DIIS POLICY BRIEF
The West must allow a
power shift in international
organizations
February 2014
Emerging market and developing countries have become increasingly frustrated with Western states for
clinging to their power, in the IMF and other international organizations. Adjustments are needed and
the emerging cooperation among the BRICS sends a clear signal to the West to stop stalling the process.
Jakob Vestergaard,
[email protected]
Robert H. Wade,
[email protected]
OVERVIEW OF THE CURRENT STALEMATE
Everyone agrees, in principle, that the global governance
organizations established after the Second World War –
notably the IMF and the World Bank – must adapt their
governance to the fact of a now more multipolar world.
Everyone agrees, in principle, that member countries’
share of votes in the governing boards should relect their
present-day relative economic weight.
At irst glance the IMF has already taken a big step towards raising the voting power of “Emerging Market and Developing Countries” (EMDCs). In 2010, its member countries agreed both to boost the lending power of the IMF and
to shift 6.2 % of quota shares, and hence voting power, in
favour of “dynamic” EMDCs. In November 2010, Managing Director Dominique Strauss-Kahn hailed this agreement as “the most fundamental governance overhaul in the
IMF’s 65-year history and the biggest-ever shift of inluence in favor of emerging market and developing countries”.
However, more than three years later the shift has yet to be
implemented, largely because the US Congress has still not
approved what the US executive branch agreed to. Moreover, the key shift from developed countries to EMDCs
is only 2.6%, the rest being shifts within the category of
emerging market and developing countries from “overre-
POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS
•
The IMF should realign quota shares to address
long-standing voting power imbalances, notably
the overrepresentation of European countries
and underrepresentation of emerging market
economies.
•
The IMF should agree to a new quota formula
that establishes a much closer link (than does
the current formula) between relative economic
weight in the world economy and voting power
in the IMF.
•
To preserve the voting power of the poorest
developing countries, the share of basic votes in
total votes should be doubled (from 5.5 % to at
least 10%), so as to restore them to the same
level as when the IMF was founded.
•
Western states must assume responsibility for
taking these steps – for the sake of boosting the
effectiveness of global economic governance
and checking the present drive towards
"coalitions of the willing" in various plurilateral
arrangements.
1
DIIS POLICY BRIEF
presented” EMDCs to “underrepresented” EMDCs. Such
a small change comes nowhere close to aligning share of
votes with any plausible measure of economic weight.
If economic weight is measured by gross domestic product
(GDP), then the agreed 2010 reforms will still leave very large
discrepancies between share of economic weight and share
of voting power. On average, a dollar of EU4 (Germany,
France, UK and Italy) GDP is worth more than twice as big
a share of votes as a dollar of GDP from the BRIC countries
(Brazil, Russia, India and China).
However, while most member states agree that, in the
interests of simplicity and consistency, economic weight
should be measured by GDP, the Europeans are adamant
that economic weight is not just GDP but also “openness”.
Intra-Europe trade boosts Europe’s weight, while intra-US
or intra-China trade does not boost theirs. he BRICS
(Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa) argue that
if measures beyond GDP are to be included in the determination of quota and voting shares, criteria of “contributions to global growth” should be among them.
he result is stalemate on the commitment made in 2010
to revise the quota formula in time for the next reallocation of quotas. he deadline for a new formula has been
postponed several times, and the latest deadline, January
2015, also seems optimistic given that the quota formula
negotiations have been put on hold until the US Congress
approves the 2010 reforms.
the Fund. But at the same time as they agreed the NAB,
the G20 countries committed themselves to revise the
governance of the Fund so as to shift quota share and voting power in favor of dynamic emerging market economies. heir communiqué from the summit in Pittsburgh
in September 2009 announced that “[w]e are committed
to a shift in International Monetary Fund (IMF) quota
share to dynamic emerging markets and developing countries of at least 5%”.
Given their marching orders by the G20, the Executive
Directors set out to negotiate the shift. In 2010 they announced a major success: an agreement to shift 6.2 % in
quota shares (hence voting power) from overrepresented to
underrepresented countries.
But this was misleading, to put it politely. Less than half of
the mentioned igure is what really matters: a shift of voting power from advanced economies to EMDCs. he G7
countries, as a group, concede only 1.8 percentage points
of their voting power, in aggregate. Table 1 presents the voting power of 15 large countries, as it currently stands (as
of December 2013) and as it will be if or when the 2010
voice reforms take efect.
So not only has the 2010 quota share reallocation – modest as it is – yet to take efect, but the IMF is continuing
forward without a legitimate quota formula, despite repeated airmations that a new formula must be agreed. Lack
of agreement suits the Europeans well, for it protects their
current overrepresentation.
With this overview in mind, we will now elaborate on the
discussion, even at the cost of some repetition of what has
just been said.
THE 2010 QUOTA REFORMS
he voice reforms agreed in 2010 formed part of a larger
post-2008-crisis compromise among representatives of
the world’s largest economies. he G20 summit in London in 2009 agreed to a tripling of the inancial resources
of the IMF, including substantial contributions from Japan, China and a number of other large emerging market
economies. his took the form of New Arrangements to
Borrow (NAB), which introduced a new funding channel
for the IMF to supplement the standard channel of quota
subscriptions paid by member states.
Unlike quota shares, these additional funds did not give
contributing member countries a higher voting share in
2
Note: A selection of 15 of the world’s 30 largest economies, based on a
50/50 2012 GDP ‘blend’ (i.e. giving 50 % weight to GDP at market
prices and 50% weight to GDP in purchasing power parity terms).
Source: World Development Indicators (November 2013). Data for
current voting power are July 2013 actual voting shares.
As can be seen, most changes are microscopic. In only two
cases out of 15 large countries the change in voting power
will be larger than half a percentage point (China, with a
2.26 percentage point increase, and Belgium, with a 0.56
percentage point loss).
VOTING POWER IMBALANCES REMAIN
MASSIVE
Most member states agree that voting share should be closely linked to GDP share, as the simplest, least unambiguous
measure of economic weight. Table 2 shows voting power-toGDP ratios, both as of today and if and when the changes agreed in 2010 are put into efect. If voting power were aligned
with GDP share we should expect all countries to cluster close
to 1. As can be seen, the voting power-to-GDP ratios show
a wide dispersion. hey vary ive-fold, from 0.45 in the case
of China to 2.15 for Belgium. Not just China but also India
(0.60) and Brazil (0.73) are underrepresented, while the larger
European countries are overrepresented by this criterion.
On average, a dollar of GDP in the EU4 countries is worth
more than twice as much as a dollar of GDP in one of the
BRIC countries, in terms of voting power in the Fund.
his means that the aggregate voting power of the EU4
is higher (17.6 %) than the aggregate voting power of the
BRICs (10.3 %), despite the fact that the GDP of the
BRICs, as a share of world GDP, is almost twice as large
(24.5 %) as the GDP of the EU4 (13.4 %).
QUOTA FORMULA REVISION IN PERIL
he problems are not just that the shifts agreed upon in
2010 have not been implemented, and that even if and
when they are implemented they will leave massive voting power imbalances. On top of these is the problem of
revising the quota formula that has guided allocations of
shares in the IMF for decades. Successive deadlines have
come and gone, with next to no agreement.
he existing quota formula allocates quota shares to member countries on the basis of four variables (with their
weights in the formula given in parentheses):
• size of a member’s economy, as measured by GDP
(50%);
• member’s integration into the world economy, or
‘openness’ (30 %);
• member’s potential need for IMF resources,
measured in terms of ‘variability’ of current receipts and
net capital lows (15%); and
• member’s inancial strength and ability to contribute to
the Fund’s inances, as measured by its foreign exchange
reserves (5%).
Instead of announcing a new formula in January 2013, as
planned, the Executive Board of Directors (EBD) reported
to the Board of Governors on the outcome of the Quota
Formula Review (IMF 2013). he main conclusions were:
(a) “it was agreed that GDP should remain the most
important variable, with the largest weight in the formula
and scope to further increase its weight”; and
(b) there was “considerable support for dropping variability from the formula” (IMF 2013: 2-3).
Beyond these, the Executive Directors could agree on little.
hen in October 2013, following the IMF’s annual meetings, the council of ministers which steers the IMF (International Monetary and Finance Committee) declared in
its communiqué:
Note: A selection of 15 of the world’s 30 largest economies, based on a
50/50 2012 GDP ‘blend’ (i.e. giving 50 % weight to GDP at market
prices and 50% weight to GDP in purchasing power parity terms).
Source: World Development Indicators (November 2013). Data for
current voting power are July 2013 actual voting shares.
“we urge the Executive Board to agree on a new quota
formula… [and] reairm that any realignment in quota
shares is expected to result in increased shares for dynamic
economies in line with their relative positions in the world
economy”.
But again, in the subsequent period from October to December 2013 the Executive Board has made no progress,
and recently postponed the deadline to January 2015.
3
DIIS POLICY BRIEF
UNDERSTANDING THE QUOTA FORMULA
STALEMATE
At the core of the stalemate is the notion of relative country economic weight. he default position for most countries remains “share of world GDP”, simply because of its
simplicity. But the Europeans insist that economic weight
is not just GDP but also “openness”; integration with the
world economy. Not coincidentally, Europe’s weight is
then boosted by intra-Europe trade, while the weights of
the US, China, India, Brazil et al. are not boosted by their
internal trade. With this and related arguments Europeans
insist that European countries are in fact underrepresented, not overrepresented – an assertion which provokes
much scowling and scoing from other participants, including the BRICS. Many countries are prepared to accept
that “openness” should have some weight in the new quota
formula, but say that the current measure of openness is
“seriously lawed relecting both conceptual and methodological issues” and must be replaced by a measure that
avoids the positive bias for intra-Europe trade (IMF 2013:
3). And they go on to say that if “openness” is included, so
should other factors. he BRICS demand a weight for
“contribution to global economic growth”. In response to
such galloping complexity, many participants fall back on
share of GDP as the only viable criterion – only to encounter outraged European objection.
they have been signaling that they – especially the BRICS
– will “be more careful and selective before agreeing” to
activate the New Arrangements to Borrow (NAB), in the
words of a participant. And the BRICS are well along in
the negotiation of a BRICS Development Bank and a
BRICS Contingent [Foreign Exchange] Reserve Arrangement (for currency swaps or pooling), scheduled to be
signed at the 2014 BRICS summit.
It is diicult to escape a sense that Western governments
are allowing their drive to cling to power to obscure the
bigger issues at stake. Western governments must go
beyond their rhetorical commitment to shift voting power
towards EMDCs, and actually do it – for the sake of boosting the efectiveness of multilateral economic governance
and checking the present drive towards “coalitions of the
willing” in plurilateral arrangements, a drive which raises
the prospect of a return to the “competing power blocs” of
18th to 20th century Europe and the chronic instability
they generated.
MULTILATERALISM AT RISK
Many representatives from EMDCs, including the BRICS,
are getting increasingly frustrated with Western determination to cling to power not just in the IMF but also in the
World Bank and other important international economic
governance organizations. hey are plotting how to induce
Western states to agree to real reductions in the Western
“voice”. One way is for them to move towards the exit. So
FURTHER READINGS
IMF (2010). IMF Quota and Governance – Elements of an Agreement. Report of the Executive Board to the Board of
Governors. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
IMF (2013). Report of the Executive Board of Governors on the Outcome of the Quota Formula Review. Washington,
DC: International Monetary Fund.
Lesage, D., Debaerre, P., Dierckx, S. and Vermeiren, M. et al (2013). IMF reform after the crisis. International Politics, 50
(4): 553-578.
Vestergaard, J. and Wade, R. (2013). Protecting power: How Western states retained their dominant voice in the World
Bank’s governance reforms. World Development, 46: 153-164.
he opinions expressed in this policy brief are those of the authors alone and do not necessarily relect the oicial opinion of the
Danish Institute for International Studies.
DIIS · DANISH INSTITUTE FOR INTERNATIONAL STUDIES
Østbanegade 117, DK-2100 Copenhagen, Denmark · tel: +45 32 69 87 87 · e-mail:
[email protected] · www.diis.dk
4