THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM UNDER
ALTERNATIVE MONETARY REGIMES
William N. Butos
I. Introduction
During the past decade a significant change has occurred in the
kinds of questions explored by monetary economists. Heretofore,
one of the central issues concerned the “rules versus discretion”
debate of a central bank empowered monopolistically to supply base
money. However, with the publication of studies by Klein (1974),
Thompson (1974), and Hayek (1976/1978), the range of alternatives
expanded to include the possibility of regimes based on the private
provision of inconvertible media of exchange. Subsequent research
by White (1984b) rehabilitated the idea of free banking with fractional reserves and full convertibility of a commodity money. In
addition, laissez-faire cashless payments systems have been studied
by Black (1970), Fama (1980), and Greenfield and Yeager (1983).
In general, the literature on private provision ofmoney has focused
on the theoretical properties of such regimes, especially in connection with the constraints necessary to ensure stability of the banking
structure and the value of money. An equally important body of
research by White (1984a), King (1983), Rockoff (1974), and Rolnick
and Weber (1983, 1984) has examined historical episodes of market
alternatives to government provision of money.
Consideration of alternative monetary regimes might proceed in
terms ofthe inherentproblem ofthe effective acquisition, utilization,
and production of knowledge in an economic system. The purpose
of this paper is to explore the problem of constraints on knowledge
as it applies to monetary regimes. To limit the range of the largely
Cato Journal, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Winter 1986). Copyright © Cato Institute. All rights
reserved.
The author is Assistant Professor ofEconomics atTrinity College. He wishes to thank
Gerald P. O’Driscoll, Jr., Ray Lombra, Will Mason, James Dorn, Pat Gunning, and
Mack Ott for helpful comments. The usual caveat applies.
849
CAm JOURNAL
three cases will be considered: the current regime,
i.e., the Federal Reserve System (Fed); the monetarist regime, which
relies on a monetary growth rate rule; and a regime of competing,
inconvertible currencies as proposed by Hayek and others.
Section II provides an overview of the “knowledge problem.”
Section III examines current and monetarist regimes, and section IV
discusses a regime of competing currencies. Section V summarizes
the major results and implications of the paper and suggests areas for
further research.
critical discussion,
H. The Knowledge Problem
One way societies have attempted to overcome constraints on
knowledge is by developing media of exchange. Economists are in
general agreement that money is an efficient device for coordinating
individuals’ plans. Yet, because money is ubiquitous and plays a
crucial role in coordinating plans, a monetary system faces special
difficulties if money itself or attendant institutions become sources
and conduits of disruption. This prospect has a significant bearing in
assessing monetary regimes. Regimes may differ in how well they
utilize current information and adapt to new and novel information;
if so, this would figure prominently in their evaluation.
In analyzing the knowledge problem as it pertains to monetary
regimes, it is necessary to treat regimes as autonomous decisionmaking units. This means that, in addition to whatever characteristics
differentiate them, they share a property relative to the system in
which they function. Both the legally endowed Federal Reserve
System and the undesigned market structures of Hayek’s system of
competing currencies constitute loci ofknowledge activity. Although
both function in frameworks of different constraints and rules, the
presumption must be that the content of their knowledge does not
coincide with that of the economic system’s functioning units.
The claim is that knowledge is not redundant between any two
decision-making units. This claim carries the implication that a monetary regime’s effectiveness in coordinating the plans of individuals
(or in offsetting the results of those plans) depends on its success in
acquiring and anticipating knowledge as well as usefully organizing
such knowledge to guide its actions. Since knowledge is not uniformly distributed across different minds, the “knowledge problem”
is precisely that constraints exist on what can be known.
Given that differential knowledge distinguishes decision-making
units of the monetary regime from those of the economic system, it
is useful to structurethe discussion around two main questions: What
850
THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
is the kind of knowledge that individuals and the economic system
produce, and can the decision-making units ofthe monetary regime
acquire this knowledge?
The central element of complex orders, such as the market, is the
absence of any locus of control. Knowledge is not centered in any
one place; instead, it is dispersed. As Hayek (1948, p. 78) observes,
the division of knowledge presents “the problem of the utilization
of knowledge which is not given to anyone in its totality.” Knowledge
exists in the form of “objective” market data, such as prices and
quantities, which express outcomes of transactions undertaken by
individuals. Knowledge also exists in the form ofunorganized “practical” knowledge of “particular circumstances of time and place”
(Hayek 1948, p. 80). It is by acting on this dispersed knowledge that
each individual contributes to changes in prices and the pattern of
resource allocation. In effect, individuals’ specialized and particulate
knowledge is transformed into outcomes (and new knowledge) that
are socially beneficial.
In viewing the market process as a mechanism by which bits of
knowledge are transformed into market data, the tendency must be
resisted to treat the knowledge problem as wholly a matter of somehow collecting dispersed knowledge, as if it were shells on a beach
waiting to be picked up. Knowledge has no existence apart from the
minds classifying it, and knowledge is a significant only because
individuals attach usefulness to it. “Objective” market data are surface-level manifestations of knowledge subjectively held by individuals. The content of such knowledge not only includes perceptions
about existing market data and “practical” knowledge, but also theories ofcausal relationships, anticipations ofthe future, and an unspecifiable body of inarticulated or tacit knowledge.’
From a subjectivist economics perspective, individuals utilize this
knowledge to formulate plans. Such plans arise from complex mental
processes that draw on knowledge available only to those individuals. Thus, the same set of “objective” data maybe interpreted differently and formulated into plans based on the unique substrata of
knowledge inhering in each individual. This means that an intrinsic
aspect of the knowledge problem is the diversity of individual plans
and the creation of novelty. Although individuals act purposively to
attain their ends, the system itself generates outcomes that cannot
be specified a priori. The system is end-independent.
Conceiving of the market order as open-ended and nondeterministic draws attention to its evolutionary character. Since knowledge
‘See Polanyi (1966).
851
CATO JOURNAL
drives the system, the path of the system through time will involve
the creation, utilization, and destruction of knowledge. What was
relevant knowledge yesterday will be made useless tomorrow by
newly created and discovered knowledge. The dynamic pattern of
the spontaneous market order is characterized by Weimer (1983, p.
25) to involve “regulatory principles of change”:
lI]t seems to be informative to consider the evolution of spontaneous orders as an essential tension between three sets ofprinciples
that regulate change: creativity or productivity, rhythm, and opponent process regulation. The interaction of these principles creates
an essential tension between the previous form or organization, the
ongoing state, and changes that may occur. This tension between
tradition and innovation, stability and change, is an inherent aspect
of evolving cosmic structures.
The novelty created by spontaneous orders stems from the infinite
applicability ofgeneral rules of conduct to particular circumstances.2
Rules, as opposed to directives, are generative principles that limit
the range of permitted action but do not specify a particular kind of
action or result. Thus, while the rules that guide action are finite, the
diversity they permit is not.
The discussion thus far has focused on the dispersed, subjective,
and evolutionary character of knowledge. But is it possible to gain
and utilize such knowledge, and what is the status ofthe knowledge
that is acquired?
Although individuals clearly have access to certain kinds of particulate knowledge, they are precluded from detailed knowledge ofthe
system’s structure and the plans ofothers. The coordination of diverse
plans, given the inevitability of ignorance, is, however, attributable
to the economy of knowledge necessary for the market’s operation.
By decentralizing control, the market makes possible the effective
use of dispersed knowledge and thus widens “the span of our utilization of resources beyond the span of the control of any one mind”
(Hayek 1948, p. 88).
Constraints on what can be known also apply to the decisionmaking units of a monetary regime. Like those of the economic
system, such units do not have direct access to dispersed knowledge
or to detailed structural knowledge of the economy. The “objective”
data generated by the market is available (at a positive cost), but it
does not provide insight into the specific individual plans and novel
outcomes that arise.
2
See Hayek (1967).
852
THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
The knowledge problem confronting regimes is regime-specific
because they differ in their degree of centralization and in their
objectives. For a centralized monetary regime, such as the Fed, the
existence of data in the form generated by the market (individual
prices and quantities) has little use. Rather, the collected data must
be organized in a way that is compatible with the decision-making
process and activity the regime undertakes. Specifically, data must
be statistically aggregated or indexed. This follows because a centralized regime’s concern (and presumed responsibility) is not associated with isolated market phenomena, but, instead, is directed to
the broader contours of economic activity at the sectoral or macroeconomic level.
In contrast, a monetary regime composed of competing firms, such
as Hayek’s, has no identifiable or direct concern with macroeconomic
outcomes. Rather, the firms’ objectives are to produce products and
services that generate profits. For example, their need to construct
aggregate indices of economic activity, if present at all, is plainly
secondary to the acquisition and utilization of knowledge proximate
to their situation. The kind of knowledge that competitive money
issuing firms require, therefore, is quantitatively and qualitatively
different from that of a centralized regime. While constraints on
knowledge apply to both, the nature of those constraints differs with
respect to the regime’s organization and charge.
III. The Current and Monetarist Monetary Regimes
In this section, I examine two monetary regimes based on government (orcentral bank) provision of base money. I assume the regimes
differ only in the range of discretion allowed the central bank in
issuing base money.3 In the current regime this range is bounded in
the sense that the Fed formulates and implements “sound monetary
policy” consistent with broad policy objectives relating to inflation,
unemployment, and balance of payments equilibrium.4 In the monetarist regime the range is specified as a particular (monetary aggregate) growth rate rule.
3
Obviously, other important features, such as regulatory functions, methods of reserve
accounting, discount rate setting, and foreign exchange intervention might also differ
across regimes.
4
The centralization ofFed power and the identification of long-term monetary policy
goals evolved over several decades, The original purpose ofthe Federal Reserve Act
of 1913 was to provide an elastic currency and discount commercial paper, and to
improve bank supervision. Following World War II, the Employment Act of 1946 and
the Humphrey-Hawkins Act of 1978 established the legislative framework for monetary
policy.
853
CATO JOURNAL
The Current Monetary Regime
As a consequence ofthe broad range ofdiscretion Congress allows,
the Fed is obliged to formulate and implement monetary policy.
Notwithstanding the problem of assigning priorities to potentially
competing long-term policy goals,5 at both the formulation and execution stages the knowledge problem arises in important ways. Critics of the Fed, spanning the gamut of different schools, have argued
that the Fed has not consistently or adequately fulfilled its charge to
stabilize the economy, and may have actually destabilized the economy. I will argue that the knowledge problem is the root difficulty.
The problem for policymakers is to formulate policy for a nonstatic,
changing economy. The key point is that the kind of knowledge the
Fed would need to formulate and implement optimal policy is not
available. In the market, knowledge is dispersed and subjective; it
exists as particulate data and as plans in the minds of individuals.
Knowledge is neither centralized nor exogenously provided, but is
produced anew by the continuous activity of interacting individuals.
In general, the Fed’s policy process involves the use of such tools
as open market operations and the discount rate to effect changes in
various “operating targets” (a short-term interest rate, such as the
federal funds rate, or a reserve aggregate, such as nonborrowed
reserves). The operating targets, typically assumed to be capable of
tight control by the Fed, are then linked to “intermediate targets”
(such as Ml and M2), which, in turn, are thought to have a systematic
relation to the long-run policy goals.
In this stylized overview of the Fed’s approach to monetary policy,
the knowledge problem intrudes at each turn. My focus here is
twofold: on the collection, interpretation, and analysis of data to
assess and forecast the past and future state of the economy, and,
second, on the selection of an operating target and procedure to
implement monetary policy.
Within this framework, the Fed’s approach to the formulation of
policy involves filtering a wide range of real and monetary variables
to produce a forecast of the economy’s performance up to one year
in the future. Given the desired objectives of monetary policy, a
5
The literature on Fed behavior often specifiesa centralbank utility function containing
a vector of policy goals. The problem is to maximize the function (or, alternatively, to
minimize deviations of desired and actual outcomes) subject to various constraints.
See, for example, Lombra and Torto (1976). This approach, however, cannot specify
the weights of the Fed’s policy goals orclaim the weights are constant overtime. Public
choice approaches to Fed behavior, moreover, have suggested that a more completely
specified utility function should include arguments related to profits, prestige, and
power. See, for example, Toma (1982) and Shughart and Tollison (1983).
854
THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
growth rate of a monetary aggregate (Ml or M2) is selected that
minimizes the deviation between the forecasted and desired values
of the policy goals. The second stage of the Fed’s approach involves
the selection of the operating target and procedures to attain the
desired growth rate of the monetary aggregate.
At each Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meeting staff
economists review the economy’s recent performance. Drawing on
aggregated and sectoral data for real and financial variables, an overall picture of the economy is constructed. This picture, however, is
substantially built on data that are known only with a considerable
lag. While some indicators of economic activity, especially those
related to financial markets, are available quickly, those that pertain
to real activity are generally available only with a one quarter or
greater lag. As a result, the picture of the economy that can be constructed refers to the economy as it existed in the past.
Suppose, for example, that the Fed chooses a monetary aggregate
target (M*). In a simple income-expenditure model, this selection
gives an LM (money market equilibrium) schedule in interest rate
and income space, given money demand. Now, assume “the” interest
rate is observed to rise. The question that will confront policymakers
is: What has happened? If money demand has increased (given M*),
the rise in the interest rate will be associated with a fall in income.
Alternatively, ifautonomous spending, say investment expenditures,
has increased, the rise in the interest rate will be associated with an
increase in income. The appropriate (discretionary) policy response
in the former case might be to increase the nominal stock of base
money. The problem, however, is that the information necessary to
make that inference will not become available without a substantial
lag. If the source of change is not correctly identified, the policy
response itself will be inappropriate.
The staff economists of the Fed also prepare for the FOMC forecasts of the economy derived from a large macroeconometric model.
Such models sometimes perform reasonably well over the near term,
but their predictive accuracy, especially for real variables, starts to
fall off sharply beyond two quarters or when their structural parameters—referring ultimatelyto individuals’ behavior—change or become
unstable. The knowledge problem enters here because detailed
structural knowledge of the economy is beyond the capability of
models. Although the Fed’s econometric model might provide reasonably accurate forecasts for an economy in which the future did
not diverge greatly from the past, this is not the relevant context to
assess discretionary policy.6
‘A detailed study of staff projections contained in the Greenbook (nonfinancial) and
855
CATO JOURNAL
The kinds of difficulties encountered in preparing macroeconometric forecasts also arise in the procedures used to reach the desired
intermediate target.7 Since the mid-l970s, the Fed has devoted
increased attention to achieving a specified growth-rate range of a
monetary aggregate. To implement this policy objective, the Fed
employs certain operating procedures. Let us assume, therefore, that
the FOMC has decided on a growth rate of Ml equal to M*. According
to the “demand approach,” the Fed estimates a money demand function using the targeted growth rate of the money stock and a forecasted value for income (Y’). The resulting equation is then solved
for the equilibrium rate of interest (i*) consistent with M* and Y’.
Over the relevant policy horizon, the Fed adds (or subtracts) reserves
necessary to hit P’.
Alternatively, the “supply approach” uses the money multiplier
model to determine the change in reserves consistent with achieving
M*. Here, the estimated value of the money multiplier is used to
solve for desired reserves, given M’~
Both procedures are designed to achieve tighter control over a
monetary aggregate target and have figured prominently in Fed policy during the past decade.9 Yet, each procedure suffers drawbacks
that can confound the intentions of policymakers. For the “demand
approach,” the estimated demand function for money may be subject
Bluebook (financial) during the period 1970—73 is found in Lombra and Moran (1980).
Among the many useful insights into the policymaking process uncovered by Lombra
and Moran is the systematic underestimation of inflation by the staff. Nevertheless,
they concluded that the Fed staff did about as well as other forecasters.
7J ignore the controversy of which intermediate target is “optimal.” Within the framework of a stochastic IS-LM model Poole (1970) has shown that the choice depends on
the relative instabilities of the IS and LM schedules.
‘The “supply approach” discussed here is a convenient wayto describe the formulation
of monetary policy. It should be noted, however, that the (nonborrowed) reserves
approach that the Fed adopted in October 1979 differs with the “supply approach” at
the empirical and operational level. Specifically, in money multiplier models the Fed
exercises control by altering the quantity ofreserves. As Lombra (1980, p. 283) notes,
however, in the Fed’s view the “system is equilibrated through the movement of
interest rates which, through their effect on bank revenues and costs, determine banks’
desired asset and liability positions.” For anelyticel purposes, nevertheless, these two
mechanisms can be treated as compatible.
‘Ostensibly, the “supply approach” replaced the “demand approach” in 1979. Whether
this constituted a “new regime,” as much ofthe literature suggests, is doubtful, Above
all, I would argue that Fed behavior is fundamentally “flexible.” Narrow characterizations are likely to be misleading or relevant only over fairly short policy horizons.
The operating procedures adopted in 1979 actually widened the acceptable range of
volatility in the federal funds rate. In 1982 the Fed narrowed this range and also placed
more emphasis on M2.
856
THE
KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
to various shocks, specification error, and parameter instability.10 If
so, the Fed’s response of supplying reserves to achieve a certain
level of the desired interest rate will systematically over- or undersupply reserves during the policy period and, hence, generate undesired deviations in money growth. Since weekly and monthly fluctuations in money stock measures may arise irrespective of monetary
policy, the Fed is unable to ascertain in the near term if those money
stock figures stem from technical problems in its procedures or “white
noise.” As a result, symptoms of a problem in the procedures appear
with a time-lag.11 In the meantime, money growth is tied to the
targeted interest rate.
The “supply approach,” on the other hand, requires reasonably
accurate forecasts of the money multiplier over the relevant policy
horizon. If the multiplier is predictable, controlling the money stock
simply requires the Fed to control reserves. Empirical studies by
Johannes and Rasche (1979) and Balbach (1981) find that variations
in the multiplier tend to even out on a quarterly or annual basis. The
reduced-form models that underpin multiplier estimates, however,
abstract from the short-run dynamics of bank and public behavior,
thus obfuscating the role of interest rates. Since the Fed views the
impact on the money stock of changes in reserves as occurring through
the movement of interest rates, the multiplier approach is uninformative with respect to the linkages involved in short-run monetary
control.
Critics of the multiplier approach point to the “large” annualized
monthly variations in the multiplier that, given tight control ofreserves,
increase the amplitude ofinterest rate fluctuations.12 The destabilizing effects of such swings on financial markets cannot be discounted
any more than the reaction ofthe Fed to modify those swings. In the
context of a discretionary monetary regime the long-run multiplier
predictability is unhelpful without a supporting theory of Fed behav“The literature on these issues is vast. Goldfeld’s (1976) finding that conventional
money demand functions seriously underpredicted money demand after 1974 led to a
search for the “missing money.” The apparent instability of money demand has been
attributed to various sources, including regulatory change, financial innovation, and
money supply endogeneity. A useful survey is found in Judd and Scadding (1982).
11
Even if targeted money growth is outside the desired quarterly range, the Fed’s
corrective steps may be to take the past growth rate as given and attempt to hit the
targeted range over the nextquarter. This racheting phenomenon or “base drift” seems
to have existed during the 1970s, as noted by Lombra and Torto (1976).
“Lombra and Kaufman (1985) point out that during the period 1979—82 the Fed’s
“supply approach” may have reflected a damage-control mechanism in that shocks
affected both quantities and rates, Under the “demand approach” only quantity would
be affected.
857
CATO JOURNAL
ior, especially as it relates to short-run monetary control. Lindsey
(1983), for example, provides evidence for 1979—81 in which variations in nonborrowed reserves are strongly and negatively correlated
with monthly variations in the multiplier.
Since the data available to policymakers are necessarily ex post
and aggregated, they refer to outcomes of the market process that
may not be relevant for current and future plans. The data do not
reveal decisions or plans individuals will embark on. If the study of
unintended consequences of purposeful activity is the central problem of economic inquiry, recourse to historical data provides an
ambiguous, if not misleading, basis for inferring novelty in economic
activity. Moreover, the rendering of collected data into broad aggregates represents formalist constructions that are disembodied from
the plans and actions of individuals. The market generates prices
and quantities, but not, for example, a price level or a homogenous
output. The treatment of such aggregates as independent entities
neglects the underlying and implicit market processes that they allege
to explain and results in the loss of detailed market-generated
information.
The purview of the Fed should always be future-oriented. In particular, it must form judgments of the likely path of the economy
without policy, and then devise a program to steer the system toward
a set of desired outcomes. Here, finally, the knowledge problem
intrudes because the future path of the economy can be only conjectured. As we have seen, forecasts of key economic variables must be
generated to set the stage for policy implementation. But the problems here can be severe. To forecast accurately the future path of the
economy(and hencejustify anyparticularpolicy), policymakers require
detailed kno~vledgeof the economy’s structure. The dispersion of
knowledge, its inherent subjectivity, and the prospect of novelty
suggest, however, a set of constraints that will prevent policymakers
from consistently meeting this requirement.
A Monetarist Monetary Regime
Some years ago, Milton Friedman (1960) suggested constraining
the Fed to adhere to a fixed monetary growth rule. In his “Statement
on the Conduct of Monetary Policy,” Friedman (1976, p. 559) argued:
The ultimate target should be a rate of growth in M2 of roughly 3
to 5 percent a year. That would roughly match the rate ofgrowth in
our productive potential. Given the highly stable velocity of M2
over more than a decade, it would be consistent with roughly stable
prices.
858
THE KNOWLEDGE
PROBLEM
The objective of the monetarist fixed, stable growth rule is to
remove discretion from policymaking and, hence, policy activism as
an independent source of instability. In addition to historical evidence (see, for example, Friedman and Schwartz 1963) monetarists
make a series oftheoretical arguments supporting this point ofview.’3
Inter alia, these arguments include the dynamic stability ofthe economic system, the long-run neutrality of changes in money, and the
stability of money demand. In terms of policy, monetarism emphasizes the uncertain environment in which activist monetary policymakers are forced to operate and the timing problems associated with
possibly long and variable lags in the economic system.
The monetarist point of view recognizes implicitly the informational constraints confronting policymakers. Hence “optimal” policy—stabilizing the path of the economy and offsetting cyclical fluctuations—is a chimera because it would require knowledge that
policymakers do not and cannot have. As Brunner (1983, p. 25)
observes:
Nevertheless, many Keynesians implicitly, and sometimes quite
explicitly, assert that they possess knowledge about the position
and movements ofthese [IS and LM] curves. Indeed, they proclaim
to possess specific knowledge about the mix of fiscal and monetary
policies that at any moment would guide the curves to the “full
employment” equilibrium.
Sensitivity to knowledge constraints also appears to underpin the
monetarist preference for “reduced-form” econometric models as
opposed to large, structural Keynesian models. According to monetarism, the economy is too complex to be captured adequately, even
in detailed econometric models. Moreover, if the transmission mechanism of monetary impulses involves relative price and portfolio
effects across a broad spectrum of assets, as monetarists contend,
then modeling only a small number of channels would bias large
structural models against picking up the ubiquitous effects of monetary changes.
The monetat-ist growth rule, therefore, might be a plausible approach
to monetary policy in a world of uncertainty. If the system in the
long-run attains its natural rate of unemployment, the only outstanding policy question from the monetarist perspective is: at what rate
of inflation? The monetarist answer to this question involves a monetary quantity rule for a price level (or rate) objective. The automaticity of the rule is, according to monetarism, the proximate requirement to achieve overall monetary and systemic stability. But would
3
‘ Mayer (1975) provides a useful overview ofmonetarism.
859
CATO JOURNAL
the adoption of a quantity rule solve monetary problems? Would it
dispense with policy decision making?’4 And would it, in short, be
capable of dealing effectively with the knowledge problem?
To examine this question, let us suppose that the Fed is forced to
adopt a growth rate rule.’5 Further, assume that the Fed’s self-imposed
impediments to monetary control, such as lagged reserve accounting,
nonuniform reserve requirements, and a nonmarket-related discount
rate, are removed.’6 In this setting, a once-for-all and publicly
announced FOMC directive would specify that the trading desk
purchase some fixed amount of securities at regular intervals.’7
The apparent automaticity of a monetarist regime, however, does
not mean that decision making by the Fed is unnecessary. First, a
determination must be made as to which monetary aggregate should
serve as the operating target. Presumably, it would be one which the
Fed could control tightly and which bore a systematic relation to the
relevant intermediate target. The preferred monetarist aggregate is
the monetary base, controlled by asset-side manipulation of the Fed’s
balance sheet. Once selected, the operating target’s growth rate would
4
‘ This is the same question Will Mason (1984, p. 1) raises in the context of a gold
standard: “The gold standard failed because it became mistaken for an automatic
mechanism that would solve our monetary problems for us.”
15
According to Friedman (1982), a more realistic alternative is to place the Fed under
the control of the Treasury Department orCongress. It is not clear why shifting control
to another agency would ensure adherence to a growth rate rule in the absence of a
constitutional constraint.
5
‘ Greater uniformity ofreserve requirements was specified in the Monetary Control
Act of 1980, and a form of contemporaneous reserve accounting was reintroduced in
1984.
7
‘ Currently, the FOMC’s directive becomes publicly available only after a lag ofseveral
weeks. This practice was unsuccessfully challenged in a civil action in 1975. The Fed’s
position is that immediate release of the directive would cause financial markets to
overreact, leading to increased volatility of interest rates and speculative profits for
astute “Fed watchers” (see Burns 1978, especially pp. 392—93). Voicker (1984, p. 3)
also argues that “one danger in immediate release of the directive is that certain
assumptions might be made that we are committed to certain operations that are, in
fact, dependent on future events, and these interpretations and expectations would
tend to diminish our needed operational flexibility.” On the surface, the Fed’s position
is inconsistent with the efficient-markets hypothesis and reduces to the claim that less
publicly available information is preferable to more. Michael Dotsey (1984) has developed a model which suggests that the variance ofthe federal funds rate is smaller when
the FOMC delays release ofthe directive, As he points out, however, this may augment
the Fed’s utility if smoothing interest rates is an objective but increase financial institutions’ costs, given that they have a strong incentive to uncover the direction of
monetary policy. Also see O’Brien (1981). Under a monetarist regime, the issue of the
directive’s delayed release does not arise since the directive would not change and the
Fed would not act to smooth interest rates.
860
THE KNOWLEDGE
PROBLEM
be hooked into a money multiplier to give the growth path ofa money
stock intermediate target (see Friedman 1982).
I suggested earlier that the money multiplier approach may involve
certain difficulties.” While these mainly serve to highlight potentially important issues in implementing a monetarist growth rule, the
introduction of dynamism into the economy, however, sets the stage
for a more fundamental problem, namely, which money stock should
the Fed target? My claim is that the Fed does not determine what
money is, but discovers ex post what individuals use for money.” In
the context of a monetary growth rule, the presumed (policy) exogeneity of money exists only to the extent that the market permits.
Because the particular kinds of financial assets that may become
money result from entrepreneurial activity on the market, no one,
including the Fed, can know beforehand what they might be. While
the government may legalize different kinds of media of exchange
and the Fed may incorporate their quantity into a measure of the
money stock, only through a market process is money legitimated.
Even if the Fed is able to control a particular collection of assets
called money, say Ml, there is no guarantee that the measure is the
appropriate one for controlling nominal GNP.
These considerations suggest an interesting dilemma for monetarists. It is widely agreed that month-to-month variations in the measured money stock contain a substantial amount ofrandomness. Tight
control of the money stock target is, therefore, not possible in the
short run. Monetarists, however, do claim that on a quarterly or
annual basis, these random deviations even out and permit a monetary rule to achieve its targeted range. As a result, it is argued that in
the long run the Fed is in a position to control the money stock and
researchers can treat the money stock as an exogenous (policy determined) variable.
This latter claim might be correct if the collection of assets used
to mediate exchanges were unchanged. To the extent, however, that
5
‘ 1n figures reported by Rasche (1982) forecasts of the base multiplier show sizable
monthly errors but considerably smaller yearly ones, suggesting that the errors tend to
“average out” over time. Such results would appear to provide a strong basis for a
growth rate rule. However, the large monthly forecast errors will tend to generate more
volatile interest rates (see Lombra and Struble 1979; Auerbach 1982). Second, Rasche
uses a time series model to generate money multiplier forecasts. The significant feature
of suchmodels is that they require no explicit behavioral assumptions; they are purely
ex post, historical, nontheoretic.
5
‘ See Menger (1892). Monetarists identify the appropriate money stock to target on the
basis of its ability to track nominal GNP, See, for example, Rasche (1982) and Cagan
(1982). The empirical definition of money, however, confuses the concept of money
with its measurement. On this, see Mason (1976).
861
CATO JOURNAL
financial market innovations arise, that presumption is cast into doubt
and suggests that the long-run money stock exogeneity and controllability assumption is contingent upon the dynamics of the market
process. The fact that the measurement of the aggregates has undergone periodic revision during the past several years highlights the
difficulties facing policymakers in a rapidly changing environment.’0
The desire of financial institutions to circumvent regulations by
issuing new kinds of liabilities surely has played a significant role in
this process,” as has the recent trend toward deregulation. The prospect exists that financialinnovation will gradually wind down, although
recent experience suggests that the opposite may be more nearly the
case. Indeed, a case can probably be made that the major task confronting Congress, the Fed, FDIC, and the comptroller of the currency is whether the legislature and regulators will ratify changes
in the financial sector. In any event, the evolution of financial institutions is likely to continue to surprise policymakers and theorists
alike.
Recent innovation in the financial sector illustrates the novelty
inherent in a complex system like the market. When individuals
perceive new institutional arrangements they are motivated to exploit
opportunities and to do things differently. In so doing, not only do
they take advantage of their proximity to particulate knowledge, but
they also generate new information and hence unintentionally contribute to the formation of new social institutions and structures. In
those activities that are closely related to money and monetary institutions, special difficulties are generated for policymakers. Although
I suggested earlier that such problems may be particularly pressing
for discretionary policymakers, they also arise when rules are imposed
to constrain the range of discretion.
In a monetarist regime, the need to deal with the dynamic properties of the financial system may require periodic changes in the
55
In 1982 the FOMC narrowed the targeted range of fluctuation in the federal funds
rate and placed greater emphasis on M2 (rather than Ml). According to the Fed this
was necessitated by the uncertainty surrounding the introduction of new financial
assets, Volcker (1983, p. 38) observes: “Deposit flows in response to the advent ofthe
money market deposit and super NOW accounts have been massive. As expected, these
inflows have had a major impact on the growth ofsome of the aggregates—particularly
M2. . . . The range ofuncertainty on these points is substantial
Also, Lyle Gramley
(1982, p. 395) notes: “Financial innovation in the United States has had important and
far-reaching ramifications. It has raised questions about the appropriate definition
[measurement?l of money, the precision of the Federal Reserve’s control over the
money stock, the meaning ofchanges in money balances, and the mechanism by which
monetary policy affects economic activity.”
51
See Kane (1977).
862
THE KNOWLEDGE
PROBLEM
monetary rule. Even if the Fed were able to control tightly a particular money stock measure, there is no a priori assurance that the
aggregate would contemporaneously reflect the appropriate collection of financial assets used as money in a dynamic economy. The
uncertainty surrounding the nature, significance, and transience of
financial sector innovation would measurably complicate adherence
to an established monetary rule. Because financial sector innovation
is an ongoing, open-ended process, the knowledge policymakers
would need does not exist. Thus, in a dynamic financial environment
the knowledge problem effectively drives a wedge between the
intentions ofpolicymakers and the undesigned process ofthe market.
IV.
A Regime of Competing Currencies
The monetary regimes discussed in section III are based on government (or Fed) provision ofbase money. In this section, I consider
a denationalized regime in which private firms Issue non-convertible
fiduciary money, as proposed by Hayek (1978).
As envisioned by Hayek, the denationalized monetary regime’s
essential characteristics would include the following: (1) private bank
issuance ofliabilities (non-interest bearing notes and demand deposits) denominated in a unit with a registered trademark and redeemable at a contractually fixed rate with another currency, which Hayek
(1978, p. 42) suggests could be Swiss francs, dollars, or D-marks; (2)
each bank would announce its intention to keep the purchasing
power of its currency constant by adjusting the stock of its currency;
(3) the purchasing power of each bank’s currency would be defined
in terms of a standard composed of a basket of commodities.
Hayek suggests that since individuals’ dominant preference is for
currencies ofstable value, a competitive selection process will result
in the survival of those currencies that maintain their value in terms
of the commodity basket. According to Hayek, the mechanism that
ensures this outcome is the operation of an organized currency
exchange market. In this market, movements in exchange rates
between currencies would provide signals to the issuing banks to
contract (or expand) the stock of their currencies. Thus, if bank A
overissued its currency, the value of currency A in terms of other
currencies would fall. To prevent further depreciation and to ensure
the preservation of the public’s desire to hold its currency, bank A
would have to take steps to contract the stock of its currency. If the
bank views its brand-name currency as a capital asset, the incentive,
as Klein (1974) suggests, is for the bank not to overissue. Generalizing
863
CATO JOURNAL
this result implies that the supplies of currencies by private firms
will be bounded.22
In terms of the knowledge problem, Hayek’s proposed regime
appears to offer several attractive features not evident in those considered in section III of this paper. Perhaps the most obvious is the
absence of the need for a policymaking role by the Fed. As discussed
earlier, the Fed’s obligation to supply base money carries the corresponding charge of formulating and implementing monetary policy.
The various manifestations of the knowledge problem inherent in
that charge do not arise under Hayek’s proposal because government
money would be just another currency subject to the same competitive constraints as all other currencies. Fed “monetary policy” (in
the usual sense of that term) would be irrelevant.23
Currency issuing firms in a Hayekian regime pursue “monetary
policy” only in the sense that they contract (or expand) their balance
sheets to maintain a stable value of their currencies in terms of the
commodity basket. Unlike a centralized monetary authority, such
firms have no need to constructmodels of the economy to determine
appropriate policy. Their purview, moreover, is unrelated to the path
and levels ofaggregates in the economy. As a result, they are neither
burdened with the task nor have the incentive to collect particulate
information on a scale approaching that of a centralized monetary
authority. Instead, each bank in Hayek’s scheme has ready access to
the information relevant for its decision making by consulting the
currency exchange market. The signals that the currency exchange
generate summarize the market’s assessment ofbanks’ past (or recent)
behavior and presumably provide information useful in guiding their
future behavior. This suggests that even though changes in a bank’s
balance sheet will alter commodity basket prices in terms of its
currency, the bank has no special incentive to expend resources to
acquire that information. Rather, the bank is able to economize on
what it needs to know by referring to the currency exchange market.
As Hayek (1978, p. 56) puts it:
The bank would therefore have to look to the effects of changes in
its circulation, not so much directly on the prices of other commod~Girton and Roper (1979, 1981) argue that a competitive system of substitutable (fiduciary) monies will generate the optimum quantity of money. They show that for a
costlessly produced money, the real cost of holding it, not its price, will be driven to
zero. In their model the equilibrium real rate of return on alternative assets requires
banks to offer the same real rate for money balances by paying a positive nominal
interest rate or by contracting money to generate an equivalent rate of deflation,
~Girton and Roper (1981, p. 27) argue that “a money supplied at a fixed rate of growth
would be driven from circulation if the public is offered substitutable convertible
currencies.”
864
THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
ities, but on the rates ofexchange with the currencies against which
they are chiefly traded,
In a regime of competing currencies, the problem of inherent
constraints on knowledge is not“solved” in the same sense as raising
the thermostat solves the problem of being cold. The sensation of
feeling cold disappears, but the problem ofknowledge does not. The
relevant issue, rather, is the extent to which dispersed knowledge is
used effectively. In Hayek’s monetary regime, an economy of knowledge is achieved because decision making and control are decentralized. The informational efficiencies associated with individuals’
access to practical knowledge of “particular circumstances of time
and place” (Hayek 1948, p. 80) provide the negative-feedback regulative mechanism essential for the coordination of plans. In the
Denationalisation of Money Hayek (1978, p. 98) writes:
Indeed, if. . .the main advantage of the market order is that prices
will convey to the acting individuals the relevant information, only
the constant observation of the course ofcurrent prices ofparticular
commodities can provide information on the direction in which
more or less money ought to be spent. [Money] should be part of
the self-steering mechanism by which individuals are constantly
induced to adjust their activities to circumstances on which they
have information only through the abstract signals ofprices. It should
be a serviceable link in the process that communicates the effects
of events never wholly known to anybody and that is required to
maintain an order in whichthe plans ofparticipating persons match.
Although Hayek’s proposed regime may seem to deal effectively
with aspects of the “knowledge problem,” I am not suggesting that
it is without potential drawbacks. There is a sense in which Hayek’s
monetary regime assumes away the possible existence of certain
informational problems. Ifwe suppose that several media of exchange
circulate within a given locale, individuals would incur increased
information and transaction costs.a~Among the efficiencies associated
with the use ofmoney is the decrease in the number of relative prices
compared to barter. For a barter system with n commodities, (n12)(n1) relative prices exist, while only (n-i) relative prices exist if one
commodity serves as money and is traded on every market. As the
number of circulating currencies increases, the number of relative
prices existing on the market also rises, thus generating increased
costs of information.
This difficulty would be diminished, and eventually eliminated,
as the number of competing currencies in a locale approached one
54
See Mundell (1961), Klein (1974).
865
CATO JOURNAL
and as the circulation area of that currency grew larger. But the
reduction in information and transactions costs this implies would
expose the system to other difficulties. As the number of competing
currencies dwindled, the competitive constraints facing the remaining ones become associated increasingly with potential entrants and
decreasingly with actual competitors. If potential entrants face nontrivial start up costs to induce individuals to use their currency,
established issuers are situated to exploit their position and reap
extra-normal profits by overissuing their currencies. There is a limit
pricing problem here that reduces the incentives for issuers to fulfill
their announced intention to maintain the value of their currencies
within a narrow range.”
On the other hand, the existence of entry costs does not give
existing issuers carte blanche or imply that conditions will favor the
establishment of a “super-currency.” The notion that the need for
currency competition will bring forth currency competition is relevant here as a binding, though unspeciflable, constraint upon established issuers.
A second difficulty may also arise with overlapping currency areas
concerning variations in currency exchange rates. If exchange rates
fluctuate, people are exposed to capital value losses. The loss may
be temporary if the depreciated currency’s bank moves to restore its
exchange value. However, the possibility exists that to avoid those
risks people will shift to other currencies, further destabilizing the
value of the depreciated currency. This may be particularly relevant
if payments systems use electronic funds transfers, in which deposits
can be withdrawn almost instantaneously. Although banks might
develop interbank lines ofcredit to insure their liquidity, those lines
may tend to dry up (or become more costly) when they are needed
most.’°In the face of these considerations individuals may reduce
their overall risk of capital value loss by diversifying their money
holdings. While this reintroduces the problem of currency areas
mentioned above, it may also have the desirable effect ofmaintaining
~Vaubel (1977) argues that currency competition will necessarily evolveinto currency
unification (i.e., nationalized monies) because the production of money is subject to
economics of scale and hence involves a natural monopoly. Vaubel’s claim assumes
that the quality of money increases as its domain expands (p. 458). This is true in the
sense that information costs fall as the currency area increases. But it may not be true
if “quality” is associated with stable purchasing power.
56
The problem here is that a potential interbank lender may not have adequate information on the status of the balance sheet of the troubled bank. An adverse exchange
rate movement in abank’s currency may indicate a serious problem or mightbe entirely
temporary. If the lender assumes the former, credit maybe difficult to obtain.
866
THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
an underlying demand for several currencies. In this case, a competitive market in money is furthered.’7
In terms of variations in currency exchange rates, an underlying
issue is that the currency exchange market is driven in part by expectations of future exchange rate movements. While no special advantage is gained by postulating “animal spirits,” it is well to remember
that expectations are ultimately psychological and subjective. Consequently, the meshing of expectations and the dovetailing of plans
will not always be smooth or complete. It is plausible to assume that
individuals will revise false expectations, but the learning process
this involves and the character ofreformulated expectations may be
difficult to specify. In the absence of a more detailed treatment of
expectations, the operation ofthe currency exchange market is something of a loose joint in Hayek’s proposal.
V. Conclusion
The failure of the current monetary regime to achieve consistently
stable prices probably explains the increased interest in exploring
alternative monetary regimes. Criticisms of the Fed, whether they
focus on the details of Fed behavior or attribute monetary problems
to the stewards of monetary policy, concern the knowledge problem
it faces as an institution. As a result, the agenda established for the
Fed may be excessively optimistic and, in the end, unobtainable.
Lucas (1980, p. 209) notes, “as an advice-giving profession we are in
way over our heads.”
The yet untried monetarist proposal may be a plausible regime in
that it would alleviate monetary policymakers of some of the difficulties suggested by the knowledge problem. Nevertheless, serious
doubts about it arise in a dynamic context. A monetary rule would
likely eliminate the possibility of severe inflation, but the problem
of financial asset and quasi-money stock endogeneity cannot be dismissed, especially if financial regulations and the monetary growth
rule constraints become binding.
A regime of competing currencies along the lines suggested by
Hayek offers an interesting alternative to government provision of
base money. Implicitly, Hayek’s proposal is a critique of having
monetary policy at all. For Hayek, Fed monetary policy, by discretion
or a growth rule, is macroeconomic “central planning” that fails to
achieve the economy ofknowledge attributed to market mechanisms.
Hayek’s proposal is not without difficulties, but their severity is open
27
Girton and Roper (1981) show that exchange rate instability is reduced as currency
substitution increases between competitive, endogenously supplied monies.
867
CATO JOURNAL
to further question. Since our knowledge of a regime of competing
(inconvertible) currencies is largely theoretical, its actual operation
remains something of a mystery. In any event, additional theoretical
and historical work would be useful. Among the issues that here
seem pertinent, the question of Hayek’s suggestion for a commodity
basket as the standard of value would merit further study, given that
convertible (gold) commodity standards have historically emerged
as the preferred ones. In this sense, White’s (1984a) proposal may be
more consistent with what we know about monetary regimes.
Second, Hayek’s regime does not specify a role for a lender (or
lenders) of last resort. Presumably, such institutions are not inconsistent with Hayek’s regime, and there is evidence to suggest that
they would emerge in a free banking environment (see White 1984a).
Additional study of this function is essential for proposals recommending abolition ofgovernment monopolization ofmoney. A useful
starting point might be to consider the international interbank loan
market.
References
Auerbach, Irving M. “Comment.”Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 14
(November 1982): 761—67.
Balbach, Anatol, “How Controllable is Money Growth?” Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review 63 (April 1981): 3—12.
Black, Fischer. “Banking and Interest Rates in a World Without Money: The
Effects of Uncontrolled Banking.” Journal of Bank Research 1 (Autumn
1970): 9—20.
Brunner, Karl. “Has Monetarism Failed?” CatoJournal 3 (Spring 1983): 23—
62.
Burns, Arthur. Reflections of an Economic Policy Maker. Washington, D.C.:
American Enterprise Institute, 1978.
Cagan, Philip. “The Choice Among Monetary Aggregates as Targets and
Guides for Monetary Policy.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 14
(November 1982): 666—86.
Dotsey, Michael. “Monetary Policy, Secrecy, and Federal Funds Rate Behavior,” Manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank ofRichmond, 1984.
Fama, Eugene. “Banking in the Theory of Finance.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 6 (January 1980): 39—57.
Friedman, Milton. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham
University Press, 1960.
Friedman, Milton. “Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy.” In Current Issues in Monetary Theory and Policy, pp. 556—65. Edited by Thomas
M. Havrilesky and John T. Boorman. Arlington Heights, Ill.: AHM, 1976.
Friedman, Milton. “Monetary Policy: Theory and Practice.” Journal ofMoney,
Credit and Banking 14 (February 1982): 98—118.
Friedman, Milton, and Schwartz, Anna. A Monetary History of the United
States, 1867—1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.
868
THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
Girton, Lance, and Roper, Don. “Substitutable Monies and the Monetary
Standard.” In The Political Economy of Policymaking, pp. 233—46. Edited
by M. P. Dooley, H. M. Kaufman, and R. E. Lombra. Beverly Hills: Sage,
1979.
Girton, Lance, and Roper, Don. “Theory and Implications of Currency Substitution.”Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 13 (February 1981): 12—
30.
Goldfeld, Stephen. “The Case ofthe Missing Money.” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity 3 (1976): 683—730.
Gramley, Lyle. “Financial Innovation and Monetary Policy.” Federal Reserve
Bulletin (July 1982): 393—400.
Greenfield, Robert L., and Yeager, Leland B. “A Laissez-Faire Approach to
Monetary Stability.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 15 (August
1983): 302—15.
Hayek, F. A. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” In Individualism and
Economic Order, pp. 77—91. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948.
Hayek, F. A. “Notes on the Evolution of Systems of Rules of Conduct.” In
Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics, pp. 66—81. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967.
Hayek, F. A. Denationalisation of Money. London: Institute of Economic
Affairs, 1976; 1978, 2d ed.
Johannes, James, and Rasche, Robert. “Predicting the Money Multiplier.”
Journal of Monetary Economics 8 (July 1979): 301—25.
Judd, John P., and Scadding, John L. “The Search for a Stable Money Demand
Function.” Journal of Economic Literature 20 (September 1982): 993—
1023.
Kane, Edward. “Good Intentions and Unintended Evil.” Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 9 (February 1977): 55—69.
King, Robert G. “On the Economics ofPrivate Money.”Journal of Monetary
Economics 12 (July 1983): 127—58.
Klein, Benjamin. “The Competitive Supply of Money.” Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 5 (November 1974): 423—53.
Lombra, Raymond E. “Monetary Control: Consensus or Confusion?” In
Controlling Monetary Aggregates III, pp. 268—303. Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston, 1980.
Lombra, Raymond E., and Kaufman, Herbert M. “Central Bank Behavior and
Money Stock Determination: Pitfalls of Policy Analysis.” Manuscript,
Department of Economics, Pennsylvania State University, 1985.
Lombra, Raymond E., and Moran, Michael. “Policy Advice and Policymaking
at the Federal Reserve.” In Monetary Institutions and the Policy Process,
pp. 9—68. Edited by KarlBrunner andAllan H. Meltzer. Amsterdam: NorthHolland, 1980.
Lombra, Raymond E., and Struble, Fredrick. “Monetary Aggregate Targets
and the Volatility of Interest Rates: A Taxonomic Discussion.” Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking 11 (August 1979): 184—200.
Lombra, Raymond E., and Torto, Raymond. “The Strategy of Monetary Policy.” In Current Issuesin Monetary Theory and Policy, pp.422—43. Edited
by Thomas M. Havrilesky and John T. Boorman. Arlington Heights, Ill.:
AHM, 1976.
869
CATO JOURNAL
Lucas, Robert E. “Rules, Discretion, and the Role ofthe Economic Advisor.”
In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, pp. 199—210. Edited by
Stanley Fischer. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980.
Mason, Will E. “The Empirical Definition of Money: A Critique.” Economic
Inquiry 14 (December 1976): 525—38,
Mason, Will E. “The Case for the Gold Standard: Semantics vs. Substance.”
Manuscript, 1984.
Mayer, Thomas. “The Structure ofMonetarism, land II.” Kredit und Kapital
2—3 (1975): 191—215; 293—313.
Menger, Carl. “On the Origin of Money.” Economic Journal 2 (June 1892):
239—55,
Mundell, Robert A. “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas.” American
Economic Review 51 (September 1961): 657—65.
O’Brien, James M. “Estimating the Information Value of Immediate Disclosure of the FOMC Policy Directive.” Journal of Finance 36 (December
1981): 1047—61.
Polanyi, Michael. The Tacit Dimension. New York: Doubleday, 1966.
Poole, William, “Optimal Choice ofMonetary Policy Instruments in a Simple
Stochastic Macro Model.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (May 1970):
197—216.
Rasche, Robert. “Is the Federal Reserve’s Monetary Control Policy Misdirected?” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 14 (February 1982): 119—
47.
Rockoff, Hugh. “The Free Banking Era: A Reexamination.”Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 6 (May 1974): 103—16.
Rolnick, Arthur, and Weber, Warren E. “New Evidence on the Free Banking
Era,” American Economic Review 73 (December 1983): 1080—91.
Rolnick, Arthur, and Weber, Warren E. “The Causes ofFree Bank Failures:
A Detailed Examination.” Journal of Monetary Economics 14 (November
1984): 267—91.
Shughart, William F., and Tollison, Robert D. “Preliminary Evidence on the
Use of Inputs by the Federal Reserve System.” American Economic Review
73 (June 1983): 291—304.
Thompson, Earl A. “The Theory of Money and Income Consistent With
Orthodox Value Theory,” In Trade, Stability and Macroeconomics: Essays
in Honor of Lloyd Metzler, pp. 427—53. Edited by Paul A. Samuelson and
George Horwich. New York: Academic Press, 1974.
Toma, Mark. “Inflationary Bias of the Federal Reserve System.” Journal of
Monetary Economics 10 (September 1982): 163—90.
Vaubel, Roland. “Free CurrencyCompetition.” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv
112, no. 3 (1977): 435—59.
Voicker, Paul. “Statement Before House Committee on Banking, Finance,
and Urban Affairs.” Federal Reserve Bulletin (May 1983): 337—40,
Volcker, Paul. “Letter to Chairman Fauntroy of House Subcommittee on
Domestic Monetary Policy, August 14, 1984.”
Weimer, Walter B. “Spontaneously Ordered Complex Phenomena and the
Unity of the Moral Sciences.” Manuscript, 1983.
White, Lawrence H. “Competitive Money, Inside and Out.” Cato Journal 3
(Spring 1983): 281—300.
870
THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
White, Lawrence H. Free Banking in Britain: Theory, Experience, and Debate,
1800—1845. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984a.
White, Lawrence H. “Free Banking as an Alternative Monetary System.” In
Money in Crisis, pp. 269—302. Edited by Barry Siegel. Cambridge, Mass.:
Ballinger, 1984b.
871
THE PROBLEM OF MONETARY
CONTROL: ANOTHER VIEWPOINT
EdwardJ. Green
My comment will focus on the part of Professor Butos’ (1986) paper
that deals explicitly with the Federal Reserve System. This portion
of the paper can be read simply as an analysis of a specific monetary
policy regime that the Federal Reserve imposed during the period
1979—82. However, it is clear that Butos views that particular regime
as being broadly representative ofthe policies that the Federal Reserve
and other central banks have followed over the course of a substantially longer historical period. Thus, his paper can also be read as a
comparison of the institution of central banking with other political
and economic institutions that have been recommended for the provision ofmoney. The present comment will focus on this latter, more
general, aspect of the paper.
In his paper, Butos proposes answers to three questions that he
has implicitly posed. The first of these questions is, what is the
appropriate role ofa monetary institution? Following Professor F. A.
Hayek, Butos suggests that a monetary institution should foster an
environment in which nominal prices can effectively aggregate and
disseminate the incomplete and dispersed information possessed by
individual market agents. The second question is, how do monetary
institutions actually operate? Butos’ discussion ofthe Federal Reserve
System is consistent with the assumption that there is a good-faith
effort to achieve the appropriate goal of informational efficiency that
has just been mentioned. The third question is, how does the actual
performance of the monetary institution compare with its intended
performance? Butos argues that, although it acts in good faith, the
Federal Reserve System achieves only limited success in enhancing
the informational efficiency of prices.
Cato Journal, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Winter 1986). Copyright © Cato Institute. All rights
reserved.
The author is Professor of Economics at the University of Pittsburgh.
873
CATO JOURNAL
One might expect an economist writing in the tradition of Hayek
to approach his subject from a substantially different perspective
from that of many other economists. The preceding account ofButos’
paper should make it clear, though, that his perspective actually is
not very different from others’. Virtually all economists would agree
that his three questions are the appropriate ones to pose. Virtually
all would define the appropriate goal of the monetary institution in
terms of optimizing some narrowly economic objective function,
although quantities such as the levels of output and employment
would be competing candidates to be optimized. (Perhaps it is a
tribute to Hayek that the informational efficiency of the price system
is now considered to be a narrowly economic objective on a par with
these others.) With the notable exception of the public choice school,
most economists would probably subscribe to the view that central
banks (although not necessarily all public-sector institutions) typically act in good faith to do what they are supposed to do. There
would be less agreement with Butos concerning the extent that central banks succeed in their good-faith endeavor, but this is a question
about which the economics profession in general is not unanimous.
In this comment, I would like to suggest that another aspect of
Hayek’s thinking would be relevant to thinking about the questions
stated above. In particular, I refer to his work on constitutional theory.
In that work, he has emphasized that government should not be
viewed as a single optimizing agent, or indeed as an agent that ought
to optimize something. Rather, government is a set of evolving institutions that ought to provide a stable environment in which privatesector agents would be able to make intelligent decisions. In the
economic sphere, “price stability” is a way of describing such a
stable, reliable environment. However, this notion is quite different
from the idea that the monetary authority ought to minimize the
variance of a lime series of price levels. Thus the conception of the
monetary authority that I have in mind here is contrary to that embodied in much of contemporary macroeconomic theory where solving
such a minimization problem is taken to be the objective ofthe central
bank. (Incidentally, the inappropriateness of this objective is the
theme of much of economists’ work on indexation.)
Rather, an important component of “price stability” ought to be
that the monetary system is reasonably insulated from political interference. Aside from the criticisms that Butos raises regarding a constant money supply growth rule, it is hard to see how such a rule
would be an effective insulating device. If Congress were to mandate
such a rule, it could just as easily and quickly reverse the mandate
when such a reversal would be politically expedient. It may be that,
874
COMMENT ON BUTOS
in order meaningfully to insulate the price system from political
interference, it is necessary to have a bureaucracy to act as a buffer.
Its role as such a buffer is one of the important things to understand
about the Federal Reserve System.
Of course, there are costs as well as benefits to having buffers, and
bureaucracies can be either well or badly designed. Let me mention
three observations regarding these issues. First, in order to insulate
the monetary system from politically powerful interests and institutions, the monetary authority itself presumably needs to have considerable political power. This suggests that power in the monetary
authority may need to be more highly centralized than would be the
case if it were really an apolitical, technocratic agency. In particular,
it seems naive not to expect the Chairman of the Federal Reserve
Board firmly to control the FOMC. Second, it seems inevitable that
a monetary authority will allow very strong political pressures to be
transmitted in attenuated form to the monetary system. When Congress directs the authority to do something to ameliorate what constituents perceive to be a terrible situation, the Chairman cannot
simply argue that his job is to foster long-term price stability and that
that is what he is doing. When we look for a politically viable way to
insulate the monetary system, then we are looking for a less-thanideal way to insulate it. Third, the monetary authority will be staffed
by human beings who have interests and incentives. Thus, all problems ofpublic-sector bureaucracies that are pointed out by the public
choice school will be experienced to some extent by the monetary
authority. In 1986, the recognition that political agents are not Plato’s
guardians should not shock anyone. Rather, it should prompt people
to think about the problem of designing monetary institutions in a
way that will minimize these problems, subject to the constraint that
the authority must retain the substantial political power that is required
for its work. In the case of the Federal Reserve System, the division
of the monetary authority into regional banks, and the employment
of a large staff of academic economists (who owe some allegiance to
a set of professional values, as well as to their immediate employer)
arguably address these concerns.
The preceding paragraph should be read as an expression of what
I do not find completely satisfactory about the way that most macroeconomists of various schools think about the problem of monetary
control. Insofar as he deals with the Federal Reserve System, I read
Butos’ paper as being closer to this mainstream conception than he
may realize himself to be. The observations that I have made above
are not intended as statements of established fact, but rather as sensible conjectures deserving of further exploration. I hope that both
875
CATO JOURNAL
macroeconomists and students of political economy will find this
program to be attractive.
Reference
Butos, William N. “The Knowledge Problem under Alternative Monetary
Regimes,” Cato Journal 5 (Winter 1986): 849—71.
876