles to alternative employment contracts. This index measures whether the law allows alternatives to standard employment contracts, such as part-time contracts, fixed-term
contracts, and specific regimes for the employment of a family member. The index varies
from 0 to 1, with 1 indicating greater obstacles to alternative employment contracts.
r Regulation of employment conditions. This index measures the extent of regulation in the
conditions of employment, including work hours, leaves, mandatory minimum wages, and
the regulation of employment conditions through the constitution. The index varies from
0 to 1, with 1 indicating greater regulation.
r Grounds for dismissal. This index measures whether specific reasons are necessary for
an employer to dismiss an individual employee. Due consideration is paid to whether it
is unfair to terminate a contract without a cause, to whether the law establishes a “list of
fair grounds” for dismissal and to whether redundancy is considered a “fair” ground for
dismissal. The index varies from 0 to 1, with 1 indicating greater regulation.
r Dismissal procedures. This index measures the regulation that is applied upon dismissal
procedures, such as notification of third party before dismissal, mandatory retraining or
replacement before dismissals, the existence of priority rules applying to dismissals or
reemployment. The index varies from 0 to 1, with 1 indicating greater regulation.
r Regulation of contract termination. This index measures the ease of terminating an employment contract. It takes into account the preceding two variables as well as the mandatory
notices and severance payments, and the right to job security in the constitution.
r Regulation of employment. This index is an aggregation of the indicators on (i) obstacles to
alternative employment contracts, (ii) regulation of employment conditions, (iii) regulation
of contract termination. It varies between 0 and 3, with 3 indicating greater regulation.
r Regulation of collective relations. This index measures the regulation of collective industrial
relations, taking into account collective bargaining (labour union power, right to unionize in
the constitution, right to collective bargaining), worker participation in management (right
to appoint members of the board of directors, mandatory workers council) and collective
disputes (right to strike, restrictions to the right to strike, employer’s responses to strikes,
etc).
3.3.4. IPR framework
Finally, the fourth aspect of the legal framework that is likely to affect contracting decisions is
the efficacy of trademark laws. Two qualitative index are used here, both taken from Ostergard
(2000). The first one measures the strength of trademark law, relative to the standards set
by the US Chamber of Commerce. This variable ranges from 0 to 8, with 8 indicating
strong trademark protection. The second indicator relates to the enforcement score of IPR
protection, assessed through the Country Reports on Economic and Trade Practices of the
US State Department. This index ranges from 0 (low enforcement) to 4 (high enforcement).
Unfortunately, the most recent year for which IPR laws and enforcement are coded is 1994.
Assuming that the IPR legislation has barely changed since then and 2003 (the year the
Forby’s Guide survey was conducted) might appear like a crude simplification, but trademark
legislation had already undergone important changes in the six years to 1994, which should
Springer
66
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
reduce the extent of changes brought in since then (Ostergard, 2000).9 As suggested earlier,
the extent and direction of IPR legislation on franchise contracts remains very ambiguous
and the regressions conducted here should help us clarify this topic.
The Table 3 suggests that the pattern of influence of institutions over the franchise rate
is likely to be quite complex. For instance, let us consider Germany, which presents a high
franchise rate. This might be due to a high level of formalism, a highly regulated job market,
and a very effective system of IPR enforcement. Yet, United Kingdom, which also presents
a high franchise rate, has a low degree of formalism and scores low in most measures of
labour regulation. Moreover, there are several instances where the subcomponents of our
institutional index offer diverging patterns. For instance, Germany has a relatively high
level of procedural formalism, but its judiciary seems relatively unprofessionalized. It also
regulates tightly the resort to alternative employment contracts, yet scantly regulates the
conditions of employment. Finally, its enforcement of IPRs seems very efficient, but its
trademark legislation probably presents some voids since it does not get the maximal rating,
as Switzerland does for instance. Overall, however, our variables for labour regulation are
positively correlated one with the other, and the same pattern holds for the formalism–
related variables. As far as IPR law is concerned, however, it seems that a greater efficacy
of trademark law is met with less effective enforcement, which could be explained by the
fact that tighter laws are more difficult to enforce. Also note that the national frameworks
in this regard do not exhibit much variance :we are comparing nations with an effective IPR
framework with some countries that present a slightly more performing IPR system. For
instance, apart from Austria and Switzerland with a maximum trademark rate of 8, all other
countries have a trademark rate of 7. Likewise, most of our observations refer to national
systems of enforcement that are rated as rather effective :only Austria, Belgium and Spain
have a rating of 3, while all others display a maximum rating of 4. Such convergence in the IPR
frameworks is unsurprising :common economic conditions as well as several harmonization
treaties have led IPR law and its implementation towards a common standard. Thus, our
study will consider whether marginal changes in the IPR frameworks can significantly alter
the contracting behavior of resident firms.
4. Empirical results
A maximum likelihood Tobit estimator is used in the regressions to control for the significant
number of potential franchisors in our sample (as in all samples of franchising practices—see
Lafontaine (1992) for another instance) that franchise all or none of their outlets, resulting
in some sample censoring. In a first subsection, we consider the explanatory power of the
usual moral hazard/contract theory parameters.
4.1. Testing contract theory
The Table 4 presents the results that are obtained when the only parameters included in the
regression are contractual or network characteristics. These variables turn out to have a very
9 An important reform in Europe has been the introduction of a European trademark system. Instead of applying
for national, standard trademarks in each member country, firms now have the possibility to make a single
application at the European trademark office in Alicante. The trademark will be valid in the whole EU, but the
enforcement process and the related legislation remain national, so that differences across European countries
may still influence firms’ behavior.
Springer
Country
Franchise
rate
Civil
law
Common
law
German
system
Written
process
Formalism
Professionalized
juridiction
Legal
justification
Obstacles to
alternative contracts
Germany
0.78
1
0
1
0.87
3.76
0.33
1
0.72
Austria
0.65
1
0
1
0.85
3.62
0.66
1
0.22
Belgium
0.56
1
0
0
0.75
3.17
0.33
0.33
0.72
Canada
0.44
0
1
0
0.5
2.32
0.33
0
0.56
Spain
0.63
1
0
0
1
4.81
1
1
0.83
United States
0.60
0
1
0
0.75
2.96
0.33
0.33
0.56
France
0.65
1
0
0
0.75
3.6
0.33
1
0.74
Great–Britain
0.77
0
1
0
0.71
2.22
0.66
0.33
0.56
Switzerland
0.78
1
0
1
0.62
3.96
0.66
0.66
0.56
Country
Franchise
rate
Employment
conditions
Dismissal
regulation
Collective
dismissals
regulation
Termination
contracts
Employment
laws
Collective
Relations
Trademark
efficacy
IPR
enforcement
Germany
0.78
0.35
0.67
0.57
0.50
1.57
1.76
7
4
Austria
0.65
0.40
0
0.43
0.18
0.8
0.84
8
3
Belgium
0.56
0.82
0
0.14
0.22
1.77
1.03
7
3
Canada
0.44
0.49
0
0.29
0.17
1.22
0.32
7
4
Spain
0.63
0.85
0.67
0.71
0.50
2.18
2.12
7
3
United States
0.60
0.29
0
0.14
0.08
0.92
0.36
-
-
France
0.65
0.54
0.33
0.71
0.31
1.59
2.12
7
4
Great–Britain
0.77
0.26
0.33
0.14
0.20
1.02
0.25
7
4
Switzerland
0.78
0.46
0
0.14
0.26
1.28
0.77
8
4
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
Table 3 Summary statistics
67
Springer
Source: Forby’s Guide Survey
68
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
Table 4 Determinants of the
franchise rate—Baseline
regressions
Network rate of franchising
Model
(a)
0.51∗∗
(0.21)
−0.07
(0.05)
−0.09∗
(0.05)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
Total number of units
0.03∗
(0.02)
0.05∗∗
(0.02)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
Management assistance
0.03
(0.09)
0.03
(0.08)
0.01
(0.09)
Extent of training
−0.10
(0.07)
−0.06
(0.07)
−0.05
(0.07)
Network age
−0.06
(0.04)
−0.01
(0.04)
0.00
(0.04)
Years without franchises
−0.35∗∗∗
(0.09)
−0.35∗∗∗
(0.09)
−0.35∗∗∗
(0.09)
Financial support
0.10∗∗
(0.04)
0.06
(0.05)
0.06
(0.05)
Qualifications
0.07
(0.06)
0.04
(0.06)
0.03
(0.06)
−0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.02
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
Tied input sales (yes/no)
No specific requirement
Salesman required
D-Great Britain
0.07
(0.12)
D-United States
−0.12
(0.12)
D-France
0.02
(0.11)
D-Spain
−0.11
(0.23)
D-Belgium
−0.14
(0.19)
D-Switzerland
0.34∗
(0.20)
−0.38∗
(0.20)
D-Canada
0.20∗∗
(0.09)
D-Germany
Note: Standard errors in
parenthesis. ∗∗∗ ,∗∗ and ∗ denote
the 1%, 5% and 10% levels of
significance.
Springer
(c)
0.54∗∗
(0.21)
intcpt
0.76∗∗∗
(0.20)
(b)
Civil law
0.06
(0.08)
German tradition
0.20∗∗∗
(0.07)
N
546
546
546
LR Test
73.20∗∗∗
103.66∗∗∗
90.12∗∗∗
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
69
low explanatory power. For instance, variables that we think to be related to the importance of
franchisee’s efforts are not associated to significant coefficients. Likewise, some but not all of
the parameters supposed to reflect the importance of the franchisor’s effort are not significant
either, like the extent of training and management assistance. One plausible explanation is
that these moral hazards are dealt with through contract provisions and the level of variable
and fixed fees, as several empirical studies have shown (Lafontaine, 1992; Brickley, 2002;
Pénard et al., 2004). For instance, the provision of management assistance or of training can
be contracted and even be charged on to the franchisee. Preclusion of future competition
can also be contractually enforced. Another source of bias lies in the great ambiguity that
surrounds these variables, since any effect, positive or negative, can be rationalized, as we
explained in Section 3.2. For instance, greater requirements can serve as a rationing device
on top of signalling tasks that are difficult to control through a hierarchical structure.
Like several empirical tests, our model does not validate the financial constraints approach
developed by Caves and Murphy (1976). If anything, the financial support provided by the
franchisor to his franchised units seems to exert a positive influence on the rate of franchising.
Therefore, franchising is certainly not motivated by the lack of capital resources on the
franchisor’s side. This positive influence disappears, however, when country dummies or
the legal systems are introduced into the regression. It might be that financially supportive
franchisors are mostly present in countries prone to franchising for other reasons than financial
market imperfections or that the country dummy variables better capture these imperfections
than the (financial support) variable defined here.
Actually, there are only three firm parameters that seem particularly relevant to explain
the rate of franchising :the total number of units in the network, the proportion of years spent
out of franchising by the franchisor and the existence of tied sales in the franchise contract.
Let us consider them in turn:
r The total number of units of the network exerts a positive influence on the franchise rate.
This indicator has several meanings, however. A high number of units could indicate larger
geographic dispersion and higher control costs, thus leading to a higher franchising rate.
It may also signal more valuable trademarks, which should be more easily franchised
out because their value has been credibly established. Simultaneously, however, great
trademarks can increase the franchisees’ incentives to cheat and free-ride on the network’s
goodwill. According to our results, the first two effects tend to dominate over the last one.10
r The proportion of years spent out of franchising can also be loosely connected to concerns
with moral hazard :given that building a franchise network has proved difficult, it is unlikely
that the franchisor will ever let his trademark be ruined by loose franchisees or that he will
try to cheat on them. Thus, franchising appears as a more credible option and can be more
easily concluded. Simultaneously, however, delays in franchising point out to significant
difficulties in applying the business concept to franchising, which may not fade out once
franchising has begun. This more straightforward effect tends to dominate.
r Finally, tied sales exert a negative influence upon the rate of franchising. According to
Lafontaine (1992), the existence of tied sales makes the franchise unit closer to a corporate owned unit, so that it is probably less advantageous to franchise in such conditions.
Her variable was not significant, but it consisted in the sector level of inputs sales from
franchisors to franchisees, so that it may not have adequately captured this phenomenon.
10
Note however that a similar variable used by Lafontaine (1992) had a negative influence on the franchise
rate.
Springer
70
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
Thus, our model is globally insufficient to explain the differences in franchising across
firms and across countries. As model (b) demonstrates, there are significant country-specific
effects in our regressions. In particular, all other things equal, franchising appears to be more
frequent in Germany and Switzerland and less widespread in Canada, relative to Austria which
was chosen as a reference here. More generally, these coefficients are jointly significantly
different from 0 (F-test = 3.84) and significantly different one from another (F-test = 3.95).
In regression (c), we try to capture some of these country specific effects through the use
of two dummy variables reflecting the legal tradition of the network’s country. It turns out
that civil law countries do encourage franchising (relative to common law systems) but only
when they stem from a German tradition.11 Finally, only three of our sectoral dummies
have significant coefficients. Franchising seems less frequent in the hotel industry, but more
widespread in the printing and real estate sectors.
4.2. Introducing institutional parameters
To better address the issue of national specificities in the practice of franchising, we introduce
three categories of country-specific variables in the dataset. The first one is related to the extent
of formalism in the judiciary, as defined and measured by Djankov et al. (2003) (Table 5).
The other two are related to the costs and advantages of franchising in a given institutional
context. Namely, we explore how labour regulation and trademark law affect the rate of
franchising in national networks (Tables 6 and 7). In all these regressions, dummy variables
related to the legal tradition are used to control for other country specific effects (due to
the low number of countries in our dataset, country dummies could not be used because of
collinearity with the institutional variables).
The formalism of the judiciary does not influence franchising at all (Table 5).As described
in the variables section, four distinct indicators are used, none of which turns out to be
significant. Basically, the other results are barely altered. Similarly, none of the coefficients
for the industrial dummies is really affected. Finally, crossing these various indicators of
formalism with our sectoral dummies did not produce additional results. Rather, the three
industry dummies that were significantly different from 0 (hotel, estate agencies, and printing
firms) were no longer so when crossed with the various indicators of formalism used here.
This lack of result can have several explanations. First, the measures used by Djankov et
al. (2003) may be inappropriate in the case of franchising, and more specific indicators are
needed to confirm these results. Second, any adverse effect of greater formalism either on
the franchisor or on the franchisees may be circumvented by efficient negotiation, so that this
aspect of law does not influence the organizational choices of the parties.
The inclusion of labor regulations in the regressions turns out to be more successful
(Table 6). As expected, the results differ significantly depending on the type of labor regulation which is being looked at. Nonetheless, a positive influence of labor regulation upon
franchising is generally noted. Indeed, obstacles to alternative contract forms, more demanding grounds for dismissals, obstacles to contract termination, general labor regulation and
industrial/collective relations laws all have a positive influence upon the rate of franchising.
The effect is particularly significant for the regulation governing contract termination: as
11 One element that could help explain this prominence of franchising in Germany is that franchisees enjoy
a favorable court bias there, since they can revoke their contract for a full year after its conclusion and be
reimbursed of their specific costs unless the contract specifies otherwise (Couture, 1997). Undeniably, this
effect could be very fragile since greater protection of franchisees can also discourage the trademark owners
to franchise their assets.
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
71
Table 5 Determinants of the franchise rate—Procedural formalism
Network rate of franchising
Model
(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)
Intcpt
1.00∗
(0.54)
0.47
(0.46)
0.52∗∗
(0.24)
0.38
(0.23)
Civil law
0.16
(0.13)
0.06
(0.08)
0.06
(0.08)
−0.10
(0.15)
German tradition
0.21∗∗∗
(0.07)
0.19∗∗
(0.08)
0.20∗∗∗
(0.07)
0.18∗∗
(0.07)
Tied input sales (yes/no)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
Total number of units
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
Management assistance
0.01
(0.08)
0.01
(0.09)
0.01
(0.09)
0.01
(0.08)
Extent of training
−0.04
(0.07)
−0.05
(0.07)
−0.05
(0.07)
−0.06
(0.07)
Network age
0.00
(0.04)
0.00
(0.04)
0.00
(0.04)
0.00
(0.04)
Years without franchises
−0.35∗∗∗
(0.09)
−0.35∗∗∗
(0.09)
−0.35∗∗∗
(0.09)
−0.34∗∗∗
(0.09)
Financial support
0.06
(0.05)
0.06
(0.05)
0.06
(0.05)
0.06
(0.05)
Qualifications
0.04
(0.06)
0.03
(0.06)
0.03
(0.06)
0.03
(0.06)
No specific requirement
0.02
(0.06)
0.02
(0.06)
0.02
(0.06)
0.02
(0.06)
Salesman required
0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.02
(0.06)
Formalism
−0.39
(0.41)
Extent of written procedures
0.08
(0.78)
Extent of profesionalism
−0.01
(0.26)
Legal justifications
0.43
(0.34)
N
546
546
546
546
LR Test
91.05∗∗∗
90.13∗∗∗
90.13∗∗∗
91.74∗∗∗
Note: Standard errors in parenthesis.
levels of significance.
∗∗∗ ,∗∗
and
∗
denote the 1%, 5% and 10%
terminating labor contracts becomes more regulated, franchisors resort more to franchising, possibly with the hope that their (smaller) franchised units are either exempted from
these regulations or that their business conditions (bankruptcy, for instance) will help them
circumvent these laws. On the other hand, the regulation of employment itself (minimum
wage, hours of work, paid holidays, maternity leaves, etc.) seems to discourage franchising,
Springer
72
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
Table 6 Determinants of the franchise rate—Labor regulation
Network rate of franchising
Model
(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)
(e)
(f)
(g)
Intcpt
0.86
(0.54)
0.11
(0.13)
0.24∗
(0.07)
−0.49
(0.41)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.02
(0.08)
−0.05
(0.07)
0.00
(0.04)
−0.35∗
(0.09)
0.05
(0.05)
0.04
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.61∗∗
(0.28)
1.20∗∗
(0.55)
0.42∗∗
(0.17)
−0.01
(0.12)
−0.30
(0.41)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.02
(0.08)
−0.05
(0.07)
0.00
(0.04)
−0.35∗
(0.09)
0.06
(0.05)
0.04
(0.06)
0.02
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.78
(0.55)
0.07
(0.13)
0.15∗∗∗
(0.08)
−0.27
(0.41)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.02
(0.08)
−0.05
(0.07)
0.00
(0.04)
−0.34∗
(0.09)
0.05
(0.05)
0.04
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
1.00∗∗∗
(0.54)
0.10
(0.16)
0.22∗
(0.08)
−0.42
(0.41)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.01
(0.08)
−0.04
(0.07)
0.00
(0.04)
−0.35∗
(0.09)
0.05
(0.05)
0.04
(0.06)
0.02
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.77
(0.55)
0.03
(0.14)
0.14∗∗∗
(0.08)
−0.29
(0.41)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.02
(0.08)
−0.05
(0.07)
0.00
(0.04)
−0.34∗
(0.09)
0.05
(0.05)
0.04
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.74
(0.56)
0.04
(0.15)
0.24∗
(0.07)
−0.41
(0.41)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.02
(0.08)
−0.05
(0.07)
0.00
(0.04)
−0.35∗
(0.09)
0.05
(0.05)
0.04
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
1.14∗∗
(0.55)
−0.06
(0.18)
0.26∗
(0.08)
−0.59
(0.42)
−0.08∗
(0.05)
0.04∗∗
(0.02)
0.02
(0.08)
−0.04
(0.07)
0.00
(0.04)
−0.35∗
(0.09)
0.05
(0.05)
0.04
(0.06)
0.02
(0.06)
0.01
(0.06)
Civil
law
German
tradition
Formalism
Tied input
sales (yes/no)
Total number
of units
Management
assistance
Extent of
training
Network
age
Years without
franchises (%)
Financial
support
Qualifications
No specific
requirement
Salesman
required
Obstacles to alternative
employment contracts
Regulation of
employment conditions
Grounds for
dismissals
Regulation
of dismissals
Regulation of
contract termination
Regulation of
employment
Regulation of
collective relations
N
546
LR Test
95.82∗∗∗
−1.39∗∗
(0.63)
0.33∗∗
(0.14)
0.18
(0.32)
0.69∗∗
(0.33)
0.42∗∗
(0.25)
546
546
546
546
546
95.95∗∗∗ 96.27∗∗∗ 91.36∗∗∗ 95.26∗∗∗ 93.84∗∗∗
0.33∗∗
(0.19)
546
93.99∗∗∗
Note: Standard errors in parenthesis. ∗∗∗ ,∗∗ and ∗ denote the 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance.
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
73
probably because larger firms have greater facilities to deal with these constraints. The regulation of dismissals (including mandatory notices and approvals by third parties, mandatory
retraining and replacements before dismissals) does not seem to influence the franchise rate,
possibly because their effect on the franchisor and the franchisees are more balanced than
for the other indicators.
Table 7 Determinants of
franchise rate—IPR protection
Network rate of franchising
Model
(a)
(b)
Intcpt
−6.24∗
(3.74)
−8.59∗∗
(3.96)
Civil law
0.50∗
(0.29)
0.46
(0.29)
German tradition
−0.06
(0.11)
−0.06
(0.11)
Formalism
−1.42∗
(0.80)
−1.19
(0.81)
Grounds for dismissal
1.17∗∗∗
(0.44)
0.97∗∗
(0.45)
Trademark law
3.79∗
(1.95)
4.17∗∗
(1.96)
0.82∗
(0.45)
Enforcement of IPR law
Note: Standard errors in
parenthesis. ∗∗∗ ,∗∗ and ∗ denote
the 1%, 5% and 10% levels of
significance.
Tied input sales (yes/no)
−0.09∗∗
(0.04)
−0.08∗
(0.04)
Total number of units
0.05∗∗∗
(0.02)
0.05∗∗∗
(0.02)
Management assistance
0.12
(0.08)
0.12
(0.08)
Extent of training
−0.02
(0.06)
−0.02
(0.06)
Network age
−0.02
(0.04)
−0.02
(0.04)
Years without franchises
−0.35∗∗∗
(0.08)
−0.37∗∗∗
(0.08)
Financial support
0.03
(0.04)
0.04
(0.04)
Qualifications
0.06
(0.06)
0.07
(0.06)
No specific requirement
0.03
(0.05)
0.04
(0.05)
Salesman required
−0.03
(0.06)
−0.03
(0.05)
N
464
464
LR Test
101.82∗∗∗
105.16∗∗∗
Springer
74
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
Table 7 considers the impact of trademark law and enforcement of IPRs. The indicator
relative to the grounds needed for dismissals is also included in the regressions to control
for some aspects of labor regulation. The indicator of trademark efficacy has a positive coefficient, significant at the 10% threshold. Its inclusion still further enhances our previous
results for the formalism indicator is now significant at the 10% threshold, and negative
Table 8 Determinants of the franchise rate—Ordered multinomial regressions
Network rate of franchising
Model :
(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)
(e)
(f)
Tied sales
(Yes/No)
−0.22
(0.19)
−0.27
(0.19)
−0.28
(0.20)
−0.30
(0.20)
−0.40∗
(0.22)
−0.38∗
(0.22)
Total number
of units
0.08
(0.07)
0.11
(0.07)
0.12
(0.07)
0.11
(0.07)
0.23∗∗
(0.10)
0.23∗∗
(0.10)
Management
assistance
−0.14
(0.35)
−0.19
(0.35)
−0.20
(0.35)
−0.14
(0.35)
0.21
(0.40)
0.24
(0.40)
Extent of
training
−0.21
(0.29)
−0.04
(0.30)
−0.02
(0.30)
−0.07
(0.30)
−0.05
(0.32)
−0.06
(0.32)
Network age
−0.22
(0.15)
−0.02
(0.16)
−0.01
(0.16)
0.02
(0.17)
−0.08
(0.18)
−0.09
(0.18)
Years without
franchises
−1.27∗∗∗
(0.34)
−1.28∗∗∗
(0.35)
−1.29∗∗∗
(0.35)
−1.23∗∗∗
(0.35)
−1.53∗∗∗
(0.38)
−1.59∗∗∗
(0.38)
Financial
support
0.32∗
(0.18)
0.17
(0.19)
0.15
(0.19)
0.08
(0.19)
0.14
(0.23)
0.15
(0.23)
Qualifications
0.24
(0.26)
0.10
(0.26)
0.11
(0.26)
0.15
(0.26)
0.31
(0.30)
0.32
(0.30)
No specific
requirement
−0.13
(0.23)
−0.05
(0.23)
−0.06
(0.23)
−0.10
(0.23)
−0.05
(0.26)
−0.02
(0.26)
Salesman
required
−0.08
(0.25)
−0.05
(0.25)
−0.06
(0.25)
−0.08
(0.25)
−0.24
(0.28)
−0.26
(0.28)
Civil law
0.26
(0.32)
0.57
(0.51)
0.11
(0.52)
2.29
(1.46)
2.11
(1.44)
German
tradition
0.72∗∗
(0.28)
0.77∗∗∗
(0.29)
0.40
(0.31)
−0.77
(0.56)
−0.71
(0.56)
−1.31
(1.64)
−0.79
(1.68)
−6.75∗
(4.08)
−5.80
(4.04)
2.07∗∗∗
(0.57)
7.26∗∗∗
(2.18)
6.35∗∗∗
(2.28)
23.47∗∗
(9.63)
23.92∗∗
(9.66)
Formalism
Dismissal
regulation
Trademark law
Enforcement
of IPR law
2.82
(2.14)
N
546
546
546
546
464
464
LR Chi2
62.13∗∗∗
75.66∗∗∗
76.29∗∗∗
89.42∗∗∗
93.80∗∗∗
95.53∗∗∗
Note: Standard errors in parenthesis.
significance.
Springer
∗∗∗ ,∗∗
and
∗
denote the 1%, 5% and 10% levels of
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
75
as hypothesized in our discussion. The labor regulation indicator remains negative but its
significance is increased. Remember however that countries with strong trademark laws are
also less effective at enforcing these laws. Thus, the role of trademark laws in franchising
might have been underestimated. Model (b) adds a parameter controlling for the enforcement
efficacy of IPR laws :unsurprisingly, this inclusion enhances the explanatory power of the
trademark indicator, which becomes significant at the 5% threshold. Further, better enforcement encourages franchising, as hypothesized in our discussion, although this effect is only
significant at the 10% threshold. The inclusion of this variable also makes the indicator of
formalism insignificant. Overall, the performance of the trademark and enforcement indicators is in accordance with our expectations, especially given the ambiguity of the theoretical
relationship (see part 2.3) and the low variance of these parameters in our sample.
4.3. Robustness
Unsurprisingly, the R 2 obtained with the tobit procedures are very low ranging from 0.08
in the baseline regressions to 0.151 in the final regression. Nonetheless, the likelihood ratio
tests seem very satisfying, the 1% threshold being systematically exceeded. To better capture
the goodness of fit of our model as well as to strengthen our empirical evidence, we perform
additional regressions using categorical variables and an ordered multinomial logit test.
More precisely, our observations are classified into three categories depending on the extent
of franchising :the first, second and third class assemble those franchisors with a franchise
rate respectively inferior to 0.3, comprised between 0.3 and 0.8 and superior to 0.8. The
results are presented in Table 8. The loss in information content due to the aggregation of
some of the dependent variable’s values results in slightly altered results. In particular, the
significance of the tied sales dummy and of the total number of units are less robust, though
they reach the usual standards of significance in the final two regressions (models e and
f ). Results on institutions are basically left unaltered, except for the enforcement indicator
which is no longer significant, though it remains positive. Most importantly, more than 65%
of our observations are correctly predicted. Using an ordered multinomial logit over four
categories (0, 0–0.8, 0.8–1, 1) leads to similar results but inevitably reduces the prediction
power to 45%.
5. Conclusion
This empirical analysis of franchise rates across nine industrialized countries brings only
limited support to the framework of the contract theory. Most of the variables related to this
corpus (management assistance, training, franchisee’s qualifications, all of which should be
related to moral hazards concerns) turn out to be insignificant. Though this may partly reflect
noises in some of our proxys, it also suggests that the explanatory power of the contract
theory framework is significantly reduced when set in an international setting.
The inclusion of institutions in this framework has turned out to be of greater empirical
relevance, as variances in institutional parameters help explain some of the difference in
franchise rates across countries. Variables related to the laws themselves, as opposed to the
legal traditions and characteristics of the judiciary, are especially influential. The effectiveness
of intellectual property rights, notably trademarks, encourages a greater resort to franchising
as the theory of property rights would suggest. Labor regulation has a more ambiguous impact,
depending on the type of constraints imposed upon firms, but on average, it exerts a positive
influence on franchising. The franchise contract thus appears as an organizationalstrategy at
Springer
76
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
least partly aimed at alleviating the administrative and incentive costs generated by greater
labor regulation. By extension, the paper confirms the significant influence exerted by legal
rules over the organizational structure of firms.
Acknowledgments We thank Ulrich Kessler for letting us use his dataset on franchising, Marie Obidzinski
for her support in the collection of institutional data and Eric Brousseau for useful suggestions.
References
Anderlini, L., Felli, L. & Postlewaite. (2001). “Courts of Law and Unforeseen Contingencies.” Journal of
Economic Literature. March, 2001.
Arora, A., Ceccagnoli, M. & Cohen, W. (2003). “R&D and the Patent Premium.” NBER Working Paper
No. 9431.
Bai, C. E. & Tao, Z. (2000). “Contract Mixing in Franchising as a Mechanism for Public Good Provision.”
Journal of Economics and Management Strategy. 9(1), 85–113.
Bercovitz, J. (2000). “An Analysis of Contract Provisions in the Business Format Franchise Agreements.”
Mimeo, Fuqua School of Business, Duke University.
Bercovitz, J. E. (1999). “The Organizational Choice Decision in Business-Format Franchising: An Empirical
Test.” Mimeo, The Fuqua School of Business, Duke University.
Bessy, C., Brousseau, E. & Saussier, S. (2001). “Payment Schemes in Technology Licensing Agreements :A
Transaction Cost Approach.” Working Paper, ATOM, U. of Paris I.
Botero, J., Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez De Silanes, F & Shleifer, A. (2002). “The Regulation of Labor.”
Mimeo, Yale University, November 2002.
Bradach, J. L. (1997). “Using Plural Form in the Management of Restaurant Chains.” Administrative Science
Quarterly. 42, 276–303.
Brickley, J. A. (2002). “Royalty Rates and Up-front Fees in Share Contracts: Evidence from Franchising.”
Journal of Law, Economics & Organization. 18(2), 511–535.
Brickley, J. A. (1999). “Incentive Conflicts and Contractual Restraints: Evidence from Franchising.” Journal
of Law and Economics. XLII, 745–774.
Brickley, J. A., Dark, F. H. & Weisbach M. S. (1991). “The Economic Effect of Franchise Termination Laws.”
Journal of Law and Economics. XXXIV, 101–132.
Brickley, J. A. & Dark, F. H. (1987). “The Choice of Organizational Form: The Case of Franchising.” Journal
of Financial Economics. 18, 401–420.
Caves, R. E.& Murphy W. F. (1976). “Franchising: Firms, Markets and Intangible Assets.” Southern Journal
of Economics. 42,572–586.
Cohen, W., Nelson, R. & WALSH J. (2000). “Appropriability Conditions and Why Firms Patent and Why
They Do Not in the American Manufacturing Sector.” NBER Working Paper No. 7552.
Couture, M. (1997). “La Franchise ‡ l’Heure de la Mondialisation.” Le Journal du Barreau. 29, June.
Crain, M. & Hopkins, D. (2001). “The Impact of Regulatory Costs on Small Firms.” Small Business Research
Summary. 207.
Coase, R. (1960). “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics. III, 1–44.
Disdier, A. & Mayer, T. (2004). “How Different is Eastern Europe ? Structure and Determinants of Location
Choices by French Firms in Eastern and Western Europe.” forthcoming in the Journal of Comparative
Economics.
Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). “The Regulation of Entry.” Quaterly
Journal of Economics. CXVII, 1–37.
Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). “The Practice of Justice.” Harvard
University Mimeo.
Edwards, P., Ram, M., & Black J. (2003). “The Impact of Employment Legislation on Small Firms: A
Case Study Analysis.” Employment Research Series No. 20, Department of Trade and Industry, United
Kingdom.
Falvey, R., Foster, N. & Greenaway D. (2004). “Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Growth.”
manuscript, U. of Nottingham.
Ferrantino, M. (1993). “The Effect of Intellectual Property Rights on Trade and International Investment.”
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv. 129, 300–331.
Gallini, N.& Lutz, N. (1992). “Dual Distribution and Royalty Fees in Franchising.” Journal of Law, Economics
& Organization. 8, 471–501.
Springer
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
77
Ginarte, J. & Park, W. (1998). “Determinants of Patent Rights :A Cross-National Study.” Research Policy. 28,
283–301.
Hadfield G. (1990). “Problematic Relations: Franchising an The Law of Incomplete Contracts.” Stanford Law
Review. 42, 927.
Henisz, W. (2000). “The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth.” Economics and Politics. 12, 1–31.
Holmes, T. J. (1998). “The Effect of State Policies on the Location of Manufacturing: Evidence from State
Borders.” Journal of Political Economy. 106, 4, 667–705.
Kaplow L. (2000). “General Characteristics of Rules.” In B. Bouckaert and G. DeGeest, Edward (eds.),
Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. Elgar, Cheltenham.
Knack, S. & Keefer, P. (1995). “Why Don’t Poor Countries Catch Up? A Cross Country Test of an Institutional
Explanation.” Economic Inquiry. 35(3), 590–602.
Kugler, A., Jimeno, J. & HERNANZ V. (2003). “Employment Consequences of Restrictive Permanent Contracts :Evidence from Spanish Labor Reforms.” Working Paper 2003–14, FEDEA.
Lafontaine F. (1992). “Agency Theory and Franchising; Some Empirical Results.” RAND Journal of Economics. 23, 263–283.
Lafontaine F. (1993). “Contractual Arrangements as Signaling Devices:Evidence from Franchising.” Journal
of Law, Economics & Organization. 9, 256–289.
Lafontaine, F. (1995). “Pricing Decisions in Franchised Chains:A Look at the Restaurant and Fast-Food
Industry.” Working Paper NBER 5247.
Lafontaine, F. & Shaw, K. L. (1999). “The Dynamic of Franchise Contracting: Evidence from Panel Data.”
Journal of Political Economy. 107, 1041–1080.
Lafontaine, F. & Shaw, K. L. (2004). “Targeting Managerial Control: Evidence from Franchising.” Working
Paper, University of Michigan Business School, forthcoming in the RAND journal of Economics.
Lafontaine, F. & Slade, M. (2001). “Incentive Contracting and the Franchise Decision.” In K. Chatterjee and
W. Samuelson (eds.), Advances in Business Application of Game Theory. Kluwer Academic Press.
La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). “Legal Determinants of External
Finance.” Journal of Finance. LII, 1131–1150.
La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). “Law and Finance.” Journal of Political
Economy. CVI, 1113–1155.
Lee, J. & Mansfield, E. (1996). “Intellectual Property Protection and US Foreign Direct Investment.” Review
of Economics and Statistics. 78, 181–186.
Lerner, J. (1995). “Patenting in the Shadow of Competitors.” Journal of Law and Economics. 38, 463–496.
List, J. A. & Co C. Y. (2000). “The Effect of Environmental Regulation on Foreign Direct Investment.” Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management. 40, 1–20.
Maskus, K. & Penubarti, M. (1995). “How Trade-Related Are Intellectual Property Rights?” Journal of
International Economics. 39, 227–248.
Mathewson, F. & Winter, R. (1985). “The Economics of Franchise Contracts.” Journal of Law and Economics.
28, 503–526.
Minkler A. (1990). “An Empirical Analysis of Firm’s Decision to Franchise”. Economics Letters. 34, 133–
156.
Minkler, A. P. & Park, T. A. (1994). “Asset Specificity and Vertical Integration in Franchising.” Review of
Industrial Organization. 9, 409–423.
Nickell, S. & Layard R. (1999). “Labor Market Institutions and Economic Performance.” In D. Card and O.
Ashenfelter (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics. 3C, 3029–3084.
North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Chp. 3, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 17–26.
Norton, S. W. (1988). “An Empirical Look at Franchise as an Organizational Form.” Journal of Business.
April, 197–218.
Ostergard, R. (2000). “The Measurement of Intellectual Property Rights Protection.” Journal of International
Business Studies. 31, 349–360.
Oxenfeldt, A. R. & Kelly, A. O. (1969). “Will Successful Franchise Systems Ultimately Become WhollyOwned Chains?” Journal of Retailing. 44, 69–83.
Oxley, J. (1999). “Institutional Environment and the Mechanisms of Governance :The Impact of Intellectual Property Protection on the Structure of Inter–Firm Alliances.” Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization. 38, 283–309.
Penard, T., Raynaud E., & Saussier, S. (2004). “Théorie des Contrats et réseaux de franchise.” Revue FranÁaise
d’Economie. 4, 151–191.
Penard, T., Raynaud, E. & Saussier, S. (2003). “Dual Distribution and royalty rates in Franchised Chains:An
Empirical Analysis Using French Data.” Journal of Marketing Channels. 10, 5–31.
Posner, R. (1998). Economic Analysis of Law. 5th edition, New York: Aspen Law & Business.
Springer
78
Eur J Law Econ (2006) 21: 53–78
Sakikabara, M. & Branstetter, L. (2001). “Do Stronger Patents Induce More Innovation ? Evidence from the
1988 Japanese Patent Law Reforms.” RAND Journal of Economics. 32, 1, 77–100.
Scott, F. A. (1995). “Franchising versus Vertical Integration as a Decision Variable of the Firm.” Review of
Industrial Organization. 10, 69–81.
Shavell, S. (2004). Fondations of Economic Analysis of Law. Harvard University Press.
Sorenson, O. & Sorensen, J. B. (2001). “Finding the Right Mix:Organizational Learning, Plural Forms, and
Franchise Performance.” Strategic Management Journal. 22(6-7), 713–724.
Smarzynska, B. (2004). “Composition of Foreign Direct Investment and Protection of Intellectual Property
Rights in Transition Economies.” World Bank discussion paper 2228, forthcoming in the European
Economic Review.
Smith, P. (1999). “Are Weak Patent Rights a Barrier to US Exports ?” Journal of International Economics.
48,151–177.
Smith, P. (2001). “How Do Foreign Patent Rights Affect US Exports, Affiliate Sales and Licenses.” Journal
of International Economics. 55, 411–439.
Viscusi, W. K. & Moore, M. (1993). “Product Liability, Research and Development and Innovation.” Journal
of Political Economy. 101(1), 161–184.
Wei, S. J. (2000). “How Taxing is Corruption on International Investors ?” Review of Economics and Statistics.
82, 1–11.
Williamson, O. (1991). “Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives.” Administrative Science Quaterly. June, 269–296.
Yang, G. & Maskus, K. (2001). “Intellectual Property Rights and Licensing: An Econometric Investigation.”
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv. 134(2), 210–221.
Springer