Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Can water pricing policies regulate irrigation use?

The paper proposes a reassessment of the hopes vested in pricing mechanisms to regulate water diversions in the irrigation sector, focusing on large scale (surface) public irrigation. It first lists a series of major constraints that explain why the economic rationale applied to urban water supply cannot readily be transposed to surface irrigation. It then offers a review of situations where water is scarce and where irrigation schemes are able to distribute water volumetrically, either at the bulk or individual level. Such situations are relatively rare at the world level but they provide the context where volumetric pricing policies can be implemented and can demonstrate their potential for putting demand and use in line with supply. The review provides clear evidence that, instead of administered prices, quotas are almost invariably chosen as the main regulation mechanism, with prices mostly used to regulate use at the margin, beyond the quota, rather than for rationing scarce water.

Can water pricing policies regulate irrigation use? Paper presented to the 13th World water Congress, 1-4 September 2008, Montpellier, France François Molle, IRD 1 Abstract The paper proposes a reassessment of the hopes vested in pricing mechanisms to regulate water diversions in the irrigation sector, focusing on large scale (surface) public irrigation. It first lists a series of major constraints that explain why the economic rationale applied to urban water supply cannot readily be transposed to surface irrigation. It then offers a review of situations where water is scarce and where irrigation schemes are able to distribute water volumetrically, either at the bulk or individual level. Such situations are relatively rare at the world level but they provide the context where volumetric pricing policies can be implemented and can demonstrate their potential for putting demand and use in line with supply. The review provides clear evidence that, instead of administered prices, quotas are almost invariably chosen as the main regulation mechanism, with prices mostly used to regulate use at the margin, beyond the quota, rather than for rationing scarce water. The paper then reviews the advantages and limitations of quotas and attempts to explain why they are systematically preferred to pure price-based regulation. If made tradable, quotas or entitlements can be more easily reallocated among users according to criteria of economic efficiency. Such situations still remain rare because there are several cultural, technical and institutional constraints to their development, most notably in developing countries. Finally the paper expands its conclusions to irrigation in general and shows that although much hope has been vested in pricing mechanisms for regulating water use their potential is much lower than is commonly believed. 1 Institut de Recherche pour le Développement, 911, Avenue Agropolis BP 64501, 34394 Montpellier Cedex 5, France, [email protected] Introduction In the 1990s, economists have stressed the importance of treating water as an economic good and, in particular, of "setting the price right" in order to provide the right economic incentives to water users (World Bank, 2003; Molle and Berkoff, 2007). After decades of water resources development based on systematic supply augmentation, often at very high financial or environmental costs, emphasis was shifted to demand-management, roughly defined as "doing better with what we have," in opposition to increasing supply (Winpenny, 1994). Underpricing of irrigation water has been singled out by many water and development experts as one of the crucial reasons for unabated use of water in irrigation, a sector that accounts for 70% of world withdrawals (and much more in most developing countries) (Molle and Berkoff, 2007). The World Water Vision reckons that "users do not value water provided free or almost free and so waste it" (Cosgrove and Rijsberman, 2000), while Sandra Postel (1992) considers that "water is consistently undervalued, and as a result is chronically overused." Environmentalists have placed hopes in water pricing as a means of reducing human abstraction and improving ecosystem health (WWF, 2002); and the EU (2000) also considered that "efficient water pricing reduces the pressure on water resources" and has stressed the importance of full cost pricing and made it a cornerstone of the recent Water Framework Directive. But pricing mechanisms (administered or as defined by markets) may, potentially, have several roles: 1) ensuring the recovery of Operation and Maintenance (O&M) costs; 2) promoting conservation, by eliciting water-saving behaviours, 3) prompting shifts in cropping patterns that come with higher water productivity, 4) assisting in the allocation of water across economic sectors. I am concerned here with the second objective, whereby reductions in agricultural water diversions are expected to be reduced when prices increase. My scope is (large) public surface irrigation schemes, although pressurized delivery is also considered in the discussion. The first section explains briefly why the hopes vested in pricing mechanisms have been frustrated. The second section investigate in more detail how water scarcity, both in the short term (when, for a given season, the available stocks fall short of demand) and in the longer term (when conservation is needed to restrain use) is managed in the specific situations where water is distributed to users volumetrically. A short conclusion follows. This necessarily narrows our scope to only a minor fraction of public irrigation worldwide, as most public schemes in the world–especially gravity irrigation schemes–do not use volumetric management (Tsur, 2004; Burt, 2002). Even limited in scope, the review will provide an important insight on how water scarcity is actually managed in technically more efficient schemes. Major constraints to efficiency pricing of irrigation water A powerful narrative associating low efficiency in irrigation systems with the low level of water charges has widely promoted the idea that raising charges would achieve substantial conservation of resources. This narrative, and the hopes associated with it, were predicated upon the (relative and varied) success observed in the water supply sector. Based on the common wisdom that cheap resources are wasted, increasing irrigation water prices has become a central tenet of all global water events, national water policies, and expert recommendations. But public irrigation seldom resembles the on/off on-demand distribution of water in the urban sector. Supply is variable because runoff is variable and because surface hydraulic infrastructures rarely allow a precise regulation of water distribution. Demand is also variable because rainfall and crop water requirements are variable. The main constraints to the efficiency of price mechanisms and the major flaws of the narrative include (Molle and Berkoff, 2007): • • • • • First, even if average scheme efficiencies suggest otherwise, water is not always wasted: a) it may be temporarily abundant in a given location, with no impact on other uses because these are either satisfied or too distant to allow reallocation; b) losses occur locally but return to the water cycle and are reused downstream; and c) in the extreme case of an overallocated (closed) basin, only losses to a sink can be recovered and there may be little water to be saved. Second, even when some water is wasted, the causes often lie largely beyond the control of the end-users (the farmers): a) farmers can do little to prevent system losses that may constitute up to half of the total; and b) system wastage and shortages are often largely due to unpredictable supply to the scheme, improper internal management and/or poor design rather than farmer behavior. Losses are thus primarily a management issue. When system management improves, “wastage” declines, thus again lowering the potential gains from introducing water pricing at the user level. In other words farmers usually merely use whatever water is effectively supplied to them, rather than what they wish to receive, as opposed to urban supply where the tap can be opened or closed at will. Third, even when water is wasted at farm level, raising prices generally has no impact on irrigation efficiency. This is mainly because few irrigation systems have volumetric management, and even those that have often do not charge users volumetrically. Fourth, in the rare cases where water is charged according to volume (see next section), prices are almost invariably too low to induce a change in behavior. This is all the more true because such schemes are frequently pressurized and associated with high value crops, which means that: (a) water costs are negligible in the crop budget, (b) efficiency is already high, and (c) the costs of achieving higher efficiency would normally offset any gains from a lower water bill. Fifth, while the range of prices that correspond to the order of magnitude of O&M costs is in most cases too low to elicit water savings, it is, in addition, unrealistic to expect that administered prices will ever increase much beyond O&M costs for the sake of encountering elasticity in demand. Empirical evidence shows that the only rare cases where the water charges exceed O&M costs are where basin management taxes are added, and excess is generally around 10 to 20% of O&M costs only: in the case of state-managed schemes users are unlikely to accept paying more than the cost of supply (anything beyond this is considered as a tax and is rejected); in the case of farmermanaged schemes, users never self-inflict them prices higher than O&M costs and find other mechanisms to share scarcity in time of shortage. All in all, these facts and constraints explain why, after 15 years of high expectation, there is hardly any convincing case that prices mechanisms will ever make a significant difference in large-scale public irrigation water use. Exceptions can be found in deep aquifer-based irrigation, when abstraction costs become too high. Such cases approximate the situation of urban water, with on-demand supply of more expensive water. We may now examine in more detail whether price mechanisms are used to manage scarcity in schemes that offer volumetric management of water. Managing water scarcity in irrigation schemes Metering of individual consumption is costly and problematic: a hydraulic device that measures flows is needed at the head of each farm (or plot) and the collection cost of data regarding the evolution of flow with time tends to be prohibitive unless water is pressurized and meters can be installed. Even in the latter case, monitoring of meters is often problematic because users tend to tamper with them, if they severely constrain their use or raise their water charges. In gravity irrigation systems, cases of metering at the individual level can be found in Australia (propellers at the farm level) or in the US (Parshal flumes) and thus tend to be confined to situations with rather large farms and strong enforcement and monitoring capacity. In developing countries with numerous smallholders there are situations where quantities are estimated based on the time of delivery: the flow in the tertiary (or sometimes secondary) canal is assumed to be more or less stable and the duration of supply provides an approximation of what the users receive: in a tertiary canal, for example, farmers can receive water during a fixed amount of time, sequentially or following other types of predefined arrangements. This is the case of the warabandi system in northwestern India and Pakistan, where all outlets to tertiary canals (shacks) in a secondary are designed to ensure the same discharge; or in schemes in Morocco. To offset this problem of monitoring of use, it is often advocated that water use should be monitored at the bulk level, typically that of water user associations (WUA) at the secondary (or tertiary) level (World Bank, 1986; Carruthers et al., 1985; Repetto, 1986; Asad et al., 1999). If users pay fees to the WUA that reflect their real water use, and if prices are high enough for demand to be responsive, then bulk allocation potentially encourages conservation. This however requires robust and transparent arrangements that ensure equitable sharing of water within a tertiary unit. The difficulty often comes when the flow or the duration of supply tends to vary when water gets scarcer, which generally undermines the arrangements that are established for average conditions and gives way to conflicts and free-riding strategies. The following review will therefore distinguish between volumetric management at the secondary/tertiary level (or "block") and volumetric management at the level of the individual user. Bulk allocation Several countries have adopted bulk allocation, often as part of a policy of management transfer, where farmers are left responsible for management at the block level. Examples include: • • • Experience in the Mahaweli System H in Sri Lanka showed that allocation at block level can lead to lower diversions. Distributary canals under the responsibility of Water User Associations (WUAs) had their inflow monitored daily by both the agency and a water master paid by the WUAs. Water charges were not differentiated at farm level, and though WUAs were charged in proportion to water allocations, charges were not based on actual volumetric measurement and were too low to provide incentives for water savings (IWMI unpublished data). Pricing was thus ineffective but the discipline coming from the bulk allocation system was beneficial. Improvements primarily came from stricter scheduling and improved main system management, resulting in more predictable and uniform flows and reduced conflicts. In 1993, Turkey accelerated the transfer of the management of 87% of its 1.9 million ha of largescale irrigation. Irrigation districts (IDs) (generally corresponding to a secondary canal), are expected to levy a fee that covers the O&M costs of the area under their purview but receive bulk water at no cost. While the program was successful in transferring costs to farmers (recovery was around 95% in 2003, against 32-50% in agency-managed schemes: Çakmak et al., 2004), and in improving the reliability of supply at the secondary level (Yercan, 2003), farmers have little say on the amount of water allocated to them: even if farmers were to pay for their allotment there would be little incentive for individual farmers to improve water management because they do not control how much water flows into their areas (transfer agreements do not mention specific water allotments). In such a situation, bulk allocation improves reliability, equity, and cost recovery of O&M costs at the WUA level but prices have no impact on short- or long-term conservation. Bulk allocation as defined in the Mexico transfer program goes one step further (Kloezen, 1998, 2002). Allotments to módulos (blocks) are defined each year based on the water available in the dams but these decisions are taken by the National Water Commission (CNA) together with a Hydraulic Committee which represents users. The WUAs are responsible for O&M and funded through a user fee they collect; the delivery of bulk water is paid for through a small portion of the fee that is channeled to the CNA. These seasonal allotments are tradable (within the district) and WUAs of the same irrigation district can freely make arrangements to sell/purchase water among them. The fee is internal and proportional to the area cultivated and there is therefore no relation between the water received by the WUA and what farmers pay; the fee is determined by O&M costs, not by conservation objectives. Economic efficiency is raised by the possibility of internal trading. • Lessons from China are masked by the diversity of physical and institutional settings (Lohmar et al., 2007). Water reforms supported by the World Bank have focused on improving O&M and on higher financial user participation, as a means of reverting degradation of infrastructure and maintaining or expanding agriculture in a situation of declining overall supply. Water is often delivered by Irrigation Districts to villages or to secondary canals where management is entrusted to townships, villages, WUAs or to private operators. Water is often charged volumetrically but these entities are quite large and individuals have no incentive to adopt water-saving practices because 1) they frequently pay per unit of land, 2) they are often unaware of how much they pay for water and how the fee is used, 3) they have already effectively adjusted to scarcity by improving practices, shifting calendars or developing conjunctive use (wells, farm ponds, etc.). Many of the reasons for inefficient water use lie beyond the scope of the farmers (Yang et al. 2003). Yet, the Chinese experience is particularly interesting because of attempts to instill incentives at the level of the WUA or the private manager who receives financial incentives to reduce water deliveries, part of which may be passed on to farmers in order to ensure their support (Lohmar et al., 2007). Recent research by Liao et al. (2005) showed that fees remain too low to cover full O&M costs, that elasticity is very small, and that significant price increases would “seriously impair” production in areas which could not be compensated with groundwater. Water prices are fixed by special provincial Price Bureaus that take into account national policies such as rural poverty alleviation and self-sufficiency in grains. Prices are not used at levels that could constrain demand but internal incentive mechanisms are being tested. • In Israel, water to different sectors and bulk users is allocated through quotas to cooperatives and communities. They are supposed to be fixed each year but, in practice, tend to be sticky and are only curtailed in times of drought. Consequently, these quotas have been gradually perceived as water rights by agricultural users (Plaut, 2000; Kislev, 2001). Prices are fixed by the government and by sectors and are made uniform so that farmers in the Negev desert pay the same price as farmers close to the source. For a given allotment, farmers pay for water following an increasing block rate established in 1989 and frequently revised. Since the mid-eighties farmers have not, on average 2 , consumed their full quota (Kislev, 2001). This suggests that the tiered system contributes to regulating water demand at the margin, but other factors such as low world prices for agricultural products, high labor costs, and economic specialization also contribute to this situation (Kislev, 2005). In addition, most cooperatives charge their members an average price and these, therefore, do not face tier pricing. The Israeli case shows that quotas are combined with a blocktariff system, the former allowing a transparent 3 and equitable way to share scarcity, and the latter providing both flexibility at the margin and collective incentives to save in the last tier. Distribution within the community, although supposed to be equitable and based on landownership, has sometimes evolved over time, as land endowments, crop types, and technology have changed. This reallocation both within and among communities has probably been insufficient to ensure maximum efficiency (Plaut, 2000; Lees, 1985) but has combined a degree of equity and flexibility. Water markets have been advocated but the shift from a resource owned by the state and allocated 2 While farmers in some areas have lowered their consumption, others would readily use more water if it were available, even at higher prices (Kislev, 2005). 3 Plaut (2000) disagrees with the statement that quotas are transparent and sees the definition of quotas as secretive and rife with rent-seeking and arbitrariness. for specific uses to a commodity with water rights is encountering cultural resistance as well as opposition from vested agricultural interests (Feitelson, 2001). • In Japan, water is distributed to around 7,000 Land Improvement Districts (LIDs) that serve an average area of 500 hectares. LIDs receive a volume that is specified each fortnight and that is calculated to be ensured 9 years out of 10. They are totally autonomous within their area (including headwork management) and they act as authorized suppliers of water in their command areas (Kobayashi, 2006). Charges are defined as per cultivated area flat rates and calculated to recover O&M costs and part of the investment costs. Farmers' rights are not specified at the individual level and monitoring and metering at this level are deemed unrealistic. The basic principle of this charging system lies in preserving equity among members. • Other examples of volumetric bulk allocation include Andhra Pradesh and Maharashtra (India), Northern Vietnam, Iran, and Taiwan. In the Zayandeh Rud basin, Iran, bulk allocation is done at the secondary and tertiary levels; canals are equipped with baffle distributors which allow managers to fix the discharge in both secondary and tertiary canals. Allocation is not directly proportional to landholding and is also based on the type of crop, the history of the water use of individual farmers, and the kind of water rights (Hoogesteger, 2005). Price mechanisms are ineffective because charges are too low (2-3% of the income), far below the marginal value of water, and because scarcity is managed through locally defined and socially accepted arrangements. Several conclusions can be drawn from these examples of bulk allocation. First, bulk allocation is primarily a mechanism that goes with partial financial and managerial autonomy of WUAs, allowing agencies to shift part of the O&M costs on to them. Second, bulk allocation improves the predictability and reliability of deliveries at main canal and block levels (Bosworth et al., 2002). Third, bulk water pricing can generate revenue, but even if farmer charges are assessed in relation to delivered quantities, they are seldom charged on a volumetric basis; and even if they are so charges are seldom high enough to promote conservation (Asad et al., 1999; Tiwari and Dinar, 2001). Fourth, incentives from volumetric pricing are seldom passed on from the group to users, although innovative schemes in China suggest there is potential for this to happen. Fifth, when supply availability is below demand, quotas are reduced in proportion to the shortfall; prices remain constant and are not raised in order to reduce demand in line with supply. The deficit is generally spread more or less equally across quotaholders. In sum, although water pricing at the block level could theoretically elicit conservation and/or be used to reduce demand when supply drops, management is first and foremost based on reasonable use (block quotas), with occasional deficits distributed over the blocks. Internal trading (like in Mexico) improves scheme efficiency but potential conservation effects are cancelled by the fact that individual payments are not volumetric. It is only in China's experiences, where (private) managers have an incentive to reduce bulk allocation, with the benefits shared by farmers, that a potential for reducing diversions can be identified. Individual quotas and on-demand irrigation systems In some cases, technical control over the distribution of water is high enough to allow volumetric monitoring of water supply at the farm level. These systems tend to be concentrated in developed and/or arid countries, and are often pressurized rather than gravity systems. • In the large-scale irrigation systems of Morocco, farmers pay a minimum fee equivalent to 3,000 m3/ha (Ait Kadi, 2002). The water charge is based primarily on cost-recovery rather than on conservation criteria, though in pump schemes the water bill can be up to 65-70% of gross income (e.g., in Souss Massa groundwater scheme: Ait Kadi, 2002) and in these cases it undoubtedly influences farmer behavior. Water use is regulated by supply–not by demand management–through quotas. When reductions are needed (in case of drought) or possible (because of a shift to microirrigation, as subsidized by the government), quotas are modified by varying the number of irrigation turns or the duration of delivery according to the crop (e.g., some crops like sugar beet or trees are given higher priority) (see Petitguyot, 2003, for the example of the Tadla scheme). Quotas are thus adjusted to circumstances and can hardly be trimmed. In most cases, farmers have to pay for their quotas even if they do not use them fully but this is rarely the case since, on the contrary, many supplement supply with groundwater for which they pay a higher price per cubic meter. With water charges already covering O&M costs in gravity schemes it is unlikely that charges will ever be at levels that constrain individual demand, no elasticity being anticipated even with a 100% increase (El-Gueddari, 2002). Again, the regulation mechanism used is quotas, with adjustment in case of shortage (Hellegers et al., 2007). • In the Jordan Valley, individual quotas are based on crop type, thus partly promoting water savings (Molle et al., 2008). Water is sourced from a regulated open canal and delivered through pumping stations and collective pressurized networks. Yet, water variability and canal capacity preclude arranged or on-demand irrigation and water is rotated at block level within the area served by a network (pumping station are also 'on' according to a given schedule). Charges are set in relation to O&M costs (65% at present), not to regulate use or demand, and would have little impact on demand if they were to fully cover O&M costs. Adjustments in time of shortage are obtained by reducing crop-based quotas uniformly, not by increasing prices. On-farm conservation is hindered by uneven pressure in networks, poorly designed micro-irrigation equipment, the cost of adopting improved technology, and by the already low quotas. If raised, water costs could make some crops like citrus or open-field vegetables hardly profitable but the result would be a shift in farm management and economic efficiency, rather than water savings (Molle et al., 2008). • Montginoul and Rieu (2001) report an experience from the Charentes region, western France, where two dams were built to increase supply to irrigation but with a strong concern to limit demand. A binomial pricing policy (with a fixed part and a component varying with the volume consumed) was shown to be impracticable “because to have a meaningful impact on consumption the price would have to be increased to such an extent that the farmers’ income would be lower than before the dams were built” (Montginoul and Rieu, 2001). The system eventually selected was a quota system (fixed for 10 days, depending on the amount of water in the river), with extra volumes charged at 10 times the nominal variable charge and threats of withdrawal of the CAP premiums. Acceptance of the system by farmers ensured self-monitoring and curbed opportunistic behaviors. • • 4 The Neste system, in the southwestern part of France, is an intricate set of reservoirs distributed over 11 interlinked catchments that distribute water to 50,000 hectares supplied by 2,000 individual or collective pumping stations and irrigated by sprinklers (Hurand, 2001). Water requirements per unit of land are rather low (1,750-2,000 m3/ha). Metering is possible at the farm level and the pricing system adopted consists of an allocated quota priced at an average price together with an overconsumption price for any excess use. Prices are calculated to ensure full recovery of running costs and the price structure arranged to respond to the high marginal value of water during the irrigation period, while “leaving [each] farmer free 4 to manage his water efficiently according to his own water value function” (Tardieu and Préfol, 2002). In the south of Italy, which is subject to dry climatic conditions, the Capitanata region also offers an example of a pressurized irrigation system where scarcity is handled through quotas (Mastrorilli et al., 1997; Altieri, 2001). These quotas are low by all standards (2,000 m3/ha) but some relative flexibility is offered at the margin through a block system in which the upper tier is heavily priced. This flexibility is, however, relative because continuous overuse is dealt with by threats of disconnection; while water is generally delivered on demand, some problems (e.g., combined peak However, in 3 years out of the last 10 years, exceeding the quota was simply banned because of water shortage. demands for areas with homogeneous cropping patterns) have led to establishing a rotational delivery schedule. • • • • Irrigation in Spain is also based on volumetric management either at the bulk level (6,188 comunidades de regantes are granted volumetric water use licenses, which are distributed among members according to varied methods) or at the individual level (farmers within state-managed schemes). A total of 41% of the Spanish irrigated area is under sprinkler or micro-irrigation (Berbel et al., 2001), which allows easier volumetric control. The Genil Cabral and Fuente Palmera irrigation cooperatives in the Guadalquivir basin, for example, are quite recent pumping schemes “designed to minimize water losses in distribution and to maximize yields per drop in water application through automated, on-demand watering (sprinklers and drip irrigation)” (Maestu, 1999). In Genil Cabral, the automated computerized control system allows the cooperative to impose penalties on those who exceed consumption by more than 10% of a limit that is reviewed every year. The excess, up to 10%, is billed at twice the price and any volume over this limit at 25 times the unit cost. This high-tech system is adapted to high-scarcity conditions (allotments of 2,000 m3/ha) and enables control of marginal use through pricing. A system that comes close to fully on demand is that operated by the Canal de Provence in France, where the main canal is dynamically regulated to meet agricultural and municipal demands and includes additional temporary storage capacity (water towers, tanks). Farmers are free to irrigate as they wish (under the conditions of discharge and pressure they have subscribed to). Prices are set to recover full financial costs and not to control demand, but the price structure is complex (Jean, 1999), distinguishing between users, fixed and variable charges, and peak and normal demands. The system is not water-short and managers only discourage water use beyond the subscribed amount by specific tariffs. Many other (surface water) systems with individual volumetric control can be found in the US, especially where farms are large and the number of farmers small. In 1989, the Broadview District, supplied by the (California) Central Valley project, accepted a two-tiered price system. The district had triggered public outrage after the discovery that its effluents were loaded with selenium and had devastating effects on wildlife in the Kesterson Refuge (Wichelns et al., 1996). At the same time, a 5-year drought was starting to affect the region. Under pressure to limit their water diversion and drainage flows, farmers realized that improved practices could reduce their use of water and keep them in the first tier. However, because of the drought, Broadview’s water supply had to be decreased by more than 50% during the 1990-1994 period. Instead of raising prices in order to reduce demand accordingly, it was found preferable “to begin allocating water among individual farmers” proportionally to the size of their farms, while providing cheap loans to encourage farmers to purchase sprinklers and gated pipe irrigation systems (Wichelns, 2003). While the price structure may have contributed to encouraging farmers to improve management, quotas were eventually adopted when scarcity arose. Other cases include Peru, China and Canada. In one system of northern Peru studied by Vos (2002), pricing was volumetric but was not used to manage scarcity: rather in times of shortages the rules employed promoted equity and quotas were set up to limit use. In Shangdong, China, the use of integrated circuit (IC) machines ensures that farmers cannot obtain irrigation water without paying (Easter and Liu, 2005) and seems to provide reliable on-demand water (no evidence is provided on whether prices regulate demand). The southeast Kelowna Irrigation, Canada, is a "mixed" provider, supplying not only 400 farms but also 1,900 domestic connections. Irrigation uses 85% of the resources and the district is periodically relatively water-short. Increased domestic use due to development and requests for additional land to be serviced with irrigation water have put pressure on the irrigation district to seek opportunities for system expansion. With the lack of adequate locations for new reservoirs, users are under pressure to prove that their licenses correspond to "responsible use." Individual metering has been introduced to instill conservation, allow equitable distribution and drought-management plans. This did not impact on use and, in 2001, irrigation entitlements were defined, with a metered rate penalty for excess use following an increased block system (in 2003). The system was seen to enhance equitable use of water and avoid the pitfalls of open-access regimes (Pike, 2005). • In some countries (e.g., in western states of the USA, Australia, Chile, etc.) quotas are defined as individual rights and a legal framework has been developed for trading these rights. Management continues to be determined by entitlements and water distribution is still, usually, by ‘arranged demand.’ However, water trading redistributes entitlements and contributes to higher economic returns. System constraints, third-party concerns and regulatory aspects may confine trades to neighboring farmers, with little impact on the overall irrigation water use, but in some contexts water is traded out of agriculture (e.g., the Colorado-Big-Thompson scheme: Howe, 1986; Mariño and Kemper, 1999; Howe and Goemans, 2003). In Australia, users enjoy individual water entitlements and they can schedule deliveries to their farms. In case of shortage, entitlements are reduced proportionally to the deficit but trading among right-holders is possible (Turral et al., 2004). Although water charges are covering O&M costs, resource management at the basin level and, lately, part of the remediation of environmental externalities, they remain much under the marginal value of water. Thus administered prices are not used to instill conservation or allocate water in times of scarcity, a function devoted to market transactions that amount to around 10% of total water entitlements for temporary lease, and less than 1% for permanent transfers. Quotas vs. regulation through prices Several lessons can be drawn from the above review. The first (obvious and reiterated) lesson is that both bulk allocation/quotas and pricing policies are only possible with quite stable water regimes and/or modern hydraulic infrastructures. Pressurized distribution networks primarily lend themselves to such policies but there are also cases of individual quotas in high-tech surface water systems associated with pumping stations. The Neste system in France, for example, has 200 river flow measurement locations, 40 automated regulators with remote control, and 150 real-time monitoring points of the amounts of water pumped by collective stations (Tardieu, 1999). The Canal de Provence and the Central California canal systems are even more sophisticated, with open-channel dynamic regulation. The Capitanata (Italy) and many collective Spanish systems are fully pressurized. Second, our examples showed that the use of bulk water pricing (where it exists) is mainly oriented toward revenue generation and maintenance, rather than toward economic efficiency or incentives for users to change consumption patterns (Asad et al., 1999; Tiwari and Dinar, 2001). Rather than impacting users' behaviors, the main benefit lies in the improvements in overall management demanded from irrigation agencies. Even where bulk water management and pricing are established, incentives are generally not passed to persons individually. Experience in China suggests that incentives to block managers or semi-private contractors may have the potential to redistribute collective gains and elicit improvements in collective management. Third, even if volumetric supply is possible at the farm level, in practice price incentives are predominantly used at the margin, to control use in excess of defined quotas or entitlements. Even in such cases, the option to resort to the second tier has to be cancelled sometimes when supply is insufficient (Capitanata, Neste). This gives users some flexibility, regardless of whether water is distributed by ‘arranged demand’ or is under the control of users, and provides incentives for water saving at the margin. However, allocation is always based on equitable 'reasonable use' quotas and falls short of both true on-demand irrigation and efficiency pricing. Fourth, systems with quotas, either at the individual or at the block level, generally deal with droughts and shortages by revising quotas downward. The frequency of such adjustments depends on the variability of the resource and on the total amount of water allocated relative to average supply, but since irrigation invariably receives a low priority in allocation this frequency increases as nonagricultural uses claim a larger share of the resource (Molle and Berkoff, 2006). It is only 1 year out of 10 in Japan but more frequent in Mexico or Jordan. In some cases, quotas can even be reduced to zero, as seen in the Zayandeh Rud basin (Iran) in 2001 (Molle et al., 2007). Fifth, reduction of quotas is generally done in a uniform manner across users. However, there are particular situations where some entitlements are less affected either because of economic reasons (e.g., trees vs. short-duration crops) or social reasons (areas with ancient water rights). This also shows that although they allow equity when defined uniformly, quotas may also integrate local perception of rights. In other words, even in the rare cases where water is scarce and where conditions are met to regulate demand through pricing, supply is invariably managed through administered quotas or water entitlements. None of the systems reviewed has used prices to raise pressure over users in order to crowd out underachievers and reduce demand according to available supply. This holds true for both the short term (seasonal shortages), and the longer term (conservation objectives). Reasons for the predominance of quotas include: their transparency; their ability to ensure equity when supply is inadequate (Tsur and Dinar, 1995); their administrative simplicity and relatively low transaction costs; their capacity for bringing water use directly in line with continuously varying available resources; and the more limited overall income loss incurred (as compared with price-based regulation). Indeed, regulation through prices would be tantamount to raising financial pressure on users in order to eliminate those who have less capacity and capital to adjust. In other words, if water supply is short of demand by, say, 30%, quotas consist in reducing every user’s supply by 30%, while regulation through prices consists of raising prices until the least "economically efficient" operators (who together make up 30% of the demand), are priced out. But raising prices also reduces the income of those who are more efficient and–when the fees accrue to the state–entails a transfer of wealth from farmers to public coffers, two consequences that are likely to face opposition. Latinopoulos' (2005) study of farmers' response to raised water prices in Greece found that elasticity corresponded with price levels which created serious income losses and observed that quotas are "a more natural and effective way" to obtain the same result with no dramatic reduction in income. Quota-based equity is also preferred because irrigation systems are socio-technical systems in which farmers are bound by a multitude of social ties and by their use of water, labor and other inputs. Whenever social relations are not too critically lopsided, equity is generally preferred to allocation to the higher bidder (unless water rights are linked to the initial investments in the system itself). However, there are exceptions to this rule, as illustrated by the well-known water markets in Valencia (Spain) (Maass and Anderson, 1978), which combine community-driven irrigation and auction of the available water in times of scarcity. In public irrigation, equity is understandingly preferred and promoted through quotas, partly because of a cultural inclination (e.g., in Japan: Kobayashi, 2006, or France: Tardieu and Préfol, 2002), partly because it is clearly the mechanism that encounters less opposition and minimizes political and transaction costs. Based on a worldwide review of irrigation pricing policies Cornish et al. (2004) concluded that "When water is scarce, the surest and most common way to make customers use less water is to limit supply;" this has indeed been the most favored solution for restraining demand (Bate, 2002). As stressed by Wichelns (1999), farmers respond to water rationing or changes in water allotments “by modifying crop choices and input decisions, just as they would respond to changes in explicit water prices:” since quotas fulfill the goal of curtailing demand and provide incentives to intensify agriculture, the additional benefits they provide in terms of formal equity and lesser economic impact on users help explain the prevalence of this regulation mechanism. But quotas also have their drawbacks (Chohin-Kuper et al., 2002; Bate, 2002). While price or market regulation tends to promote economic efficiency at the cost of equity (Okun, 1975), quotas (when nontransferable) foster equity at the cost of efficiency and can lack flexibility in response to changing circumstances, as in Israel. The Israeli case is instructive of the difficulty to readjust quotas once they have been defined and, at the same time, of the growing mismatch which can materialize between one village quota and its real use or needs (Plaut, 2000). The trajectories of kibbutzim and cooperatives depend not only on many factors, including ethnic composition, level of education, political linkages but also on the links to markets, the availability of nonagricultural opportunities, and the possible development of additional local resources (Lees, 1998). With time, some settlements (and some farmers within each settlement) tend to intensify agriculture, while others shift to partial farming. Resulting imbalances between quotas and needs have led to some inefficiency; in the 1980s, some farmers would irrigate carelessly so as to fully use their quota for fear of seeing it reduced (Lees, 1998) and trading within, as well as between, communities has emerged (Kislev, 2005). Quotas are also rarely adjusted to rebalance overall combined supply when the use of groundwater develops, as in Morocco, and they may hinder intensification, as in Jordan where citrus farmers are reluctant to shift to vegetables because their entitlements would be divided by two, with little hope of obtaining it again if they ever would like to revert to trees (Molle et al., 2008). While the Neste system in France has publicly known lists of subscribers with their entitlements, as well as waiting-lists of unserved users and clear rules (“young farmers,” ranking in the list, etc.) for selection of new beneficiaries when contracts are cancelled (Tardieu, 1999), these criteria may perhaps not be considered as fair by some users, while they also do not attempt to maximize economic return. Cases from Australia, Chile or western US have also shown that trading of entitlements solves the problem of quota 'stickiness' and of the limited potential of administered prices for reducing use and managing scarcity, while at the same time ensuring a better economic efficiency of water use. Such situations remain rare because there are several cultural, technical and institutional constraints to their development, most notably in developing countries (Livingston, 1995; Siamwalla and Roche, 2001; Colby, 1990; Gaffney, 1997). A combination of both desired priority principles and state-regulated transactions may address equity concerns while promoting efficient allocations (Seagraves and Easter, 1983; Bjornlund and McKay, 1999; Johansson et al., 2002). It is true that management of quotas cannot fully simulate the economic scarcity signals of a market price. But given the socioeconomic and practical constraints to, and the political costs of, promoting irrigation pricing for managing scarcity, the establishment of quotas (the ‘visible hand of scarcity’) appears a far more satisfactory and practical solution to water savings in almost all real-life circumstances (Molle and Berkoff, 2007). Even in Europe, where pricing is being strongly promoted, Garrido's (2002) review concluded that "irrigation pricing reforms should not expect significant reductions in farmers' water consumption" and that "efficient allocation can be made without prices." The virtues of rationing (in the short term) and/or the allocation of quotas (for long-term allocation) are getting more attention from the World Bank (2006) who reckoned that "quotas work better than prices when water users are not very responsive to water price changes." Bosworth et al. (2002) also concluded that "getting the prices right" is not the most appropriate solution to managing scarcity, while Dinar and Saleth (2005) reckoned that "The fact that efficient water pricing schemes are rare, if not completely absent, even in economically advanced regions with extreme water scarcity levels, provides sufficient evidence for the persistence of a vast gap between the development of pricing theory and its practical application. Use of pricing for rationing scarce water use is almost nonexistent." Conclusions This article has shown that the hopes vested in price-based regulation of the irrigation sector have been largely frustrated. Several factors explain why the economic rationale that applies to urban water supply is not valid in public surface irrigation schemes. Irrigation schemes are rarely demand based, losses largely lie beyond the responsibility of farmers, and management remains a central issue. In addition water charges are seldom proportional to volumetric use and, when this is the case, the range of prices acceptable -under or close to O&M costs- is usually too low to elicit water saving behaviours. A zoom on situations of water scarcity where irrigation schemes are able to distribute water volumetrically, either at the bulk or individual level, provided clear evidence that the definition of quotas is invariably chosen as a regulation mechanism. In contrast to the large theoretical literature that has promoted price-based regulation as a key instrument of water demand management, it appeared that prices were mostly used to regulate use at the margin, beyond the quota, rather than for rationing scarce water. This is certainly an important role but one that falls short of efficiency pricing and remains limited to those relatively rare schemes where water is supplied volumetrically, on demand or on arranged demand. Quotas may be subject to arbitrariness if their definition is not transparent and do not easily adapt to changing economic circumstances, incurring losses in overall economic efficiency. However, quotas were found to be consistently preferred to purely economic regulation for managing scarcity because they are more equitable, more transparent, and more efficient in putting demand in line with supply, with limited overall income loss compared with price-based regulation. These combined advantages explain why quotas are adopted as a mechanism to manage scarcity and curtail demand use. In sum, it is high time to reassess, in the light of empirical evidence, the hopes vested in price mechanisms for reducing water diversions. The objective of recovering O&M costs, however, remains paramount. References Ait Kadi, M. (2002). Irrigation water pricing policy in Morocco’s large scale irrigation projects. Hommes Terre & Eaux 32(124), 25-33. Altieri, S. (2001). Gestione tecnica ed administrative, in autogoverno, di un comprensorio irriguo pubblico. In: Leone, A., Basile, A. (Eds.), Proceedings of the trans-national workshop on ‘Managing Water Demand in Agriculture through Pricing: Research Issues and Lessons Learned.’ CNR (National Research Council), Ercolano, Italy, pp. 213-19. Asad, M., Azevedo, L.G., Kemper, K.E., Simpson, L.D. (1999). Management of water resources: bulk water pricing in Brazil. World Bank Technical Paper. World Bank, Washington, DC, USA. Bate, R. (2002). Water – can property rights and markets replace conflict? In: Morris, J. (Ed.), Sustainable Development: Promoting Progress or Perpetuating Poverty? Profile Books, London. Berbel, J., Lopez, M.J., Gomez Barbero, M. (2001). Survey of current institutional framework for water management in European irrigated systems: Spain. Report for the WADI Project. University of Cordoba, Spain. Bjornlund, H., McKay, J. (1999). Do water markets promote a socially equitable reallocation of water? A case study of a rural water market in Victoria, Australia. Paper Presentation, 6th Conference of the International Water and Resources Consortium, Hawaii. Bosworth, B., Cornish, G., Perry, C., van Steenbergen, F. (2002). Water charging in irrigated agriculture. Lessons from the literature. Report OD 145. HR Wallingford, Wallingford. Burt, C.M. (2002). Volumetric water pricing. Irrigation Training and Research Center, San Luis Obispo, California. Çakmak, B., Beyribey, M., Kodal, S. (2004). Irrigation water pricing in water user associations, Turkey. Water Resources Development 20(1), 113–124 Carruthers, I.D., Peabody, N.S.III, Bishop, A.A., LeBaron, A.D., Mehra, R., Ramchand, O., Peterson, D., Wood, D. H. (1985). Irrigation pricing and management. Report to USAID. DEVRES Inc., Washington, DC, 562 pp. Chohin-Kuper, A., Rieu, T., Montginoul, M. (2002). Economic tools for water demand management in the Mediterranean. Paper presented to the forum on ‘Progress in Water Demand Management in the Mediterranean’ Fiuggi, 3-5 Oct. 2002. Colby, B.G. (1990). Transactions costs and efficiency in western water allocation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72 (5), 1184-1192. Cosgrove, W., Rijsberman, F. (2000). World water vision: making water everybody’s business. Earthscan Publishers, London, 108 pp. Dinar, A., Maria Saleth, R. (2005). Issues in water pricing reforms: from getting correct prices to setting appropriate institutions. In: Folmer, H., Tietenberg, T. (Eds.), The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 2005/2006. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. Easter, K.W., Liu, Y. (2005). Cost recovery and water pricing for irrigation and drainage projects. Agriculture and Rural Development Discussion Paper No 20. World Bank, Washington, DC. El Gueddari, A.B.S. (2002). Système de tarification de l'eau d'irrigation au Maroc: principes et évolution. FAO Regional Office for the Near East, Cairo, Egypt. EU (2000). Pricing policies for enhancing the sustainability of water resources. Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament and the Economic and Social Committee (COM-2000. 477 final). European Union, Brussels. Feitelson, A. (2001). A retreat from centralized water management? The Israeli case. Paper presented to the 2nd IWHA Conference, Bergen, August 2001. Gaffney, G. (1997). What price water marketing? California's new frontier - Special Issue: Commemorating the 100th Anniversary of the Death of Henry George. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 56(4), 475-520. Garrido, A. (2002). Transition to Full-Cost Pricing of Irrigation Water for Agriculture in OECD Countries. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Environment Directorate, Paris. Hellegers, P., Perry, C., Petitguyot, T. (2007). Water pricing in Tadla, Morocco. In: Molle, F., Berkoff, J. (Eds.), Irrigation Water Pricing: The Gap Between Theory and Practice. Chapter 11. Comprehensive Assessment of Water Management in Agriculture. CABI, Wallingford, pp. 262-276. Hoogesteger, J.D. (2005). Making do with what we have: Understanding drought management strategies and their effects in the Zayandeh Rud Basin, Iran. MSc Thesis. Wageningen University. Howe, C.W. (1986). Innovations in water management: lessons from the Colorado-Big Thompson Project and the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, Chapter 6 In: Frederick, K.D. (Ed.), Scarce Water and Institutional Change. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC. Howe, C.W. (2003). The functions, impacts and effectiveness of water pricing: evidence from the United States and Canada, Mexico. In: Inter-American Development Bank (Ed.), Water Pricing and Public Private Partnership in the Americas. Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC, pp. 70-184. Howe, C.W., Goemans, C. (2003). Water transfers and their impacts: lessons from three Colorado water markets. Journal of the American Water Resources Association 39(5), 1055–65. 13. Hurand, P. (2001). La gestion opérationnelle d'un système hydrographique complexe: le Système Neste. Tarbes, France: Compagnie d’Aménagement des Coteaux de Gascogne. www.cacg.fr/pages/publi/pdf/Systeme%20Neste.pdf. Jean, M. (1999). Politique de tarification et application pratique: l’exemple du Canal de Provence. Paper presented at the conference ‘Pricing Water’ – Lisboa, Portugal, 6 et 7 Septembre 1999. Johansson, R.C., Tsur, Y., Roe, T.L., Doukkali, R., Dinar, A. (2002). Pricing irrigation water: a review of theory and practice. Water Policy 4(2), 173-199. Jourdain, D. (2004). Impact des politiques visant à réduire la consommation brute en eau des systèmes irrigués: Le cas des puits gérés par des collectifs de producteurs au Mexique. Unpublished PhD thesis. University of Montpellier I, Montpellier, France. Kislev, Y. (2001). The water economy in Israel. Prepared for the conference on ‘water in the Jordon Valley: Technical Solution & Regional Cooperation’ University of Oklahoma, International Programs Center, Center for Peace Studies, Norman, Oklahoma, Nov 13-14, 2001. Kislev, Y. (2005). Personal communication by email, 19/05/2005. Kloezen, W.H. (1998). Water markets between Mexican water user associations. Water Policy 1, 437-455. Kloezen, W.H. (2002). Accounting for water: institutional viability and impacts of market-oriented irrigation interventions in central Mexico. Ph.D thesis. Wageningen University, Wageningen, Netherlands. Kobayashi, H. (2006). Japanese water management systems from an economic perspective: the agricultural sector. In: OECD (Ed.), Water and Agriculture: Sustainability, Markets and Policies. OECD (Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development), Paris, pp. 121-136. Latinopoulos, P. (2005). Valuation and pricing of irrigation water: an analysis in Greek agricultural areas. Global NEST Journal 7 (3), 323-335. Lees, S.H. (1985). Differential water-use efficiency among Israeli small-scale farmers. 22p. Lees, S.H. (1998). The political ecology of the water crisis in Israel. University Press of America Inc. Lanham, MD, USA, 187 pp. Liao, Y., Gao, Z., Bao, Z., Huang, Q., Feng, G., Cai, J., Han, H., Wu, W. (2005). China’s water pricing reforms for irrigation: effectiveness and impact. Draft Research Report. Irrigation and Drainage Department, China Institute of Water Resources and Hydropower Research and International Water Management Institute, Beijing. Livingston, M.L. (1995). Designing water institutions: market failures and institutional response. Water Resources Management 9(3), 203-220. Lohmar, B., Lei, B., Huang, Q., Gao, Z. (2007). Water pricing policies and recent reforms in China: the conflict between conservation and other policy goals. In: Molle, F., Berkoff, J. (Eds.), Irrigation Water Pricing: The Gap Between Theory and Practice. Chapter 12. Comprehensive Assessment of Water Management in Agriculture. CABI, Wallingford, pp. 227-294. Maass, A., Anderson R.L. (1978). And the desert shall rejoice. Conflict, growth, and justice in arid environments. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Maestu, J. (2001). The political economy of the implementation of changes in pricing practices in Spain. What can we learn? In: European Commission (Ed.), Pricing Water. Economics, Environment and Society. Conference Proceedings, Sintra. European Commission, Brussels, pp. 247-67. Mariño, M., Kemper, K.E. (1999). Institutional frameworks in successful water markets. World Bank Technical Paper No. 427. World Bank, Washington, DC. Mastrorilli, M., Corona, P., de Seneen, G. (1997). Italy: the Capitanata irrigation scheme - experiences in water sustainability. In: OECD (Ed.), Workshop on the Sustainable Management of Water in Agriculture, The Athens Workshop, Case studies. OCDE, Paris, pp. 99-108. Molle, F, Venot J.P., Hassan, Y. (2008). Irrigation in the Jordan Valley: are water pricing policies overly optimistic? Agricultural Water Management 95(4): 427-438. Molle, F., Berkoff, J. (2007). Water pricing in irrigation: mapping the debate in the light of experience. In: Molle, F., Berkoff, J. (Eds.), Irrigation Water Pricing: The Gap Between Theory and Practice. Chapter 2. Comprehensive Assessment of Water Management in Agriculture. CABI, Wallingford, pp. 21-93. Molle, F., Berkoff, J. (2006). Cities versus agriculture: revisiting intersectoral water transfers, potential gains and conflicts. IWMI Comprehensive Assessment Research Report 10. IWMI Comprehensive Assessment Secretariat, Colombo, Sri Lanka. Molle, F., Hoogesteger, J., Mamanpoush, A. (2007). Macro and micro-level impacts of droughts: the case of the Zayandeh Rud River Basin, Iran. Irrigation and Drainage 57, 1-9. Montginoul, M., Rieu, T. (2001). Irrigation water pricing reforms and implementing procedures: Experience acquired in Charente and in Morocco. In: European Commission (Ed.), Pricing Water. Economics, Environment and Society. Conference Proceedings, Sintra. European Commission, Brussels, pp. 256-67. Okun, A.M. (1975). Equality and efficiency: the big tradeoff. The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC. Pike, T. (2005). Agricultural water conservation program review. Internal Report South East Kelowna Irrigation District. Kelowna, Canada. Plaut, S. (2000). Water policy in Israel. Institute for Advanced Strategic and Political Studies, Washington, DC. Postel, S. (1992). Last oasis: facing water scarcity. W.W. Norton & Co., New York. Repetto, R. (1986). Skimming the water: rent seeking and the performance of public irrigation systems. Research Report 4. World Resource Institute, Washington, DC. Seagraves, J.A., Easter, K.W. (1983). Pricing irrigation water in developing countries, Water Resources Bulletin 4, 663-671. Shevah, Y., Kohen, G. (1997). Economic considerations for water used in irrigation in Israel. In: Kay, M., Franks, T., Smith, L. (Eds.), Water: Economics, Management and Demand. E & FN Spon, London, UK, pp. 2936. Siamwalla, A., Roche, F. (2001). Irrigation management under resource scarcity. In: Siamwalla, A. (Ed.), The Evolving Roles of the State, Private, and Local Actors in Rural Asia. Study of Rural Asia. Oxford University Press, Hongkong, pp. 183-212. Tardieu, H. (1999). Agriculture irriguée, gestion de l’eau et développement territorial. Tarbes, France: Compagnie d’Aménagement des Coteaux de Gascogne. http://www.cacg.fr Tardieu, H., Préfol, B. (2002). Full cost or ‘sustainability cost’ pricing in irrigated agriculture: Charging for water can be effective, but is it sufficient? Irrigation and Drainage 51 (2), 97-107. Tiwari, D.N., Dinar, A. (2001). Role and use of economic incentives in irrigated agriculture. Working Paper. World Bank, Washington, DC. Tsur, J. (2004). Introduction to special section on irrigation water pricing. Water Resource Research 40(7), 1-9. Turral, H.N., Etchells, T., Malano, H.M.M., Wijedasa, H.A., Taylor, P., McMahon, T.A.M., Austin, N. (2004). Water trading at the margin: the evolution of water markets in the Murray Darling Basin. Water Resources Research 41(7), 1-8. Vos, J.M.C. (2002). Metrics matters: the performance and organization of volumetric water control in large-scale irrigation in the north coast of Peru. PhD thesis. Wageningen University, Wageningen. Wichelns, D. (1999). Economic efficiency in irrigation water policy with an example from Egypt. International Journal of Water Resources Development 15(4), 542-560. Wichelns, D. (2003). Experience in implementing economic incentives to conserve water and improve environmental quality in the Broadview Water District, California. The World Bank, Washington, DC. Wichelns, D., Houston, L., Cone, D. (1996). Economic incentives reduce irrigation deliveries and drain water Volume. Irrigation and Drainage Systems 10, 131-141. Winpenny, J. (1994). Managing water as an economic resource. development policies studies. Routledge and Overseas Development Institute, London, 133 pp. World Bank (1986). World Bank lending conditionality: a review of cost recovery in irrigation projects. Report No 6283. Operations Evaluation Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. World Bank (2003). World Bank water resources sector strategy: strategic directions for World Bank engagement. World Bank, Washington, DC. World Bank (2006). Reengaging in agricultural water management: challenges, opportunities, and trade-offs. Water for Food Team, Agriculture and Rural Development Department (ARD). World Bank, Washington, DC. WWF (2002). Pricing as a tool to reduce water demand. WWF-Spain/ADENA's ‘Alcobendas: water city for the 21st century’ - a demonstration project. http://www.panda.org/downloads/europe/pricing2.pdf Yang, H., Zhang, X., Zehnder, A.J.B. (2003). Water scarcity, pricing mechanism and institutional reform in northern China irrigated agriculture. Agricultural Water Management 61, 143-161. Yercan, M. (2003). Management turning-over and participatory management of irrigation schemes: a case study of the Gediz River basin in Turkey. Agricultural Water Management 62, 205-214.