THE EFFECTIVENESS OF ALCOHOL CONTROL POLICY IN
SOUTH AFRICA:
ESTIMATING THE PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND FOR
ALCOHOL
ABSTRACT:
Alcohol control policy is a topical issue in South Africa, as new measures to further
restrict the consumption of alcohol are being considered. This study examines the
possible effectiveness of increases in excise taxes on alcohol as one such measure.
Using an empirical analysis, the study considers the price elasticity of demand for
alcohol among different groups of consumers in South Africa. The results suggest that
demand for alcohol is inelastic, particularly for heavy drinkers. While alcohol is found to
be an inferior good, different income groups are not found to have a significantly
different price elasticity of demand. Furthermore, lowincome, heavydrinking
households are found to be the least responsive to changes in the price of alcohol.
THE EFFECTIVENESS OF ALCOHOL CONTROL POLICY IN SOUTH AFRICA:
ESTIMATING THE PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND FOR ALCOHOL
1. Introduction
The effectiveness of alcohol control policy is a discussion worth noting in South Africa’s
present context. As efforts are made to reevaluate the role that alcohol abuse plays in
our society, it is equally important to evaluate the potential effectiveness of any policies
that would seek to discourage the abusive consumption of alcohol.
The damaging effect that alcohol plays in South Africa is a broadly discussed issue. It is
continually noted that alcohol plays a significant role in the number and the severity of
the crimes committed in our country; alcohol is a major catalyst in domestic violence in
our homes; a concerning proportion of the accidents that take place on South African
roads are attributed to alcohol, and many diseases are caused by heavy drinking, for
which South Africa is widely noted (Parry, 2012; World Health Organisation, 2011).
Because of the social and medical problems that alcohol presents to our society, there
have been calls to increase the scope and stringency of alcohol control policy, in order
to discourage heavy drinking. Among other suggestions for discouraging heavy
consumption, such as imposing restrictions on the advertising of alcohol and reviewing
the age limit for drinking in the country, one popular suggestion is raising excise taxes
to increase the price of alcohol. Economic theory suggests that raising the price of
alcohol would cause a fall in consumption of alcohol; however, this relies on the critical
assumption that the demand for alcohol among drinkers is sufficiently sensitive to
changes in price. Another assumption that this policy suggests is that an increase in the
price of alcohol will affect all drinkers similarly enough such that even heavy drinkers, at
whom the policy is aimed, will be induced to consume less alcohol.
This paper seeks to investigate the relationship between the price of alcohol and its
consumption; in particular, it seeks to investigate whether a price increase will induce a
substantial decrease in alcohol consumption among heavy drinkers. To do this, this
paper seeks to analyse whether there are differences in the price elasticity of demand
among different groups of the South African population. In particular, it will analyse
whether persons of lower incomes have the same sensitivity to the price of alcohol as
persons of higher incomes. This will help in answering the question of whether the
increase in excise taxes is an effective policy move, and if it exhibits the same
effectiveness for all groups of the population.
This paper will proceed as follows. Firstly, it will explore the existing literature on alcohol
policy and the effectiveness of various tools in reducing alcohol consumption. It will then
present the methodology which will be followed in the present study, as well as a
discussion on the data set that will be used for the study. Thereafter, the findings of the
study will be presented, followed by conclusions drawn from these findings.
2. Alcohol Control Policy In The Literature
The problems associated with alcohol consumption are welldocumented in the
literature. These economic costs of alcohol consumption can be classified either as the
social costs that abusive drinking produces through its negative externalities, or the
individual costs borne by drinkers themselves. Odejide (2006) discusses the societal
cost of abusive drinking in the African context, particularly when undertaken by the youth,
as involving an increase in vehicular accidents, reckless sexual behaviour and violence.
Other social costs associated with problem drinking include loss of employment, marital
disharmony and domestic violence (Odejide, 1978). Therefore, excessive alcohol
consumption is argued to impose a burden not only to those who engage in abusive
drinking, but to society in general.
Alcohol also presents a disease burden to society that is equal to that imposed by
tobacco globally. Room et al. (2005) find that alcohol is causally related to more than
sixty medical conditions. This includes cirrhosis of the liver, haemorrhagic stroke, breast
and liver cancer, and neurological conditions such as epilepsy. Alcohol abuse is also
associated with unintentional injuries such as poisoning and homicide. Moreover, Rehm
and his colleagues (2009b) find that approximately 6.3% of all disabilityadjusted life
years were lost due to alcoholattributable causes. Of these deaths, 16.12% were due
to HIV/AIDS. Indeed, Parry, et al. (2010) review the relationship between alcohol
consumption and the progression of HIV infected patients and show through the
literature that there is evidence suggesting that alcohol consumption worsens the
disease course of HIV/AIDS, shortening the lifespan of HIV positive individuals.
The various problems associated with the excessive consumption of alcohol have
prompted the development of an extensive body of literature on the demand for alcohol
and how different measures of public policy can affect this demand to reduce abusive
drinking. In particular, Fogarty (2006) suggests that in order for public policy to be
effective in reducing the economic cost of alcohol abuse, the nature of alcohol demand
must be understood. That is, in order to reduce the economic cost of alcohol abuse, the
levels of drinking among consumers and the sensitivity of the demand for alcohol must
be understood.
One view of alcohol demand among consumers holds that there is a fundamental
difference between normal drinking behaviour that may be associated with general
levels of consumption, and problematic drinking behaviour that presents a cost to
society. In their study of the nature of alcoholism, Taylor and Helzer (1983), Vaillant and
HillerSturmhöfel (1996) and Vaillant (1983) all treat alcoholism as a psychological
disorder with genetic and environmental causes, which implies a qualitative difference
between normal drinking behaviour and the heavy drinking that characterises
alcoholism.
An opposing view holds that all social drinking behaviour may be modelled on a
continuum of increasing levels of consumption. Ledermann’s hypothesis (1956), the
basis for a significant portion of research on the distribution of alcohol consumption,
models alcohol consumption as a lognormal distribution. This model relies only on
mean consumption; it views excessive drinking as closely connected to the mean
consumption, such that a high prevalence of excessive drinking is associated with a
relatively high mean level of consumption. Therefore, Ledermann’s model views the
entire population as being at risk of exposure to the negative consequences associated
with alcohol. Lemmens (1993) studied this suggested regularity in the distribution of
alcohol consumption, and its implication that a decrease in the average per capita
consumption would result in lower economic costs associated with alcohol
consumption. Lemmens finds that the regularity in the distribution of consumption is
supported by findings in empirical studies, and suggests that this has implications for
who in the distribution is targeted by public policy to discourage excessive drinking in
the population as a whole. In particular, this implies that a policy that successfully
reduces the mean level of alcohol consumption will effectively reduce consumption
among excessive drinkers and thus reduce the economic costs of alcohol abuse.
Duffy (1993) also investigated Ledermann’s hypothesis of a lognormal distribution of
the consumption of alcohol. He finds that the literature based on Ledermann’s
contribution suggests that since the proportion of heavy drinkers is an increasing
function of mean consumption, policy aimed at reducing mean consumption will
effectively reduce the number of heavy drinkers and thus alcoholrelated problems. Duffy
suggests that if consumption does not have a lognormal distribution, this effect will not
hold and any blanket policy that seeks to decrease per capita consumption will be
ineffective in reducing the economic costs of alcohol abuse. This assertion points to the
development of an alcohol control policy that will target the demand for alcohol among
heavy drinkers in particular, rather than a blanket policy which will prove to be ineffective
if consumption does not have a lognormal distribution.
Various policy measures have been suggested in order to control the consumption of
alcohol. These include restrictions on the availability of alcohol, education programmes
on its harmful effects, restrictions on advertising and increased excise taxes on alcohol
(Dejong, 1997). Toomey and Wagenaar (1999) also discuss some policy measures
that can be used to reduce the risk of alcohol problems by changing the way in which
alcohol is marketed and sold. These measures can be classified either as
individuallevel programmes or institutional policies; the policy implemented would
depend on the type of drinking behaviour. Many have called for the restriction on the
advertising of alcohol, in particular, as alcohol marketing has been argued to cause an
increase in the consumption of the youth (Kessler, 2005), a group at high risk of alcohol
abuse. An increase in excise taxes in order to increase the real cost of alcohol has
been of particular interest in the literature, and this policy measure faces less opposition
from the alcohol industry than restrictions on alcohol marketing (Nelson, 2010; Kessler,
2005).
The effectiveness of policy implementation in the reduction of alcohol intake has been a
subject of interest in the literature. In particular, many have studied the impact of excise
taxes on the demand for alcohol among different groups in the population (e.g. Gallet,
2007). Manning et al. (1995), for instance, investigated the price sensitivity of light,
moderate and heavy drinkers in order to evaluate the impact of excise taxes on alcohol
among these groups. Manning et al argue that since the economic costs associated
with alcohol come from heavy drinking in particular, and not from light or moderate
drinking, an effective policy mix will discourage excessive alcohol use rather than all
consumption of alcohol. They find that the demand for alcohol of heavy drinkers is less
responsive to a change in price than the demand of lighter drinkers. Therefore, a policy
that seeks to reduce alcohol consumption will not necessarily have the same effects on
all members of the drinking population. Saffer and Chaloupka (1998) also noted the
variation in response to alcohol policy according to demographic differences, and they
analysed the demand for alcohol in China, to see whether the price sensitivity of
drinkers would be similar to that of drinkers in developed countries. They find that price
elasticity in China is very small compared to the elasticity in developed countries, and
suggest that alcohol tax increases alone would be ineffective as a control policy in that
country.
Further study in this field may seek to analyse the ownprice elasticity of demand for
alcohol among South African drinkers in particular, and the variation among beer, wine
and spirits. Furthermore, it may analyse the variation in the ownprice elasticity of
demand for alcohol among types of drinkers, as this may have serious consequences
for the policy mix implemented to reduce alcohol abuse. The purpose of this paper is to
analyse this variation in demand among income groups in South Africa.
3. Methods
The methodology we proceed with is an adaptation of the study on the demand for
alcohol as conducted by Manning, Blumberg and Moulton (1995). We maintain the
essential procedures that they undertake with their data, allowing for certain variations
that will make the analysis more appropriate to South Africa, and observe whether
South African data will provide similar results to those of the Michigan data used by
Manning et al (1995). We make a further departure from the Manning et al. study to
accommodate our use of unit values to estimate elasticities, whereas Manning et al.
used Tobit regressions.
The main concern in this study is the sensitivity of alcohol consumption to changes in
price. In particular, we want to compare price elasticities of alcohol consumption among
different groups of consumers. In order to do this, we define four distinct income groups
from the data as well as three different levels of drinking. We use Cox and Klinger’s
(1988) definition of light drinking as up to 432 standard drinks per annum, moderate
drinking as between 432 and 792 drinks per annum, and heavy drinking as at least 792
drinks per annum. These definitions of the different levels of drinking are particularly
appropriate for use in this study, as the data set measures consumption in standard
drinks rather than alcohol content.
Before proceeding with defining a model with which to analyse the data, we recognise
that the study involves the twofold issue of the initial decision to drink and then the
quantity of alcohol to consume once the individual has decided to drink. This is of
particular relevance in this present study of South African data, as about twothirds of
the adult population are not drinkers (World Health Organisation, 2011). Ignoring the
determinants of the decision to drink will lead to unreliable results. We run a logistic
regression equation to determine the main determinants of the initial decision to drink.
Of particular interest are the socioeconomic differences that occur between those who
choose to drink and abstainers.
We then turn our attention to the issue of the sensitivity of alcohol consumption among
the subset of the population who chooses to drink. NIDS data poses a challenge for the
present study in that it does not contain any information on prices faced by households
and individuals. Instead, households are requested to answer questions regarding their
monthly expenditure on different household consumable goods, amongst others,
alcohol. Furthermore, individuals are asked questions regarding their weekly
consumption of alcohol. We therefore implement a method to impute a proxy price of
alcohol based on the quantity and expenditure data, in order for us to derive meaningful
elasticity estimates.
In order to tackle the matter of missing price information in survey data, Deaton (1988)
proposes a method of estimating the unit value of goods that respondents face. The
method requires that the survey data is gathered in several clustered households such
that we control for measurement error, and so that there is sufficient variation in unit
values between the clusters. If this is the case, then Deaton suggests that we compute
the unit value of household purchases as follows:
v=
total expenditure
physical quantity
The problem with the unit value is that it is not the same as price. Unit values are
affected by the actual market prices that consumers face and the quality of purchases.
Because consumers who purchase highquality items will also have higher unit values,
unit values are not exogenous, as they are chosen, and they are therefore likely to be
correlated with income. Furthermore, because they are computed from data reported by
respondents, unit values are prone to measurement error.
Deaton proposes a methodology that accounts for the endogeneity of unit values and
thus allows for the use of unit values in regressions. First, we estimate the unit value v;
we then compute an average unit value across each cluster in order to control for
measurement error, such that each household in a given cluster faces the same unit
value. We write the unit value and alcohol quantity functions as follows:
ln vhc = α1 +
1
lnxhc +
lnqhc = α0 +
n
1
1
lnnhc + ∑ ζj( nj ) + uhc
xlnxhc +
j
0
Z hc + f c + uhc
where vhc is the unit value of alcohol purchased by household h in cluster c; qhc is the
quantity of alcohol consumed by household h in cluster c; xhc is the total household
expenditure of household h in cluster c; nhc is the household size of household h in
cluster c, and the ratio
nj
n
is a control for the proportion of adults in the household; Z hc is
a vector of the sociodemographic characteristics of the household; f c is the
clusterspecific fixed effect and the uhc is the idiosyncratic error of the household. When
we estimate the above equations we obtain the coefficients
1
and
x,
elasticity of expenditure with respect to the household unit value, and
1
where
x
is the
is the elasticity
of household expenditure on alcohol with respect to the quantity of alcohol consumed.
We then construct the following equations:
y0c = lnqhc −
y1c = lnvc −
xlnxhc
1
xhc
where we have taken averages such that the equation y0c represents the average cluster
quantity and equation y1c represents the average cluster unit value. These equations
allow us to estimate the effect of market price on consumption because they contain
quantities and unit values that have been stripped of the effect of household
expenditure. Therefore, if we regress y0c on y1c we will obtain estimate of the price
elasticity of demand for alcohol that we can use for the intended purposes in this study
(Deaton, 1997).
Before we use the above methodology to obtain elasticities, we perform a oneway
analysis of variance test to determine the variation of unit values between the clusters.
TABLE I : Analysis
of Variance Test
for Household
Clusters
Source of Variation
Within Groups
SS
18067620193
5
10432164585
7
1
3165
4
Total
28499784779
2
3165
5
Between Groups
df
MS
18067620193
5
F
5482
2
Pvalu
e
F
crit
0
4
3295686
Table I reports the results of the ANOVA test for spatial variation between household
clusters. The Fscore for the test is highly significant, such that we can proceed using
Deaton’s unit values in our analysis.
Another matter of interest is the regression that will be used in the study. Because many
observations in the sample will report a zero quantity value if they do not consume
alcohol, the alcohol consumption problem will have a corner solution. This results in a
violation of the assumption of normality in the distribution of the data, as the variable
quantity will take on the value zero with a positive probability. An appropriate model to
use in this case would be the Tobit model developed by Tobin (1958), as it deals well
with truncated or censored data, and has been used widely in studies of limited
dependent variables (Mroz, 1987; Austin, Escobar & Kopec, 2000; Bellemare &
Barrett, 2006). However, as Deaton (1997) explains, the unit values we use in this study
can only be derived in the specific method outlined by Deaton (1988), such that we are
restricted to the use of OLS in our study. Although this represents a problem for the
unbiasedness of our estimates, it is still arguably our best alternative to derive reliable
estimates of demand elasticity.
Having obtained a method of estimating meaningful price elasticities, we proceed with
the following regressions. First, we run a conditional OLS regression for those
respondents who are drinkers, which we compare with Tobit regressions featuring
similar regressors; this will allow us to say something about the effect that the initial
decision to drink has on elasticity estimates of those respondents who choose to drink
alcohol. Secondly, we run another conditional OLS regression, this time including
interaction terms between the unit value of alcohol and income; this will allow us to say
something about whether there are differences in the elasticities of alcohol demand
among different income groups. Thirdly, we run a conditional OLS regression including
the interaction terms between the level of drinking of a consumer and the unit value of
alcohol that they face. Finally, we include interaction terms between the level of drinking
of the consumer and their income, to establish if something can be said about the
relative elasticities of these groups.
4. Data
The primary data source is Wave 1 of the National Income Dynamics Study (NIDS) of
2008. This survey was completed by 7 503 households from different parts of the
country. It features a broad set of information on each household’s expenditure, income,
and demographic composition, as well as information on the individuals in each
household. This makes NIDS data particularly suitable for the present use of estimating
various elasticities, as it features information on much of the behaviour we would like to
observe. Although Wave 2 of 2012 of the study is also available, we make use of Wave
1 because it is more representative of the population, as it is not subject to attrition like
Wave 2.
Table II reports the summary statistics of selected variables in the Wave 1 data set,
where the base group that has been selected is white males from an urban area. We
use survey weights that are specific to the data set to ensure that the sample is
representative of the population. We construct the quantity, family size, rural, log of unit
value and monthly household income variables at a household level. The remainder of
the variables are defined at an individual level.
TABLE II
MEANS OF THE DATA
Of particular importance is the construction of the quantity variable. In the survey,
respondents are asked to respond to questions concerning their drinking behaviour,
such as how often they drink, and the number of drinks they consume when they drink
alcohol. These variables about the frequency and intensity of consumption were
aggregated at a household level. Although this results in a loss of precision concerning
the behaviour of each respondent, it allows us to construct the unit value of alcohol that
the household faces.
As is expected from the World Health Organisation’s report on alcohol consumption in
South Africa (World Health Organisation, 2011), only approximately 24% of the
respondents in the survey state that they consume alcohol. We find that the average
number of drinks consumed per household is 368 per annum, which may be considered
as light consumption of alcohol; however, among the respondents who are drinkers, the
average number of drinks consumed per annum is 1 013, which is considered heavy
consumption.
Another variable of interest is religion. The survey asks respondents what their religious
affiliation is, if any, and the importance of religious activities in their lives. This is used to
construct the religion variable, which is unity if religious activities are either important or
very important to the respondent, and zero otherwise. In the sample, 89% of
respondents consider religious activities as significant to them, which corresponds to
previous findings that religion is a significant social factor in South Africa (Garner, 1998,
2000). The high number of abstainers in South Africa can be partially attributed to the
importance of religion in society as Islam and certain Christian denominations prohibit
the consumption of alcohol.
Because NIDS data is survey data, however, it is subject to certain imperfections that
present challenges to the present analysis. Firstly, the data contains missing information
for some variables where respondents either do not know, cannot recall or refuse to
answer the question about the matter at hand. This results in fewer observations, which
is a problem of varying degree across the variables. Furthermore, the missing
information limits the extent to which we can make manipulations to the data in order to
say something interesting about certain aspects of the respondents’ behaviour, as it
affects the reliability of the study. For instance, although the data set contains 3 982
households where at least one resident is a current drinker, only 1 495 households
indicate that they spend money on alcohol. Additionally, because the data collection
process relies on responses from the participating households, NIDS data is prone to
measurement error. Information on subjects such as the respondents’ incomes and
expenditures rely on the recall of the respondents, which is prone to recall bias.
Nevertheless, because of the large sample size and the use of methods such as
Deaton’s unit values, NIDS data will still allow us to analyse consumer behaviour in a
comprehensive manner.
NIDS data features information on whether an individual drinks alcohol, and in the event
that they are a current drinker, how much they usually drink. This allows us to observe
the two dependent variables of interest, namely the decision to consume alcohol and
the quantity of alcohol consumed. Furthermore, the data allows us to create a
comprehensive set of independent variables that allow us to explain what determines
the decision to drink, and the sensitivity of alcohol consumption to various
characteristics of the individual. This will enable us to make comparisons between the
sensitivity of alcohol consumption of individuals with different characteristics.
5. Empirical Results
5.1 The drinking decision
We first analyse the determinants of the decision to drink, and secondly the
determinants of the quantity of alcohol consumed, given that an individual drinks. To do
this, we first run a logistic regression in which the dependent variable is consumption,
and we use a set of regressors that is similar to that of Manning et al. We adjust the
education variables such that they better represent the education levels in South Africa;
we adjust the race groups to reflect South African racial groups and we change the
geographical regions to make them relevant to South Africa. We also add an indicator
variable, religion, that is equal to unity when the respondent considers themselves
religious, and zero otherwise.
The Logit column of Table III reports the results of the logistic consumption equation. We
run this regression at the individual level, such that the female, age, race and religion
variables are all at the individual level. The family size, rural, and household income
variables are all at the household level, as well as the unit value variable, which is
common within each cluster. We report the marginal effects of the equation, where the
base group that has been selected is white males from an urban area with a tertiary
education and no religious affiliation.
We note that female respondents are significantly less likely to drink alcohol than male
respondents, while the coefficient on the age variable is positive such that older
respondents are more likely to consume alcohol. The quadratic variable for age is
significant and has a negative coefficient, such that the effect of age on the probability
of drinking is reversed at the age of 50. Interestingly, the possession of some high
school education until at least Grade 11 causes a significant reduction in the probability
of drinking, more so than the possession of a Grade 12 education.
Black respondents are less likely to consume alcohol than white respondents, as are
Indian and Coloured respondents. We also find that the religion variable is negative and
statistically significant, such that religious respondents are 14% less likely to consume
alcohol than those who are not religious. We note that the Christian and Muslim
affiliations result in respondents being less likely to drink.
TABLE III
THE DRINKING DECISION AND CORE REGRESSION
Independent Variable
Base
Female
Male
Age
Black
Coloured
Indian
Religion
Christian
Muslim
Hindu
Jewish
Traditional
ln (Income)
Family Size
ln(Income).family size
Grade 7
Grade 11
Grade 12
Rural
Logit
0.166***
(0.021)
0.014***
(0.001)
White
0.329***
(0.025)
White
0.145***
(0.012)
White
0.157***
(0.17)
No religion 0.140***
(0.17)
No
0.048**
affiliation
(0.015)
No
0.179***
affiliation
(0.013)
No
0.065
affiliation
(0.067)
No
0.067
affiliation
(0.082)
No
0.067***
affiliation
(0.017)
0.058*
(0.028)
0.059***
(0.012)
0.006***
(0.002)
Tertiary
0.050**
(0.016)
Tertiary
0.066***
(0.014)
Tertiary
0.029
(0.015)
Urban
0.038***
Conditional
OLS
Tobit
0.168
(0.253)
0.001
(0.006)
0.094
(0.112)
0.198
(0.13)
0.08
(0.27)
0.188*
(0.083)
0.498*
(0.227)
0.005
(0.005)
0.062
(0.114)
0.069
(0.131)
0.112
(0.289)
0.195*
(0.087)
0.832*
(0.025)
0.076
(0.076)
0.020*
(0.01)
0.206
90.123)
0.075
(0.114)
0.071
(0.117)
0.262***
0.113*
(0.052)
0.071
(0.059)
0.015*
(0.008)
0.141
(0.124)
0.094
(0.118)
0.061
(0.123)
0.231***
Western Cape
Limpopo
Eastern Cape
Limpopo
Northern Cape
Limpopo
Free State
Limpopo
KwazuluNatal
Limpopo
NorthWest
Limpopo
Gauteng
Limpopo
Mpumalanga
Limpopo
log of Unit Value
ln(Income).ln(unit
value)
N
* p<0.05, ** p<0.01,
*** p<0.001
(0.009)
0.167***
(0.028)
0.105***
(0.024)
0.150***
(0.03)
0.179***
(0.03)
0.035
(0.019)
0.175***
(0.026)
0.095***
(0.025)
0.105***
(0.027)
0.056*
(0.027)
(0.057)
0.382**
(0.128)
0.236
(0.135)
0.283*
(0.137)
0.206
(0.143)
0.112
(0.126)
0.467***
(0.133)
0.119
(0.133)
0.148
(0.145)
0.832**
(0.17)
(0.048)
0.293**
(0.105)
0.142
(0.109)
0.099
(0.111)
0.092
(0.115)
0.072
(0.098)
0.248*
(0.105)
0.04
(0.11)
0.076
(0.115)
0.463**
(0.147)
0.007
0.029
0.017
(0.004)
13489
(0.022)
3484
(0.019)
6241
We note that the coefficient on the unit value of alcohol is negative and significant. This
suggests that the price of alcohol that the individual is faced with in the market has a
negative effect on their decision to drink, such that a 10% increase in the market price
will result in the individual being 0.58% less likely to consume alcohol. We also note that
the coefficient on the income of the household is negative, such that individuals with
higher incomes are less likely to consume alcohol. This finding is of value for the
present study, because it suggests that individuals with lower incomes may indeed be
more reliant on alcohol than those with higher incomes.
Finally, the coefficient on the family size variable is negative, such that respondents from
larger households are less likely to drink. The interaction term between family size and
household income, however, is positive. This means that an increase in income for an
individual from a larger household will reduce the probability of drinking less than for a
respondent from a smaller household, all else equal. This effect of household size on the
probability of drinking could be a result of poverty: larger households tend to have lower
incomes, such that individuals from larger households may not be able to afford to drink.
However, for those individuals who come from larger households, an increase in
income will have a smaller effect in reducing their probability of drinking, as the income
must be spread across more household members. While this finding suggests that poor
individuals are more likely to consume alcohol, a regression of the quantity of alcohol
consumed on income is necessary in order to draw inference on whether poverty results
in higher consumption of alcohol.
5.2 Core OLS Regression
In order to analyse the effect that variables such as income have on the demand for
alcohol, we estimate the alcohol consumption equation. In this equation, the variable of
interest is the log of alcohol quantity consumed, while a set of regressors similar to
those used by Manning et al. is used as explanatory variables. Unlike Manning et al.,
however, the consumption equation is analysed at the household level instead of the
individual level. This is done because NIDS data contains most of the variables of
interest, such as expenditures and household income, at the household level rather than
the individual level. For the individuallevel characteristics such as gender and age, we
assign the entire household with the characteristics of the household head. We define
the base group in the regression as white households with a male head who has a
tertiary education, residing in an urban area in Limpopo.
In Table III we compare the findings of the conditional OLS regression with that of the
Tobit regression. We find that, although the partial effects on the quantity of alcohol
consumed differ between the two methods, both regressions have the same significant
variables and the same signs on their coefficients. If the partial effects are significantly
different then the OLS coefficients suffer from sample selection bias, such that they will
be unreliable estimates. In order to test for sample selection bias, we use the Heckman
twostage model, and find that the coefficient on λ is highly significant. This suggests
that sample selection bias indeed is a problem in this equation; however, because
Deaton specifies the unit value method using OLS, we proceed using conditional OLS
rather than the Tobit model.
In the core regression of the consumption equation, we note that although gender and
age are significant determinants in the initial decision to drink, they have an insignificant
effect on the quantity of alcohol consumed once the respondent chooses to drink. In the
Tobit model of the core regression, however, the presence of a female household head
has a significant, negative effect on the quantity of alcohol that the household consumes.
The geographic location of the household is found to have a significant effect on the
quantity of alcohol that it consumes. Rural households are found to drink significantly
less than urban households. While other provinces are found to have no significant
effect on consumption, households from the Northern Cape, the Western Cape and
NorthWest Province are found to drink significantly more than the base group. This is
an unsurprising, as there is evidence suggesting particularly high levels of alcohol
abuse in the Western Cape and Northern Cape (Freeman, Parry, 2006).
Household income is found to have a significant effect on the level of household alcohol
consumption. The income elasticity of demand is negative and inelastic, such that a
given increase in income will result in a smaller reduction in the quantity of alcohol
consumed. This result differs from that of the study done by Manning et al. (1995), who
find that income elasticity is inelastic and positive. At the mean log of unit value and
family size, a 10% increase in income will result in a 6.93% reduction in alcohol
consumed. This suggests that alcohol is an inferior good. The interaction between
income and unit value, which measures whether the price elasticity of demand differs
with the level of household income, is found to be insignificant in the core regression.
This suggests that the responsiveness of alcohol demand to changes in the price of
alcohol does not significantly depend on the level of household income.
Interestingly, while family size has a negative effect on the probability of drinking is no
longer a significant determinant on the quantity consumed once the respondent
chooses to drink. Income is also found to be an insignificant determinant of the quantity
consumed. When the two variables are interacted with each other, however, we find the
variable to be significant. For two respondents who start off with the same household
income, with one respondent belonging to a large household and the other belonging to
a small household, a given increase in household income will increase the quantity
consumed more for the respondent from a larger household than the one from a smaller
household. As with the effect on the initial decision to drink, this may suggest that
respondents from poorer households appropriate an increasing share of their income to
alcohol consumption, however, this hypothesis would need to be tested directly.
We also note that the coefficient on unit value is negative and significant, such that an
increase in the unit value of alcohol will result in a decrease in the quantity of alcohol
consumed. We compute the price elasticity of demand at the mean log of household
income and find that a 10% increase in unit value will result in a 5.98% reduction in
quantity consumed, such that the demand for alcohol is price inelastic. Of particular
interest in the study will be whether this elasticity differs among light, moderate and
heavy drinkers, as well as across different levels of household income.
5.3 Demand elasticity by level of drinking
We now consider whether the price elasticity of demand for alcohol differs among
different levels of consumption. We define two indicator variables for moderate and
heavy consumption, such that the base group is light drinkers. In order to test whether
the price elasticity of demand is significantly different across the different levels of
consumption, we interact the unit value of alcohol with the indicator variables for level of
consumption, and include these in the core regression. The sum of the coefficients on
the interaction term and the log of unit value variable is then the price elasticity of
demand for that level of consumption. When included in the core regression, the
interaction terms are found to be significant and positive. Because the coefficient on the
log of unit value is negative while the coefficient on these variables is positive,
moderate and heavy drinkers are less responsive to changes in the price of alcohol,
such that their demand is more inelastic. These findings are similar to those of Manning
et al.’s study, where moderate and heavy drinkers were also found to have more price
inelastic demand than light drinkers.
Specification 1 in Table IV reports the results for the regression that includes all the
variables in the core regression, and the interaction terms between level of consumption
and the log of unit value. We note that household income remains a significant
determinant of the quantity of consumption, such that an increase in income will result in
a decrease in quantity consumed. Family size is also significant and negative, such that
an increase in household size has a similar effect to an increase in household income.
Furthermore, the interaction between family size and household income remains
significant.
When we include the interaction terms between the log of the unit value of alcohol and
level of consumption, the coefficient on the unit value of alcohol is now the price
elasticity of demand for light drinkers. We find that this coefficient is negative and highly
significant; the demand for alcohol among light drinkers is found to be elastic, such that
at the mean level of household income, a 10% increase in the unit value of alcohol will
still result in a 15.9% reduction in the quantity of alcohol consumed. The interaction
between the indicator variable for moderate drinkers and the log of unit value gives us
the price elasticity of demand among moderate drinkers. This variable is also highly
significant and negative, but the elasticity is less elastic, with ɛ=1.213 at the mean level
of household income.
TABLE IV
DIFFERENT SPECIFICATIONS OF THE DEMAND FOR ALCOHOL
Independent Variable
ln (Income)
Family Size
ln (Income).family size
Rural
ln (Unit Value)
Ln (Income). ln(unit value)
Moderate. ln(unit value)
Specificatio
n1
Specification
2
Specification
3
0.176***
(0.047)
0.152*
(0.061)
0.029***
(0.008)
0.152***
(0.046)
0.81***
(0. 025)
0.097**
(0.041)
0.380***
(0.050)
0.137*
(0.058)
0.1
(0.076)
0.023*
(0.01)
0.274***
(0.057)
0.833
(0.025)
0.0987
(0.003)
0.203***
(0.051)
0.188**
(0.067)
0.034***
(0.009)
0.178***
(0.05)
0.824***
(0.025)
0.098***
(0.003)
Heavy. ln(unit value)
Midlowincome.ln(unitvalue
)
Midhigh income. ln(unit
value)
High income. ln(unit value)
Low.moderate.ln(unit
value)
0.695***
(0.041)
8
.
5
9
e
0
6
9.15e06
(1.28e06)
(1.27e06)
2.197e06
(1.72e06)
Low.heavy. ln(unit value)
Midlow.light. ln(unit value)
Midlow.moderate. ln(unit
value)
6
.
8
5
e
0
6
*
Midlow.heavy. ln(unit
value)
Midhigh.light. ln(unit value)
Midhigh.moderate. ln(unit
value)
6
.
3
5
e
0
6
*
0.477*
(0.134)
0.619***
(0.088)
2.3e05
(1.48e06)
(2.88e06)
1.71e05***
(2.19e06)
2.22e05
(1.48e06)
(2.88e06)
Midhigh.heavy.ln(unit
value)
1.72e05***
(2.18e06)
4.34e04***
(1.92e05)
High.light. ln(unit value)
High.moderate.ln(unitvalu
e)
High.heavy. ln(unit value)
Rsquared
N
* p<0.05, ** p<0.01, ***
p<0.001
0.42
3494
0.118
3494
2.71e04***
(4.46e05)
2.0e04***
(3.4e05)
0.324
3494
The elasticity among heavy drinkers is unsurprisingly the most inelastic, with ɛ=0.898 at
the mean level of household income. This suggests that heavy drinkers will adjust their
quantity of alcohol consumed less following a change in price, such that any increase in
price will result in alcohol becoming a larger proportion of their expenditure. Of
particular concern then is whether lowerincome households tend to be heavydrinking
as well, as this will imply that poorer households will be hurt most by increases in the
price of alcohol.
We find that the interaction between household income and unit value is significant and
positive, such that an increase in the price of alcohol will result in a smaller reduction in
the quantity of alcohol consumed for households with larger incomes. This would
suggest that lowerincome households are more sensitive to changes in the price of
alcohol than higherincome households. Of particular interest is whether this finding is
similar across different levels of income.
5.4 Demand elasticity by income group
In order to analyse whether the sensitivity to the price of alcohol differs across different
levels of household income, we define four income groups: low, midlow, midhigh, and
high income households, where the groups are defined according to the income
quartiles within the data set. We compare the elasticity of demand for alcohol among
the different income groups by interacting the unit value of alcohol with indicator
variables for the different income groups, where the base group is lowincome
households.
Specification 2 in Table IV reports the results of a regression with variables from the
core regression, and the interaction terms between income and the log of unit value. We
find that income still has a significant negative effect on the quantity of alcohol that a
household consumes, although the income elasticity of demand is now less elastic than
in prior regressions. The interaction between household income and unit value,
however, is no longer significant. We also note that the coefficient on the unit value of
alcohol is now insignificant. Furthermore, the interaction terms between the income
group of the household and unit value are all highly insignificant, such that an increase in
the price of alcohol will not have a significantly different effect on the quantity of alcohol
consumed across the different income groups. We therefore cannot conclude that
lowerincome households are more sensitive to changes in the price of alcohol than
higherincome households.
5.5.
Demand elasticity by income group and level of drinking
Although the above analysis suggests that households do not differ in their sensitivity to
changes in price across the income groups, a question of interest is whether the price
elasticity of demand for alcohol differs between households with different levels of
consumption across the different income groups. That is, we are interested in whether
two households that are both heavy drinkers will have different sensitivities to changes
in the price of alcohol if they belong to different income groups. In order to test this
hypothesis, we define interaction terms between the log of the unit value of alcohol,
indicator variables for the level of consumption, and indicator variables for the different
income groups. Our base group here is low income households that are light drinkers,
such that the coefficient on the unit value variable reports the price elasticity of demand
for this group.
Specification 3 in Table IV reports the results for the regression with all the variables in
the core regression, and the interaction terms between the log of unit value, level of
consumption and income group. We note that household income is a significant
determinant of the quantity of alcohol consumed by the household. The income elasticity
of demand is now even more elastic, such that an increase in income will now result in a
larger decrease in the quantity of alcohol consumed. The interaction term between
household income and the log of unit value of alcohol is also significant; a given
increase in the price of alcohol will have a more significant effect on consumption
among higherincome households.
Of particular interest is the price elasticity of demand among the income groups across
the different levels of consumption. We find that the coefficient on the unit value of
alcohol is negative and highly significant. We also find that all the interaction terms
between the log of unit value, income and level of consumption are highly significant,
with the exception of the midlowincome, light drinking and midhighincome, light
drinking households. Although economically minor, the coefficients on midlowincome,
moderate drinking; midlowincome, heavy drinking and highincome, light drinking
households are all negative, such that their demand for alcohol is more elastic than the
base group. The coefficients on the other interaction terms are all positive, such that
these groups have more inelastic demand than the base group.
Because we interact the log of unit value with level of drinking as well as income, the
price responsiveness of alcohol will now depend not only on the level of consumption,
but also on the level of income at which we evaluate the price elasticity. That is, for a
given level of drinking, the price elasticity of demand will change as income changes.
We therefore need to choose some meaningful level of income at which we may
compare the magnitudes of the price elasticities of the different types of consumers.
TABLE V
PRICE ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND FOR DIFFERENT INCOME GROUPS AND LEVELS
OF DRINKING
Income
750
1200
2000
5250
Income category
Low income
Midlow income
Midhigh income
High income
Level of Drinking
Light
Light
Light
Light
Ԑp
1.473
1.519
1.569
1.664
750
1200
2000
Low income
Midlow income
Midhigh income
Moderate
Moderate
Moderate
0.996
1.519
1.569
5250
High income
Moderate
1.66
750
1200
2000
5250
Low income
Midlow income
Midhigh income
High income
Heavy
Heavy
Heavy
Heavy
0.854
1.519
1.569
1.66
Table V reports the price elasticity of demand for each type of consumer for the median
household income of that particular income group. At the median level of household
income, the price elasticity of demand for all light drinkers is found to be highly elastic; a
10% increase in the price of alcohol will result in approximately a 15% reduction in the
quantity of alcohol consumed by all light drinkers. All moderate drinkers are also found
to have a highly priceelastic demand for alcohol, although lowincome, moderate
drinkers are less priceelastic in their demand. Heavy drinkers are also found to have a
similar price elasticity of demand when the income group is controlled for.
The coefficients we are most interested in, however, are those on lowincome, heavy
drinking households. The coefficient on lowincome, heavy drinking households is the
least priceelastic in the sample. A 10% increase in the price of alcohol will only result in
a 8.5% reduction in the quantity of alcohol consumed by these households, such that
their demand is inelastic. Lowincome households that are heavy drinkers are thus two
times less elastic in their demand for alcohol than higherincome households that
consume the same quantity of alcohol.
6. Conclusions
The above finding supports the hypothesis that alcohol control policy that is based on
changing the price of alcohol will affect consumers in different ways. Heavydrinking
consumers are unsurprisingly found to be less elastic in their demand for alcohol, such
that an increase in the price of alcohol will result in them appropriating a larger portion
of income to expenditure on alcohol. While we find no significant difference in the
elasticities of lowerincome and higherincome households, alcohol is still found to be
an inferior good when the level of drinking is not controlled for, such that lowerincome
households appropriate a larger portion of their income to alcohol expenditure.
Furthermore, among the group of households in the study that may be classified as
heavy drinkers, lowincome households have a highly inelastic demand for alcohol,
while the elasticity of highincome households is not significantly different from that of
light drinkers. This implies that increases in the price of alcohol will not reduce the
quantity of alcohol consumed by lowincome, heavy drinking households, but will rather
result in them reallocating their income towards expenditure on alcohol. The same
policy, however, will be significantly more effective in other groups of consumers.
This suggests that any policy based solely on the increase of excise taxes will have no
significant impact on reducing the social and economic cost of alcohol abuse among
lowerincome areas in society. In particular, since many of the problematic behaviours
associated with alcohol use is specifically associated with alcohol abuse, increasing
the price of alcohol will not effectively reduce the abuse of alcohol and will thus fail to
alleviate this burden to society.
We note that there are several limitations to the study. Firstly, as Manning et al. (1995)
noted in their analysis, respondents may underreport their alcohol consumption, which
would lead to biased results. Respondents may also incorrectly report their
expenditures on alcohol or household income, which would further lead to biased
estimates of price and income elasticities. Secondly, the National Income Dynamics
Survey data does not contain information on the market prices faced by households.
This drawback imposes the use of estimation methods in order to obtain price
elasticities, resulting in the loss of precision in the analysis. Despite these limitations,
however, the results are importance to alcohol control policy, as they suggest the
possible impact of current policy considerations.
REFERENCES
Abel, E.L., Kruger, M.L. & Friedl, J. 1998. How Do Physicians Define
?Light,??Moderate,? And ?Heavy? Drinking? Alcoholism: Clinical And Experimental
Research. 22(5):979984. DOI:10.1111/J.15300277.1998.Tb03692.X.
Austin, P.C., Escobar, M. & Kopec, J.A. 2000. The Use Of The Tobit Model For
Analyzing Measures Of Health Status. Quality Of Life Research. 9(8):901910.
Bellemare, M.F. & Barrett, C.B. 2006. An Ordered Tobit Model Of Market Participation:
Evidence From Kenya And Ethiopia. American Journal Of Agricultural Economics.
88(2):324337.
Casswell, S. & Maxwell, A. 2005. Regulation Of Alcohol Marketing: A Global View.
Journal Of Public Health Policy. 26(3):343358.
Chaloupka, F.J., Grossman, M. & Saffer, H. 2002. The Effects Of Price On Alcohol
Consumption And AlcoholRelated Problems. Alcohol Research And Health.
26(1):2234.
Chow, G.C. 1960. Tests Of Equality Between Sets Of Coefficients In Two Linear
Regressions. Econometrica. 28(3):591605.
Chung, C., Dong, D., Schmit, T.M., Kaiser, H.M. & Gould, B.W. 2005. Estimation Of
Price Elasticities From CrossSectional Data. Agribusiness. 21(4):565584.
DOI:10.1002/Agr.20065.
Colditz, G.A., Dejong, W., Emmons, K., Hunter, D.J., Mueller, N. & Sorensen, G. 1997.
Harvard Report On Cancer Prevention, Vol 2, Prevention Of Human Cancer. Cancer
Causes & Control. 8:S1&.
Cox, W.M. & Klinger, E. 1988. A Motivational Model Of Alcohol Use. Journal Of
Abnormal Psychology. 97(2):168180.
Deaton, A. 1987. Estimation Of OwnAnd CrossPrice Elasticities From Household
Survey Data. Journal Of Econometrics. 36(1):730.
Deaton, A. 1997. The Analysis Of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric
Approach To Development Policy. Johns Hopkins University Press.
Dee, T.S. 2001. Alcohol Abuse And Economic Conditions: Evidence From Repeated
CrossSections Of IndividualLevel Data. Health Economics. 10(3):257270.
DOI:Http://Www3.Interscience.Wiley.Com/CgiBin/Jhome/5749.
Duffy, J.C. 1993. Alcohol Consumption And Control Policy. Journal Of The Royal
Statistical Society.Series A (Statistics In Society). :225230.
Fogarty, J. 2006. The Nature Of The Demand For Alcohol: Understanding Elasticity.
British Food Journal. 108(4):316332.
Fogarty, J. 2010. The Demand For Beer, Wine And Spirits: A Survey Of The Literature.
Journal Of Economic Surveys. 24(3):428478.
DOI:10.1111/J.14676419.2009.00591.X.
Gallet, C.A. 2007. The Demand For Alcohol: A Meta‐Analysis Of Elasticities*.
Australian Journal Of Agricultural And Resource Economics. 51(2):121135.
Garner, R.C. 1998. Religion And Economics In A South African Township.
Garner, R.C. 2000. Safe sects? Dynamic religion and AIDS in South Africa. The
Journal of Modern African Studies. 38. pp4169
Ground, M. & Koch, S.F. 2008. Hurdle Models Of Alcohol And Tobacco Expenditure In
South African Households1. South African Journal Of Economics. 76(1):132143.
Gruenewald, P.J., Ponicki, W.R., Holder, H.D. & Romelsjö, A. 2006. Alcohol Prices,
Beverage Quality, And The Demand For Alcohol: Quality Substitutions And Price
Elasticities. Alcoholism: Clinical And Experimental Research. 30(1):96105.
DOI:10.1111/J.15300277.2006.00011.X.
Heather, N. & Robertson, I. 1997. Problem Drinking. Oxford University Press Oxford:.
Hentz, J.J. 1996. Democratization In South Africa: The Elusive Social Contract By
Timothy D. Sisk Princeton University Press, 1995. Pp. Xvi + 342. $39.50. £29.95. The
Journal Of Modern African Studies. 34(04):739. DOI:10.1017/S0022278X0005597X.
Jones, S.C., Hall, D. & Munro, G. 2008. How Effective Is The Revised Regulatory Code
For Alcohol Advertising In Australia? Drug And Alcohol Review. 27(1):2938.
DOI:10.1080/09595230701499175.
Kasolo, F. 2011. SocioEconomic Context: South Africa, 2011. World Health
Organisation.
Kessler, D.A. 2005. Alcohol Marketing And Youth: The Challenge For Public Health.
Journal Of Public Health Policy. 26(3):292295.
Kitchin, P.D. 1981. Some SocioEconomic Determinants Of Alcohol Consumption: A
Research Note. International Journal Of Social Economics. 8(5):3135.
DOI:Http://Www.Emeraldinsight.Com/Ijse.Htm.
Ledermann, S. 1964. Alcool, Alcoolisme, Alcoolisation. Presses Universitaires De
France.
Lemmens, P.H. 1993. Regularity In The Distribution Of Alcohol Consumption. Journal
Of The Royal Statistical Society.Series A (Statistics In Society). :231235.
Lemmens, P.H. 1993. Regularity In The Distribution Of Alcohol Consumption. Journal
Of The Royal Statistical Society.Series A (Statistics In Society). :231235.
Manning, W.G., Blumberg, L. & Moulton, L.H. 1995. The Demand For Alcohol: The
Differential Response To Price. Journal Of Health Economics. 14(2):123148.
DOI:10.1016/01676296(94)000423.
Mroz, T.A. 1987. The Sensitivity Of An Empirical Model Of Married Women's Hours Of
Work To Economic And Statistical Assumptions. Econometrica: Journal Of The
Econometric Society. :765799.
Nelson, J.P. 2010. Alcohol Advertising Bans, Consumption And Control Policies In
Seventeen OECD Countries, 1975–2000. Applied Economics. 42(7):803823.
Odejide, O.A. 2006. Alcohol Policies In Africa. African Journal Of Drug And Alcohol
Studies. 5(1):2739.
Odejide, A.O. 1978. Alcoholism: A Major Health Hazard In Nigeria? Nigerian Medical
Journal : Journal Of The Nigeria Medical Association. 8(3):230232.
Parry, C., Rehm, J. & Morojele, N. 2010. Is There A Causal Relationship Between
Alcohol And HIV? Implications For Policy, Practice And Future Research. African
Journal Of Drug And Alcohol Studies. 9(2).
Parry, C.D. 2005. South Africa: Alcohol Today. Addiction. 100(4):426429.
Parry, C., Burnhams, N.H. & London, L. 2012. A Total Ban On Alcohol Advertising:
Presenting The Public Health Case. SAMJ: South African Medical Journal.
102(7):602604.
Paton, A. 1985. The Politics Of Alcohol. British Medical Journal (Clinical Research
Edition). 290(6461):12.
Room, R., Babor, T. & Rehm, J. 2005. Alcohol And Public Health. The Lancet.
365(9458):519530.
Saffer, H. & Chaloupka, F. 1998. Demographic Differentials In The Demand For
Alcohol And Illicit Drugs.
Saffer, H. & Dave, D. 2002. Alcohol Consumption And Alcohol Advertising Bans.
Applied Economics. 34(11):13251334. DOI:10.1080/00036840110102743.
Skog, O. 1985. The Collectivity Of Drinking Cultures: A Theory Of The Distribution Of
Alcohol Consumption.*. British Journal Of Addiction. 80(1):8399.
DOI:10.1111/J.13600443.1985.Tb05294.X.
Taylor, J.R. & Helzer, J.E. 1983. The Natural History Of Alcoholism. In The Biology Of
Alcoholism. Springer. 1765.
Tobin, J. 1958. Estimation Of Relationships For Limited Dependent Variables.
Econometrica: Journal Of The Econometric Society. :2436.
Toomey, T.L. & Wagenaar, A.C. 1999. Policy Options For Prevention: The Case Of
Alcohol. Journal Of Public Health Policy. :192213.
Tremblay, V.J. & Okuyama, K. 2001. Advertising Restrictions, Competition, And
Alcohol Consumption. Contemporary Economic Policy. 19(3):313321.
DOI:Http://Www.BlackwellSynergy.Com/Loi/Coep/.
Vaillant, G.E. 1983. The Natural History Of Alcoholism. Harvard University Press
Cambridge, MA.
Vaillant, G.E. & HillerSturmhöfel, S. 1996. The Natural History Of Alcoholism. Alcohol
Health & Research World.
Wilsnack, R.W., Vogeltanz, N.D., Wilsnack, S.C. & Harris, T.R. 2000. Gender
Differences In Alcohol Consumption And Adverse Drinking Consequences:
CrossCultural Patterns. Addiction. 95(2):251265.
DOI:10.1046/J.13600443.2000.95225112.X.
World Health Organization 2011. Global Status Report On Alcohol And Health. Geneva:
World health organization. 286.
Yen, S.T. & Jensen, H.H. 1996. Determinants Of Household Expenditures On Alcohol.
Journal Of Consumer Affairs. 30(1):4867.
DOI:10.1111/J.17456606.1996.Tb00725.X.