Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
Farm sustainability assessment: some procedural issues
M. Andreolia,*, R. Rossib, V. Tellarinic
b
a
University of Pisa, Dip. Economia aziendale,Via C. Ridol® 10, 56124 Pisa, Italy
Tuscany Region, Dip. delle Politiche Territoriali e Ambientali, Area Tutela e valorizzazione delle risorse ambientali,
Via di Novoli 26, 50127 Florence, Italy
c
University of Pisa, Dip. Economia dell'Agricoltura dell'Ambiente Agro-forestale e del Territorio,
Via del Borghetto 80, 56124, Pisa, Italy
Abstract
This article discusses some procedural issues relating to a multicriterial assessment of farm sustainability, based on the
criteria proposed by the European Union Concerted Action on `The Landscape and Nature Production Capacity of
Sustainable/Organic Types of Agriculture'. Two main problems are stressed: (1) the treatment of basic information used for
evaluating farm performances as regards the criteria; and (2) the dif®culties in evaluating a case-study farm. Firstly, the
problem of implementing multicriterial analyses when using qualitative ordinal data and discrete quantitative data is faced,
stressing the importance of clearly de®ning and applying procedures that can be transferred and repeated. This is due to the
fact that almost all research contributions describe in detail multicriterial methods and results, but give little space to the
problem of collecting and analysing basic information. Nevertheless, ®nal results heavily depend on the way basic data has
been gathered and processed in order to obtain the indices that have been used for the assessment. The lack of standards and of
procedure description hampers the comparison of assessments and the possibility to judge their suitability to the aim of farm
sustainability assessment. Secondly, the problem of ®nding external points of reference for judging a case-study farm is
confronted. Case-studies can be important as `models' for other farms. Indeed, it is easier to persuade farmers to adopt farming
styles and decisions that somebody else has already successfully implemented rather than to adopt unexplored ways of
managing their farms. This asks for reliable methods to assess a single farm, but almost all multicriterial methods only provide
a tool for ranking a set of objects, e.g. farms, from the best to the worst. Conclusions provide some comments on the
usefulness of these approaches. # 1999 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Sustainable farming; Multicriterial analysis; Tuscany; Landscape production; Italy; Case-study assessment
1. Introduction
The use of multidimensional approaches, e.g. based
on multicriterial analysis, has been a major improve*
Corresponding author. Tel.: 39-050945315; fax: 39050541403.
E-mail addresses:
[email protected] (M. Andreoli),
[email protected] (R. Rossi),
[email protected] (V. Tellarini)
0169-2046/99/$20.00 # 1999 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 1 6 9 - 2 0 4 6 ( 9 9 ) 0 0 0 4 5 - 6
ment in respect to reductionistic approaches typical of
a culture too much based on specialisation (Tellarini
et al., paper presented at the EU Concerted Action on
Landscape and Nature Production Capacity meeting
held in Wageningen, 1996). Studying phenomena
from a holistic point of view means taking into
account all their relevant facets. Although a holistic
approach consents to achieve a full understanding of
the phenomena, it asks for tools capable of coping
42
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
with multidimensional problems. From an application
point of view, the importance of a multidimensional
approach in setting up interventions for agriculture is
apparent when considering that policies aiming to
steer agricultural production or to subsidise farms
do not only affect economic and productive results
but also affect, e.g. the quality of environment and
landscape. The effects of farming on environmental
pollution and landscape quality have been studied in
Italy, e.g. by Pennacchi, 1994, 1998; Accademia
Nazionale di Agricoltura, 1991; Chiusoli, 1994. Policies having only one aim, such as supporting farmers'
income as the `old' common agricultural policy
(CAP), have often resulted not only in reaching,
and sometimes only partially, the intended goal, but
they have caused other unforeseen `side-effects'.
According to Croci-Angelini (1995), CAP has resulted
in deepening regional disparities, while Baldock
and Beaufoy (1993) concluded that rationalised
intensive agriculture has been associated with
damage and destruction of the environment, natural
and seminatural habitats and (visual) landscapes. The
negative effects that can result from farming have
increased the need for sustainable farming practices.
A review of the meaning and evolution of sustainability in agriculture has been recently provided by
Polinori (1998).
A checklist for `Sustainable Landscape Management' has been produced as the ®nal report of the EU
Concerted Action on `The Landscape and Nature
Production Capacity of Sustainable/Organic Types
of Agriculture' (van Mansvelt and van der Lubbe,
1999). This checklist provides an inventory of indices
that might be relevant when analysing farming activity
impacts. These criteria, ``using a unifying concept
derived from Maslow's study on human motivation
translated to the landscape and perceived as a re¯ection of the priorities and motivations leading the
actions of people'' (van Mansvelt and van der Lubbe,
1999), have been organised in six main ®elds: (1)
environment, (2) ecology, (3) economy, (4) sociology,
(5) psychology, and (6) physiognomy/cultural geography. Due to the variety of relevant ®elds, sustainable
farming has to be analysed using a multidimensional
approach. This, however, implies the need to cope
with criteria expressed in different units of measurement and with data that are not homogeneous as regard
to the level of precision. This asks, ®rst of all, for a
very careful treatment of the data used for building the
indices on which to base the ®nal assessment of farm
performance, and, secondly, for a rational choice of
the methodology to be used for reaching an `overall
judgement' (Colorni and Laniado, 1988, 1992). In this
context, `overall judgement' indicates a summary of
all the performance that the object of the analysis has
shown for all the relevant criteria.
This article attempts to systemise a series of considerations relating to the above problems, which
where stimulated by some of the contributions of
the members of the EU Concerted Action on Landscape and Nature Production.
2. The importance of `a priori' clarification of
rules and procedures
According to Tellarini (1995), in social science
empirical research it is possible to distinguish two
different phases: the ®rst, called `private phase', which
concerns research organisation, data gathering, data
veri®cation and data processing; and the second,
called `public phase', which involves summarising
and commenting results. The ®rst phase is de®ned
as private, because it is very seldom fully described by
the researcher, since this would take too much space,
especially in the case of a multidisciplinary and multicriterial approach. Thus, when presenting multicriterial analyses, quite often only the list of criteria that
have been used is provided, without giving any explanation on the way the basic data have been gathered
and transformed into indices (e.g. environmental
impact criteria in Ciani et al., 1993). According to
Colorni and Laniado (1992), the Environmental
Impact Assessments performed during the 1980s
``were, in fact, more `surveys' than assessments.
Moreover, such `surveys' were performed according
to different points of view, with no reference to a
common standard: this makes comparison of different
studies dif®cult and, even, worse, means that it is often
impossible for a public authority to really check the
adequacy of the impact study.'' In the same way, the
lack of a common standard and of the information
needed for fully understanding how criteria have been
built does not allow a rational use of many of the
studies on the impact of farmers' choices, especially
on non-economic parameters. Consequently, although
43
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
the importance of `a priori' clari®cation of rules
relating to a scienti®c method may seem an obvious
concern, nevertheless, in our opinion, it is important to
underline that:
The use of qualitative data requires greater
attention in the description of hypotheses adopted
and of the procedure used for building criteria,
since qualitative data are more difficult to interpret
objectively than quantitative data. In other words,
in our opinion, it is easier to evaluate the difference
between a 1000 and a 2000 Euro monthly income
than to judge how great is the difference between a
good or a normal level of ``offer of sensory
qualities, such as colours, smells and sounds.'';
Although it is very seldom possible to fully
describe in an article the procedures leading to
the building of criteria used for an assessment,
nevertheless it is necessary that before starting an
analysis researchers fully state the procedures for
gathering and processing basic information. These
procedures should accommodate for the specific
requirements of qualitative and quantitative data
processing. If, during the analysis, one or several
procedures would demonstrate not to be suitable, it
is necessary to go back and start over again.
Following a stated procedure ensures consistency
in data gathering and processing.
2.1. The problem of processing qualitative data
When facing a multicriterial analysis, researchers
very often have to cope with qualitative variables.
Many of the parameters proposed by the EU Concerted Action members for evaluating farm performance (van Mansvelt and van der Lubbe, 1999), such
as landscape completeness or wholeness, are qualitative. Moreover, in many cases the cost of quantitative
information is so high that, although it might be
possible to measure a phenomenon exactly, it is preferable to use a `discrete scale' (e.g. income classes)
rather than a continuous scale, or even to use qualitative data, provided that they can be ordered
(Andreoli and Tellarini, 1999).
In the latter case, researchers have to translate
qualitative ordinal information into numerical codes
due to the requirements of software for multicriterial
analysis. However, researchers should remember that
only methods capable to cope with qualitative ordinal
data, e.g. concordance absolute index, would give
correct results. For building concordance indices it
is necessary to compare every possible pair of objects
for each criterion and to check if the ®rst has a better,
worse or equal performance than the other ones
(Colorni and Laniado, 1992). Consequently, this
method cannot be used when the analysis is performed
on one case-study. The problem of dealing with only a
single case-study farm will be discussed later.
Let us take the case of erosion in the analysis of two
case-study farms (see Rossi et al., 1997; Rossi and
Nota, 1999). The erosion analysis was performed by
using a ®ve-step scale, since the quality of information
was judged insuf®cient for a ®ner scale, where each
step was represented by a symbol that was associated
to a real situation. The observed situations and associated symbols were the following:
Clear absence of erosion:
Absence of erosion with some uncertainty:
Minimal erosion (without consequences):
Moderate erosion: ÿ
Severe erosion: ÿÿ
When transforming qualitative ordinal data into
numerical codes and processing them with multicriterial methods, researchers should make sure that: (1)
numerical codes are attributed in a rational way,
ranking qualitative data, e.g. from the best to the
worst, and attributing to them decreasing, or increasing, numerical codes; and (2) the method used for
performing multicriterial analysis is suitable for processing qualitative ordinal information, as in the case
of concordance absolute index method.
In the above-described erosion case (Rossi et al.,
1997; Rossi and Nota, 1999), provided that data are
considered qualitative ordinal, the translation into
numerical codes of the symbols can be done as
follows:
Symbol
Value
1.00
0.75
0.50
ÿ
0.25
ÿÿ
0.00
In this case, values have been obtained by giving
score `1' to the best situation and score `0' to the worst
one and ®nding the three intermediate values in such a
way that the scale has a `constant stepping'. This
method is very similar to normalisation procedures,
44
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
which will be described later. However, when transforming qualitative ordinal data, it is only important
that numerical codes can allow ranking situations
from the best to the worst, independently from how
much a situation differs from the next one. Thus, any
scale with decreasing or increasing values can be
accepted, independently from the `stepping'.
2.2. Using continuous or discrete quantitative data
If in the case of erosion, the above symbols represent a quantitative phenomenon expressed as a discrete scale, the proposed conversion would no longer
be correct, insofar as the situation of clear absence of
erosion with some uncertainty is much closer to that
of clear absence of erosion than to that of minimal
erosion (Andreoli et al., 1998). Again, this difference
is smaller than that between moderate erosion and
severe erosion. In other words, the proposed numerical
conversion is correct only if erosion data are processed
as qualitative ordinal data. If the initial information is
processed as quantitative data, the scale between clear
absence of erosion and severe erosion must be divided
in a way that more correctly re¯ects the differences in
the impact of the erosion levels (Andreoli and Tellarini, 1999). Fig. 1 provides a graphical representation
of a possible numerical conversion of the above
symbols in the case of qualitative ordinal information
(graphic on the left-hand side) and quantitative information (graphic on the right-hand side).
2.3. From indices expressed in physical units to
indices expressed in terms of `Utility'
Performing a multicriterial analysis based on continuous quantitative data implies confronting the problem that criteria are expressed in different units of
measurement. Measurement units are not relevant if
data are qualitative ordinal, because they are used only
to compare, for each criterion, if one object of the
analysis has a better, worse or equal performance than
another. On the contrary, in the case of quantitative
data it should be taken into account how much a value
differs from another. If all values are transformed into
a common unit of measurement, by means of normalisation or other procedures, it is possible to reach an
`overall judgement' for every object of analysis by
summing up all the values it has scored for the relevant
criteria.
One of the most common ways for normalising the
values of a criterion (Colorni and Laniado, 1988)
consists:
(a) in giving score 0 to the lowest value observed
value in the analysis for that criterion;
(b) in giving score 100 to the highest observed in
the analysis for that criterion;
Fig. 1. Conversion of symbols relating to real situations into numerical codes, in the case of qualitative ordinal (A) and quantitative discrete
(B) data.
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
(c) in calculating all the intermediate values by
means of a linear transformation.
This kind of normalisation has the advantage of
always obtaining, for each criterion, positive values
ranging from 0 to 100, but it is subject to two main
criticisms. First of all, the normalised value given to an
object is strictly dependent on which other objects are
considered in the analysis; in other words, normalised
values for a group of objects for analysis could change
if a new object is added or if one of the previous is
eliminated from the analysis (Colorni and Laniado,
1988). Secondly, as seen in the above-described example of erosion, very seldom a linear and automatic
transformation of values consents to adequately represent differences existing between `real situations'.
Conversion of data expressed in physical units into
a common measurement unit can also be done by
transforming criteria into goals or `objectives' (Colorni and Laniado, 1992). This means expressing criteria in terms of `satisfaction' or `utility' resulting
from the physical value of the criterion itself, e.g.
evaluating the satisfaction resulting from one, or
several, levels of farm incomes or from varying levels
of pollutant concentration rather than measuring them
in thousands of Euro or in ppm. Thus, rather than
transforming criteria in monetary terms, as in the case
of cost-bene®ts analysis (Dasguta and Pearce, 1975),
the common unit of measure chosen is `Utility'. The
concept of Utility is often used in economic analysis,
e.g. in describing consumers' behaviour. Indeed, while
entrepreneurs are supposed to aim to pro®t maximisation, consumers are supposed to aim at maximising the
utility resulting from the consumption of products and
services (Samuelson and Nordhaus, 1993). When
parameters are expressed in terms of Utility, high
values have always a `positive meaning' and low
values have a `negative meaning', while this is not
true if working with physical units. From this point of
view, working with Utility values is easier, because it
is not necessary to remember how an index is de®ned
(or calculated) for knowing if a high value is desirable,
or not.
When it is possible to set a target (e.g. an optimal
share of fodder crops or a satisfactory level of income)
for every parameter, the transformation of conventional data into Utility can be done by giving score `1'
when the target is achieved and score `0' when it is
45
not. Since this method provides a too rough measurement scale Ð only two values are allowed Ð it is
usually necessary to ®nd an alternative procedure.
When quantitative continuous physical data are available, it is possible to have a Utility function that is
continuous, rather than dichotomous. Given that the
relationship between physical and utility values is very
seldom linear, it is necessary to de®ne it case by case.
Between the concentration of a pollutant in ppm
(parameter in physical terms) and the Utility associated with it, for example, there is an inverse relationship so that as pollution increases, Utility decreases.
This relationship is not linear, since it is assumed that
the level of pollution has no negative effects on the
environment, as long as it is very limited. As the
pollutant concentration increases, the quality of the
environment worsens, at ®rst quite slowly and then
ever more rapidly. In other cases, for example when
the density of a natural population is involved, there is
no consistently positive or negative relationship
between the physical parameter (e.g. expressed as
number of animal/ha) and the Utility value. When
the density is low its increase determines an increase
in Utility, in that the species is reaching optimum
density levels; then there is a range of optimum
density within which the Utility function maintains
its maximum level, but beyond which the satisfaction
level decreases again (Andreoli and Tellarini, 1999).
The use of Utility function could be criticised in so
far as there could be subjectivity in building them. As
Bosshard (1997) states ``experiences in landscape
planning, especially in the last few years, con®rm
epistemological consideration, viz. that a model for
evaluating cannot be `objective' Ð in the sense of
being generally valid. Rather, every validation is
individually dependent on at least the following three
premises:
temporary, culturally dependent ideas of values;
the prevailing physical situation;
the personal standpoint of the participants, including that of the experts, with respect to the presentation of the problem.''
This statement does not only apply to the problem
of building Utility functions for parameters, but above
all affects the problem of deciding the relative importance (weight) to be given to each criterion in comparison to the other ones. Subjectivity in transforming
46
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
physical values in satisfaction values Ð as the importance given to each criterion Ð could be limited by
applying a procedure capable to accommodate for
these causes of variability. In other words, in our
opinion, a `satisfactory' level of objectivity and comparability of results might be reached, if rational
procedures and benchmarks for transforming physical
values in utility values are de®ned. In the same way,
although weighting is a subjective process, it is possible to limit its subjectivity by giving guidelines and a
rational procedure for attributing weights. A method
for attributing weights taking into account the features
of impacts (temporary/permanent, local/national,
short/long term) and impacted resources (renewable/
not renewable, common/rare, strategic/not strategic) is
proposed in Schmidt di Friedberg (1987). Finally, only
an exact knowledge of the hypotheses on which data
conversion in Utility values and weighting of criteria
have been performed can allow readers to judge on the
reliability of an analysis. Indeed, the quality of results
of an assessment does not depend only on the methodology used for the evaluation, but heavily depends
also on the way data used for the assessment have been
obtained.
3. Analysing a single case-study
Analysing a single case-study is in some way more
dif®cult than analysing a set of objects, insofar as it is
not possible to perform comparisons between objects.
Thus, analysing a single case-study does not allow
using qualitative ordinal data, because there is no
suitable object to compare data with. Moreover, this
means that it is not possible to normalise values due to
the lack of internal reference points. Indeed, having
only one value for each criterion (the one of the casestudy), the concepts of minimum, maximum and
average no longer have any meaning. Consequently,
when analysing only one case-study, the transformation of criteria into a common unit of measurement has
to be done by means of Utility functions. This, because
Utility functions are (or could be) based on external
reference points. Due to the fact that Utility data have
to be used as quantitative ones, the conversion from
physical to Utility units has to be done very carefully.
Thus, in our opinion, the conversion should start by
de®ning a procedure that:
sets external points of reference for the minimum
and maximum values of the scale, namely the
physical situations that correspond to value `0'
and value `1' of the Utility function. This process
is similar to the one of calibrating a thermometer
scale, where value 0 is given to the situation of
melting ice and value 100 is given to the situation of
boiling water. Varying benchmarks should/could be
used for every region. Indeed, according to Hendriks et al. (1999), external reference values may or
must differ for different landscape types/regions;
since an external point of reference cannot be
global, but it must be filled in regionally (see also
Rossi et al., 1997). A Utopic region is needed as
guiding image for farm development;
does not apply automatic conversions, implying a
linear transformation of data, but it tries to define
values that are representative of differences in
satisfaction relating to real situations. From this
point of view, if it is not possible to reconstruct the
whole Utility function, it suffices to be able to find
the Utility level attributable to the case-study.
It is important to note that what is stated as regards
conversion procedures, is not only valid for the analysis of a single case-study farm, since the same
principles can be adopted when a set of objects are
analysed. In fact, while assessing one farm it is only
necessary to place a single value in the range de®ned
by the 0±1 external points of reference; in the case of a
set of objects, there is a number of values to be
transformed that correspond to the number of objects.
In both cases, in our opinion, it is important to discuss
the way external reference points could be chosen.
Individuating the values against which to calibrate
the scale means deciding which situations to use as
references for the maximum and minimum points on
the scale. An `objective procedure' for individuating
reference points could be the one of taking the best
situation achievable in the long term for each parameter as a reference for the maximum Utility. In this
case, the term of comparison for judging a case-study
would be a `Utopic farm'. The Utopic condition is not
so much tied to the achievement of a predetermined
maximum target for a single parameter (which might
actually be possible for real farms), as to the possibility of reaching the maximum value of all indicators
contemporarily. Indeed the concept of Utopic Farm is
similar to the one of an `Ideal Point', often used in the
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
case of multiple criteria analysis (see, e.g. Romero and
Rehman, 1989), which is characterised by the contemporary achievement of all the optimum values
(individually achievable) for con¯icting objectives.
Using Utopic values as reference points allows for
differences due to the speci®c region under examination insofar as it is possible to refer to a situation that
expresses the absolute maximum possible of that
parameter, independently of the area where the
case-study is located (absolute or general Utopia),
or to refer to a relative maximum, expressing the
maximum level actually possible in that particular
region (relative or local Utopia). The choice of a local
(or relative) Utopia or a general (or absolute) Utopia
conditions the reading of the results as well as the
possibilities of comparison when evaluations of different situations are required. So, whereas evaluations
expressed against the standard of a general Utopia are
directly comparable, since they use the same scale,
those expressed according to the standard of a local
Utopia indicate the position of the farm with respect to
the maximum result obtainable in the reference
region, so that the scale is calibrated with a maximum
value that varies according to context.
Since it is the whole performance, and not one
regarding a single parameter, that indicates how much
the case-study farm differs from a Utopic farm, it is
important to describe how this `overall judgement' on
farm performance can be reached. The easiest way of
doing it is to sum up all the Utility values scored by
each farm, after multiplying them for their weights. In
this case each weight represents the relative importance given to a criterion in comparison with the other
ones. It should be noted that some researchers are
against weighting criteria because weights are the
result of ``a subjective, uncertain and con¯ictual
operation'' (Colorni and Laniado, 1992) and, consequently, they might be unreliable. However, not using
weights when summing up the performance scored for
criteria means giving to all of them the same weight,
i.e. weight 1; this is again a subjective decision and
probably less correct than explicitly giving weights. In
this context, in our opinion, it is more suitable to try to
control subjectivity, e.g. by giving guidelines for
weight attribution (as in Schmidt di Friedberg,
1987) or by checking how much the results of the
analysis are dependent on the chosen set of weights,
than avoiding using them. In other words, if subjec-
47
tivity is unavoidable, it is at least possible to try to
control it and to explicitly state the hypothesis that can
be considered subjective in order to make the analysis
as `transparent' as possible (Colorni and Laniado,
1992). Since weights are strictly dependent on the
socio-economic and environmental context where the
analysis is placed, it is not possible to ®nd a weighting
system that could be generally valid in every situation.
It is apparent, for instance, that developing countries
where people still suffer from starvation are more
concerned with productive problems of agriculture
than with those of landscape preservation. On the
contrary, in `rich' countries, environment and landscape are given an increasing interest, in comparison
with the problem of agricultural production, which
nowadays is often higher than needed. Thus, if a
situation implies a level for a criterion which is below
the minimum required, nobody would be ready to
compensate a decrease in this criterion with an
increase in another one, which is less important or
which currently has a satisfactory level. Once these
physical survival requirements, or needs considered
strictly necessary, have been met, it is possible to
`trade' between criteria, exchanging the `surplus' of a
criterion for an increase in another one. Thus, the
trade-off between objectives (represented by criteria)
heavily depends on their initial values. Indeed, according to a marginalistic approach (Samuelson and Nordhaus, 1993) usually the importance of an improvement
in a criterion is increasingly lower when passing from
a mere matching of requirements to increasing levels
of surpluses. The above statement is, in our opinion,
perfectly coherent with the Maslow's approach to
human motivation used as a unifying concept in the
EU Concerted Action on The Landscape and Nature
Production Capacity of Organic/Sustainable Types of
Agriculture (van Mansvelt, 1997; van Mansvelt and
van der Lubbe, 1999; Stobbelaar and van Mansvelt,
1999).
The use of weighted sum as a method for assessing
the overall farm performance and of score 1 as the
maximum Utility value results in giving to the Utopic
farm an overall judgement of 1. This, because weights
are recalculated in such a way that their sum is always
1. Thus, the performance scored by a case-study farm
should be read taking into account that the maximum
possible level of the overall judgement (i.e. the one of
the Utopic farm) is 1. In other words, if a real case-
48
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
study farm would have an overall judgement of 0.78,
this would mean that its performance is 78% (0.78/1)
of the maximum possible, namely the overall judgement of the Utopic farm.
It should, however, be remembered that, as shown
above, exactly de®ning what Utopia is can be problematic, especially as regards the choice of whether to
take as reference the maximum values possible for the
various parameters (not always easy to establish) or
those that can be considered maximum in the examined context. Indeed, while the Utopic value for the
erosion parameter might be objectively generalised in
a `clear absence of erosion', this is not the case for
parameters such as farm income, where Utopia might
be characterised by extremely high values, completely
incongruent with the context of the farm under study.
To set the external reference for 0 score could be still
harder, since using a `too bad' external reference point
for score 0 might result in underestimating differences
between the other situations. Moreover, the distance
between actual farm and Utopia depends on the units
of measurement adopted, or rather, on the weighting
system used. In other words, when different vectors of
weights are used, the distance of a case-study farm
from Utopia or `perfection' may vary considerably.
Finally, it is important to remember that Utopia is,
by de®nition, Pareto-dominant on all the actual or
potential farm situations. ``A Pareto optimal solution
is a feasible solution for which an increase in the value
of one criterion can only be achieved by degrading the
value of at least one other criterion'' (Romero and
Rehman, 1989). Consequently, a situation is Paretodominant when it is not worse for all parameters and
better for at least one. Since Utopia is characterised by
scoring the maximum value for each criterion, this
means that real farms could match its performance,
but not perform better. Thus, Utopia could not be used
as a `second object of analysis' for performing a multicriterial analysis based on qualitative ordinal data.
Since farmers could consider the Utopic performance to be `out of reach', researchers could consider
using a reference point that is closer to the real casestudy situation. From this point of view, another way
of calibrating the scale could be the one of using as
reference points targets that could be achieved by the
case-study farm in the short or long run. In this way,
the judgement would consist in an assessment of what
the performance of the farm is in comparison with its
potential performance in the long or short run. In other
words, with this kind of approach, it could be possible
to judge how much ef®cient a farm is; the `inef®ciency' being de®ned as the distance between the
case-study farm real situation and its potentiality. Here
too, it is essential to understand the type of reference to
be used as external term of comparison, a problem
that, as in the previous case, brings us back to that of
the calibration of the scale. The use of a potential value
rather than a Utopic one leads, however, to even
greater problems of de®nition, depending on which
of the following courses is chosen:
To consider the case-study farm as a homogeneous
part of the region in which it is located. In this case,
the `local Utopia' could be used as the term of
external comparison, i.e. the best performance
theoretically obtainable in that context. This course
is open to two main criticisms. Firstly, the potentiality of the farm is not necessarily that of the
surrounding territory. Indeed, with regard to economic performance, e.g. if the size of the farm is
atypical of the area, farm actual potentiality could
be quite different from that of the surrounding
farms. Secondly, that reference is still made to a
Utopic rather than to a potential situation in that
account is not taken of the fact that the various
objectives are conflicting. In other words, the maximum potential value obtainable for an individual
parameter might coincide with the Utopic one,
insofar as Utopia refers to the contemporary
achievement of the maximum value for all parameters. Thus, by trying to include in `potentiality'
the concept of conflicting objectives, it is much
more difficult to individuate the set of maximum
values for the various objectives that may be contemporarily reached. When analysing a set of
farms, a possible way of calculating farm potential
in a homogeneous context could be that of considering a select case-study as a benchmark for
comparison, after checking that farms under study
have the chance of performing as well as the casestudy farm. Although this `applied' potentiality
might solve the problem of finding a set of reference values, nevertheless it might underestimate
the `theoretical' potentiality. Despite possible criticisms, the local Utopia approach is easy to apply
and extends to other farms insofar as it does not ask
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
for repeating a double evaluation for them all, i.e.
actual and potential situations. However, the adjective `potential' might be misleading since, as we
have seen, it is more a question of local Utopia (or
of comparison with case-studies) rather than the
specific potentials of the farm under study.
To consider the real potentialities of the farm under
examination, that need not necessarily coincide
with those of the surrounding territory for all
parameters. The application of this type of
approach involves two rather difficult problems.
First of all, it involves the need to carry out a double
evaluation, one of the actual situation and another
of the potential situation of the farm. In other
words, unlike the case of Utopia with its common
reference scale for the whole area, here the potentiality of the farm is considered to be specific of the
farm itself. Secondly, as in the previous case, the
difficulty of defining the potentialities of a farm
with regard to a series of criteria relative to objectives that cannot be pursued contemporarily. So,
unlike analyses in which only one parameter is
evaluated, here there might not be just one but many
potential situations depending on the priority given
to the achievement of the various objectives. This
results in great difficulty in the individuation of
the potential situation to be taken as a referent.
Moreover, unlike the previous case, it is not possible
to use case-studies as external references insofar as
farm features are not similar to the one in context.
In conclusion, we believe that it is much more
dif®cult to determine the margin of improvement of
overall farm ef®ciency by making use of targets
potentially achievable by the actual farm than to
individuate the distance from a situation of local
Utopia, even if the former method is formally more
correct. This results from the above-mentioned fact
that the main difference between a potential situation
and Utopia consists in not being capable of pursuing
and achieving contemporarily an excellent evaluation
for con¯icting objectives.
4. Concluding remarks
Performing a farm sustainability assessment is not
an easy task, especially if all the relevant effects of
farmers' choices have to be taken into account. From
49
this point of view, although the increasing interest of
researchers and the whole society are bringing about
many studies on this topic, there is still a long way to
go. The checklist of criteria proposed by the EU
Concerted Action on Landscape and Nature Production constitutes a ®rst step in this direction, providing
an inventory of criteria that could be relevant for farm
sustainability assessment. Of course, since the checklist is supposed to be valid at the European level,
researchers have to select every time which criteria to
use and which ones are not suitable for an analysis
performed in a speci®c context. The second step that
should be undertaken is providing guidelines and
standards for using the criteria. This involves two
different sets of problems. Firstly, the framework
provided by the EU Concerted Action members for
sustainability assessment is quite complex. Thus, even
if this approach guarantees the reliability of results,
nevertheless it asks for a very expensive and timeconsuming data gathering. From this point of view, it
might be very interesting to have `shortcuts', i.e.
simpli®ed procedures for gathering information that
guarantees a `satisfactory', although not optimal, level
of quality of information while greatly reducing the
effort needed for data collection. Secondly, it would be
important to have surveys based on standard procedures, capable of providing researchers with the reference points for calibrating criteria scales for a variety
of contexts, characterised by speci®c socio-economic,
environmental, and other, features. This kind of
research is not always greatly appreciated, since it
requires a lot of time and effort and then only provides
information for further research. In our opinion, however, this kind of research is important since it allows
to perform further analyses, whose results can be
compared. Moreover, since in the analysis of casestudy farms researchers could more easily be biased
from their opinion on the farms they have selected, the
use of standard procedures should be strongly advised.
This article has confronted some of the issues relating
to procedures that could be used for implementing
farms assessment using a multicriterial approach, and
it has tried to stress the main problems that can cause
surveys and analyses not to be reliable or comparable.
This with the aim of promoting a discussion leading to
the de®nition of standards that could be employed not
only in theoretical research, but also in applied
research.
50
M. Andreoli et al. / Landscape and Urban Planning 46 (1999) 41±50
Acknowledgements
This research has been supported by National
Research Council under contributions Nos.
94.00965.CT06 and 95.03251.CT06, and by the University of Pisa.
References
Accademia Nazionale di Agricoltura, 1991. Agricoltura e Ambiente, Edagricole, Bologna.
Andreoli, M., De Simone, A., Rossi, R., Tellarini, V., 1998. Una
proposta di percorso per la valutazione di realtaÁ aziendali o
comprensoriali in base ad un set di criteri di tipo qualitativo, Il
Borghetto, Pisa.
Andreoli, M., Tellarini, V., 1999. Farm sustainability evaluation:
methodology and practice. Agric. Ecosys. Environ., in press.
Baldock, D., Beaufoy, G., 1993. Nature conservation and new
directions in the EC common agriculture policy. Report for the
Ministry of Agriculture, Nature Management and Fisheries,
The Netherlands. Institute for European Environmental Policy,
Arnhem and London.
Bosshard, A., 1997. What does objectivity mean for analysis,
valuation and implementation in agricultural landscape planning? A practical and epistemological approach to the search
for sustainability in `agri-culture', Agric. Ecosyst. Environ. 63/
2,3: 133±143.
Ciani, A., Boggia, A., Marinozzi, G., 1993. Metodologie di
valutazione di alternative di parchi: il caso del Parco del Nera.
Genio Rurale 11, 46±54.
Chiusoli, A., 1994. La rinaturalizzazione del paesaggio agrario:
una esigenza ambientale, culturale e civile. Genio Rurale 4, 42±
51.
Colorni, A., Laniado, E., 1988. VISPA, Software Territoriale e
Ambientale, CLUP, Milan.
Colorni, A., Laniado, E., 1992. SILVIA: a decision support system
for environmental impact assessment. In: Colombo, A.G. (Ed.),
Environmental Impact Assessment, ECSC, EEC, EAEC,
Brussels and Luxembourg, printed in the Netherlands,
pp. 167±180.
Croci-Angelini, E., 1995. Effectiveness and redistribution of the
regional policy in the European Community. In: Sotte, F. (Ed.),
The Regional Dimension in Agricultural Economics and
Policies. Proceedings of the 40th Seminar of the European
Association of Agricultural Economists, Grafica Tiburtina,
Rome, pp. 251±274.
Dasguta, K., Pearce, D.W., 1975. Analisi costi benefici, teoria e
pratica, ISEDI, Milan.
Hendriks, K., Stobbelaar D.J., van Mansvelt J.D., 1999. The
appearance of agriculture. Assessment of landscape quality of
(organic and conventional) horticultural farms in West-Friesland, Agric. Ecosys. Environm., in press.
Pennacchi, F., (Ed.), 1994. La riforma Mac Sharry. Effetti nelle
aziende R.I.C.A., CNR-RAISA n. 2224, Quaderni dell'Istituto
di Economia e Politica Agraria, Tipografia dell'UniversitaÁ degli
Studi di Perugia, Perugia.
Pennacchi, F., (Ed.), 1998. SostenibilitaÁ Efficienza e Successo
Aziendale. Una valutazione nelle aziende della R.I.C.A., CNRRAISA, Quaderni dell'Istituto di Economia e Politica Agraria,
quaderno n. 24, Tipografia dell'UniversitaÁ degli Studi di
Perugia, Perugia.
Polinori, P., 1998. Agricoltura e SostenibilitaÁ. In: Pennacchi, F.
(Ed.), SostenibilitaÁ Efficienza e Successo Aziendale. Una
valutazione nelle aziende della R.I.C.A., CNR-RAISA, Quaderni dell'Istituto di Economia e Politica Agraria, quaderno n.
24, Tipografia dell'UniversitaÁ degli Studi di Perugia, Perugia,
pp. 3±37.
Romero, C., Rehman, T., 1989. Multiple Criteria Analysis for
Agricultural Decision, Elsevier, Amsterdam.
Rossi, R., Nota, D., Fossi, F., 1997. Landscape and nature
production capacity of organic types of agriculture: examples
of organic farms in two Tuscan landscapes, Agric. Ecosys.
Environm. 63/2,3: 159±171.
Rossi, R., Nota, D., 1999. Nature and landscape production
potentials of organic types of agriculture: a check of evaluation
criteria and parameters in two Tuscan farm-landscapes, Agric.
Ecosys. Environm., in press.
Samuelson, P.A., Nordhaus, W.D., 1993. Economia (Italian ed. of
Economics), 14th ed., Zanichelli, Bologna, 1993.
Schmidt di Friedberg, P. (Ed.), 1987. Gli indicatori ambientali,
Franco Angeli, Milan.
Stobbelaar, D.J., van Mansvelt, J.D., 1999. The process of
landscape evaluation. Introduction to the second special Agric.
Ecosys. Environm. issue of the Concerted Action: the Landscape and Nature Production Capacity of Organic/Sustainable
Types of Agriculture, Agric. Ecosys. Environm., in press.
Tellarini, V., 1995. Approcci metodologici, in Cannata, G., (Editor)
Aziende e famiglie nella collina e montagna appenniniche.
Studi di casi, CNR-RAISA, FrancoAngeli, Milan, pp. 23±38.
van Mansvelt, J.D., 1997. An interdisciplinary approach to
integrate a range of agro-landscape values as proposed by
representatives of various disciplines, Agric. Ecosys. Environm.
63/2,3: 233±250.
van Mansvelt, J.D., van der Lubbe, M.J., 1999. Checklist for
Sustainable Landscape Management, Elsevier, Amsterdam.