CSAE WPS/2004-34
Global Aid Allocation: Are Nordic Donors Different?
Scott Gates
Centre for the Study of Civil War, PRIO and
Norwegian University of Science and Technology (NTNU)
and
Anke Hoeffler
Centre for the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford and
International Peace Research Institute, Oslo (PRIO)
December 2004
Both authors gratefully acknowledge funding from the MULTI program of the
Research Council of Norway for this project. We thank Morten Bøås, David Dollar,
Paul Collier, Jan Dehn, Nils Petter Gleditsch, Rune Hagen, Trond Folke Lindberg,
Hildegunn Nordås, Arve Ofstad, Olav H. Seim, and Astrid Suhrke for their valuable
help and comments.
Abstract:
The Nordic development assistance programs have earned a reputation for
commitment to human rights and democracy. Is the reputation deserved? We address
this question by comparing how much aid donors give and to which recipient
countries. Using a global panel data set, spanning the period 1980-99 and 91 recipient
countries, we find that individual bilateral donors vary considerably from one another.
Nordic aid distribution differs significantly from other bilateral aid donor patterns:
Norway, Denmark, Sweden and Finland provide more aid to democracies but do not
penalise poor trade policies. Unlike other bilateral donors the four Nordics do not
provide more aid to political allies. We also find some evidence that recipients with a
good human rights record receive more aid from Nordic donors.
1. Introduction
International aid agencies are motivated by different objectives. For example,
NORAD, the Norwegian aid agency states:
‘The purpose of Norwegian development cooperation is to contribute
towards lasting improvements in economic, social and political
conditions for the populations of developing countries, with particular
emphasis on ensuring that development aid benefits the poorest
people.’
Furthermore, one of the main goals is ‘To contribute towards promoting peace,
democracy and human rights’.1 Many other international aid agencies state the
achievement of the Millennium Development Goals as their main objective. Denmark,
Germany, the UK, the Netherlands and other donors state explicitly that aid is aimed
at reducing global poverty. However, other aid agencies seem to be at least partly
motivated by self-interest. USAID’s mission statement makes this explicit:
‘U.S. foreign assistance has always had the twofold purpose of
furthering America's foreign policy interests in expanding democracy
and free markets while improving the lives of the citizens of the
developing world.’2
In this paper we examine the patterns of aid allocation across different donor
countries. The consensus is that strategic interests, colonial history, trade, and political
institutions of the recipient country dominate bilateral aid (most recent studies include
Alesina and Dollar (2000), Boschini and Olofsgård (2001) and Neumayer (2003)).
The Nordic donors, however, tend to be regarded as exceptions. One problem in the
existing literature is that the Nordic countries, Norway, Denmark, Sweden and
Finland are usually aggregated in the analysis and to date no systematic examination
of Nordic aid distribution patterns has been made.
Using comprehensive OECD data on aid disbursements during the period
1980 to 1999, we compare bilateral aid flows, focusing in particular on the individual
Nordic countries. Like previous studies we find that there are profound differences
1
http://www.norad.no
2
http://www.usaid.gov
between the specific political factors that shape different countries’ aid allocation
patterns. Our results indicate that the aid allocation patterns of the Nordic countries
are not the same as those of other bilateral aid agencies. We find strong evidence that
Nordic donors provide more aid to the poorest countries and to democracies but do
not penalise countries with less open trade policies. We also find some indication that
recipients with a good human rights record receive more aid from Nordic donors.
The paper is organized as follows: after a brief review of previous research
regarding the distribution of aid we present some descriptive data focusing on Nordic
countries. In Section 3 we use a global panel data set for our regression analysis for a
comparison of individual donor aid allocations. Section 4 concludes.
2. Data Description – Patterns of Aid Allocation
2.1 Global Patterns of Bilateral Aid Allocation
A number of studies have examined the patterns of aid allocation (see, for example,
McKinley and Little, 1978; McKinley and Little, 1979; Mosely, 1981; Maizels and
Nissanke, 1984; Trumbull and Wall, 1994; Ludborg, 1998; Schraeder, et al., 1998;
Alesina and Dollar, 2000; Burnside and Dollar, 2000; Boschini and Olofsgård, 2001;
Collier and Dollar, 2002; Neumayer, 2003). With few exceptions most analyses of
bilateral aid allocations show that political and strategic interests of donors trump
concern for growth or poverty reduction. The Nordic countries, however, tend to stand
out as exceptions. The problem is that for most analyses the Nordics are aggregated3
and no systematic examination of individual Nordic donors’ allocation patterns has
been made. Alesina and Dollar conclude that in the aggregate Nordic donors provide
the right incentives; more aid goes to poor recipients with good trade policies and
open democratic regimes. This may be partly due to historical reasons, Nordic donors
have no colonial legacies and since all of the four donors are small countries they do
not try to foster global strategic interests. Furthermore, all Nordic donors have a
tradition of a social democratic welfare state where all citizens are entitled to welfare.
This principle of universality generates a shared conception of citizenship and social
spending is comparatively high in Nordic countries. Moreover, this system of socio-
3
Alesina and Dollar (2000) even include the Netherlands and Canada in their aggregation.
political values does not only provide the determinants for domestic but also for
international justice. Foreign aid can thus be seen as an extension of the principles of
the welfare state beyond the domestic borders.4 Noël and Thérien (1995) suggest in
their empirical study that states with large welfare budgets are more generous in
providing foreign aid. Norway, the Netherlands, Denmark and Sweden are among the
welfare states with large aid budgets, however, this correlation does not hold for
Finland, Switzerland and France.
We now turn to a description of Nordic aid allocation before we present a
detailed regression analysis of the factors that determine this allocation in section 3.
2.2 Nordic Patterns of Bilateral Aid Allocation
Throughout this paper we use the definition of aid as used by the OECD and base all
of our empirical work on their data. The OECD provides online information on the aid
flows from bilateral and multilateral donors to recipient countries. In our analysis we
included official development assistance (ODA) to developing countries as well as
official aid (OA) to the so called "Part II" countries which include more advanced
developing countries as well as Central and Eastern European Countries and Newly
Independent States of the former Soviet Union (CEEC and NIS).5 Data are available
from 1960 and is provided in current US dollars. In this paper we analyse the total net
ODA/OA flows for the period 1980-99. Total ODA/OA includes grants or loans to
countries that are undertaken by the official sector in order to promote economic
development and welfare. The financial terms are concessional; if the ODA/OA
consists of a loan it must have a grant element of at least 25 per cent. While technical
co-operation is included, grants, loans and credits for military purposes are excluded.
For most years the flows are positive, however, due to the re-payments of loans the
flows are negative for some years.
Using the US GDP deflator we calculate aid flows in constant 1995 dollars. In
this section we concentrate on the average taken over the years 1997, 1998 and 1999
in order to smooth out any unusual events. The pattern of aid allocation by donors is
shown in Table I. Bilateral aid from the 22 Development Assistance Committee
4
For a detailed discussion see Stokke (1989).
5
For a detailed list please refer to the Appendix. The concepts of ODA and OA are the same -- they
only differ in the type of recipient country.
(DAC) member countries6 accounts for the largest share, 65.4 percent, of total global
aid. About 45 percent of total aid originates from only four countries: Japan (17.3
percent), USA (9.2 percent), France (9 percent) and Germany (7.5 percent). The
Nordic donors contribute considerably less in absolute terms; nevertheless, Denmark,
Sweden and Norway contribute each between 2.5 and 2.9 percent of total global aid.
Multilateral aid agencies give 33.6 percent. The remaining two percent of total global
aid that is not from a DAC country or a multilateral organization are accounted for by
bilateral Arab donors.
Relative to their GDP, donors differ hugely in their generosity7. As column 4,
Table I shows only four countries exceed the UN target of 0.7 percent of Gross
National Income (GNI) and three of these four are Denmark, Norway and Sweden.
Denmark's ODA to GNI ratio was 0.99 percent, while Norway’s was 0.87 percent,
and Sweden’s was 0.74 percent.
We now examine who receives this aid. In Table II we list the major recipients
of Nordic Aid. For Norway topping the list are Tanzania and Mozambique, receiving
7.1 percent and 6.9 percent of Norwegian aid, respectively. Other important recipients
are the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia, Bosnia, Zambia and Bangladesh. Sweden
allocates the largest share to Tanzania (6.8 percent) and Mozambique (about 6
percent) followed by South Africa (about 5 percent). Much of Danish aid is also
allocated to Sub-Saharan Africa. Top of the list are Tanzania (8.8 percent), Uganda
(7.8 percent) and Mozambique (5.3 percent). Finland’s allocation is somewhat
different, neighbouring Russia heads the list (9.3 percent), followed by China (8.2
percent) and Mozambique (6.7 percent). The Republic of Yugoslavia and Bosnia and
Herzegovina also feature prominently. Estonia just makes it into the top ten, receiving
3.8 percent of Finnish aid. To summarize, much of Norwegian, Danish and Swedish
aid is allocated to Sub-Saharan African countries; for each donor six out of the top ten
recipients are in Sub-Saharan Africa. Finland’s aid allocation seems to be more
dominated by regional concerns. Russia and Estonia are among the top ten recipients,
while only two Sub-Saharan countries receive considerable amounts of aid
(Mozambique and Tanzania).
6
A list of the 22 DAC countries is listed in the Appendix.
7
Hopkins (2000) provides a detailed discussion of aid volumes over time.
Recently, donors have been encouraged to coordinate bi-lateral aid in the
recipient countries in order to improve aid efficiency and public service delivery
(World Bank, 2004). Furthermore, tied aid is now widely regarded as being more of
an aid for the donor country than for the recipient countries and channelling aid
through non-governmental organizations (NGOs) has been seen as preferable to
giving aid to corrupt governments. In Table III we examine how much aid is
channelled through multilateral organisations and through NGOs, how much is
provided in grants and how much tied aid each Nordic donor provides. In each case
we compare this with the average of the 22 DAC donors.
The average DAC country gives about two thirds of ODA directly to the
recipient countries and channels about one third through multilateral agencies.
Norway and Sweden provides a relatively high proportion of ODA bilaterally, 74 and
70 percent, respectively. Thus, less than the average is channelled through
multinational organizations. Denmark and Finland in contrast spend a lower than
average proportion of their ODA on bilateral aid, 59 and 58 percent, respectively. The
average DAC country provides about 90 percent of its aid as grants, for all Nordic
countries this is considerably higher, just under 100 percent. About one quarter of all
DAC aid is provided as tied aid. Among the Nordic donors, Denmark provides a
relatively high proportion of ODA as tied aid (29 percent), followed by Finland (15
percent). The other two Nordic donors tie very little of their bilateral aid, Norway
only provides one percent as tied aid, while Sweden provides about two percent.
Interestingly, Nordic donors, with the exception of Sweden, channel negligible
amounts of aid through NGOs.
In order to complete our brief overview of Nordic aid we examine the
allocation by major purpose in Table IV. Traditionally much of aid has been provided
as project aid, often in an attempt to address the issues of fungibility and to provide
show cases for donor involvement.8 However, programme aid can help to strengthen
ownership of reform in selected countries and reduce the cost of collaboration
between donor and recipient (World Bank, 2004). Comparing the major purposes of
aid commitments we see that all of the Nordic donors provide more aid for social and
administrative infrastructure, but less aid for economic infrastructure than the average
DAC donor. Within the provision of social infrastructure all Nordic donors put a
8
Mosley and Eeckhout (2000) discuss project and programme aid.
particular emphasis on the provision of health care. All Nordics provide free access to
health care in their countries and may thus have a particular motivation and expertise
in providing basic health care in recipient countries. All of the Nordic donors provide
less programme assistance than the average DAC donor (7 percent); Norway only
provides 0.5 percent as programme assistance.
Our brief overview provides us with a number of stylised facts regarding
contemporary aid distribution. Multilateral agencies provide one third of the total
global aid budget and four large donors provide about 54 percent of total global aid.
Nordic countries may be comparatively small donors in total aid terms but are very
generous in providing aid. Denmark, Sweden and Norway are among the few donors
who fulfil the UN target of giving more than 0.7 percent of their GNI as aid. Much of
Nordic aid goes to Sub-Saharan Africa, with the notable exception of Finland. Much
of Finnish aid is allocated to the neighbouring Russia and Estonia. Nordic countries
provide a larger than average share of aid as grants. With the exception of Denmark
very little aid is tied. Apart from Sweden hardly any aid is channelled through NGOs.
All Nordic donors tend to concentrate on the provision of social infrastructure rather
than economic infrastructure, a relatively large proportion is provided for health care.
Nordic donors prefer project aid to programme aid. In order to examine these
differences in aid allocation in more detail, we now turn to regression analysis in
Section 3.
3. Data Analysis
We analyse the global allocation of aid during 1980-1999 by using averages for five
year sub periods, 1980-84, 1985-89, 1990-94 and 1995-99. We are able to estimate
the aid allocation to 91 recipient countries. However, we do not have information for
all countries for all years, making this global panel unbalanced. We estimate our
model by pooled OLS and report robust standard errors. The dependent variable is the
logarithm of aid given by a particular donor or a group of donors.9 As explanatory
9
Following the standard practice in this literature we added a small amount of aid to all observations,
thus avoiding missing values when taking the logarithm of the zero observations. As an alternative
treatment of the zero values we used Tobit estimation and found the results to be qualitatively similar.
Results presented in Table VII.
variables we use a range of socio-economic characteristics of recipient countries, as
well as their history and geo-strategic importance. The results are shown in Table V.
In the first two columns we investigate the donor behaviour of the multinational
versus bilateral donors. Here we summed the total aid given by all multi-lateral
agencies and for the bilateral aid we summed the total aid given by the 22 DAC
countries. The results suggest that the aid allocation of multi- and bilateral donors is
relatively similar. The effect of income is negative, donors give more aid to poorer
countries.10 Countries with large populations also receive more aid. We use the
parallel market premium as an indicator of trade policy. Repressive trade regimes are
characterized by a higher premium, but it can also be argued that generally poor
macro-economic management causes a higher premium. We think that this proxy of
trade policies is a suitable one because it allows us to analyse macroeconomic policies
in general. In any case it is preferable to a dummy categorizing open or closed trade
regime because this continuous variable allows us to consider different degrees of
openness. For multi- as well as bi-lateral donors the coefficient on trade policy is
insignificant. We measure democracy using the Polity IV data set which measures
openness of political institutions on a scale of 1 to 10, with higher values indicating
more democratic regimes (Jaggers and Gurr, 1995). Democracy is significant at the
ten percent level, more democratic countries receive more aid. We also include a
measure of human rights violations which is based on information published by
Amnesty International. The index (as compiled by Cornett and Gibney, 2004) runs
from 1 to 5, with higher values indicating worse human rights. Our democracy and
human rights variables are not highly correlated; the correlation coefficient is only
-0.06. Thus, democracy and the human rights variable seem to measure different
aspects of political rights. The human rights index is not significant, (i.e. neither
multilateral nor bilateral donors seem to take human rights into account when
allocating aid). With respect to regional allocation multi- and bilateral donors are
somewhat different. While both give more to Egypt, the multilateral donors give
significantly less to Israel while the bilateral donors give significantly more to Israel.
10
Like Alesina and Dollar (2000) we also ran specifications with a squared income term. Although we
find both the level and the squared term to be significant we decided not to report these results because
the inflexion point was outside the sample range. Thus, we conclude that the often hypothesized curvilinear relationship is not relevant for any of the recipient countries included in our analysis.
Neither donor group gives more aid to Latin American nor to Sub-Saharan African
countries; these dummies are insignificant. Religion does not seem to be a very
important determinant either. Countries with higher proportions of Catholics or
Muslim populations are no different than other countries; the coefficients are
insignificant. However, countries with a higher proportion of Protestants receive less
aid. To summarize, when looking at aggregates multi- and bilateral donors allocate
aid according to income, population and democracy. Egypt receives more aid than
other countries, ceteris paribus. Human rights and trade policies do not seem to be
important factors in the global allocation of aid. Our model is provides a better
explanation for multilateral aid (R2=0.59) than for bilateral aid (R2=0.42).
A comparison of the aid allocation patterns of Nordic donors to the previous
bilateral donors suggests that Nordic donors follow a somewhat different pattern. In
column 3 we consider the total aid given by Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden.
The income effect is negative and larger countries receive more aid. This conforms to
the general pattern of bilateral aid allocation although the descriptive statistics
indicating that Nordic donors allocate a lot of aid to smaller countries. The coefficient
on the parallel market premium is positive, i.e. countries with closed trade policies
receive more aid. Countries with higher democracy scores receive more aid and
countries with worse human rights records receive less aid. Egypt receives more aid,
ceteris paribus. The Israel dummy is negative at the ten percent level. Our descriptive
statistics in section 2 seemed to suggest that Nordic donors give a lot of aid to SubSaharan African countries; however, the region as a whole does not receive
preferential treatment when we account for a number of country specific
characteristics. The Latin America dummy is also insignificant. Countries with higher
proportions of Protestants, Catholics and Muslims receive less aid. Our model
provides a reasonable fit (R2 =0.52).
In columns 4-7 we investigate the four Nordic donors separately. Like in the
previous models the coefficient on the income term is negative and highly significant.
Nordic donors allocate more aid to poorer countries. Like the other DAC donors all
Nordic donors give more to large countries. All Nordics give more aid to countries
with poor trade policies but also to more democratic regimes. Only Denmark gives
less aid to countries with poor human rights, this variable is not significant for the
other three donors. Egypt receives significantly more aid from Denmark, Sweden and
Finland. Israel receives significantly less aid from Norway, Denmark and Finland.
Sub-Saharan Africa does not receive more aid but Denmark and Finland allocate
significantly less to Latin American countries. Norway, Denmark and Finland give
less aid to countries with high proportions of Protestants, Catholics and Muslims. For
Sweden, none of the religious variables are significant. We also introduce an index of
political allegiance between the donor country and the recipients. Using UN voting
patterns, Gartzke and Jo (2000) derive an index from -1 to 1 with higher values
indicating more similar voting patterns. With respect to this UN variable none of the
Nordic donors give more aid to political allies. To summarize, unlike the average
bilateral donor, Nordic donors allocate aid according to democracy and human rights
records but not to political allies. Countries with poor trade policies receive more aid,
ceteris paribus. In general, the model seems more suited to explain the Norwegian
and Danish allocation than the Swedish and Finnish one.
Our model also provides a good explanation of the aid allocation by the big
five bilateral donors (USA, UK, France, Japan and Germany) and for the Netherlands
and Canada. We present these results in columns 9 to 15. All donors give more aid to
larger countries. The parallel market premium is significantly negative for the US and
Japan, i.e. countries with less open policies receive less aid. In contrast, France, the
Netherlands and Canada give more aid to poor trade policy countries. The US, the
UK, Germany and the Netherlands allocate more aid to democracies; France, Japan
and Canada do not. However, Japan and Canada give less aid to countries with poor
human rights; this variable is insignificant for all the other donors. All donors without
exception allocate more aid to recipients who are their political allies with respect to
UN voting patterns. Recipients also tend to receive more aid if they are former
colonies. Obviously, geo-strategic interests vary across donors but Egypt receives
more aid from all donors apart from the UK. Israel receives more aid from the USA,
Germany and the Netherlands but less from the UK and Japan. Sub-Saharan African
countries receive less aid from Japan and Latin American countries receive more aid
from the Netherlands and Canada but less from the UK. Catholic countries receive
more aid from France and less aid from Japan and Canada. Protestant and Muslim
countries tend to receive less aid across the donors. The model explains the aid
allocation of France (R2=0.72) and the UK (R2=0.66) particularly well and least well
for the US (R2=0.46).
When we compare the aid allocation for individual donors we can thus
observe distinct patterns. All of the donors provide more aid to poor countries. Two
donors (US and Japan) give less aid to recipients with poor trade policies. Some
donors allocate more aid to democracies and Japan as well as Canada give less aid to
regimes with poor human rights records. However, all of these donors give more aid
to former colonies and to their UN-friends.
The patterns for the Nordic countries (Norway, Denmark, Sweden and
Finland) are distinct. All Nordic donors give more aid to democracies and in the
aggregate they give less aid to recipients with poor human rights. UN voting
behaviour seems to be insignificant in their allocation decisions. However, poor trade
policies are not penalised, countries with poor trade policies receive more aid.
A recent debate in the World Bank regards the LICUS, Low Income Countries
under Stress.11 These countries are very poor, have epidemic diseases, organized
crime, some are experiencing civil war or a war has just recently ended. The term
LICUS is currently applied to a large variety of countries, some are resource rich but
policy poor (Angola), some have exceptionally weak government capacity (Haiti) and
some are post-conflict countries (Sierra Leone). The Bank estimates that about 500
million people live in such countries. As can be seen in Table VI, six out of the
current 13 LICUS countries receive aid from Nordic donors. Sweden and Norway
provide aid to five countries each. In contrast, Denmark gives to only one of these
countries. Finland does not provide aid to any LICUS country. Sweden and Norway in
this way differ significantly from the other two Nordic donors.
On a parenthetical note, two important donors, Canada and the Netherlands,
are often seen as different to the big five donors and more like the Nordic donors. Our
regressions suggest that they are indeed different. Although they both give more aid to
UN- friends, they seem to reward democracies (Netherlands) and penalise human
rights violations (Canada). However, comparing the results for individual bilateral
donors in Table IV, we cannot conclude that the Netherlands and Canada are like
Nordic donors. Their patterns of giving vary considerably from the Nordics,
particularly in comparison to Norway and Sweden. They should therefore not be
treated as if they follow the same behavioural patterns as for example Alesina and
Dollar (2000) assume.
11
World Bank (2003).
Robustness Checks
Cornett and Gibney (2004) provide two measures of human rights. One is based on
information published by Amnesty International and the other on information by the
US State Department. In the appendix, Table Va, we examine whether the results are
sensitive to the use of the different human rights variables. The two variables are
highly correlated (ρ=0.87) and the results are qualitatively similar. The main
difference is that the human rights variable is not significant at the conventional levels
for the Nordic donors (column 3). All other results remain unchanged.
We also examined whether the results are sensitive to the selection of a
particular time period. Due to a number of reasons, for example the end of the Cold
War and a shift in donor behaviour from conditionality towards selectivity, one could
hypothesize that aid allocations in the 1980s and those in the 1990s were motivated by
different determinants. The study by Dollar and Levin (2004) suggests that donors
have become more selective in the sense that during the 1980s aid was allocated
indiscriminately to recipients with poor or good governance, but that donors have
since shifted to assisting countries with good governance. In order to test this
hypothesis we run our model on data for the 1980s and the 1990s separately. We
could not confirm the hypothesis that donors have become more selective with respect
to recipients’ economic policy. With respect to democracy we could not find any
change in donor behaviour either. However, the coefficient on human rights was
insignificant for most donors in the 1980s but was significant for a number of donors
in the 1990s. 12 Thus, we cannot confirm that donors’ behaviour changed significantly
over the past 20 years, possibly with the exception of being more sensitive to the
recipients’ human rights record.
One further econometric issue is that the aid allocation regressions are not
independent of each other. It may be the case that aid allocations are positively or
negatively correlated. Donors may follow other donors and support certain recipients
or perhaps decide to give aid to recipients who do not receive aid from other donors.
Aid allocations may be complements or substitutes and thus not independent of each
other. To investigate this possibility we used the method of Seemingly Unrelated
12
Multi, DAC and Nordic donors, Denmark, France (p=0.104), France, Japan and Canada. For
Germany the human rights variable is significant in both periods, but only at the ten percent level in the
1980s. In the 1990s the variable is significant at the one percent level.
Regressions (SURE). We present these results in Table VIII. In the first block we
allow the error terms of the multi- and bi-lateral aid allocations to be correlated. The
correlation coefficient is 0.79 and we can reject the hypothesis that this correlation is
zero. However, the regression coefficients are similar to our OLS estimates and our
results are qualitatively unchanged. We arrive at the same conclusion when we allow
for correlation between the error terms of the multilateral allocation, the DAC
bilateral allocation (excluding Nordic donors) and the Nordic donors. Again, we can
reject the hypothesis that the error terms are uncorrelated. The main results remain
unchanged.
4. Conclusions
The Nordic development assistance programs have earned a reputation for their
generosity as well as their commitment to human rights and democracy. In our paper
we examine whether this reputation is deserved. First, we find that Nordic donors,
with the exception of Finland, are relatively generous in the provision of aid. Norway,
Denmark and Sweden are among the few countries to fulfil the UN target of giving at
least 0.7 percent of their GNI as aid. Nordic donors give to poor countries, many of
which are Sub-Saharan African. Relatively little of their aid is tied (Denmark is an
exception) and they concentrate on social infrastructure provision, mainly in the
health sector. Relatively little of their aid is channelled through multilateral agencies
and the amount channelled through NGOs is negligible.
We then address the question whether Nordic donors differ in their aid
allocation patterns by comparing how much aid donors give and to which recipient
countries. Using a global panel data set we find that individual bilateral donors vary
considerably from one another. Nordic aid distribution differs significantly from other
bilateral aid donor patterns: Norway, Denmark, Sweden and Finland provide more aid
to democracies but do not penalise poor trade policies. We also find some evidence
that recipients with a good human rights record receive more aid from Nordic donors.
Unlike any of the other DAC donors, Nordic donors do not give more aid to political
allies. Nordic aid allocation seems remarkably free from self-interest and, indeed,
more orientated towards their stated objectives of poverty alleviation, the promotion
of democracy and human rights. Norway and Sweden serve as leaders in these
regards. One slight exception may be Finland, which more recently has provided more
aid to recipients in its region (mainly Russia and Estonia) rather than to very poor
developing countries.
Bilateral donors have multiple objectives and in this study we confirm that
bilateral donors’ aid allocations differ significantly. Our emphasis is largely on
describing who gives aid to whom but we do not prescribe who should receive aid.13
Aid is most effective in recipient countries with good governance and strong
institutions. In the past donors tried to buy policy reform by attaching conditions to
aid packages; however, in general conditionality did not achieve the desired
objectives. Conditionality did not bring about lasting reform if there was no strong
domestic movement for change. Weak domestic ownership and an unwillingness of
donors to withdraw assistance in cases of non-compliance are the most often cited
causes behind the failure of conditionality.14 The work by Burnside and Dollar (2000)
suggested selectivity as a new strategy; donors should give aid to recipients with good
policies because only in good policy environments will aid be growth enhancing. The
study by Burnside and Dollar received considerable attention and criticism. Hansen
and Tarp (2001) and Dalgaard, Hansen and Tarp (2004) mainly base their criticism on
the econometric shortcomings.
A bigger criticism of the Burnside and Dollar article is a policy critique. If aid
is mainly allocated to select countries with good policies, this implies that donors
should disengage from countries with bad governance and poor institutions. Yet, if
donors want to make progress on the Millenium Development Goals and combat the
adverse regional and global consequences generated by LICUS, disengagement is not
an option. Donor engagement in these countries must be different to the average poor
country and should be tailored to the specific situation. Increasing funding is not
enough because government delivery mechanisms are poor. Instead the emphasis
should be on an indirect, but catalytic role in building the ownership of reforms in
societies. This may include supporting civil society groups, independent think tanks
and distribution of information. A focused reform agenda should be developed and
agreed upon, the success of early reforms improves the chances of a larger future
reform agenda. A further step would consist of strategic capacity building which
13
McGillivray (2004) provides a detailed discussion of descriptive and prescriptive approaches.
14
For a further discussion see Collier (1997) and World Bank (1998).
could include secondments from IFIs and bilateral donors as well as the mobilization
of expertise in the diaspora community. In addition the operational challenge of
delivering services to poor people needs to be tackled. Since these countries do not
provide strong authorizing environments for incurring debt liabilities the World Bank
should not be the major development agency in LICUS. Bilateral donors, the EU and
UNDP are grant making agencies and are therefore most likely to provide assistance
to LICUS countries. These recent changes in the development agenda could enable
Nordic donors to use their deservedly excellent reputation to initiate and help to
design reforms, assist with capacity building and service delivery in LICUS. Norway
and Sweden, in particular, already give aid to about half of these cases. These two
donors are presented with an exciting opportunity to take the (joint) lead in some of
these countries and help to develop the LICUS programme.
5. References
Alesina, A. and D. Dollar. 2000. “Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and Why?”
Journal of Economic Growth 5: 33-63.
Andersen, O. M. 2000. “Sector Programme Assistance”, in F. Tarp (Ed.), Foreign Aid
and Development: Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future. Routledge, London
and New York, pp. 178-194.
Boone, P. 1996. “Politics and the Effectiveness of Foreign Aid”, European Economic
Review, 40, 289-329.
Boschini, A. and A. Olofsgård. 2001. “Foreign Aid: an Instrument for Fighting
Poverty or Communism?” Mimeo.
http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/B-SPAN/sub_instrumental.htm
Burnside, C. and D. Dollar. 2000. “Aid, Policies and Growth”, American Economic
Review, 90, 847-868.
Collier, P. 1997. The Failure of Conditionality, in C. Gwin and J. Nelson (eds)
Perspectives on Aid and Development. Washington D.C.: Overseas Development
Council.
Collier, P. and J. Dehn. 2001. “Aid, Shocks, and Growth”. World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper No 2688. Washington DC.
Collier, Paul and David Dollar. 2002. “Aid Allocation and Poverty Reduction”.
European Economic Review 45: 1470-1500.
Cornett, Linda and Mark Gibney. 2004. “Political Repression and Human Rights
Abuse”. Mimeo. University of North Carolina, Asheville.
Dalgaard, C.-J, H. Hansen, F. Tarp. 2004. ”On the empirics of foreign aid and
growth”. EconomicJournal 114: F191- F216
DFID, 2001. Statistics on International Development. DFID, Statistics Department,
East Kilbride.
Dollar, D. and Levin, V. 2004. “The Increasing Selectivity of Foreign Aid, 19842002”. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3299, Washington D.C.
Frey, B. S. and F. Schneider, 1986. “Competing Models of International Lending
Activity”. Journal of Development Economics 20: 225-245.
Gartzke, Erik and Dong-Joon Jo. 2002. The Affinity of Nations Index, 1946-1996.
Version 3.0. http://www.columbia.edu/~eg589/datasets.html.
Hansen, E and F. Tarp. 2001. “Aid and growth regressions”. Journal of Development
Economics 64: 547-570.
Hopkins, R. F. 2000. “Political Economy of Foreign Aid”, in F. Tarp (Ed.), Foreign
Aid and Development: Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future. Routledge,
London and New York, pp. 423-449.
Ludborg, P. 1998. “Foreign Aid and International Support as a Gift Exchange”.
Economics and Politics 10: 127-141.
McGillivray, M. 2004. “Descriptive and Prescriptive Analyses of Aid Allocation:
Approaches, Issues, and Consequences”. International Review of Economics and
Finance, 13, 275-292.
McKinley, R.D. and R. Little. 1978. “The French Aid Relationship”. Development
and Change XX: 459-478.
McKinley, R.D. and R. Little. 1979. “The US Aid Relationship: A Test of the
Recipient Need and the Donor Interest Models”, Political Studies, 29, 236-250.
Maizels, A. and M. K. Nissanke. 1984. “Motivations for Aid to Developing
Countries”, World Development, 12, 879-900.
Morrissey, O. 2002. “British Aid Policy since 1997: Is DFID the Standard Bearer for
Donors?”, CREDIT Research Paper, Centre for Research in Economic Development
and International Trade, University of Nottingham.
Mosely, P. 1981. “Models of Aid Allocation Process: A Comment on McKinley and
Little” Political Studies 29: 245-253.
Mosley, P. and Eeckhout, M. J. 2000. “From project aid to programme assistance”, in
F. Tarp (Ed.), Foreign Aid and Development: Lessons Learnt and Directions for the
Future. Routledge; London and New York, pp. 131-153.
Neumayer, E. 2003. Neumayer, Eric. The Pattern of Aid Giving - The Impact of Good
Governance on Development Assistance. Routledge: London and New York.
Noël, A. and J.-P. Thérien. 1995. “From Domestic to International Justice: The
Welfare State and Foreign Aid”. International Organization, 49(3): 523-553.
OECD. 2001. International Development Statistics. Data CD Rom.
Schraeder, P.J, S.W. Hook and B. Taylor, 1998. “Clarifying the Aid Puzzle: A
Comparison of American, Japanese, French, and Swedish Aid Flows”. World Politics
50: 294-320.
Stokke O. 1989. “The Determinants of Aid Policies: Some Propositions Emerging
from a Comparative Analysis” in: Stokke O. (ed.) Western Middle Powers and Global
Poverty: The Determinants of the Aid Policies of Canada, Denmark, the Netherlands,
Norway and Sweden. Uppsala: The Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, 275322.
Trumbull, W.N. and H.J. Wall, 1994. “Estimating Aid-allocation Criteria with Panel
Data”, Economic Journal 104: 876-882.
World Bank, 1998. Assessing Aid: What Works, What Doesn’t, and Why. Oxford
University Press: Oxford.
World Bank. 2003. Assessing Aid. What Works, What Doesn’t and Why. Policy
Research Report. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
World Bank. 2004. World Development Report. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Table I. Who Gives Aid? – A Donor Profile
Total
DAC
Multilateral
Nordics
Japan
USA
France
Germany
UK
Netherlands
Denmark
Sweden
Canada
Norway
Australia
Spain
Italy
Switzerland
Austria
Belgium
Finland
Portugal
Ireland
Luxembourg
Greece
New Zealand
ODA
(const US$)
39943.8
26140.3
13406.4
2313.1
6891.2
3691.7
3577.4
2999.3
1481.8
1347.8
765.8
718.6
717.5
652.8
571.8
567.0
453.4
435.5
381.6
297.2
175.9
132.8
96.7
68.1
59.8
56.5
% of
Total
% of
Bilateral
100
65.4
33.6
5.8
17.3
9.2
9.0
7.5
3.7
3.4
1.9
1.8
1.8
1.6
1.4
1.4
1.1
1.1
1.0
0.7
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.2
0.1
0.1
na
100
na
8.8
26.4
14.1
13.7
11.5
5.7
5.2
2.9
2.7
2.7
2.5
2.2
2.2
1.7
1.7
1.5
1.1
0.7
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.2
ODA
% GNI
ODA
per Capita
0.25
0.1
0.41
0.27
0.26
0.8
0.99
0.74
0.31
0.87
0.27
0.24
0.15
0.31
0.23
0.32
0.32
0.25
0.31
0.62
0.15
0.27
55
13
61
37
25
86
144
81
24
147
30
14
8
61
47
29
34
13
26
160
6
15
Note: We used the US GDP deflator to convert the current net aid flows into 1995 constant US dollars.
Aid figures are three year averages (1997-99). The difference between the total aid and the sum of
multilateral and DAC Bilateral Flows is mainly accounted for by Arab donors.
Table III. Who Receives Aid – Recipient Profile
Norway's Top Ten Recipients
Sweden's Top Ten Recipients
% of
% of
US$
Norway's
US$
Sweden's
(Millions)
ODA
(Millions)
ODA
Tanzania
46.05
7.05
Tanzania
48.91
6.81
Mozambique
44.75
6.85
Mozambique
42.91
5.97
Yugoslavia, Fed. Rep.
35.14
5.38
South Africa
35.84
4.99
Bosnia - Herzegovina
31.84
4.88
Viet Nam
32.50
4.52
Zambia
30.61
4.69
BosniaHerzegovina
27.31
3.80
Bangladesh
30.56
4.68
Ethiopia
27.27
3.79
Uganda
26.82
4.11
Bangladesh
24.84
3.46
Russia
25.39
3.89
Nicaragua
23.60
3.28
Ethiopia
25.09
3.84
Angola
21.65
3.01
Angola
21.38
3.28
Zimbabwe
19.59
2.73
Denmark's Top Ten Recipients
Finland's Top Ten Recipients
% of
US$
Denmark's
US$
% of
country
(Millions)
ODA
(Millions)
Finland's ODA
Tanzania
67.91
8.87
Russia
16.43
9.34
Uganda
59.62
7.79
China
14.31
8.14
Mozambique
40.88
5.34
Mozambique
11.72
6.67
Bangladesh
40.28
5.26
Tanzania
10.31
5.86
Viet Nam
36.31
4.74
Yugoslavia, Fed
8.27
4.70
Ghana
35.60
4.65
BosniaHerzegovina
8.22
4.67
Egypt
32.65
4.26
Nepal
8.06
4.58
India
30.84
4.03
Nicaragua
7.81
4.44
Burkina Faso
28.78
3.76
Viet Nam
7.80
4.44
South Africa
26.99
3.52
Estonia
6.67
3.79
Note: We used the US GDP deflator to convert the current net aid flows into 1995 constant US dollars.
Aid figures are three year averages (1997-99).
Table III: Loans and Grants
bilateral % of total
multilateral % of total
grants % of bilateral
loans % of bilateral
Tied aid % of bilateral
Technical co-operation % of bilateral
Developmental food aid % of bilateral
Emergency and distress relief % of bilateral
Contributions to NGOs% of bilateral
Administrative costs% of bilateral
Denmark
Finland
Norway
Sweden
59.20
40.85
99.71
0.29
29.2
8.11
0.00
8.50
0.68
8.41
57.93
42.31
118.67
-18.67
15.3
25.17
0.00
19.23
1.75
6.29
73.50
26.50
98.61
1.39
0.9
13.49
0.00
24.57
0.00
6.75
70.31
29.69
99.74
0.26
1.9
4.11
0.00
23.71
8.92
7.87
DAC
Countries
67.16
32.84
89.56
13.08
26.34
38.43
3.08
12.87
3.39
8.99
Notes: Tied aid are based on commitments (excluding technical co-operation and administrative costs).
All figures are 1999 values. Data Source: OECD (2001).
Table IV: Aid by Major Purposes
Commitments
% of bilateral
Social and Administrative infrastructure
Education a)
of which: Basic education
Health
of which: Basic health
Population b)
Water supply and sanitation
Government and civil society
Other social infrastructure/service
Economic infrastructure
Transport and communications
Energy
Other
Production
Agriculture
"Industry, mining and construction"
Trade and tourism
Multisector
Programme assistance
Debt relief c)
Emergency aid
Administrative expenses
Unspecified
TOTAL
Denmark
Finland
Norway
Sweden
45.6
1.2
0.1
14
10.4
0.1
20.1
8.4
1.9
9.4
6.6
2.5
0.2
13.2
13.2
0
0
10
1.7
0
0
10.2
9.9
100
34.2
7.4
0.2
6.4
3.5
0.5
4.6
8.2
7.2
5.3
1.1
3.6
0.6
4.9
3.9
0.9
0.1
8.3
1.4
14.1
18.3
6.7
6.8
100
43.9
10.4
6.5
5.8
2.3
2.1
3
12.8
9.8
6.5
1.7
3.1
1.7
6.7
5.1
1.4
0.2
10
0.5
2.2
21.5
5.5
3.1
100
33.8
5.8
2.9
4.2
1.2
2.7
3.6
10.5
7
9
3.4
2.6
3
3.8
3.1
0.1
0.6
6.3
1.8
2.8
23.6
7.9
11
100
TOTAL
DAC
29.9
10.7
1.2
4.2
2
1.8
4.1
4.2
4.9
17.2
8.7
4.6
3.9
8.1
5.5
2.2
0.4
7.4
6.9
7.4
11.1
5.9
6.1
100
Notes: All figures are for 1999 and they provide percentages of bilateral aid commitments.
a) Including students and trainees.
b) Population and reproductive health.
c) Including forgiveness of non-ODA debt.
Source: OECD (2001)
Table V: Aid Allocation by Donor
Ln GDP
Ln Population
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
Multi
DAC
Nordic
Norway
Denmark
Sweden
Finland
-1.525
-1.054
-1.388
-1.149
-1.087
-0.759
-0.409
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.003)***
0.265
0.351
0.415
0.366
0.402
0.374
0.370
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Trade Policy
0.002
-0.000
0.042
0.032
0.037
0.050
0.042
(BMP)
(0.515)
(0.954)
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Democracy
0.047
0.060
0.129
0.139
0.075
0.133
0.058
(0.062)*
(0.056)*
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.024)**
(0.000)***
(0.015)**
Human Rights
-0.041
-0.106
-0.240
-0.017
-0.448
-0.041
0.137
(AI)
(0.707)
(0.370)
(0.048)**
(0.879)
(0.001)***
(0.760)
(0.270)
-1.667
0.610
-0.625
0.547
UN-friend
Egypt
Israel
SS-Africa
Latin America
Catholic
Protestant
Muslim
(0.123)
(0.590)
(0.657)
(0.585)
0.847
2.306
2.127
0.371
2.944
0.626
2.755
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.184)
(0.000)***
(0.064)*
(0.000)***
-1.396
3.593
-1.115
-1.902
-1.631
-1.123
-1.189
(0.069)*
(0.000)***
(0.076)*
(0.002)***
(0.001)***
(0.223)
(0.074)*
-0.304
-0.249
0.093
0.057
0.141
-0.124
0.059
(0.199)
(0.413)
(0.799)
(0.866)
(0.716)
(0.769)
(0.837)
0.292
0.240
-0.477
-0.389
-0.809
-0.562
-0.803
(0.405)
(0.580)
(0.157)
(0.228)
(0.010)**
(0.116)
(0.001)***
-0.580
-0.351
-0.899
-1.134
-1.388
-0.405
-0.729
(0.183)
(0.506)
(0.039)**
(0.005)***
(0.001)***
(0.425)
(0.060)*
-1.079
-1.630
-2.340
-1.605
-2.806
-0.626
-1.263
(0.097)*
(0.059)*
(0.007)***
(0.065)*
(0.000)***
(0.537)
(0.056)*
0.260
0.046
-0.932
-1.391
-1.572
-0.781
-1.150
(0.270)
(0.861)
(0.016)**
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.105)
(0.001)***
Observations
296
296
301
290
270
290
288
R-squared
0.594
0.422
0.519
0.488
0.467
0.323
0.397
Note: OLS regressions with White corrected standard errors. P-values in parentheses, ***, ** and *
denote significance at the one, five and ten percent level, respectively.
Table V continued
Ln GDP
Ln Population
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
USA
UK
France
Japan
Germany
Netherlands
Canada
-1.393
-0.820
-0.287
-0.681
-0.593
-0.992
-1.120
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.010)**
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
0.060
0.526
0.609
0.674
0.520
0.454
0.541
(0.603)
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Trade Policy
-0.045
-0.001
0.011
-0.021
0.004
0.021
0.010
(BMP)
(0.000)***
(0.754)
(0.022)**
(0.000)***
(0.249)
(0.000)***
(0.089)*
Democracy
0.124
0.058
0.011
-0.000
0.077
0.123
0.022
(0.003)***
(0.024)**
(0.613)
(0.993)
(0.001)***
(0.000)***
(0.440)
Human Rights
0.131
-0.033
-0.117
-0.193
-0.031
0.059
-0.346
(AI)
(0.456)
(0.780)
(0.176)
(0.091)*
(0.726)
(0.601)
(0.004)***
UN-friend
Own colony
Other colony
Egypt
Israel
SS-Africa
Latin America
Catholic
Protestant
Muslim
2.621
2.399
3.706
6.133
5.073
1.668
2.929
(0.003)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.053)*
(0.002)***
0.598
0.574
0.777
0.000
0.137
0.812
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(.)
(0.146)
(0.000)***
0.082
-0.029
0.136
0.165
0.038
0.229
(0.441)
(0.691)
(0.014)**
(0.022)**
(0.481)
(0.000)***
4.735
0.163
2.559
0.650
1.937
1.983
1.464
(0.000)***
(0.670)
(0.000)***
(0.008)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
3.282
-4.812
0.218
-1.470
2.147
0.811
-1.057
(0.006)***
(0.000)***
(0.700)
(0.025)**
(0.001)***
(0.090)*
(0.143)
-0.267
-0.398
0.342
-1.513
0.265
0.143
-0.473
(0.595)
(0.159)
(0.141)
(0.000)***
(0.310)
(0.656)
(0.132)
0.827
-0.582
-0.150
0.251
0.019
0.751
0.603
(0.160)
(0.052)*
(0.599)
(0.404)
(0.952)
(0.022)**
(0.059)*
0.403
-0.550
1.045
-1.059
0.012
-0.237
-1.022
(0.566)
(0.133)
(0.004)***
(0.005)***
(0.971)
(0.553)
(0.011)**
-0.307
-0.890
-1.716
-1.716
-1.180
-1.916
-0.346
(0.764)
(0.247)
(0.002)***
(0.012)**
(0.034)**
(0.007)***
(0.668)
0.635
-1.063
0.432
-0.848
0.161
-0.868
-0.535
(0.205)
(0.001)***
(0.105)
(0.009)***
(0.537)
(0.010)**
(0.116)
Observations
259
286
289
284
286
287
290
R-squared
0.456
0.661
0.721
0.607
0.563
0.521
0.504
Note: OLS regressions with White corrected standard errors. P-values in parentheses, ***, ** and *
denote significance at the one, five and ten percent level, respectively. All regressions include time
dummies.
Table VI. Nordic Aid to LICUS (Low Income Countries Under Stress)15
LICUS pilot countries (03/04)
Donor (rank) average 01/02
Angola
Norway (5), Sweden (7)
Guinea-Bissau
Sweden (6)
Haiti
Liberia
Papua New Guinea
Somalia
Norway (4), Sweden (8)
Sudan
Norway (5), Sweden (10)
Tajikistan
Zimbabwe
Denmark (6), Norway (8), Sweden (9)
Comoros
Central African Republic
Burundi
Togo
15
LICUS as defined by the World Bank (2004).
Norway(7)
Table VII: Tobit Results
Ln GDP
Ln Population
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
Multi
DAC
Nordic
Norway
Denmark
Sweden
Finland
-1.530
-1.059
-1.485
-1.401
-1.360
-0.948
-0.534
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.001)***
0.263
0.349
0.436
0.432
0.479
0.444
0.430
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Trade Policy
0.002
-0.000
0.042
0.035
0.041
0.054
0.044
(BMP)
(0.796)
(0.966)
(0.001)***
(0.003)***
(0.005)***
(0.001)***
(0.000)***
Democracy
0.048
0.061
0.137
0.156
0.101
0.157
0.085
(0.034)**
(0.020)**
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.010)***
(0.000)***
(0.006)***
Human Rights
-0.038
-0.104
-0.234
-0.031
-0.443
-0.015
0.164
AI
(0.664)
(0.307)
(0.049)**
(0.786)
(0.003)***
(0.922)
(0.160)
-0.984
1.764
0.376
1.332
UN-friend
Egypt
Israel
SS-Africa
Latin America
Catholic
Protestant
Muslim
Observations
(0.374)
(0.208)
(0.833)
(0.350)
0.861
2.321
2.199
0.512
3.243
0.779
2.823
(0.134)
(0.001)***
(0.005)***
(0.480)
(0.000)***
(0.433)
(0.000)***
-1.393
3.598
-0.952
-1.858
-2.433
-0.298
-0.859
(0.025)**
(0.000)***
(0.255)
(0.040)**
(0.058)*
(0.829)
(0.453)
-0.286
-0.231
0.130
0.057
0.298
-0.156
0.126
(0.253)
(0.420)
(0.698)
(0.857)
(0.470)
(0.722)
(0.697)
0.323
0.271
-0.331
-0.221
-0.672
-0.434
-0.786
(0.221)
(0.373)
(0.343)
(0.513)
(0.120)
(0.351)
(0.025)**
-0.611
-0.381
-1.012
-1.219
-1.515
-0.602
-0.794
(0.065)*
(0.323)
(0.022)**
(0.005)***
(0.004)***
(0.308)
(0.072)*
-1.131
-1.686
-2.482
-1.708
-3.519
-0.652
-1.387
(0.043)**
(0.009)***
(0.001)***
(0.019)**
(0.000)***
(0.514)
(0.063)*
0.260
0.047
-0.970
-1.494
-1.742
-0.880
-1.096
(0.363)
(0.889)
(0.012)**
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.087)*
(0.004)***
296
296
301
290
270
290
288
Note: Tobit regressions. P-values in parentheses, ***, ** and * denote significance at the one, five and
ten percent level, respectively.
Table VIII: SURE Results
(1)
(2)
Multi
DAC
Multi
DAC
Nordic
Ln GDP
-1.497
-1.047
-1.495
-1.042
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Ln Population
0.272
0.349
0.270
0.339
0.428
non Nordic
-1.286
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Trade Policy
0.003
-0.000
0.003
-0.003
0.042
(BMP)
(0.760)
(0.971)
(0.749)
(0.781)
(0.000)***
Democracy
0.049
0.064
0.054
0.065
0.140
(0.026)**
(0.014)**
(0.013)**
(0.011)**
(0.000)***
-0.039
-0.103
-0.057
-0.111
-0.240
(0.647)
(0.304)
(0.494)
(0.265)
(0.038)**
Human Rights
Egypt
Israel
SS-Africa
Latin America
Catholic
Protestant
Muslim
0.848
2.320
0.882
2.346
2.192
(0.126)
(0.000)***
(0.106)
(0.000)***
(0.003)***
-1.523
3.556
-1.557
3.585
-1.388
(0.012)**
(0.000)***
(0.009)***
(0.000)***
(0.088)*
-0.298
-0.235
-0.283
-0.276
0.238
(0.220)
(0.411)
(0.236)
(0.331)
(0.469)
0.223
0.231
0.249
0.218
-0.348
(0.387)
(0.449)
(0.326)
(0.469)
(0.317)
-0.639
-0.342
-0.614
-0.301
-1.128
(0.048)**
(0.369)
(0.054)*
(0.425)
(0.010)***
-1.223
-1.661
-1.280
-1.648
-2.437
(0.023)**
(0.009)***
(0.016)**
(0.009)***
(0.001)***
0.165
0.048
0.161
0.085
-1.055
(0.554)
(0.884)
(0.557)
(0.794)
(0.005)***
Observations
292
292
290
290
290
Test of
χ2(1)=180.27
χ2(3)=293.45
Independence
(0.0000)
(0.0000)
Note: Zellner’s seemingly unrelated regressions. P-values in parentheses, ***, ** and * denote
significance at the one, five and ten percent level, respectively.
Appendix
Donor Countries:
Development Assistance Committee (DAC) consists of the following 22 member
countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway,
Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States.
Recipient Countries:
Part I (Developing Countries and Territories),
Afghanistan, Albania, Algeria, Angola, Anguilla, Antigua snd Barbuda, Argentina,
Argentina, Armenia, Aruba, Azerbaijan, Bahamas, Bahrain, Bangladesh, Barbados,
Belize, Benin, Bhutan, Bolivia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Botswana, Brazil, Brunei,
Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cambodia, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Cayman Islands, Central
African Republic, Chad, Chile, China, Chinese Taipei, Colombia, Comoros,
Democratic Republic of the Congo, Congo, Cook Islands, Costa Rica, Croatia, Cuba,
Cyprus, Côte d'Ivoire, Djibouti, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Timor (East),
Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Equatorial Guinea, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Ex-Yugoslavia,
Falkland Islands, Fiji, French Polynesia, Gabon, Gambia, Georgia, Ghana, Gibraltar,
Grenada, Guatemala, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Hong Kong,
China, India, Indonesia, Indus Basin, Iran, Iraq, Israel, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakstan,
Kenya, Kiribati, Korea, Democratic Republic of Korea, Kuwait, Kyrgyz Republic,
Laos, Lebanon, Lesotho, Liberia, Libya, Macao, Macedonia (former Yugoslav
Republic), Madagascar, Malawi, Malaysia, Maldives, Mali, Malta, Marshall Islands,
Mauritania, Mauritius, Mayotte, Mekong Delta Project, Mexico, Micronesia,
Fed.States, Moldova, Mongolia, Montserrat, Morocco, Mozambique, Myanmar,
Namibia, Nauru, Nepal, Netherlands Antilles, New Caledonia, Nicaragua, Niger,
Nigeria, Niue, Northern Marianas Ilands., Oman, Pakistan, Palau, Palestinian
Administrated Areas, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Peru, Philippines,
Qatar, Rwanda, Samoa, Sao Tome and Principe, Saudi Arabia, Senegal, Seychelles,
Sierra Leone, Singapore, Slovenia, Solomon Islands, Somalia, South Africa , Sri
Lanka, St. Helena, St. Kitts-Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent and Gr., Sudan, Suriname,
Swaziland, Syria, Tajikistan, Tanzania, Thailand, Togo, Tokelau, Tonga, Trinidad and
Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Turkmenistan, Turks and Caicos Islands, Tuvalu, Uganda,
United Arab Emirates, Uruguay, Uzbekistan, Vanuatu, Venezuela, Viet Nam, Virgin
Islands (U.K.), Wallis and Futuna, Yemen, Yugoslavia, Federal Republic of Zambia
and Zimbabwe.
Part II (More Advanced Developing Countries and Territories, CEECs and
NISs)
Bahamas*, Bermuda**, Brunei**, Cayman Islands**, Chinese Taipei**, Cyprus**,
Falkland Islands**, Hong Kong, Israel**, Kuwait*, Qatar*, Singapore*, United Arab
Emirates*, Belarus, Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania,
Moldova, Poland, Romania, Russia, Slovak Republic and Ukraine.
Note: Countries marked * (**) countries transferred to Part II of the list of recipients
on 1st January 1996 (1st January 1997).
Descriptive Statistics
Variable
Obs
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min
Max
ln aid Multi
295
3.994493
1.691126
-2.302585
7.499106
ln aid DAC
295
4.981449
1.642774
-2.302585
8.046826
ln aid Nordic
301
1.388836
2.067621
-2.746202
5.783576
ln aid Norway
300
.1258485
1.871366
-3.267433
4.434826
ln aid Denmark
281
.0244244
2.1202
-6.242906
4.502431
ln aid Sweden
300
.1616112
2.046517
-2.302585
4.742642
ln aid Finland
298
-.7686568
1.657275
-3.286446
3.916511
ln aid USA
266
2.652011
2.248561
-2.302585
7.539036
ln aid UK
296
1.08997
2.067972
-2.688248
5.417122
ln aid France
299
2.279297
1.802724
-2.302585
6.239629
ln aid Japan
293
2.789519
1.978212
-2.302585
7.039991
ln aid Germany
294
2.990328
1.467749
-2.302585
6.384249
ln aid Netherlands
297
1.399527
1.784591
-2.302585
5.026023
ln aid Canada
300
1.31594
1.740259
-2.302585
4.843287
ln GDP
301
7.492099
.8610504
5.700444
9.904387
(ln GDP)2
301
56.87049
13.08573
32.49506
98.09689
ln Population
301
16.22056
1.515608
13.24458
20.91389
BMP
301
109.7522
701.5169
-89.16
11662.38
Democracy
301
3.033223
3.743291
0
10
UN-friend UK
290
.171524
.2066543
-.2614399
.9453666
UN-friend US
290
-.3878603
.3399373
-.8622133
.8511644
UN-friend France
290
.297018
.1528049
-.1190089
.918759
UN-friend Japan
290
.6968468
.1357362
.2490123
1
UN-friend Germany
290
.4980488
.1776126
-.0526277
1
UN-friend Sweden
290
.8333317
.1047406
.1643767
1
UN-friend Finland
290
.8332932
.1159606
.1581469
1
UN-friend Norway
290
.6881542
.1069672
.1435359
1
UN-friend Denmark
290
.6747575
.0969902
.1675813
.9809415
UN-friend Netherlands
290
.5099341
.1355987
.0410541
1
UN-friend Canada
290
.527515
.1638131
-.1033741
1
Human Rights AI
301
2.954873
.8966183
1
5
Human Rights US
301
2.728405
.9293629
1
5
Catholic
301
.3452824
.3633995
0
.966
Protestant
301
.1151296
.1532783
0
.715
Muslim
301
.285711
.3738647
0
.998
Correlation Coefficients
ln aid DAC
ln aid Multi
ln aid DAC
0.7333
1.0000
ln aid Nordic
ln GDP
ln aid Nordic
0.6629
0.6134
1.0000
ln GDP
-0.6633
-0.3359
-0.4822
1.0000
(ln GDP)
2
(ln GDP)2
Ln Pop.
BMP
-0.6776
-0.3507
-0.4930
0.9977
1.0000
ln Population
0.3685
0.4274
0.3749
-0.0040
-0.0118
1.0000
BMP
-0.0120
-0.0294
0.0851
-0.0044
-0.0081
-0.0185
1.0000
Democracy
-0.1316
0.0722
0.0404
0.3497
0.3367
0.0292
-0.0744
UN-friend UK
-0.0749
-0.0062
-0.1177
0.1537
0.1567
-0.0861
-0.1375
UN-friend US
-0.1793
-0.0314
-0.2274
0.1428
0.1488
-0.1286
-0.0780
UN-friend France
-0.0353
0.0282
-0.0864
0.1210
0.1214
-0.0796
-0.1365
UN-friend Japan
0.1239
0.0359
-0.0179
0.0081
0.0039
-0.0439
-0.1602
UN-friend Germany
0.0046
0.0237
0.0563
0.1639
0.1643
0.0059
-0.1422
UN-friend Sweden
0.3254
0.1751
0.0941
-0.2682
-0.2795
-0.1225
-0.0123
UN-friend Finland
0.2822
0.1085
0.0545
-0.2639
-0.2735
-0.1282
0.0250
UN-friend Norway
0.1936
0.1534
0.0128
-0.0533
-0.0596
-0.1037
-0.1434
UN-friend Denmark
0.2269
0.2099
0.0442
-0.0640
-0.0716
-0.1156
-0.1391
UN-friend Netherl.
0.0230
0.0583
-0.0913
0.0745
0.0735
-0.1293
-0.1409
UN-friend Canada
0.0561
0.0819
-0.0064
0.0999
0.0996
-0.0650
-0.1905
Human Rights AI
0.2044
0.2198
0.0605
-0.0182
-0.0227
0.4810
0.0820
Human Rights US
0.2656
0.2237
0.2061
-0.1527
-0.1580
0.4893
0.1630
Democracy
UN-friend
UN-friend
UN-friend
UN-friend
UN-friend
UN-friend
UK
US
France
Japan
Germany
Sweden
UN-friend UK
0.1772
1.0000
UN-friend US
0.0467
0.8567
1.0000
UN-friend France
0.2008
0.9677
0.8029
1.0000
UN-friend Japan
0.0876
0.8119
0.5753
0.7772
1.0000
UN-friend
0.3009
0.5846
0.2267
0.6171
0.4602
1.0000
-0.0585
0.1050
-0.0340
0.1920
0.4229
-0.1314
1.0000
-0.1371
0.0472
-0.0133
0.1133
0.3592
-0.3000
0.9692
0.1544
0.7232
0.4485
0.7511
0.8825
0.4268
0.6860
0.1998
0.5589
0.2433
0.6236
0.7235
0.4211
0.7621
0.1759
0.9467
0.7554
0.9669
0.8533
0.5792
0.3633
0.2575
0.8454
0.5199
0.8075
0.8696
0.7319
0.2151
Germany
UN-friend
Sweden
UN-friend
Finland
UN-friend
Norway
UN-friend
Denmark
UN-friend
Netherlands
UN-friend
Canada
Human Rights AI
-0.0605
-0.0688
-0.0441
-0.0870
-0.0334
-0.0140
-0.1074
Human
-0.1006
-0.2171
-0.2523
-0.2254
-0.1578
0.0006
-0.1314
UN-friend
UN-friend
UN-friend
UN-friend
UN-friend
Human
Human
Finland
Norway
Denmark
Netherlands
Canada
Rights AI
Rights US
Rights
US
UN-friend
0.5833
1.0000
0.6389
0.9493
1.0000
0.2782
0.8710
0.7610
1.0000
0.0848
0.8364
0.7392
0.8559
Norway
UN-friend
Denmark
UN-friend
Netherlands
UN-friend Canada
1.0000
Human Rights AI
-0.1050
-0.0674
-0.0726
-0.0886
-0.0252
1.0000
Human Rights US
-0.1386
-0.1640
-0.1309
-0.2278
-0.1036
0.8665
1.0000
Table Va: Aid Allocation by Donor (US State Department Human Rights data)
Ln GDP
Ln Population
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
Multi
DAC
Nordic
Norway
Denmark
Sweden
Finland
-1.552
-1.188
-1.344
-1.104
-1.026
-0.664
-0.350
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.001)***
(0.009)***
0.279
0.376
0.426
0.366
0.390
0.374
0.362
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Trade Policy
0.005
0.003
0.042
0.031
0.039
0.047
0.039
(BMP)
(0.223)
(0.684)
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Democracy
0.047
0.051
0.117
0.132
0.059
0.119
0.054
(0.061)*
(0.104)
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.082)*
(0.001)***
(0.022)**
-0.168
-0.226
-0.151
0.012
-0.312
0.051
0.163
(0.128)
(0.064)*
(0.195)
(0.911)
(0.031)**
(0.692)
(0.157)
-1.685
0.298
-0.762
0.548
Human Rights
UN-friend
Egypt
Israel
SS-Africa
Latin America
Catholic
Protestant
Muslim
(0.120)
(0.798)
(0.572)
(0.585)
0.800
2.178
2.125
0.351
2.961
0.685
2.781
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.206)
(0.000)***
(0.045)**
(0.000)***
-1.450
3.733
-1.150
-1.933
-1.886
-1.171
-1.158
(0.051)*
(0.000)***
(0.061)*
(0.001)***
(0.000)***
(0.193)
(0.074)*
-0.403
-0.467
0.219
0.067
0.313
0.031
0.075
(0.050)*
(0.092)*
(0.526)
(0.831)
(0.388)
(0.938)
(0.781)
0.193
0.028
-0.259
-0.309
-0.631
-0.314
-0.741
(0.531)
(0.944)
(0.390)
(0.282)
(0.028)**
(0.306)
(0.001)***
-0.399
-0.107
-1.099
-1.221
-1.607
-0.574
-0.750
(0.303)
(0.826)
(0.007)***
(0.001)***
(0.000)***
(0.239)
(0.041)**
-1.164
-1.513
-2.364
-1.668
-2.959
-0.951
-1.430
(0.057)*
(0.063)*
(0.003)***
(0.042)**
(0.000)***
(0.313)
(0.024)**
0.310
0.100
-0.996
-1.387
-1.717
-0.811
-1.118
(0.179)
(0.703)
(0.008)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.083)*
(0.002)***
Observations
308
308
313
301
281
301
299
R-squared
0.599
0.447
0.531
0.492
0.462
0.318
0.400
Note: OLS regressions with White corrected standard errors. P-values in parentheses, ***, ** and *
denote significance at the one, five and ten percent level, respectively.
Table Va continued …
Ln GDP
Ln Population
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
USA
UK
France
Japan
Germany
Netherlands
Canada
-1.272
-0.788
-0.304
-0.742
-0.617
-0.951
-1.111
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.008)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
0.015
0.537
0.623
0.713
0.566
0.468
0.567
(0.893)
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Trade Policy
-0.049
-0.002
0.013
-0.018
0.006
0.019
0.013
(BMP)
(0.000)***
(0.666)
(0.002)***
(0.000)***
(0.107)
(0.000)***
(0.029)**
Democracy
0.121
0.043
0.008
-0.026
0.070
0.104
0.003
(0.002)***
(0.084)*
(0.695)
(0.279)
(0.003)***
(0.000)***
(0.915)
0.198
-0.091
-0.166
-0.278
-0.092
0.064
-0.327
(0.263)
(0.471)
(0.042)**
(0.022)**
(0.297)
(0.572)
(0.005)***
2.637
2.327
3.674
6.083
5.008
1.657
2.634
(0.003)***
(0.001)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.061)*
(0.007)***
0.580
0.536
0.794
0.000
0.158
0.785
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(.)
(0.082)*
(0.000)***
0.063
-0.084
0.156
0.125
0.048
0.202
(0.517)
(0.253)
(0.003)***
(0.069)*
(0.366)
(0.000)***
4.842
0.099
2.550
0.547
1.939
1.993
1.492
(0.000)***
(0.782)
(0.000)***
(0.022)**
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
(0.000)***
Human Rights
UN-friend
Own colony
Other colony
Egypt
Israel
SS-Africa
Latin America
Catholic
Protestant
Muslim
3.108
-4.713
0.142
-1.281
2.284
0.980
-1.095
(0.009)***
(0.000)***
(0.784)
(0.045)**
(0.000)***
(0.035)**
(0.074)*
-0.182
-0.296
0.336
-1.484
0.317
0.229
-0.339
(0.695)
(0.286)
(0.127)
(0.000)***
(0.212)
(0.460)
(0.258)
0.747
-0.492
-0.115
0.387
0.161
0.927
0.820
(0.153)
(0.077)*
(0.658)
(0.180)
(0.577)
(0.003)***
(0.007)***
0.411
-0.603
1.038
-1.210
0.013
-0.376
-1.179
(0.509)
(0.083)*
(0.002)***
(0.001)***
(0.968)
(0.332)
(0.003)***
-0.985
-1.078
-1.887
-1.413
-1.293
-2.036
-0.681
(0.338)
(0.120)
(0.000)***
(0.030)**
(0.014)**
(0.002)***
(0.380)
0.595
-0.921
0.374
-0.836
0.160
-0.849
-0.670
(0.232)
(0.004)***
(0.136)
(0.008)***
(0.533)
(0.014)**
(0.045)**
Observations
270
297
300
295
297
298
301
R-squared
0.438
0.644
0.736
0.620
0.589
0.532
0.515
Note: OLS regressions with White corrected standard errors. P-values in parentheses, ***, ** and *
denote significance at the one, five and ten percent level, respectively.
Data Sources:
Aid
Average aid received in constant 1995 US Dollars (millions) over each five year
period. Following Alesina and Dollar we added 0.1 to each observation before taking
logarithms. Source: OECD 2001.
Population
Total population. Source: WDI 2001.
Trade Policy (Black Market Premium)
We measure openness to trade by taking the parallel (‘black’) market premium. In
order to make the coefficients easier to compare we multiplied the premium by 100.
Source: Global Development Network. www.worldbank.org\research\gdn
Democracy
We used the democracy score from the Polity IV data set which measures openness of
political institutions on a scale of 1 to 10, with higher values indicating more
democratic regimes. For further documentation see Jaggers and Gurr (1995).
Human Rights
We use two measures of human rights violations, one is based on information
published by Amnesty International the other is based on US State Department
information. The index ranges from 1 to 5, with higher values indicating worse human
rights. Source: Cornett and Gibney, 2004.
UN-friends
Based on UN voting patterns, the UN-friend index ranges from -1 to 1, with higher
values indicating more similar voting patterns. Source: Gartzke and Jo (2000).
Religious Affiliations
Catholic, Protestant and Muslim denote the percentage of the population in a country
who declared in a survey that they follow a particular religion. We used data from
1980. Source: Barratt (1982)
Colonies
Dummies indicate whether a recipient was a former colony. Source: Burnside and
Dollar (2000).
Regions
Regional dummies for Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America were taken from
Burnside and Dollar (2000).