188 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
Rethinking the Transnational Capitalist Class
William K. Carroll 1
It has been more than four decades since Stephen Hymer (1974) first
mooted that globalizing capital was begetting, in its pathways, an international
bourgeoisie, and nearly two decades since Leslie Sklair’s (2001) pathbreaking
The Transnational Capitalist Class. 2 The basic thesis that with capitalist
globalization comes a tendency toward formation of a transnational capitalist
class (TCC) is well established, but a tendency is not a fait accompli, and as social
scientists and activists we need to be attentive to the complexities in class
formation and global political economy. That means clarifying some continuing
ambiguities. In this article, I attempt to clarify: 1) how key terms like global,
transnational, regional and national apply within transnational capitalist class
formation; 2) how the distinction between a capitalist class in-itself and for-itself
applies to the TCC; and 3) how insights from the Amsterdam School, which
embarked upon the first sustained research program on the TCC in the 1980s,
can add nuance to our analysis of TCC formation.
From the start, there have been different conceptions of the TCC in
play. In his foundational statement Hymer noted the basic process that underlies
TCC formation: the internationalization of capital which leads an
internationalizing segment of the capitalist class to “detach their interests from
the home market” and to support an international regime that “allows free
movement of capital between countries” (Hymer, 1974). In a related paper,
Hymer (1972, 100-1) drew a direct link between internationalization of capital
and “international class consciousness on the part of capital”. Kees Van der Pijl
(1984), a decade later, focused on the region within the world-system in which
capitalist internationalization was most intense, what he called the Lockean
heartland, and the Atlantic ruling class that, over the course of three centuries,
had come to form a hegemonic fraction. Van der Pijl’s densely historical
treatment was complemented by Meindert Fennema’s (1982) network analysis,
1
William K. Carroll is Professor of Sociology at the University of Victoria.
This article is based on a paper presented at the 4th Biennial Conference of the Network
for the Critical Study of Global Capitalism in Havana, November 1-3, 2017. It extends
analyses in Carroll (2012, 2013). It has benefited from my involvement in the SSHRCfunded Corporate Mapping Project and from comments by Gordon Bailey.
2
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 189
which evidenced a developing international network of banks and industrial
corporations, strongly centred on the North Atlantic. By 1987 Robert Cox
offered a Gramscian alternative to realist and idealist International Relations
theories, noting that with globalization “the historic blocs underpinning
particular states become connected through the mutual interests and ideological
perspectives of social classes in different countries, and global classes begin to
form” as states themselves become internationalized (1987, 358). What Cox
called a transnational managerial class had emerged, consisting of top managers
and directors of multinational corporations, those controlling major national
enterprises, and locally-based smaller capitalists linked into the transnational
capitalist circuitry.
In the 1990s, the terminology began to shift, from internationalization
to globalization and from the multinational to the transnational. Robinson and
Harris’s influential 2000 article repeated Hymer’s basic thesis, adding in a
discussion of how the now-transnational capitalist class contained within itself
political factions pushing three analytically distinct globalization projects – the
free-market, the structural and the regulatory. Sklair’s The Transnational
Capitalist Class was the first major study that framed its object within the nowconventional terminology, though he had already presented the basic thesis in
his Sociology of the Global System. Sklair’s thesis on TCC formation is that,
although it consists of four distinct fractions (executives of TNCs and their
subsidiaries, globalizing state bureaucrats, globalizing professionals and a
globalizing consumerist-media elite) “there is one central transnational capitalist
class that makes system-wide decisions, and … it connects with the TCC in each
community, region, country, etc” (1994, 175). This thesis is repeated in
Robinson’s (2004) “theory of global capitalism”, which depicts the globalization
of capital, the formation of a TCC and the emergence of a transnational state
(TNS) as interdependent developments.
Inspired mainly by Sklair and Robinson, the Network for the Critical
Study of Global Capitalism has held biannual meetings since 2011, resulting in
several published collections that comprise a loosely organized school of thought
(Struna, 2013; Harris and Hrubric, 2016; Sprague, 2016). 3 Concurrently, a series
of studies, reviewed below, have examined capitalist transnationalization within
specific places in the world-system. These studies move to a more concretecomplex level, and raise issues as to how we characterize geographically-specific
3
The Network’s website is at https://netglobalcapitalism.wordpress.com/
190 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
segments of transnationalized capital. Are nationally-based capitalist fractions
(resident say in China) part of the TCC by virtue of their connections into TN
circuitry? Is the TCC one coherent entity? How do North-South inequities figure
in TCC formation? Most broadly, how do continuing geopolitical-economic
realities shape TCC formation?
The Global, Transnational, Regional and National
The basic thesis in global capitalism theory holds that global capitalism
is undergoing an “epochal shift”, “characterized by the rise of truly transnational
capital and the integration of every country into a new globalized system of
production and finance, a transnational capitalist class as would be global ruling
class, and transnational state apparatuses.” (Robinson, 2017, 171). In this
formulation, the global and the transnational stand in for each other. Yet there is
value in distinguishing between them. With Sklair (2001), we can identify
transnational practices, which cross borders but do not originate from states
(which engage in international practices). The “global” is a more abstract term. It
refers, within capitalism, not to specific practices but, systemically, to the world
market. At mid-19th century, the tendency for capital to globalize was famously
observed by Marx and Engels (1968, 38): “The need of a constantly expanding
market for its products chases the bourgeoisie over the entire surface of the
globe.” It is the world market (not only for trade but for capital) that creates the
systemic dominion of capital, within which the law of value operates as the
expression of alienated labour.
Actual relations and practices are not “global” in this sense, but always
situated, though varying in scale and scope, from the local to the transnational.
As the world market and especially the world capital market deepens and
widens, capital’s structural power grows. Global integration of accumulation
since the 1970s has meant that “economic calculations of all kinds – from
purchases in the supermarket to the determination of the prime interest rate –
are subject, quite explicitly, to international calculation” (Bryan, 1995, 13). For
businesses and state bodies, the fact that competitors function in a globalized
field is enough to lead to the embrace of a standpoint of global capital (Ross and
Tracte, 1990, 7-9). It is this shift in the general horizons of economic calculation
– for various agents at various sites of the world system – that marks our present
era, and that has underwritten transnational neoliberalism as a hegemonic
project (Carroll, 2003). That project has in turn further widened and deepened
the world market. Of course, what underlies the market are production relations.
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 191
By the late 20th century not only had the capital market become globalized, but a
segment of production itself had become reconfigured into transnational
commodity chains that optimize on costs of production.
Nevertheless, capitalist globalization has not eliminated national spaces;
it has made them more permeable. As a concept predicated on the continuing
reality of such spaces, the transnational enables us to examine regionalism and
spatially-driven fractionation within the TCC. Most TNCs have well-established
home bases, from which they have grown. Unlike pregnancy, transnationality is
not simply present or absent. A company can be a little transnational or a lot. A
few giant companies are extremely transnational (“stateless”), but most have
clear operating bases in one country and some are minimally transnationalized.
Rugman and Verbeke (2007) showed that as of 2002 only nine of the Fortune
500 corporations had achieve balanced sales across the three regions of the
Triad, with most TNCs “organized at the regional level rather than the global
level.” A follow-up study by Podrug et al (2018) found that between 2002 and
2012 six of the nine had retreated from regionally-balanced international sales
while nine corporations had joined the ranks of highly transnationalized
companies, bringing the total to 12. This is modest evidence of increasing
transnationality, but the main take-away is that most large corporations
continue to have regionalized business strategies, and economic interests. In
this sense an arch distinction between “national” and “transnational” capitalist
fractions, with the latter conflated with “global capital” may miss a more
complex reality. The same holds of course for national states, which have
pursued regionalization strategies within blocs such as NAFTA and the EU.
Such blocs have promoted specific circuits of regional accumulation, shoring up
many companies’ regional business strategies. Much of what is transnational is
regional – organized in blocs that do not break with geopolitical logic but
reproduce it, even as they also contribute to the widening and deepening of the
world market.
There is also the question of the transnational and the international.
Some years ago, Jerry Harris (2003, 330) provided helpful clarification on this
when he looked more concretely at the military-industrial fraction of the
American bourgeoisie, whose interests he took to be quite distinct from the
TCC. The former is strongly (co)dependent upon the US state, but is also
involved in the international arms trade and in massive foreign investment.
Harris pointed out that TNCs like Boeing accumulate capital internationally
rather than transnationally; hence contradictions within the military-industrial
192 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
fraction could raise “a significant challenge to globalization” Harris’s study
points to divisions between capital that accumulates transnationally (in circuits
that transect borders without the commercial involvement of states) and capital
that accumulates “internationally” (in international circuits that involve states
commercially). The examples could be multiplied, since across the globe there is
considerable state support for various corporations that, although
transnationally invested, retain national moorings (whether US-based Boeing or
Canada-based Bombardier).
As our analysis becomes more concrete, as we take up phenomena such
as the US military-industrial complex, the TCC appears less as a coherent,
homogeneous collective actor that has transcended or captured national states,
and more as a highly variegated and regionalized formation containing within
itself tensions and contradictions. Of course, most capitalists, worldwide, are not
transnationalized in their investments, and only a few control big capital that is
highly transnational. The most important and archetypal are those who
command the leading transnational asset managers – Blackrock, Fidelity etc. –
coming closest to Bill Gate’s utopian vision of friction-free capital that flows
within a unified world market. In its demography, the capitalist class, worldwide,
is overwhelmingly national, but the numerically tiny segment that does operate
transnationally controls vast stocks and flows of capital (much of it fictitious).
Building more nuance into the picture – recognizing the concreteness
of
transnational
practices
and
the
continuing
relevance
of
regional/national/local formations – is important, if we are to avoid overly
schematic formulations. A master division between transnational and national,
one hegemonic the other fading, is too arch to provide much analytical
purchase, especially when analysis moves to a more concrete-complex level,
which is where history is made. 4 In short, the TCC grand narrative operates at
an overly abstract level. Part of the problem, as others have noted (Moore, 2002;
Van der Pijl, 2005) is a studied insensitivity to space, which is both a material
reality and a political/economic/cultural construction. As Robinson (2017)
warns, spatiality, and state territoriality, should not be reified, but neither should
they be ignored. Concretely, the agency of transnational capitalists does not
escape national contexts but occurs simultaneously in several contexts.
4
For a discussion of the abstract-simple and the concrete-complex in social-scientific
reasoning see Jessop (2008, 2).
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 193
“Transnational social forces do not operate outside states but inside different
states at the same time” (Van Apeldoorn, 2004, 145).
Class-in-Itself and Class-for-Itself
A second clarification concerns the distinction between class in-itself
and for-itself. Since the 1970s the transnational circuits of capital have densified
so that within many TNCs production occurs through transnational commodity
chains optimized for corporate profit while financial capital circulates
transnationally at the click of a mouse (or, ditching the mouse, through a
programmed trade in fictitious capital). These are the bases for a TCC-in-itself,
and they are well established, although Sean Starrs cautions us about the scale of
transnationalization. 5 As a class-in-itself, the TCC wields capital’s structural
power molecularly, in a multitude of decisions that add up to a (shifting) verdict
on places, states and industries. So, even if the transnationalized capitalist
fraction is relatively small it exerts a market-mediated class power of great
significance. Transnational networks of finance and investment provide a
fundamental structural basis for the TCC (Harris, 2014). However, a TCC-foritself implies more – a class capacity to exert hegemonic leadership in a
transnational field. The latter is a tendency held in check by the continuing
political power of national states and by the fact that the vast majority of the
world’s capitalists – the 99% within the infamous 1% – in fact, are not
transnationally invested.
What pulls the top tier of a capitalist class together and enables its
collective agency are the elite relations that integrate leading capitalists, their
corporations and associated organic intellectuals into corporate communities
(Domhoff, 2006). Such integration enables a moving consensus among leading
capital interests, but corporate communities simultaneously reach into civil and
political society via policy-planning, lobbying and related processes, creating
capacity for capital as a class-for-itself. An issue here is, how does a transnational
corporate community develop in relation to the national corporate communities
5
As of 2015, only six percent of the world’s total household wealth (excluding primary
residence, thus a proxy for the wealth of capitalists) was managed offshore; i.e., “94% of
the world’s total household wealth of $168 trillion is managed onshore by firms of the
same nationality as their clients” This does not deny the formation of a TCC-in-itself, but
it does emphasize the continuing importance of national ruling classes, and associated
states. See Starrs (2017, 649).
194 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
that pre-exist it? The answer is that the actual historical process of TCC
formation has been on a trajectory from nationally-focused monopoly capital to
transnationalized monopoly capital, with all the path dependencies that implies.
Historically, the transnational corporate community takes shape as an accretion
of transnational relations to well-developed national business communities
embodying fractions of monopoly capital (Carroll, 2010).
Given this historical process, it should not surprise us that national
corporate communities persist, even if transnational elite relations increase
gradually. Research on Canada is relevant here. Canada’s major corporations
have transnationalized while remaining core players in the national corporate
community, tied in with the more domestically-focused firms (Carroll, 2004;
Klassen and Carroll, 2011) In general, each national corporate community
exercises leadership within a system of alliances that extend domestically to
think tanks, business councils, lobbies, industry groups, foundations and
political parties. The persistence of national corporate communities is also
evident in the extent of foreign ownership of shares listed on different stock
exchanges. Despite rising levels of foreign ownership, domestic ownership is still
prevalent for many large corporations, worldwide. In capitalism’s dominant
state, American ownership of the largest US-based firms is especially
concentrated – American investors own on average 84% of the shares of the
largest 50 US-based corporations. For Starrs (2017, 652) this indicates “the
continued existence of an American-based capitalist class, even as their
accumulation of profit flows in from around the world – implying a continued
reliance on “their” US state as the primary author and guarantor of this global
system.”
When we follow the actual historical process, we find that the top tier of
the capitalist class is not a clearly discernable TCC-for-itself that has broken free
of national moorings. Rather, it consists in monopoly capital that is
transnationalized to varying degrees and in various regional configurations. The
transnational network of capitalists and their organic intellectuals, linked into
national corporate networks, forms part of an apparatus of class power that is
both transnational and national.
This interpretation is consistent with what we now know about the
global network of interlocking directorates. Mapping interlocks among the
world’s five million corporations, Heemskerk and colleagues have searched for
communities based on actual elite relations, and have assessed whether and how
these communities transect national borders. This study concludes that
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 195
corporate communities continue to be nationally focused and that transnational
communities are clustered regionally (and in some cases linguistically, e.g.
Portugal and Brazil). The network is largely Euro-North American (with scant
participation of capitalists based in the global south), and centred upon Europe
(Heemskerk et al, 2016). It follows in the tracks of the Atlantic ruling class, but
points away from the American hegemony that was integral to its post-World
War Two consolidation. Related research has shown that, in Latin America,
where capitalists groups are predominantly organized around families, “a
cohesive transnational corporate network has not emerged” (Cárdenas, 2015,
438). The same pattern holds throughout much of Asia (Burris and Staples,
2012). The weak participation of the global south in a TCC-for-itself is also
reflected in a relatively low turnout of BRICs’ elites at the World Economic
Forum (Stephen, 2014).
To summarize, the research literature on corporate communities – the
epicenters for capitalist class collective agency – underlines the persistence of
national networks and the slow accretion of transnational elite relations, which
are centred upon Europe and extend mainly to North America. As a class-initself, the TCC is a regional formation, replicating the north-south logic of
colonialism and imperialism.
The Amsterdam School
If
a
closer
look
at
key
distinctions
(global/transnational/international/regional,
class-in-itself/class-for-itself)
supports a more variegated view of the TCC, the same may be said of the
distinction William Robinson has drawn between national states and what he
considers a now-dominant transnational state (TNS). For Robinson, the latter
includes both international organizations like the WTO and parts of national
states that have been “captured” by the TCC (Robinson, 2014, 2017). There are
two problems in this characterization: 1) like national business communities,
national states persist as weighty condensations of power, even if within them,
transnational capital’s structural power and political influence have grown; 2)
key criterial attributes for a TNS – a monopoly over the use of force and a
relatively unified, hierarchically organized ensemble of power (Jessop, 2008, 911) – have not developed in the contemporary geopolitical economy.
International organizations like the WTO are, in my view, not components of a
TNS; they are quasi-state apparatuses that exercise power largely delegated to
them by national states. In any case, Robinson’s doubtful assertion of TNS
196 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
ascension leads him prematurely to dismiss the study of international relations
as an exercise in reification that falsely attributes agency to national states (2017,
174). 6 If there is a kernel of truth in this it is that the predominant theoretical
current in International Relations (IR) – US-centred “realism” – is founded
precisely on such reification. Yet IR is not a homogeneous field.
The Amsterdam School (AS) of “transnational historical materialism”
has opened an alternative based in Gramscian political economy, which avoids
state reification by tracing the historical formation of state-society complexes in
interaction with transnational class formation. As its leading theorist, Kees van
der Pijl, has argued, capitalism arose within an expanding zone of bourgeois
property relations, gaining pace in 17th C Britain, then stoked by the industrial
revolution – to form a Lockean heartland of market-oriented societies. Under
British and then American hegemony, this heartland grew as “an organically
unified group of states at the centre of the international political economy.”
(Van der Pijl, 1998, 64).
For other state-society complexes coming to capitalist modernity, the
existence of a heartland, already occupying “the international terrain
commercially and culturally” pushed them in the direction of state-centred
development (Van der Pijl, 1998, 83). Yet these Hobbesian contenders, from the
Bonapartist state of the early 19th C through the fascist states of the Axis powers
to the Soviet Bloc, were eventually absorbed into the expanding heartland,
sometimes after military defeat. By the late 20th C, the hyperliberal state, on the
Thatcher/Reagan model, had emerged as the predominant state form. Its
subsequent expansion, from the Lockean heartland of anglophone capitalism to
a transnational hegemonic project for global capitalism and the TCC, was
facilitated by financialization (itself a product of neoliberal policy that
cumulatively skewed profit distribution toward short-term financial assets as
opposed to fixed-capital industrial investment), by the consolidation of global
governance around the Washington Consensus (promoting investor rights as
“free trade” and mandating austerity programs in the debt-ridden global South),
and by the collective agency of a TCC centred in the North Atlantic, supported
6
Robinson himself has recently expressed doubt as to the TNS’s governmental efficacy,
observing its ‘fragmentary and highly emergent nature’, ‘the dispersal of formal political
authority across many national states and the loose nature of a TNS apparatus with no
center or formal constitution’ (2017, 185). Why one would label such a situation a ‘state’
is unclear.
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 197
by many strata of organic intellectuals and an expanding assemblage of policyplanning groups. (Carroll and Sapinski, 2016, 30).
In this perspective the TCC develops in a specific geopolitical context
(the existing inter-state system, the heartland, US hegemony) as an accretion to a
core that is Euro-North American. A significant chapter in this process has been
“the neoliberalization of continental Europe and the closely associated making of
a European TCC” (Carroll and Sapinski, 2016, 45). Indeed, as we have seen,
Europe has been the epicenter in the nascent formation of a TCC-for-itself. But
the project of European unification has been less about relinquishing national
sovereignty than about consolidating monetary and financial integration and
accelerating neoliberal restructuring to ratchet-up regional competitiveness
(Bierling, 2006). As Van Apeldoorn observes,
“Transnationalization here does not imply the withering away
of national states and national social formations but rather the
rise of relations across national borders and the constitution of
actors that operate not “above” the national state, but in
different national contexts simultaneously. It is from this
perspective that we can understand how transnational class
agency has helped to transform the project of European
integration into an ever more undiluted neoliberal project.
The essence of this hegemonic class project has been the
creation of a transnational space for capital in which the
latter’s rule is established precisely by preserving the formal
sovereignty of the member states while subordinating their
democratic governance to the dictates of the single market”
(2013, 189).
When we turn, with members of the Amsterdam School, to the contemporary
state-capital nexus in the US, further insights become available. Whereas
Robinson views imperialist adventures such as the 2003 American-led war on
Iraq as expressions of TCC power refracted through a TNS for which the US
state is a “point of condensation” (Robinson, 2017, 184), Van Apeldoorn and De
Graaff’s analysis of the state-capital nexus at the centre of American open door
imperialism presents a more sensitive account. Charting the corporate
affiliations of successive US administrations since the 1990s, they reveal not only
a remarkable number of connections into the “national” American corporate
198 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
community, but a strong presence of “US-based transnational capital” (2012,
600).
The predominance of the latter, at once national and transnational, at
the heart of the US state-capital nexus illustrates how capital’s continuing
national moorings are related dialectically to transnational circuits of
accumulation. US-based capital is not in any simple sense bifurcated into
“national vs. transnational”. And if the US Open Door has since the late 1940s
facilitated the global expansion of US capital while elaborating a Lockean
Heartland and absorbing Hobbesian challengers, the uneven and contradictory
character of accumulation and state power cautions us against extrapolating
from past to future – particularly in a conjuncture of “Trumpism” when,
according to Der Spiegel, “the West as an entity, it would seem, is disintegrating”
(Der Spiegel Online, 2017).
The example of Chinese capitalism is equally instructive. Following
global capitalism theory, Harris (2012, 30) has suggested that China’s current
emphasis on developing its home market “is simply globalisation with Chinese
features,” reflecting “the strategic thinking of the transnational capitalist class, in
China, the U.S. and globally.” In this account, “national development in China is
an essential feature of transnational capitalism.” Despite its insights, the problem
with this analysis is again its overly abstract and formulaic character.
It is certainly true that capitalism in China is embedded in the world
market. At a rarefied level of abstraction, it is also true that all capitalists,
including China’s state-capitalist class, have a common interest in sustaining the
world market. This is the terrain of class-in-itself. But to read China’s pivot to an
autocentric accumulation strategy as an expression of TCC agency strains
credibility. After all, global capitalism theory identifies the TCC with the project
of capitalist globalization, not with the development of national markets. A
stronger account can be built by recognizing, with and De Graaff and Van
Apeldoorn, that China’s state/society complex is not based on the Lockean
scenario of an autonomous capitalist class and expansive civil society, but on “a
state class organized around the Communist Party – which is still the dominant
source of power in Chinese society” (De Graaff and Van Apeldoorn, 2018, 4).
As China assumes a more pro-active role on the world stage, a number
of initiatives portend geopolitical rivalry with the US. These include:
•
a more assertive military posture, particular in the South-China Sea;
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 199
•
•
•
establishment in 2015 of the Beijing-headquartered Asian
Infrastructure and Investment Bank (AIIB) which now has 57
members, regrouped under Chinese leadership;
the related “Belt and Road Initiative”, which “if successful will establish
a vast network of infrastructure (roads, rails, ports and maritime
routes) incorporating more than 60 countries across Asia, Europe, the
Middle East and Africa - with China at its heart” (De Graaff and Van
Apeldoorn, 2018, 7);
China-led negotiations for a Regional Comprehensive Economic
Partnership (RCEP) agreement which would form a free trade area
covering almost half the world population and potentially providing
China a major position and platform in regional free trade, from which
the US would be excluded.
China’s “state-directed” form of capitalism figures significantly in these
developments, as a hybrid formation incorporating aspects of Hobbesian
challenger states within the context of globalizing capitalism. Chinese stateowned enterprises (SOEs) operate extensively abroad and have formed
partnerships with western TNCs. Yet, they perform dual roles, adhering to
profit-maximizing norms but retaining the responsibilities of state-owned
companies at home (with priorities of e.g. energy security and social stability).
This dual character means that even if corporate motives increasingly drive their
investment decisions, they “remain firmly tied to the state’s interests and
priorities” (De Graaff and Van Apeldoorn, 2018, 9). The directors of these firms
are intimately connected to the state. A large majority occupy top-level state
positions before and during their SOE directorship.
In appreciating the hybridity of China’s state class, we can avoid a
forced choice between transnational and national. Clearly, Chinese state-owned
enterprises (and the wealthiest private Chinese capitalists) participate in the
formation of a TCC-in-itself. Yet China’s hybridity means that its major
capitalists are for the most part detached from the transnational corporate
community that loosely embodies a TCC-for-itself. 7 And China’s major
7
The tendency toward TCC formation means that China’s hybridity should not be
mechanically projected into the future. The recent Chinese decision to open its financial
sector to more foreign investment may portend a shift toward fuller integration into
200 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
initiatives cannot be read simply as “globalizing”; they represent a state-centred,
regionally based bid for leadership, blending “national interests” (always an
ideological construction) with the wider interests of China’s partners, and
presenting an alternative to US-centred geopolitical economy.
A final insight we can take from the AS clarifies the issue of class
fractions. As we have seen, an arch division of capital into transnational and
national fractions is misleading, and too blunt an instrument to take us very far
analytically. Beginning with Kees van der Pijl’s 1984 study, the School has
emphasized the division, deeply structured into capital’s circuitry, between
money capital and productive capital. These furnish distinctive standpoints in
the construction of hegemonic projects. The key issue is “how strategic divisions
in bourgeois politics and the structural dynamics of capital accumulation are
inter-related.” Mindful of this, “the fractionation of the capitalist class is
understood as a moment of the underlying process of class formation, rather
than as an aberration or an insignificant epiphenomenon” (Overbeek, 2004, 7,
115). Within this perspective, neoliberalism, embracing the standpoint of money
capital, also expresses the fractional predominance of financial capital which,
since the 1970s, has integrated a transnational historical bloc.
Recently, Van der Pijl and Yurchenko have explored the relation
between fractional divisions and political projects in neoliberalism’s post-2008
“second life”. In neoliberalism’s prehistory, during the era of Fordist-Keynesian
class compromise, capitalism’s “lead circuit” was that of productive capital (mass
production for mass consumption), furnishing the basis in the global North for a
general interest in robust national economies. But in the 1970s, as productivity
gains in the heartland fell behind wage increases, depressing profits,
corporations shifted production to low-wage zones. Concurrently, the circuit of
money-capital gained global sweep and the swelling volume of internationally
mobile money capital fed inflation. The Volcker Shock of 1979 was aimed at
restoring the discipline of capital at home while obliging indebted states to avoid
default by privatizing assets. It thereby “widened the sphere of capital
accumulation under the auspices of interest-bearing money capital,” expanding
the basis for a neoliberal project (2015, 502). The objective in this “systemic”
phase of neoliberalism was to restore profitability via real accumulation, in no
small measure through attacks on organized labour. But as financialization
global capital markets. See ‘China opening financial sector to more foreign investment,’
Toronto Globe and Mail 11 November 2017: B1, 5.
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 201
created an ever-expanding volume of fictitious capital, neoliberalism “slowly
mutated into a ‘predatory’ version in which real capital accumulation becomes a
secondary consideration altogether” (2015, 503).
In neoliberalism’s predatory phase, it is money-dealing capital, claiming
profit through speculative arbitrage, which dominates the accumulation process.
When the bubble inevitably bursts, state bailouts displace financial crisis into a
crisis of public finance, and “austerity, the asset-stripping of entire
societies…becomes the downside of refuelling speculative money-dealing
capital” (2015, 512). In turn, societal asset stripping provokes protective
responses from below. Any dominant fraction’s hegemony rests upon the
alliances it is able to form and sustain with subordinate groups and classes. If the
Fordist-Keynesian project was broadly based in the class compromise in the
global North between capital and labour (and in the cliental of the welfare state),
systemic neoliberalism found its base, more narrowly, in the asset-owning
middle classes. As it becomes more predatory, and as its base thins from an
alliance of capital and the propertied middle class to an exclusivist oligarchy,
Van der Pijl and Yurchenko see neoliberalism becoming more authoritarian,
ratcheting up the free market/strong state dynamic already salient in
Thatcherism. 8 Sensitivity to the fractional divisions in capital, to the changing
shape and form of capitalism’s circuitry, and to the alliances that congeal (or fail
to congeal) into an historical bloc is a key virtue in the AS. In my view, these
concerns are requisite to an adequate analysis of the transnational capitalist class
and its agency within global capitalism.
Conclusion
To conclude, efforts to understand global capitalism and the TCC can
benefit from greater clarity on concepts such as the global and the transnational,
and class-in-itself and for-itself. Although the world market has broadened and
deepened and the circuitry of capital has become dramatically more
transnational in the past half-century, as a class-for-itself, the TCC is a regional
tendency that co-exists amid structures and practices of an era of capitalism
fading but not extinguished – including massive north-south disparities (some
of which have been intensifying through uneven development (Kiely, 2014)).
The Amsterdam School’s insights can provide additional clarity in this liminal
age of overlapping periods, with national formations still intact though
8
See also Bruff (2014) and Gamble (1988).
202 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
“inhabited” by the global, and vice versa, and with capital both nationally
moored and transnationally ascendant (Sassen, 2008; Garrod, 2017).
The troubled presidency of Donald Trump – who espouses a racialized,
ecologically toxic economic nationalism distinct from the allegedly progressive
neoliberalism of the Clintons and Obama – highlights this liminality, while
confirming that the American capitalist class has not been dissolved into a TCCfor-itself, despite Trump’s own transnational-capitalist bona fides. Beyond that,
the Trump phenomenon points to a continuing geopolitical-economic reality
that has gone unacknowledged in the global capitalism school: the exceptionality
of the US as a dominant, though no longer hegemonic, state. To the extent that
the Trump administration is pursuing a coherent accumulation strategy, it is not
to serve benignly as “the point of condensation for pressures from dominant
groups around the world to resolve problems of global capitalism and to secure
the legitimacy of the system overall” (Robinson, 2017, 184), but to make
America(n capital) great again. Although the era of unmitigated American
hegemony is long past, the United States retains an exceptional position within
global geopolitical economy. This exceptionalism is based in several legacies of
the American Century, as I have noted elsewhere (Carroll, 2013). 9 Continuing
dollar hegemony (which enables the chronically indebted US state to stay afloat
and to finance its bloated military) and unchallenged military dominance are
key, but the unparalleled size of the US home market and the fractured,
disorganized state of the American working class also serve now to underpin an
accumulation strategy for stoking domestic investment and reviving national
industrial (including military-industrial) dominance at the expense of “trading
partners” now vilified as enemies of working-class America.
Framed as a populist expression of the American national interest, this
strategy combines protectionism with trickle-down economics, but continues
the neoliberal commitment to such international quasi-state organizations as the
WTO – all in a bid to strengthen US-based capital, both national and
transnational. It underlines the fact that a half century of capital crosspenetration among the advanced states has muted but has not eliminated
9
My position supports Panitch and Gindin’s (2012, 1) claim that “the American state has
played an exceptional role in the creation of a fully global capitalism and in coordinating
its management, as well as restructuring other states to those ends,” but argues that with
the decline of American hegemony there has been a shift to more collective-imperialist
coordination among the advanced capitalist powers.
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 203
geopolitical rivalry, particularly as economic/ecological crisis intensifies
competition. A transnational capitalist and President at odds with the
TCC/TNS script for global governance in a borderless world, Trump personifies
a reality of our time: despite the World Economic Forum and the transnational
corporate community it convenes, as a class-for-itself, the TCC is not yet made.
It may never be, if democratic movements of the left have their way.
References
Bierling, H. J. (2006). EMU, financial integration and global economic
governance. Review of international political economy, 13, 420–48.
Bruff, I. (2014). The rise of authoritarian neoliberalism. Rethinking Marxism, 26,
113-29.
Bryan, D. (1995). The chase across the globe. San Francisco: Westview Press.
Burris, V. & Staples, C. (2012). In search of a transnational capitalist class:
Alternative methods for comparing director interlocks within and
between nations and regions. International journal of comparative
sociology, 53, 323–42.
Cárdenas, J. (2015). Are Latin America’s corporate elites transnationally
interconnected? A network analysis of interlocking directorates. Global
networks, 15, 424–445.
Carroll, W. K. (2003). Undoing the End of History: Canada-centred reflections
on the challenge of globalization. In Y. Atasoy and W. K. Carroll (Eds.),
Global shaping and its alternatives (33-55). Aurora, Ontario: Garamond
Press.
Carroll, W.K. (2004). Corporate power in a globalizing world. Toronto: Oxford
University Press
Carroll, W. K. (2010). The making of a transnational capitalist class. London:
Zed Books.
Carroll, W. K. (2013). Global capitalism, American Empire, collective
imperialism? Studies in political economy, 92, 93-100.
Carroll, W. K. & Sapinski, J. P. (2016). Neoliberalism and the transnational
capitalist class. In K. Birch, J. MacLeavy & S. Springer (Eds.), The
handbook of neoliberalism (25-35). London: Routledge.
Cox, R. (1987). Production, power and world order. New York: Columbia
University Press.
204 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
De Graaff, N. & Van Apeldoorn, B. (2018). US-China relations and the liberal
world order: Contending elites, colliding visions? International affairs
94(1), 1-19.
Der Spiegel Online. (2017 June 30). Merkel concerned G-20 summit could end
in
fiasco
http://www.spiegel.de/international/world/eu-us-tradeconflict-threatens-to-escalate-ahead-of-g-20-a-1155342.html#ref=nlinternational.
Domhoff, G. W. (2006). Who rules America? New York: McGraw-Hill.
Fennema, M. (1982). International networks of banks and industry. Den Haag:
Nijhoff.
Gamble, A. (1988). The free economy and the strong state. London: Macmillan.
Garrod, J. Z. (2017). A (reluctant) defence of the theory of the transnational
state. Studies in political economy, 98(3), 279-297
Harris, J. (2003). The conflict for power in transnational class theory. Science &
society, 67, 329–39.
Harris, J. (2014). Transnational capitalism and class formation. Science & society,
78, 312–333.
Harris, J. (2012). Outward bound: Transnational capitalism in China. Race &
class, 54, 13 – 32.
Harris, J., & Hrubec, M. (2016). Introduction: The formation of global
capitalism, International critical thought, 6, 327-8.
Heemskerk, E. M., Takes, F. W., Garcia-Bernardo, J. & Huijzer, M. J. (2016).
Where is the global corporate élite? A large-scale network study of local
and nonlocal interlocking directorates. Sociologica, 2, 1-31.
Hymer, S. (1972). The internationalization of capital. Journal of economic issues,
6, 91-110.
Hymer, S. (1974). ‘International politics and international economics: A radical
approach’, mimeographed.
Kiely, R. (2014). Imperialism or globalisation? … Or imperialism and
globalisation: Theorising the international after Rosenberg’s ‘postmortem’. Journal of international relations and development, 17, 288-91.
Klassen, J., & Carroll, W. K. (2011). Transnational class formation?
Globalization and the Canadian corporate network. Journal of worldsystems research, 17, 379-402.
Marx, K., & Engels, F. (1968). Manifesto of the Communist Party. In K. Marx
and F. Engels, Selected works, (35-63). New York: International
Publishers.
Re thinking the Transnational Cap italist Class | 205
Moore, J. W. (2002). Capital, territory, and hegemony over the Longue Duree.
Science & society, 65, 476–84.
Jessop, B. (2008). State power. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Overbeek, H. (2004). Transnational class formation and concepts of control:
Towards a genealogy of the Amsterdam Project in international
political economy. Journal of international relations and development 7,
113–141.
Podrug, N., Filipović, D. & Kuveždić, M. (2018). Multinational corporations:
The changing strategic orientation in the Twenty-First Century. In I.
Vrdoljak Raguž, N. Podrug & L. Jelenc (Eds.), Neostrategic management
(139-58). Cham, Switzerland: Springer.
Robinson, W. I. (2004). A theory of global capitalism. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press.
Robinson, W. I. (2017). Debate on the new global capitalism: transnational
capitalist class, transnational state apparatuses, and global crisis.
International critical thought, 7(2), 171-189.
Robinson, W. I., & Harris, J. (2000). Towards a global ruling class? Globalization
and the transnational capitalist class, Science & society, 64, 11-54.
Ross, R. F. S., & Tracte, K.C. (1990). Global capitalism: The new leviathan.
Albany: State University of New York Press.
Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. (2007). Liabilities of regional foreignness and the
use of firm-level versus country¬ level data: a response to Dunning et
al. Journal of International Business Studies, 38, 200–205.
Sassen, S. (2008). Neither global not national: novel assemblages of territory,
authority and rights. Ethics & global politics, 1(1-2), 61-79.
Sklair, L. (1991). Sociology of the global system. London: Harvester.
Sklair, L. (1994). Capitalism and development in global perspective. In L. Sklair
(Ed.), Capitalism and development (165-88). London: Routledge.
Sklair, L. (2001). The transnational capitalist class. Oxford: Blackwell.
Sprague, J. (Ed.). (2016). Globalization and transnational capitalism in Asia and
Oceania. London: Routledge.
Starrs, S.K. (2017). The global capitalism school tested in Asia: Transnational
capitalist class vs taking the state seriously. Journal of contemporary
Asia, 47, 641-658.
Stephen, M. D. (2014). Rising powers, global capitalism and liberal global
governance: A historical materialist account of the BRICs challenge.
European journal of international relations, 20, 912–938.
206 | Social Ine q uality and the Sp e ctre of Social Justice
Struna, J. (2013). Global capitalism and transnational class formation.
Globalizations, 10, 651-7.
Van Apeldoorn, B. (2004). Theorizing the transnational: a historical materialist
approach. Journal of international relations and development, 7, 142–
176.
Van Apeldoorn, B. (2013). The European Capitalist Class and the Crisis of Its
Hegemonic Project, Socialist register, 50, 189-206.
Van Apeldoorn, B. & de Graaff, N. (2012). The limits of Open Door imperialism
and the US state-capital nexus. Globalizations, 9, 593–608.
Van der Pijl, K. (1984). The making of an Atlantic ruling class. London: Verso.
Van der Pijl, K. (1998). Transnational classes and international relations.
London: Routledge.
Van der Pijl, K. (2005). A theory of global capitalism. New political economy, 10,
273-7.
Van der Pijl, K. & Yurchenko, Y. (2015). Neoliberal entrenchment of North
Atlantic capital: From corporate self-regulation to state capture. New
political economy 20, 495-517.