ISSN 1518-3548
Working Paper Series
The Effect of Adverse Supply Shocks on
Monetary Policy and Output
Maria da Glória D. S. Araújo, Mirta Bugarin,
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Jose Ricardo C. Silva
April, 2006
ISSN 1518-3548
CGC 00.038.166/0001-05
Working Paper Series
Brasília
n. 103
Apr
2006
P. 1-44
Working Paper Series
Edited by Research Department (Depep) – E-mail:
[email protected]
Editor: Benjamin Miranda Tabak – E-mail:
[email protected]
Editorial Assistent: Jane Sofia Moita – E-mail:
[email protected]
Head of Research Department: Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo – E-mail:
[email protected]
The Banco Central do Brasil Working Papers are all evaluated in double blind referee process.
Reproduction is permitted only if source is stated as follows: Working Paper n. 103.
Authorized by Afonso Sant'Anna Bevilaqua, Deputy Governor of Economic Policy.
General Control of Publications
Banco Central do Brasil
Secre/Surel/Dimep
SBS – Quadra 3 – Bloco B – Edifício-Sede – M1
Caixa Postal 8.670
70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil
Phones: (5561) 3414-3710 and 3414-3567
Fax: (5561) 3414-3626
E-mail:
[email protected]
The views expressed in this work are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banco Central or
its members.
Although these Working Papers often represent preliminary work, citation of source is required when used or reproduced.
As opiniões expressas neste trabalho são exclusivamente do(s) autor(es) e não refletem, necessariamente, a visão do Banco
Central do Brasil.
Ainda que este artigo represente trabalho preliminar, citação da fonte é requerida mesmo quando reproduzido parcialmente.
Consumer Complaints and Public Enquiries Center
Address:
Secre/Surel/Diate
Edifício-Sede – 2º subsolo
SBS – Quadra 3 – Zona Central
70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil
Fax:
(5561) 3414-2553
Internet:
http://www.bcb.gov.br/?english
The Effect of Adverse Supply Shocks on
Monetary Policy and Output*
Maria da Glória D. S. Araújo**
Mirta Bugarin***
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos**
Jose Ricardo C. Silva**
Abstract
The aim of the present research is to use a model economy built for Brazil,
based on an optimizing dynamic general equilibrium model, in order to perform
numerical simulations to derive the ability of the artificial economy to explain
the impact of monetary policy interventions on short run economic performance
in terms of the inflation rate, output gap, interest rate and level of economic
activity in the face of an adverse supply shock. Alternative specification of
monetary reaction functions are introduced into the model economy in order to
perform a sensitivity analysis of derived impulse responses to those
interventions facing the negative productivity shock. The preliminary results
suggest that the introduction of habit persistence into the consumption
hypothesis does not make much difference. However the introduction of
different monetary reaction functions does alter the impulse response of output,
inflation rate, and nominal interest rate. A common result is the decline in
potential output for all models. Additionally, the only case where a reduction in
the output gap is observed is when using the Taylor rule that takes into
consideration the output gap and past interest rates with high persistence.
Keywords: stochastic dynamic general equilibrium model, stochastic process,
staggered price.
JEL Classification: E27, E52, E62.
*
The views expressed in this work are those of the authors and not reflect those of the Banco Central do Brasil
or its members.
**
Research Department, Banco Central do Brasil, Brazil. Correspondent author’s e-mail:
[email protected]
***
Department of Economics, Universidade de Brasília, Brazil.
3
1. Introduction
Modeling economic dynamics is important for those who rely on macroeconomic
analysis, especially the monetary authority. The behavior of the economy, and its dynamic
responses to policy and external shocks are relevant to understanding how the economy
reacts to different shocks in different situations. For example, given a set of conditions and
a characterization of how different monetary policy rules will affect the reaction function of
the economy. This paper attempts to evaluate the effect of an adverse supply shock (for
example an oil price increase) on a Brazilian model economy using a dynamic general
equilibrium framework. It is part of ongoing research based on Bugarin et al (2005), aimed
at building a model economy for monetary policy analysis based on an optimizing dynamic
general equilibrium model. Its main characteristic consists of forward-looking agents facing
a staggered price setting in a small open economy.
The pioneering theoretical work can be traced back to Taylor (1988, 1993). Svensson
and van Wijnbergeh (1989), Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995, 1996), Betts and Devereux (1997.
1998), Kollmann (1997, 1999), Gali and Monacelti (1999). Ghironi (1999), Benigno and
Benigno (2000), Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2000), Smets and Woutcrs (2000), Corsetti
and Pesenti (2001).
Following Bugarin et al. (2005), the special feature of this line of modeling is to
construct a tractable micro-founded dynamic setting with forward-looking rational agents in
a small open economy, which, through estimation or calibration processes, enables us to
derive qualitative and quantitative assessments of an adverse supply shock into the model
economy.
As suggested by McCallum and Nelson (1998), McCallum and Nelson (2001), and
Fraga, Goldfajn and Minella (2003), the openness of the economy is introduced by means
of intermediate goods imports into the domestic economy's productive process.1 This
characterization has two main advantages. First, it leads to a c1eaner and simpler
theoretical structure compared to the usual alternative treatment of imports as consumption
1
See Calvo, Celasun and Kumhof (2003) for a model with tradable and non-tradable consumption goods.
4
goods. Second, it better captures the dynamic features presented in the data, namely the
lagged correlation between the inflation rate and changes in the exchange rate, as well as
the share of imports as a major item (60.6%) in imports for Brazil.2
The preliminary results suggest that the introduction of habit persistence into the
consumption hypothesis does not make much difference. However, the introduction of
different monetary reaction functions does alter the impulse response of output, the
inflation rate, and the nominal interest rate. A common result is the decline in potential
output for all models. Additionally, the only case where a reduction in the output gap is
observed is when using the Taylor rule that takes in consideration the output gap and past
interest rates with high persistence.
The present study is divided into the following sections. Section 2 introduces the
model economy, defines the dynamic equilibrium concept and characterizes the state space
representation of the artificial economy. Section 3 presents the detailed description, or the
parameterization process. The model's behavioral, technological as well as policy
determined sets of parameters are set based on calibration or time series estimation. Section
4 presents the impulse responses to the exogenous shock to the artificial economy, which
can be alternatively attributed to technology, aggregate demand, UIP, monetary policy rule,
external income or fiscal innovation processes, and then summary statistics. The numerical
computation of the equilibrium is based on the Schur decomposition in order to account for
forward-looking endogenous variables. Section 5 presents a summary and conclusions. The
main results are summed up in the last section in order to identify potential extensions to
future research.
2. The Artificial Economy
The benchmark model follows closely the one introduced by McCallum and Nelson
(1998) and McCallum (2001). Its main feature includes an open economy where optimal
behavior of consumers/producers lead to equilibrium transition paths of endogenously
determined variables. Some of theses variables, like for instance the aggregate supply of the
economy, behaves in a forward-looking manner to take into consideration staggered pricing
2
Source: Banco Central do Brasil
5
mechanism that generates inflation inertia and recessionary disinflations in the economy
that allow the monetary policy interventions as well as the exogenous stochastic processes
to produce, in equilibrium, real effects in the short run.
Moreover, the monetary policy intervention is modeled by means of alternative
Taylor type rules, which determine a reaction of the nominal interest rate to predetermined
as well as forward-looking variables. These rules are based on research results presented by
Fraga et ali (2003), Minella et ali (2003) and Alves and Muinhos (2002)
2.1 The Representative Household (Consumer-Producer) Problem
There is a continuum of households acting as consumers-producers over the interval
[0,1] deriving utility from a stream of optimally chosen sequence of consumption, C, and
real balance holdings, M/P. Hence we can formally write down the problem faced by these
agents as follows.
max E 0 ∑ β t u C t + j , C t + j −1 , M t + j / Pt +A j
∞
t =0
[(
)]
(1)
subject to the available CES production technology using labor, N , and imported
intermediate goods, IM, as inputs of the production process, i.e.
[
(
Yt = α 1 At N td
v1
1
]
1
d v1 v1
t
) + (1 − α )(IM )
(2)
and, (real) budget constraint:
(
)
( Pt / Pt A ) DYt d + ( Pt / Pt A ) EX td − Ct + Wt / Pt A ( N tS − N td ) + TRt − ( M t − M t −1 ) / Pt A −
− Bt −1 (1 + rt ) + Bt − Qt IM − Qt B (1 + κ t ) + Qt Bt* = 0
−1
d
t
*
t +1
−1
(3)
where,
(i) the instantaneous utility function is assumed to be separable across consumption
and money balances and captures the habit formation as depicted below:
6
(
)
u C t , C t −1 , M t / Pt A = exp(vt )(σ /(σ − 1))(C t / C t −1 )
h
σ −1
σ
+ (1 − γ ) −1 ( M t / Pt A )1−γ
(4)
with σ >0, σ ≠ 1, ≠ 1, h h ∈ [0,1) and 0< <1. Using Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) composite
θ −1
1
θ −1
consumption index, Ct = ∫ Ct ( j ) θ dj , θ > 1 with all j goods differentiated from each
0
θ
other;
(ii) technology parameters are such that α 1 ∈ (0,1], v1 ∈ (−∞,+∞) , At representing a
technology shock parameter, Ntd the labor demanded at time t and IMtd the imported input
in production purchased by the household;
(iii) given the monopoly power to each specific home production, Pt denotes the
good’s price as a choice variable. The household takes the domestic aggregate price level
PtA, the nominal exchange rate St and the foreign price level Pt* as given. Moreover, since
the household cannot price discriminate between domestic and foreign consumers, the price
of that good for foreigners is given by Pt/St.
(iv) DYtd denotes the domestic demand for the particular good. Note that if we
define the foreign demand for the same good as EXtd, then total production of the specific
good is Ytd = DYtd+ EXtd. The aggregate domestic demand then is given by
1−θ
1
1−θ
A
d
A −θ
A
DYt = ( Pt / Pt ) DYt , where Pt = ∫ Pt ( j ) dj and DYt A is the aggregate of DYt d . It
0
1
is also assumed that the foreign demand for the respective household is given by
EX td = ( Pt / Pt A ) −θ EX tA where EXtA is the aggregate export of the economy, such that
aggregate export demand is positively related to the real exchange rate, Qt = S t Pt* / Pt A , i.e.
EX tA = ( S t Pt* / Pt A )η Yt *b where η > 0, b > 0 .3
3
Since it is assumed a small open economy, the effect on domestic production on foreign price index is
negligible.
7
(v) each household is endowed with one unit of workable time per period, supplies
it inelastically, i.e. NtS, facing a nominal wage Wt.
(vi) as a producer, each household chooses labor as well as imported input in an
optimal manner, Ntd and IMtd.
(vii) Government issues domestic debt. This asset could be considered as a perfect
substitute of domestic private security which can be purchased at 1/(1+rt) per unit at time t.
Households also can purchase foreign bonds at a price, in units of foreign output, given by
1/(1+κ)(1+rt*). The domestic and foreign bonds purchased by the household at time t is
expressed as Bt and Bt* respectively. We also assume that the transversality conditions for
assets hold, as well as government budget constraint and bond market clearing condition.
2.2 Optimality Conditions
The above characterization allows us to derive the following first order conditions,
where ξt and λt denotes the Lagrange multipliers for the technology constraint and the
budget constraint respectively.
(a) as consumer choosing optimally consumption and saving, in other words, with
respect to Ct, Mt/PtA, Bt+1 and Bt+1*:
h
exp(vt )(1 / C t −1 )
Mt
A
P
t
−γ
σ −1
σ
h −σh −σ
−1
C tσ − βh exp(vt −1 )C t
σ
σ −1
C t +σ1 − λ = 0
1 Pt A
A − 1 = 0
+ λt Et
(1 + rt ) Pt −1
(5)
(6)
λt − βEt λt +1 (1 + rt ) = 0
(7)
Qt λt − βEt λt +1 (1 + κ t )(1 + rt* ) = 0
(8)
and,
(b) as a producer, choosing optimally production inputs Ntd and IMtd:
8
λt
ξ t
v1 Y
Wt 1−v1
A
− α 11−v1 At 1−v1 td
Pt
Nt
1
1
λt 1−v1
1−v Yt
Qt − (1 − α1 )1 1
d
IM t
ξ t
1
1
=0
(9)
= 0
(10)
Observe that under price flexibility the mark-up is constant equal to
λt
θ
=
.
ξt θ −1
2.3 Uncovered Interest Parity
If one defines domestic and foreign interest rate as Rt = rt + Et ∆pt +1 and
Rt * = rt * + E t ∆pt +1 * respectively, where pt = log Pt A , pt * = log Pt * and ∆ indicates the
first difference operator, first order conditions (7) and (8) above imply that uncovered
interest parity holds in equilibrium, i.e.
Rt = Rt * + Et ∆s t +1 + κ t
(11)
where st = log S t .
2.4 Price Adjustment Decision
The above household characterization give him/her market power to decide its own
price Pt. Taking log of domestic and foreign demand for the household specific good, as
presented in (iv) above, we have:
dy td = dy tA − θ ( pt − ptA )
(12)
extd = extA − θ ( pt − ptA )
(13)
implying the following relationship between the log of relative output yt-ytA and the log of
relative price pt-ptA:
9
yt − ytA = −θ ( pt − ptA )
(14)
Following Calvo (1983) it is assumed that the households have to set their
respective prices according to the pricing equation below.
∆p = βEt ∆pt +1 + ωygapt
(15)
setting w = 0.02.
2.5 Flexible Price Output
Under price flexibility, labor input equals Nt = NtS = 1 for all t, then the flexible
price output is given by:
d
v
Y t = α 1 ( At ) 1 + (1 − α 1 ) IM t
( )
v1
v1
1
(16)
and taking a log linear approximation:
yt = (1 − δ 1 )α 1 + δ 1 m t
(17)
IM SS
where, using the Euler equation (5), δ = (1 − α 1 ) SS
Y
SS
SS
= θ Q IM
θ − 1 Y SS
v1
, ss denoting
steady state values.
Defining again qt= log Qt, the logarithm of the real exchange rate, Q, optimality
condition (10) implies:
imt = y t −
λ
1
log t
1 − v1
ξt
1
1
−
qt +
log(1 − α 1 )
1 − v1
1 − v1
10
(18)
Using the fact that under price flexibility the mark-up is constant, i.e.
λt
θ
,
=
ξt θ −1
the corresponding log of imports at the flexible price output is given by4:
im t = y t −
1
qt
1 − v1
(19)
Thus, the flexible price output is function of the technology shock as well as the real
exchange rate, i.e.
y t = α1 −
1
θ Q SS IM SS
qt
(1 − v1 )(1 − δ 1 ) (θ − 1) Y SS
(20)
This relationship indicates that in this model exchange rate has an impact on
domestic prices: changes in the (log) nominal exchange rate st, that affect the (log) real
exchange rate, qt, lead to changes in pt through Et −1 p t .
2.6 Log-Linearization
(a)
Log-linearizing Euler equation (5), without considering the constant term, we have:
βh2σ + βhσ − βh2 −1
σ −1
σ −1
1 − βhρ
ct − h
ct −1 − βh
Et ct +1 +
logλt =
vt
σ (1 − βh)
σ (1− βh)
σ (1 − βh)
1 − βh
(b)
(21)
Log-linearizing (7) in turn give us expression:
log λt = Et log λt +1 + Rt − Et ∆pt +1
(22)
From above two conditions, the corresponding expectational difference equation for
consumption changes with habit persistence is given by5:
4
Neglecting constant term.
5
For h=0 the equation correspond to the case of non-h ext
Woodford (1996).
11
= ηq t + byt* habit persistence as presented by
β (h − σh) Et ∆ct + 2 + (1 + βh 2 − σβh 2 − σβh) Et ∆ct +1 + σ (1 − βh) Et ∆pt +1 =
= (h − σh)∆ct + σ (1 − βh) Rt − σ (1 + ρ − βhρ 2 + βhρ )
(23)
(c) In order to complete the log-linearized first order conditions we have to add the
following set of equations:
export function
ext = ηqt + byt*
(24)
real exchange rate
qt = s t − pt + p t*ηqt
(25)
flexible price output
y t = at − ωqt
(26)
Rt = Rt + Et st −1 − st + κk t
(27)
nominal aggregate domestic production
xt = p t + y t
(28)
output gap
y 't = yt − y t
(29)
*
UIP
C SS EX SS
EX SS
C SS
aggregate domestic output consistency yt = SS ct + SS ext + [1 − SS − SS ]g t (30)
Y
Y
Y
Y
Et y 't +1 = φ y 't
expected aggregate supply
import input function
where, φ =
imt = y t +
1
1
y 't −
qt
θ (1 − v1 )
1 − v1
(31)
(32)
δ1
1 − (1 − 4α 2 β )1 / 2
c
and ω =
.
,α =
(1 − v1 )(1 − δ 1 )
2αβ
1 + c + cβ
2.7 Foreign Exogenous Variables
We assume that both foreign interest rate Rt* as well as price level Pt* are constant
for all t, and that the log of external output follows an AR(1) stable process, i.e.:
yt* = ρ y* yt*−1 + ε t* , ε t* ≈ N (0, σ ε2* )
(33)
12
2.8 Adverse technological innovation
In order to capture the impact of adverse supply, it is assumed that it works as an
adverse technological innovation as suggested by Hall (1988) and Finn (2000)., i.e.
at = ρ a at −1 + eat , eat ≈ N (0,σ ea2 )
(34)
Therefore, in our model economy an adverse supply shock will enter as a negative
unitary shock eat .
Based on previous studies, the next sub-section introduces the monetary reaction
functions considered in our study.
2.9 Taylor Type Monetary Policy Rules
Alternative specification of monetary reaction functions were introduced into the
model economy in order to perform a sensitivity analysis of derived impulse response to
those interventions and to test robustness of the responses. The choice of the adopted
monetary policy reaction functions is based on the existing literature for the Brazilian
economy. All the reaction functions are built on a basic Taylor Rule where the monetary
authority would react adjusting the nominal interest rate, R according to past interest rate,
to expected deviation of future inflation rate form the target, E(πt-1 - π*), and to observed
(past) output gap, y´t-1, smoothing it out around a long run equilibrium rate given by the
parameter µ0. Coefficients vary to different estimations and specifications in this basic
model.
(i)
Rule 1
Is based on Alves e Muinhos (2003). They estimate a Taylor Rule for the Brazilian
economy using a model specification very similar to the one used in Fraga et Ali (2003)
and Minella et ali (2002 e 2003). According to the authors an optimal monetary policy
reaction function, using inflation expectation, captured by Market Expectation Time Series
of Investor Relation Group of Banco Central do Brasil, can be summarized as follows.
13
2
Rt = µ Rt −1 + µ Et (π t + j − π * ) ρ + µ yt´´−1 + ε mr , emr ≈ N (0, σ mr
) (35a)
1
(ii)
2
3
Rule 2
This rule follows the results of Minella et ali (2003), and also Fraga et ali (2003)
estimations without output gap, once the estimations with output gap present contra
intuitive estimators for the parameters of the output gap.
2
Rt = µ Rt −1 + µ Et (π t + j − π * ) ρ + ε mr , emr ≈ N (0, σ mr
)
1
(iii)
2
(35b)
Rule 3
This rule follows the simulations done by Minella et ali (2003), where the monetary
authority react only to expected inflation deviation from the target, that means:
2
Rt = µ Et (π t + j − π * ) ρ + ε mr , emr ≈ N (0, σ mr
)
2
(35c)
2.10 The Model Economy in State Space Representation
Pulling conditions (22), (23) and (25) to (32) with alternative policy rules (35a) to
(35c) above, we can rewrite the system of equations that describes the equilibrium motion
of this model economy as follows.
A(24 x 24) Etyt+1 = B(24 x 24) yt + C(24 x 6) zt
(36)
where yt=[yE yP]
YE = [ y
~ ´
t , yt , y t , Rt , qt , st , ct , log λt , ext , ∆xt , pt , ∆pt , ∆pt +1 ,imt ]0
´
YE = [c , R , y , E ∆x , E
t −1 t −1 t −1 t −1
t t −1 y t , Et −1 yt ,∆pt −1, pt −1, Et −1∆pt +1, Et −1∆pt ]
and zt = [at , vt , ε mr ,t , κ t , yt* , g t ] vector of 6 exogenous shock processes.
Moreover, the dynamics of zt can be summarized as:
zt = a zt-1 + ut
(37)
14
where the elements of a are given by coefficients of processes (24) to (32), assuming
constant Rt* and Pt*.
Therefore, the equilibrium rational expectation solution to (36) is then given by:
yt = P1 kt + P2 zt
(38)
Kt = G Kt-1 + Nt
(39)
and,
where Kt+1 = [kt+1 zt+1]’, Kt = [kt zt]’ and Nt = [0 ut], expressing the endogenous variables
yE,t in terms of predetermined endogenous variables kt = [ct-1, Rt-1, yt-1, ∆pt-1, pt-1] as well as
exogenous stochastic processes zt.
3 Parameterization of the Model Economy
This section describes the procedure employed to parameterize the artificial
economy constructed above. Econometric estimation of some parameters, calibration based
on aggregate empirical relationships and results from previous studies on the Brazilian
economy were employed as explained bellow.
1)
Technology Parameters
Given
the
CES
production
function
used
in
1
ν1 ν1
Yt = [α1 ( At ) + (1 − α1 )( IM t ) ] , the following values are adopted:
v1
v1 = 0.7, estimated by Pessoa (2004)
α1 = 0.65, estimated by Gomes et ali (2003)
15
the
model,
i.e.
2)
Consumption Index Parameter
The model uses the Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) composite consumption index, i.e.
Ct = [ ∫ Ct ( j )
1
θ −1
θ
θ
θ −1
dj ]
, θ > 1 . Following McCallum (2000) we set θ = 6 , which implies a
0
mark-up value of 20%, i.e. 6/(6-1) = 1.2.
3)
Export Function Parameters (in log)
Given the export function ext = ηqt + byt* , the respective elasticity of exports to real
exchange rate, qt, and rest of the world income, yt* , were estimated. The best fit gives us
the following estimated values, η = 0.788 and b = 0.79. These values are very similar to
the ones estimated by Pastore and Pinoti (1999) anc Faini, Pritchett and Clavijo (1992).
4)
Imported Input Demand Function
The import function of the artificial economy is given by the optimality condition of
monopolistically competitive firms, i.e.
impt = yt + m1dyt − m2 qt , m1 =
1
1
. Therefore, using the above parameter
, m2 =
θ (1 − v1 )
1 − v1
values, we set m1 = 0.556, and m2 = 3.33.
Observe that alternatively, we can estimate the real exchange rate as well as the income
elasticity of imports, such that parameters θ and vt can be calibrated accordingly. Using
estimates of Faini, Pritchet and Clavijo (1992) we obtain θ=2.97 and vt=1.91. These values
are also used to perform the sensitivity analysis.
5)
Preferences Parameters
Recalling
u (Ct ) = eν t
that
the
σ Ct
σ − 1 Cth−1
σ −1
σ
instantaneous
utility
function
is
assumed
as
and taking the inter-temporal discount factor β = 0.99 as
16
presented by Bugarin, M. et ali (2000), the consumption Euler equation give us the
remaining needed parameters related to the optimal consumption decision of the
households, i.e. in log we have:
c3 Et ct +1 = c1ct − c2 ct −1 − λt + c4 vt ,
c1 = ( βh 2σ + βhσ − βh 2 − 1) /(σ (1 − βh)),
c2 = h((σ − 1) /(σ (1 − βh)),
c3 = βc2 ,
c4 = (1 /(1 − βh))(1 − βhρν )
where ρν denotes the persistence parameter of the shock to consumption demand which is
estimated bellow. The parameters σ = 0.4 and h = 0.8 are set to derive the values for c1 to c4
following the suggestion of McCallum and Nelson. Observe that that there are in the
literature relatively wide ranges of values for these parameters, which represent the risk
aversion and habit persistence of households. Accordingly, we set these values rather
arbitrarily so that sensitivity analysis is going to be performed later on. In particular, the
value σ = 0.6 and h = 0.6 reported by Lam and Tkacz (2004) are considered as alternative
values.
6)
Monetary Policy Rule
The alternative Taylor type monetary policy rules are assumed according to
specifications introduced in section 1.10 before, which give us the following parameter
values present in Table 1:
Table 1: Taylor Rule Parameter
µRt-1
µExp(π-π*) µygap
Rule 1: complete
0,80
0,26
0,16
Rule 2: without output gap
0,90
5,70
-
-
1,50
-
Rule 3: expectation only
17
Almeida Peres, Souza e Tabak (2003) have also estimated a Taylor rule for an open
economy version in which the lagged nominal exchange rate and the contemporaneous
variation in the real exchange rate are both introduced. Nevertheless in our numerical
simulation we choose to restrict our analysis only to the above rules. This strategy follows
the results introduced by Minella et ali (2003) who shows that the nominal exchange rate is
not significant in a Taylor rule specification for the Brazilian economy.
7)
Calvo’s Pricing Equation
Following Calvo (1983) the model’s pricing equation is characterized as:
∆pt = βEt ∆pt +1 + ωygapt , following McCallum (2000) we set ω = 0.02.
8)
Parameters for Exogenous AR (1) Stochastic Shocks Processes
The numerical characterization of the stochastic process affecting different behavioral
equations of the model economy is performed recalling that these shocks are strictly
considered as state variables in the economy. Therefore, it is important to remark that
herein we are not interested in fitting the best time series models to the data. We are rather
concerned with the numerical characterization of the AR(1) exogenous stochastic processes
included in our artificial economy:
(i)
Technological shock affecting potential output: following the
estimations of TFP given by Alves and Muinhos (2002) this shock is characterized as an
AR(1) stochastic process a persistence parameter value of ρiasc=0.9.
(ii)
Technological shock affecting potential output with high persistence:
this shock is characterized as an AR(1) stochastic process a persistence parameter value of
ρiasc=0.99.
4. Numerical Simulations
With the model economy constructed in Section 2 and the parameterization of
Section 3, several numerical simulations were performed as exercises aiming to describe
the economic performance of our model economy. The algorithm used closely follows
18
McCallum and Nelson’s (1998) strategy, which uses the Schur decomposition to solve for
the forward-looking endogenous variables, as suggested by Klein (2000). Moreover,
McGrattan’s (1999) algorithm is implemented in order to get the actual and lagged
correlations of the artificially obtained series.
Particular attention is given to the impulse responses of the output gap, aggregate
output, inflation rate and nominal interest rate. Moreover, the main statistics on
contemporaneous standard deviations are presented.
Based on the calibration procedure introduced in Section 2, the habit persistence in
consumption is captured in the model by means of the behavioral parameter 0<h<1, which
enters into the instantaneous utility function, given by (4), i.e. U(C,Ct-1)= exp(vt)(σ/(σ1))(Ct/Ct-1h)
σ-1/σ
, from which is derived the expectational Euler equation (23). In other
words, “h” represents the importance of previous consumption in the utility function: close
to 0 means there is no consumption in t-1 in the function. Accordingly, the closer “h” is to
one, the more persistent the habit is in consumption. Following McCallum and Nelson
(1998) we set h=0.8 as an alternative specification with habit persistence in consumption
and h=o for the case of no persistence. In this case, the contemporaneous utility function is
given by U(C,Ct-1)= exp(vt)(σ/(σ-1))(Ct/Ct-1h) σ-1/σ.
The impulse responses resulting from the numerical simulation tend to show similar
results, independent of habit persistence, as will be shown in section 4.2.
The monetary policy intervention is captured by the alternative Taylor Rule
specification (41a to 41c), as explained before. There are some differences in the reaction
functions in accordance with the different Taylor Rules adopted, which will be described
below in the subsections.
In order to illustrate the way that this artificial economy reacts to an adverse supply
shocks, we present the figures o section 4.2, which show the impulse responses to unitary
shocks (innovations) to technology, taking into consideration the three different Taylor
Rules described before.
19
4.1 Summary Statistics of Artificial Vs Real Series
This section presents the summary statistics of the artificial series simulated averse
supply shocks, as done in Bugarin et al. (2005). These statistics are compared to the ones
corresponding to the real time series data. It is important to note that the statistics obtained
from empirical evidence are very sample dependent. We report below only the ones
corresponding to 1996:Q1 to 2003:Q4.
Table 2 below shows the respective standard deviations. The model economy with
Taylor Rule 3 (only expectation) and habit persistence in consumption is able to better
reproduce the volatility of observed inflation rates. Rule 2 (without output gap) with
persistence in consumption presents the closes volatility of output gap and nominal interest
rate. None of the models mimics the volatility observed in the output gap.
Data(*)
Inflation Rate
Output
Output Gap
Interest Rate
0.012904
0.056826
0.009978
0.048025
Model with Habit Persistence, h=0
Taylor Rule from
Lagos e Muinhos
0.016410
0.097889
0.081828
0.015929
Taylor Rule without
Output Gap
0.001696
0.043490
0.162603
0.015434
Simple Expectational
Taylor Rule
0.006362
0.075509
0.176772
0.008976
Model with Habit Persistence, h=0,8
Taylor Rule from
Lagos e Muinhos
0.017653
0.101863
0.090790
0.019726
Taylor Rule without
Output Gap
0.002082
0.049180
0.163813
0.021847
Simple Expectational
Taylor Rule
0.010599
0.099702
0.187875
0.014176
(*) Times Series data on quarterly from 1996.II to 2005.I. Data source: Banco Central do Brasil
20
4.2 Responses to Adverse Technological Productivity Shock
Figures 1a and 2a below show the impulse response function derived from the
model economy when analyzing a unitary adverse supply shock with an AR parameters of
0.9 and policy rule 1 (35a). These figures show a decrease in output and a higher decrease
in potential output that result in an increase in the output gap. The use of this policy
produces an initial small decrease in prices followed by an increase, and a lagged increase
in the interest rate. The assumption of different habit persistences (h=0 and h=0.8) did not
make any difference in the responses.
Figure 1a: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0 and Taylor Rule from
Lagos e Muinhos (2004) with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.9
Aggregate Ouput Response
Inflation Rate Response
0
0
-0.2
-0.05
-0.4
-0.1
-0.6
-0.15
-0.8
0
10
20
30
-0.2
40
Output Gap Response
0.03
0.3
0.02
0.2
0.01
0.1
0
0
10
20
30
10
20
30
40
Nominal Interest Rate Response
0.4
0
0
40
-0.01
21
0
10
20
30
40
Figure 2a: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0.8 and Taylor Rule from
Aggregate Ouput Response
Inflation Rate Response
0
0
-0.2
-0.05
-0.4
-0.1
-0.6
-0.15
-0.8
0
10
20
30
-0.2
40
Output Gap Response
0.03
0.6
0.02
0.4
0.01
0.2
0
0
10
20
30
10
20
30
40
Nominal Interest Rate Response
0.8
0
0
40
-0.01
0
10
20
30
40
Lagos e Muinhos (2004) with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.9
Figures 3a and 4a below show the impulse response function derived from the model
economy when analyzing a unitary adverse supply shock with an AR parameters of 0.9 and
policy rule 2 (35b), where the reaction to the output gap was shut down. These figures show
an increase in the output gap as a function of a significant decrease in potential output.
Output, inflation and the interest rate, however, do not show significant variation, when the
monetary authority does not react to changes in the output gap. The assumption of different
habit persistences (h=0 and h=0.8) did not make any difference in the responses.
22
Figure 3a: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0 and Taylor Rule
without Output Gap with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.9
x 10
-15
Aggregate Ouput Response
x 10
2
-16
Inflation Rate Response
1.5
1
1
0
0.5
-1
-2
0
10
20
30
0
0
40
x 10
Output Gap Response
1.5
0
1
-0.5
0.5
-1
0
0
10
20
30
-1.5
0
40
23
10
20
30
40
-14
Nominal Interest Rate Response
10
20
30
40
Figure 4a: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0.8 and Taylor Rule
without Output Gap with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.9
x 10
-15
x 10
Aggregate Ouput Response
5
-16
Inflation Rate Response
2
0
0
-2
-5
-10
0
-4
10
20
30
-6
0
40
x 10
Output Gap Response
1.5
10
1
5
0.5
0
0
0
10
20
30
-15
-5
0
40
10
20
30
40
Nominal Interest Rate Response
10
20
30
40
Figures 5a and 6a below show the impulse response function derived from the
model economy when analyzing a unitary adverse supply shock with an AR parameters of
0.9 and policy rule 3 (35c), where the reaction of the monetary authority to the output gap
and past interest rates was shut down. These figures show an increase in the output gap as a
function of a significant decrease in potential output. Output, inflation and interest rates,
however, do not show significant variation, when the monetary authority does not react to
changes in the output gap. The assumption of different habit persistences (h=0 and h=0.8)
did not make any difference in the responses. These results are the same as those observed
with policy rule 2 (35b).
24
Figure 5a: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0 and Simple
Expectational Taylor Rule with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.9
x 10 -16
x 10 -16
Aggregate Ouput Response
Inflation Rate Response
5
8
0
6
-5
4
-10
2
-15
0
10
20
30
40
0
0
10
20
30
40
x 10 -16
Output Gap Response
Nominal Interest Rate Response
1
5
0
0.5
-5
0
0
10
20
30
40
-10
0
25
10
20
30
40
Figure 6a: Impulses Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0.8 and Simple
Expectational Taylor Rule with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.90
x 10 -15
x 10 -16
Aggregate Ouput Response
4
Inflation Rate Response
0
3
-1
2
-2
1
0
0
10
20
30
40
-3
0
10
x 10 -16
4
Output Gap Response
1.5
20
30
40
Nominal Interest Rate Response
2
1
0
0.5
0
0
-2
10
20
30
40
-4
0
10
20
30
40
Figures 1b and 2b below show the impulse response function derived from the
model economy when analyzing a unitary adverse supply shock with an AR parameters of
0.99, to simulate a higher persistence of the shock, and policy rule 1 (35a). These figures
show a decrease in output, the output gap (meaning that, in this case, output falls more than
potential output), inflation and the interest rate. Furthermore, these figures indicate that the
responses take longer periods (longer than 40 periods). The assumption of different habit
persistences (h=0 and h=0.8) did not make any difference in the responses.
26
Figure 1b: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0 and Taylor Rule from
Lagos e Muinhos (2004) with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.99
Aggregate Ouput Response
Inflation Rate Response
0
0
-0.2
-0.5
-0.4
-1
-1.5
-0.6
0
10
20
30
40
-0.8
Output Gap Response
0
10
20
30
40
Nominal Interest Rate Response
0.5
0
-0.2
0
-0.4
-0.5
-1
-0.6
0
10
20
30
40
-0.8
27
0
10
20
30
40
Figure 2b: Impulses Response to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0.8 and Taylor Rule from
Lagos e Muinhos (2004) with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.99
Aggregate Ouput Response
Inflation Rate Response
0
0
-0.2
-0.5
-0.4
-0.6
-1
0
10
20
30
40
-0.8
Output Gap Response
0.2
0.4
0
0.2
-0.2
0
-0.4
0
10
20
30
10
20
30
40
Nominal Interest Rate Response
0.6
-0.2
0
40
-0.6
0
10
20
30
40
Figures 3b and 4b below show the impulse response function derived from the
model economy when analyzing a unitary adverse supply shock with an AR parameters of
0.99 and policy rule 2 (35b), where the reaction to the output gap was shut down. These
figures do not show any significant movement in output, inflation or the interest rate
(movements of order 10-14), while the output gap increases, revealing a reduction in
potential output. As observed with rule one, this movement in the output gap does not
return to equilibrium in the period of study (40 periods). The assumption of different habit
persistences (h=0 and h=0.8) did not make any difference in the responses.
28
Figure 3b: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0 and Taylor Rule
without Output Gap with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.99
x 10 -15
x 10 -16
Aggregate Ouput Response
Inflation Rate Response
1
2
0
1.5
-1
1
-2
0.5
-3
0
10
20
30
40
0
0
10
20
30
40
x 10 -14
Output Gap Response
Nominal Interest Rate Response
1.5
0
1
-0.5
0.5
-1
0
0
10
20
30
40
-1.5
0
29
10
20
30
40
Figure 4b: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0 and Taylor Rule
without Output Gap with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.99
x 10 -15
x 10 -16
Aggregate Ouput Response
Inflation Rate Response
1
2
0
1.5
-1
1
-2
0.5
-3
0
10
20
30
40
0
0
10
20
30
40
x 10 -14
Output Gap Response
Nominal Interest Rate Response
1.5
0
1
-0.5
0.5
-1
0
0
10
20
30
40
-1.5
0
10
20
30
40
Figures 5b and 6ba below show the impulse response function derived from the
model economy when analyzing a unitary adverse supply shock with an AR parameters of
0.99 and policy rule 3 (35c), where the reaction of the monetary authority to the output gap
and past interest rates where shut down. As observed with figures 3b and 4b, there are no
significant movements in output, inflation and the interest rate, while the output gap
increases, revealing a reduction in potential output. This movement in the output gap does
not return to equilibrium in the period of study (40 periods).
30
Figure 5b: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0 and Simple
Expectational Taylor Rule with persistence parameter of AR(1): 0.99
x 10
-16
x 10
Aggregate Ouput Response
5
4
0
3
-5
2
-10
1
-15
0
10
20
30
0
0
40
x 10
Output Gap Response
1
-16
Inflation Rate Response
10
20
30
40
-16
Nominal Interest Rate Response
5
0
0.5
-5
0
0
10
20
30
40
-10
0
31
10
20
30
40
Figure 6b: Impulse Responses to Unitary Productivity Shock, h = 0.8 and Simple
Expectational Taylor Rule with persistence parameter of AR (1): 0.99
x 10
-15
x 10
Aggregate Ouput Response
2
-16
Inflation Rate Response
3
1.5
2
1
1
0.5
0
0
10
20
30
0
0
40
x 10
Output Gap Response
1
10
20
30
40
-16
Nominal Interest Rate Response
6
4
0.5
2
0
0
10
20
30
0
0
40
10
20
30
40
5. Summary and Conclusions
The main purpose of this paper is to observe the reaction functions of a model
economy for monetary policy analysis, based on an optimizing dynamic general
equilibrium model, to an adverse supply shock. Its principal characteristic consists of
forward-looking agents facing a staggered price setting in a small open economy. The
special feature of this line of modeling is to construct a tractable micro-founded dynamic
setting with forward looking rational agents in a small open economy, which, through
estimation or calibration processes, enables us to derive qualitative and quantitative
assessments of various exogenous (stochastic) interventions into the model/economy, being
an extension of Bugarin et al. (2005).
32
The exercise presented in this paper indicates that an open economy dynamic general
equilibrium model, such as the one used here, constitutes a useful laboratory for short-run
analysis.
In summary, the following are the main results of the above numerical simulations:
•
The existence, or not, of habit persistence does not make a significant difference
in the impulse responses;
•
As a result of the adverse supply shock, potential output falls independently of
the monetary policy rule adopted;
•
When the monetary authority focuses on the output gap and past interest rates
(rule 1), the decrease in potential output is accompanied by a decrease in output. When
using AR=0.9, estimated by Alves and Muinhos (2002), the decrease in potential output
was higher than the decrease in output, leading to an increase in the output gap. The
opposite was observed when technological progress was more persistent. Interest rates
increase in the first case and decrease in the second. With this rule, inflation presents an
initial decrease, returning to equilibrium with AR=0.9;
•
When the monetary authority does not put any weight on the output gap (rules 2
and 3), the only significant movement observed was an increase in the output gap
(indicating a reduction in potential output). Output, inflation and interest rates did not show
any significant movement, independent of persistence;
Therefore, the main conclusion of this work is that potential output decreases in the
case of an adverse supply shock. But this decrease will have different impacts on output,
inflation and interest rates, depending on the monetary policy rules adopted. Additionally, a
higher persistence of the technological shock presents a reduction in the output gap as a
response, and does not converge to equilibrium in the 40 periods analyzed.
33
Bibliographical References
Alves, Sergio AL and Muinhos, M.K. (2003), "Medium Size-Macroeconomic Model for
the Brazilian Economy”, Banco Central do Brasil, Working Paper Series 64.
Almeida, C.L de, Peres, M.A., Souza, G. da Silva and Tabak, B.M. (2003) "Optimal
Monetary Policy Rules: the case of Brazil”, Banco Central do Brasil, Working Paper Series
63.
Altig, D. Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M. and Linde, J. (2002) “An Estimated Dynamic,
General Equilibrium model for Monetary Policy Analysis” mimeo.
Alvarez, F., Atkenson, A. and Kehoe, P.J. (1999) “Money and Interest rates with
Endogenously Segmented Markets”, NBER Working paper Series, 7060.
Anderson. G. and Moore, G. (1985) “A Linear Algebraic Procedure for Solving Linear
Perfect Foresight Models”, Economic Letters, 17 247-252.
Araújo, c.H. V. and Guilllén, O.T. de C. (2002) "Componentes de Curto e Longo Prazo das
Taxas de Juros no Brasil”, Banco Central do Brasil, Working Paper Series 55.
Blanchard, O. J. and Kahn, C. (1980) “The Solution of Linear Difference Models under
Rational Expectations”, Econometrica, Vol. 48, Issue 5, 1305-1312.
Bugarin, Mirta, Muinhos, Marcelo K. , Silva, Jose Ricardo C. and Araújo, Maria da Glória
D. S. (2005), “A Dynamic Small Open Economy General Equilibrium Model with
Staggered Price for Brazil,” mimeo.
Calvo, G.A. (1983) “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework”, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 12, 383-398.
Calvo, G.A. and Vegh, C. (1994) “Stabilization Dynamics and Backward-Looking
Contracts”, Journal of Development Economics, 43, 59-84.
Calvo, G.A., Celasun, O. and Kumhof, M. (2003) “Inflation Inertia and Credible
Disinflation – The Open Economy Case”, NBER Working Paper Series No 9557.
Chari, V.V., Kehoe, P. and McGrattan, E.R. (2001) “Can Sticky Price Models Generate
Volatile and Persistent Real Exchange Rates?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis,
Research Department Staff Report 277.
Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C.L. (1998) “Monetary Policy Shocks: What
Have We Learned and to What End?”, NBER Working Papers, No 6400.
Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C.L. (2001) “Nominal Rigidities and the
Dynamics Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy”, mimeo.
34
Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler, M. (2001) “A Simple Framework for International
Monetary Policy Analysis”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Paper Series.
Cochrane, J. (2000) “Money as Stock: price level determination with no money demand”,
NBER Working Paper Series, 7498.
Cooley, T. F. (ed.) (1995) Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. Princeton University
Press.
Dixit, A.K. and Sliglitz, J. "Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity”,
American Economic Review, 67, 297-308.
Engel, C. (1999) “On the Foreign Exchange Risk Premium in Sticky Price General
Equilibrium Models”, NBER Working Paper Series, 7067.
Fraga, A, Goldfajn, I., and Minella, A. (2003) "Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market
Economies”, NBER Macroeconomics Annual Number 18, The MIT Press, Cambridge,
Massachusetts.
Fuhrer, J. and Moore, G. (1995) “Inflation Persistence”, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
110 127-159.
Finn, Mary, (2000), “Perfect Competition and the Effects of Energy Price Increases on
Economic Activity,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32:400-416.
Gali, J. (2001) “New Perspectives in Monetary Policy, Inflation and the Business Cycle”,
forthcoming in Dewatripont, M., Hansen, L. and Turnovsky, S. eds, Advances in Economic
Theory, Cambridge University Press.
Gomes, V., Bugarin M. and Ellery, R. (2002) "Long-run Implications of Investment and
Capital Remuneration for Brazil”, mimeo, Depto de Economia, UnB.
Hall, Rober E. (1988), “The relation between Prices and Marginal Cost in U.S. Industry.”
Journal of Political Economy 96 (October): 921-947.
Hall, Robert E. (1990), “Invariance Properties of Solow´s Productivity Residual.” In
Growth-Productivity-Unemployment, edited by Peter A. Diamond. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT
Press.
Kim, In-Moo and Loungani, P. (1992), “The Role of Energy in Real Business Cycles
Models,” journal of Monetary Economics, 173-190.
Klein, P. (2000) “Using the Generalized Schur Form to Solve a Multivariate Linear
Rational Expectations Model”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 24, 14051423.
35
Lam, J-P. and Tkacz, G. “Estimating Policy Neutral Interest Rates for Canada Using a
Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Framework”, Bank of Canada Working papers,
2004-9.
Lane, P. (2001), “The New Open Economy Macroeconomics: A Survey”, Journal of
International Economics, 54(2), 235-266.
Leeper, E. (1991) “Equilibria Under Active and Passive Monetary and Fiscal Policies”,
Journal of Monetary Economics, 27, 129-147.
Leeper, E., Sims, C. and Zha, T. (1996) “What Does Monetary Policy Do?”, Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 1-63.
Loureiro, A. S. and Holanda Barbosa, F. de (2004) "Risk Premia for Emerging Markets
Bonds: evidence from Brazilian Government Debt, 1996-2002”, Banco Central do Brasil
Working Paper Series 85.
McCallum, B.T. (1998) "Solution to Linear Rational Expectation Models: a compact
exposition”, Economic Letters, 61, 143-147.
McCallum, B. T. and Nelson, E. (1998) “Nominal Income Targeting in an Open Economy
Optimizing Market”, NBER Working Paper Series, WP 6675.
____________ (2001) “Monetary Policy for an Open Economy: an alternative framework
with optimizing agents and sticky prices”, mimeo GSIA Carneige Mellon University.
Minella, A, Freitas, P., Goldfajn, I. and Muinhos, M. (2002) "Inflation Targeting in Brazil:
Lessons and Challenges”, Banco Central do Brasil, Working Paper Series, 53.
Miranda, P.C., Muinhos, M.K. and Graminho, F.M. (2002) “A Taxa de Juros de Equilíbrio:
uma abordagem múltipla”, mimeo, DEPEP, Banco Central do Brasil.
Pessoa, S. A. (1999) "Ajustamento de uma Economia após Elevação da Produtividade",
Pesquisa e Planejamento Econômico, Vo129, No 1,323-371.
Rotemberg, J. (1982) “Sticky prices in the United States”, Journal of Political Economy,
90, 1187-1211.
Rotemberg, J. and Woodford, M. (1996), “Imperfect Competition and the Effect of Energy
Price Increases on Economic Activity,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 28:549-577.
Taylor, J.B. (1980), “Aggregate Dynamics And Staggered Contracts”, Journal of Political
Economy, 88, 1-24.
Taylor, J.B. (1998), “Staggered Price and Wage Setting in Macroeconomics”, NBER
Working Paper, No 6754.
36
Woodford, M. (1995) “Price Level Determinancy Without Control of a Monetary
Aggregate”, NBER Working Paper Series, 5204.
Woodford, M. (1998) “ Doing Without Money: controlling inflation in a post monetary
world”, Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 173-219.
Woodford, M. (2002) “Inflation Stabilization and
Macroeconomics, 2(1), article 1.
37
Welfare”,
Contributions
to
Banco Central do Brasil
Trabalhos para Discussão
Os Trabalhos para Discussão podem ser acessados na internet, no formato PDF,
no endereço: http://www.bc.gov.br
Working Paper Series
Working Papers in PDF format can be downloaded from: http://www.bc.gov.br
1
Implementing Inflation Targeting in Brazil
Joel Bogdanski, Alexandre Antonio Tombini and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa
Werlang
Jul/2000
2
Política Monetária e Supervisão do Sistema Financeiro Nacional no
Banco Central do Brasil
Eduardo Lundberg
Jul/2000
Monetary Policy and Banking Supervision Functions on the Central
Bank
Eduardo Lundberg
Jul/2000
3
Private Sector Participation: a Theoretical Justification of the Brazilian
Position
Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang
Jul/2000
4
An Information Theory Approach to the Aggregation of Log-Linear
Models
Pedro H. Albuquerque
Jul/2000
5
The Pass-Through from Depreciation to Inflation: a Panel Study
Ilan Goldfajn and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang
Jul/2000
6
Optimal Interest Rate Rules in Inflation Targeting Frameworks
José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto, Fabio Araújo and Marta Baltar J. Moreira
Jul/2000
7
Leading Indicators of Inflation for Brazil
Marcelle Chauvet
Sep/2000
8
The Correlation Matrix of the Brazilian Central Bank’s Standard Model
for Interest Rate Market Risk
José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto
Sep/2000
9
Estimating Exchange Market Pressure and Intervention Activity
Emanuel-Werner Kohlscheen
Nov/2000
10
Análise do Financiamento Externo a uma Pequena Economia
Aplicação da Teoria do Prêmio Monetário ao Caso Brasileiro: 1991–1998
Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior
Mar/2001
11
A Note on the Efficient Estimation of Inflation in Brazil
Michael F. Bryan and Stephen G. Cecchetti
Mar/2001
12
A Test of Competition in Brazilian Banking
Márcio I. Nakane
Mar/2001
38
13
Modelos de Previsão de Insolvência Bancária no Brasil
Marcio Magalhães Janot
Mar/2001
14
Evaluating Core Inflation Measures for Brazil
Francisco Marcos Rodrigues Figueiredo
Mar/2001
15
Is It Worth Tracking Dollar/Real Implied Volatility?
Sandro Canesso de Andrade and Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Mar/2001
16
Avaliação das Projeções do Modelo Estrutural do Banco Central do
Brasil para a Taxa de Variação do IPCA
Sergio Afonso Lago Alves
Mar/2001
Evaluation of the Central Bank of Brazil Structural Model’s Inflation
Forecasts in an Inflation Targeting Framework
Sergio Afonso Lago Alves
Jul/2001
Estimando o Produto Potencial Brasileiro: uma Abordagem de Função
de Produção
Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho
Abr/2001
Estimating Brazilian Potential Output: a Production Function Approach
Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho
Aug/2002
18
A Simple Model for Inflation Targeting in Brazil
Paulo Springer de Freitas and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Apr/2001
19
Uncovered Interest Parity with Fundamentals: a Brazilian Exchange
Rate Forecast Model
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Paulo Springer de Freitas and Fabio Araújo
May/2001
20
Credit Channel without the LM Curve
Victorio Y. T. Chu and Márcio I. Nakane
May/2001
21
Os Impactos Econômicos da CPMF: Teoria e Evidência
Pedro H. Albuquerque
Jun/2001
22
Decentralized Portfolio Management
Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Jun/2001
23
Os Efeitos da CPMF sobre a Intermediação Financeira
Sérgio Mikio Koyama e Márcio I. Nakane
Jul/2001
24
Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Shocks, Backward-Looking Prices, and
IMF Conditionality
Joel Bogdanski, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and
Alexandre Antonio Tombini
Aug/2001
25
Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Reviewing Two Years of Monetary Policy
1999/00
Pedro Fachada
Aug/2001
26
Inflation Targeting in an Open Financially Integrated Emerging
Economy: the Case of Brazil
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Aug/2001
27
Complementaridade e Fungibilidade dos Fluxos de Capitais
Internacionais
Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior
Set/2001
17
39
28
Regras Monetárias e Dinâmica Macroeconômica no Brasil: uma
Abordagem de Expectativas Racionais
Marco Antonio Bonomo e Ricardo D. Brito
Nov/2001
29
Using a Money Demand Model to Evaluate Monetary Policies in Brazil
Pedro H. Albuquerque and Solange Gouvêa
Nov/2001
30
Testing the Expectations Hypothesis in the Brazilian Term Structure of
Interest Rates
Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Sandro Canesso de Andrade
Nov/2001
31
Algumas Considerações sobre a Sazonalidade no IPCA
Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Roberta Blass Staub
Nov/2001
32
Crises Cambiais e Ataques Especulativos no Brasil
Mauro Costa Miranda
Nov/2001
33
Monetary Policy and Inflation in Brazil (1975-2000): a VAR Estimation
André Minella
Nov/2001
34
Constrained Discretion and Collective Action Problems: Reflections on
the Resolution of International Financial Crises
Arminio Fraga and Daniel Luiz Gleizer
Nov/2001
35
Uma Definição Operacional de Estabilidade de Preços
Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho
Dez/2001
36
Can Emerging Markets Float? Should They Inflation Target?
Barry Eichengreen
Feb/2002
37
Monetary Policy in Brazil: Remarks on the Inflation Targeting Regime,
Public Debt Management and Open Market Operations
Luiz Fernando Figueiredo, Pedro Fachada and Sérgio Goldenstein
Mar/2002
38
Volatilidade Implícita e Antecipação de Eventos de Stress: um Teste para
o Mercado Brasileiro
Frederico Pechir Gomes
Mar/2002
39
Opções sobre Dólar Comercial e Expectativas a Respeito do
Comportamento da Taxa de Câmbio
Paulo Castor de Castro
Mar/2002
40
Speculative Attacks on Debts, Dollarization and Optimum Currency
Areas
Aloisio Araujo and Márcia Leon
Apr/2002
41
Mudanças de Regime no Câmbio Brasileiro
Carlos Hamilton V. Araújo e Getúlio B. da Silveira Filho
Jun/2002
42
Modelo Estrutural com Setor Externo: Endogenização do Prêmio de
Risco e do Câmbio
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Sérgio Afonso Lago Alves e Gil Riella
Jun/2002
43
The Effects of the Brazilian ADRs Program on Domestic Market
Efficiency
Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima
Jun/2002
40
Jun/2002
44
Estrutura Competitiva, Produtividade Industrial e Liberação Comercial
no Brasil
Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillén
45
Optimal Monetary Policy, Gains from Commitment, and Inflation
Persistence
André Minella
Aug/2002
46
The Determinants of Bank Interest Spread in Brazil
Tarsila Segalla Afanasieff, Priscilla Maria Villa Lhacer and Márcio I. Nakane
Aug/2002
47
Indicadores Derivados de Agregados Monetários
Fernando de Aquino Fonseca Neto e José Albuquerque Júnior
Set/2002
48
Should Government Smooth Exchange Rate Risk?
Ilan Goldfajn and Marcos Antonio Silveira
Sep/2002
49
Desenvolvimento do Sistema Financeiro e Crescimento Econômico no
Brasil: Evidências de Causalidade
Orlando Carneiro de Matos
Set/2002
50
Macroeconomic Coordination and Inflation Targeting in a Two-Country
Model
Eui Jung Chang, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Joanílio Rodolpho Teixeira
Sep/2002
51
Credit Channel with Sovereign Credit Risk: an Empirical Test
Victorio Yi Tson Chu
Sep/2002
52
Generalized Hyperbolic Distributions and Brazilian Data
José Fajardo and Aquiles Farias
Sep/2002
53
Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Lessons and Challenges
André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Nov/2002
54
Stock Returns and Volatility
Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Solange Maria Guerra
Nov/2002
55
Componentes de Curto e Longo Prazo das Taxas de Juros no Brasil
Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho de
Guillén
Nov/2002
56
Causality and Cointegration in Stock Markets:
the Case of Latin America
Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima
Dec/2002
57
As Leis de Falência: uma Abordagem Econômica
Aloisio Araujo
Dez/2002
58
The Random Walk Hypothesis and the Behavior of Foreign Capital
Portfolio Flows: the Brazilian Stock Market Case
Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Dec/2002
59
Os Preços Administrados e a Inflação no Brasil
Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Thaís Porto Ferreira
Dez/2002
60
Delegated Portfolio Management
Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Dec/2002
41
61
O Uso de Dados de Alta Freqüência na Estimação da Volatilidade e
do Valor em Risco para o Ibovespa
João Maurício de Souza Moreira e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber
Dez/2002
62
Taxa de Juros e Concentração Bancária no Brasil
Eduardo Kiyoshi Tonooka e Sérgio Mikio Koyama
Fev/2003
63
Optimal Monetary Rules: the Case of Brazil
Charles Lima de Almeida, Marco Aurélio Peres, Geraldo da Silva e Souza
and Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Feb/2003
64
Medium-Size Macroeconomic Model for the Brazilian Economy
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Sergio Afonso Lago Alves
Feb/2003
65
On the Information Content of Oil Future Prices
Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Feb/2003
66
A Taxa de Juros de Equilíbrio: uma Abordagem Múltipla
Pedro Calhman de Miranda e Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Fev/2003
67
Avaliação de Métodos de Cálculo de Exigência de Capital para Risco de
Mercado de Carteiras de Ações no Brasil
Gustavo S. Araújo, João Maurício S. Moreira e Ricardo S. Maia Clemente
Fev/2003
68
Real Balances in the Utility Function: Evidence for Brazil
Leonardo Soriano de Alencar and Márcio I. Nakane
Feb/2003
69
r-filters: a Hodrick-Prescott Filter Generalization
Fabio Araújo, Marta Baltar Moreira Areosa and José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto
Feb/2003
70
Monetary Policy Surprises and the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest
Rates
Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Feb/2003
71
On Shadow-Prices of Banks in Real-Time Gross Settlement Systems
Rodrigo Penaloza
Apr/2003
72
O Prêmio pela Maturidade na Estrutura a Termo das Taxas de Juros
Brasileiras
Ricardo Dias de Oliveira Brito, Angelo J. Mont'Alverne Duarte e Osmani
Teixeira de C. Guillen
Maio/2003
73
Análise de Componentes Principais de Dados Funcionais – Uma
Aplicação às Estruturas a Termo de Taxas de Juros
Getúlio Borges da Silveira e Octavio Bessada
Maio/2003
74
Aplicação do Modelo de Black, Derman & Toy à Precificação de Opções
Sobre Títulos de Renda Fixa
Octavio Manuel Bessada Lion, Carlos Alberto Nunes Cosenza e César das
Neves
Maio/2003
75
Brazil’s Financial System: Resilience to Shocks, no Currency
Substitution, but Struggling to Promote Growth
Ilan Goldfajn, Katherine Hennings and Helio Mori
42
Jun/2003
76
Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market Economies
Arminio Fraga, Ilan Goldfajn and André Minella
Jun/2003
77
Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Constructing Credibility under Exchange
Rate Volatility
André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Marcelo Kfoury
Muinhos
Jul/2003
78
Contornando os Pressupostos de Black & Scholes: Aplicação do Modelo
de Precificação de Opções de Duan no Mercado Brasileiro
Gustavo Silva Araújo, Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Antonio
Carlos Figueiredo, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber
Out/2003
79
Inclusão do Decaimento Temporal na Metodologia
Delta-Gama para o Cálculo do VaR de Carteiras
Compradas em Opções no Brasil
Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Gustavo Silva Araújo,
Eduardo Facó Lemgruber
Out/2003
80
Diferenças e Semelhanças entre Países da América Latina:
uma Análise de Markov Switching para os Ciclos Econômicos
de Brasil e Argentina
Arnildo da Silva Correa
Out/2003
81
Bank Competition, Agency Costs and the Performance of the
Monetary Policy
Leonardo Soriano de Alencar and Márcio I. Nakane
Jan/2004
82
Carteiras de Opções: Avaliação de Metodologias de Exigência de Capital
no Mercado Brasileiro
Cláudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo e Gustavo Silva Araújo
Mar/2004
83
Does Inflation Targeting Reduce Inflation? An Analysis for the OECD
Industrial Countries
Thomas Y. Wu
May/2004
84
Speculative Attacks on Debts and Optimum Currency Area: A Welfare
Analysis
Aloisio Araujo and Marcia Leon
May/2004
85
Risk Premia for Emerging Markets Bonds: Evidence from Brazilian
Government Debt, 1996-2002
André Soares Loureiro and Fernando de Holanda Barbosa
May/2004
86
Identificação do Fator Estocástico de Descontos e Algumas Implicações
sobre Testes de Modelos de Consumo
Fabio Araujo e João Victor Issler
Maio/2004
87
Mercado de Crédito: uma Análise Econométrica dos Volumes de Crédito
Total e Habitacional no Brasil
Ana Carla Abrão Costa
Dez/2004
88
Ciclos Internacionais de Negócios: uma Análise de Mudança de Regime
Markoviano para Brasil, Argentina e Estados Unidos
Arnildo da Silva Correa e Ronald Otto Hillbrecht
Dez/2004
89
O Mercado de Hedge Cambial no Brasil: Reação das Instituições
Financeiras a Intervenções do Banco Central
Fernando N. de Oliveira
Dez/2004
43
90
Bank Privatization and Productivity: Evidence for Brazil
Márcio I. Nakane and Daniela B. Weintraub
Dec/2004
91
Credit Risk Measurement and the Regulation of Bank Capital and
Provision Requirements in Brazil – A Corporate Analysis
Ricardo Schechtman, Valéria Salomão Garcia, Sergio Mikio Koyama and
Guilherme Cronemberger Parente
Dec/2004
92
Steady-State Analysis of an Open Economy General Equilibrium Model
for Brazil
Mirta Noemi Sataka Bugarin, Roberto de Goes Ellery Jr., Victor Gomes
Silva, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Apr/2005
93
Avaliação de Modelos de Cálculo de Exigência de Capital para Risco
Cambial
Claudio H. da S. Barbedo, Gustavo S. Araújo, João Maurício S. Moreira e
Ricardo S. Maia Clemente
Abr/2005
94
Simulação Histórica Filtrada: Incorporação da Volatilidade ao Modelo
Histórico de Cálculo de Risco para Ativos Não-Lineares
Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Gustavo Silva Araújo e Eduardo
Facó Lemgruber
Abr/2005
95
Comment on Market Discipline and Monetary Policy by Carl Walsh
Maurício S. Bugarin and Fábia A. de Carvalho
Apr/2005
96
O que É Estratégia: uma Abordagem Multiparadigmática para a
Disciplina
Anthero de Moraes Meirelles
Ago/2005
97
Finance and the Business Cycle: a Kalman Filter Approach with Markov
Switching
Ryan A. Compton and Jose Ricardo da Costa e Silva
Aug/2005
98
Capital Flows Cycle: Stylized Facts and Empirical Evidences for
Emerging Market Economies
Helio Mori and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Aug/2005
99
Adequação das Medidas de Valor em Risco na Formulação da Exigência
de Capital para Estratégias de Opções no Mercado Brasileiro
Gustavo Silva Araújo, Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo,e Eduardo
Facó Lemgruber
Set/2005
100 Targets and Inflation Dynamics
Sergio A. L. Alves and Waldyr D. Areosa
Oct/2005
101 Comparing Equilibrium Real Interest Rates: Different Approaches to
Measure Brazilian Rates
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Márcio I .Nakane
Mar/2006
102 Judicial Risk and Credit Market Performance: Micro Evidence from
Brazilian Payroll Loans
Ana Carla A. Costa and João M. P. de Mello
Apr/2006
44