International Journal of Agriculture and Forestry 2012, 2(2): 1-5
DOI: 10.5923/j.ijaf.20120202.01
Farm – Level Determinants of Agricultural
Commercialization
Chukwukere Austin Okezie1,*, Jamalludin Sulaiman1, Aloysius Chidi Nwosu2
1
School of Social Sciences, Universiti Sains Malaysia 11800 USM, Penang, Malaysia
Department of Agricultural Economics, Michael Okpara University of Agriculture, Umudike, P.M.B.7267 Umuahia, Abia State, Nigeria
2
Abstract The study examined the increasing commercialization of subsistence agriculture and identified the driving
forces of the commercialization process. The study defined some concepts under which the process of agricultural commercialization was examined. The study was conducted in the three agricultural zones of Abia state, Nigeria. A total of 120
farm families spread across the state were enlisted for the study. Data were collected bimonthly for a period of six months
with structured questionnaires. Data analysis involved the use of descriptive statistics and quantitative techniques. Results
show that agriculture is not subsistence oriented. There is some considerable degree of market-orientation. Off- farm income
was identified as important source of the commercialization of agriculture. The farm-level determinants of commercialization
were labour, fertilizer and planting materials. The production elasticity of labour is high and there are diseconomies of scale.
The study observes that the full potentials of agriculture have not been harnessed as agriculture is labour intensive and relies
heavily on crude implements.
Keywords Determinants, Agriculture, Subsistence, Commercialization, Farm-Income
1. Introduction
There is widespread agreement that agriculture is central
to economic growth in the countries of sub-Saharan Africa,
since it is thought to account for 70 percent of total employment, 40 percent of total merchandize exports, and
one-third of GDP, with these propositions being much higher
in many countries of the region (Jaffer, 1992; DFID, 2002;
Rahman and Manprasert, 2006). Economic growth, urbanization and the withdrawal of labour from the agricultural
sector lead to the increasing commercialization of agriculture.
Agricultural commercialization means more than the marketing of agricultural outputs, it means the product choice
and input use decisions are based on the principle of profit
maximization (von Braun et al 1991; Pingali and Rosegrant,
1995; Yoon-Donn and Yoon, 2009). Commercial reorientation of agricultural production occurs for primary stable
cereals as well as for the so-called high value cash crops. On
the input side, commercialization implies that both traded
and non-traded inputs are valued in terms of their market
value.
Commercialization of agricultural systems leads to greater
market orientation of farm production; progressive substitution out of non-traded inputs in favour of purchased inputs;
and the gradual decline of integrated farming systems and
* Corresponding author:
[email protected] (Chukwukere Austin Okezie)
Published online at http://journal.sapub.org/ijaf
Copyright © 2012 Scientific & Academic Publishing. All Rights Reserved
their replacement by specialized enterprises for crop, livestock, poultry and aquaculture products. The farm level
determinants of increasing commercialization are the rising
opportunity costs of family labour and increased market
demand for food and other agricultural products.
As economies grow, there is a gradual but definite movement out of subsistence food crop production, generally in a
monoculture system, to a diversified market- oriented production system (Cohen, 1988; Delgado, 1995; von Braun,
1994; Panashat, 2011). The countries of East Asia are at the
high end of the agricultural commercialization pathway,
while Southeast Asia and parts of Latin America are rapidly
moving towards commercialization. The countries of South
Asia and much of Sub-Saharan Africa are at the lower end of
the commercialization pathway (Norsida and Nawi, 2010).
While the speed of commercialization differs substantially
across continents and countries they are all moving in the
same direction (Pingali and Rosegrant, 1995).A major question in the abundant literature of agricultural growth and
development in sub-Saharan Africa is how to encourage
peasants primarily engaged in subsistence farming to become market-oriented (Hinderink and Sterkenberg, 1987;
Inmink and Alarcon, 1993; Kennedy, 1994; von Braun,
1995).
In Nigeria despite government efforts to diversify the
economy, the economy does not rely heavily on agricultural
output, and agriculture’s role in the economy has declined.
Besides high percentage of the labour force in agriculture
food insecurity at the household level has become a major
developmental challenge. This study was designed primarily
2
Chukwukere Austin Okezie et al.: Farm - Level Determinants of Agricultural Commercialization
to assess the extent of agricultural commercialization at the
farm level and to ascertain the determinants of agricultural
commercialization.
2. Methodology
2.1. Study Area
The study was carried out in Abia State. Abia state is one
of the thirty-six states of the Federal Republic of Nigeria.
The state is located in the South East agro-ecological zones
of Nigeria. Abia State lies between longitudes 7o00E and
8o00E and latitude 4o451N and 6o171N of the equator. The
climate is tropical and humid all the year round. The rainy
season ranges from March to October. The dry season occurs
from November to February. The mean annual rainfall
ranges from 2000mm to 2500mm with the southern areas
receiving more than the northern areas. The temperature
ranges between 22℃ minimum to 31℃ (maximum). The
vegetation is predominantly lowland rainforest. The major
crops grown are arable crops (e.g cassava, rice, yam etc).
Others include banana, plantain, maize, vegetables etc. major
cash crops grown in the state include oil palm, kolanut, cocoa,
rubber and cashew. Other farming activities include sheep
and goat rearing, poultry and rabbit keeping and off-farm
activities especially processing and utilization (FOS, 1999).
The population of the state was estimated at about 2.8
million in 1991 (NPC, 2006). The population density is
about 364 persons/km2 with 63% in agricultural production.
This largely informed the choice of the state for the study.
The average household size is about six persons per family
(FOS, 1999). Abia State comprises 17 Local Government
Areas (L.G.A’s) divided into three agricultural zones namely,
Aba, Ohafia and Umuahia. In Aba zone, there are seven
L.G.A’s namely: Aba North, Aba South, Osisioma Ngwa,
Obioma Ngwa North, Ukwa East, Ukwa West and Ugwunagbo. In Ohafia zone, there are five L.G.A’s namely:
Isuiukwuato, Ohafia, Bende, Arochukwu and Umunneochi.
In Umuahia Zone, there are five L.G.A’s namely: Umuahia
North, Umuahia-South, Ikwuano, Isiala Ngwa North and
Isiala Ngwa South. Umuahia however is the state capital.
Abia State offers an interesting scenario in the study of
agricultural commercialization. The state being mainly agrarian with expanding population shows evidence of outmigration of the youths from the rural sector in search of
white collar jobs and trading. The state produces many food
crops and cash crops like cocoa, oil palm, cashew, rubber etc.
2.2. Sampling Procedure
A total of 120 farm households were chosen from the three
agricultural zones of Abia State. A multi-stage stratified
random sampling technique was adopted in selecting respondent households. First, all the 17 LGA’s were listed to
form a separate sampling frame from the three zones. Two
Local Government Areas (LGA’s) was purposively selected
from each of the zones making a total of 6 LGA’s, from the
state. Secondly, from each of the 6 LGA’s, four farming
communities were purposively selected. The essence of the
purposive selection is to ensure that rural communities
whose major occupation is farming were selected. Thirdly, in
each of the 24 communities/villages, a list of farm households were compiled with the assistance of village heads and
resident ADP extension agents. From each village, 5
households were randomly selected for the study.
2.3. Data Collection
A variety of techniques including observation, recall, and
direct measurement were used in the survey. Well-trained
Enumerators who were resident Extension agents assisted in
data collection. The pre-testing of questionnaire was undertaken and thereafter the study households were visited bimonthly over a six-month period.
2.4. Analytical Procedure
The analytical approach adopted comprises a set of equations describing the key relationships involved in the commercialization process. They relate to a household’s time
allocation, sources of income, spending of income, and
determinants of the degree of subsistence. The analytical
approach adapted is greatly applied in works on commercialization of agriculture (see von Braun, et al. 1991; Kennedy and Cogill 1987; von Braun and Kennedy 1994;
Govereh and, Jayne 1996; Farouque and Tekeya, 2008). The
term ‘subsistence’ as used in this study describes production
of goods for consumption by the household. Accordingly,
the term commercialization defines the volume of produce
and household resources that enter the exchange economy.
This includes off-farm employment of labour and capital.
The extent of subsistence orientation and commercialization may be addressed from different angles. Agricultural
subsistence orientation (Consumption concept) is measured
by the extent to which farm households consume out of their
aggregate agricultural produce as compared with the value of
total agricultural produce:
CA = AS/AP
(1)
Where CA = Agricultural subsistence ratio
AS = Value of non-marketed agricultural produce (N)
AP = Total value of agricultural production (N)
In addition to this consumption – oriented concept, it can
be imagined that subsistence agriculture develops towards
“commercialization” on the input side but not on the output
side; for instance, when farm households sell their labour in
the off-farm labour market and invest proceeds in augmenting their subsistence production.
A more comprehensive concept of commercialization will
take into account the overall degree of market integration of
rural households into the exchange economy and does not
just look into agriculture. This may be approached from the
income earning side (Income concept).
Subsistence orientation at the income generation side of
the household (Income concept), can be defined as follows:
(2)
CY = AS/Ytot
International Journal of Agriculture and Forestry 2012, 2(2): 1-5
With total income Ytot being
(3)
Ytot = AP – AC + Yo + Yw + YL
Where CY = Subsistence share in total income;
AC = Cost of agricultural production;
Yo = Any other income from transfers or renting out asset
(such as land);
Yw = Off-farm wage income (from integration into the
labour market), and
YL = Income equivalent of leisure
The income concept captures market integration/ penetration of households beyond agricultural sector. Landed
rural households may commercialize through specialization
in crop production or shifts in production functions through
technical change combined with increased input demand
(integration in input markets). Also farm households may
commercialize via increased off-farm work partly at the
expense of market surplus from agricultural production. This
means that there may be substitution between (AP-AC) and
Yw, leaving CY in equation (2) rather stable, with different
patterns of subsistence orientation.
The analysis started with classification of households
based on the concepts outlined in the analytical framework.
To ascertain the farm-level determinants of agricultural
commercialization, an aggregate all-crop production function of the Cobb-Douglas type was modeled. The function is
started thus:
(4)
Y 1 = f (X1, X2, X3, X4, X5, X6, X7, X8)
Where
Y1 = Agricultural Commercialization defined as the value
of crop sales in household over the total value of crop production multiplied by 100.
X1 = Farm size in rent per hectare in Naira
X2 = Labour input in wage per manday
X3 = Depreciation taking care of capital inputs (tools and
implements) in Naira
X4 = Years of schooling of household head as proxy for
management.
X5 = Fertilizer in Naira per kilogram per hectare
X6 = Planting Materials in Naira per hectare
X7 = Off-farm income in Naira
X8 = Age of head of household
3. Results and Discussion
3.1. Household Subsistence Orientation: Concepts and
Basic Patterns
The extent of subsistence orientation based on the criteria
outlined in the methodology can be assessed by looking at
the inter-relationship between farm size (Person-land ratio)
and market integration. In Table 1 it is important to note that
the average persons per hectare at the bottom quartile is 20,
for the second quartile, it is 13.1, the third quartile is 8.1 and
2.6 persons for the top quartile. Equally, 78 percent of the
sampled households fell within the top quartile (land-richest).
The implication of this result from the table is that majority
3
of the households (78 percent) retain only 37.7 percent of
total agricultural production for subsistence. Thus households are more market-oriented as a greater percentage of
agricultural production enters the exchange economy.
Crop sales constitute the main source of marketed surplus
and table 1 show that the land-richest sale 85.4 percent of the
value of agricultural production far above the sample average of 52.4 percent. In the land – poorest group crops sales
constitute only 16.1 percent of the total value of agricultural
production. This implies that more the output enters the
market.
Table 1. Farm Size, Subsistence Orientation in Agricultural Production
(Consumption Concept) and Main Source of Market Orientation.
Person-land
Ratio Group
Value of subsistence in
percent of Total Agricultural Production
(Concept I)
Value of crop sales in
percent of total
Agricultural Production
Bottom quartile
(land poorest)
66.0
16.1
Second quartile
70.0
43.0
Third quartile
60.9
67.5
Top quartile
(land richest)
37.7
85.4
Average
43.9
52.4
Households were ranked according to income concept –
the relative importance of subsistence production to total
income (Table 2). It was revealed that households that were
least subsistence – oriented earned the highest income per
capita (Column 2). Households that were most-subsistenceoriented earned the lowest income. Off-farm income as a
percentage of total income was lowest at the top quartile
(1.11 percent). Most subsistence households earn less in
terms of of-farm income. Off-farm income was highest at the
second and third quartile groups while it was 5.93 percent at
the bottom quartile (least subsistence-oriented). It is important to note that off-farm income is of considerable importance in Abia State, since 38 percent of the sampled households who were least subsistence-oriented (Bottom quartile)
earn off-farm income above the average.
Landholding of households is a major factor that determines households’ income earning in the state. Table 3 show
income earnings by farm size groups. Grouping households
in quartiles by farm size show that the top 25 percent (with
an average of 12.78 hectares) has farms 8.5 times larger than
the bottom quartile (1.51 hectares). The number of households at top quartile is only 4 percent compared to the high
percentage at the bottom quartile – 64 percent. Farm income
per capita at the top quartile is 4.9 times higher than that in
the bottom quartile (Column 2). In aggregate given the low
percentage of the sampled population at the top quartile,
income from the bottom can be said to be more significant
given that they constitute 64 percent of the sample. Off-farm
incomes decreases as farm size increase (column 5).
Households with smaller landholding may likely spend more
4
Chukwukere Austin Okezie et al.: Farm - Level Determinants of Agricultural Commercialization
time off-farm.
Table 2. Subsistence Orientation and Income.
Group by Degree of
subsistence over total
income* (Income
concept)
Farm size
Total income per
capita (Average
=100)
Off-farm
income per
capita
(hectares)
(average value of
sample)
Percent of
total income
Bottom quartile (least
susitence-oriented)
4.00
153.5
5.93
Second quartile
2.67
75.9
6.36
Third quartile
2.49
51.5
6.14
Top quartile (most
susitence-oriented)
2.38
46.3
1.11
Average
3.11
100.0
5.58
* Total income includes off-farm income, transfers and remittances.
Table 3. Income by Farm Size Group.
Farm
size
Group
Farm size
(Average
of group)
(Hectares)
Bottom
quartile
Second
quartile
Third
quartile
Top
quartile
Average
Farm Income
per capita
(Average
= 100)
Total income
Per capita
(Average
=100)
(Average value of sample)
Share of Income
from
off-income &
agriculture
(Percent of total
income)
1.51
58.9
69.3
92.76
7.24
5.79
131.9
118.0
96.84
3.16
8.03
300.8
299.7
99.68
0.32
12.78
286.1
204.5
99.07
0.93
3.42
100.0
100.0
94.45
5.55
3.2. Farm-Level Determinants of Agricultural
Commercialization
Household production resources determine the degree of
subsistence or agricultural commercialization in farm
households. To explore the determinants of agricultural
commercialization, an aggregated all-crop production function of the Cobb-Douglas type was specified. Results of the
Cobb-Douglas production estimates are presented in Table 4.
The variables included in the model were able to capture
58.7 percent of the variability in agricultural commercialization and the model result was significant at 1 Percent. The
socio-economic factors of land, capital, management as
proxied by schooling of head of household and off-farm
income impinge were not found to be significant determinants of agricultural commercialization at the farm-level.
However, labour, fertilizer and planting material were found
to be significant determinants of agricultural commercialization. The production elasticity of fertilizer and planting
material were found to be low, 0.167 and 0.164 respectively.
The results of the econometric estimation show the
dominant role of labour in the farm sector. The production
elasticity of labour is high 0.73 which confirms the analogy
that agriculture is still labour-intensive in the state. In prin-
ciple, adding up the production elasticity of the three key
factors of production (LAND, LABOUR, and CAPITAL)
gives a rough indication of the nature of economies of scale.
This exercise suggests that, the sum of production elasticity
is 0.57, implying that there is diseconomies of scale. This is
not surprising given the fact that the production technology
is very much limited to hoe and cutlass. There is
out-migration of the youths leaving farming to women and
aged and retired persons. There is still higher opportunity of
getting higher returns per unit of factor input given the
diseconomies of scale observed in the study area.
Table 4.
Farm-level Determinants of Agricultural Commercialization.
Variable
Coefficients
Std Error
t-values
Constant
Land (X1)
Labour (X2)
Capital (X3)
Schooling of HH(X4)
Fertilizer (X5)
Planting Material(X6)
Off-farm income (X7)
R2 – adjusted
F – value
3.92**
-0.17
0.73***
0.00
0.06
0.17*
0.16**
0.02
0.59
22.35***
1.74
0.38
0.40
0.14
0.27
0.03
0.04
0.02
2.26
-0.78
3.45
0.02
0.92
1.99
2.00
0.31
Note: HH = Head of Household. *, ** and *** significant at 10, 5 and 1
percent respectively.
4. Conclusions
Commercialization of agricultural system is a universal
phenomenon that is triggered by economic growth. To drive
economic growth, policy direction shifted from subsistence
production to commercialized systems. The extent of commercialization of agriculture in Abia State was captured by
the concepts defined. Agricultural production is not subsistence-oriented as only 43.9 percent of agricultural production is for home consumption. Subsistence food production
constitutes about 45.8 percent of total income. The value of
own-production to total consumption value is 28.5 percent
implying that households are market oriented in consumption. The farm-level determinants of agricultural commercialization were labour, fertilizer and planting materials This
is however, a prior expected as agriculture is still labour
intensive. The dominant role of labour of is indicated by the
high production elasticity of labour 0.73 while that of fertilizer and planting materials were 0.167 and 0.164 respectively. The production elasticity of the factors of production
indicates that there are diseconomies of scale in the study
area. This is an indication that the potentials of agriculture
have not been fully harnessed.
REFERENCES
[1]
S. Jaffee, 1992, Enhancing agricultural growth through
diversification in sub-Saharan Africa in Barghouti, S. Garbus,
International Journal of Agriculture and Forestry 2012, 2(2): 1-5
5
S. and Umuli, D. (eds) Trends in Agricultural Diversification:
Regional Perspectives. Technical Paper No. 180, August
1992. The World Bank, Washington, DC
[11] J. Hinderink and K.Sterkenburg 1987, “Agricultural commercialization and government policy in Africa”. KPI Limited, New York, USA
[2]
DFID. (2002). Eliminating hunger: strategy for achieving the
Millennium Development Goal on Hunger, DFID. London,
May 2002
[3]
Md. H. Rahman, and M. Somprawin. Landlessness and its
impact on economic development: A case study on Bangladesh. Journal of Social Sciences, 2: 54-60. DOI:
10.3844/jssp.2006.54.60
[12] M. D. C. Immink and J. A. Alarcon, 1995, Household income,
food availability and commercial crop production by Smallholder farmers in the Western Highlands of Guatemala,
Economic Development and Cultural Change 41:319-342
[4]
[5]
[6]
[7]
[8]
[9]
J. von Braun, H. Haen and J. Blanken, 1991, “Commercialization of agriculture under population pressure: effects on
production, consumption, and nutrition in Rwanda.” Research
Report 85. International Food Policy Research Institute
P. L. Pingali, and M.W. Rosegrant, 1995, ‘Agricultural
commercialization and diversification: processes and policies’, Food Policy, 20 (3): 171-185
K. Yoon-Doo and S. Yoon, 2009, “A note on the improvement of evaluation system in wholesale markets of agricultural and fishery products”. American Journal of Applied
Sciences, 6: 1604-1612. DOI: 10.3844/ajassp.2009.1604.
1612
R. Cohen Ronald ed. 1988, “Food production and commercialization of African agriculture”. In: satisfying Africa’s
food needs. Lynne Publishers Boulder/London
C. L. Delgado, 1995, “Agricultural diversification and export
promotion in Sub-Saharan Africa”. Food Policy, Vol. 20, No.
3 pp. 225 – 243, 1995
I. Panashat, 2011, “Unique identity of Lanna Silver Jewelry: a
development as a commercial product”. Journal of Social
Sciences, 7: 447-450. DOI: 10.3844/jssp.2011.447.450
[10] M. Norsida and N. M. Nawi, 2010, The practice of contract
farming among fresh fruit and vegetable suppliers in Malaysia. American Journal of Agricultural and Biological Sciences,
5: 321-330. DOI: 10.3844/ajabssp.2010.321
[13] E. Kennedy, 1994, Production, employment and Income
effects of Commercialization of Agriculture in J. von Braun
and E. Kennedy (eds), Commercialization of Agriculture,
Economic Development and Nutrition. PP. 37 – 64. John
Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, M. D
[14] J. von Braun, 1995, “Agricultural commercialization: impacts
on income and nutrition and implications for policy. Food
Policy, 20 (3): 187 – 202
[15] FOS, 1999, Annual Abstract of statistics. Federal Office of
Statistics, Abuja, Nigeria
[16] NPC. 2006, National population commission – Nigerian
Population census report
[17] E. Kennedy and B. Cogill 1987, “Income and nutritional
effects of the commercialization of agriculture in South
Western Kenya’. Research Report 63. Washington, D.C.;
International Food Policy Research Institute
[18] J. von Braun and E. Kennedy 1994, “Agricultural commercialization, economic development and nutrition”. IFPRI
Publication. Food Policy Statement 19
[19] J. Govereh and T. S. Jayne 1996, “Effects of cash crop production on food crop productivity in Zimbakwe: synergies or
trade – offs?” Policy Synthesis 40: 1-6 Department of Agricultural Economics Michigan State University
[20] M.G. Farouque, and H. Tekeya, 2008, Farmers' use of integrated soil fertility and nutrient management practices for
sustainable crop production: a field-level study in Bangladesh.
American Journal of Agricultural and Biological Sciences, 3:
716-723. DOI: 10.3844/ajabssp.2008.716.723