part ii
THE ECONOMIC
AS CULTURE
0001316365.INDD 115
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
0001316365.INDD 116
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
CULTURE AND
THE ECONOMY
carlo tognato
Introduction
A great variety of social theorists have repeatedly denounced the almost inexorable
process of disenchantment within modern societies that allegedly leads technical
rationality to progressively displace any non-instrumental cultural logic from social
life1. Such a pessimistic understanding of modernity adds to a particularly grim
picture of the economy. Supporters of this view, after all, consider that rational disenchantment has pushed furthest in the economic arena. The recent birth of the
euro, they argue, provides a typical example of this. The euro, in the end, is a purely
functional artifact—just money without identity: “No one loves it, all accept it”
(Hörisch 2004, p. 122).
If such a reading of the economy were correct, then romantics that entered the
economic sphere after the spur of cultural reenchantment would be warned:
“Abandon all your hope those who enter.” The reality of economic life, however,
seems to point to a different direction. During the transition to the European
Monetary Union, for example, a reader of the Financial Times summarized the
reading as European governments made of the Maastricht criteria: “The difference
between happiness and misery is a 0.2 per cent deficit of the gross domestic product! A 2.9 per cent deficit is fine and enables one to live in happiness and bliss, while
a 3.1 per cent deficit condemns a country to chaos, misery, and eternal damnation.”2
On the occasion of the European Council meeting that launched the euro, in turn,
the Portuguese Prime Minister saluted the new currency: “As Jesus Christ decided
to found a church, he told Peter: ‘You are Peter and upon this rock I will build my
church.’ Today we can say: ‘You are Euro, and upon this new currency, we will build
0001316365.INDD 117
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
118
the economic as culture
our Europe.’”3 Then, during the celebration of the appointment of the President and
Vice-President of the European Central Bank, Hans Tietmeyer, then President of
the Deutsche Bundesbank, one of the purest institutional distillates of modern
technical rationality, addressed an audience of bankers and public officials with a
prayer of Sarastos, high priest of Ancient Egypt.4 Finally, in a scientific colloquium,
Otmar Issing, then Chief Economist of the Deutsche Bundesbank, confessed that
any appointee to the Board of the Bundesbank experiences a transformation of his
own identity that is comparable to the one Thomas Beckett underwent when Henry
II appointed him Archibishop of Canterbury. Beckett turned into a strenuous
defender of the Church’s interests, dared contradict the Crown of which he had
been till then a faithful servant, and took up his new responsibilities to the point of
accepting martyrdom (Issing 1991, pp. 7–8). These examples seem to suggest that
cultural codes, metaphors, rituals, and identities still matter in the modern economy. Rational disenchantment, as a consequence, might be less pervasive than many
social theorists would have us believe.
Economists have traditionally underplayed the role of culture in the economy,
fearing that cultural explanations would sacrifice the profession’s commitment to
testable hypotheses (Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales 2006). In the past two decades,
however, the establishment of a neo-institutionalist tradition within economics has
marked a clear departure in this respect (North 1990, 1994). By drawing on the work
of Banfield (1958), Putman (1993), and Fukuyama (1995), economists have started to
systematically recognize the influence of culture on trust and hence on economic
performance (Landes 1993; Knack and Keefer 1996; La Porta, et al. 1997).
Economic sociology, in turn, has experienced in the past three decades a vibrant
revival. During this period, a culturalist strand of scholarship has persistently claimed
that culture has not at all been squeezed out of the market. On the contrary, it actively
participates to shape economic action and even makes it viable. Still, its contributors
could have pushed their cultural analysis even further. In this chapter, I will discuss
how far they went and what they possibly missed. Doing so will provide a clearer
picture of the intellectual mission of a cultural sociology of the economy, its theoretical horizon, and its pragmatic relevance in times of economic crisis.
With particular reference to this latest point, I will suggest, people today are
starting to doubt whether an economic profession that could not anticipate or prevent the current crisis will be able to repair it. Corporations across all industrial
sectors are involved in scandals that are dangerously undermining the confidence of
the public. And central banks are being forced to bring down interest rates to a level
at which monetary policy simply becomes powerless before deflationary pressures.
Soon enough, as deflation deepens and unemployment lines get longer and longer, the general public will start to wonder whether it is time to do away with independent central banks whose single-minded institutional task—the control of
inflation—has suddenly passed out of fashion. At this historical juncture, economists and economic institutions may undergo a crisis of confidence with unpredictable consequences on the economic system. Scholars have a moral obligation to
offer fresh insights into the mechanisms that sustain public confidence or help
0001316365.INDD 118
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
culture and the economy
119
to repair it. I will argue that a cultural sociology of the economy is specifically
equipped to contribute in this respect.
Over the past three decades, the culturalist strand of scholarship within economic sociology has tended to restrict its horizon of observation on single institutional settings. By putting the question of confidence and legitimacy at its analytical
core, and by taking scandals as its primary empirical focus, a cultural sociology of
the economy, instead, attempts to overcome the “middle range malaise” of such
scholarship by concentrating on the connections between institutional settings on
the one hand and the central myths that underpin the functioning of the economy
on the other. Functionalists did try to push in this direction, but the analytical horizon of their value sociology fell short of letting them appreciate the full role of myth
and ritual in economic life. A cultural sociology of the economy, on the contrary,
capitalizes on the richer understanding of cultural structures and practices sociologists have gained since the demise of Parsonsian sociology.
Before proceeding, I will lay out the structure of this chapter. I will start by briefly
tracking the precursors of a cultural analysis of economic life within classical sociological theory. Then, I will do the same with reference to contemporary economic
sociology. This will allow me to show in what way a cultural sociology of the economy builds on both sociologies, while at the same time distancing itself from them
in important ways. After pinning down the intellectual vocation and the theoretical
horizon of a cultural sociology of the economy, I will devote the second part of this
chapter toward grounding its pragmatic relevance. A cultural sociology of the economy, I will suggest, promises to contribute to the advancement of three fields of
inquiry that have experienced an exciting development in the past three decades—
the literature on organizational legitimacy, on the sociology of financial markets, and
on the sociology of money. Pushing the research frontier of these three literatures
ahead into a more decisively culturalist direction will enable sociologists to tackle
three of the most pressing problems that loom on the horizon of the current world
economic crisis: the loss of confidence on the part of the general public for private
corporations, the economic profession, and independent central banks.
Classical Sources of a Cultural
Sociology of the Economy
Different classical sources provide a fertile ground from which a cultural sociology
of the economy can draw for the purpose of nurturing its intellectual project.
Economic sociologists have traditionally included Durkheim, Weber, Parsons, and
Polanyi among their classics. These are important referents also for a cultural sociology of the economy, as well, although the later Durkheim of The Elementary
Forms of Religious Life tends to be far more important for cultural sociologists than
for economic sociologists. Recently, Swedberg (2004) has recognized Alexandre de
0001316365.INDD 119
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
120
the economic as culture
Toqueville as an important classic in economic sociology. I will here suggest that
Toqueville also deserves equal recognition within a cultural sociology of the economy. By directly addressing the cultural linkages between democracy and capitalism, after all, the French thinker touched on one of the core research interests of this
field of inquiry that, I will argue, makes it most useful under the current historical
circumstances. At a time when economists and major economic institutions run the
risk of losing the confidence of the public as a result of the ongoing world economic
crisis, shedding light over such linkages may help understand how to maintain and,
if necessary, how to repair such confidence.
Bearing this in mind, I will only briefly touch on the contributions of Durkheim,
Weber, Parsons, and Polanyi that are most relevant for the construction of a cultural
sociology of the economy and dwell instead a little bit longer on Toqueville’s
Democracy in America, which has traditionally received lesser attention in economic
sociology.
Economic sociologists generally tend to emphasize the early Durkheim of The
Division of Labour in Society, Professional Ethics and Civic Morals, and Suicide. A cultural sociology of the economy definitely values the early Durkheim’s references to
the autonomous role collective beliefs and morality respectively play in the emergence of private property and in the maintenance of contractual obligations. The
later Durkheim of The Elementary Forms of Religious Life, however, is a much more
crucial reference for a cultural sociology of the economy. Recently, Smelser and
Swedberg (2005, pp. 10–11) have referred to it while stressing the central role morality plays in Durkheim’s economic sociology. Still, they do so in a rather tangential
way. A cultural sociology of the economy, instead, places The Elementary Forms at
its core. After all, people invest economic life with sentiment and meaning, and their
understanding of economic reality is mediated by the collective representations of
that reality. As a result, Durkheim’s analysis of the ritual mechanisms by which people establish shared meaning becomes especially critical.
Max Weber constitutes another central referent for any cultural sociologist
committed to recover the autonomous influence of culture on economic life. His
conception of economic action as inherently meaningful and his extensive work on
the economic ethics of Protestantism, Confucianism, Hinduism, and Judaism constitute an important resource on which cultural sociologists can build (Weber [1922]
1978, [1904] 1998, [1915] 1946a, [1920] 1946b, [1946] 1971). A cultural sociology of the
economy, though, will distance itself from Weber’s tragic thesis on the disenchantment of modernity and will instead strive to systematically recognize the instances
of cultural reenchantment in modern economic life.
Talcott Parsons, together with Neil Smelser, are other important referents for a
cultural sociology of the economy. Their exploration of the boundary exchanges
between the economy and the cultural-motivational subsystem spurs cultural sociologists to think of the role of culture in economic life in more systemic terms.
Parson and Smelser’s Economy and Society (1956) as well as Smelser’s (1963, 1976)
subsequent work in economic sociology, however, did not manage to relevantly
impact the subfield. For a cultural sociology of the economy, their attention to the
0001316365.INDD 120
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
culture and the economy
121
role of norms and values in economic life is surely important but falls short of being
sufficient. After all, symbols, cultural codes, narratives, genres, and cultural practices as well deserve to be considered.
Karl Polanyi, in turn, has become particularly fashionable among economic
sociologists since the birth of the new economic sociology, which has borrowed
from him the concept of “embeddedness” (Polanyi [1944] 1957, [1957] 1971; Polanyi,
Arensberg, and Pearson [1957] 1971). Polanyi attacks neoclassical economics for its
formalism and for conceiving the economy as a process that is totally disembedded
from institutional and cultural contexts. Instead, he points out, economic activities
and institutions are embedded in noneconomic motives and institutions, and,
therefore, social and institutional contexts in the end permeate the logic of meansends (Polanyi, Arensberg, and Pearson [1957] 1971). Polanyi further develops this
thesis as he discusses his typology of exchange relations—reciprocity, redistribution, and market exchange. The first two, he suggests, are embedded in social relations (Polanyi [1944] 1957, p. 46). In particular, reciprocity builds on friendship,
kinship, among other different social ties, whereas redistribution relies on other
political and religious underpinnings. On the other hand, the other pattern of integration—market exchange—is guided according to Polanyi only by the pursuit of
gain: “A market economy is an economic system controlled, regulated, and directed
by markets alone; order in the production and distribution of goods is entrusted to
this self-regulating mechanism” (Polanyi [1944] 1957, p. 68). Economic sociologists
have recently criticized such a conclusion and have shown, instead, that market
exchange as well is embedded into noneconomic norms and institutions (Lie 1991).
A cultural sociology of the economy surely coincides with such a reading of this
important classic.
Swedberg (2004, p. 3) has recently argued that Toqueville’s Democracy in America
deserves a place among the classics in economic sociology. His book, after all, provides an important complement to Weber’s Protestant Ethics. On the one hand,
Toqueville shows that consumerism, rather than ascetism, was an important building block of the American religious practices and that the endless drive among
Americans to consume more and more without ever being fully satisfied5 crucially
contributed to keep the American economy dynamic. On the other hand, Toqueville
reminds us that the American Christian tradition managed to exercise some control
over consumerism, thereby avoiding the anomie and the anxiety that an endless
pursuit of unsatisfiable desires would otherwise trigger within the population
(Swedberg 2004, p. 18). In short, the spirit of American capitalism according to
Toqueville could build both on the spirit of American traditional religion and on
the spirit of freedom that characterizes American civilization (Tocqueville 1956,
p. 43; in Swedberg 2004, p. 27).
These elements in Toqueville’s analysis are clearly relevant for a cultural sociology of the economy, as well. I would argue, though, that Democracy in America
deserves its inclusion among the classics of this field even more because of
Toqueville’s analysis of the linkages between American democracy and American
capitalism. According to Toqueville, a free democratic society leads to a vibrant
0001316365.INDD 121
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
122
the economic as culture
economy. Democracies cultivate an ideal of the individual—rational and calm—
that is particularly suitable to the market arena. They stimulate the creation of voluntary organizations, thereby developing those organizational skills that are so
valuable in the economy. They make people comfortable with chance and uncertainty, a necessary disposition to survive in the market arena. And they orient their
citizens toward the present rather than the past as in aristocratic societies or than
the future as among the followers of religion. Such orientation, in turn, positively
contributes to sustain market activities. Teasing out, as Toqueville does, the values
and cultural practices that democracy and capitalism have in common is one first
step toward a comprehensive understanding of the cultural linkages between
democracy and the capitalist economy. What is missing, though, is an acknowledgment that democracy occupies a central position in modern societies that turns it
into a pillar of collective identity. As a result, linkages between democracy and the
economy are not only conducive to enhance functional performance in the economic arena, but also help to shift the economy and its institutions to the center,
root them into collective identity, and make them more robust as a consequence of
their cultural reenchantment.
After referring to the five classics, a cultural sociology of the economy would be
well advised to refer to for inspiration. I will now consider the body of scholarship
within contemporary economic sociology that has systematically pursued a cultural
analysis of economic life. This literature, after all, provides the launching pad from
which a cultural sociology of the economy can take off.
Cultural Analysis in Contemporary
Economic Sociology
In the course of the 1980s, a new economic sociology, built on Polanyi’s notion of
embeddedness (Polanyi [1944] 1971, 1957), took shape. This new research program
set out to recover the role of social relations in market processes. The works of
White (1981) on production markets as role structures: Burt (1983) on networks and
market competition; Baker (1984) on the social structure of securities markets; and
Granovetter (1974, 1985) on social ties in labor markets set the beginning of this
research tradition. Later, its contributors made an effort to complement the early
structural orientation of the field. Baker, for example, added interactionism to
White’s network perspective (Baker and Faulkner 1991). Podolny (1993) focused on
status order and positions rather than roles in the analysis of production markets.
Fligstein (1996) complemented the embeddedness approach with the cultural frame
perspective. And Granovetter (1990a, pp. 108–110; 1990b, pp. 95–106) made an effort
to bring Berger and Luckmann’s (1966) constructivism into the network approach
(Swedberg 1997, p. 165). More recently, Carruthers and Babb (2000) have accepted
that “modern markets are filled with meaning.” Therefore, to understand production
0001316365.INDD 122
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
culture and the economy
123
and consumption, it is necessary to take stock of the systems of cultural meaning in
which they are embedded.
This later turn on the part of Carruthers and Babb (2000) appears to make an
effort to respond to those critics who have complained that previous efforts to bring
culture into the horizon of the new economic sociology have not gone far enough
(Lie 1997; Zukin and DiMaggio 1990; Nee and Ingram 1998; Krippner 2001). In particular, according to Krippner (2001), the social embeddedness approach that sprung
out of Granovetter’s seminal work did away with the very social relations it meant
to recover and focused exclusively on the structure of the ties. As a result, neither
their social content nor their different meanings played any role. On such ground,
Krippner concludes, the new economic sociology has not met its promise of recognizing, along with Polanyi, that the study of economic life calls for the analysis of
the concrete institutions that shape economic practice and that “markets, even in
ideal form, are not the expression of primal, timeless instincts; they are rather fully
social institutions, reflecting a complex alchemy of politics, culture, and ideology”
(Krippner 2001, p. 782).
While new economic sociologists have apparently run into such difficulties, a
culturalist strand of scholarship within economic sociology has instead managed to
strike a more effective balance between social-structural and cultural analysis.
Different contemporary anthropologists, cultural historians and cultural studies
specialists, mostly working on consumption and money, have served as a source
of inspiration for this literature (Douglas 1967; Geertz 1973; Sahlins 1976; Douglas
and Isherwood 1979; Crump 1981; Agnew 1986; Appadurai 1986; Reddy 1984;
Taussig 1986; Miller 1987). Karin Knorr Cetina, Mitchel Abolafia, Nicole Biggart,
and Viviana Zelizer are possibly the four most accomplished contributors to this
line of research.
Karin Knorr Cetina is one of the leading figures of a new field of inquiry—the
sociology of finance—that has emerged over the past decade out of a fruitful convergence between economic sociology and the social studies of science. Unlike the
other three major contributors to the culturalist strand within economic sociology,
her work has a markedly phenomenological character. Global currency markets, she
observes, are “collective disembodied systems generated entirely in a symbolic
space” (Knorr 2005, p. 38). The global world they contribute to bring about is delivered to its participants by a “constellation of technical, visual, and behavioral components packaged together on financial screens.” Such screens, she insists, are not
windows on physically different realities. They are the reality of financial markets.
They are the core of the market and most of its context (Knorr 2005, p. 45). Through
the screens the market “brings out its life-like depth. . . . As an omnipresent complex
‘Other’, the market on screen takes on a presence and a profile in its own right with
its own self-assembling and self-integrating features” (Knorr 2005, p. 48).
By focusing on the interaction between human and nonhuman actants, Knorr
Cetina opens up a fascinating window into the lifeworld of financial markets. One
gets the impression, though, that the horizon of meaning she adopts for the purpose of capturing such a lifeworld is too narrow to account for the semantic richness
0001316365.INDD 123
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
124
the economic as culture
of some of her ethnographic material. For example, in one occasion she observes
that “when traders arrive in the morning, they strap themselves to their seats, figuratively speaking” (Knorr 2005, p. 44). Abolafia finds in his ethnography of Wall
Street that traders compare themselves with fighter-jet pilots. If this is the case, then
their strapping to their seats is a bit more than just figurative. Rather, it echoes a
dimension of their lifeworld that apparently escapes Knorr Cetina’s horizon of
interpretation. In her study with Urs Bruegger on the foreign exchange market in
Zurich, in turn, she remarks that sex and violence permeate the vocabulary by which
traders describe their relation to the market (Knorr and Bruegger 2000, p. 154).
References to sex and violence have traditionally characterized military talk and
therefore appear to be consistent with the finding that traders see themselves as
fighter-jet pilots. If this is the case, one may start to wonder whether the morning
after a particularly “bloody” day of trading, traders will get back to their computers
and feel they “love the smell of napalm in the morning.” Or alternatively, whether in
the course of a coordinated attack against a currency, they will hear the trumpets of
Wagner’s Walkiries. If one believes that meaning is not just the endogenous product
of a given setting of interaction but rather has a citational character, then one will
be bound to expand the horizon of interpretation in order to correctly pin down the
lifeworld of a given object of analysis. For the case at hand, this implies that scholars
will have to push the analysis much further in order to capture the cultural embeddedness of trading. Doing so will enable them to track the spurs of those intertextual references that might pin down the “global” lifeworld of financial markets to
specific cultural contexts. And this could ultimately give away the fact that what
appears to be global might be in the end just a prolongation of some cultural
specificity.
Like Knorr Cetina, Mitchel Abolafia has worked on financial markets. In his
1996 ethnography, Making Markets (1996), the author shows in what ways the exercise of self-interest within three different trading floors reflects a panoply of local
institutional and cultural mechanisms—the “elaborate occupational cultures that
prescribe manners, attitudes, and styles of play,” the “scripts defining who can play
and how the game should be played,” and the broader cultural horizon within which
such scripts are embedded (Abolafia 1996, p. 231).
While recognizing that trading is a deep play in which there is much more at
stake than just money (Abolafia 1996, p. 17), Abolafia clearly draws from Geertz
(1973). Still, this is not the only inspiration the author draws from anthropology.
Victor Turner’s notion of social drama, as well, helps him pin down the cultural
structure that underpins the unfolding of Michael Milken’s scandal, which he discusses at the end of his book. His analysis of the dramatic dimensions of such a
scandal, however, never gets him as far as taking a performative turn in his study.
His discussion of the scandal also sheds light over the limits of his approach to
the analysis of cultural embeddedness. For example, when Milken justifies financial
innovation as a means to overcome discrimination among entrepreneurs with
regard to access to funding, Abolafia does not seem to hear the echo in Milken’s
argument of that discourse of the American civil society within which the principle
0001316365.INDD 124
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
culture and the economy
125
of equality among citizens is inscribed, and which constitutes the cultural horizon
within which Milken may have possibly articulated his argumentative strategy.
Surely, Abolafia accounts to some important extent for the cultural embeddedness
of trading and pushes it far enough to capture the linkages between trading and
other fields of action like gambling and combat, which in turn lead traders to compare themselves with fighter pilots and professional athletes—disciplined, coolheaded, focused, and emotionally distant (Abolafia 1996, p. 18). Yet, he does not
seem to count on a clear analytical criterion that enables him to decide how far one
should push the analysis in order to adequately account for the cultural embeddedness of the object under inquiry.
Finally, Abolafia draws from Swidler’s (1986, p. 284) understanding of culture
as “a repertoire of capacities from which varying strategies of action may be
constructed.” However, since Abolafia shows that identities and emotions also play
an important role in the way traders carry out their job, one wonders whether a
deeply instrumental and totally malleable understanding of culture can actually
reflect their experience. After all, one would expect that the internal logic of culture
and the emotional investments traders make on particular cultural scripts would
increase their rigidity and therefore their autonomous effects on traders’ actions.
Together with Knorr Cetina and Abolafia, Nicole Biggart is one of the most
accomplished contributors to the culuralist strand within economic sociology. In
her Charismatic Capitalism (1989), Biggart uses a Weberian framework to show that
modern capitalism has allowed the survival of organizational forms such as directselling organizations that seem to have escaped the iron-cage logic of rational disenchantment. Such organizations, she points out, are charisma-based rather than
legal-rational. They allow and foster cooperative rather competitive relations within
their staff. They encourage rather than repress emotions on the part of their members. And they use social networks to reach their business goals rather than cutting
them off.
In her analysis of direct-selling organizations, Biggart devotes her attention to
the role values, collective representations and beliefs, narratives, and rituals play in
their operation. Echoing Toqueville’s insights on the spirit of American capitalism,
she observes that in the nineteenth century Protestant ethics in America got twisted,
and wealth was no longer seen as a sign of God but rather as a result of individual
accomplishment and character. On such ground, meritocracy, initiative, and perseverance were positively valued and ended up by constituting the core set of values
that still inspires direct-selling organizations. After pinpointing the ethics that
underpin the operations of such organizations, Biggart could have addressed the
cultural codes that most directly inspire such values. Alexander and Smith (1993),
and Alexander (2006) would provide a neat basis to start from. Instead, she pursues,
in a different direction, the analysis of collective representations and beliefs as well
as the narratives that set them in motion. For example, the author shows that the
idea of family structures both identities and actions within direct-selling organizations (Biggart 1989, p. 14) Kinship terms, as a result, describe work relations as
between daughter-dealers and mother-managers. Meetings are represented as family
0001316365.INDD 125
7/14/2011 4:26:36 PM
126
the economic as culture
reunions. And home parties, where the selling is conducted, are referred to as dates.
Apart from family, religion also provides a constellation of metaphors that contribute to structure the experience of direct-selling organizations. For example, their
members attribute a transformational power to the products they sell to the point
that they “obscure the financial transaction that in fact is taking place: they present
themselves as direct-selling companies that paradoxically do not sell” (Biggart 1989,
p. 116). Quite interestingly, while Biggart refers to Douglas and Isherwood’s work on
the anthropology of consumption to discuss the transformation in meaning that
products undergo in direct-selling organizations, she does not push her analysis to
the point of systematically discussing the performative dimensions of such a process and therefore the elements that influence its authenticity. Despite that, Biggart’s
analysis goes as far as hinting at performance when she addresses the ritual dimensions of direct-selling organizations. For example, she points out, public confessional rituals set the stage for witnessing the transformation of the self members of
direct-selling organizations undergo as they grow within such organizations. Also,
public celebrations serve as rituals in which the miraculous powers of leaders get
reaffirmed.
Together with Knorr Cetina, Biggart, and Abolafia, Viviana Zelizer is another
outstanding contributor to the culturalist strand within economic sociology. Surely,
she is the scholar who has carried out such an approach with the greatest coherence
over the longest period of time (Zelizer 1979, 1985, 1994, 2005). Zelizer’s analysis
successfully integrates cultural with structural analysis. To explain the emergence
of the American insurance industry; or the social construction of the economically
useless and yet emotionally priceless child between 1870 and 1930 in America; or the
changing social meanings of money, Zelizer takes stock both with the effects of
cultural frames as well as of class and family structures. All along in her career,
Zelizer has stressed the importance of overcoming the “mythology” within economic sociology that conceives two hostile worlds—one of rationality, efficiency,
and impersonality, on the one side, and one of self-expression, cultural richness,
and intimacy, on the other—which are crucial to keep separate in order to avoid
mutual corruption. At the same time, her work must be commended for resisting
the temptation to reduce economic phenomena to economic calculation culture,
or power and for insisting that “we have no choice but to pave crossroads connecting continuously negotiated, meaning-drenched social relations with the whole
range of economic processes” (Zelizer 2005a, p. 349).6 Finally, it is important to
remember Zelizer’s insistence, particularly in her later works, on one pragmatic
point. By vindicating the salience of culture in modern economic life, a culturesensitive economic sociology will not be doomed to marginality. Instead, it will be
able to add value to the analysis of important macroeconomic phenomena that
economists have not quite fully grasped. Although Zelizer is particularly vocal on
this point, immediate pragmatic relevance is apparently also one of the characterizing features of the contributions by Biggart and Abolafia to the culturalist strand
of economic sociology that distinguishes their work from the culture-sensitive
work of other sociologists.
0001316365.INDD 126
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
culture and the economy
127
Zelizer’s work has systematically shed light over the pervasive intrusion of
different cultural logics into the market sphere. In this sense, she has contributed to
the line of research within sociology that has been vindicating for the margin for
cultural reenchantment in modern life. Also, she has paid constant attention to the
cultural embeddedness of economic action. Like Abolafia, however, it is unclear
whether she relies on a clear analytical criterion that helps her decide whether her
analysis of cultural embeddedness has gone sufficiently far and how far ahead it
could possibly push. Without making such a criterion explicit, the reader cannot
decide whether her treatment of cultural embeddedness is sufficiently encompassing. Finally, Zelizer acknowledges that economic phenomena can undergo a process
of cultural transformation that is mediated both by culture and social structure.
Still, she does not directly address the contingency and the instability of such a
process nor does she explicitly tackle it as a matter of cultural performance.
The need for a performative turn in her analysis cannot but be all the more
urgent as her research moves into the field of economic ethics. Zelizer (2007, p. 9) has
recently stressed the importance for sociology to understand how ethical questions
arise in economic life, what their distinctive properties are, how economic actors
respond to them, what produces violations, and what effects such responses have on
economic performance. To answer such questions, she continues, it is not sufficient
to look at the work moral philosophers, feminist thinkers, economists, and economic
sociologists have produced in their studies of professions, crime, inheritance, consumption, care, and corruption. Rather, it is necessary to examine the relationship
between general ethical contexts and the specific forms of code organizations adopt.
“National ethical traditions,” after all, “shape contrasting approaches to both the
construction and the contents of formal ethical codes” (Zelizer 2007, p. 20). Still, the
scripts people resort to in order to come across as economically ethical are only part
of the story. Discursive competence is not sufficient to come across as authentically
committed to ethical behavior in the economic arena. Actors, instead, need to be
performatively competent in this respect. This is why a performative turn in Zelizer’s
most recent research agenda is all the more urgent.
Outline of a Cultural Sociology
of the Economy
The debate among economic sociologists over the opportunity to introduce cultural analysis within their horizon of inquiry has traditionally focused on the
question of whether cultural analysis should replace social-structural analysis or
whether it should complement it. Zelizer, for example, has advocated for the latter.
Similarly, DiMaggio distanced himself from a full-scale cultural analysis of the
economy and has suggested instead that economic sociology “should include a ‘cultural’ component—but not more” (DiMaggio 1994, p. 27).
0001316365.INDD 127
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
128
the economic as culture
The narrow focus of such a debate has prevented the profession from
systematically discussing how scholars should go about accounting for the cultural
dimension of economic life. Should they take a cultural-structural approach? Or
should they rather adopt a pragmatic focus? Or, alternatively, should they resort to
a framework that integrates both perspectives? Furthermore, taking stock with the
role of culture in the economy implies addressing the phenomenon of cultural
embeddedness of economic action. So, how far should scholars push the analysis of
such a phenomenon? And where should they draw the line? These are the basic
theoretical questions that structure the core of a cultural sociology of the economy.
In this section, I will argue that the emerging field of neo-Durkheimian sociology,
which in the past two decades has systematically addressed the phenomenon of
cultural reenchantment in modern societies, can provide one possible set of answers
to such questions. Answering them, I will suggest, will help distinguish the inner
theoretical makeup of a cultural sociology of the economy from the culturalist
strand of scholarship within economic sociology.
To make my point, I will proceed by steps. I will start by showing how the later
Durkheim of The Elementary Forms of Religious Life can help make sense of cultural
reenchantment in modern societies, and what the limits of Durkheim’s analytical
framework are in this respect. This will allow me to introduce the neo-Durkheimian
extension of his framework. Then, after teasing out the main analytical features of
neo-Durkheimian analysis, I will be able to draw its implications with respect to the
two questions I have introduced at the beginning of this section: how to study the
cultural dimension of economic life, and how to go about the study of cultural
embeddedness.
Traditional communities constituted the main focus of Durkheim’s Elementary
Forms of Religious Life. Still, the author explicitly envisaged the possibility of applying his framework to the analysis of social life in modern societies. After all, as
Smith and Alexander (2005, p. 26) have recently acknowledged, Durkheim considered that the internal patterning of religious life and social organization in modern
societies are homologous. He stressed the power and compulsion that characterizes
both religious and social symbols. He showed that value-conflicts in modern societies get transfigured into an agonic struggle between the sacred and the profane. He
recognized that actors still move to avoid pollution and to restore purity. And finally,
he acknowledged the lasting power of the ritual in modern societies for the purpose
of establishing solidarities. In other words, to put it with Alexander (1988, p. 177),
Durkheim did not merely lay out a sociology of religion but rather put forward a
religious sociology that used religion as a metaphor to understand society.
Since the 1980s, a neo-Durkheimian tradition has emerged within sociological
theory that has systematically applied Durkheim’s “religious sociology” to the study
of different spheres of social life in modern societies (Smith and Alexander 2005,
p. 14). As the research tradition consolidated, though, the limits of Durkheim’s
framework have become increasingly apparent. Scholars have recognized that, as a
result of structural differentiation, and due to conflict, competition, and reflexivity,
social integration in modern societies is much more fragile and contingent than
0001316365.INDD 128
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
culture and the economy
129
Durkheim envisaged. The experience of meaning is much less immediate as a result
of its being mediated by drama and contrivance. These differences have led Smith
and Alexander (2005, p. 26) to suggest that drawing a straightforward homology
from Durkheim between traditional and modern societies is “not enough and too
much.” As a consequence, neo-Durkheimians have had to resort to a more general
analytical framework that enables them to approach modern social life as a cultural
accomplishment without reducing its contingency and its instability. Alexander’s
latest macrosociological theory of social action as performance has provided a powerful tool in this respect (Alexander 2006).
On such a ground neo-Durkheimians have been able to argue that modern
societies—to put it with Shils (1975)—still have a sacred center that works as their
“ultimate and irreducible” transcendent core. They have been able to acknowledge
that at the symbolic level all spheres of social life are still latently linked to the center
and that whenever social action moves to the center, it can rise above the profane
realm of routine function and partake in the sacredness of collective identity. This
is what according to neo-Durkheimians makes cultural reenchantment possible in
modern societies. On the other hand, they have recognized that for social action to
move to the center, cultural linkages must be turned on effectively, and this constitutes a highly unstable performative accomplishment.
These considerations bear two important analytical implications. First, taking
stock of the cultural embeddedness of social action implies accounting for the rich
web of cultural linkages that latently anchor it to the center.7 To adequately deal
with cultural embeddedness, as a result, analysts must consider the center as their
relevant horizon of interpretation. Second, since cultural reenchantment crucially
depends on the effectiveness of the linkages—and since this is a matter of cultural
performance—neither a purely cultural-structuralist nor a purely action-oriented
framework is suitable to capture that. Rather, one must resort to one framework
that integrates both perspectives. Alexander’s cultural pragmatics satisfies such a
requirement.
These conclusions surely provide an answer to the two basic theoretical questions that stand at the core of a cultural sociology of the economy. At the same
time, though, it raises a new question that falls beyond the analytical horizon of
the culturalist strand of scholarship within economic sociology. What stands at the
sacred center of modern societies, after all?
According to Alexander, democracy constitutes an important building block of
the center and therefore contributes to define the identity of modern societies.
Democracy, he maintains, is not just a set of technical rules. Rather, it is “a world of
great and idealizing expectations, but also overwhelming feelings of disgust and condemnation.” This world, he insists, is articulated through “a transcendental language
of sacred values of the good and profane symbols of evil” (Alexander 2006, p. 4), “a
historically contingent final vocabulary,” to put it with Rorty (1989, pp. 190–192), by
means of which people express what brings them together and what sets them apart
(Alexander 2006, p. 56). Such a language consists of “a highly generalized symbolic
system that divides civic virtue from civic vice in a remarkably stable and consistent
0001316365.INDD 129
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
130
the economic as culture
way.” Its general structure can be isolated and approached as “a relatively autonomous
symbolic form” (p. 56). Alexander and Smith (1993) and subsequently Alexander
(2006) show that such structure can be represented as a system of binary attributes
that define legitimate and illegitimate motivations, social relations and institutions
in democratic societies. Such cultural codes, in the end, are a core building block of
the sacred center of modern societies.
Baiocchi (2006) has recently shown that alternative discourses may compete
against that of civil society in the makeup of the symbolic center of democratic
societies. For example, in the specific case of Brazil, he shows that the codes of
liberty and repression, based on the liberal tradition, must compete against a corporatist code that draws from a nonliberal political culture in which the collective
primes over the individual.
If the analysis of the above-mentioned authors is correct, then it is possible to
conclude that in modern secular societies, different spheres of social life, for example, the economy, are latently linked to a sacred symbolic center. Such a center is
structured by the discourses of political legitimation citizens resort to in order to
determine who is in and deserves the solidarity of the other fellow citizens and who
is out and can therefore be neglected. Alexander’s codes of liberty and repression,
Baiocchi’s corporatist code, or Tognato and Cuellar’s codes of the patron and the
populace are the cultural structures that can makeup the center of democratic societies at different stages of modernization. Understanding the meaning of economic
action will therefore require that the analyst takes stock with the immediate cultural
context within which economic action is embedded; but also on the one hand with
the rich network of symbolic linkages that latently connect economic action to the
cultural codes at the center and on the other with the performative conditions that
turn such linkages effective.
Such considerations help better qualify the topography that underpins Spillman’s
(1999) map of a cultural sociology of the economy. According to Spillman (1999,
p. 1047), such a field should concentrate on the analysis of three phenomena: the
cultural construction of the objects of market exchange, the cultural construction
of parties to market exchange, and finally the cultural construction of the norms of
exchange. The literature on consumer culture (Tomlison 1990, Biernacki 1995) and
the sociology of the state literature (Pusey 1991), as Spillman (1999, p. 1054) points
out, have addressed the first phenomenon, that is, the commodification of previously uncommodified spheres. Still, Spillman continues, it is necessary to systematically account for such a process as one of contested reframing, as Zelizer (1985) did
with reference to life insurance and Frenzen, Hirsch, and Zerillo (1994) did with
regard to the transformation of debt into the socially more acceptable consumer
credit. The cultural construction of the parties to market exchange, in turn, she
adds, needs to be approached in terms of construction of a peculiar kind of imagined community (Anderson 1991). Cultural sociologists can help in this respect by
shedding light over the relevant cultural boundaries: how they change and how they
get redesigned. “The idea of imagined community,” she insists, “should be used to
extend the notion of embeddedness typically understood in terms of structural
0001316365.INDD 130
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
culture and the economy
131
dimensions of network” (Spillman 1999, p. 1058). Finally, she concludes, a cultural
sociology of the economy must take stock with the plurality of logics of action and
of vocabularies of motive that permeate market exchange.8 This implies tracking
the norms, the narratives, and the rituals that underpin and help legitimize it
(Spillman 1999, pp. 1061–1062). According to Spillman, three literatures have contributed to this respect: that of state/market relations (Carruthers 1996; Dobbin
1994; Fligstein 1996; Pusey 1991); consumer society and on advertising (Frenzen,
Hirsch, and Zerillo 1994; Tomlison 1990) and the meaning of money (Zelizer 1994;
Carruthers and Espeland 1997).
Now, looking at Spillman’s map with neo-Durkheimian lenses will help realize
that the three lines of inquiry she identifies are no isolated basins. Rather, their
waters flow from the very same source—the sacred center of society. Distance from,
and connection with, the center are in the end the topographic principles that organize such a map.
After briefly laying out the central features of a cultural sociology of the economy, it is now possible to refer back to the authors I presented in the previous two
sections and identify the main points of difference and contact between them.
I will start with the classics. A cultural sociology of the economy builds on the
late Durkheim of The Elementary Forms of Religious Life but does not stop there.
Rather, it follows the interpretative stream from Durkheim through Parsons, Shils,
and Douglas to the neo-Durkheimian tradition that emerged in the 1980s and
extended Durkheim’s analytical framework to better fit modern complex differentiated societies.
Also, a cultural sociology of the economy is sympathetic with a systemic perspective that is keen to systematically track the boundary exchanges between the
economy and the other spheres of social life. After all, if this were not the case, the
field would not be interested in taking into consideration the rich network of symbolic linkages that connects the economy with the sacred center of society. This
constitutes a point of contact with the Economy and Society perspective Parsons and
Smelser advocated. On the other hand, the focus on the symbolic and the performative marks a clear departure from the value sociology that underpins Parsons and
Smelser’s economic sociology.
With reference to Weber, in turn, a cultural sociology of the economy shows
that economic life in modern societies is still linked to powerful sources of charisma
that occasionally get turned on. Under such circumstances, economic interaction is
transformed into a matter of collective identity and acquires the features that flow
from the sacred.
A cultural sociology of the economy relies on an analytical criterion that makes
it possible to determine how far the analysis of cultural embeddedness of economic
action should push. This enables cultural sociologists to meet Polanyi’s invitation to
adequately address the embeddedness of economic action and economic institutions. On the other hand, unlike Polanyi, the field does not consider that the deepening of a capitalist economy necessarily implies a disembedding effect from social
life. Market exchange, instead, is firmly embedded into culture. Only, this time, as
0001316365.INDD 131
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
132
the economic as culture
capitalism deepens, one witnesses a relative strengthening of the latent symbolic
linkages between the economic sphere and the sacred center of society with respect
to the linkages between the other spheres of social life and the center.
Finally, a cultural sociology of the economy understands the relationship
between capitalism and democracy in modern society in terms of the symbolic
linkage of the economic sphere to the sacred center of society whereby the identity
of society is coded. The field therefore reads Toqueville more from a Durkheimian
perspective than from a Weberian one.
With the culturalist strand within economic sociology, in turn, a cultural sociology of the economy shares the belief that the economic sphere in capitalist societies is still permeated by culture and cultural practices. Unlike such tradition,
however, it explicitly acknowledges that the economic sphere is linked to the sacred
center of society where the very identity of society is defined, and, therefore, whenever such linkages are effectively turned on, economic action turns into a matter of
identity. This provides an analytical criterion to establish how far the analysis of
cultural embeddedness should push, what it would call for, and why analysts should
address the performative dimension of the cultural transformation of economic
action into a matter of collective identity.
In this section, I have suggested that a cultural sociology of the economy is characterized by a number of analytical questions and operational concerns that differentiate it from other culture-sensitive analyses of the economy within sociology. For
the next question, on the other hand, following Zelizer’s recommendation, I will suggest that such a field is also immediately relevant at the pragmatic level. More precisely, it promises to contribute to push ahead into a more decisively culturalist
direction the research frontier of three literatures—on organizational legitimacy, the
sociology of financial markets, and the sociology of money—and enable, as a result,
sociologists to tackle three of the most pressing problems that loom at the horizon of
the current world economic crisis: The loss of confidence within the general public
for private corporations, the economic profession, and independent central banks.
The Use of a Cultural Sociology
of the Economy
As the world moves toward an economic crisis of historic proportions, the legitimacy of private corporations, economic professions, and independent central banks
starts to shake. Around the world, private corporations have been hit by a long
stream of scandals that has contributed to undermine their institutional credibility.
Economists have not been able to anticipate or warn against the crisis, and people
are now wondering whether they will be up to the task of steering the boat out of
the current fog. Central banks, in turn, have responded to the deepening deflation
by cutting interest rates to unprecedented levels. As monetary policy becomes
0001316365.INDD 132
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
culture and the economy
133
increasingly powerless concerning the recession, people will start to wonder what
the use of independent central banks is if their only institutional task—the control
of inflation—has suddenly passed out of fashion as a result of the crisis. As private
corporations, economists, and independent central banks run the risk of losing
people’s confidence, it is imperative to understand the mechanisms that underpin
its creation, maintenance, and repair. A cultural sociology of the economy can contribute in this respect by helping understand the deep sources of legitimacy of economic institutions in modern societies.
To understand how private corporations can defend their legitimacy in times of
crisis, I will first draw from the literature on organizational legitimacy that has been
consolidating in the past three decades. Such a literature, I will suggest, misses the
important dimensions of the defense of legitimacy a cultural sociology of the economy can instead help recover, thereby opening up a whole field of inquiry sociologists have not systematically yet explored.
Different definitions of organizational legitimacy are currently available in the
literature. According to Maurer (1971, p. 361), for example, legitimacy has to do with
the process by which an organization justifies its right to exist. Suchman (1995, p. 574),
in turn, suggests that organizational legitimacy is a “generalized perception or
assumption that the actions of an entity are desirable, proper, or appropriate within
some socially constructed system of norms, values, beliefs, and definitions.”9
For the study of organizational legitimacy, Weber constitutes one important
classical referent. Administrative systems, he suggests, draw legitimacy from either
charisma, tradition, or law. In 1960, Parsons proposed a cultural institutional perspective and stressed the importance for organizational goals to link to wider societal values and functions.
In the past three decades, two main approaches have contended the field of
organizational analysis. On the one hand, the ecological perspective has treated
legitimacy just as a parameter that influences the emergence and decline of organizational populations over time (Carroll and Hannan 2000; Hannan and Freeman
1992). As a result, it has not dwelt on the mechanisms that construct it. The institutionalist perspective, on the other hand, has done so by showing that organizations
achieve legitimacy by adjusting their structures, procedures, policies, and goals
with legal norms and regulations, field-level norms, or taken-for-granted cultural
constructs.
Within the institutionalist camp, then, some have emphasized passive adherence on the part of organizations to the structuration dynamics that unfold at
the field level and have therefore downplayed managerial agency and managerstakeholder conflict (Barron, et al. 1986; Baum and Powell 1995; DiMaggio and
Powell 1983; Meyer and Rowan 1977; Scott 2001; DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Meyer
and Scott 1983; Powell and DiMaggio 1991; Zucker 1987). Others, on the contrary,
have stressed active adherence, thereby pointing out that organizations instrumentally use and manipulate evocative symbols of conformity with widely held social
values to obtain public support. Such a strand, to put it with Suchman, presupposes
a high degree of management control over the legitimation process, an “almost
0001316365.INDD 133
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
134
the economic as culture
limitless malleability of symbols and rituals against the exogenously constrained
recalcitrance of tangible, real outcomes” (Pfeffer and Salancik 1978; Ashforth and
Gibbs 1990; Dowling and Pfeffer 1975; Pfeffer 1981).
Organizational crises—accidents, scandals, and product safety incidents—
constitute a privileged field to observe what the foundations of legitimacy are, how
legitimacy gets maintained, and how it can be possibly repaired (Marcus and Goodman
1991; Bucholz, Evans, and Wagley 1985; Godson 1975; Keirmann, and Olsen 1972;
Kemeny 1979; Perrow 1984; Sethi 1977; Sharplin 1985; Shrivastava 1987; Starling and
Baskin 1984; Sturdivant 1985; Davidson, Chandy and Cross 1987; Fields and Janjigian
1989; Marcus and Goodman 1989; Boulton 1978; Fisse and Braithwaite 1983;
Franklin 1986; Post 1978; Sampson 1973; Litschert and Nicholson 1977; Davidson and
Worrell 1988; Goodpaster 1984; Sapolsky 1986; Starling and Baskin 1985; Whiteside
1972; Bromiley and Marcus 1989). On such terrain, institutional analysis has been
fruitfully complemented by impression management studies. Institutionalists, on the
one hand, have shown that organizations introduce structural reforms and changes
in their procedures or staff in order to meet field-level norms. In other words, analysts
working along this tradition focus on the content of the measures that help maintain,
repair, or recover organizational legitimacy. Impression management scholars, on the
other hand, have focused instead on the communicative techniques that organizations, and particularly their spokespersons, resort to for the purpose of defending
themselves (Goffman 1973, 1974, 1981; Schenkler 1980; Tedeschi and Reiss 1981; Tedeschi
1981). Contributors to this approach have therefore been interested in tracking the
verbal accounts by which organizations deny or admit their responsibility, blame others, offer excuses, explain or justify their deeds, and apologize (Elsbach 1994; Elsbach
and Sutton 1992; Elsbach and Sutton 1998; Marcus and Goodman 1991; Sutton and
Callahan 1987; Sutton and Kramer 1990; Suchman 1995; Leary and Kowalski 1990;
Giacalone and Rosenfeld 1989, 1991; Staw, Mckechnie, and Puffer 1983; Bettman and
Weitz 1983; Salancik and Meindl 1984; Metzler 2001; Fisse and Braithwaite 1983).
Impression management scholars have also occasionally resorted to stigma theory
while addressing the communicative tactics organizations adopt to eschew or deal
with stigma (Sutton and Callahan 1987; Goffman 1963; Page 1984; Jones et al. 1984).
Both institutionalists and impression management scholars, however, have
missed out on a number of important issues crucial to the management of an organizational crisis and therefore to the recovery or repair of legitimacy. Focusing on
the mere scripts organizations follow in their verbal accounts completely neglects
all the other dimensions that make up the cultural pragmatics of apologies, denials,
explanations, and justifications, and that ultimately determines whether they will
be received by the public as authentic and therefore satisfactory. A script must distill
a whole set of background collective representations—symbols, codes, narratives,
and genres—that the public considers to be consistent with the meaning the script
seeks to project on its audiences. Also, the actors must match the script they are
uttering and the collective representations they are seeking to evoke through their
performance. Similarly, the staging of the apologies, denials, explanations, and
justifications, the means that are brought together to produce the performance, the
0001316365.INDD 134
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
culture and the economy
135
way social power is perceived to be influencing it, and the composition of the
audiences will crucially impact on the reception that organizations will get. In other
words, it may well happen that the very same script will be received satisfactorily by
some specific audience in a particular performative setting and will instead be
rejected in an alternative one.
Bringing in the performative horizon within which legitimacy can be maintained, challenged, repaired, and recovered yields two corollaries that help clarify
two further elements both the institutionalist and the impression management perspectives miss and a cultural sociology of the economy, instead, helps capture. The
logic of technical reason generally structures the profane realm of routine organizational life. When the legitimacy of an organization, and therefore its right to exist as
such, are challenged, and when, as a result, the stakes of both the organization and
its challengers soar, either party may consider escalating conflict by shifting the
game by symbolic linkage onto some alternative arena in which each party can
mobilize new allies in its favor, reverse the distribution of forces on the field, and
possibly win the battle over the organization’s legitimacy. As a result of the process
of competitive symbolic linkage among the players, the struggle will in the end land
onto some arena that works as a focal point for the general public. This is what
some sociologists would refer to as the symbolic center of society. When the crisis
gets to the center, it is no longer something that has to do with the profane realm of
routine institutional life in which technical arguments are enough to win an argumentative battle. Rather, it becomes something that pertains, and possibly shakes
the values, beliefs, and symbols that identify society as such. It will have entered the
absolute sacred space of identity.
As Alexander has shown, the language and the structures of feelings that underpin democracy are one crucial building block of the center of modern societies. In
the course of a crisis, as a consequence, both the organization and its challengers
will have an incentive to recast the vocabulary of technical reason within the structures of meaning making up the codes of liberty and repression that constitute the
center. Since in some societies, however, other discourses of political legitimation,
based on alternative structures of meaning, contend the definition of the center, it
is possible that, in the battle for legitimacy, the organization and its opponents will
adopt different vocabularies. In this case, their confrontation may occasionally lead
to a tragicomedy of errors.
If the center of society is the relevant horizon within which the struggle for
organizational legitimacy is embedded, then the codes that constitute the center
will need to be considered in order to account for the full meaning of the organization’s announcements. This pushes the analysis further with respect to the reach of
impression-management studies, but it also does so with respect to the cultural
institutionalism Parsons supported, which in turn focused exclusively on norms
and values and left out other important elements that make up the cultural environment of action (Alexander 1988a).
Such a conclusion may also contribute to sharpen up the neo-institutionalist
argument on rationality as a legitimizing myth (Meyers and Rowan 1977). When
0001316365.INDD 135
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
136
the economic as culture
organizations appeal to the rationality of their procedures as a legitimacy title, the
meaning of such a rationality crucially depends on the horizon of interpretation
within which one reads it and on the resolution of the lenses with which one looks at
it. It can be pure and simple technical rationality. Or it can alternatively be technical
rationality turned into a transcendent cultural logic that contributes to the composition of the sacred center of society. In this case, it may work as a myth. At the center,
though, rationality turned into a transcendent cultural logic may be embedded
within the different structures of meanings that can make up the center. For example,
it may be part of the codes of liberty and repression that concurs to constitute the
symbolic core of modern democratic societies. For this reason, the horizon of analysis a cultural sociology of the economy takes as reference can help sharpen up the
neoinstitutionalist understanding of rationality as a legitimizing myth.
In conclusion, nowadays private corporations have been hit by scandals of corruption, political irresponsibility, and greed. As they come under attack, public
debate over their misbehavior will increasingly follow the cultural logic of the discourse of civil society that contributes to makeup the symbolic core of modern
democratic societies and, occasionally, the logic of alternative discourses of political
legitimation that may contend the control of the symbolic center of such societies.
The battle over organizational legitimacy, in other words, will no longer be fought
in terms of technical rationality but rather in terms of civic virtues and civic vices.
Also, the battle may well stretch across multiple institutional arenas—mass media,
legal, scientific, political-bureaucratic, aesthetic, and religious. Cultural sociologists
are well equipped to show in what way, along the battle over their own legitimacy,
private corporations may strive to translate their interests by resorting to the cultural codes that structure the symbolic center of their own societies in an effort to
maintain, recover, or repair their own legitimacy.
After hinting at the way a cultural sociology of the economy may contribute to
address one pragmatic problem that is looming at the horizon of the current world
economic crisis—the loss of public confidence into private corporations—I will
now discuss how cultural sociologists may help shed light over the mechanisms that
influence public confidence into the community of economists. To do so, I will first
draw from the sociology of finance literature that has emerged over the last decade
and show in what way a cultural sociology of the economy can complement it.
During the last decade, a new literature has emerged—the sociology of financial markets—that has built on economic sociology and anthropology on the one
hand and the social studies of science on the other. As Beunza, Hardie, and Mackenzie
(2006) have recently pointed out, the new field does with trading floors what the
social studies of science has previously done with laboratories. In other words, it
approaches financial markets as “heterogeneous assemblages of human beings and
technical devices, devoted to the production of workable knowledge” (p. 39) and
seeks to recover their materiality, which, following Mackenzie (2007, p. 357), is not
just about physicality but rather about physical objects, technological systems,
human bodies, legal systems, cultures, procedures, beliefs, and social relations
expressed by objects and bodies.
0001316365.INDD 136
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
culture and the economy
137
With particular reference to culture, the sociology of financial markets has
pushed the analysis far enough to take stock with different forms of it: cultural
scripts, cultural styles, discourses, frames, the influences by fiction literature on economic reality, collective identities, and even the more performative dimensions of
culture that involve emotions and the bodies. More concretely, Mackenzie (2007)
has followed Thrift (2000) and Maurer (2001, 2005) in taking stock with the cultural
geographies of derivatives and has shown that financial markets have their own
internal cultures, follow different cultural scripts, and are characterized by different
styles. For example, he contrasts Chicago’s rough and tumble style with London’s
gentlemanly capitalism and observes how the cultural script that has traditionally
related investment to gambling structures the market of derivatives (Goede 2005).
MacKenzie (2007, p. 368) has also been keen on tracking down the concrete channels through which culture actually impacts economic reality. “ ‘Culture,’ ” he says,
“is . . . not simply ‘the context’ within which derivative trading takes place. Via matters, such as the law of gambling, it shapes and is enmeshed with the detailed
mechanics of this trading.” Yenkey (2007), on his part, has shown how the meaning
of information and transparency in the U.S. securities markets has changed over
time during the twentieth century. Information disclosure, he argues, was earlier
justified as a measure to prevent a corporation from carrying out actions that would
damage the interests of individuals. Later, however, it got grounded by quite a different discourse, that is, the right of investors to gain equal access to profit opportunities. Czarniawska (2005), in turn, has shown how fictional representations of
women in finance may influence the way they are actually perceived in real life and
has referred to Abolafia (1996) for the purpose of acknowledging that social processes can indeed get structured by cultural genres. Hardie and Mackenzie (2006)
have introduced along with Callon (2005) and Callon and Caliskan (2005) the
notion of agencement to capture the idea that agency is not only made up by human
beings “embedded in institutions, conventions, personal relationships” but rather
by human bodies as well as “prostheses, tools, equipment, technical devices, algorithms, etc.” Frames, the authors add, influence such agencement. Preda (2005), on
his part, has drawn from Pollner (2002, p. 231) to conceive investors as an “imagined
community” and has set out to establish what such an imagined community is
about and how it comes about. His analysis of investors has also gone as far as
acknowledging the influence of the literary field on the configuration of the investor. Moral pamphlets, comedies, satire, and visual allegories, for example, played a
role in shaping the figure of the investor during the eighteenth century. Preda’s
analysis has also taken into consideration some of the more performative dimensions of culture such as the mis-en-scene during the eighteenth century of the figure
of the investor in a closed world of alleys and pubs. Hassoun (2005) has further
contributed to address the performative side of culture by tackling the expression of
various types of emotions—sympathy, aggressiveness, admiration, anger, rivalry,
shame, and humiliation—on the trading floors and by shedding light over the categories of indigenous thought, to put it with Mauss ([1906] 1968), that signify such
emotions. Finally, Zaloom (2003, 2004, 2006) has explicitly taken stock with the role
0001316365.INDD 137
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
138
the economic as culture
of the body in financial markets. For example, in her participative ethnography,
Zaloom has reported that training had also to do with training “our bodies to operate as uninterrupted conduits between the dealing room and the online world,
allowing our fingers to become seamless extensions of our economic intentions”
(Caitlin Zaloom in Beunza, Hardie, and Mackenzie 2006, p. 731).
Such an extensive engagement on the part of the sociology of financial markets
with a broad spectrum of cultural phenomena, however, does not make a cultural
sociology of the economy redundant within such a field of inquiry. To see why, it is
useful to address the way the sociology of financial markets deals with the question
of the performativity of economics. Callon’s thesis on the performativity of economics has been one of the shaping forces of the sociology of financial markets.
According to Callon (1998, p. 30) “the economy is embedded not in society but in
economics.” While showing the performative effects economics has on the economic reality of financial markets, sociologists working within this emerging field
of inquiry have been careful to acknowledge that performativity becomes possible
not in a social vacuum but rather as a result of the social embeddedness of economics. Mackenzie and Millo (2003), for example, explicitly show that the performative
effects of economics are not brought about by homines oeconomici but rather by
social agents who are influenced by cultures, moral communities, and places of
political action. The cultural and legal barriers to the creation of financial derivative
markets in the United States in the late 1960s and early 1970s were overcome by
economics. Still, the peculiar culture and social structures of the Chicago markets
influenced the chances that certain economic ideas had to become popular among
traders and shape their activities as a consequence. For this reasons, the performativity of the classic option pricing theory was not “a matter of simple self-fulfilling
prophecy (Merton 1949) or of the discovery of the correct way to price options.
It was a contested, historically contingent outcome” (Mackenzie and Millo 2003,
p. 138). “Economics indeed facilitated the emergence of derivative markets by disembedding derivatives from the pervasive moral framework in which they were
dangerously close to wagers. However, neither economists on their own nor the
unaided persuasive power of economic theory created” the institutions that would
later preside over the organization of the derivative markets in Chicago (Mackenzie
and Millo 2003, p. 139). Mackenzie and Millo (2003) plausibly argue that the justification of derivatives in terms of public interest that a number of prestigious
Princeton economists put forward played an important role to overcome the suspicion the public had felt about derivatives since the 1929 crash. While the authors
seem to take for granted that the general public would believe the opinion of such
economists in that specific case, one cannot do so and expect that the public will
always automatically believe economists and economics in any society and under
any historical circumstances, which is in turn quite crucial to support Callon’s performativity thesis. The growing literature on the public understanding of science
can serve as a platform to reflect on the mechanisms that help ground such belief
(Farr 1993; Gross 1994; Nelkin 1994; Bud 1995; Baurer 1995; Michael 1998; Irwin 2001;
Leggett and Finlay 2001; Valenti 2002; Bates 2005; Cretaz 2006; Wagner 2007).10 Still,
0001316365.INDD 138
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
culture and the economy
139
such literature has not pushed far enough in the analysis of the cultural mediations
that ultimately produce it. A cultural sociology of the economy may therefore come
in to do the job by contributing, with its special sensibility, to the construction of
legitimacy in the public sphere.
Following my argument with reference to private corporations, one might conjecture that linking economics to the codes of liberty and repression at the symbolic
center of democratic societies might work toward legitimizing it before the general
public. Quite interestingly, though, the symbolic transformation that appears to
have legitimized economics so far has pointed to a radically different direction. In
modern western societies, in other words, economics has taken, in the eyes of the
public, the position theology used to occupy before modernity. The theologian of
secularization, Harvey Cox, for example, has drawn the attention to the covert
operation in public discourse over the economy of myths of origin, legends of the
fall, and doctrines of sin and redemption. “The lexicon of The Wall Street Journal
and the business sections of Time and Newsweek,” says Cox (1999, p. 19),“bear a
striking resemblance to Genesis, the Epistle to the Romans, and Saint’s Augustine’s
City of God.” Behind descriptions of market reform, monetary policy, and the convolution of the Dow, he adds, it is possible to make out “pieces of a grand narrative
about the inner meaning of human history, why things had gone wrong, and how
to put them right.” Within the community of economists, McCloskey has denounced
economics as “modernist faith” with its own “Ten Commandments and Golden
Rule,” its “nuns, bishops, and cathedrals,” its “trinity of fact, definition, and holy
value,” its starting as a “crusading faith” and its later hardening “into ceremony” (in
Nelson 2001, p. xx ). Heyne (1996, p. 1) has suggested that “any economist seeking to
understand the world of human interactions with the hope to make them more
effective operates within a theological framework.” Along a similar line, Cramp
(1994, p. 187) has argued that, to understand the economy, one needs the “knowledge of who we are and why we are here,” which is a fundamentally theological
question. And Nelson (1991, 2001) has suggested that economics embodies a hidden
metaphysics that provides a way of ordering, interpreting, and giving meaning to
events, as well as a source of ultimate meaning and purpose for human beings. At
the core of such metaphysics, Nelson continues, there is the belief that scarcity is the
primary cause of pain, suffering, and death, and that by virtue of its inspirational
power, economics can save us from the consequences of scarcity. As Sahlins (2000,
p. 531) puts it, humanity received pain and death as a punishment for Adam’s sin.
“Still, God was merciful. He gave us Economics.” And it is out of such inspirational
power that economists have come to claim their moral ground to exercise today the
authority theologians used to exercise in the past (Nelson 1991, p. 8). And this is
responsible for the ever-expanding role economics and economists have taken up in
modern societies:
An economics devoid of theological significance would be cautious, hesitant,
retiring—a pale imitation as compared with the central role of economic
thinking in the events of the past three centuries. Only a religion, and not a mere
system of ordering practical affairs, could have had such vast power to shape the
0001316365.INDD 139
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
140
the economic as culture
modern era. Even when they intend otherwise, economists who join the
economics profession may become part of the life and ritual of a community
grounded in a powerful secular theology. (Nelson 1994, p. 236)
Mackenzie and Millo (2003) have recently observed that in Malaysia in the late 1990s
and early 2000s the legitimation of derivatives passed by enrolling Islamic jurists rather
than neoclassical economists (Kamali 1997, Maurer 2001). The above-mentioned
cultural horizon within which economics may have become legitimate in Western
societies may suggest that the logic of the two situations is probably not that radically distant from a cultural standpoint.
The logic of the cultural mediations that would appear to legitimize economics
and the community of economists in modern societies would therefore seem to run
counter to the logic supporting the legitimacy of private corporations. The latter,
after all, appear to draw their legitimacy by linking themselves to the codes of liberty
and repression that make up the symbolic center of modern democratic societies,
while the former seem to have done so by undergoing a process of cultural transformation in the public sphere that has established them respectively as a secular theology and as a priesthood. Such a contrast is quite puzzling. Possibly, as a result of the
current world economic crisis and of the possible crisis of confidence the economic
profession may undergo, the discipline may be drawn to gradually tap into an alternative source of legitimacy by appearing less priestly and more democratic. A cultural sociology of the economy can help tackle the differences in legitimation
between private corporations and the community of economists and can shed light
over the possible shifts in the sources of legitimation the community of economists
may experience in the near future.
After hinting at the way a cultural sociology of the economy may contribute to
address another pragmatic problem that is looming at the horizon of the current
world economic crisis—the loss of public confidence into the community of economists—I will now discuss how cultural sociologists may help shed light over the
mechanisms that influence public confidence for independent central banks. To do
so, I will first draw from the sociology of money literature and show in what way a
cultural sociology of the economy can complement it.
Most of the nineteenth- and twentieth-century social theory has stigmatized
the amoral, or even the immoral, dimensions of modern money. Utilitarians, for
example, considered money to be indifferent to nonpecuniary values. Marx, on his
part, regarded money to constitute a reality without any intrinsic meaning (Marx
[1844] 1964, p. 169; [1858–1859] 1973, p. 222; [1867] 1984, p. 96; [1858] 1972, p. 49).11
Weber and Simmel, in turn, saw it as a vehicle of the process of rationalization of
modern social life (Weber [1946] 1971, p. 331; [1922] 1978, p. 86; Simmel [1908] 1950,
p. 412).12 Collins (1979, p. 190) remarks that sociologists have traditionally regarded
money as if it were not a social reality and have dismissed its ritual use as an example of “residual atavism” (Simmel [1900] 1978, p. 441; in Zelizer 1989, p. 345).
In the course of the past two decades, though, a new body of literature—to put
it with Maurer (2006, p. 19)—has turned “away from Western folk theories of
monetary transformation (the root of all evil, the camel through the eye of the
0001316365.INDD 140
7/14/2011 4:26:37 PM
culture and the economy
141
needle . . . ) embodied in influential accounts from Aristotle to Marx, Weber, and
Simmel.” This literature has built on a number of contributions that, within anthropology, psychology, and sociology, have resisted the above-mentioned stereotyped
representations of money. Anthropologists have documented how money is morally
or ritually ranked within primitive societies and have been, as a result, far more sensitive to the fact that money can exist outside the market and can become a nonmarket
medium (Polanyi 1957, pp. 264–266; Bohannan 1959; Dalton 1965; Einzig 1966;
Thomas and Znaniecki [1918–1920] 1958, pp. 164–165; Akin and Robbins 1999; Guyer
1995b; Parry and Bloch 1989; Gamburd 2004; Znoj 1998; Crump 1981, pp. 125–130;
Melitz 1970). Douglas (1967), for example, stressed that money can acquire a social
or sacred character when it is used ritually or to amend status. Economic psychologists, in turn, have challenged the idea of fungibility of money (Lea, Tarpy, and
Webley 1987, pp. 319–342). And within the sociological profession, Simiand (1934)
provided a very rare statement about the extra-economic social basis of money and
the symbolic, sacred, and magical significance it can manifest.
More recently, Belk and Wallendorf (1990, pp. 35–36) have pointed out that the
economic view misses “the more emotional, qualitative meanings of money” and
the way in which affect, norms and values mediate the dealings with it. Following
the psychoanalytic perspective, Belk and Wallendorf (1990, p. 46) agree with Krueger
(1986, p. 3) that “money is probably the most emotionally meaningful object in
contemporary life; only food and sex are its close competitors as common carriers
of such strong and diverse feelings, significances, and strivings.” At the same time,
Belk and Wallendorf (1990, p. 35) have remarked that “contemporary money retains
sacred meanings” and that the crossing by money of the boundary between the
sacred and the profane is regulated even within modern societies through ritual
processes. “Contemporary consumer society,” Belk and Wallendorf (1990, p. 36)
add, “has been characterized as one that often venerates money and imbues it with
meaning. Money is revered, feared, worshipped, and treated with the highest respect.
Money is, in sociological parlance, considered sacred” (Durkheim 1915). These
authors find evidence of the sacredness of money in the sacrifices that are made for
money, in its contaminating character, and in the myth, mystery, and ritual that are
involved in the acquisition and use of it. Their reading echoes a similar reflection by
Desmonde about the sacred dimension of money:
To many of us, money is a mystery, a symbol handled mainly by the priests of
high finance and regarded by us with much of the same reverence and awe as the
primitive feels toward the sacred relics providing magical potency in a tribal
ritual. As if in a higher plane of reality, the symbol seems to operate in an
incomprehensible, mystical way, understood and controllable only by the magic
of brokers, accountants, lawyers, and financiers. . . . Like spellbound savages in the
presence of the holy, we watch in wonder the solemn proceedings, feeling in a
vague, somewhat fearful way that our lives and the happiness of our children are
at the mercy of mysterious forces beyond our control. . . . Apart from the esoteric
rites of high finance, money seems to function in everyday life much like a
miraculous talisman, bringing to us the gratification of almost every conceivable
desire. Wherever we go, if we have money, people hasten to do our bidding, as if
0001316365.INDD 141
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
142
the economic as culture
placed under a magical charm by the presence of these worn-down coins and
soiled pieces of green paper. . . . Like a magical charm, money brings power, which
can be used either for good or bad purposes. (Desmonde 1962, pp. 3–5)13
It is, however, Viviana Zelizer who, in the past two decades, has spearheaded a whole
research program on money that has successfully countered the received wisdom
within sociology about its nature and its functioning in modern societies. Zelizer’s
work (1989, 1994, 1996, 2000, 2005) on the social meaning of money constitutes the
culmination of a decade of research on the relations between market and morals.
Along with Zelizer’s micro-cultural approach to the study of money, though,
particularly in the past decade, a macro-cultural line of research has emerged that
has recognized the role played by money in the consolidation of national space and
in the production and reproduction of citizens within it (Carruthers and Babb 1996,
Gilbert 1999, 2005; Gilbert and Helleiner 1999; Helleiner 1997, 1998, 1999; Hewitt
1994, 1999; Pointon 1998; Foster 1999; Zelizer 1999). Occasionally, this literature has
stressed the transformation of national currencies into national symbols and has
emphasized the highly emotional charge that is attached to them as a result of such
transformation.
A cultural sociology of the economy can build on it and help systematically
account for the consequences that the linkage of a national currency to the symbolic
center of society can have on the legitimation of the independent central bank.
Tognato (2008) provides a clear example in this respect with reference to the Deutsche
Bundesbank. Since World War II, he suggests, two different self-understandings of
the German society have contended the symbolic center of the Federal Republic: the
so-called Holocaust identity and the Wirtschaftswunder identity (Giesen 1998).
The latter appealed to the economic miracle that the Federal Republic experienced
in the 1950s and 1960s both as a medium to expunge the Angst for the recent past
from the conscience of the average German citizen and as a pretext for reclaiming
full sovereignty for the Federal Republic, thereby liberating it from the state of
political submissiveness into which it had been boxed since World War II. Tognato
observes that the experience of the hyperinflation in the early 1920s, the destabilizing effects that monetary chaos had on the Weimar Republic, the subsequent rise to
power of Hitler and the establishment of the Nazi dictatorship, the experience of
World War II, the destruction and humiliation that came with it, and the horrors
that were perpetrated in the concentration camps set the stage for a linkage of the
D-Mark to the Wirtschaftwunder identity. The D-Mark, as a result, turned into “the
national symbol”14, the only one which Germans could be proud of, 15 something
that gave them back their self-esteem after the atrocities of the Nazi regime,16 that
rescued them “from the political, economic, and moral ruins of the war,”17 and
helped “the German Phoenix rise from the ashes of World War II.”18 The D-Mark,
in a way, gave Germans “a piece of identity, even before that the national anthem
and the national flag came.”19 As the D-Mark turned into a national symbol, the
Deutsche Bundesbank became its custodian. And as the D-Mark acquired in
Germany a profound existential value for the person in the street, the Bundesbank
got transformed into an institutional solution to the Angst that the German past
0001316365.INDD 142
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
culture and the economy
143
still produced. The Bundesbank was founded as an economic institution, but in the
course of its history it took up the latent function of an existential device. A a result,
it became absolute (Tognato 2008). Such transformations in meaning reflected the
ongoing anchoring of German monetary affairs to the existential dimension of
the Wirtschaftwunder identity. At the same time, symbolic linkage also applied to the
political dimension of the Wirtschaftswunder identity. In other words, the Bundesbank
turned into the instrument that enabled Germany to exercise its full sovereignty, at
least within the monetary sphere, thereby breaking free from the regime of semisovereignty into which the Federal Republic had been embedded since World War II.
As the Financial Times, for example, put it, the Bundesbank constituted a formidable
“Bundesbunker,” which was impossible to penetrate.20 The reconstitution of German
monetary affairs at the symbolic center of German society triggered a latent moralization of the German monetary arena. Inflation would take up a moral connotation,
and central bankers would therefore be legitimized to ask the public for sacrifices in
order to keep it under check. As money and monetary policy acquired moral meaning, then the central bank would also undergo a transformation and turn into the
moral compass of a society, as David Horowitz, former President of the Bank of
Israel, once put it. Its authority would no longer be strictly technical. As some observers have remarked with reference to the Bundesbank, its authority “stems from moral
prowess as well as economic muscle.”21 Tognato (2008) shows that once the German
monetary game got to the symbolic center of society and underwent a process of
moralization, narrative frames drawn from the Christian tradition come into play
and prevented it from losing its moral dimension. For example, the conquest of the
moral ground that monetary stability can secure became framed as a perpetual challenge that never ends and that calls for a continuous struggle (Tietmeyer 1997).
Following Tognato (2008), it would appear that the legitimacy of the most
beloved independent central bank in the world did not stem from a symbolic linkage to the codes of liberty and repression that make up the symbolic center of modern societies, but rather correlated to a different set of cultural elements that make
up German political culture and appear to constitute an important dimension of
the German symbolic center. Kennedy (1991, p. 4) has observed that “in many
respects the Bundesbank incorporates the ideals of an earlier age of political development. Largely immune to the pressures of pluralistic politics, it sees itself as the
representative of a good higher than particular interests.” Such an ethos, she continues, is not just a technique or a policy style. Rather, it is rooted to the ideal of
Rechtstaat and the German political theory that has traditionally attributed special
dignity to the instruments of the state that are supposed to enhance the public good
over particularistic interests (Kennedy 1991, pp. 2–3, 10–12). Furthermore, it rests on
a civil service tradition that, since Hegel, has elevated German civil servants to the
rank of a “universal class” that stands for the ethical interest of the whole. In May
1945, she continues, the Constitutional Court ruled for the so-called Traditionsbruch,
according to which public officials would no longer serve the state as a living and
permanent continuity but would rather serve the constitutional order” (Smith 1979,
p. 68–69; in Kennedy 1991, p. 12). Despite such a break, however, the Bundesbank
0001316365.INDD 143
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
144
the economic as culture
and the Constitutional Court have probably continued to constitute the only two
institutional spheres in which the old tradition of German civil service has survived
(Kennedy 1991, p. 28).
As the world economic crisis deepens, one must therefore wonder what deep
sources of legitimacy independent central banks around the world will be able to
draw on in order to resist the consequences of an increasing skepticism on the part
of the public about the maintenance of an institutional task—the control of inflation—that will appear as going out of fashion. A cultural sociology of the economy
may help shed light in this respect.
I have begun this section by indicating three possible fields of application of a
cultural sociology of the economy. I have suggested that, as the ongoing world economic crisis deepens, private corporations, economists, and independent central
banks may run the risk of losing people’s confidence. As a result, it becomes imperative to understand the mechanisms that underpin its creation, maintenance, and
repair. A cultural sociology of the economy can contribute in this respect by enhancing our understanding of the deep sources of legitimacy of economic institutions in
modern societies. To make my point, I have built on three different literatures—that
on organizational legitimacy, the emerging sociology of financial markets, and the
sociology of money.
Conclusion
Many believe that the economy constitutes one of the most disenchanted spheres of
modern social life. Norms and values but also cultural codes, metaphors, rituals,
and identities, however, still shape economic experience in our days. A cultural sociology of the economy is there to remind us of this.
Different classics provide a fertile ground from which such sociology can draw
for the purpose of nurturing its intellectual project. The later Durkheim of The
Elementary Forms of Religious Life, Weber, Parsons, Polanyi, and Alexandre de
Toqueville constitute important referents in this respect.
While economists have just recently started to take stock of culture, during the
past three decades, a culturalist strand of scholarship within economic sociology
has insisted on the persisting role of culture in modern economic life. Karin Knorr
Cetina, Mitchel Abolafia, Nicole Biggart, and Viviana Zelizer are the four most
accomplished contributors to this line of research.
The debate among economic sociologists over the opportunity to introduce
cultural analysis within their horizon of inquiry has traditionally focused on the
question of whether cultural analysis should replace social-structural analysis or
whether it should complement it. The narrow focus of such a debate has prevented
the profession from systematically discussing how scholars should go about accounting for the cultural dimension of economic life. Should they take a cultural-structural
0001316365.INDD 144
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
culture and the economy
145
approach? Or should they rather adopt a pragmatic focus? Or should they instead
resort to a framework that integrates both perspectives? Furthermore, taking stock
with the role of culture in the economy implies addressing the phenomenon of
cultural embeddedness of economic action. So, how far should scholars push the
analysis of such a phenomenon? And where should they draw the line? These are
the basic theoretical questions that structure the core of a cultural sociology of the
economy. I have argued that the emerging field of neo-Durkheimian sociology,
which in the past two decades has systematically addressed the phenomenon of
cultural reenchantment in modern societies, can provide one possible set of answers
to such questions. Answering them, I have suggested, helps distinguish the inner
theoretical makeup of a cultural sociology of the economy from the culturalist
strand of scholarship within economic sociology.
I have then concluded that, from a pragmatic standpoint, a cultural sociology
of the economy can help tackle three of the most pressing problems that loom on
the horizon of the current world economic crisis: the loss of confidence within the
general public for private corporations, the economic profession, and independent
central banks. And more precisely, it can do so by shedding light over the mechanisms by which such confidence can be maintained, recovered, or repaired. To make
this point, I have shown how cultural sociologists can help advance the analysis in
this respect further beyond the frontier of three relevant literatures—that on organizational legitimacy, the sociology of financial markets, and the sociology of money.
NOTES
1. See for example Marx ([1844] 1964), Maine (1875), Tönnies ([1887] 1955), Durkheim
([1893] 1947), Weber ([1904] 1998), Simmel ([1900] 1978), Habermas (1984).
2. “No sense in strict 3% deficit as the magic figure for Emu. Letters to the Editor,” The
Financial Times, June 3, 1997, USA Edition, p. 12.
3. Otmar Issing, “Wider die Papiergaunerreien,” Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, April
6, 1996, p. 17.
4. “O Isis and Osiris, give/the spirit of Wisdom to the new pair./Guide the steps of the
wanderers./Strengthen them with patience in danger” (Tietmeyer 1997b, p. 11).
5. Toqueville ([1835–40] 2000, p. 511) stresses that people “dream constantly of the
goods they do not have.” In Swedberg (2004, p. 8).
6. See also Zelizer (2007, p. 1060).
7. The analysis of such cultural linkages may entail tracking the metaphoric transformations of economic phenomena that help catapult them onto the center, the narrative
strategies actors resort to, the specific genres they tap into, and even the visual representations they draw from. With particular reference to the latter, Emmison (1986) offers an
interesting example.
8. See DiMaggio (1994, p. 39; 1990, pp. 117–119) and Davis (1996, pp. 213–226) in
Spillman (1999, p. 1061).
9. See also Scott (2001) and Aldrich (2001).
0001316365.INDD 145
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
146
the economic as culture
10. See also the entire first volume of Public Understanding of Science (1992).
11. In Zelizer (1989, pp. 345–346).
12. In Zelizer (1989, pp. 344–346).
13. See also Crump (1992, pp. 669–677).
14. Jordan Bonfante, “A German Requiem,” Time Magazine, July 6, 1998, p. 21.
15. Ibidem.
16. Susanne Nicolette Strass, “Abschied vom einem stark Stück Deutschland,”
Frankfurter Neue Press, June 20, 1998.
17. Jan Fleischhauer, “Der Erzbischof aus Frankfurt,” Der Spiegel, Nr. 23, 1997.
18. Bonfante, “A German Requiem.”
19. “Die DM hat den Deutschen ein Stück Identität gegeben,” Süddeutsche Zeitung,
June 22, 1998; Kohl Helmut Kohl, “50 Jahre Deutsche Mark,” Presse- und Informationsamt
der Bundesregierung, July 7, 1998, Nr. 49, p. 632.
20. “In the Bundesbunker,” Financial Times, July 17, 1992, p. 18.
21. D. Marsh, P. Norman, Q. Peel, and C. Parkes, “Tietmeyer: high-priest of hard
money doctrine,” The Financial Times, October 1, 1993.
REFERENCES
Abolafia, Mitchel. 1996. Making Markets: Opportunism and Restraint on Wall Street.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Agnew, Jean-Christophe. 1986. Worlds Apart in Anglo-American Thought, 12550–1750.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Akin, David, and Joel Robbins. 1999. Money and Modernity. State and Local Currencies in
Melanesia. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Aldrich, Howard. 2001. Organizations Evolving. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Alexander, Jeffrey. 1988a. Action and Its Environments. New York: Columbia University Press.
——— . 1988b. “Religious Sociology and Cultural Sociology.” Pp. 1–21 in Durkheimian
Sociology: Cultural Studies, edited by Jeffrey Alexander. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
——— . 2006. The Civil Sphere. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Alexander, Jeffrey, and Philip Smith. 1993. “The Discourse of American Civil Society:
A New Proposal for Cultural Studies.” Theory and Society 22(2): 151–207.
Anderson, Benedict. 1991. Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origin and Spread of
Nationalism. Rev. ed. London and New York: Verso.
Appadurai, Arjun. 1986. “Introduction: Commodities and the Politics of Value.” Pp. 3–63 in
The Social Life of Things: Commodities in Cultural Perspective, edited by Arjun
Appadurai. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Ashforth, Blake, and Barrie Gibbs. 1990. “The Double-Edge of Organizational
Legitimation.” Organization Science 1: 177–194.
Baiocchi, Gianpaolo. 2006. “The Civilizing Forces of Social Movements: Corporate and
Liberal Codes in Brazil’s Public Sphere.” Sociological Theory 24(4): 285–311.
Baker, Wayne. 1984. “The Social Structure of a National Securities Market.” American
Journal of Sociology 89: 775–811.
Baker, Wayne, and Robert Faulkner. 1991. “Role as Resource in the Hollywood Film
Industry.” American Journal of Sociology 97: 279–309.
0001316365.INDD 146
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
culture and the economy
147
Banfield, Edward. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. New York: Free Press.
Barron, James, Frank Dobbin, and P. Devreaux Jennings. 1986. “War and Peace: The
Evolution of Modern Personnel Administration in US Industry.” American Journal of
Sociology 92: 350–383.
Bates, Benjamin. 2005. “Public Culture and Public Understanding of Genetics: A Focus
Group Study.” Public Understanding of Science 14: 47–65.
Baum, Joel, and Walter Powell. 1995. “Cultivating an Institutional Ecology of
Organizations.” American Sociological Review 60: 529–538.
Baurer, Martin. 1995. “Familiarizing the Unfamiliar.” Public Understanding of Science
4: 205–210.
Belk, Russell, and Melanie Wallendorf. 1990. “The Sacred Meaning of Money.” Journal of
Economic Psychology 11: 35–67.
Berger, Peter and Thomas Luckmann. 1966. The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise in
the Sociology of Knowledge. London: Penguin.
Bettman, James, and Barton Weitz. 1983. “Attributions in the Board Room: Causal
Reasoning in Corporate Annual Reports.” Administrative Science Quarterly 28: 165–183.
Beunza, Daniel, Iain Hardie, and Donald Mackenzie. 2006. “A Price Is a Social Thing:
Towards a Material Sociology of Arbitrage.” Organization Studies 27: 721–734.
Biernacki, Richard. 1995. The Fabrication of Labor: Germany and Britain, 1640–1914.
Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Biggart, Nicole Woolsey. 1989. Charismatic Capitalism. Direct Selling Organizations in
America. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.
Bohannan, Paul. 1959. “The Impact of Money on an African Subsistence Economy.” Journal
of Economic History 19: 491–503.
Boulton, David. 1978. The Grease Machine. New York: Harper & Row.
Bromiley, Philip, and Alfred Marcus. 1989. “The Deterrent to Dubious Corporate Behavior:
Profitability, Probability and Safety Recalls.” Strategic Management Journal 10: 233–250.
Buchholz, Rogene, William Evans, and Robert Wagley. 1985. Management Responses to Public
Issues: Concept and Cases in Strategy Formulation. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Bud, Robert. 1995. “Science, Meaning and Myth in the Museum.” Public Understanding of
Science 4: 1–16.
Burt, Ronald. 1983. Corporate Profits and Cooptation. New York: Academic Press.
Callon, Michel, and Koray Caliskan. 2005. “New and Old Directions in the Anthropology
of Markets.” Paper presented to the Wenner-Grenn Foundation for Anthropological
Research, New York, April 9.
Callon, Michel, ed. 1998. The Laws of the Markets. Oxford: Blackwell.
Callon, Michel. 2005. “Why Virtualism Paves the Way to Political Impotence: A Reply to
Daniel Miller’s Critique of The Law of the Markets.” Economic Sociology: European
Electronic Newsletter 6(2): 3–20.
——— . 2007. “What Does It Mean to Say That Economics Is Performative?” Pp. 311–357 in
Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics, edited by Donald
MacKenzie, Fabian Munesa, and Lucia Siu. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Carroll, Glenn, and Michael Hannan. 2000. The Demography of Corporations and
Industries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Carruthers, Bruce. 1996. City of Capital: Politics and Markets in the English Financial
Revolution. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Carruthers, Bruce, and Sarah Babb. 1996. “The Color of Money and the Nature of Value:
Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America.” American Journal of Sociology
101(6): 1556–1591.
0001316365.INDD 147
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
148
the economic as culture
——— . 2000. Economy/Society. Markets, Meanings, and Social Structure. Thousand Oaks,
CA: Pine Forge Press.
Carruthers, Bruce, and Wendy Espeland. 1997. “The Price is Right: On Money and
Morality.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Sociological
Association, Toronto.
Collins, Randall. 1979. “Review of The Bankers, by Martin Mayer.” American Journal of
Sociology 85: 190–194.
Cox, Harvey. 1999. “The Market as God: Living with the New Dispensation.” Atlantic
Monthly 283(3): 18–23.(March).
Cramp, A. B., 1994. “Mapping of (Economic) Meaning: Here Be Monsters.” In Economics
and Religion, edited by H. Geoffrey Brennan and A. M. C. Waterman. Boston: Kluwer.
Cretaz, Fabienne von Roten. 2006. “Do We Need a Public Understanding of Statistics?”
Public Understanding of Science 15: 243–249.
Crump, Thomas. 1981. The Phenomenon of Money. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
——— . 1992. “Money as a Ritual System.” American Bahavioral Scientist 35 (6): 669–677.
Czarniawska, Barbara. 2005. “Women in Financial Services: Fiction and More Fiction”
Pp. 121–137 in The Sociology of Financial Markets, edited by Karin Knorr Cetina and
Alex Preda. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Dalton, George. 1965. “Primitive Money.” American Anthropologist 61(1): 44–65.
Davidson, Wallace, and Dan Worrell. 1988. “The Impact of Announcements of Corporate
Illegalities on Shareholders Returns.” Academy of Management Journal 31: 195–200.
Davidson, Wallace, P. Chandy, and Mark Cross. 1987. “Large Losses, Risk Management and
Stock Returns in the Airline Industry.” Journal of Risk and Insurance 57: 162–172.
Davis, John. 1996. “An Anthropologist’s View of Exchange.” Social Anthropology 4: 213–226.
Desmonde, William. 1962. Magic, Myth, and Money. New York: Free Press of Glencoe.
DiMaggio, Paul. 1990. “Cultural Aspects of Economic Action and Organization.” Pp. 113–136
in Beyond the Marketplace: Rethinking Economy and Society, edited by Roger Friedland
and A. F. Robertson. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.
——— . 1994. “Culture and the Economy.” Pp. 22–57 in The Handbook of Economic
Sociology, edited by Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
DiMaggio, Paul, and Walter Powell. 1983. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional
Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organization Fields.” American Sociological
Review 48: 147–160.
Dobbin, Frank. 1994. Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the
Railway Age. Cambridge, UK, and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Douglas, Mary. 1967. “Primitive Rationing.” Pp. 119–145 in Themes in Economic
Anthropology, edited by Raymond Firth. London: Tavistock.
Douglas, Mary, and Baron Isherwood. 1979. The World of Goods. Towards an Anthropology
of Consumption. New York: Basic Books.
Dowling, John, and Jeffrey Pfeffer. 1975. “Organizational Legitimacy: Social Values and
Organizational Behavior.” Pacific Sociological Review 18: 122–136.
Durkheim, Emile. [1893] 1947. The Division of Labour in Society. Trans. by George Simpson.
Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
——— . 1951. Suicide. New York: Free Press.
——— . 1957. Professional Ethics and Civic Morals. London: Routledge.
——— . [1915] 1995. The Elementary Forms of Religious Life. Trans. by Karen Fields. New
York: Free Press.
Einzig, Paul. 1966. Primitive Money. Oxford: Pergamon.
0001316365.INDD 148
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
culture and the economy
149
Elsbach, Kimberly. 1994. “Managing Organizational Legitimacy in the California Cattle
Industry. The Construction and Effectiveness of Verbal Accounts.” Administrative
Science Quarterly 39(1): 57–88.
Elsbach, Kimberly, and Robert Sutton. 1992. “Acquiring Organizational Legitimacy through
Illegitimate Actions: A Marriage of Institutional and Impression Management
Theories.” Academy of Management Journal 35(4): 699–738.
——— . 1998. “Averting Expected Challenges through Anticipatory Impression
Management: A Study of Hospital Billing.” Organization Science 9: 68–86.
Emmison, Michael. 1986. “Visualizing the Economy: Fetishism and the Legitimation of
Economic Life.” Theory, Culture & Society 3: 81–96.
Farr, Robert. 1993. “Common Sense, Science and Social Representations.” Public
Understanding of Science 2: 189–204.
Fields, Andrew, and Vahan Janjigian. 1989. “The Effect of Chernobyl on Electric-Utility
Stock Prices.” Journal of Business Research 18: 81–88.
Fisse, Brent, and John Braithwaite. 1983. The Impact of Publicity on Corporate Offenders.
Albany: State University of New York Press.
Fligstein, Neil. 1996. “Markets as Politics: A Political-Cultural Approach to Market
Institutions.” American Sociological Review 61: 656–673.
Foster, Robert. 1999. “In God We Trust. The Legitimacy of Melanesian Currencies.”
Pp. 214–231 in Money and Modernity: State and Local Currencies in Melanesia, edited by
David Atkins and Joel Robbins. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Franklin, Roger. 1986. The Defender: The Story of General Dynamics. New York: Harper & Row.
Frenzen, Jonathan, Paul Hirsch, and Philip Zerillo. 1994. “Consumption, Preferences, and
Changing Lifestyles.” Pp. 403–425 in The Handbook of Economic Sociology, edited by
Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Fukuyama, Francis. 1995. Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New York:
Free Press.
——— . 2003. “Still Disenchanted? The Modernity of Postindustrial Capitalism.” CSES
Working Paper Series #3, Department of Sociology, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.
Gamburd, Michelle. 2004. “Money That Burns Like Oil: A Sri Lankan Cultural Logic of
Morality and Agency.” Ethnology 43(2): 167–184.
Geertz, Clifford. 1973. The Interpretation of Cultures. New York: Basic Books.
Giacalone, Robert, and Paul Rosenfeld, eds. 1989. Impression Management in the
Organization. Hillsdale, NJ.: Erlbaum.
——— . 1991. Applied Impression Management. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.
Giesen, Bernhard. 1998. Intellectuals and the Nation: Collective identity in a German Axial
age. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Gilbert, Emily. 1999. “Forging a National Currency: Money, State-Making and NationBuilding in Canada.” Pp. 25–46 in Nation-States and Money: The Past, the Present and
the Future of National Currencies, edited by Emily Gilbert and Eric Helleiner.
London: Routledge.
——— . 2005. “Common Cents: Situating Money in Time and Space.” Economy and Society
34(3): 357–388.
Gilbert, Emily, and Eric Helleiner, eds. 1999. Nation-States and Money: The Past, the Present
and the Future of National Currencies. London: Routledge.
Godson, John. 1975. The Rise and Fall of the DC-10. New York: David Mckay.
Goede, Marieke de. 2005. Virtue, Fortune and Faith: A Genealogy of Finance. Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press.
Goffman, Ervin. 1961. Encounters. Indianapolis, IN: Bobbs Merrill.
0001316365.INDD 149
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
150
the economic as culture
——— . 1963. Stigma: Notes on the Management of Spoiled Identity. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice-Hall.
——— . 1967. Interaction Ritual: Essays on Face-to-Face Behavior. Garden City, NY:
Doubleday/Anchor.
——— . 1969. Strategic Interaction. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
——— . 1973. The Presentation of Self in Everyday Life. Woodstock, NY: Overlook Press.
——— . 1974. Frame Analysis. New York: Harper Colophon.
——— . 1981. Forms of Talk. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Goodpaster, Kenneth. 1984. Ethics in Management. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School.
Granovetter, Mark. 1974. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Granovetter, Mark. 1985. “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of
Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91(3): 481–510.
——— . 1990a. “Interview.” Pp. 96–114 in Economies and Sociology: Redefining Their
Boundaries, edited by Richard Swedberg. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
——— . 1990b. “The Old and the New Economic Sociology: A History and an Agenda.”
Pp. 89–112 in Beyond the Market Place: Rethinking Economy and Society, edited by
Roger Friedland and A. F. Robertson, New York: Aldine de Gruyter.
Gross, Alan. 1994. “The Roles of Rhetoric in the Public Understanding of Science.” Public
Understanding of Science 3: 3–23.
Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2006. “Does Culture Affect Economic
Outcomes?” Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2): 23–48.
Guyer, Jane, ed. 1995. Money Matters: Instability, Values and Social Payments in the Modern
History of West African Communities. Portsmouth, NH: Heinemann.
Habermas, Jürgen, 1984. The Theory of Communicative Action, Vol. 1—Reason and the
Rationalization of Society. Boston: Beacon.
Hannan, Michael, and John Freeman. 1992. The Dynamics of Organizational Populations.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Hardie, Iain, and Donald Mackenzie. 2006. “Assembling an Economic Actor: The
Agencement of a Hedge Fund.” Paper presented at the New Aspects in a Financialized
Economy and Implications for Varieties of Capitalism Workshop, Institute of
Commonwealth Studies, London, May 11–12.
Hassoun, Jean-Pierre. 2005. “Emotions on the Trading Floor: Social and Symbolic
Expressions.” Pp. 102–120 in The Sociology of Financial Markets, edited by Karin Knorr
Cetina and Alex Preda. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Helleiner, Eric. 1997. “One Nation, One Money. Territorial Currencies and the Nation-State.”
Working Paper 17. Oslo, Norway: Arena.
——— . 1998. “National Currencies and National Identities.” American Behavioral Scientist
41: 1409–1436.
——— . 1999. “Historicizing Territorial Currencies: Monetary Space and the Nation-State
in North America.” Political Geography 18: 309–339.
——— . 2002. “One Money, One People. Political Identity and the Euro.” Pp. 183–202 in
Before and Beyond EMU, edited by Patrick Crowley. London: Routledge.
Hewitt, Virginia. 1994. Beauty and the Banknote: Images of Women on Paper Money.
London: British Museum Press.
——— . 1999. “A Distant View. Imagery and Imagination in the Paper Currency of the
British Empire, 1800–1960.” Pp. 97–116 in Nation-States and Money: The Past, the
Present and the Future of National Currencies, edited by Emily Gilbert and Eric
Helleiner. London: Routledge.
0001316365.INDD 150
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
culture and the economy
151
Heyne, Paul. 1996. “Theological Visions in Economics and Religion.” Forum for Social
Economics 25(2): 1–7.
Hörisch, Jochem. 2004. Gott, Geld, Medien. Frankfurt am main: Suhrkamp Verlag.
Irwin, Alan. 2001. “Constructing the Scientific Citizen: Science and Democracy in the
Biosciences.” Public Understanding of Science 10: 1–18.
Issing, Otmar. 1991. “Geldpolitik im Spannungsfeld von Politik und Wissenschaft.” Speech
delivered at the Scientific Colloquium in occasion of the 65th Birthday of Prof. Dr.
Dr. h.c. Norbert Kloten, Stuttgart, March 15.
Jones, Edvard, et al. 1984. Social Stigma: The Psychology of Marked Relationships. New York:
WHO.
Kamali, Mohammed. 1997. “Islamic Commercial Law: An Analysis of Options.” American
Journal of Islamic Social Science 14: 17–37.
Kemeny, John. 1979. The Need for Change: The Legacy of TMI. Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office.
Kennedy, Ellen. 1991. The Bundesbank: Germany’s Central Bank in the International
Monetary System. London: Pinter.
Knack, Stephen, and Philip Keefer. 1996. “Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff?
A Cross-Country Investigation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 1251–1288.
Knorr Cetina, Karin. 2005. “How Are Global Markets Global? The Architecture of a Flow
World.” Pp. 38–61 in The Sociology of Financial Markets, edited by Karin Knorr Cetina
and Alex Preda. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Knorr Cetina, Karin, and Urs Bruegger. 2000. “The Market as an Object of Attachment:
Exploring Postsocial Relations in Financial Markets.” Canadian Journal of Sociology
25(2): 141–168.
——— . 2002. “Global Microstructures: The Virtual Societies of Financial Markets.”
American Journal of Sociology 107(4): 905–950.
Kohl, Helmut. “50 Jahre Deutsche Mark.” Speech by the Federal Chancellor. Presse- und
Informationsamt der Bundesregierung, 07/07/1998, Nr. 49.
Krippner, Greta. 2001. “The Elusive Market: Embeddedness and the Paradigm of Economic
Sociology.” American Journal of Sociology 30(6): 775–810.
Krueger, David. 1986. “Money, Success, and Success Phobia.” Pp. 3–16 in The Last Taboo:
Money as a Symbol and Reality in Psychotherapy and Psychoanalysis, edited by David
Krueger. New York: Brunner & Masel.
Landes, David. 1993. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations. New York: Norton.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1997.
“Trust in Large Organizations.” American Economic Review 87(2): 222–279.
Lea, Stephen, Roger Tarpy, and Paul Webley. 1987. The Individual in the Economy: A Survey
of Economic Psychology. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Leary, Mark, and Robin Kowalski. 1990. “Impression Management: A Literature Review
and Two Component Model.” Psychological Bulletin 107: 34–47.
Leggett, Monica, and Marie Finlay. 2001. “Science, Story, and Image: A New Approach to
Crossing the Communication Barrier Posed by Scientific Jargon.” Public
Understanding of Science 10: 157–171.
Lie, John. 1991. “Embedding Polanyi’s Market Society.” Sociological Perspectives 34(2): 219–235.
——— . 1997. “Sociology of Markets.” Annual Review of Sociology 23: 341–360.
Litschert, Robert, and Edward Nicholson. 1977. The Corporate Role and Ethical Behavior.
New York: Petrocelli/Charter.
MacKenzie, Donald. 2003. “An Equation and Its World: Bricolage, Exemplars, Disunity and
Performativity in Financial Economics.” Social Studies of Science 33: 831–868.
0001316365.INDD 151
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
152
the economic as culture
——— . 2007. “The Material Production of Virtuality: Innovation, Cultural Geography,
and Facticity in Derivative Markets.” Economy and Society 36(3): 355–376.
MacKenzie, Donald, and Yuval Millo. 2003. “Constructing a Market, Performing Theory:
The Historical Sociology of a Financial Derivatives Exchange.” American Journal of
Sociology 109(1): 107–145.
Maine, Henry. 1875. Lectures on the Early History of Institutions. London: J. Murray.
Marcus, Alfred, and Robert Goodman. 1991. “Victims and Shareholders: The Dilemmas of
Presenting Corporate Policy During a Crisis.” Academy of Management Journal 31(29):
281–305.
Martin, Christine. 2004. “Vernichtetes Geld und vernichtendes Geld: Das Geldmotiv in den
zwei zeitgenoessischen Romanen ‘Die Nacht der Haendler’ von Gert Heidenreich und
‘MOI’ von Heiko Michael Hartmann.” Master Thesis, Department of German and
Slavic Studies, University of Waterloo.
Marx, Karl. [1844] 1964. “The Power of Money in Bourgeois Society.” In The Economic and
Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844. New York: International.
——— . [1858] 1972. A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy, edited by Maurice
Dobb. New York: International.
——— . [1858–1859] 1973. Grundrisse. New York: Vintage.
——— . [1867] 1984. Capital. Vol. 1, edited by Friedrich Engels. New York: International.
Maurer, Bill. 2001. “Engineering an Islamic Future: Speculations on Islamic Financial
Alternatives.” Anthropology Today 17(1): 8–11.
——— . 2005. Mutual Life, Limited: Islamic Banking, Alternative Currencies, Lateral Reason.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
——— . 2006. “The Anthropology of Money.” Annual Review of Anthropology 35: 15–36.
Maurer, John. 1971. Readings in Organizational Theory: Open System Approaches. New York:
Random House.
Mauss, Marcel. [1906] 1968. “Introducción a la Analyse de Quelques Phénomène Religieux.”
In Oevres, edited by V. Karady and M. Mauss. Paris: Minuit.
McCloskey, Deirdre. 1985. The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin
Press.
Melitz, Jacques. 1970. “The Polanyi School of Anthropology on Money: An Economist’s
View.” American Anthropologist 72: 1020–1040.
Merton, Robert. 1949. “The Self-Fulfilling Prophecy.” Pp. 179–195 in Social Theory and Social
Structure, by Robert Merton. New York: Free Press.
Metzler, Maribeth. 2001. “Responding to the Legitimacy Problem of Big Tobacco: An
Analysis of the ‘People of Philip Morris’ Image Advertising Campaign.”
Communication Quarterly 49: 366–381.
Meyer, John, and Brian Rowan. 1977. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as
Myth and Ceremony.” American Journal of Sociology 83: 340–362.
Meyer, John, and Richard Scott. 1983. Organizational Environments: Rituals and Rationality.
Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.
Michael, Mike. 1998. “Between Citizen and Consumer: Multiplying the Meanings of the
‘Public Understanding of Science.’” Public Understanding of Science 7: 313–327.
Miller, Daniel. 1987. Material Culture and Mass Consumption. Oxford: Blackwell.
Nash, Keir, Dean Mann, and Phil Olsen. 1972. Oil Pollution and the Public Interest:
A Study of the Santa Barbara Oil Spill. Berkeley: Institute of Government Studies,
University of California.
Nee, Victor, and Paul Ingram. 1998. “Embeddedness and Beyond: Institutions, Exchange
and Social Structure.” Pp. 19–45 in The New Institutionalism in Sociology, edited by
Mary Brinton and Victor Nee. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
0001316365.INDD 152
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
culture and the economy
153
Nelkin, Dorothy. 1994. “Promotional Metaphors and Their Popular Appeal.” Public
Understanding of Science 3: 25–31.
Nelson, Robert H. 1991. Reaching for Heaven on Earth; The Theological Meaning of
Economics. Lanham, MD.: Rowan & Littlefield.
——— . 1994. “Economics as Religion.” In Economics and Religion, edited by H. Geoffrey
Brennan and A. M. C. Waterman. Boston: Kluwer.
——— . 2001. Economics as Religion: From Samuelson to Chicago and Beyond. University
Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.
——— . 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge,
UK, and New York: Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass. 1994. “Economic Performance through Time.” American Economic Review
84: 359–367.
Page, Robert. 1984. Stigma. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Parry, Jonathan, and Maurice Bloch, eds. 1989. Money and the Morality of Exchange.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Parsons, Talcott, and Neil J. Smelser. 1956. Economy and Society. New York: Free Press.
Perrow, Charles. 1984. Normal Accidents: Living with High-Risk Technologies. New York:
Basic Books.
Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1981. “Management as Symbolic Action: The Creation and Maintenance of
Organizational Paradigms.” Pp. 1–52 in Research in Organizational Behavior, edited by
Larry Cummings and Barry Staw. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Pfeffer, Jeffrey, and Gerald Salancik. 1978. The External Control of Organizations. Stanford,
CA: Stanford Business Books.
Podolny, Joel. 1993. “A Status-Based Model of Market Competition.” American Journal of
Sociology 98: 829–872.
Pointon, Marcia. 1998. “Money and Nationalism.” Pp. 229–254 in Imagining Nations, edited
by Geoffrey Cubitt. Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press.
Polanyi, Karl. [1944] 1957. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origin of
Our Times. Boston: Beacon Press.
——— . [1957] 1971. “The Economy as Instituted Process.” Pp. 139–174 in Primitive, Archaic
and Modern Economies, edited by George Dalton. Boston: Beacon Press.
Polanyi, Karl, Conrad Arensberg, and Harry Pearson. [1957] 1971. “The Place of Economies
in Society.” Pp. 239–242 in Trade and Market in the Early Empires, edited by Karl
Polanyi, Conrad Arensberg, and Harry Pearson. Chicago: Henry Regnery.
Pollner, Melvin. 2002. “Inside the Bubble: Communion, Cognition and Deep Play at the
Intersection of Wall Street and Cyberspace.” Pp. 230–246 in Virtual Society? Technology,
Cyberbole, Reality, edited by Steve Woolgar. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Post, James. 1978. Corporate Behavior and Social Change. Reston, VA: Reston Publishing.
Powell, Walter, and Paul DiMaggio, eds. 1991. The New Institutionalism in Organizational
Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Preda, Alex. 2005. “The Investor as a Cultural Figure of Global Capitalism” Pp. 141–162 in
The Sociology of Financial Markets, edited by Karin Knorr Cetina and Alex Preda.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Pusey, Michael. 1991. Economic Rationalism in Canberra: A Nation-Building State Changes
its Mind. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Putnam, Robert, Robert Leonardi, and Raffaella. Nannetti. 1993. Making Democracy Work:
Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rambo, Eric. 1994. “A Culturalist Perspective on Economic Welfare.” Culture 8(3–4): 1, 4–7
Reddy, William M. 1984. The Rise of Market Culture: The Textile Trade and French Society,
1750–1900. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
0001316365.INDD 153
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
154
the economic as culture
Rorty, Richard. 1989. Contingency, Irony and Solidarity. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Sahlins, Marshall. 1976. Culture and Practical Reason. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
——— . 2000. “The Sadness of Sweetness; or, the Native Anthropology of Western
Cosmology.” Pp. 537–583 in Culture in Practice. Selected Essays, edited by Marshall
Sahlins. New York: Zone Books.
Salancik, Gerald, and James Meindl. 1984. “Corporate Attributions as Strategic Illusions of
Management Control.” Administrative Science Quarterly 29: 238–254.
Sampson, Anthony. 1973. The Sovereign State of ITT. New York: Stein & Day.
Sapolsky, Harvey. 1986. Consuming Fears. New York: Basic Books.
Schenkler, Barry. 1980. Impression Management. Monterrey, CA: Brooks Cole.
Scott, Richard. 2001. Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Sethi, S. Prakash 1977. Up Against the Corporate Wall. 3rd ed. Englewoods Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice-Hall.
Sharplin, Arthur. 1985. “Union Carbide of India Ltd.: The Bhopal Tragedy.” Case Research
Journal 23: 229–248.
Shils, Edward. 1975. Center and Periphery. Essays in Macrosociology. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Shrivastava, Paul. 1987. Bhopal: Anatomy of a Crisis. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
Simiand, Francois. 1934. “La Monnaie, Réalité Sociale.” Annales Sociologiques, ser. D: 1–86.
Simmel, Georg. [1908] 1950. The Sociology of Georg Simmel, edited by Kurt Wolf. Glencoe,
IL: Free Press.
——— . [1900] 1978. The Philosophy of Money. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Smelser, Neil. 1963. The Sociology of Economic Life. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
——— . 1976. Comparative Methods in the Social Sciences. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Smelser, Neil, and Richard Swedberg. 2005. The Handbook of Economic Sociology, 2nd ed.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
Smith, Gordon. 1979. Democracy in Western Germany: Parties and Politics in the Federal
Republic. London: Heineman.
Smith, Philip, and Jeffrey Alexander. 2005. “Introduction: the New Durkheim.” Pp. 1–37 in
The Cambridge Companion to Durkheim, edited by Jeffrey C. Alexander and Philip
Smith. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Spillman, Lyn. 1999. “Enriching Exchange: Cultural Dimensions of Markets.” American
Journal of Economics and Sociology 58(4): 1047–1071.
Starling, Grover, and Otis Baskin. 1985. Issues in Business and Society: Capitalism and Public
Response. Boston: Kent Publishing.
Staw, Barry, Pamela McKechnie, and Sheila Puffer. 1983. “The Justification of
Organizational Performance.” Administrative Science Quarterly 26: 501–524.
Sturdivant, Frederick. 1985. The Corporate Social Challenge: Case and Commentaries.
Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.
Suchman, Mark. 1995. “Managing Legitimacy: Strategic and Institutional Approaches.”
Academy of Management Review 20(3): 571–610.
Sutton, Robert, and Anita Callahan. 1987. “The Stigma of Bankruptcy: Spoiled
Organizational Image and its Management.” Academy of Management Journal
30(3): 405–436.
Sutton, Robert, and Roderick Kramer. 1990. “Transforming Failure into Success:
Impression Management, the Reagan Administration, and the Iceland Arms Control
Talks.” Pp. 221–245 in International Cooperation and Conflict: Perspectives from
Organizational Theory, edited by Robert Kahn and Mayer Zald. San Francisco:
Jossey-Bass.
0001316365.INDD 154
7/14/2011 4:26:38 PM
culture and the economy
155
Swedberg, Richard. 1987. “Economic Sociology: Past and Present.” Current Sociology 35: 1–221.
——— . 1997. “New Economic Sociology: What Has Been Accomplished? What Is Ahead?”
Acta Sociologica 40: 161–182.
——— . 2004. “Toqueville and the Spirit of American Capitalism.” Paper presented at the
Norms, Beliefs, and Institutions of 21stCentury Capitalism: Celebrating Max Weber’s
The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism Conference, October 8–9, 2004,
Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.
Swidler, Ann. 1986. “Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies.” American Sociological
Review 20: 273–286.
Taussig, Michael. 1986. The Evil and Commodity Fetishism in South America. Chapel Hill:
University of North Carolina Press.
Tedeschi, James. 1981. Impression Management Theory and Social Psychological Research.
New York: Academic Press.
Tedeschi, James, and Marc Reiss. 1981. “Identities, the Phenomenal Self, and Laboratory
Research.” Pp. 3–22 in Impression Management Theory and Social Psychological
Research, edited by J. Tedeschi. New York: Academic Press.
Thomas, William, and Florian Znaniecki. [1918–1920] 1958. The Polish Peasant in Europe
and America. New York: Dover Publications.
Thrift, Nigel. 2000. “Pandora’s Box? Cultural Geography of Economics.” Pp. 689–704 in
Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography, edited by Gordon Clark, Meric Gertler, and
Maryann Feldman. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Tietmeyer, Hans. 1997a. “Monetary Stability—A Perpetual Challenge.” Speech delivered by
the President of the Deutsche Bundesbank, First European Equity Traders Convention
of the Federation of European Stock Exchanges, Frankfurt am Main, June 19.
——— . 1997b. “Der Euro: ein entnationalisiertes Geld.” Speech delivered by the President
of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Österreichisch-Deutschen Kulturgesellschaft, Wien,
November 27.
Tocqueville, Alexis de. 1959. Journey to America. Translated by George Lawrence, edited by
J. P. Mayer. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
——— . [1835–1840] 2000. Democracy in America. Translated and edited by Harvey
Mansfield and Delba Winthrop. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Tognato, Carlo 2008. “Bringing Culture Back In: A Neo-Durkheimian Perspective on
Central Banking.” Innovar 18(31): 93–116.
Tomlison, Alan, ed. 1990. Consumption, Identity and Style: Marketing, Meanings, and the
Packaging of Pleasure. London and New York: Routledge.
Tönnies, Ferdinand. [1887] 1955. Community and Association. London: Routledge and
Kegan Paul.
Valenti, JoAnn. 2002. “Communication Challenges for Science and Religion.” Public
Understanding of Science 11: 57–63.
Wagner, Wolfgang. 2007. “Vernacular Science Knowledge: Its Role in Everyday Life
Communication.” Public Understanding of Science 16: 7–22.
Weber, Max. [1915] 1946a. “The Social Psychology of the World Religions.” Pp. 267–301 in
From Max Weber, edited by Hans Gerth and C. Wright Mills. Oxford and New York:
Oxford University Press.
——— . [1920] 1946b. “The Protestant Sects and the Spirit of Capitalism.” Pp. 302–322 in
From Max Weber, edited by Hans Gerth and C. Wright Mills. Oxford and New York:
Oxford University Press.
——— . [1946] 1971. “Religious Rejections of the World and Their Directions.” Pp. 323–359
in From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, edited by H. Gerth and C. Wright Mills.
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.
0001316365.INDD 155
7/14/2011 4:26:39 PM
156
the economic as culture
——— . [1922] 1978. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretative Sociology, Vol. 1,
edited by Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of
California Press.
Weber, Max. [1904] 1998. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, 2nd ed. Los
Angeles: Roxbury.
White, Harrison. 1981. “Where Do Markets Come From?” American Journal of Sociology
87: 517–547.
Whiteside, Thomas. 1972. The Investigation of Ralph Nader. New York: Arbor House.
Yenkey, Christopher. 2007. “Morality, Rationality, and the Social Meaning of Information:
The Institutionalization of Transparency in the U.S. Securities Markets.” CSES
Working Paper Series #40, May.
Zaloom, Caitlin. 2003. “Ambiguous Numbers: Trading Technologies and Interpretation in
Financial Markets.” American Ethnologist 30: 258–272.
——— . 2004. “The Productive Life of Risk.” Current Anthropology 19: 365–391.
——— . 2006. Out of the Pits: Trading and Technology from Chicago to London. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Zelizer, Viviana. 1979. Morals and Markets: The Development of Life Insurance in the United
States. New York: Columbia University Press.
——— . 1985. Pricing the Priceless Child: The Changing Social Value of Children. New York:
Basic Books.
——— . 1988. “Beyond the Polemics on the Market: Establishing a Theoretical and
Empirical Agenda.” Sociological Forum 3: 614–634.
——— . 1989. “The Social Meaning of Money: ‘Special Monies.’ ” American Journal of
Sociology 95(2): 342–377.
——— . 1992. “Repenser le Marché.” Actes de la Recherche en sciences sociales 94: 3–26.
——— . 1994. The Social Meaning of Money. New York: Basic Books.
——— . 1996. “Payments and Social Ties.” Sociological Forum 11: 481–495.
——— . 1999. “Official Standardization vs. Social Differentiation in Americans’ Uses of
Money.” Pp. 82–96 in Nation-States and Money: The Past, the Present and the Future of
National Currencies, edited by Emily Gilbert and Eric Helleiner. London: Routledge.
——— . 2000. “The Purchase of Intimacy.” Law & Social Inquiry 25(3): 817–848.
——— . 2005a. “Culture and Consumption.” Pp. 331–354 in The Handbook of Cultural
Sociology, 2nd ed., edited by Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
——— . 2005b. The Purchase of Intimacy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
——— . 2007. “Ethics in the Economy.” Journal for Business, Economics, and Ethics (ZfWU)
1: 8–23.
Znoj, Heinzpeter. 1998. “Hot Money and War Debts: Transactional Regimes in
Southwestern Sumatra.” Comparative Studies in Society and History 40: 193–222.
Zucker, Lynne. 1987. “Institutional Theories of Organizations.” Annual Review of Sociology
13: 443–644.
Zukin, Sharon, and Paul DiMaggio, eds. 1990. Structures of Capital: The Social Organization
of the Economy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
0001316365.INDD 156
7/14/2011 4:26:39 PM