Monetary Policy
Comes of Age:
A 20th Century Odyssey
Marvin Goodfriend
I
n the early 1960s the Federal Reserve (Fed) was little known outside of the
financial services industry and university economics departments. Twenty
years later Fed Chairman Paul Volcker was one of the most recognized
names in American public life. Now hardly a week goes by when the Fed
is not featured prominently in the business news. The Fed was thrust into
the limelight in the intervening years when the public came to associate it
with inflation-fighting policy actions that raised interest rates and weakened
economic activity. Even though inflation has been held in check since the mid1980s, the public remains acutely aware of Fed policy today.
Monetary economists and central bankers alike now understand that effective monetary policy must be built on a consistent commitment to low inflation.
That is why in recent years the Fed has made low inflation a particularly high
priority. The large fraction of the public having first-hand experience with high
inflation naturally supports the view that inflation must be contained. As the
collective memory of inflation fades, however, public support for low inflation
will become increasingly difficult to sustain. A permanent national commitment
to price stability requires that citizens personally unfamiliar with the trauma of
high inflation understand the rationale for price stability and the tactical policy
actions needed to maintain it.
The author is senior vice president and director of research. This article, which originally
appeared in this Bank’s 1996 Annual Report, benefited greatly from the comments of Doug
Diamond, Mike Dotsey, Bob Hetzel, Tom Humphrey, Bob King, Ben McCallum, Alan
Stockman, and Alex Wolman. It should be emphasized that the views expressed are the
author’s alone and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve System.
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly Volume 83/1 Winter 1997
1
2
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
This article reviews the history of U.S. monetary policy in the 20th century
with the aim of providing that understanding. It identifies mistakes that led to
high and volatile inflation, lessons learned from the experience, and principles
applied in the pursuit of low inflation today. U.S. monetary policy came of age
in the 20th century in the sense that the country left the strict rules of the gold
standard for the freedom of an inconvertible paper standard, which the Fed
only slowly and painfully learned to manage. What follows is the story of that
20th century odyssey.
Section 1 discusses monetary policy under the gold standard and the circumstances that led to the founding of the Fed. Section 2 outlines the main
conceptual obstacles that had to be overcome in order to manage monetary
policy under a paper standard. The causes and disruptive consequences of
inflationary policy at mid-century are discussed in Section 3.
Certain key theoretical and practical developments paved the way for the
Fed to take responsibility for controlling inflation in the early 1980s. Section
4 covers these developments. Progress in the theory of the demand for and the
supply of money as well as empirical evidence supporting the theory played
key roles here. The failure of nonmonetary approaches to controlling inflation
was also important. The recognition that a credible Fed commitment to price
stability could minimize the unemployment cost of achieving low inflation also
played a role.
Section 5 recommends that the Fed be given a legislative mandate for low
inflation. The case is based on lessons learned in the inflationary 1960s, ’70s,
and early ’80s, and on the principles that have been applied successfully to
maintain low inflation since then. The closing section summarizes the monetary
policy lessons learned on the 20th century odyssey.
1. MONETARY POLICY UNDER THE GOLD STANDARD
When the Federal Reserve was established in 1913, inflation was not the problem it was to become in the latter part of the century. The nation was on a gold
standard and the purchasing power of money in 1913 was about what it had
been 30 years before, or for that matter, 100 years before. The gold standard
sharply restricted inflation by requiring that money created by the U.S. Treasury
be backed by gold.1
The classical gold standard yielded price stability only to the extent that
the Treasury’s stock of monetary gold happened to expand at a rate sufficient
1 Technically, the United States was on a bimetallic (gold and silver) standard until 1900.
Though it is true that the money supply was limited by the size of the Treasury’s gold and silver
holdings, there was considerable short-run variability in the money multiplier. See Cagan (1965)
and Freidman and Schwartz (1963).
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
3
to satisfy the economy’s demand for money at stable prices. For instance, slow
growth in the gold supply caused the price level to decline at over 1 percent
per year from 1879 to 1897, and gold discoveries and new mining techniques
caused inflation to average over 2 percent per year between 1897 and 1914.
Nevertheless, by the standard of what was to come, the variation of inflation
was very small.
Although the economy grew rapidly throughout the gold standard years,
the period was marked by a number of recessions associated with temporary
deflations and substantial interest rate movements. Sudden sustained short-term
interest rate spikes of over 10 percentage points occurred on eight occasions
between the Civil War and the founding of the Federal Reserve. Five of these
spikes were associated with bank runs characterized by a demand to convert
bank deposits into currency that could not be satisfied by the fractional cash
reserves held by banks. 2
Finally, in response to the banking panic of 1907 and the ensuing recession,
the nation was no longer willing to run monetary policy entirely according to
the classical gold standard rules. The Federal Reserve was established in the
United States with the power to create currency and bank reserves at least
somewhat independently of the nation’s monetary gold. The Fed was given
authority to create currency and reserves by making loans to banks through its
discount window or by acquiring securities in the money market. The Fed’s
mission was to provide an elastic supply of money to smooth short-term interest
rates against liquidity disturbances, while preserving the link between money
and gold in the long run in order to restrain inflation.3
Through its dominant presence in the market for currency and bank reserves, the Fed easily gained control of short-term interest rates and eliminated
the kind of interest rate spikes seen earlier.4 By smoothing short-term interest
rates, however, the Fed was obliged to substitute its discretionary management of short rates for the impersonal market forces that had determined rates
previously. The Bank of England had successfully managed short rates for
decades in the context of the classical gold standard.5 And the Fed could have
followed similar gold standard operating procedures. However, the classical
gold standard collapsed with World War I, and the nation was never willing to
support Fed procedures geared to defending the gold standard. The Fed was left
without clear operational procedures for positioning short-term interest rates to
stabilize economic activity around full employment with stable prices.
2
Major banking panics occurred in 1873, 1884, 1890, 1893, and 1907.
This latter understanding was viewed as part of the Fed’s mission, although it is only
implicitly, not explicitly, stated in the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 itself.
4 See Goodfriend (1988).
5 See Hawtrey (1938).
3
4
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
2. THE OBSTACLES TO UNDERSTANDING
MONETARY POLICY
Improvements in monetary policy that seemed within reach after the founding of
the Fed proved elusive. The 1930s saw the sharpest deflation, the worst banking
crisis, and the longest and deepest economic depression in American history.6
Then, beginning in the mid-1960s there were two decades of unprecedented
peacetime inflation that tripled the general price level by the early 1980s.7
Why has it taken so long for the Fed to give price stability pride of place?8
Initially, there was a tendency to underestimate the disruptive potential of inflation and a willingness to be tolerant of each new burst of inflation in the hope
that it would soon die down. Such hope seemed reasonable since protracted
peacetime inflation had never before been a problem in the United States.
Another difficulty was that it took some time for economists to develop a
framework capable of understanding monetary policy in the absence of a link
to gold. Prior to the 20th century the world had little practical experience with
monetary regimes in which money was unbacked by a commodity such as
gold or silver. With some exceptions, mainly during wartime, there was little
empirical evidence on such regimes and little interest in analyzing them.
The main problem was confusion within the economics profession about
the determination of the general price level and the control of inflation in a
regime of inconvertible paper money.9 There was also little understanding of
the role played by inflation expectations in the wage- and price-setting process
and in the determination of interest rates. Finally, the relationship between
unemployment and inflation was seriously misunderstood. The resolution of
these disputes provided the foundation for today’s monetary policy success.
3. INFLATIONARY MONETARY POLICY
AT MID-CENTURY
Largely as a result of the nation’s unfortunate experience with inflation in
the period from the mid-1960s through the early 1980s, monetary economists
6 According to Friedman and Schwartz (1963) U.S. real net national product fell by more than
one-third from 1929 to 1933, implicit prices of goods and services fell by more than one-quarter,
and wholesale prices by more than one-third. More than one-fifth of the commercial banks in the
United States holding nearly one-tenth of the deposits closed because of financial difficulties. As
a result of the sharp contraction in economic activity, the unemployment rate peaked at over 20
percent in 1932–33, and remained above 10 percent for the remainder of the decade.
7 The Fed had already recognized inflation as a problem on three occasions prior to the
mid-1960s: in the aftermath of World War II, during the Korean War and the period of the 1951
Fed-Treasury Accord, and again in the mid-1950s. See footnote 12.
8 Under the leadership of Benjamin Strong, Governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, the Fed made price stability a priority briefly in the 1920s. See Hetzel (1985).
9 See, for example, Bronfenbrenner and Holzman (1963) and Friedman (1987).
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
5
and central bankers now understand that the costs of inflationary monetary
policy are significant and varied. First are the costs that even a steady, perfectly anticipated inflation imposes on society. Then there are the disruptive
and destabilizing costs of unstable inflation, more difficult to quantify but substantial nonetheless. These latter costs stemmed from alternating expansionary
and contractionary policy actions. Specifically, there was a tendency—known
as go-stop monetary policy—for the Fed to exacerbate the cyclical volatility of
inflation and unemployment. And there was a related tendency to produce rising
inflation and increasingly volatile inflation expectations over time. The forces
giving rise to these tendencies are identified and described below together with
their disruptive consequences.
The Cost of Steady Inflation
The cost of steady inflation begins with the fact that a steadily falling purchasing power of money causes people to hold less cash than they would if prices
were stable. Attempts to economize on money holdings manifest themselves
in several ways. Banks invest in teller machines, people visit banks or teller
machines more frequently, businesses devote more time and effort to managing
their cash balances, etc.10 Even more important, individuals and firms take
steps to protect the value of their savings and investments against loss due to
inflation. The effort and resources devoted to dealing with inflation are wasted
from society’s point of view in the sense that they could be better employed
in producing goods and services.
Another major cost of steady inflation stems from the incomplete indexation of the tax system. The biggest problem in this regard results because taxes
are assessed on nominal interest earnings and nominal capital gains, that is, on
investment returns in dollars. Inflation causes nominal returns to rise because
investors demand compensation for the declining purchasing power of money.
For instance, long-term bond rates contain a premium for expected inflation
over the life of the bond. Since nominal returns are taxed as income, however,
inflation reduces the after-tax return to saving and investment and thereby tends
to inhibit capital accumulation and economic growth.11
10 Estimates in Lucas (1994) imply that the economization of money balances that occurred
at a rate of inflation of 5 percent per year (associated with a short-term nominal interest rate of
about 6 percent) wasted about 1 percent of U.S. GDP. The payment of interest on transactions
deposits in recent years raises money balances and reduces this welfare cost somewhat. The bulk
of the welfare gain to reducing inflation is probably realized at a slightly positive inflation rate.
See Wolman (1997).
11 Feldstein (1996) reports that the net present value of the welfare gain of shifting from
2 percent inflation per year to price stability forever is about 30 percent of the current level of
GDP.
6
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
Go-Stop Monetary Policy12
A central bank such as the Fed that is charged with conducting monetary policy
on a discretionary basis is naturally inclined to give considerable weight to the
public’s mood. Go-stop monetary policy was, in good part, a consequence of
the Fed’s inclination to be responsive to the shifting balance of public concerns
between inflation and unemployment. Of course, difficulties in judging the
strength of the economy and in gauging inflationary pressures compounded the
problem, as did ignorance of the lags in the effect of policy.
For the most part the public tolerated inflation as long as it was low,
steady, and predictable. When labor markets were slack, the public was even
willing to risk higher inflation in order to stimulate additional economic activity.
Only when economic activity was strong and inflation moved well above the
prevailing trend did inflation top the list of public concerns.
It is easy to understand why inflation need not greatly concern the public
when it is steady and predictable. Individuals and firms are inconvenienced
only slightly by steady inflation. As long as wages, prices, and asset values
move up in tandem, there are no big financial consequences, especially when
inflation is low. Likewise, a temporary and modest increase of inflation around
a low, well-established trend need not immediately arouse concerns.
However, a persistent departure of inflation above trend causes anxieties
because people wonder where a new trend might be established. Investors
worry about how much of an inflation premium to demand in interest rates;
businesses worry about how aggressively to price in order to cover rising costs;
and workers worry about maintaining the purchasing power of their wages.
In marked contrast to inflation, which affects all, unemployment actually
affects relatively few at a given time. The unemployment rate in recent decades
has risen at most to only about 10 percent of the labor force. The public is
concerned about unemployment not so much because of those who are currently
unemployed but because people are afraid of becoming unemployed. It follows
that the public is generally more concerned about unemployment when the
unemployment rate is rising, even if it is still low, than when it is falling, even
if it is already high.
The above-mentioned reasoning helps explain why the Fed produced gostop monetary policy in the 1960s and ’70s. In retrospect, one observes the
following pattern of events.
12 Friedman (1964, 1972, and 1984) discusses go-stop policy. Romer and Romer (1989)
document that since World War II the Fed tightened monetary policy decisively to fight inflation
on six occasions beginning, respectively, in October 1947, September 1955, December 1968, April
1974, August 1978, and October 1979. The unemployment rate rose sharply after each policy
shock. Only two significant increases in unemployment were not preceded by Fed action to fight
inflation. One occurred in 1954 after the Korean War and the second occurred in 1961, after the
Fed tightened monetary policy to improve the international balance of payments.
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
7
First, because inflation became a major concern only after it clearly moved
above its previous trend, the Fed did not tighten policy early enough to preempt
inflationary outbursts before they became a problem.
Second, by the time the public became sufficiently concerned about inflation for the Fed to act, pricing decisions had already begun to embody higher
inflation expectations. Thus delayed, a given degree of restraint on inflation
required a more aggressive increase in short-term interest rates with greater
risk of recession.
Third, in any cyclical episode there was a relatively narrow window of
broad public support for the Fed to tighten monetary policy. The window
opened after inflation was widely recognized as the major concern and closed
when tighter monetary policy caused the unemployment rate to begin to rise.
Often the Fed did not take full advantage of a window of opportunity to raise
short rates, because it wanted more confirmation that higher short-term rates
were required.
Fourth, it was probably easier for the Fed to maintain public support for
fighting inflation with prolonged rather than preemptive tightening. A more
gradual lowering of interest rates in the later stage of a recession was a less
visible means of fighting inflation than raising rates more sharply earlier. Once
unemployment peaked and began to fall, the public’s anxiety about it diminished. Prolonged tightening was attractive as an inflation-fighting measure in
spite of the fact that it probably lengthened the “stop” phase of the policy cycle.
Rising Inflation and Unstable Inflation Expectations
Over time, deliberately expansionary monetary policy in the “go” phase of the
policy cycle came to be anticipated by workers and firms. Workers learned
to take advantage of tight labor markets to make higher wage demands, and
firms took advantage of tight product markets to pass along higher costs in
higher prices. Increasingly aggressive wage- and price-setting behavior tended
to neutralize the favorable employment effects of expansionary policy. And the
Fed became evermore expansionary on average in its pursuit of low unemployment, causing correspondingly higher inflation and inflation expectations.
Lenders demanded unprecedented inflation premia in long-term bond rates. And
the absence of a long-run anchor for inflation caused inflation expectations and
long bond rates to fluctuate widely.13
The breakdown of mutual understanding between the markets and the Fed
greatly inhibited the conduct of monetary policy. The Fed continued to manage
closely short-term nominal interest rates.14 But the result of an interest rate
13 The monthly average 30-year bond rate rose from around 8 percent in early 1978 to peak
above 14 percent in the fall of 1981. The long bond rate was near 13 percent as late as the
summer of 1984.
14 See Cook (1989).
8
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
policy action is largely determined by its effect on the real interest rate, which
is the nominal rate minus the public’s expected rate of inflation. And the Fed
found it increasingly difficult to estimate the public’s inflation expectations and
to predict how its policy actions might influence those expectations. Compounding the problem, enormous increases in short-term interest rates were required
by the early 1980s to stabilize the economy. Stabilization policy became more
difficult because the public could not predict what a given policy action implied
for the future, and consequently, the Fed could not predict how the economy
would respond to its policy actions.
4. THE CONTROL OF INFLATION:
DISINFLATION IN THE 1980S
By the late 1970s, policymakers and monetary economists had come to understand the costly and disruptive features of inflation discussed above. With
considerable public support, the Fed under the leadership of Chairman Paul
Volcker initiated the great disinflation in October 1979, marking the beginning
of the period in which the Fed would make lowering inflation a priority. What
followed was a tightening of monetary policy that succeeded in bringing the
inflation rate down permanently for the first time in the post–Korean War period, first from over 10 percent to around 4 percent by 1983, and then to around
3 percent by the mid-1990s.
This section reviews three developments that paved the way for the Fed
to take responsibility for price stability. Most important was the progress that
economists made in understanding money demand and supply. Next was the
failure of nonmonetary approaches to controlling inflation. Finally, and to a
lesser extent, was the idea advanced by monetary economists that the unemployment cost of disinflation might be minimized if the disinflation were
credible.
The Central Bank’s Responsibility for Inflation
The consensus among monetary economists that central banks are responsible
for inflation is built on both theory and evidence. Above all, there is the substantial body of evidence from the inflationary experiences of a great many
nations, including the widespread inflation in the industrialized world during
the 1960s and ’70s, showing that sustained inflation is always associated with
excessive money growth. The evidence also clearly indicates that inflation is
stopped by slowing the growth of the money supply.15
15
See, for instance, Friedman (1987), Poole (1978), and Sargent (1986).
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
9
The theory of money demand and supply supports the cross-country evidence by illuminating the mechanics of the link between monetary policy and
inflation. The theory of money demand implies that control of the money supply
is necessary and sufficient to control the trend rate of inflation. And the theory
of money supply implies that a central bank can control the trend rate of money
growth. As will become clear below, money demand may be thought of as the
fulcrum by which a central bank controls inflation, and the money supply may
be thought of as the lever by which it does so.
Money Demand
The theory of money demand asserts that individuals and businesses choose to
hold a target stock of money that is proportional to their expenditures, a target
that balances the convenience of holding money against the foregone interest
earnings.16 The key implication of money demand theory for monetary policy
is that there is a reasonably stable long-run relationship between a nation’s
demand for money and its production and exchange of goods and services.
It follows that sustained inflation results when the growth of the nation’s
money stock exceeds the rate of growth of the nation’s physical product. 17
Prices must rise in this case because otherwise individuals and firms would
spend their growing excess money balances. Since one person’s expenditure is
another person’s receipts, the spending would put upward pressure on prices
until the inflation rate matched the rate of money growth in excess of the
growth of output. Only then would the ongoing increase in the stock of money
be willingly absorbed by the public.
The theory of money demand also implies that the overall price level cannot move very much over the long run if the stock of money grows in tandem
with the growth of output.18 If an inflation were to start, it would reduce the
purchasing power of a given nominal stock of money and cause individuals
and businesses to cut their spending in an effort to maintain their inventory of
monetary purchasing power. With no additional money balances forthcoming
in the aggregate, the downward pressure on spending would stop the inflation.
Money Supply
The nation’s basic money supply consists of currency and checkable deposits
held by households and businesses. A central bank can control the former
16
See McCallum and Goodfriend (1987).
The public’s target ratio of money to expenditure may exhibit a trend at times in response
to, say, rising interest rates or technical progress in the payments system. For instance, the ratio of
money to expenditure will trend downward if money provides transaction services more efficiently
over time. In that case, the money growth rate consistent with price stability will be below the
growth of physical product.
18 See the preceding note.
17
10
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
because it has a monopoly on the creation of currency.19 Checkable deposits
are created by banks. A central bank also has the power to control checkable
deposits because banks must hold reserves to service their deposits, and a
central bank controls the aggregate stock of bank reserves.20
The financial services industry has long been creating new instruments
in which the public can hold liquid balances, e.g., certificates of deposit and
money market mutual funds. New financial instruments usually do not add to
the basic money supply since they are only imperfect substitutes for currency
or checkable deposits.21 Nevertheless, the introduction of money substitutes
has adversely affected the predictability of money demand in the short run.
In practice, however, money demand is sufficiently stable and money supply
sufficiently controllable over time, so that financial innovations do not fundamentally alter a central bank’s power over inflation.22
Failed Approaches to Controlling Inflation
A variety of nonmonetary approaches to controlling inflation were tried in the
1960s and ’70s. In the United States, for example, the federal government
published voluntary wage-price guidelines at various times to persuade firms
and workers to forego price and wage increases deemed excessive.23 Actual
controls were imposed for a few years in the early ’70s but for the most part
they were lifted by the mid-’70s.24 By the end of the period, both controls and
guidelines came to be regarded as arbitrary, unfair, and ineffective. Moreover,
where they were effective they often created allocative disruptions, e.g., price
controls in the energy sector created shortages and long lines at gas stations.
In the early 1960s economists believed that budget policy might play a
key role in fighting inflation. In the United States, however, it quickly became
clear in the Vietnam War period that political concerns would immobilize fiscal
policy as a practical economic policy tool. Moreover, it later became clear that
19 Electronic private substitutes for government currency have become feasible recently. See
Lacker (1996).
20 See Cagan (1965).
21 There have been exceptions, however. For instance, a new deposit type known as the
negotiable order of withdrawal (NOW) account was introduced in the late ’70s and early ’80s as
part of the deregulation of the prohibition of interest on checkable deposits. NOW accounts were
interest-earning substitutes for demand deposits and so were immediately included in the Fed’s
M1 measure of the basic money supply for purposes of targeting and control. See Broaddus and
Goodfriend (1984).
22 For instance, see Lucas (1988) and Meltzer (1963) on the long-run stability of the demand
for M1.
23 See Heller (1966) and Shultz and Aliber (1966).
24 See Kosters (1975).
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
11
the inflation of the 1970s was not closely related to the government’s fiscal
situation.25
Even after the Fed under Chairman Volcker had begun its momentous
disinflation, the Carter administration imposed credit controls in early 1980
in an effort to foster the process. The credit control program caused a sharp
recession with little impact on inflation and was phased out at midyear.26
Thus did policymakers learn the hard way that policies for stopping inflation other than monetary control didn’t work. As much as anything else, the
failure of nonmonetary approaches to disinflation set the stage for the Fed to
take responsibility for bringing inflation down.
Credibility for Low Inflation and the Unemployment Cost of Disinflation
In the early 1960s policymakers were inclined to accept the inflationary consequences of policy actions taken to stimulate aggregate demand and employment.
That inclination was based to a great extent on evidence of a century-long negative Phillips curve correlation between unemployment and (wage) inflation
in the United Kingdom that appeared to offer a trade-off in which the benefits of lower inflation would have to be balanced against the costs of higher
unemployment.27
When stimulative policy succeeded in driving down the unemployment
rate in the ’60s, the resulting increase in inflation at first seemed consistent
with a stable Phillips curve trade-off; and the rising inflation was tolerated as
a necessary evil.28 In the 1970s, however, the Phillips curve correlation broke
down as inflation and unemployment both moved higher, and it became clear
that high inflation could not buy permanently low unemployment. 29
Even though protracted inflation was widely understood by the late 1970s
to have costs with no offsetting benefits, it was recognized that bringing inflation down would be costly too. Previous experience with go-stop policy
made it clear that there was a short-run trade-off between unemployment and
inflation.30 Policymakers expected the temporary unemployment cost of a large
permanent disinflation to exceed the costs of earlier disinflations that the Fed
had produced in the “stop” phase of its policy cycles.
25
Government fiscal concerns are the driving force behind high inflations. See Sargent
(1986).
26
See Schreft (1990).
See Phillips (1958).
28 See Heller (1966) and Tobin (1972).
29 See Fischer (1994), pp. 267–68.
30 King and Watson (1994), for example, report a significant negative correlation between
unemployment and inflation over the business cycle.
27
12
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
To some degree a view then emerging in the academic community might
have encouraged the Fed to pursue the disinflation. The view holds that the
unemployment cost of disinflation can be minimized if a disinflation policy is
credible. The idea that credibility would govern the costliness of disinflation
has since become widely accepted in theory.31 The acquisition and maintenance
of credibility for low inflation have become major practical concerns of Fed
policymakers and central bankers around the world.
The idea underlying the role of credibility is that wage- and price-setting
behavior is geared to expectations of money growth. The Fed supports the
ongoing inflation as long as money grows in excess of output. If the Fed’s disinflation is credible, the Fed slows money growth and wage and price inflation
come down, too, with little effect on employment. On the other hand, if the
disinflation is not credible, then wage and price inflation continues as before.
If the Fed persists in slowing money growth anyway, a deficiency of aggregate
demand causes unemployment as households and businesses cut spending in
an attempt to maintain their targeted monetary purchasing power.32
In practice, however, disinflation is nearly always costly because credibility
for low inflation is hard to acquire after it has been compromised. Moreover, a
central bank’s commitment to low inflation is only as credible as the public’s
support for it. The Fed probably embarked on the disinflation in 1979, in part,
because the public finally seemed ready to accept it.
Although its discount rate changes often made the headlines prior to 1979,
the Fed rarely sought publicity for its monetary policy actions. Chairman
Volcker broke sharply with tradition by initiating the period of disinflationary policy with a high-profile announcement signaling that the Fed would
take responsibility for inflation and bring it down.33 In so doing, Chairman
Volcker built credibility by staking his own reputation and the Fed’s on
31 Barro and Gordon (1983), Fellner (1976), Sargent (1986), and Taylor (1982) contain early
discussions of credibility as it relates to monetary policy. Persson and Tabellini (1994) contains
a recent survey of research on the role of credibility in monetary and fiscal policy. The new
large-scale Federal Reserve Board macroeconomic model is designed to take account of different
degrees of credibility in policy simulations. See “A Guide to FRB/US” (1996).
32 What happens is this: In the first instance households and businesses attempt to exchange
financial assets for money. Such actions, however, cannot satisfy the aggregate excess demand
for money directly. They drive asset prices down and interest rates up until the interest sensitive
components of aggregate expenditure grow slowly enough to eliminate the excess demand for
money. As the disinflation gains credibility, wage and price inflation slows, and real aggregate
demand rebounds until the higher unemployment is eliminated.
Ball (1994) shows that a perfectly credible disinflation need have no adverse effects on
employment even in a model with considerable contractual inertia in the price level.
33 The Fed did not explicitly assert its responsibility for inflation in the initial announcements
of its disinflationary policy. However, by emphasizing the key role played by money growth in the
inflation process, and by announcing a change in operating procedures to emphasize the control
of money, the Fed implicitly acknowledged its responsibility for inflation. See Federal Reserve
Bulletin (November 1979), pp. 830–32.
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
13
achieving the low inflation objective. The unprecedented increases in shortterm interest rates that followed further demonstrated the Fed’s commitment
to reducing inflation.34
Nevertheless after two decades of rising inflation, a widespread skepticism
worked against Fed credibility.35 Wage and price setters doubted that there
would be sufficiently widespread public support for the Fed’s disinflation. Indeed, the inflation was not broken until a sustained slowing of money growth
beginning in 1981 created a serious recession that tested the Fed’s determination and the public’s support.36 Although the recession was the worst since
the 1930s, it was less severe than might have been expected considering the
size of the accompanying disinflation. Most remarkable is that the roughly 6
percentage point disinflation occurred in just two years: 1981 and 1982. The
size and speed of the disinflation suggests that the acquisition of credibility
played a key role in making it happen.
5. MONETARY POLICY AT THE CLOSE OF THE
CENTURY: MAINTAINING LOW INFLATION
The Fed has succeeded in maintaining low inflation for almost 15 years now.
With luck the United States should enter the 21st century with inflation near
what it was under the gold standard at the opening of the 20th century.
Macroeconomic performance during the low inflation period has been good,
34 The Fed took short-term rates from around 11 percent in September 1979 to around 17
percent in April 1980. This was the most aggressive series of actions the Fed has ever taken in
so short a time, although the roughly 5 percent increase in short rates from January to September
of 1973 was almost as large. See Goodfriend (1993).
35 The collapse of confidence in U.S. monetary policy in 1979 and 1980 was extraordinary.
The price of gold rose from around $275 per ounce in June 1979 to peak at about $850 per ounce
in January 1980, and it averaged over $600 per ounce as late as November 1980. Evidence of
a weakening economy caused the Fed to pause in its aggressive tightening in early 1980. But
with short rates relatively steady, the 30-year rate jumped sharply by around 2 percentage points
between December and February, signaling a huge jump in long-term inflation expectations. The
collapse of confidence in early 1980 was caused in part by the ongoing oil price shock and the
Soviet invasion of Afghanistan in December 1979. But the Fed’s hesitation to proceed with its
tightening at the first sign of a weakening economy probably also played a role. In any case, the
Fed responded with an unprecedented 3 percentage point increase in short rates in March, taking
them to around 17 percent. See Goodfriend (1993).
36 After making its disinflationary policy commitment in October 1979, the Fed let the
growth of effective M1 overshoot its target range in 1980 and the inflation rate continued to rise,
peaking at over 10 percent in the fourth quarter. Then, in sharp contrast to the preceding four
years, effective M1 actually undershot its target range in 1981. Effective M1 grew around 4.6
percentage points slower in 1981 than its average annual growth over the preceding five years.
Further, the actual 2 percent shortfall in M1 from the midpoint of its 1981 target was built into
the 1982 target path. See Broaddus and Goodfriend (1984).
The unemployment rate rose from around 6 percent in 1978 to average nearly 10 percent in
the recession year of 1982.
14
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
especially when compared to the inflationary period preceding it. The only
recession during the period, in 1990–91, was mild by recent standards. Over
the period as a whole, employment growth has been strong and productivity
growth may have picked up somewhat. Moreover, both short- and long-term
interest rates are around one-third of what they averaged in the early 1980s
and are much less volatile too.
The promise of low inflation is being fulfilled. The challenge today is for
the Fed to understand the secret of its success. In that regard the low inflation
period has as much to teach as the traumatic period that preceded it. In reviewing below the lessons learned and principles applied, we shall see that the best
way of assuring our continued monetary policy success would be for Congress
to give the Fed a legislative mandate for low inflation.
Lessons Learned and Principles Applied
One of the most important lessons learned from the last four decades is that
credibility for low inflation is the foundation of effective monetary policy. The
Fed has acquired credibility since the early 1980s by consistently taking policy
actions to hold inflation in check. In effect, the Fed has reestablished a mutual
understanding between itself and the markets. From this perspective, wage and
price setters keep their part of an implicit bargain by not inflating as long as
the Fed demonstrates its commitment to low inflation. Ironically, the Fed has
learned from nearly a century of experience to pursue rule-like behavior in
order to fully achieve the gains from moving away from the gold standard.
Experience shows that the guiding principle for monetary policy is to preempt rising inflation. The go-stop policy experience teaches that waiting until
the public acknowledges rising inflation to be a problem is to wait too long. At
that point, the higher inflation becomes entrenched and must be counteracted
by corrective policy actions more likely to depress economic activity.
The main tactical problem for the Fed is to decide when preemptive policy
actions are necessary and how aggressive they should be. In this regard, the
Fed must be careful to consider any adverse effect that a poorly timed policy
tightening could have on employment and output. For that matter, the Fed
must be prepared to ease monetary policy when a weakening economy calls
for it. The central bank’s credibility depends not only on its inflation-fighting
credentials but also on its perceived competence.
A natural starting point to balance these concerns is to use a policy ruleof-thumb based on historical data to benchmark Fed policy. The stance and
direction of monetary policy can then be chosen in light of historical experience
conditioned on any special current circumstances. The most relevant historical experience is, of course, the relatively brief low inflation period since the
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
15
mid-1980s. As the Fed extends low inflation over time, the nation will build
up a richer relevant history against which to benchmark policy.37
However, even our brief experience with low inflation contains useful insights such as this. In some years, such as 1994, inflationary pressures might
be judged to call for a particularly aggressive preemptive tightening. At other
times, such as in 1996, there might be some concern about the potential for
rising inflation but enough doubt to adopt a wait-and-see attitude. The Fed’s
success in 1994 and 1996 suggests that the key to effective management of
short-term interest rates over the business cycle is to move rates up decisively
and preemptively when warranted in order to build credibility for low inflation.
With credibility “in the bank,” so to speak, the Fed can hold rates steady or
move them down out of concern for unemployment at other times.38 The lesson
is that credibility enhances flexibility.
A Legislative Mandate for Price Stability
Largely as a result of the common understanding of the theory and history of
monetary policy reviewed above, there is today a consensus among monetary
economists and central bankers that maintaining low inflation is the foundation of effective monetary policy. Moreover, there is an emerging consensus
that a central bank’s commitment to price stability should be strengthened by
legislation making low inflation the primary goal of monetary policy.39
37 Simple policy rule specifications studied with models estimated on historical data can be of
great practical value in benchmarking actual policy decisions. McCallum (1988) and Taylor (1993)
present two rules, respectively, that are particularly useful in this regard. McCallum models the
monetary base (currency plus bank reserves) as the Fed’s policy instrument, and has it responding
to a moving average of base velocity and departures of nominal GDP from a target path. Taylor
models the real short-term interest rate (the market interest rate minus expected inflation) as the
policy instrument, and has it responding to inflation and the gap between actual and potential
GDP.
Each specification has advantages and disadvantages. Taylor’s rule matches more closely
the way the Fed thinks of itself as operating. But McCallum’s rule makes clear that the ultimate
power of the Fed over the economy derives from its monopoly on the monetary base. McCallum’s
rule has the advantage that it could still be used if disinflation happened to push the market short
rate to zero, or if inflation expectations became excessively volatile. In either situation the Fed
might be unable to use the real short rate as its policy instrument.
38 See Board of Governors “Monetary Policy Report to Congress” (1994, 1995, and 1996).
39 In 1995, Senator Connie Mack introduced a bill that would make low inflation the primary
goal of monetary policy. In 1989, Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan testified in favor of a prior
resolution that would have mandated a price stability objective for the Fed. Academics as diverse
as Blinder (1995), Fischer (1994), and Friedman (1962) all agree that the Fed should be given
some sort of mandate for low inflation. The remarkable convergence of professional thinking
in favor of a mandate was evident at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s August 1996
conference on price stability. See Achieving Price Stability (1996).
Inflation targeting is employed by a number of central banks around the world. See Leiderman
and Svensson (1995).
16
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
The recommended priority for price stability derives not from any belief
in its intrinsic value relative to other goals such as full employment and economic growth. Price stability should take priority for two reasons: first, the Fed
actually has the power to guarantee it over the long run, and second, monetary
policy encourages employment and economic growth in the long run mostly
by controlling inflation.40 Also, and this is very important, a mandate for price
stability would not prevent the Fed from taking the kinds of policy actions it
takes today to stabilize employment and output in the short run. What it would
do is discipline the Fed to justify these actions against a commitment to protect
the purchasing power of money.
Two often-repeated objections to a mandate for low inflation deserve mention here. One is the notion that low inflation targeting is largely irrelevant because two enormous oil price increases in the 1970s—in 1973/74 and 1979/80—
were responsible for the worst inflation of that period.41 The claim continues
that our success in controlling inflation will be determined by whether we
have large oil price shocks in the future or not. Clearly, oil price increases
create a problem for the economy: the higher price of oil diverts expenditure
to oil products and raises real costs throughout the economy, with adverse
consequences for demand and employment in non-oil sectors.
The economy must adjust to the higher real cost of oil in any case. The
problem for a central bank is to make sure that the adjustment problem is not
compounded with monetary instability. A central bank with a mandate for low
inflation is more likely to resist excessive monetary accommodation than one
with a weaker commitment to price stability. This is because an oil price shock
will be less likely to set in motion wage and price increases that the central
bank will be inclined to accommodate. The Fed was in just this predicament
when the 1970s oil price shocks hit, since rising inflation trends were already
well established before each oil shock. The destabilizing effects on inflation,
inflation expectations, and employment and output would almost surely have
been less troublesome in a climate of stable inflation.
A second objection to a mandate for low inflation is that it would hold
back economic growth. In fact, the opposite is more nearly true. In terms of
the earlier discussion of money demand and supply, trend growth of national
output continually raises the demand for money, and the Fed accommodates
the growing demand for money at stable prices.
Would monetary policy prevent the economy from growing faster if labor
productivity unexpectedly surged? Not for long, because unemployment would
begin to rise as businesses found that they could meet demand with less labor
40 Rudebusch and Wilcox (1994) report empirical evidence on inflation and productivity
growth. Dotsey and Ireland (1996) study the question in a quantitative, theoretical model.
41 Oil prices rose from around $3 to $12 a barrel during the 1973/74 oil price shock, and
from about $15 to over $35 in 1979/80.
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
17
input. And the Fed would resist rising unemployment by easing monetary
policy to encourage faster growth in aggregate demand. In short, the Fed’s
policy procedures do not “target growth.” A mandate for price stability would
allow the Fed to naturally and automatically accommodate an increase in productivity growth over time.
Ultimately the Fed can only secure full credibility for low inflation with the
backing of the public. The public’s misunderstanding of the tactics of monetary
policy is particularly troublesome. For instance, accusations that the Fed was
“busting ghosts” when it ran short-term interest rates up in 1994 threatened to
undermine support for policy actions that were clearly called for.42 Preemptive
policy actions in 1994 laid the foundation for continued economic expansion.
The task ahead must be to broaden and deepen the public’s understanding and
support for the strategy and tactics of monetary policy and to lock in credibility
for low inflation with a legislative mandate.
6. CONCLUSION
American monetary policy has come full circle in the 20th century. Early in
the century the nation overcame a long-standing distrust of government intervention in the monetary system to establish a central bank. The Federal
Reserve embodied the idea that discretionary monetary policy could improve
on the rules of the gold standard, rules that were seen as unduly restrictive.
We now know that the faith then placed in discretion over rules was somewhat
misplaced. Today, monetary economists and central bankers alike understand
that effective monetary policy must be built on a consistent commitment to low
inflation.
Numerous lessons were learned on the 20th century odyssey. The most important is that the Federal Reserve, through its management of monetary policy,
is responsible for inflation. This became clear partly as a result of advances
in monetary theory and partly as a result of evidence on money demand and
money supply. It was also the result of a learning process in which nonmonetary
approaches to controlling inflation were seen to fail, and the monetary approach
succeeded.
Discretionary monetary policy actions can be invaluable in fighting a financial crisis or a weak economy. But we learned that the promise of discretion
can be realized fully only in the context of a monetary policy that makes price
stability a priority. Otherwise discretion leads inexorably to go-stop policy that
brings rising and unstable inflation and inflation expectations, with adverse
consequences for interest rates and employment.
42 See Thurow (1994). By successfully keeping inflation in check, preemptive policy actions
necessarily appear to be busting ghosts. So the appearance of ghost busting is a consequence of
good monetary policy.
18
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
The go-stop experience taught that the Fed should fight inflation by tightening monetary policy before price pressures break out into the open. Waiting
until inflation has begun to rise may better assure public support for higher
short-term interest rates. But delayed tightening allows higher inflation to
become more firmly established, requiring even higher rates to choke it off,
with a greater risk of recession.
An emerging consensus among monetary economists and central bankers
supports the need for a legislative mandate to make low inflation the primary
goal of monetary policy. That recommendation has broad backing for three
reasons. A central bank can guarantee low inflation over time. Monetary policy
most effectively stabilizes employment over the business cycle when it has
credibility for low inflation. And full credibility for low inflation needs the
support of a legislative mandate.
Monetary policy has come of age in the 20th century in the sense that
monetary economists and central bankers have come to terms with the past—
lessons have been learned and principles have been applied successfully. The
country should build on that professional consensus to broaden the public’s understanding and support for price stability and the preemptive policy procedures
to sustain low inflation. The nation has the opportunity to bring a tumultuous
chapter in its monetary history to a close. It should grasp that opportunity and
enjoy the benefits that sustained price stability would bring.
REFERENCES
Achieving Price Stability. A Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City. Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 1996.
“A Guide to FRB/US: A Macroeconomic Model of the United States.”
Manuscript. Macroeconomic and Quantitative Studies, Division of Research and Statistics, Federal Reserve Board: July 1996.
Ball, Laurence. “Credible Disinflation with Staggered Price-Setting,” American
Economic Review, vol. 84 (March 1994), pp. 282–89.
Barro, Robert J., and David B. Gordon. “Rules, Discretion and Reputation in
a Model of Monetary Policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 12
(July 1983), pp. 101–21.
Blinder, Alan. “Central Banking in Theory and Practice,” The Marshall
Lecture, Cambridge University, Federal Reserve Board, processed May
1995.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. “Monetary Policy Report
to Congress,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, July 1994, February 1995, and
August 1996.
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
19
. “Announcements,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 65 (November
1979), pp. 830–32.
Broaddus, Alfred, and Marvin Goodfriend. “Base Drift and the Longer
Run Growth of M1: Experience from a Decade of Monetary Targeting,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol. 70
(November/December 1984), pp. 3–14.
Bronfenbrenner, Martin, and Franklyn D. Holzman. “Survey of Inflation
Theory,” American Economic Review, vol. 53 (September 1963), pp.
593–661.
Cagan, Phillip. Determinants and Effects of Changes in the Stock of Money,
1875–1960. New York: Columbia University Press, 1965.
Cook, Timothy. “Determinants of the Federal Funds Rate: 1979–1982,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol. 75 (January/February
1989), pp. 3–19.
Dotsey, Michael, and Peter Ireland. “The Welfare Cost of Inflation in General
Equilibrium,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 37 (February 1996),
pp. 29–47.
Economic Report of the President. Washington: Government Printing Office,
1996.
Feldstein, Martin. “The Costs and Benefits of Going from Low Inflation to
Price Stability,” NBER Working Paper 5469. Forthcoming in C. Romer
and D. Romer, eds., Monetary Policy and Inflation. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1997.
Fellner, William. Towards a Reconstruction of Macroeconomics: Problems of
Theory and Policy. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute for
Public Policy Research, 1976.
Fischer, Stanley. “Modern Central Banking,” in Forrest Capie, Stanley
Fischer, Charles Goodhart, and Norbert Schnadt, eds., The Future of
Central Banking: The Tercentenary Symposium of the Bank of England.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994.
Friedman, Milton. “The Quantity Theory of Money,” in John Eatwell, Peter
Newman, and Murray Milgate, eds., The New Palgrave Dictionary of
Money and Finance. New York: The Stockton Press, 1987.
. “Monetary Policy for the 1980s,” in John H. Moore, ed., To
Promote Prosperity: U.S. Domestic Policy in the Mid-1980s. Stanford:
Hoover Institution Press, 1984.
. An Economist’s Protest: Columns in Political Economy. New
Jersey: Thomas Horton and Company, 1972.
20
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
. Statement before U.S. Congress, House of Representatives,
Committee on Banking and Currency in The Federal Reserve System After
Fifty Years. Subcommittee on Domestic Finance. Hearings, 88 Cong. 2
Sess. Washington: Government Printing Office, 1964.
. “Should There Be an Independent Monetary Authority?” in
Leland Yeager, ed., In Search of a Monetary Constitution. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1962.
, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United
States, 1867–1960. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1963.
Goodfriend, Marvin. “Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation Scare Problem:
1979–1992,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly,
vol. 79 (Winter 1993), pp. 1–24.
. “Central Banking Under the Gold Standard,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 29 (Autumn 1988), pp. 85–124.
, and William Whelpley. “Federal Funds: Instrument of Federal
Reserve Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review,
vol. 72 (September/October 1986), pp. 3–11.
Greenspan, Alan. Statement before the U.S. Congress, House of Representatives, Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy of the Committee on
Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs, Zero Inflation. Hearing, 101 Cong.
1 Sess. Washington: Government Printing Office, 1989.
Hawtrey, R. G. A Century of Bank Rate. London: Longran, 1938.
Heller, Walter W. New Dimensions of Political Economy. Cambridge, Mass.:
Harvard University Press, 1966.
Hetzel, Robert L. “The Rules versus Discretion Debate over Monetary Policy
in the 1920s,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol.
71 (November/December 1985), pp. 3–14.
King, Robert G., and Mark W. Watson. “The Post-War U.S. Phillips Curve: A
Revisionist Econometric History,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series
on Public Policy, vol. 41 (December 1994), pp. 157–219.
Kosters, Marvin H. Controls and Inflation: The Economic Stabilization
Program in Retrospect. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute
for Public Policy Research, 1975.
Lacker, Jeffrey M. “Stored Value Cards: Costly Private Substitutes for
Government Currency,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly, vol. 82 (Summer 1996), pp. 1–25.
Leiderman, Leonardo, and Lars Svensson, eds. Inflation Targets. London:
Center for Economic Policy Research, 1995.
M. Goodfriend: Monetary Policy Comes of Age
21
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. “On the Welfare Cost of Inflation,” Center for Economic
Policy Research, Stanford University, February 1994.
. “Money Demand in the United States: A Quantitative Review,”
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 29 (Autumn
1988), pp. 137–68.
McCallum, Bennett T. “Robustness Properties of a Rule for Monetary Policy,”
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 29 (Autumn
1988), pp. 173–204.
, and Marvin S. Goodfriend. “Demand for Money: Theoretical
Analysis,” in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London:
Macmillan Press, 1987, reprinted in Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Review, vol. 74 (January/February 1988), pp. 16–24.
Meltzer, Allan. “The Demand for Money: The Evidence from the Time Series,”
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 71 (June 1963), pp. 219–46.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini, eds. Monetary and Fiscal Policy,
Vol. 1: Credibility. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1994.
Phillips, A. W. “The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change
of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957,” Economica,
vol. 25 (November 1958), pp. 283–99.
Poole, William. Money and the Economy: A Monetarist View. United States:
Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, 1978.
Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer. “Does Monetary Policy Matter?
A New Test in the Spirit of Friedman and Schwartz,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 4 (1989), pp. 121–70.
Rudebusch, Glenn, and David Wilcox. “Productivity and Inflation: Evidence
and Interpretations,” Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C., 1994.
Sargent, Thomas J. Rational Expectations and Inflation. New York: Harper
and Row, 1986.
Schreft, Stacey L. “Credit Controls: 1980,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Review, vol. 76 (November/December 1990), pp. 25–55.
Schultz, George P., and Robert Z. Aliber, eds. Guidelines: Informal Controls
and the Market Place. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1966.
Taylor, John B. “Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice,” CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39 (December 1993),
pp. 195–214.
. “Establishing Credibility: A Rational Expectations Viewpoint,”
American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, vol. 72 (May 1982),
pp. 81–85.
22
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
Thurow, Lester C. “The Fed Goes Ghostbusting,” The New York Times,
May 6, 1994.
Tobin, James. “The Cruel Dilemma,” in Arthur M. Okun, ed., Problems of
the Modern Economy: The Battle Against Unemployment. Revised. New
York: W. W. Norton and Company, Inc., 1972.
Wolman, Alexander. “Zero Inflation and the Friedman Rule: A Welfare
Analysis,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
(forthcoming 1997).