ii
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
This study was conducted within the Greater Access to Trade Expansion (GATE)
program funded by the United States Agency for International Development (USAID). I
would like to thank Peter Davis, Sarah Gammage, Marceline White and Ingrid Woolard
for their comments and suggestions. The opinions and errors in this paper are my own
and not necessarily those of IFPRI or USAID.
iii
iv
TABLE OF CONTENTS
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ................................................................................................. iii
TABLE OF CONTENTS.....................................................................................................v
LIST OF TABLES AND FIGURES.................................................................................. vi
ABSTRACT...................................................................................................................... vii
I.
INTRODUCTION ...................................................................................................9
II.
TRADE POLICY, GROWTH AND EMPLOYMENT IN SOUTH AFRICA......12
Trade Reform in South Africa during the 1990s ...................................................12
Trade and Economic Growth .................................................................................14
Trade, Employment and Wages.............................................................................16
Gender Dimensions of Employment, Wages and Poverty.....................................18
III.
MODELING THE EFFECTS OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION ON MEN AND
WOMEN ................................................................................................................22
IV.
MODEL RESULTS ...............................................................................................28
Baseline Scenario...................................................................................................28
The Impact of Recent Trade Liberalization ...........................................................31
Future Gains from Trade Rationalization ..............................................................41
V.
CONCLUSION......................................................................................................44
REFERENCES ..................................................................................................................46
LIST OF DSGD DISCUSSION PAPERS.........................................................................50
v
LIST OF TABLES AND FIGURES
Tables
1.
Decomposition of Economic Growth, 1985-2003 .................................................15
2.
Employment by Gender and Sector, 1995 and 2003 .............................................19
3.
Monthly Wage or Labor Remuneration by Gender and Sector, 1995 and 2003 ...20
4.
Macroeconomic Results from the Simulations, 1993-2003...................................29
5.
Sectoral GDP Growth Results from the Simulations, 1993-2003 .........................30
6.
Observed Changes in Tariffs under Trade Liberalization, 1993-2003 ..................32
7.
Employment Results from the Simulations, 1993-2003 ........................................35
8.
Factor Employment Shares within Sectors, 1993 ..................................................36
9.
Changes in the Female-to-Male Wage Ratio in the Simulations, 1993-2003........38
10.
Changes in the Poverty Headcount from the Simulations, 1993-2003..................39
Figures
1.
Nominal Tariffs and Surcharges, 1988-2004.........................................................13
2.
Household Population Distribution by National Expenditure Deciles, 1995 ........21
3.
Additional Per Capita Expenditure Relative to the Base Scenario, 1993-2003.....43
vi
ABSTRACT
Trade liberalization is a central part of South Africa’s post-Apartheid
development strategy. However, despite considerable reforms, the country has failed to
generate pro-poor growth, with both unemployment and inequality worsening over the
last ten years. This has raised concern that trade liberalization may have worked against
the country’s development objectives. This study uses a dynamic general equilibrium and
microsimulation model to assess the effects of trade liberalization on growth,
employment and poverty in South Africa. More specifically, it examines how men and
women have been affected differently and whether liberalization has contributed to the
faster rise in female unemployment and poverty. The results suggest that trade policies
have not contributed to increased poverty and that trade-induced technological change
has accelerated growth. However, liberalization has changed the sectoral structure of
production and has exacerbated income inequality. While male and female workers have
benefited from trade-induced growth, it is male-headed households who have benefited
more from rising factor incomes. Trade reforms have however contributed to the
observed decline in the gender wage gap, but this has been driven by rising employment
amongst higher-skilled female workers. As such, the decline in poverty amongst femaleheaded households has remained small. While further liberalization may increase growth
and reduce poverty, it is men and male-headed households who are more likely to benefit.
These findings suggest that, while there is no trade-off between trade reform and poverty
reduction, the country should not rely on further liberalization to generate pro-poor
growth or address the prevailing inequalities between different population groups, such as
men and women.
vii
viii
HAS TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN SOUTH AFRICA AFFECTED
MEN AND WOMEN DIFFERENTLY?
James Thurlow 1
I.
INTRODUCTION
The 1990s marked a turning point for South Africa. The country emerged from
Apartheid and reentered the global economy after more than a decade of isolation.
However, the new democratic government inherited the challenges of slow growth and
severe poverty and inequality, thus demanding a shift in the country’s development path.
In 1995 the government unveiled its ‘Growth, Employment and Redistribution’ (GEAR)
strategy (Republic of South Africa, 1995). The objective of this broad package of policies
was to establish a “fast-growing economy that creates employment and encourages a
redistribution of incomes in favor of the poor”. To achieve the necessary growth, GEAR
called for a “transformation towards a competitive outward-oriented economy”.
Accordingly, trade liberalization has been one of the central policies of South Africa’s
development strategy over the last ten years.
Trade liberalization since 1994 has been pronounced, reflecting the government’s
strong commitment to outward-oriented industrialization. However, the country has so far
failed to generate pro-poor growth (Hoogeveen and Ozler, 2005). Despite some success
in job creation during the 1990s, both unemployment and poverty have worsened due to
rapid increases in the workforce and falling real wages (Casale et al., 2004).2 This
coexistence of substantial trade liberalization and rising poverty raises concern that trade
policies may have worked against the country’s development objectives and questions the
government’s commitment to further liberalization. Moreover, the 1990s saw sharp
differences in economic outcomes between men and women. The rapid ‘feminization’ of
1
James Thurlow is a Post Doctoral Fellow at IFPRI’s Development Strategy and Governance Division.
2
Woolard and Leibbrant (2001) review changes in poverty in South Africa. Recent evidence suggests that
the rise in poverty during the 1990s may have slowed (Meth and Dias, 2004) or possibly reversed (Van der
Berg et al., 2005).
9
the labor market has been only partially offset by faster growth in female employment
and a narrowing gender wage gap. As a result, unemployment amongst women has risen
rapidly and poverty has remained most severe amongst female-headed households.3
While the increased participation of women in the labor market may reflect improved
opportunities and a reversal of past discrimination, it has also increased the susceptibility
of women to changes in trade and industrial policies. Therefore, determining the effects
of trade liberalization on employment and wages, and examining how men and women
are affected differently, is important for understanding why the current development
strategy has failed to reduce poverty and inequality. Accordingly, this study assesses the
impact of trade liberalization on employment and poverty amongst men and women in
South Africa.
Section 2 provides an overview of South Africa’s trade policies over the last ten
years. This section also considers how growth, employment and wages have changed
during the 1990s, and reviews the existing empirical evidence on liberalization’s impact
on each of these aspects. In particular, the different experiences of men and women are
considered, as well as variations in their employment patterns and wages. Although a
number of studies have examined specific aspects of the recent liberalization episode,
few studies have attempted to reconcile the evidence to provide a comprehensive
assessment of its impact on poverty. Section 3 describes the dynamic general equilibrium
and microsimulation model that is used in this study to jointly assess the impact of trade
liberalization on growth, employment and poverty, and to examine how trade policies
have influenced the distribution of incomes across men and women. Section 4 presents
the results from the model simulations. Three scenarios are considered: the static effects
of reducing tariffs; the dynamics gains from liberalization; and the likely impact of
further tariff rationalization. The final section summarizes the influence of past and future
3
Headship is based on the de jure head of the household. Female-headed households accounted for 30.7
percent of all households in 1995. Disproportionately more female heads are African and over the age of
35. This is true in both rural and urban areas, although women are far more likely to head households in
rural areas than are men. This distribution of headship may reflect HIV/AIDS, whose prevalence is highest
amongst Africans and in rural areas.
10
trade policies on men and women’s livelihoods, and reconsiders the trade-off between
liberalization and poverty reduction.
11
II.
TRADE POLICY, GROWTH AND EMPLOYMENT IN SOUTH AFRICA
South Africa has substantially changed its trade regime over the last three
decades. Prior to 1970 the country adopted a policy of import-substitution
industrialization. Since then trade policy has shifted towards achieving greater openness,
first through the stimulation of exports during the 1970s and 1980s, and then later
through a more concerted attempt at trade liberalization during the 1990s. This section
focuses on this more recent period and reviews the nature and extent of trade reforms
over the last ten years. It then examines the country’s growth and trade performance and
its effects on employment and wages amongst men and women.
Trade Reform in South Africa during the 1990s
Despite previous attempts at trade reform, South Africa entered the 1990s with
high and variable tariffs and a complex system of quantitative restrictions. Although the
1990s was a period of unprecedented trade liberalization, the earliest years of the decade
saw an increase in protection. The average nominal tariff rate climbed to almost 20
percent by 1993 and varied considerably across commodities (Figure 1). Unlike most
developing countries, South Africa imposed high tariffs on consumer products and lower
tariffs on imported machinery and capital goods. This uneven structure of protection
contributed to the country’s long-standing dependence on exports as a means of financing
imported investment goods. The resulting current account constraint was exacerbated by
the introduction of sanctions during the 1980s. The Apartheid government responded by
introducing ad hoc import surcharges and actively promoting exports.
Trade liberalization did not start in earnest until the new government came into
power. Import surcharges were removed on capital goods in 1994 and consumer goods in
1995 (Tsikata, 1999). The pace of liberalization culminated in the 1995 Uruguay Round
and an offer to the World Trade Organization consisting of a five-year tariff reduction
and rationalization program (Cassim et al., 2004). The government’s commitment to
trade reforms was reflected in its proposal to halve average tariffs in manufacturing.
However, with the exception of consumables, initial tariff rates were already below the
12
offered rates and special dispensation was granted to the ‘sensitive’ textiles and vehicles
sectors, which were given eight years to comply to the reform program. The proposed
rationalization program involved removing quantitative restrictions, phasing-out export
incentives, and reducing the number of tariff lines and applied tariff rates.
Figure 1.
Nominal Tariffs and Surcharges, 1988-2004
Unweighted average tariff rate (%)
25
20
Consumables
15
10
All goods
Capital goods
5
Agriculture
Mining
0
1988
1990
92
94
96
98
2000
02
04
Source: Own calculations using Customs and Excise data provided by Edwards (2005).
Note: Rates are unweighted and include import surcharges. Quantitative restrictions have been converted
into their ad valorum tariff equivalent. Consumables include processed food, beverages, textiles, clothing
and furniture. Capital goods include machinery and vehicles, as well as intermediate goods such as
chemicals and metal products.
The reduction in tariffs during the 1990s was pronounced. The largest absolute
declines were on consumables. Quantitative restrictions were replaced with their tariff
equivalents, although in the case of agriculture this led to an increase in protection. The
export incentive scheme was abolished by 1997 and the number of tariff lines had
declined by 40 percent by 1999 (Lewis, 2001). Average tariff rates have halved and the
country has moved towards its proposed rationalization targets. However, the pace of
reforms has slowed considerably. In 1999 there were still 47 different applied tariff rates,
with a highest rate of 55 percent (Lewis, 2001). This falls far short of the proposed six
13
tariff bands. The removal of export incentives meant that trade reforms had a negative
effect on the anti-export bias (Tsikata, 1999). Furthermore, the continued favoring of
consumables caused the effective protection rate to increase (Fedderke and Vase, 2001).
Therefore, the system of protection still remains complex in spite of the successful
opening of the economy. Accordingly, future reforms are likely to focus on tariff
rationalization and the strengthening of regional trading agreements (Cassim et al., 2004;
Thurlow, 2006b).
Trade and Economic Growth
The South African economy performed poorly during the years leading up to the
recent liberalization episode. Gross domestic product (GDP) grew at just over one
percent per year during 1985-1993, which failed to offset two percent population growth
(Table 1). Investment fell during this period due to political instability and declining
foreign capital inflows. However, the depletion of inventories allowed the capital stock to
accumulate and contribute positively to overall growth. By contrast, labor employment
and total factor productivity (TFP) were relatively stagnant.4 Agriculture, mining and
manufacturing either grew slowly or contracted in spite of subsidized exports. What
growth did exist was primarily due to public services and government expenditures.
The country’s performance changed dramatically during the trade liberalization
period. Most notable was the acceleration of economic growth driven by rising factor
productivity. A number of studies find that this increased productivity was partly a result
of trade liberalization (Arora and Bhundia, 2003; Fedderke, 2003). For example, Jonsson
and Subramanian (2001) econometrically examine the relationship between nominal
tariff reductions and average TFP growth during the 1990s. They find a strong and robust
relationship in which a one percentage point decline in tariff rates raised the TFP growth
rate by 0.74 percentage points. Harding and Rattso (2005) update the study and find its
conclusions robust. Trade liberalization therefore appears to have contributed positively
to the accelerated growth of the 1990s.
4
TFP is measured as the simple Solow residual between factor accumulation and GDP growth.
14
Table 1.
Decomposition of Economic Growth, 1985-2003
Share of GDP (%)
1985
1993
2003
Annual Change (%)
1985-93
1993-03
Real gross domestic product (GDP)
Private consumption
Investment
Government consumption
Exports
Imports
100.0
61.2
15.7
19.3
19.7
-15.9
100.0
62.8
12.2
21.4
23.0
-19.5
100.0
64.0
16.9
19.0
26.1
-26.0
1.1
1.3
-0.7
2.7
2.3
3.5
2.7
2.7
3.9
1.4
4.3
3.9
Real gross domestic product (GDP)
Agriculture
Mining
Manufacturing
Energy and construction
Private services
Public services
100.0
4.5
8.6
22.0
7.0
42.9
14.9
100.0
4.7
7.6
20.6
6.6
43.7
16.8
100.0
4.0
5.5
19.8
6.7
50.9
13.2
1.1
0.8
-1.2
0.4
1.0
1.3
2.6
2.7
1.5
-0.7
2.2
2.7
4.4
0.1
Real gross domestic product (GDP)
Capital
Labor
Total factor productivity (TFP)
100.0
38.5
61.5
-
100.0
43.0
57.0
-
100.0
49.2
50.8
-
1.1
1.1
0.1
0.6
2.7
1.3
0.9
1.7
-
-
-
2.3
2.0
Population growth
Source: Own calculations using data from SARB (2006), TIPS (2006), and SASID (2005).
Note: All measures are in constant 2000 prices.
Both imports and exports increased rapidly during the liberalization period. The
empirical evidence suggests that higher export growth was due to changes in trade
policies (Fedderke and Vaze, 2001; Edwards and Golub, 2002; Edwards, 2003).
However, the depreciation of the real exchange rate during this time may have also been
an important factor in determining export competitiveness (Edwards and Golub, 2002).
Furthermore, the removal of trade sanctions at the end of Apartheid may have accounted
for some of the sudden increase in trade experienced during the mid-1990s (Tsikata,
1999; Edwards and Golub, 2002), although the evidence remains ambiguous (Golub and
Ceglowski, 2002). Some studies find a positive relationship between exports and
productivity growth (Belli et al., 1993; Jonsson and Subramanian 2001), possibly because
increased import competition and imported capital goods have resulted in productivityenhancing technological change (Black, 1996; Edwards, 2003). Therefore, one of the
15
mechanisms through which liberalization appears to have influenced economic growth is
through its stimulation of exports, import competition, and improved access to foreign
technology.
Finally, investment also grew strongly during the liberalization period. This is
likely due to a resurgence of foreign investment after the reestablishment of political and
economic stability. However, Jonsson and Subramanian (2001) find that trade
liberalization may have contributed positively to faster capital accumulation due to
cheaper imports. Despite higher investment growth, the increase in capital accumulation
was smaller then than the increase in either labor employment or productivity. This is
reflected in the sectoral structure of growth. Although the more capital-intensive mining
and manufacturing sectors grew faster during the 1990s, it was the more labor-intensive
service sectors that were the primary sources of overall economic growth.
The 1990s therefore represents at least a structural break if not a positive turningpoint for economic growth in South Africa. The stagnation of the 1980s was reversed,
with renewed growth driven by productivity gains from the augmentation of technology
and greater efficiency (Fedderke, 2001). Trade performance improved and foreign
markets became increasingly important. More importantly for this study, there is
considerable empirical evidence to suggest that trade liberalization enhanced
productivity. However, this positive effect on economic growth is insufficient evidence to
conclude that liberalization has had a positive effect on employment and wages and
household incomes.
Trade, Employment and Wages
Unemployment increased during the 1990s, despite the country’s stronger
economic performance. Under the broad definition, which includes the non-searching
unemployed, the national unemployment rate increased from 29.4 to 42.9 percent during
1995-2003 (Casale et al., 2004). Rising unemployment affected all population groups and
was caused by labor force participation rising considerably faster than job creation.
Poverty also increased during 1995-2000, especially amongst the country’s poorest
16
population (Hoogeveen and Ozler, 2005). This rising unemployment and poverty raises
concern over the possible effects of foreign competition and structural adjustment on
labor employment and wages.
Most studies find a negative relationship between liberalization and net aggregate
employment. For example, Bell and Cattaneo (1997) and Edwards (1999) use a factor
content approach and find that import penetration has reduced employment. However,
these studies also find that this effect has been small. This is supported by Edwards
(2001a), who finds that employment losses from import penetration were matched by
gains from export growth, and by Jonsson and Subramanian (2001) who find an
insignificant relationship between tariff-changes and sectoral employment. Furthermore,
Edwards (2003) uses firm-level data and finds that large firms affected by trade
liberalization tended to reduce employment, but that there is no evidence of this amongst
smaller firms. Therefore, the empirical evidence suggests that liberalization has had little
or no effect on net aggregate employment during the 1990s.
Movements in real wages indicate that changes in the labor market affected skillgroups differently (Edwards and Abdi, 2003). A number of studies have focused on the
factor-bias of trade-induced changes in net employment. Bhorat (1999) finds that
increased trade during the 1990s only benefited skilled labor, with lower-skilled
employment declining. Edwards (2002) decomposes the structure of production and trade
and finds that, although small, the effect of increased trade was to raise the skill-intensity
of production. Edwards (2003) uses firm-level data and concludes that trade-induced
technological change explains some of the shift towards skill-intensive production and
falling unskilled labor employment. These studies suggest that focusing on the effect of
liberalization on aggregate employment hides the differential effect of trade on
employment and wages across workers.
Trade liberalization’s bias towards higher-skilled labor may be due to the rising
capital-intensity of production that took place during the 1990s. Jonsson and
Subramanian (2001) find a positive relationship between tariff-reductions and sectoral
capital growth. Since no structural relationship is specified, the authors tentatively
17
conclude that sectors experiencing reduced import protection might have used existing
capital more efficiently. By contrast, Edwards (2003) uses firm-level data and finds that
firms affected by trade liberalization invested more heavily in capital equipment. This
corroborates observed labor trends, since increased investment has been found to be
associated with a rising skill intensity of employment (Fedderke et al., 2003).
The above studies have focused on the effects of liberalization on net employment
and do not examine the adjustment costs associated with trade reforms. Therefore, while
the empirical evidence finds that liberalization has had little effect on the level of
employment, it does not suggest that there has not been any ‘churning’ of the labor
market resulting from sectoral changes in the structure of production. Furthermore, while
the evidence suggests that higher-skilled workers have benefited more than lower-skilled
workers, the extremely high level of unemployment in South Africa makes it difficult to
draw inferences about the effects of trade on the distribution of household incomes and
poverty. Given the focus of this study on the distributional effects of liberalization, it is
necessary to go beyond the existing literature and examine not only aggregate growth,
employment and wages, but also household incomes and expenditures.
Gender Dimensions of Employment, Wages and Poverty
Male workers account for the largest share of total employment in South Africa.
However, employment grew faster for women than for men during the 1990s (Table 2).
This was offset by increased female participation or the ‘feminization’ the labor force,
such that the broad female unemployment rate increased from 37.8 to 49.0 percent during
1995-2003 (Casale and Posel, 2005). While unemployment grew more rapidly for men,
the male unemployment rate in 2003 remained significantly lower at 36.2 percent. Apart
from changes in overall unemployment, there were also substantial differences in sectoral
employment across male and female workers, especially in the primary and secondary
sectors. Male employment increased faster in the mining sector, while female
employment grew in the agricultural sector. Both men and women experienced stagnant
employment in the manufacturing and public sectors and rapidly expanding employment
18
in private services. The latter was particularly important for women, since almost three
quarters of total female employment in 1995 was in this sector. Manufacturing
employment was equally important for men and women, suggesting that both male and
female workers were likely to be affected by trade liberalization.
Table 2.
Employment by Gender and Sector, 1995 and 2003
Employment Numbers
1995 (1000s)
Men
Women
Employment Shares
1995 (%)
Men
Women
Annual Change
1995-2003 (%)
Men Women
All sectors
5,621
3,638
100.0
100.0
0.8
2.4
Agriculture
Mining
Manufacturing
Energy and construction
Private services
Public services
983
415
954
487
2,219
563
262
19
465
39
2,652
202
17.5
7.4
17.0
8.7
39.5
10.0
7.2
0.5
12.8
1.1
72.9
5.5
-2.4
2.6
-0.5
2.9
2.8
-4.4
3.8
0.4
0.1
11.5
2.7
-2.3
Source: Own calculations using the 1995 OHS and IES (StatsSA, 1996a and 1996b) and own estimates
from the 2003 (Sept) LFS (StatsSA, 2004) provided by Casale et al. (2004).
Note: Weights have been revised according to the 2001 population census and thus differ from Casale et
al. (2004).
In terms of livelihoods, rising employment was offset by falling real wages (Table
3). This is partly due to the expansion of the informal sector, which may have accounted
for as much as a half of the new jobs created during 1995-2003 (Casale et al., 2005).5
‘Informalization’ has been more pronounced for men, with formal sector employment
rising faster for female workers. Although men’s wages have remained considerably
higher than women’s, they fell at an average annual rate of 2.5 percent during 1995-2003,
compared to 0.6 percent for women. More importantly for this study, both men and
women experienced falling wages in the manufacturing sector.
Therefore, while
declining wages did not offset total increases in employment, the net effect on workers in
the manufacturing sector was negative.
This was more so for men, whose total
manufacturing wage bill declined by 2.9 percent per year, compared to 1.7 percent for
women. Overall, there has been a decline in wage gap between men and women,
5
Part of the rise of the informal sector undoubtedly reflects improvements in survey design and capture.
19
although male workers on average still earn substantially more than female workers. This
study aims to determine the extent to which trade liberalization has contributed to falling
manufacturing employment and the differential changes in labor incomes experienced by
men and women.
Table 3.
Monthly Wage or Labor Remuneration by Gender and Sector, 1995
and 2003
Monthly Wage
1995 (in 2000 Prices)
Men
Women
Female-to-Male
Wage Ratio (%)
1995
2003
Annual Real Change
1995-2003 (%)
Men
Women
All sectors
3,744
2,266
60.5
70.4
-2.5
-0.6
Agriculture
Mining
Manufacturing
Energy and construction
Private services
Public services
1,443
3,207
4,221
3,103
4,553
3,825
820
2,960
2,192
2,584
2,367
2,969
56.8
92.3
51.9
83.3
52.0
77.6
52.8
98.5
54.6
96.2
64.3
82.2
-3.9
-1.5
-2.4
-5.4
-3.1
2.7
-4.8
-0.7
-1.8
-3.7
-0.5
3.5
Source: Own calculations using the 1995 OHS and IES (StatsSA, 1996a and 1996b) and own estimates
from the 2003 (Sept) LFS (StatsSA, 2004) provided by Casale et al. (2004).
Note: Real wages for 1995 and 2003 are in constant 2000 prices.
Poverty in South Africa is also severe, with 58.4 percent of the population living
below the basic needs poverty line in 1995.6 Poverty falls disproportionately on Africanheaded households and rural areas. As with employment and wages, poverty is unevenly
distributed across men and women. Three out of four people living in female-headed
households in 1995 were poor, compared to two out of four in male-headed households.7
This unequal distribution of incomes also exists at higher income levels, with a smaller
share of the richest population living in female-headed households (Figure 2). Therefore,
not only have women become more susceptible to changes in trade policies due to their
increased participation in labor markets, but they are also more vulnerable to poverty and
account for a significant share of inequality in South Africa.
6
The basic needs poverty line is R322 per person per month in 2000 prices (Hoogeveen and Ozler, 2005).
See Table 10 for a profile of poverty across male and female-headed households.
7
See Table 10 later in this study.
20
Figure 2.
Household Population Distribution by National Expenditure Deciles,
1995
Share of population (%)
Male-headed households
Female-headed households
15
10
5
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
National population-weighted per capita expenditure deciles
100
Source: Own calculations using the 1995 OHS and IES (StatsSA, 1996a and 1996b).
Note: Expenditure deciles are based on per capita expenditures and population weighted so that the
number of people in each decile equals ten percent of the total national population.
In summary, the empirical evidence suggests that trade reforms over the last
decade have been pronounced and contributed positively to economic growth. However,
import competition and technological change may have undermined employment,
especially amongst lower-skilled workers. Both men and women suffered stagnant or
falling manufacturing employment and wages since 1995. Accordingly, this study
examines whether liberalization has contributed to rising unemployment and poverty
experienced during the 1990s and to the unequal distribution of incomes and poverty
across male and female-headed households. Since trade reforms are a key component of
South Africa’s pro-poor growth strategy, this study also considers the implications of
completing the tariff rationalization program proposed by the government at the start of
the recent liberalization episode. However, to determine the effects of trade reform on
growth and poverty, it is necessary to employ an analytical method that can link
macroeconomic policies to their microeconomic impacts, and which captures
distributional changes across male- and female-headed households.
21
III. MODELING THE EFFECTS OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION ON
MEN AND WOMEN
A number of studies have reviewed the relationship between trade, gender and
poverty (Fontana, 2003; Fontana and Wood, 2000; Winters et al., 2004). McCulloch et al.
(2002) identify four transmission mechanisms: (i) the effects of reforms on trade,
productivity and growth; (ii) the impact of growth on employment, wages and household
incomes; (iii) the effects of falling import tariffs on relative prices and household
expenditures; and (iv) the effects of lower tariff revenues on government transfers. Each
of these interrelated mechanisms depends on the specific institutional and structural
characteristics of the households and markets within a given country. This section
describes the dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model that is used to
capture these various transmission mechanisms. The model is calibrated to a highlydisaggregated social accounting matrix (SAM), which is an economy-wide database
describing the detailed structure of the South African economy (Lofgren et al., 2001;
Thurlow, 2005). This 1993 SAM is purpose-built to capture the differences between male
and female workers and male- and female-headed households in South Africa (Thurlow,
2006a). Finally, the CGE model is linked to a microsimulation module, which allows it to
retain the full detail of the household survey when estimating changes in poverty and
inequality.
Drawing on the SAM, the CGE model identifies 39 sectors/commodities. Three
geographic regions are also separately identified, thus implying that there are a total of
117 productive activities or representative producers in the model. The three regions
include (i) the main coastal provinces (Western Cape, Eastern Cape, and KwaZuluNatal); (ii) the inland core industrial provinces (Gauteng and Mpumulanga); and (iii) the
remaining inland provinces (Northern Cape, Free State, North West, and Limpopo).
While production activities are defined at the regional level, an integrated national market
for commodities is assumed (i.e., the model does not capture interregional trade).
Imperfect factor markets are assumed for the 18 different types of labor identified in each
of the three regions. Labor is disaggregated across (i) three skill groups based on
22
occupational category (skilled, semi-skilled, and unskilled); (ii) three population groups
(African, White, and Other); and (iii) male and female workers. Skilled and white labor
have upward sloping labor supply curves reflecting their low unemployment rates (Casale
et al., 2005). Semi-skilled and unskilled, non-white labor are unemployed with sectorspecific real wages fixed relative to those of skilled workers. Labor markets are defined
at the regional level (i.e., labor is mobile across sectors within regions but not between
regions). By contrast, capital is nationally mobile. The 117 representative producers in
the model make decisions in order to maximize profits, but are constrained by factor
market imperfections when choosing inputs. A nested production system is employed. At
the lower levels, a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function is defined over
factors, while at the highest level, fixed-share intermediates are combined with factor
value-added
in
a
Leontief
specification.
Factor
substitution
elasticities
are
8
econometrically estimated and vary across activities (IDC, 1997). Within the nesting of
labor demand, a workers’ skill is assumed have the highest importance, followed by
population or racial group, and finally their gender. Profit maximization implies that the
factors receive income where marginal revenue equals marginal cost based on
endogenous relative prices. By disaggregating production across sectors and employment
across labor categories, the model captures how the changing structure of growth caused
by liberalization influences employment and wages amongst male and female workers
(i.e., the second transmission mechanism described above).
Within each sector, substitution possibilities exist between production for
domestic and foreign markets. This decision of producers is governed by a constant
elasticity of transformation (CET) function which distinguishes between exported and
domestic goods, and by doing so, captures any differences between the two products.
Profit maximization drives producers to sell in those markets where they can achieve the
8
The empirically estimated component of the elasticity governs substitution between capital and labor of
different skills. This is further decomposed across race and gender assuming that substitution between
genders is easier than across races. The high elasticity for gender (1.5) assumes that producers’ see little
difference between genders after controlling for skill, relative wages, and initial employment-intensities.
The latter reflects sector-specific technology (e.g., male-intensive mining) and past discrimination and
labor practices (e.g. female-intensive domestic services).
23
highest returns. These returns are based on domestic and export prices (where the latter is
determined by the world price times the exchange rate). Under the small-country
assumption, South Africa is assumed to face a perfectly elastic world demand at fixed
world prices. The final ratio of exports to domestic goods is determined by the
endogenous interaction of relative prices for these two types of commodities. Similar
substitution possibilities exist between imported and domestic goods under a CES
Armington specification. Such substitution can take place both in final and intermediates
usage. The Armington elasticities are econometrically estimated and vary across sectors,
with lower elasticities reflecting greater differences between domestic and imported
goods (IDC, 1997). Again under the small country assumption, South Africa is assumed
to face infinitely elastic world supply at fixed world prices. The final ratio of imports to
domestic goods is determined by the cost minimizing decision-making of domestic
demanders based on the relative prices of imports and domestic goods (both of which
include relevant tariffs and taxes). By capturing relative price movements and
substitution-effects, the model allows demand to shift towards cheaper imports following
tariff reductions (i.e., the third transmission mechanism).
The model also distinguishes between various ‘institutions’ within the South
African economy, including enterprises, the government, and many representative
households. These households are derived from the 1995 Income and Expenditure Survey
(IES) and 1995 October Household Survey (OHS) (StatsSA, 1996a and 1996b).
Households are disaggregated across the three regions and, within each region, according
to rural and urban areas, the population group and gender of the household head, and
across national expenditure deciles. In total there are 240 aggregate households in the
model. Households and enterprises receive income in payment for producers’ use of their
factors of production. Both institutions pay direct taxes to government (based on fixed tax
rates), save (based on marginal propensities to save), and make transfers to the rest of the
world. Enterprises pay their remaining income to households in the form of dividends.
Households, unlike enterprises, use their income to consume commodities under a linear
expenditure system (LES) of demand. The government receives income from imposing
24
import tariffs and sales and direct taxes, and then makes transfers to households,
enterprises and the rest of the world. The government also purchases commodities in the
form of government consumption expenditure, and the remaining income of government
is (dis)saved. All savings from households, enterprises, government and the rest of the
world (foreign savings) are collected in a savings pool from which current investment is
financed. By separating demand into its component parts and capturing government
income and expenditure patterns, the model considers how changes in tariff revenues
influence the fiscal budget. Furthermore, by retaining the detailed income and
expenditure patterns of households, the model can better capture distributional change.
The model includes three broad macroeconomic accounts: (i) the savings and
investment account; (ii) the current account, and (iii) the government balance. In order to
balance these accounts, it is necessary to specify a set of ‘closure’ rules, which provide
the mechanism through which macroeconomic balance is achieved. Based on evidence
for South Africa, a savings-driven closure is assumed to balance the savings-investment
account (Nel, 2003). Under this closure, the marginal propensities to save of households
and enterprises are fixed, and real investment quantities adjust to ensure that the level of
investment and savings are equal at equilibrium. For the current account it was assumed
that a flexible exchange rate adjusts in order to maintain a fixed level of foreign savings.
In other words, the external balance is held fixed in foreign currency and the government
cannot borrow abroad to replace falling tariff revenues. For the government account, the
level of direct and indirect tax rates, as well as real government consumption expenditure,
are held constant. As such the balance on the government budget is assumed to adjust to
ensure that public expenditures equal receipts. The model assumes that the government
does not reduce transfers to households due to falling tariff revenues, but rather borrows
domestically through deficit financing (i.e., the fourth transmission mechanism).
In order to account for the dynamic growth-effects of trade liberalization, the
model described above is extended to a recursive dynamic specification in which selected
parameters are updated based on the modeling of intertemporal behavior and results from
previous periods. Current economic conditions, such as the availability of capital, are
25
endogenously dependent on past outcomes but remain unaffected by forward-looking
expectations. The dynamic model is also exogenously updated to reflect demographic and
technological changes based on observed trends. For example, population growth is
exogenously imposed on the model based on changes from the 1995 IES/OHS and the
2000 IES (StatsSA, 2001). It is assumed that a growing population generates a higher
level of consumption demand and therefore raises the supernumerary income level of
household consumption within the LES demand system.
Unlike total factor productivity (TFP) growth, which is updated exogenously, the
process of capital accumulation is modeled endogenously, with previous-period
investment generating new capital stock for the subsequent period. Although the
allocation of new capital across sectors is influenced by each sector’s initial share of
aggregate capital income, the final sectoral allocation of capital in the current period is
dependent on the depreciation rate and on sectoral profit-rate differentials from the
previous period. Sectors with above-average capital returns receive a larger share of the
new capital stock. The model therefore captures the growth-effects of liberalization by
allowing for both an exogenous adjustment in productivity growth and an endogenous
accumulation of capital due to cheaper imported capital goods (i.e., the first transmission
mechanism).
The model is initially calibrated to the information contained in the 1993 SAM.
The dynamic model is then solved for the 1993-2003 period as a series of equilibria each
one representing a single year. By imposing observed trends in sectoral GDP growth and
other dynamic adjustments from the literature, the model reproduces a counterfactual or
base growth path. Trade liberalization is then expressed as a change in tariffs and
productivity and the model is re-solved for a new series of equilibria. Differences
between the policy-influenced growth path and the counterfactual are interpreted as the
economy-wide impact of trade policies.
The poverty and distributional impacts of trade liberalization are modeled inside
the same household survey that was used to construct the SAM and CGE model (i.e., the
1995 IES). This microsimulation model fully employs the household survey data. Each
26
representative household in the CGE model is linked to its corresponding household
within the microsimulation model. Similar to the use of sample weights in the survey,
each representative household in the CGE model is an aggregation of a larger number of
households. Since poverty in this study is defined according to per capita expenditure,
changes in household expenditure for each of the 39 commodities in the CGE model are
passed down to the survey, where the poverty measure is updated and poverty and
inequality are recalculated.
The model therefore captures the four main transmission mechanisms between
trade and poverty. However, the model does not capture all of the effects of liberalization
on men and women. Most importantly, the model cannot capture how liberalization
influences the intra-household distribution incomes or expenditures (Fontana, 2003) nor
its impact on household production and leisure (Decaluwe et al., 2005). Rather the model
assumes that the distribution of incomes within households remains constant. This is a
reasonable assumption given the lack of appropriate intra-household data. Furthermore,
the model cannot capture the short-run adjustments costs of liberalization, and the results
should therefore be interpreted as the medium-run implications of trade reforms. Despite
these limitations, the model does capture the heterogeneity of household income and
expenditure patterns, and the detailed structure of production and labor markets in South
Africa. These factors are particularly important for identifying the distributional effects of
trade policy across men and women (Fontana, 2003).
27
IV. MODEL RESULTS
The CGE model is used to examine the impact of recent liberalization, as well as
the potential gains from future trade reforms. For the former, the static efficiency gains
from tariff reductions are separated from the dynamic gains from trade in order to
determine the relative importance of the various transmission mechanisms between trade
and poverty. However, the Baseline scenario first assesses the effects of the ‘preliberalization’ growth path on poverty, thus providing a counterfactual for the trade
policy scenarios.
Baseline Scenario
The Baseline scenario is calibrated to replicate the growth path that would have
been achieved if South Africa had continued with the same level and structure of growth
experienced during the pre-liberalization period (Table 1). The GDP growth rates for
each of 39 sectors in the model are calibrated to the observed growth rates for 1985-1993
(SASID, 2006), with both sectoral TFP and factor employment adjusting. The model then
solves endogenously for the remaining dimensions of growth (Table 4). Capital
accumulation and labor employment are both endogenous implying that the Solowdecomposition of growth is determined by changes in factor demands both across and
within sectors. Similarly, the expenditure composition of growth is endogenous, with the
only exception being government consumption whose growth is fixed at the observed 2.6
percent growth rate.
The projected Baseline scenario closely matches the pre-liberalization growth
path to which it is calibrated. For example, aggregate GDP growth for 1993-2003
averages 1.1 percent per year, which is identical to the growth experienced during 19851993 (Tables 1 and 4). The Baseline growth path is also similar to observed trends at the
disaggregated level. For example, the model reproduces the contraction of investment
and the slow private consumption growth experienced during 1985-1992 (Table 5). The
model also correctly estimates the productivity growth required to meet the aggregate
GDP growth rate. However, it understates capital stock growth and overstates labor
28
employment growth. This is because changes in inventories are exogenous in the model,
yet were the main driver of rising capital stocks during the late 1980s (Section 2).
Furthermore, the model does not capture the political instability of the 1980s, which may
have caused firms to favor capital over labor. However, despite these small differences,
the Baseline scenario successfully tracks the pre-liberalization growth path.
Table 4.
Macroeconomic Results from the Simulations, 1993-2003
Base
Tariff
Dynamic
Future
Initial
Scenario Reduction
Gains
Reforms
Share (%)
Simulated Average Annual Growth Rate (%),
1993
1993-2003
Real GDP (market prices)
Private consumption
Investment
Government
Exports
Imports
100.0
61.8
14.7
20.1
21.2
-17.8
1.1
1.2
-1.3
2.6
2.0
2.3
1.2
1.3
-1.2
2.6
2.9
3.4
1.8
1.9
0.4
2.6
3.3
3.9
1.9
2.0
0.7
2.6
3.5
4.1
Real GDP (factor cost)
Capital
Labor
Skilled
Semi-skilled
Unskilled
Productivity (TFP)
100.0
43.0
57.0
16.2
59.9
23.9
1.1
0.9
0.5
0.7
0.5
0.7
0.4
1.2
1.0
0.5
0.8
0.4
0.7
0.5
1.8
1.4
0.9
1.1
0.8
1.0
0.7
1.9
1.5
1.0
1.2
0.8
1.1
0.8
-3.9
-3.2
-4.7
-4.8
Real exchange rate
Current account deficit / GDP
Import taxes / GDP
Government deficit / GDP
0.9
0.8
6.7
Percentage point change from initial share,
1993-2003
-0.1
-0.1
-0.2
-0.2
0.2
-0.3
-0.3
-0.4
0.6
1.0
-0.4
-0.6
Source: Results from the South African CGE-microsimulation model.
Note: The real exchange rate is in units of local currency per unit of foreign currency (i.e., an increase is a
real depreciation). Tariff reduction and Dynamic gains scenarios include observed changes in nominal
tariff rates; Future reforms includes rationalization of current tariff system to five applied rates; Dynamic
gains and Future reforms include trade-induced TFP growth.
29
Table 5.
Sectoral GDP Growth Results from the Simulations, 1993-2003
Initial Share
(%)
1993
GDP factor cost
Agriculture
Mining
Manufacturing
Food / beverages
Textiles / clothing
Wood / paper
Chemicals
Non-metals
Metal products
Electrical machinery
Vehicles
Other manufacturing
Energy and construction
Private services
Public services
Observed Growth Rates (%)
1985-92
1993-03
Simulated Annual Growth Rate (%), 1993-2003
Base
Tariff
Dynamic
Future
Scenario
Reduction
Gains
Reforms
100.0
1.1
2.7
1.1
1.2
1.8
1.9
4.5
7.7
21.5
3.7
1.6
2.2
4.2
0.9
4.5
1.0
1.8
1.7
6.7
43.5
16.1
0.8
-1.2
0.4
0.3
-2.7
-1.0
1.9
-0.4
-2.7
2.8
0.6
10.5
1.0
1.3
2.6
1.5
-0.7
2.2
0.4
-1.1
0.7
3.3
0.7
4.2
1.3
4.7
1.4
2.7
4.4
0.1
0.8
-0.8
0.5
0.7
-2.6
-1.0
2.6
-0.2
-2.1
3.2
1.6
1.9
1.4
1.3
2.6
0.9
-0.6
0.4
0.7
-4.7
-1.2
2.7
-0.3
-2.3
3.4
1.8
1.7
1.5
1.4
2.6
1.7
0.2
1.7
2.0
-1.7
-0.3
3.5
0.8
-1.4
5.4
3.1
4.6
2.0
1.9
2.6
1.9
0.2
1.9
2.2
-1.0
-0.2
3.4
0.9
-1.4
5.3
4.1
4.6
2.1
2.0
2.6
Source: Results from the South African CGE-microsimulation model.
Note: Tariff reduction and Dynamic gains scenarios include observed changes in nominal tariff rates; Future reforms includes rationalization of
current tariff system to five applied rates; Dynamic gains and Future reforms include trade-induced TFP growth.
30
The Impact of Recent Trade Liberalization
Two scenarios are presented in this section that determines the effects of recent
trade liberalization on growth and poverty. Although both scenarios simulate the impact
of tariff reductions, only does the second scenario include the dynamic trade-induced
productivity gains that have been estimated by other studies. The design of the two
scenarios is described first before presenting the findings.
Tariff reductions during the 1990s were concentrated in the manufacturing sector,
where the largest absolute declines were on consumable products, such as food and
textiles (Table 6). Tariffs also declined for capital and intermediate goods, such as on
chemicals, machinery and metal products. As seen in the table, there is a difference
between the nominal tariff rate as it appears in the tariff schedule, and the duty that is
actually collected by customs officials. For example, the collection rate in 1993 was less
than a third of the nominal rate due to collection inefficiency and tariff exemptions. This
was certainly true for the vehicles sector, which received large duty-drawbacks as part of
the government’s industrial strategy. Since the SAM captures the actual flow of funds
between importers and the government, it is collection rates and not nominal rates that
appear in the model. However, recent trade liberalization episode is simulated by
reducing tariff collection rates by the percentage change in the nominal rate. These
scenarios therefore assume that collection efficiency is unaffected by liberalization.
The estimated dynamic gains from trade liberalization are drawn from Jonsson
and Subramanian (2001). Each percentage point decline in the nominal tariff rate raises a
sector’s TFP growth rate by 0.74 percent (Section 2). This elasticity gives the average
relationship between tariffs and TFP growth across all sectors. Therefore, by uniformly
applying this elasticity, the model does not capture the unique response of each sector to
trade reforms. However, the absolute size of the productivity gains is unique since each
sector experiences different changes in their tariffs. As such, the model provides a best
estimate of the effects of the dynamic gains from trade for each individual sector.
31
Table 6.
Observed Changes in Tariffs under Trade Liberalization, 1993-2003
Import Collected
Share
Rates
(%) 1993 (%) 1993
All sectors
Agriculture
Mining
Manufacturing
Food / beverages
Textiles / clothing
Wood / paper
Chemicals
Non-metals
Metal products
Electrical machinery
Vehicles
Other manufacturing
Energy and construction
Private services
Public services
1993
Nominal Tariff Rates (%)
Change
Ration
Tariffs1
2003 Point
(%)
100.0
4.3
15.8
5.2
-10.7
-67.4
4.1
2.9
8.8
76.3
4.3
4.0
4.9
15.0
1.3
20.6
9.5
13.4
3.2
0.2
11.7
0.0
0.5
0.2
5.5
5.0
18.9
4.8
5.0
11.9
3.7
5.3
3.2
13.0
0.0
0.6
0.0
10.5
3.0
20.0
30.6
50.7
15.7
13.5
17.4
13.3
19.9
25.0
27.7
0.0
0.6
0.0
4.5
0.9
7.3
13.3
24.0
6.0
3.8
6.0
3.9
3.4
11.9
7.4
0.0
0.6
0.0
-6.0
-2.1
-12.7
-17.3
-26.7
-9.7
-9.6
-11.4
-9.4
-16.5
-13.0
-20.3
0.0
0.0
0.0
-57.4
-71.3
-63.7
-56.7
-52.7
-61.9
-71.5
-65.4
-70.5
-82.8
-52.2
-73.2
0.0
0.0
0.0
3.2
0.9
5.8
10.4
19.1
5.1
3.7
5.7
3.7
3.2
6.8
7.3
0.0
0.6
0.0
Source: Import shares from 1993 SAM (Thurlow, 2006a); nominal rates from Edwards (2005); and TFP
growth from Jonsson and Subramanian (2001).
1
Nominal tariff rates that would apply in 2003 had the rationalization program been successfully
implemented.
The results for the Tariff Reduction and Dynamic Gains scenarios are described
sequentially. The initial effect of reducing tariffs is to lower import prices and stimulate
import demand (Table 4). However, increased imports places pressure on the current
account, which is held fixed in foreign currency. The real exchange rate therefore
depreciates to maintain macroeconomic balance.9 This partly offsets the initial fall in
import prices and raises export competitiveness. The overall effect of reducing tariffs is
therefore an acceleration in both import and export growth. Falling import prices also
benefits import-intensive investment, which in turn accelerates capital accumulation.
Falling tariff revenues and increases in the government deficit only partially offset faster
investment and capital accumulation. The net effect is therefore positive, implying that
reducing tariffs during the 1990s contributed positively to capital accumulation.
9
The real exchange rate is measured in the model as the amount of local currency required to purchase a
unit of foreign currency. Therefore, a depreciation is reflected as an increase in the real exchange rate.
32
TFP growth accelerates under the Tariff Reduction scenario because production
shifts towards more efficient sectors. However, it is when the dynamic gains from trade
liberalization are included that productivity growth is significantly enhanced. The faster
economic growth under the Dynamic Gains scenario raises household incomes and hence
government revenues and private savings. The resulting increase in loanable funds
strengthens investment and fosters higher production and exports. However, rising export
growth exceeds import growth in the Dynamic Gains scenario, thus causing the real
exchange rate to appreciate. The results for this scenario suggest that trade liberalization
contributed to the changes observed during the 1990s, such as the acceleration of trade,
investment and growth. Furthermore, the larger increase in the capital stock growth rate
relative to labor employment indicates that liberalization raised the capital-intensity of
production.
Trade liberalization also contributed to the changes in sectoral production that
took place during 1993-2003 (Table 5). For example, the consumables sectors were hurt
by falling tariffs and increased import competition, yet benefited from faster productivity
growth. This is certainly the case for the textiles and clothing sectors, which suffer under
the Tariff Reduction scenario, but whose growth rate rises considerably under the
Dynamic Gains scenario. The net effect is a slower decline in the textile sector, which is
similar to what was actually observed during the 1990s. Although the other
manufacturing sectors did not benefit as much from trade-induced productivity, they did
benefit from improved export competitiveness and cheaper imports. This led to
improvements in their net trading positions. Furthermore, all sectors benefited from
increased domestic demand resulting from higher overall economic growth. The model
captures these linkages between the manufacturing and services sectors. Faster tradeinduced growth in manufacturing generates additional demand for private services, which
grow more rapidly as a result. The predicted acceleration of services under the Dynamic
Gains scenario mirrors the sector’s actual performance during the 1990s. Liberalization
therefore explains some of the structural changes that took place in South Africa over the
last ten years, such as the expansion of the manufacturing and service sectors.
33
Trade reforms also influenced South Africa’s labor market. At the aggregate
level, rising import competition under the Tariff Reduction scenario causes a slight
decline in employment amongst semi-skilled workers but has little effect on unskilled
workers. These simulation results match the findings of other empirical studies. However,
faster trade-induced growth under the Dynamic Gains scenario generates employment for
all skill-groups, although it is skilled employment that expands fastest. While this tradeinduced increase in the skill-intensity of employment is confirmed by other studies, this is
not the case for unskilled labor, where the literature suggests that liberalization may have
caused a decline in employment. One explanation for this difference is that the model
estimates the ‘general equilibrium’ effects of liberalization thereby explicitly capturing
both its direct and indirect effects on employment. Isolating indirect transmission
mechanisms is difficult in ex-post econometric studies. Furthermore, the model captures
the ‘economy-wide’ effects of trade policies, whereas previous empirical studies have
tended to focus on manufacturing and therefore do not capture the effects of liberalization
on the service sector. Finally, another explanation is that the model does not capture how
the technology embodied in imported goods has changed during the 1990s. For example,
the nature of imported electrical machinery has changed dramatically over the last ten
years with the rise of personal computers. Predicting such innovations is obviously
beyond the ability of the model. Therefore, while the model correctly predicts the
increase in imports, it underestimates the rising skill-bias caused by these imported
capital goods.
Despite differences in methodology, both the model and the empirical evidence
produce similar results at the aggregate level. However, the objective of this study is to
go beyond the aggregate level of existing studies to estimate the distributional effects of
trade liberalization on men and women. The results for the Tariff Reduction scenario
suggest that women were more severely affected by import competition, with female
employment declining, especially in the manufacturing sector (Table 7). By contrast,
male employment increased, albeit only slightly. The reason for these differences lies in
the effect of liberalization on the consumables sectors. The food and textile sectors
34
Table 7.
Employment Results from the Simulations, 1993-2003
Initial
Employed
(1000s)
Simulated Total Growth (%), 1993-2003
Base
Tariff
Dynamic
Future
Scenario
Reduction
Gains
Reforms
Male workers
5,779
6.3
6.5
10.1
10.6
Skilled
Semi-skilled
Unskilled
932
3,617
1,230
7.2
5.8
7.3
7.5
5.8
7.6
11.5
9.4
11.1
12.1
9.9
11.7
Agriculture
Mining
Manufacturing
Private services
Public services
292
701
1,288
1,489
1,559
3.3
-8.3
-5.2
9.9
9.4
4.4
-6.2
-7.4
11.1
9.4
7.1
-2.2
-5.2
16.6
9.4
8.6
-2.8
-5.2
18.0
9.4
African
White
Other
3,750
1,232
796
6.2
5.7
7.8
6.5
5.9
7.4
9.9
9.2
12.4
10.4
9.7
13.3
Female workers
2,416
5.2
4.2
8.1
8.8
Skilled
Semi-skilled
Unskilled
399
1,292
725
8.1
3.7
6.4
8.5
1.8
6.1
13.7
5.1
10.3
14.6
5.7
11.0
Agriculture
Mining
Manufacturing
Private services
Public services
65
8
540
1,266
512
3.0
-2.5
-10.2
10.0
9.2
4.0
-0.4
-17.2
11.1
9.2
6.4
-3.8
-15.5
17.1
9.1
7.8
-4.6
-15.9
18.5
9.1
African
White
Other
1,410
657
349
5.9
6.9
-0.6
5.0
7.0
-4.4
9.2
10.2
-0.2
9.9
10.8
0.4
Source: Employment from 1995 OHS and IES (StatsSA, 1996a and 1996b). Results from the South
African CGE-microsimulation model.
Note: Tariff reduction and Dynamic gains scenarios include observed changes in nominal tariff rates;
Future reforms includes rationalization of current tariff system to five applied rates; Dynamic gains and
Future reforms include trade-induced TFP growth.
experienced the largest declines in nominal tariffs and hence rapid increases in import
competition. However, these sectors are particularly important for female employment.
For example, while female workers account for only one-third of national employment
they account for two-thirds of employment in the textiles sector (Table 8). As such, the
decline textiles production caused by falling tariffs hurts women more than men.
35
Table 8.
Factor Employment Shares within Sectors, 1993
Male workers
All
Male
Skilled
Share of total employment in each sector (%)
Female workers
Semiskilled
Unskilled
All
Female
Skilled
Semiskilled
Unskilled
All
Workers
All sectors
70.5
11.4
44.1
15.0
29.5
4.9
15.8
8.8
100.0
Agriculture
Mining
Manufacturing
Food / beverages
Textiles / clothing
Wood / paper
Chemicals
Non-metals
Metal products
Electrical machinery
Vehicles
Other manufacturing
Energy and construction
Private services
Public services
81.8
98.9
70.4
66.6
33.6
76.7
80.4
83.9
87.6
78.5
85.4
62.5
94.8
54.0
75.3
0.5
6.5
9.4
7.2
3.4
9.7
17.3
7.0
11.0
18.8
11.8
4.3
12.1
17.2
8.7
26.5
73.8
49.2
43.2
26.7
53.4
49.5
62.2
65.4
46.2
62.0
41.9
67.5
28.7
47.7
54.8
18.5
11.9
16.3
3.4
13.6
13.6
14.8
11.2
13.5
11.6
16.3
15.2
8.1
18.8
18.2
1.1
29.6
33.4
66.4
23.3
19.6
16.1
12.4
21.5
14.6
37.5
5.2
46.0
24.7
0.0
0.3
1.6
1.3
0.6
1.4
3.1
0.5
1.5
4.4
2.8
0.6
1.0
11.2
2.7
1.5
0.8
20.6
16.5
58.4
13.7
9.8
11.1
7.6
15.7
11.7
25.1
3.1
19.9
16.5
16.7
0.1
7.3
15.5
7.5
8.3
6.8
4.5
3.2
1.4
0.2
11.8
1.1
14.9
5.5
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
Source: Own calculations using the 1993 South African SAM (Thurlow, 2006a) and the 1995 OHS and IES (StatsSA, 1996a and 1996b).
Note: Skill groups based on occupational categories. Skilled includes professional and managerial workers; Semi-skilled includes clerical, sales, artisans and
production supervisor workers; and Unskilled includes all other workers.
36
Furthermore, since textiles is a large employer of semi-skilled Asian and Colored women,
it is these workers that experience the largest declines in employment after tariffs are
reduced.
Although female workers suffered under the Tariff Reduction scenario, they
benefit from higher employment under the Dynamic Gains scenario, with overall female
employment growth doubling from 4.2 to 8.1 percent. However, these benefits involve
considerable adjustment costs. While rising manufacturing growth does increase labor
demand and offsets some of the negative effects of import competition, this accelerated
growth is driven by factor productivity and hence a shedding of labor. The overall effect
of trade liberalization on manufacturing employment therefore remains negative despite
higher economic growth. Accordingly, most of the additional employment generated
under the Dynamic Gains scenario occurs outside of manufacturing, especially in the
agricultural and service sectors. This is especially important for female workers, who are
dependent on these sectors and therefore benefit from rising non-manufacturing
employment opportunities. However, migrating between sectors involves transaction
costs and uncertainty and there is also no indication that the same women who lose
manufacturing jobs find jobs elsewhere in the economy. This result suggests it is women
who are more likely to suffer as the economy adjusts to the new policy environment.
Furthermore, the new jobs created by trade-induced growth are biased towards higherskilled workers and this is particularly pronounced amongst women. These results match
the changes in employment that were observed during the 1990s, such as the rapid rise in
female employment in the agricultural and services sectors and the slow growth in
manufacturing employment (Table 2).
Despite its negative effects on manufacturing employment, trade liberalization
appears to contributed to the observed decline in the gender wage gap. This is because
female workers experienced larger increases in real wages due to rising productivity in
the manufacturing sector (Table 9). However, these productivity-induced increases were
partly offset by the migration of female workers out of manufacturing and into the lowerpaying agricultural and service sectors. Accordingly, the decline in the gender wage gap
37
was more pronounced amongst semi-skilled manufacturing workers rather than unskilled
workers. Furthermore, rising wages for unskilled and semi-skilled workers were offset by
their slower employment growth such that it is skilled workers who experience the largest
increases in labor incomes.
Table 9.
Changes in the Female-to-Male Wage Ratio in the Simulations, 1993-2003
Monthly Wage, 1993
Female
Male
Workers
Workers
All workers
Wage
Simulated Final Wage Ratio (%), 2003
Ratio (%) Base
Tariff
Dynamic
Future
1993
Scenario Reduction
Gains
Reforms
2,982
1,897
63.6
65.7
66.1
67.2
67.5
Skilled
Semi-skilled
Unskilled
7,436
2,424
1,252
4,001
1,890
752
53.8
78.0
60.1
54.8
81.7
61.0
54.9
82.2
61.1
55.5
83.9
62.2
55.7
84.3
62.4
African
White
Other
1,854
6,697
2,547
1,356
3,311
1,421
73.1
49.4
55.8
75.4
50.6
57.6
75.5
50.6
58.3
77.4
51.1
60.6
77.8
51.2
61.1
Source: Own calculations using the 1993 South African SAM (Thurlow, 2006a) and the 1995 OHS and IES
(StatsSA, 1996a and 1996b). Results from the South African CGE-microsimulation model.
Note: Tariff reduction and Dynamic gains scenarios include observed changes in nominal tariff rates;
Future reforms includes rationalization of current tariff system to five applied rates; Dynamic gains and
Future reforms include trade-induced TFP growth.
The differential impact of trade liberalization across population groups is reflected
in the changes in household poverty (Table 10). Under the Baseline scenario, the slow
growth in private consumption is more than offset by population growth, and national
poverty rises from 58.4 percent in 1993 to 66.8 percent in 2003.10 Trade liberalization
raises economic growth and consumption spending and hence lowers the final poverty
rate to 65.3 percent. Although this change appears to be small, it implies that trade
liberalization prevented over 700 000 people from falling into poverty during the 1990s.11
However, the adjustment costs of liberalization play an important role. The poverty
headcount amongst male-headed households declines under the Tariff Reduction
scenario, while it rises amongst female-headed households. This is driven by rising
10
The 1993 CGE model is linked to the 1995 household survey, implying that the initial poverty rates and
income distribution are for 1995.
11
This is 1.5 percent (66.8 minus 65.3) of the total population of 47 million people in 2003.
38
female unemployment, especially amongst urban Asian and Colored households whose
workers were more likely to be engaged in the textiles sector. This short-term rise effect
of trade liberalization is also true for male-headed households, albeit to a lesser extent.
By contrast, poverty declines amongst all population groups under the Dynamic Gains
scenario.
Table 10.
Changes in the Poverty Headcount from the Simulations, 1993-2003
Population Poverty Simulated Poverty Headcount Rate in 2003 (%)
Share in
Rate in
Base
Tariff
Dynamic
Future
1993 (%) 1993 (%) Scenario Reduction
Gains
Reforms
All households
Male-headed households
Rural
Urban
African
White
Other
Female-headed households
Rural
Urban
African
White
Other
100.0
58.4
66.8
66.7
65.3
65.2
67.6
28.9
38.7
51.4
8.6
7.6
32.4
18.7
13.7
28.6
1.2
2.5
50.8
77.3
30.9
63.0
1.1
37.1
74.4
87.4
56.6
79.3
6.9
53.7
59.9
82.7
40.9
71.2
1.2
36.4
80.6
91.2
65.1
84.8
6.5
51.1
59.8
82.6
40.8
71.1
1.2
36.6
80.6
91.1
65.2
84.8
6.5
51.7
58.4
81.5
39.0
69.4
1.1
35.6
79.1
90.3
63.0
83.4
6.0
49.8
58.3
81.3
38.9
69.2
1.1
35.4
79.0
90.3
62.7
83.3
6.0
49.7
Source: Population share and initial poverty rate from 1995 OHS and IES (StatsSA, 1996a and 1996b).
Results from the South African CGE-microsimulation model.
Note: The poverty headcount is the share of the total population falling below the poverty line, which is set
at R322 per person per month (see Hoogeveen and Ozler, 2005). Tariff reduction and Dynamic gains
scenarios include observed changes in nominal tariff rates; Future reforms includes rationalization of
current tariff system to five applied rates; Dynamic gains and Future reforms include trade-induced TFP
growth.
Changes in poverty do not accurately reflect the effects of trade liberalization on
the distribution of incomes. This can be seen in Figure 3, which shows how the additional
private expenditure resulting from trade liberalization is distributed across expenditure
deciles.12 All households benefit under the Dynamic Gains scenario since the ‘growth
incidence curve’ is always positive. However, high-income households benefit more than
12
More technically, it shows the difference between per capita expenditure growth in each of the trade
scenarios and per capita expenditure growth in the Baseline scenario.
39
low-income households. This is because trade liberalization benefits capital and higherskilled labor and it is high-income households that are more endowed with these two
factors. By contrast, low-income households are more dependent on lower-skilled labor
whose employment rises more slowly under trade liberalization. Furthermore, lowincome households face considerable unemployment and are therefore effectively
disconnected from the main benefits of liberalization (i.e., the factor market transmission
mechanism). There are also significant distributional differences across male and femaleheaded households. While high-income male and female-headed households enjoy
similar increases in expenditure, it is male-headed households that benefit more at the
lower end of the distribution. This is because female workers are more likely to be
unemployed or unskilled and hence experience smaller increases in factor incomes as a
result of trade liberalization.
Falling import prices and rising import competition also contributed to real wages
by lowering consumptions costs. While this benefits all households, it is higher-income
households who have more import-intensive consumption patterns and thus benefit more
than lower-income households. Accordingly, the direct price-effect of trade liberalization
helps reduce poverty but worsens national inequality. However, there are few differences
in consumption patterns across male and female-headed households at similar levels in
the income distribution. As such, trade liberalization and falling import prices equally
benefits both household groups. The price transmission mechanism therefore does not
explain changes in gender-inequality.
The above findings suggest that South Africa’s recent trade liberalization episode
reduced poverty during the 1990s. However, this effect was relatively small and
insufficient to offset the rise in poverty caused by slow growth and falling employment
and wages. Liberalization has also increased the bias towards capital and skilled labor,
thus reducing the gains from trade for poor households. However, low-income
households did benefit from faster non-manufacturing employment caused by the
economy-wide effects of liberalization. Although liberalization reduced poverty, it also
exacerbated inequality, especially between men and women.
40
Future Gains from Trade Rationalization
The final scenario considers the effects that might have been realized had the
government successfully implemented its tariff rationalization program. As mentioned
earlier, the government’s original proposal to the WTO was to reduce the number of
applied tariff rates to six (i.e., zero, five, ten, 15, 20 and 30 percent). However, by 1999
there were still 47 different applied rates. Since the government has already reached its
average tariff reduction targets, its future efforts are likely to focus on tariff
rationalization. Accordingly, this scenario implements the original rationalization
program by reducing nominal tariffs for each tariff line to the nearest of the six tariff
bands. These adjustments are based on the final year and so include the actual tariff
changes of the 1990s plus any additional decline in tariffs caused by rationalization. For
example, a tariff rate that declined from 50 to 25 percent during 1993-2003 under the
Tariff Reduction scenario is now reduced to 20 percent under the Future Reforms
scenario. Furthermore, the estimated elasticity linking tariff reductions to productivity
growth is still applies to this scenario. Therefore, the results for this scenario should be
compared to the Dynamic Gains scenario to determine the possible impact of future
reforms.
The changes in tariffs required to achieve the original rationalization targets are
quite small (Table 6). Most sectors experience less than a one percentage point further
decline in 2003 nominal tariffs. However, the textiles and vehicles sectors, who were
deemed ‘sensitive’ under the WTO agreement, would experience larger declines. Overall,
the consumables sectors would face the largest decline in tariffs since they still enjoy the
highest levels of protection and were exempted from most of the tariffs reductions of the
1990s. The macroeconomic effect of further reducing tariffs under the rationalization
program is to stimulate import demand and raise productivity (Table 4). Faster economic
growth increases the supply of exports, which offsets rising imports and causes an
appreciation of the real exchange rate. Economic growth raises household incomes and
savings as well as government non-tariff revenues. This offsets the revenue-loss
associated with lower tariff rates. The resulting increase in loanable funds facilitates
41
higher investment growth. These results suggest that completing the proposed tariff
rationalization program will favor investment and capital accumulation but will have
little effect on overall economic growth.
The increase in the capital stock under the Future Reforms scenario is matched by
rising labor employment. However, manufacturing employment remains stagnant due to
shedding of labor in the consumables sectors and the inability of faster export growth in
other manufacturing sectors to offset this trend. Unskilled workers benefit from the
economy-wide growth-effects of liberalization and rising employment in the nonmanufacturing services. While this is true for both men and women, it particularly
important for female workers who rely more heavily on agriculture and private services
for their livelihoods (Table 8). Again it is skilled male and female workers that benefit
the most from improved employment opportunities after trade reforms. However, while
the gender wage gap narrows for all workers, the shift in female employment from
manufacturing to lower-paying sectors offsets the rise in relative wages for women,
especially for unskilled female workers (Table 9). Accordingly, while further tariff
rationalization reduces poverty, its effect remains small and there are few difference
between male and female-headed households (Table 10).
Focusing on the effects of trade liberalization on households near to the poverty
line again hides its effect on inequality (Figure 3). High-income households benefit more
than low-income households, implying that future reforms will exacerbate inequality in
South Africa. However, it is high-income female-headed households who benefit the
most due to more rapid increases in skilled female employment. By contrast, it is femaleheaded households at the lower-end of the income distribution that benefit the least from
future reforms. Therefore, the increase in within-group inequality resulting from further
tariff rationalization is likely to be more severe for female-headed households.
42
Figure 3.
Additional Per Capita Expenditure Relative to the Base Scenario,
1993-2003
Additional expenditure growth (%)
12
Future
reforms
Male-headed households
10
Female-headed households
Dyanmic
gains
8
6
4
2
Tariff
reduction
0
-2
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
National population-weighted per capita expenditure deciles
Source: Results from the South African CGE-microsimulation model.
43
100
V.
CONCLUSION
This study has empirically examined the relationship between trade liberalization,
employment and poverty. The findings suggest that liberalization has worked against the
observed increase in poverty in South Africa. However, the positive effects of trade
reform on the incomes of the poor are likely to have been small, especially since its
primary transmission mechanism is through improved employment and wages. High
levels of unemployment and inadequate human capital has meant that poor households
are disconnected from the benefits of liberalization. Furthermore, rising import
competition has contributed to the fall in manufacturing employment during the 1990s.
While this has been more than offset by improved employment opportunities in the nonmanufacturing sectors, the associated short-term adjustment costs will have increased the
vulnerability of the poor and may have undermined their ability to participate in
subsequent trade-induced growth.
Trade reforms have also worsened inequality in South Africa. While all workers
benefited from faster economic growth, liberalization raised the capital- and skillintensity of production. Trade reforms have therefore favored higher-income households.
This is particularly pronounced for women, who were more heavily dependent on
employment in the sensitive food and textiles sectors. These sectors suffered under
import competition and, while they did eventually benefit from improved efficiency, the
ultimate effect of trade reforms was a shedding of female labor. Unskilled female
workers responded by moving to the lower-paying agricultural and services sectors. As a
result, inequality between men and women worsened at the lower end of the income
distribution. By contrast, higher-skilled women have greater sectoral mobility and were
therefore able to overcome adjustment costs and benefit from trade-induced growth.
Since this was equally true for skilled male workers, the effects of trade reforms at the
high end of the income distribution were similar for male and female-headed households.
Trade liberalization therefore has affected men and women differently. Trade
reforms have not increased poverty, but they have undermined South Africa’s attempts to
44
reduce inequality. This study suggests that, while there may not be a trade-off between
pro-growth trade reform and poverty reduction, the country should not rely on further
liberalization to generate pro-poor growth or address the prevailing inequalities between
different population groups, such as men and women. Rather, the government should
engage more heavily in targeted pro-poor strategies, such as public works programs and
social assistance, which can be better targeted towards poor and vulnerable groups. More
importantly, the country’s growth strategy should address the adjustment costs associated
with trade reforms by providing for social protection and job retraining, especially for
lower-skilled women.
45
REFERENCES
Arora, V. and Bhundia, A. 2003. “Potential Output and Total Factor Productivity Growth
in Post-Apartheid South Africa”, IMF Working Paper WP/03/178, International
Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.
Bell, T. 1993. “Should South Africa Further Liberalise its Foreign Trade”, in Lipton, M.,
and Simkins, C., (eds.) State and Market in Post-Apartheid South Africa,
Witwatersrand University Press.
Bell, T., and Cattaneo, N. 1997. “Foreign Trade and Employment in the South African
Manufacturing Industry.” Occasional Report No. 4, Employment and Training
Department, International Labour Organisation, Geneva.
Belli, P., Finger, M., and Ballivan, A. 1993. “South Africa: A Review of Trade Policies.”
Discussion Paper 4, Informal Discussion Papers on Aspects of the Economy of
South Africa, World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Bhorat, H. 1999. “Decomposing Sectoral Employment Trends in South Africa.” Paper
presented at the Trade and Industrial Policy Strategies Annual Forum,
Muldersdrift, South Africa.
Black, A. 1996. “Learning, Technical Change and the Trade Regime in the South African
Automotive Component Sector”, Industrial Strategy Working Paper No. 7,
Development Policy Research Unit, University of Cape Town, South Africa.
Casale, D., Muller, C. and Posel, D. (2004) “Two million net new jobs: A reconsideration
of the rise in employment in South Africa, 1995-2003.” South African Journal of
Economics, 72(5): 978-1002.
Casale, D. and Posel, D. (2005) “Women and the Economy: How far have we come?”
Agenda, 64:21-29.
Cassim, R., Onyango, D., and van Seventer, D.E.N. 2004. The State of Trade Policy in
South Africa. Trade and Industrial Policy Strategies, Johannesburg, South Africa.
Fofana, I., Decaluwe, B., Cockburn, J., Mabugu, R., and Chitiga, M. 2005. “Does Trade
Liberalization Leave Women Behind in South Africa?” Paper presented to the
Poverty and Economic Policy Network, Colombo, Sri Lanka (June).
Edwards, L. 1999. “Trade Liberalisation, Structural Change and Occupational
Employment in South Africa.” Paper presented at the Trade and Industrial Policy
Strategies Annual Forum, Muldersdrift, South Africa.
—————. 2001a. “Globalisation and the Occupational Structure of Employment in
South Africa.” South African Journal of Economics, Vol. 69(1), pp. 40-71.
—————. 2001b. “Trade and the Structure of South African Production, 1984-97.”
Development Southern Africa, Vol. 18(4), pp. 471-491.
46
—————. 2002. “Trade, Technology and Employment in South Africa.” Trade and
Industry Monitor, Trade and Industrial Policy Strategies, South Africa.
—————. 2003. “A Firm-Level Analysis of Trade, Technology and Employment in
South
Africa.” Globalisation and Poverty Discussion Paper No. 5, University of Cape Town,
South Africa.
Edwards, L. and Abdi, T. 2001. “Trade, Technology and Wage Inequality in South
Africa.” Development Policy Research Unit Working Paper No. 02/60, University
of Cape Town, South Africa.
Edwards, L. and Golub, S.S. 2004. “South Africa’s International Cost Competitiveness
and Exports in Manufacturing.” World Development, Vol. 32(8), pp. 1323-1339.
Fedderke, J. 2001. “The Contribution of Growth in Total Factor Productivity to Growth
in South Africa, 1970-1997”, Econometric Research Southern Africa Policy
Paper, University of the Witwatersrand, South Africa.
Fedderke, J., Shin, Y. and Vase, P. 2003. “Trade, Technology and Wage Inequality in
South
African Manufacturing Sectors.” Unpublished mimeo. University of the Witwatersrand,
South Africa.
Decaluwe, B., Cockburn, J., Fofana, I., Mabugu, R. and Chitiga, M. 2005. “Does Trade
Liberalization Leave Women Behind in South Africa”, paper presented to the
Poverty and Economic Policy Meeting, Colombo, Sri Lanka.
Fontana, M. 2003. “The Gender Effects of Trade Liberalization in Developing Countries:
A Review of the Literature”, Discussion Paper in Economics No. 101, University
of Sussex, Brighton.
Fontana Marzia and Wood Adrian. 2000. “Modeling the Effects of Trade on Women, at
Work, and at Home”, World Development, Vol. 28(7), pp. 1173-1190.
Golub, S.S. and Ceglowski, J. 2002. “South African Real Exchange Rates and
Manufacturing Competitiveness.” South African Journal of Economics, Vol.
70(6), pp. 1047-1075.
Harding, T. and Rattso, J. 2005. “The Barrier Model of Productivity Growth: South
Africa”, Working Paper Series, Department of Economics, Norwegian University
of Science and Technology, Norway.
Hoogeveen, J.G. and Ozler, B. 2005. “Not Separate, Not Equal: Poverty and Inequality in
Post-Apartheid South Africa”, William Davidson Institute Working Paper No. 79,
University of Michigan.
IDC. 1997. “Empirical Estimation of Elasticities in IDC’s General Equilibrium Model
(IDCGEM)”, Technical Series No. TS2/1997, Industrial Development
Corporation, South Africa.
47
Jonsson, G. and Subramanian, A. 2001. “Dynamic Gains from Trade: Evidence from
South Africa.” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 48(1), pp. 197-224.
Lewis, J. 2001. “Policies to Promote Growth in South Africa.” Discussion Paper No. 16,
Informal Discussion Papers on Aspects of the South African Economy, The
World Bank, Southern Africa Department.
Lofgren, H., Harris, R. and Robinson, S. 2001. “A Standard Computable General
Equilibrium (CGE) Model in GAMS.” Trade and Macroeconomics Discussion
Paper No. 75, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.
Meth, C. and Dias, R. 2004. “Increases in poverty in South Africa, 1999–2002”,
Development Southern Africa, Vol. 21(1), pp. 59-85.
McCulloch, N., Winters, L.A. and Cirera, X. 2002. Trade Liberalisation and Poverty: A
Handbook. Centre for Economic Policy Research, London, U.K.
Nell, K. 2003. “Long-run Exogeneity Between Saving and Investment: Evidence from
South Africa.” Working Paper 2-2003, Trade and Industrial Policy Strategies,
Johannesburg, South Africa.
Republic of South Africa. 1996. “Growth, Employment and Redistribution”,
Government Printer, Pretoria, South Africa.
SASID. 2006. South African Standard Industrial Database, Trade and Industrial Policy
Strategies, Pretoria, South Africa.
Statistics South Africa. 1996a. 1995 October Household Survey, Pretoria, South Africa.
—————. 1996b. 1995 Income and Expenditure Survey, Pretoria, South Africa.
—————. 2001. 2000 Income and Expenditure Survey, Pretoria, South Africa.
Thurlow, J. 2005, “A Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Model for South
Africa: Extending the Static IFPRI Model”, Trade and Industrial Policy
Strategies, Pretoria.
—————. 2006a. “A 1993 Gender and Poverty-Focused Social Accounting Matrix for
South Africa”, Development Strategy and Governance Division International
Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.
—————. 2006b. “Free Trade Agreements and Pro-Poor Growth in South Africa”,
Trade and Industrial Policy Strategies, Pretoria, South Africa.
Tsikata, I. 1999. “Liberalization and Trade Performance in South Africa.” Informal
Discussion Papers on Aspects of the South African Economy No. 13, World
Bank, Washington, D.C.
Van der Berg, S., Burger, R., Burger, R., Louw, M., Yu, D. 2005. “Trends in poverty and
inequality since the political transition: Examining the trends in poverty and
income inequality in South Africa from 1993-2004”, Bureau for Economic
Research, South Africa.
48
Winters, L.A., McCulloch, N., and McKay, A. 2004. “Trade Liberalization and Poverty:
The Evidence So Far”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 17(1), pp. 72-115.
Woolard, I. And Leibbrandt, M. 2001. “Measuring Poverty in South Africa”, in Bhorat,
H., Leibbrant, M., Maziya, M., Van der Berg, S, and Woolard, I. (eds.) Fighting
Poverty: Labor Markets and Inequality in South Africa, University of Cape Town
Press, Cape Town.
49
LIST OF DSGD DISCUSSION PAPERS
No. 01
“Market Opportunities for African Agriculture: An Examination of
Demand-Side Constraints on Agricultural Growth” by Xinshen Diao, Paul
Dorosh, and Shaikh Mahfuzur Rahman with Siet Meijer, Mark Rosegrant,
Yukitsugu Yanoma, and Weibo Li (September 2003)
No. 02
“Exploring Regional Dynamics in Sub-Saharan African Agriculture” by
Xinshen Diao and Yukitsugu Yanoma (October 2003)
No. 03
“The Effect of WTO and FTAA on Agriculture and the Rural Sector in
Latin America” by Samuel Morley and Valeria Piñeiro (February 2004)
No. 04
“Public Expenditure, Growth, and Poverty Reduction in Rural Uganda”
by Shenggen Fan, Xiaobo Zhang, and Neetha Rao (March 2004)
No. 05
“Food Aid for Market Development in Sub-Saharan Africa” by Awudu
Abdulai, Christopher B. Barrett, and Peter Hazell (April 2004)
No. 06
“Security Is Like Oxygen: Evidence from Uganda” by Xiaobo Zhang
(May 2004)
No. 07
“The Importance of Public Investment for Reducing Rural Poverty in
Middle-income Countries: The Case of Thailand” by Shenggen Fan,
Somchai Jitsuchon, and Nuntaporn Methakunnavut (June 2004)
No. 08
“Cross-Country Typologies and Development Strategies to End Hunger in
Africa” by Xiaobo Zhang, Michael Johnson, Danielle Resnick, and
Sherman Robinson (June 2004)
No. 09
“Smallholder African Agriculture: Progress and Problems in Confronting
Hunger and Poverty” by Danielle Resnick (July 2004)
No. 10
“Bridging Research, Policy, and Practice in African Agriculture” by
Steven Were Omamo (July 2004)
No. 11
“Prospects for Growth and Poverty Reduction in Zambia, 2001-2015” by
Hans Lofgren, James Thurlow, and Sherman Robinson (August 2004)
No. 12
“Road Development, Economic Growth, and Poverty Reduction in China”
by Shenggen Fan and Connie Chan-Kang (August 2004)
No. 13
“Blunt to Sharpened Razor: Incremental Reform and Distortions in the
Product and Capital Markets in China” by Xiaobo Zhang and Kong-Yam
Tan (August 2004)
No. 14
“Strategic Analysis and Knowledge Support Systems for Rural
Development Strategies in Sub-Saharan Africa” by Michael Johnson and
Danielle Resnick, with Simon Bolwig, Jordan Chamberlin, Liangzhi You,
Stanley Wood, and Peter Hazell (October 2004)
50
No. 15
“Institutions and Economic Policies for Pro-poor Agricultural Growth” by
Andrew Dorward, Shenggen Fan, Jonathan Kydd, Hans Lofgren, Jamie
Morrison, Colin Poulton, Neetha Rao, Laurence Smith, Hardwick Tchale,
Sukhadeo Thorat, Ian Urey, and Peter Wobst (November 2004)
No. 16
“The Road to Pro-poor Growth in Zambia: Past Lessons and Future
Challenges” by James Thurlow and Peter Wobst (December 2004)
No. 17
“Achieving Regional Growth Dynamics in African Agriculture” by
Awudu Abdulai, Xinshen Diao and Michael Johnson (January 2005)
No. 18
“Public Investment and Poverty Reduction in Tanzania: Evidence from
Household Survey Data” by Shenggen Fan, David Nyange and Neetha
Rao (April 2005)
No. 19
“Identifying the Drivers of Sustainable Rural Growth and Poverty
Reduction in Honduras” by Hans G.P. Jansen, Paul B. Siegel and
Francisco Pichón (April 2005)
No. 20
“Growth Options and Poverty Reduction in Ethiopia: A Spatial,
Economywide Model Analysis for 2004-15” by Xinshen Diao and
Alejandro Nin Pratt with Madhur Gautam, James Keough, Jordan
Chamberlin, Liangzhi You, Detlev Puetz, Danille Resnick and Bingxi Yu
(May 2005)
No. 21
“Fiscal Decentralization and Political Centralization in China:
Implications for Regional Inequality” by Xiaobo Zhang (July 2005)
No. 22
“The Dragon and the Elephant: Agricultural and Rural Reforms in China
and India” by Ashok Gulati, Shenggen Fan and Sara Dalafi (August 2005)
No. 23
“Rural and Urban Dynamics and Poverty: Evidence from China and
India” by Shenggen Fan, Connie Chan-Kang and Anit Mukherjee (August
2005)
No. 24
“Rural Nonfarm Development in China and India: The Role of Policies
and Institutions” by Anit Mukherjee and Xiaobo Zhang (September 2005)
No. 25
“Social Capital and the Reproduction of Economic Inequality in Polarized
Societies” by Tewodaj Mogues and Michael R. Carter (November 2005)
No. 26
“Geographic Space, Assets, Livelihoods and Well-being in Rural Central
America: Empirical Evidence from Guatemala, Honduras and Nicaragua”
by Jeffrey Alwang, Hans G.P. Jansen, Paul B. Siegel and Francisco Pichon
(November 2005)
No. 27
“Determinants of Change in Household-Level Consumption and Poverty
in Uganda, 1992/93-1999/00” by Sam Benin and Samuel Mugarura
(January 2006)
51
No. 28
“Asymmetric Property Rights in China’s Economic Growth by Xiaobo
Zhang (January 2006)
No. 29
“The Role of Agriculture in Development: Implications for Sub-Saharan
Africa” by Xinshen Diao, Peter Hazell, Danielle Resnick, and James
Thurlow (February 2006)
No. 30
“Does Good Governance Contribute to Pro-poor Growth?: A Review of
the Evidence from Cross-Country Studies” by Danielle Resnick and
Regina Birner (February 2006)
No. 31
“Village Inequality in Western China: Implications for Development
Strategy in Lagging Regions” by Li Xing, Shenggen Fan, Xiaopeng Luo,
and Xiaobo Zhang (February 2006)
No. 32
“Shocks, Sensitivity and Resilience: Tracking the Economic Impacts of
Environmental Disaster on Assets in Ethiopia and Honduras” by Michael
R. Carter, Peter D. Little, Tewodaj Mogues, and Workneh Negatu (April
2006)
No. 33
“Trade Liberalization under CAFTA: An Analysis of the Agreement with
Special Reference to Agriculture and Smallholders in Central America”
Sam Morley (May 2006)
No. 34
“Moving Up and Down: A New Way of Examining Country Growth
Dynamics” by Marc Rockmore and Xiaobo Zhang (June 2006)
No. 35
“Public Investment to Reverse Dutch Disease: The Case of Chad” by
Stephanie Levy (July 2006)
52