See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/297907844
Terrorism And Poverty: Is There A Causal Relationship?
Chapter · January 2007
CITATIONS
READS
0
16
1 author:
Ivan Manokha
Sciences Po Paris
10 PUBLICATIONS 59 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Ivan Manokha on 12 March 2016.
The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.
CHAPTER 3
TERRORISM AND POVERTY:
IS T HER E A CAUSAL R EL AT IONSHIP?
IVAN MANOKHA
INTRODUCTION
‘Without a war on poverty we will never defeat terror’, warned Benazir Bhutto, former
Prime Minister of Pakistan, in her recent critique of Western policies to combat
international terrorism.1 The existence of a causal relationship between anti-Western
terrorism and poverty has also been suggested by a range of other prominent observers
such as US President George W. Bush,2 British Prime Minister Tony Blair3 and James
Wolfensohn,4 former President of the World Bank (2002), as well as a number of
academics and journalists.5
Such arguments have in common the assumption that individuals suffering from a
lack of resources, chronic unemployment, poor education and other violations of
basic economic and social rights, may be influenced by radical ideas and recruited
as terrorists more easily than those who have a regular income and a good level of
education. Although intuitively plausible, this argument appears to be questionable
on two counts. First, the anti-Western terrorist attacks have been, first and foremost,
1
2
3
4
5
B. BHUTTO, ‘Without a War on Poverty We Will Never Defeat Terror: Dictatorship and Religious
Extremism are Fuelled by Gross Inequality’, The Guardian, 9 August 2004, www.guardian.co.uk/
print/0,4988688–103677,00.html.
G. BUSH, ‘President Outlines U.S. Plan to Help World's Poor’, Remarks by the President at United
Nations Financing for Development Conference, Cintermex Convention Center, Monterrey,
Mexico, 22 March 2002, www.whitehouse.gov/news/releases/2002/03/20020322–1.html.
J. MERRICK, ‘Blair’s major U-turn in the war on terror’, Daily Mail, 2 August 2006, at 5.
J.WOLFENSOHN, ‘Making the World a Better and Safer Place: The Time for Action is Now’, 22
Politics, (2002), at 118.
P. EHRLICH and J. LIU, ‘Some Roots of Terrorism’, 24 Population and Environment, (2002), at 183;
L. TYSON, ‘It’s Time to Step Up the Global War on Poverty’, Business Week, 3 December 2001, at
26; R. SOKOLSKY and J. MCMILLAN, ‘Foreign Aid in our Own Defense’, New York Times, 12 February
2002, at A23; C. MILLOY, ‘Terrorism feeds on the global suffering we too often ignore’, Washington
Post, 19 September 2001, at B1; W. RASPBERRY, ‘Terrorism’s fertile fields’, Washington Post,
1 October 2001, at A21.
Intersentia
43
Ivan Manokha
religiously motivated and directly related to the Israeli-Palestinian conflict and the
support that Israel receives from the United States and other Western states. Second,
the al-Qaeda terrorists who perpetrated the terrorist attacks of September 11 were
far from poor or uneducated. Furthermore, recent empirical studies that have
investigated the relationship between terrorism and poverty using statistical data on
the levels of income and education of terrorists have categorically denied any link
between the two.6
This chapter nevertheless seeks to demonstrate that such a causal link does exist and
that poverty does play a role in the development of anti-Western terrorist activity.
I suggest that in the arguments of both the proponents and the opponents of a causal
relationship between poverty and terrorism there are some important shortcomings.
First, both sides fail to make a link between anti-Western terrorism and Islamic
fundamentalism, which, in its turn, is inseparable from economic problems that
secularist and nationalist governments started to face in the 1970s in a number of
Muslim states. The militant Islam that rose to prominence in this period contained
anti-Western rhetoric and explicit calls for a jihad against the West right from the
start. Second, poverty is examined in a reductionist and isolationist manner, as a set
of statistical data for countries where terrorist organisations are located. That is to
say, poverty is not seen in relation to wealth elsewhere, nor is it explained but is taken
for granted and treated as a local problem whose solution is simply more urgent today
than before the attacks of September 11. This fails to take into account the operation
of the global political economy and structural inequalities between the West and the
rest of the world, which, as I will argue below, play a role in the development of antiWestern feelings and contribute to widespread support for anti-Western terrorism,
whether explicit or tacit. Finally, the conclusions of the empirical studies are also
problematic in that they concentrate on an analysis at the level of an individual
terrorist, ignoring the fact that in situations perceived as unjust by the participants
even those not directly affected by the injustices in question may decide to take action.
For example, opponents of racism or gender discrimination may not necessarily be
victims of such forms of discrimination. This, of course, is not to equate al-Qaeda
terrorists with freedom fighters; it is only to stress the fact that, in addition to an
examination of individual variables, structural conditions also need to be taken into
account.
6
44
A. KREUGER and J. MALECKOVA, ‘Education, Poverty and Terrorism: Is There a Causal Connection?’,
17 Journal of Economic Perspectives, (2003), at 119; A. KREUGER and D. LAITIN, ‘Faulty Terror Report
Card’, Washington Post, 17 May 2004, at 21; see also J.-F. REVEL, Anti-Americanism, (San Francisco,
Encounter Books, 2003); D. PIPES, ‘God and Mammon: Does Poverty Cause Militant Islam?’, The
National Interest, (2001–2002), at 14.
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
The argument proposed below is made of two parts. The first part carries out an
historical analysis of the development of Islamic fundamentalism and demonstrates
that it constituted, among other things, a societal reaction to acute socio-economic
problems that Muslim states began to face in the 1970s. The process of modernisation
and state-led industrialisation undertaken by nationalist and secularist governments
in a range of Muslim states in the post-independence period produced some tangible
results in the early years but was later frustrated by significant slowdowns in growth,
a rapid rise in unemployment and the impoverishment of large sectors of the
population. Coupled with the fact that most nationalist governments pursued very
authoritarian policies which became increasingly unpopular, there emerged a setting
within which Islamic ideology gradually began to be seen as offering a better
alternative and acquired more and more supporters. Although initially the project
of Islamic militantism was mostly directed against the national governments of
Muslim states, right from the beginning it also identified the West one of its enemies
and targets. The proclamation of a holy war against Western states and the development of anti-Western terrorism gained real momentum after the Iranian revolution
of 1979 and the subsequent support for Islamic fundamentalism in other countries
provided by Iran.
The second part addresses the contemporary context of anti-Western terrorism. The
socio-economic conditions in a range of Islamic states that led to the development
of radical Islamic organisations and parties have not only not improved but in many
cases have very significantly deteriorated. Such a situation is examined as an issue of
structural inequality and in terms of its causal relationship with the development of
terrorism today. The argument is built around the concept of the ‘social bandit’
borrowed from British historian Eric Hobsbawm.7 By social bandits Hobsbawm refers
to those outlaws in pre-capitalist societies who robbed the rich and gave at least some
of their loot to the poor. Their motives diverged a great deal but what was common
to all social bandits was a mythology that surrounded their activities and strong
popular sympathy and support. In a nutshell, the majority of pre-capitalist populations included poor peasants and when such ‘primitive rebels’ attacked the rich they
became popular heroes, despite the fact that they were cruel and violent. In addition,
such rebels were primitive in the sense that they lacked any concrete programme for
reform or long-term project. They did not question structural relations, nor did they
seek to understand the causes of people’s misfortunes. In this chapter I use
Hobsbawm’s notion of social bandit to describe the fact that in today’s international
setting, particularly in the context of huge international inequality and widespread
7
E. HOBSBAWM, Primitive Rebels: Studies in Archaic Forms of Social Movement in the 19th and 20th
Centuries, (Manchester, Manchester University Press, 1959); E. HOBSBAWM, Bandits, (London,
Abacus, 2000).
Intersentia
45
Ivan Manokha
poverty in the non-Western world, violence against Western states, particularly the
United States, enjoys significant sympathy elsewhere. This is not only an outcome
of inequality but has to do with other factors, particularly certain political and military
actions of the US and other Western states. What is important to note here is that the
violence perpetrated by terrorists is directed at those who are seen as beneficiaries of
the existing order, of international inequalities and injustices and who, for these
reasons, attract moral indignation. At the same time, al-Qaeda terrorism has no
concrete project of reform, only vague calls for the establishment of an Islamic
international order. Like social banditry in peasant societies, it is a primitive form of
rebellion and is bound to fail.
HIS TORIC AL DEVELOPMENT OF IS LAMIC
FUNDAMENTALISM
The roots of contemporary Islamic fundamentalism and of its anti-Western dimension
go back to the period of colonial domination of Muslim societies by Western powers.
The early form of militant Islamism, or ‘pre-fundamentalism’,8 emerged in the late
19th and early 20th centuries and was championed by such movements as the
Wahhabis in Arabia, the Mahdis in Sudan, the Sanusis in North Africa, the Khilafat
Movement in India and the Muslim Brotherhood in the pre-independence years in
Egypt.9 The pre-fundamentalist project of Islamic renewal from within and the
attempt to unite Muslims into a strong pan-Islamic movement as a means of resisting
European colonial ambitions resulted in the development of a new Islamic ideology
by such figures as Jamal ad-din al-Afghani in Iran, Mohammed Abduh and Hassan
al Banna in Egypt, Muhammad Rashid Rida in Syria, and Sayyid Ahmed Khan in
India.10 During this phase of Islamic revivalism poverty did not seem to play any causal
role; however, in order to understand better the relationship between socio-economic
conditions, Islamic fundamentalism and anti-Western terrorism today, it is important
to bear in mind the fact that the early militant Islamic ideologies had an important
anti-Western element from the outset.
In the immediate post-independence period, the Islamic project suffered a significant
setback with the rise of nationalist secular governments whose declared objective was
8
9
10
46
B. MILTON-EDWARDS, Islamic Fundamentalism since 1945, (New York, Routledge, 2004).
P. HOLT, The Mahdist State in the Sudan, 1881–1898, (London, Oxford University Press, 1958); H.
ENAYAT, Modern Islamic Political Thought, (Austin, University of Texas Press, 1982).
A. HOURANI, Arabic Thought in the Liberal Age, 1789–1939, (Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 1982); K. CRAGG, Counsels in Contemporary Islam, (Edinburgh, Edinburgh University Press,
1965).
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
to modernise Muslim societies. In Egypt under Nasser, Syria and Iraq under the Ba’th,
Iran under the Shah, Tunisia under the Neo-Dustur Party, and Algeria under the
National Liberation Front, policies of separating the state from religion were
implemented. The leaders of such regimes undertook major cultural, educational and
political campaigns to convert the Muslim masses to the ideologies of socialism or
secular nationalism, suppressing resistance to the virtual elimination of the Islamists
in many areas. Policies of modernisation were initially successful, achieving average
growth close to 2.5 per cent11 but by the mid-1970s socio-economic conditions in
virtually all Muslim states were rapidly deteriorating. We can divide the key states in
the Middle East and North Africa into two broad groups: diversified Arab economies
(DAE), which include Algeria, Egypt, Jordan, Lebanon, Morocco, Syria and Tunisia;
and oil Arab economies (OAE), which comprise Libya, Bahrain, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar,
Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates.12 Despite their different structures,
economic problems in all these states appeared roughly at the same time: the failure
of state-led import substitution industrialisation in DAE countries became apparent
in the 1970s, coinciding with oil price shocks that affected oil-exporting countries.
Thus, the adoption of state-led industrialisation by such states as Egypt, Jordan,
Algeria, Syria, Tunisia and Morocco was influenced by a development paradigm that
prevailed in the 1940s and 1950s, namely the idea that development was synonymous
with industrialisation, which was achieved through protectionism and import
substitution. Although the doctrine of import substitution emerged and developed
predominantly in Latin America, in total 78 developing countries outside the Soviet
bloc, including the Arab countries, chose in this period some form of inward-looking
development strategy13 and all of them soon started facing similar problems. First,
these closed economies borrowed heavily from foreign sources, which resulted in a
debt crisis when creditors withdrew support from further lending. Second, they
oriented investment toward non-traded goods and thus lacked the foreign exchange
earnings to service the debts.14 Third, they had a higher level of state involvement in
the economy, including the ownership of state enterprises, and loss-making state
enterprises added significantly to the overall fiscal burden of many governments in
the 1970s and 1980s, contributing to the onset of high inflation and foreign debt
crises.15 After early successes, these economies suffered sharp downturns in economic
growth, high inflation and mass unemployment in the 1970s and 1980s.
11
12
13
14
15
I. ELBADAWI, ‘Reviving Growth in the Arab World’, 53 Economic Development and Cultural Change,
(2005), at 293.
‘Economic Trends in the MENA Region’, Economic Research Forum, (Cairo, ERF, 1998).
J. SACHS et al, ‘Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration’, Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity No. 1, (1995).
WORLD BANK, World Development Report 1978, (Washington, World Bank Publications, 1978).
SACHS and WARNER, infra n. 16, at 55.
Intersentia
47
Ivan Manokha
The oil-exporting countries of the region faced different problems. First, they suffered
from an over-reliance on oil revenue, which tended to undermine the competitiveness
of the non-resource tradable sectors and hence impeded economic diversification and
growth.16 Second, economic expansion, especially during the oil boom of the 1970s,
induced structural imbalances and disequilibria: most of the growth was in the service
sector of the economy, especially government services, and in consumer-related
industries. This worked to the detriment of agricultural and industrial expansion,
which lagged behind in most Arab countries.17 Third, oil dependence generated
corrosive effects on governance and accountability and hence undermined the
institutional foundation of growth.18 Related to this was the problem of redistributing
income from oil. The gulf between the few beneficiaries of growth and all those who
were left out grew ever wider, making for a greater polarisation of the societies and
further economic asymmetries. These problems manifested themselves most acutely
following the collapse of oil prices in the early 1980s.
As a result, in the late 1970s and early 1980s, countries in the Middle East and North
Africa were marked by ‘increased unemployment, mass impoverishment, population
explosion, urban hypertrophy, lagging food production, low industrial productivity,
inadequately trained labour force, huge defence expenditures, increasing inequality,
political instability, and social fragmentation’.19 The expectations that accompanied
the onset of modernisation, particularly among the young, were crushed by harsh
socio-economic realities. The feelings of disillusionment and dissatisfaction were
further increased by the highly authoritarian nature of most governments in the
region. In every Arab state, the centralisation of power in the hands of one person
or clan has been the dominant feature of politics over the last four decades,20 with
political parties, labour unions and voluntary organisations being either outlawed
and repressed, or at least dismissed as irrelevant.21
It is against this background that the rise of militant Islam needs to be examined. The
Islamists recognised the crisis around them and formulated an approach that
16
17
18
19
20
21
48
J. NEARY and S. VAN WIJNBERGEN, Natural Resources and the Macroeconomy, (Cambridge, MIT
Press, 1985); J. SACHS and A. WARNER, ‘Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth’,
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, No. 5398, (1995).
M. FAKSH, ‘The Chimera of Education for Development in Egypt: The Socio-Economic Roles of
University Graduates’, 13 Middle Eastern Studies, (1997), at 229.
B. EIFFERT, A. GELB and N. TALLROTH, ‘Managing Oil Wealth’, 40 Finance and Development IMF
Quarterly, (2003), at 40.
C. ISSAWI, An Economic History of the Middle East and North Africa, (London, Methuen, 1982).
A. DAWISHA, ‘Arab Regimes: Legitimacy and Foreign Policy’, in G. LUCIANI (ed), The Arab State,
(Berkeley, University of California Press, 1990).
H. BARAKAT, ‘Ideological Determinants of Arab Development’, in I. IBRAHIM (ed), Arab Resources,
(London, Croom Helm, 1983).
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
facilitated their reinsertion into the public arena. They took up the cause of the poor
and called for responsible government, social justice and a more equitable distribution
of income.22 As Sheikh Naim al-Qassam, deputy leader of Hezbollah, proclaimed: ‘We
want to build society, to provide essential services and meet the prevailing
challenges’.23 Earlier on, Khomeini used such slogans as ‘Islam is for equity and social
justice’, ‘Islam will eliminate class differences’, and ‘Islam will liberate the hungry and
the oppressed from the clutches of the rich and the oppressors’.24 As Zubaida argues,
the root of the Islamic phenomenon is economic and demographic problems and the
inability of the state to cope with them; ‘this is where the Islamists are moving in’.25
For a generation of young, educated members of the middle and lower-middle classes,
as well as the impoverished masses, faced with the denial of opportunities for
education, employment and shelter, the militant Islamist ideology of the likes of
Ayatollah Khomeini and Ali Shariati of Iran, Al-Turabi of Sudan, Abul Ala Maududi
of Pakistan and Sayyid Qutb of Egypt was an attractive alternative and they constituted
the chief recruitment pool for the Islamic movements. Islamists themselves acknowledge this: ‘Islam is the religion of bad times’, said an Egyptian sheikh; ‘it is enough
to see the poverty-stricken outskirts of Algiers or the refugee camps in Gaza to
understand the factors that nurture the strength of the Islamic Resistance Movement’,
said a Hamas leader in Gaza.26 Islamic fundamentalism was therefore an indigenous
response, especially among the masses of the destitute and underprivileged, to
prevalent socio-economic and political problems and the inability of secular
governments to guarantee the basic rights of their citizens.
Thus, the 1980s witnessed the emergence on the political stage of the Middle East and
North Africa of movements and parties advocating the resurgence of Islam. These
parties enjoyed their greatest political successes in countries suffering ‘regime
exhaustion’,27 that is, a failure of regimes to develop any coherent mass base and to
achieve economic prosperity for the masses. Iran was the first country to fall to the
Islamists, followed by the Sudan. Islamic militants also made significant inroads in
Lebanon, among the Palestinians and in Syria.28 In Algeria, the Islamic Salvation Front
(FIS) was on the verge of a dramatic electoral victory over the regime party (the FLN)
in 1992 when the military took overt control of the government and imposed harsh,
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
M. FAKSH, supra n. 17.
Quoted in B. MILTON-EDWARDS, supra n. 8, at 55.
See E. ABRAHAMIAN, ‘Khomeini: A Fundamentalist?’, in L. KAPLAN (ed), Fundamentalism in
Comparative Perspective, (Amherst, University of Massachusetts Press, 1992).
S. ZUBAIDA, Islam, the People and the State: Political Ideas and Movements in the Middle East,
(London, I.B. Tauris, 1993).
Id. 14.
A. RICHARDS and J. WATERBURY, A Political Economy of the Middle East: State, Class, and Economic
Development, (Boulder, Westview Press, 1990), at 432.
T. FRIEDMAN, From Beirut to Jerusalem, (New York, Farrar Straus Giroux, 1989).
Intersentia
49
Ivan Manokha
repressive measures. In Jordan, the Muslim Brotherhood legitimately earned a
position from which it could bid for a formal share of power by electing 34 candidates
out of a total of 80 in the national parliament in 1989 to become the largest organised
group in that body. In Egypt, Islamic militants quietly constructed a network of social
support services that reportedly functioned more smoothly than the corrupt and
inefficient government bureaucracy. These groups also insinuated themselves into
the parliament by means of alliances with officially sanctioned parties.29
Development of anti-Western terrorism was an understandable outcome of the rise
of Islamic fundamentalism. The reason for this is the central role played in radical
Islamic ideologies by the idea of jihad, or holy war. The notion of jihad has many
different interpretations in Islam but what is certain is that, at least in part, it involves
the restoration and reassertion of Islamic authenticity in response to Western
hegemony. Ever since its encounter with, and subsequent domination by, the West,
Islam has been on the retreat. This is particularly so in the 20th century, prompting
one leading Islamist, Muhammad al-Bahi, to call it ‘the century of eclipse’.30 Coupled
with the fact that the origins of Islamic fundamentalism were already in part antiWestern in nature, as we have seen above, it was only a step away from anti-Western
terrorism. A move from such radical rhetoric to practice took place with the Iranian
revolution of 1979, when Iran became a major supporter of anti-Western Islamic
terrorism, of a holy war against the ‘Great Satan’ as Khomeini, following Qutb,
branded the US. The era of religiously motivated suicide missions against Western
targets was inaugurated during the Lebanese civil war (1975–90), especially in the
1980s. Taking inspiration from Iran’s Islamic revolution and also supported by Syria,
Hezbollah militants led a carefully planned suicide attack against the US Embassy in
Beirut in December 1981, killing 69 people. In 1983, Hezbollah members embracing
martyrdom were particularly effective in staging a devastating blow against the
Western military presence within the multinational force in Lebanon, killing 241 US
marines and 58 French parachutists.
To sum up, the argument made in this section traces the roots of contemporary antiWestern terrorism to the development of Islamic fundamentalism in the context of
socio-economic problems that post-independence Muslim states began to face in the
1960s and 1970s. Militant Islamism, as Taheri observed, was ‘bound to end in
terrorism’.31 As we have seen above, the anti-Western and militant element has been
present in the Islamic revival right from the start and it increased dramatically after
29
30
31
50
F. TACHAU, ‘Introduction’, in F. TACHAU (ed), Political Parties of the Middle East and North Africa,
(Westport, Greenwood Press, 1994), at xviii.
In M. FAKSH, supra n. 17, at 8.
A. TAHERI, Holy Terror: The Inside Story of Islamic Terrorism, (London, Sphere Books, 1985), at 75.
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
the Six Day War and the Iranian revolution. Therefore, as Milton-Edwards rightly
notes, ‘al-Qaeda represents the apogee of Islamic fundamentalism’.32 In other words,
we can construct a causal chain from poverty and the denial of basic socio-economic
rights in Muslim states in the 1970s, the development of radical Islamic fundamentalism that proposed a solution to these problems and gained a lot of support from the
poor and oppressed masses, to the development of anti-Western terrorism. In the
next section we will examine the current global situation and the role of ever
deteriorating socio-economic conditions in the development of anti-Western Islamic
terrorism, which seems to have reached its peak.
NEW ‘S OC IAL BANDITS’
The socio-economic problems of Arab countries discussed above coincided in time
and were, to a certain extent, causally linked, with profound transformations in the
global economic order. Following the French Regulation School and a neo-Gramscian
approach to international relations, we can describe these transformations as a shift
from an order based on a Fordist structure accumulation, which characterised in
particular developed industrialised economies in the period from the end of the
Second World War to the early 1970s, to a new post-Fordist or non-Fordist
structure.33 There is no space here to provide a detailed overview of Fordism as
a structure of accumulation. What I would like to do is to contrast the Fordist
world order with the neo-liberal international system that has succeeded it. This will
enable us to see how and why international economic inequalities have grown and
how this in turn has impacted on the development of anti-Western terrorism.
As a regime of accumulation Fordism involved a cycle of growth based on the
synchronisation of mass production and mass consumption. This cycle comprised
32
33
B. MILTON-EDWARDS, supra n. 8, at 113.
M. AGLIETTA, A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: the US Experience, (London, New Left Books, 1979);
M. AGLIETTA, ‘Capitalism at the Turn of the Century: Regulation Theory and the Challenge of Social
Change’, New Left Review No. 232, (1998), at 41; R. BOYER, ‘The Political in the Era of Globalization
and Finance: Focus on Some Régulation School Research’, 24 International Journal of Urban and
Regional Research, (2000), at 274; B. JESSOP, ‘The Changing Governance of Welfare: Recent Trends
in its Primary Functions, Scale, and Modes of Coordination’, 33 Social Policy and Administration,
(1999), at 348; B. JESSOP, ‘Fordism and Post-Fordism: A Critical Reformulation’, in B. JESSOP (ed),
Regulation Theory and the Crisis of Capitalism, (Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2001); S. GILL,
‘Globalization, Market Civilization, and Disciplinary Neoliberalism’, 24 Millennium, (1995), at 399;
S. GILL, Power and Resistance in the New World Order, (Houndmills, Palgrave, 2003); M. RUPERT,
Producing Hegemony: the politics of mass production and American global power, (Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 1995); M. RUPERT, Ideologies of Globalization: Contending Visions of
a New World Order, (London, Routledge, 2000).
Intersentia
51
Ivan Manokha
the following elements: rising productivity based on economies of scale in mass
production, rising incomes linked to productivity, increased mass demand due to
rising wages, increased profits based on full utilisation of capacity, increased
investment in improved mass production equipment and techniques and a further
rise in productivity. This regime of accumulation was marked by a specific mode of
regulation – a welfare state which managed aggregate demand, controlled finance and
generalised mass consumption norms so that most citizens could share the prosperity
generated by rising economies of scale.34 The dominant economic paradigm at the
time was the Keynesian view that state intervention in the functioning of the market
was necessary to offset nominal rigidities, particularly in the labour market, through
government spending. State governments in Western Europe, North America and
Japan engaged in inflationary policies that were aimed at stimulating demand in order
to increase consumption and thereby fuel output and growth. In addition to this, trade
unions were well organised and their collective bargaining power was recognised by
enterprise management, while the former in turn recognised the latter’s right to
control the labour process and corporate strategy. At the core of Fordism was a
‘capital-labour compromise’ as the continuous rise in productivity was matched by
the integration of wage-earners into societies for life through mass consumption and
the creation of diverse social protection systems.35 International structures of trade
and finance were based on the internationalisation of this negotiated compromise
between the factions of capital and labour in a range of capitalist states.36 In other
words, there emerged a form of a consensus among governments in the US, Western
Europe and Japan concerning the development of a capitalist world economy marked
by significant state intervention in the functioning of the market. States were allowed
to pursue inflationary economic stabilisation and social welfare policies and this
consensus was institutionalised in the framework of the International Monetary Fund
(IMF), the World Bank and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT).
Central to the established international order ‘were the ideological notions of the
“mixed economy,” which allowed for a range national policies to be practiced in a
relatively expansionist, stable structure’.37
The Fordist system, however, began to crumble in the early 1970s. A number of factors
were responsible for the decline of Fordism, including slowdowns in productivity that
were not matched by a corresponding decline in wages (to a great extent due to the
significant bargaining power of workers’ organisations), a decline in the regulatory
34
35
36
37
52
B. JESSOP 2001, supra n. 33, at 35; M. AGLIETTA and R. BRETON, ‘Financial Systems, Corporate
Control and Capital Accumulation’, 30 Economy and Society, (2001), at 434.
R. BOYER, supra n. 33, at 280.
S. GILL, Power and Resistance in the New World Order, supra n. 33, at 87.
Id.
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
power of inflation (economic actors became used to the existence of inflation and
formed their expectations accordingly in terms of wage and price setting), gradual
transnationalisation of production processes (due to slowdowns in productivity and
an inability to reduce wages in the central countries, enterprises started searching for
lower wage zones abroad), as well as exogenous factors such as oil price shocks. Of
these processes the key role was played by the transnationalisation of production,
which put pressure on labour markets in developed states, particularly on low-skilled
workers and led to a rise in unemployment. States responded with policies of labour
market deregulation (in different countries to differing extents), which have eaten
away the bargaining power of trade unions and put to an end the Fordist capitallabour compromise in industrialised countries. The Keynesian welfare state has
gradually given way to a competition state38 which is more concerned with supply-side
intervention, such as technology development and job training, than with full
employment and demand.39 A new neo-liberal economic paradigm governing state
policies replaced Keynesianism with an emphasis on tight fiscal policy, low inflation
and a reduction of state regulation of the market: liberalisation of trade and capital
movements, privatisation of state-owned enterprises, reduction of public spending
and budget deficits and improvement of state competitiveness at the international
level, particularly in terms of obtaining foreign investment. At the international level
these new policy objectives were adopted by such institutions as the IMF and World
Bank, as well as the World Trade Organisation that succeeded GATT, and they are
commonly known as the ‘Washington Consensus’.
These developments have been described as constituting the development of a
hegemonic order at the centre of which is transnational capital.40 The notion of
hegemony refers not so much to the behavioural power of capital (although the fact
that multinational corporations (MNCs) own more than 25 per cent of the world’s
stocks and assets41 is in itself far from negligible) as to its structural power related to
38
39
40
41
P. CERNY, ‘Structuring the Political Arena: Public Goods, States and Governments in a Globalizing
World’, in R. PALAN (ed), Global Political Economy: Contemporary Theories, (London, Routledge,
2000).
B. JESSOP, ‘The Transition to Post-Fordism and the Schumpeterian Workfare State’, in R. BORROWS
and B. LOADER (eds), Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State, (London, Routledge, 1994).
R. COX, Production, Power, and World Order: Social Forces in the Making of History, (New York,
Columbia University Press, 1987); R. COX, ‘Gramsci, Hegemony and International Relations’, in
S. GILL (ed), Gramsci, Historical Materialism and International Relations, (Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 1993); R. COX, ‘Civil Society at the Turn of the Millennium: prospects for an
alternative world order’, 25 Review of International Studies, (1999), at 3; S. GILL and D. LAW, ‘Global
Hegemony and the Structural Power of Capital’; and G. ARRIGHI, ‘The Three Hegemonies of
Historical Capitalism’, in S. GILL (ed), Gramsci, Historical Materialism and International Relations,
supra.
J. HARRIS, ‘Globalisation and the Technological Transformation of Capitalism’, 40 Race and Class,
(1998), at 21.
Intersentia
53
Ivan Manokha
its high mobility. States need to attract and retain investment, which in turn requires
the adoption of regulations that favour the interests of capital, such as the removal
of state controls on the import and export of capital, reform of labour regulations,
favourable taxation schemes and so on. What is important to note here is that both
developed and developing states are affected, although the former have much more
room for manoeuvre in terms of policy options. As Gill notes, ‘even the autonomy
of the United States, Japan, and the European Union is constrained in matters of
macroeconomic policy by the globalisation of finance and production. Smaller and
less self-sufficient states tend to be correspondingly more sensitive and vulnerable
to global financial pressures’.42 In addition, no state can control what happens on the
world’s financial markets, although the repercussions of stock exchange crises are felt
everywhere in the world, as the East Asian and Russian crises have demonstrated. As
Arrighi points out, ‘the main tendency of the last 30 years has been for most states,
including the US, to become the servant rather than the master of extraterritorial
finance’.43 A similar argument is made by Robinson, who observes that globalisation
‘made it structurally impossible for individual nations to sustain independent, or even
autonomous, economies, policies and social structures’, whether they are ‘developed
or underdeveloped’.44
However, as mentioned above, in this highly competitive international structure
developed political economies have more policy options and economic levers available
to them than the governments of developing states. One of the key issues that interests
us here is international trade, which is structured in a very asymmetrical and unequal
manner and operates to the advantage of the developed Western economies. As has
repeatedly been emphasised by development non-governmental organisations (NGOs)
and many civil society groups and activists, Western states promote policies of trade
liberalisation elsewhere, often as a pre-condition for economic aid but discriminate
against imports from poorer countries. Among the key examples of such policies are
the Common Agricultural Policy in the European Union and agricultural subsidies
in the United States. There also exist restrictions and quotas on imports of textile
products, particularly in the United States and more recently the EU, that affect such
countries as India, Pakistan and Egypt. According to research undertaken in 2003 by
American economists, the world’s poorer countries lose a total of $24 billion a year
because of the subsidies paid to farmers by rich nations.45 According to the World
Bank, subsidies to agriculture (which run to roughly $1 billion a day) and tariffs in
42
43
44
45
54
S. GILL, ‘Globalization, Market Civilization, and Disciplinary Neoliberalism’, supra n. 33, at 399.
G. ARRIGHI, supra n. 40, at 69.
W. ROBINSON, ‘Globalisation: Nine Theses on Our Epoch’, 38 Race and Class, (1996), at 15.
BBC ‘Adding up farming subsidies’, BBC Online, 27 August 2003, http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/
business/3183139.stm.
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
high-income countries on imports from developing countries, which are four times
those collected from industrial countries, are ‘important impediments that keep the
poor from taking advantage of trading opportunities’.46 Furthermore, ‘the damage
caused by discrimination against goods efficiently produced by poor countries such
as food, textiles and clothing can be measured against faster integration which through
lowering barriers to merchandise would increase growth and provide some $1.5
trillion of additional cumulative income to developing countries over the 2005–2015
period’.47
The competitiveness and development possibilities of the South are further weakened
by the problem of external debt, which has significantly increased over the last several
decades. Thus, if in 1970, the world’s poorest countries (roughly 60 countries classified
as low income by the World Bank) owed $25 billion in debt, by 2002 their debt had
reached $523 billion even though over the last three decades they have repaid $550
billion in both principal and interest.48 Extrapolating from United Nations Children’s
Fund (UNICEF) data, as many as 5 million children and vulnerable adults may have
lost their lives in sub-Saharan Africa as a result of the debt crunch since the late
1980s.49 As Michael Mann notes, the issue of debt ‘is often perceived in the South as
constituting countries. The US is the leading imperial actor here, partly because
the institutions of the IMF, etc. reflect an earlier era in which the American economy
was more dominant than it is today. But other Northern countries are also
implicated’.50
In this highly competitive and at the same time very unequal international economic
environment, millions of people in the developing world suffer from poverty and
poverty-related problems. According to the United Nations Development Programme
(UNDP), of the 4.6 billion people in developing countries more than 850 million are
illiterate, nearly a billion lack access to improved water sources, and 2.4 billion lack
access to basic sanitation. Around 1.2 billion people live on less than $1 a day, and
2.8 billion on less than $2 a day.51 In addition to this, there is the issue of generic drugs
46
47
48
49
50
51
WORLD BANK, Global Economic Prospects and the Developing Countries, Making Trade Work for the
Poor, (Washington, World Bank Publications, 2002), at xiii.
Id. xiii.
BBC, ‘Debt relief hopes bring out the critics’, BBC Online, 29 June 2005, http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/
business/4619189.stm; S. KAPOOR, ‘Paying for 100% Multilateral Debt Cancellation’, EURODAD
publications, January, (2005), at 5.
R. BUCKLEY, ‘The Rich Borrow and the Poor Repay: The Fatal Flaw in International Finance’, 19
World Policy Journal, (2003), at 59.
M. MANN, ‘Globalization as Violence’, online paper, (2001), www.sscnet.ucla.edu/soc/faculty/mann/
globasviol%5B1%5D.pdf.
UNDP, Human Development Report 2003: Millennium Development Goals: A compact among nations
to end human poverty, (Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2004).
Intersentia
55
Ivan Manokha
which could save the lives of millions in the developing world but which go against
the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS
agreement) and which developing countries are not allowed to produce. Thus, 11
million children die each year from preventable diseases; more than one million die
from malaria; around two million people die annually from tuberculosis and
pneumonia kills two million children every year. Overall, today more than two billion
people in developing countries have no regular access to the drugs they need, partly
because prices are too high.52
We saw in the first part how deteriorating socio-economic conditions in Arab
countries led to the development of militant Islamist parties and movements. What
we can say, with respect to the economic situation in the region today, is that it has
not improved a great deal and that in some cases it has deteriorated further. An
example of such deterioration that is of particular importance for the analysis of
terrorism is Afghanistan. Afghanistan is a country that is nowadays categorised as a
‘failed state’, that is, a state that has not been able to maintain a monopoly on the use
of the means of violence within its borders and is not able to enforce its laws
uniformly. In addition to Afghanistan, a failed state category is also used to refer to
Liberia, Sierra Leone, Somalia, Yemen, East Timor and the Solomon Islands. The
causes of such state collapses are socio-economic, primarily the inability of state
economies to survive in this highly competitive and unequal international environment, or to finance basic public services and maintain minimal state apparatuses. A
number of observers have identified a direct causal link between failed states,
particularly Afghanistan, and international terrorism.53 Indeed, Afghanistan was used
by al-Qaeda to prepare the attacks of 9/11, and it continues to be one of the key
locations of terrorist bases and training camps. In addition, Afghanistan produces
up to 96 per cent of the world’s opium, which constitutes one of the sources that is
used to finance terrorist activity.
In addition to this direct causal link between the current global economic environment, poverty that affects some states as a result of its functioning to the point of
their collapse and terrorism, I would like to address the issue of poverty and terrorism
in structural terms. That is to say, poverty and large-scale violations of basic positive
rights need to be treated not in isolation, as is done by the empirical studies mentioned
earlier, but in relation to wealth and abundance elsewhere. For example, in developed
52
53
56
OXFAM, ‘Five Questions Drug Companies Don’t Want You to Ask’, (August, 2005),
www.oxfam.org/en/files/doc_questions_drug_companies_poverty/download.
J. SACHS, ‘The Strategic Significance of Global Inequality, 24 Washington Quarterly, (2001), at 187;
E.-O. CZEMPIEL, Weltpolitik im Umbruch: Die Pax Americana, der Terrorismus und die Zukunft der
internationalen Beziehungen, (München, Verlag Beck, 2003).
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
countries fewer than one child in 100 does not reach its fifth birthday, while in the
poorest countries as many as a fifth of children do not; while in developed countries
fewer than 5 per cent of all children under five are malnourished, in poor countries
as many as 50 per cent are; and the average income in the richest 20 countries is 37
times the average in the poorest 20, a gap that has doubled in the past 40 years.54
More importantly, empirical studies fail to deal with the fact that a lot of poverty
and human misery results from the policies, particularly the trade policies discussed
above, adopted by developed countries. This, of course, does not mean that all those
who hold developed countries responsible for these inequalities and injustices have
the potential to become terrorists. However, in this context it is understandable why
more and more people believe that they are dealing with a ‘global satan’, why more
and more people can be influenced by radical ideas and cross the line between holding
Western populations responsible and committing terrorist acts against innocent
people and why those who do receive popular support and are seen as heroes or
martyrs. As Courtland Milloy of the Washington Post observed, the root causes of
terrorism lie in global suffering, ‘which is systemic and deeply rooted – in colonialism,
racism, and greed’.55
To develop this argument further I propose to employ Eric Hobsbawm’s notion of
social banditry. In his earlier study ‘Primitive Rebels’ and in a recent book ‘Bandits’
Eric Hobsbawm presents an elaborate analysis of forms of social protest in precapitalist peasant societies. ‘Social banditry’, he argues, ‘is universally found wherever
societies are based on agriculture, and consist largely of peasants and landless
labourers ruled, oppressed and exploited by someone else – lords, towns, governments, lawyers, or even banks’.56 That is to say, social banditry is a relatively uniform
phenomenon which embodies a rather primitive form of organised social protest by
peasants against their landlords in particular and oppression, exploitation and
inequality in general. Social bandits such as Robin Hood, Pancho Villa, Ned Kelly
and Frank and Jesse James are robbers and gangsters of a special kind, for although
they are seen as outlaws or criminals by the state, the peasant community regards them
as ‘heroes, champions, avengers, fighters for justice, perhaps even leaders of liberation,
and in any case as men to be admired, helped and supported’,57for they defy the laws
and correct what peasants see as injustices or wrongs. Although social banditry is
a phenomenon common to agricultural societies in different geographical areas
54
55
56
57
WORLD BANK, World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty, (Washington, World Bank
Publications, 2001).
C. MILLOY, ‘Terrorism feeds on the global suffering we too often ignore’, Washington Post, 19
September 2001, at B1.
E. HOBSBAWM, Primitive Rebels: Studies in Archaic Forms of Social Movement in the 19th and 20th
Centuries, supra n. 7, at 15.
E. HOBSBAWM, Bandits, supra n. 7, at 20.
Intersentia
57
Ivan Manokha
and has a certain historical continuity, Hobsbawm notes that ‘banditry tended to
become epidemic in times of pauperisation and economic crisis’,58 and ‘during and
after periods of abnormal hardship, such as famines and wars, or at the moments when
the jaws of the dynamic modern world seize the static communities in order to destroy
and transform them’.59 Thus, an upsurge in social banditry could be observed in
Southern Italy and the Rhineland during the revolutionary transformations and wars
at the end of the 18th century, and in Southern Italy after unification, fanned by
the introduction of capitalist law and economic policy. In Calabria and Sardinia
the major epoch of brigandage began in the 1890s when the modern economy,
agricultural depression and emigration made their impact; and in the remote
Carpathian mountains banditry arose in the aftermath of the First World War.60
What is important to note about the concept of social banditry is that it is structural
in nature, that is, it does not approach individual primitive rebels in terms of their
personal characteristics, their intentions or objectives, or the mistakes they made
which account for their eventual capture or liquidation by state forces. Social bandits
are products of their historical and social context, of the way society is organised and
interpreted by the participants. As Hobsbawm puts it in reference to a primitive rebel,
‘the peasant society creates him and calls upon him, when it feels the need for a
champion and protector – but precisely then he is incapable of helping it. For social
banditry, though a protest, is a modest and unrevolutionary protest. It protests not
against the fact that peasants are poor and oppressed, but against the fact that they
are sometimes excessively poor and oppressed.’61 In other words, on the one hand
the structure of a peasant society creates conditions that encourage the development
of primitive rebels; on the other hand, it makes such rebellions ‘primitive’ and bound
to fail right from the start, as the way social relations of inequality are understood and
interpreted is still rudimentary and preconditions for more general transformatory
or revolutionary changes do not exist. As a result, social bandits ‘might succeed from
time to time… but who really believes that, with all its chief’s genius for irregular
warfare [such rebellions] would have faced anything but defeat?’62
I would argue that the late-modern global political economy, with all its injustices
and inequalities described above, provides a setting which encourages the development of such new social bandits who today, as Hobsbawm himself notes in passing,
58
59
60
61
62
58
Id. 26.
E. HOBSBAWM, Primitive Rebels: Studies in Archaic Forms of Social Movement in the 19th and 20th
Centuries, supra n. 7, at 24.
Id. 24.
Id. 24, emphasis added.
Id. 28.
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
are ‘described as terrorists’.63 This is not to equate or in any way compare Osama Bin
Laden with Robin Hood; it is to identify the structural context which is conducive to
the development of organisations and individuals that can perceive themselves, and be
perceived by many others, as heroes and martyrs fighting against the source of evil. It is
a structural setting within which individuals, particularly the youth, can be convinced
that committing terrorist acts against the West is a just thing to do. As Granville
observed, ‘the perpetrators of the September attacks, like so many primary exponents
of fanatical and murderous ideologies through history, were neither poor nor
uneducated, but the extensive poverty and even more widespread hopelessness give
these evil leaders fertile ground not only for recruiting their active foot soldiers, but
also for building popular sympathy among the Arab masses’.64 Or, as Talbott puts it
‘while suicide bombers are privileged and educated, their constituencies are the poor
who feel victimized’.65 According to Jerrold Post, a psychological profiler at the CIA,
the political and economic policies and practices of the US government and US-based
global corporations contribute to the conditions that create a ‘roiling hatred within
the Arab world directed at the United States’ and terrorists exploit ‘feelings of despair
over economic conditions’.66 An example of this is the following statement of Bin
Laden: ‘the West intends to deprive us of our manhood; imperialism does not only
exploit us, it emasculates us’.67 It is a context within which those who hesitate can
always be given examples of different Western policies, both past (colonialist
expansion and domination) and present (the trade and credit policies discussed
above), which provide instances of exploitation, military coercion, hypocrisy and,
more importantly, profound inequalities. As French philosopher Jean Baudrillard
argues, the attacks on the United States took place because ‘it is that superpower
which, by its unbearable power, has fomented all this violence which is endemic
throughout the world... We have dreamt of this event [9/11]... because no one can avoid
dreaming of the destruction of any power that has become hegemonic to this degree’.68
Baudrillard expresses here the same idea, except that he does not place anti-US
terrorism in the larger framework of the late-modern global political economy (GPE)
and the perception of the West in it in the non-Western and particularly Muslim,
world.
63
64
65
66
67
68
E. HOBSBAWM, Bandits, supra n. 7, at 19.
B. GRANVILLE, ‘The global economy: What has changed?’, in M. BUCKLEY and R. FAWN (eds), Global
Responses to Terrorism: 9/11, Afghanistan and beyond, (New York, Routledge, 2003), at 279.
S. TALBOTT, ‘The Other Evil’, Foreign Policy, (November/December, 2001), at 75.
M. COHN, ‘Understanding, Responding To, and Preventing Terrorism’, 24 Arab Studies Quarterly
Vol. 24, (2002), at 25.
Quoted in M. MANN, supra n. 50, at 1.
J. BAUDRILLARD, The Spirit of Terrorism, (London, Verso, 2002), at 11.
Intersentia
59
Ivan Manokha
What is important to note here is that, just as the social structure of peasant societies
created primitive rebels and then condemned them to failure, the late-modern GPE
on the one hand encourages the development of primitive rebels and on the other
makes their project an inevitable failure. This is so because any rebellion against
particular identifiable actors, such as Western states or multinational corporations,
neglects the structural context within which they operate and which conditions their
policies. As argued above, the late-modern GPE is characterised by the hegemonic
position of transnational capital, which limits the range of policy options at the
disposal of state governments. Even if developed states have had many more options,
and, as we have seen above, utilised them to the disadvantage of developing nations,
particularly in terms of trade relations, these policies cannot be reduced to the
intentions and capabilities of these states alone. They need to be placed within the
context of the highly competitive environment within which states find themselves
today, a Hobbesian war of all against all, which in turn is inseparable from the logic
of capitalist accumulation. As Granville observes, ‘restricted trade access for poor
countries’ primary resources and manufactures reflects the political and social
pressures of rich country unemployment, and other internal structural weaknesses’,69
which are, in turn, inseparable from the global context. There is no space to address
these issues here in detail, but what I wish to highlight with respect to the late-modern
GPE is that although actions directed against those who are seen as beneficiaries of
the existing order may generate sympathy and approval on the part of those who lose
out, just like the actions of social bandits in peasant societies, they are bound to be
unsuccessful. Not only do anti-Western terrorists and those who support their actions
reduce all social problems to the foreign policies of a handful of Western states but
they also lack any tangible alternative whatsoever. Their statements concerning the
corrupting influences of Western culture, their calls to stop Western imperialism, by
which they mean a whole range of things from Western movies reaching Muslim
societies to the presence of American troops in Saudi Arabia and their project of
establishing a global Islamic caliphate certainly do not constitute any tangible, let
alone attractive, alternative. As a result, they will inevitably fail.
The key question that arises out of this discussion is what would happen to antiWestern terrorism were poverty to be dramatically reduced or eradicated. Based on
the arguments developed above, it is my contention that the eradication of poverty
would remove one very important structural condition responsible for the creation
of social bandits or terrorists. Of course, religious terrorism would not be eradicated,
as religious fanaticism has existed throughout history, whether in the context of
poverty or not, and in the case of Islamic terrorism today there would still remain
69
60
B. GRANVILLE, supra n. 64, at 279.
Intersentia
Chapter 3: Terrorism and Poverty: Is There a Causal Relationship?
such issues as the Israeli-Palestinian conflict and the presence of US troops stationed
in Arab countries. Nevertheless, poverty reduction would alter the structures that
produces social bandits and would inevitably reduce their number. What this means
is that to fight anti-Western terrorism it is necessary to challenge international
economic inequalities and global poverty. This necessitates a counter-hegemonic
project directed not so much against individual or collective Western actors (such
as Western states, regional and international organisations such as the EU and the
World Bank, or multinational corporations) but against the global capitalist order
itself, particularly its neo-liberal version which has developed in the last two or
three decades. An analysis of such a counter-hegemonic project is beyond the scope
of this chapter; however, it is the contention here that in the absence of such a project
the governments of developed states and other actors, particularly international
financial institutions, should strive to take seriously the obligations contained in the
International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights and other
internationally recognised standards, as well as their commitments to the Millennium
Development Goals. This is a necessary measure, for by reducing poverty and
providing for at least the most basic rights of individuals in developing countries
they would deal a significant blow to anti-Western radicals and their legitimacy in
the eyes of others.
CONC LUSION
This chapter has argued that there exists a causal link between poverty and widespread
violations of economic and social rights on the one hand and anti-Western terrorism
on the other. Contrary to similar arguments made by different prominent observers,
this chapter did not focus on poverty as a factor pushing the poor and the unemployed
into terrorism. Instead, it has provided an historical analysis of the rise and development of Islamic fundamentalism and its relationship to the socio-economic problems
that Muslim states began to face in the 1970s and the way the rise of militant Islam
appeared to many to be a solution in that context. It has also demonstrated that
Islamic fundamentalism, right from the start, had a distinctive anti-Western
dimension and that the development of anti-Western terrorism was an inevitable
outcome of its militantism and its radical interpretation of the notion of jihad. With
respect to the current context, this chapter has used Eric Hobsbawm’s concept of
social bandit to describe how the injustices, inequalities and asymmetries that
characterise the late-modern GPE today create a context within which anti-Western
terrorism takes on a form of social banditry. It encourages the rise and development
of individuals who may see themselves and be seen by others as heroes and martyrs
fighting for a just cause. The chapter concludes that although the eradication of
Intersentia
61
Ivan Manokha
all poverty in the world would not result in the complete cessation of terrorism, it
would remove a crucial structural condition that encourages anti-Western terrorism
and the support that it generates.
62
View publication stats
Intersentia