_1
_ Poverty trends since the transition
Poverty trends since the transition
Slaves as capit al invest m ent in t he Dut ch Cape Colony,
1652- 1795
JOHAN FOURI E
St ellenbosch Econom ic Working Papers: 21/ 11
DECEMBER 2011
KEYWORDS: SLAVERY, SETTLER, PROTO- I NDUSTRY, EI GHTEENTH CENTURY,
SOUTH AFRI CA
JEL: N57, N27
JOHAN FOURI E
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMI CS
UNI VERSI TY OF STELLENBOSCH
PRI VATE BAG X1, 7602
MATI ELAND, SOUTH AFRI CA
E- MAI L:
[email protected]
A WORKI NG PAPER OF THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMI CS AND THE
BUREAU FOR ECONOMI C RESEARCH AT THE UNI VERSI TY OF STELLENBOSCH
Slaves as capit al invest m ent in t he Dut ch Cape Colony,
1652- 1795
JOHAN FOURI E
ABSTRACT
The Cape Colony of t he eight eent h cent ury was one of t he m ost prosperous
regions in t he world. This paper shows t hat Cape farm ers prospered, on average,
because of t he econom ies of scale and scope achieved t hrough slavery. Slaves
allowed farm ers t o specialise in agricult ural product s t hat were in high dem and
from t he passing ships – not ably, wheat , wine and m eat – and t he by- product s
from t hese product s, such as t allow, skins, soap and candles. I n exchange,
farm ers could im port cheap m anufact ured product s from Europe and t he East .
Secondly, t he paper invest igat es why t he relat ive affluence of t he early set t lers
did not evolve int o a high growt h t raj ect ory. The use of slaves as a subst it ut e for
wage labour or ot her capit al invest m ent s allowed farm ers t o prosper, but it also
result ed in severe inequalit y. I t was t his high inequalit y t hat drove t he growt hdebilit at ing inst it ut ions posit ed by Engerm an and Sokoloff ( 2000) . The
im m igrat ion of Europeans was discouraged aft er 1717, and again during t he
m iddle of t he cent ury, while educat ion was lim it ed t o t he wealt hy. Fact or
endowm ent s int eract ed wit h inst it ut ions t o creat e a highly unequal early Sout h
African societ y, wit h long- t erm developm ent consequences.
Keywords: Slavery, Set t ler, Prot o- indust ry, Eight eent h cent ury, Sout h Africa
JEL codes: N57, N27
1
Slaves as capital investment in the
Dutch Cape Colony, 1652‐17951
)ntroduction
JO(AN FOUR)E
The Cape Colony at the southern tip of Africa offers valuable lessons on the emergence of a
productive agricultural society in a pre‐colonial, mercantilist setting. Not only was the Cape
Colony under Company rule – the Vereenigde Oostindische Compagnie, or VOC, which maintained
a unique set of formal and informal institutions – but the particular geographic position of the
Cape, as a midway point for ships sailing between Europe and the East )ndies, and the temperate
climate conducive for Mediterranean winter‐rainfall crops, engendered unique factor
endowments that gave rise to a relatively affluent settler society. And yet, it also gave rise to a
slave society and severe inequality.
This paper firstly explores the reasons for the relative prosperity of the eighteenth century Cape
settlers, estimated elsewhere to have achieved some of the highest levels of per capita wealth in
the world Fourie and Van Zanden,
. )t shows that Cape farmers prospered, on average,
because of the economies of scale and scope achieved through slavery. Slaves allowed farmers to
specialise in agricultural products that were in high demand from the passing ships – notably,
wheat, wine and meat – and the by‐products from these products, such as tallow, skins, soap and
candles. )n exchange, farmers could import cheap manufactured products from Europe and the
East.
Secondly, the paper investigates why the relative affluence of the early settlers did not evolve
into a high growth trajectory. The use of slaves as a substitute for wage labour or other capital
investments allowed farmers to prosper, but it also resulted in severe inequality. )t was this high
inequality that drove the growth‐debilitating institutions posited by Engerman and Sokoloff
. The immigration of Europeans was discouraged after
, and again during the middle
of the century, while education was limited to the wealthy. Factor endowments interacted with
institutions to create a highly unequal early South African society, with long‐term development
consequences.
The Cape economy
When Europeans first settled the Cape in
, their intention was not to found a new Dutch
homeland. Jan van Riebeeck and his party of VOC employees were sent to the Cape of Good (ope
to build and run a refreshment station for Dutch ships passing the Cape on their voyages to the
East or back to (olland. Fruit and vegetables – to provide those essential vitamins in the fight
1
Paper prepared as chapter for “Agricultural Transformation in a Global History Perspective”, edited by Ellen
Hillbom and Patrick Svensson. I would like to thank Jan Luiten van Zanden, Stan du Plessis and Servaas van der
Berg for helpful comments on an earlier draft, and for Anne Cillie and Jolandi Uys for research assistance. Ilze
Boonzaaier from the Centre for Geographical Analysis at Stellenbosch University assisted with the map design.
All errors remain those of the author.
2
Department of Economics, Stellenbosch University and Department of Economic and Social History, Utrecht
University. E-mail:
[email protected].
3
Missionary stations were the exceptions; see Fourie, Ross and Viljoen (2011).
2
against scurvy – would be grown close to the fort, while cattle would be traded with the native
Khoe, a pastoral people. Soon, though, Van Riebeeck realised that supply could not keep up with
the high ship demand, and in
he released nine Company servants to become free burgher
farmers and begin the process of colonisation. As Figure shows, the territory under European
influence would rapidly expand, first North then East, until
when the Company
relinquished power to the British.
Figure 1: Map of Cape Colony borders: 1682, 1705, 1731 and 1795
Source: Guelke
and own projections.
Cape Town remained the hub of economic activity during the entire eighteenth century. Those
closest to Cape Town settled on the fertile lands west of the first mountain ranges produced
wheat and wine, while the frontier farmers were predominantly pastoral, stock farmers. The
spread of farmers into the interior – away from the market – gave rise to the traditional view of
the Cape economy as an economic and social backwater which was more of a static than a
progressing community de Kock,
. Even in the most recent Economic (istory of South
Africa, Charles Feinstein concludes that, before the discovery of minerals in the late nineteenth
century, markets were small, conditions were difficult and progress was slow Feinstein,
.
This view has recently come under considerable scrutiny. Van Duin and Ross
were the
first to attempt a quantitative estimate of per capita consumption for the Cape, noting that the
local market was far more extensive than previous scholars maintained. Van Duin and Ross rely
on the opgaafrolle, annual censuses compiled by the Company for tax purposes. Brunt
,
too, uses the opgaafrolle to estimate the impact of changing property rights systems on
economic performance. (e finds that the arrival of the British at the end of the eighteenth
century boosted the sluggish economic growth during the Dutch period. This view is challenged
by De Zwart
. Using wage data from Company records, he shows that, in contrast to other
world regions, Cape real wages were increasing over most of the eighteenth century with little
evidence of a significant boom after British arrival.
3
Fourie
was the first to use probate inventories to document the living standards of Cape
settlers and compare these to other regions. While the literature and the evidence from the
opgaafrolle – which includes only agricultural indicators, and the limited records of export goods
provided by Van Duin and Ross
– suggest that the Cape remained primarily an
agricultural economy with wheat, wine, cattle and sheep the four main commodities produced,
the probate inventories point to greater complexity in the consumption and production choices
available to farmers. Fourie
refutes the claim that most settlers, especially those in the
interior, lived just above subsistence levels. Even the poorest of farmers owned luxury items that
indicate some market interaction and specialisation. The results point to growth in the
acquisition of per capita household assets from
until
and again between the
s
and
. These two growth episodes contest the claim that, on average, Cape settlers –
especially those that moved into the interior – moved into deeper poverty. (e argues that the
consumer revolution of the Cape Colony was certainly not only an elitist revolution.
Fourie
also argues that the extent and diversity of household assets suggest that most
farmers maintained strong links with the market – even though this market may only have
been the Company, intermediaries or even other farmers. )n order to acquire the household
assets observed in the inventories, farmers had to produce a surplus to be sold in the market.
The comparatively high levels of cattle and sheep ownership highlighted in the inventories,
suggest that stock may have been an important source of revenue. Aside from the higher rates of
return on stock farming, Neumark
also notes that stock yielded numerous by‐products
that were in demand in the Cape market. Meat, of course, was in high demand from the passing
ships at the Cape. But tallow, skins, soap and candles – produced by household and slave labour
on the farms as stock value added – offered farmers an additional source of revenue within the
regulations of Company rule, enough to acquire the goods observed in the inventories.
This transformation from subsistence agriculture to a highly productive sector producing large
surpluses requires explanation. This paper, therefore, investigates the composition of
productive assets at the Cape: Did farmers substitute wage labour with other forms of capital –
and, if so, what type of capital? Slaves are found to be the most valued productive assets at the
Cape. The composition of productive assets reflects the incentives available to farmers and
raises important questions which this paper attempts to answer: Why did settlers invest nearly
one quarter of all movable assets in slaves? Why did farmers not shift to other forms of capital
equipment? And, most importantly, how did the choice of slavery vis‐a‐vis other productive
assets influence the process of proto‐industrial take‐off in the Cape Colony?
Source material
Cape probate inventories provide a wealth of information to scholars that investigate household
production and consumption patterns. The inventarisse hereafter referred to as probate
inventories or MOOC s are lists of assets owned by deceased individuals or households. The
Orphan Chamber at the Cape was established to administer the estates of individuals who died
intestate and left heirs below
years and unmarried or unavailable TANAP,
. These
inventories MOOC ‐series was transcribed and digitised between
and
by an inter‐
disciplinary team which converted the hand‐written Dutch records held at the Cape Town
Archives Repository into a digital database of XML‐code Liebenberg et al.,
. To the MOOC
‐series were added
Stellenbosch inventories which was transcribed into Microsoft Word
by Annemarie Krzesinkski‐de Widt
and is available from the Stellenbosch Museum.
4
unique probate inventories are catalogued between
and
, which makes it one of the
largest inventory datasets used in analysis of this kind. A full account of the data treatment is
available in Fourie
.
The inventories include thousands of unique items owned by the Cape settlers. A comprehensive
analysis of household items is thus both impossible and superfluous; rather, we use twenty‐eight
items defined to ascertain the extent of household ownership and acquisition. Table provides
the descriptive statistics for the
products, where Sum signifies the total number of products
in the
inventories, Mean shows the average number of products per inventory, SD
reflects the standard deviation, Max the maximum, Med the median per inventory, p
and
p
the th and th percentiles, Non‐ counts the number of inventories that includes at
least one observation of that product‐type, and % s shows the percentage of the inventories
that have no observations of that product‐type.
Table : Descriptive statistics of
Products
Slaves
Cattle
(orses
Sheep
Ploughs
Corn sieves
Boats
Buckets
Spades
Guns
Brandy
stills
Wagons
Anvil
Bench vice
Balance
Fire‐tong
Oven
Bedstead
Chairs
Trousers
)rons
Books
Timepieces
Snuff‐box
Paintings
Mirrors
Bird cage
Gold rings
Sum
Mean
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
products in the
SD
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
Max
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
Med
inventories
p
p
Non‐
% s
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
Table already provides a glimpse of the pervasiveness of slavery at the Cape. While the most
common asset is chairs , slaves are the second most common asset owned at the Cape, even
5
more than buckets , bedsteads or mirrors . Other commodities, like cattle , sheep and horses
were also widely distributed, often more so than many of the basic household commodities like
bedsteads , fire‐tongs and ovens . Of the productive assets, only wagons were widely
dispersed, with more than % of farmers owning at least one. Aside from wagons, however, the
absence of capital goods used by the majority of the population – such as corn sieves > % ,
bench vices > % , anvils > % , and boats > % – is notable.
The table also reflects the average and median ownership of some goods; each household
owned, on average,
. cattle, while the median household owned
. Were these levels of
ownership high relative to the wealthiest societies of Europe and the Americas at the same time?
The use of probate inventories allow for simple comparisons across time and region.
Comparisons of capital goods across regions
The Dutch Cape Colony is compared across as wide a range of regions as possible. De Vries
provides estimates for Frisian probate inventories De Vries,
. Estimates by Weatherill
cover a number of jurisdictions across England and, more recently, Mark Overton et al.
, focus on sample parishes in Kent and Cromwell. For Colonial North America, we use the
Chesapeake records of Carr and Walsh
. We also refer to Jones s
majestic study,
The Wealth of a Nation to Be, although her data is not presented in a format that is easily
comparable with ours. Finally, Sheridan
uses probate records of Jamaican plantations
which informs our analysis.
Slaves were the most valuable movable assets in the Colony. Using the MOOC ‐auction rolls,
slaves accounted for % of all movable assets during the period
‐
. Given the increase
in price of slavery towards the end of the century and the decrease in other assets, particularly
cattle and sheep, one would expect this share to have increased further. As shown in Table ,
this resembles most closely the US South, where inventories held an average of . % of total
wealth invested in slaves in
. (owever, . % of American South inventories record slaves
and servants, whereas only % do in the Cape Colony. The higher value but lower incidence of
slaves at the Cape suggests that slaves were of relatively greater value compared to the
American South. )n contrast, the northern and middle colonies owned nearly no slaves Jones,
.
On a different scale were the slave‐owning sugar plantations of Jamaica, where slaves between
and
constituted
% of total inventory valuations of the sugar plantations. This
increased significantly to
, % in the
‐
period Sheridan,
. For example,
Sheridan
examines a median sugar estate , noting that between
and
such an
estate would have held an average of
slaves, increasing to
for the years
to
Sheridan,
:
. This is in sharp contrast to the average number of slaves held at the Cape,
which total . and . for the two periods.
Table 2: Comparisons of slave’s share of total household assets
Region
Source
Date
1691‐1748
Cape Colony
Own
This is for the same time period
.
‐
but from the MOOC ‐inventories.
6
1774
Thirteen colonies
New England
Middle colonies
South
Jones
Jones
Jones
Jones
Jamaica
Sheridan
.
.
.
.
1741‐
1745
1771‐
1775
.
.
Notes: Own refers to own calculations. Jones refers to Jones
calculations from MOOC ‐series. See discussion in Chapter .
. Sheridan refers to Sheridan
. Own
Livestock – including cattle, sheep and horses – was the largest component of movable assets for
Cape farmers. Table compares the average number of cattle per household with similar results
for (olland districts in Leeuwarderadeel and England Kent and Cornwall . Two measures of
the Cape Colony are included: an average across all households and an average for cattle owners
only. The reason for both measures is because, in some cases, the comparative sources may
calculate averages only for cattle owners.
Table 3: Comparisons of average household cattle ownership across various regions
Region
Source
Cape Colony
Cape Colony only cattle farmers
Kent
Cornwall
Own
Own
Overton et al.
Overton et al.
Cape Colony
Cape Colony only cattle farmers
Noordertrimdeel Leeuwarderadeel
Zuidertrimdeel Leeuwarderadeel
Own
Own
De Vries
De Vries
Date
1700‐
1750
1711‐
1723
Notes: Leeuwarderadeel is a municipality in Friesland, the Netherlands. Own refers to own calculations, Own
calculations from MOOC ‐series. See discussion in Chapter .
Tables and provide comparisons on the frequency of ploughs and wagons owned. The results
show that, between
and
, % of farmers within wealth group owned at least one
plough with
% of farmers in wealth group . Compared to De Vries s estimates of
Leeuwarderadeel farmers which show that
% of those in the top income bracket those
owning more than
cows owned at least one plough, the Cape performs surprisingly similar.
Ploughs probably permeated Leeuwarderadeel society to a greater extent than did ploughs at
the Cape, though, with only % of those at the bottom reporting ploughs in their inventories.
Table 4: Comparisons of the frequency of household plough ownership across various regions
Region
Cape Colony
Cape Colony
Cape Colony
Class
Source
Own
Own
Own
Date
1711‐
1750
7
Cape Colony
Leeuwarderadeel
Leeuwarderadeel
Leeuwarderadeel
Own
De Vries
De Vries
De Vries
‐
Notes: Leeuwarderadeel is a municipality in Friesland, the Netherlands. Own refers to own calculations, Own
calculations from MOOC ‐series. See discussion in Chapter .
While wagons were the only source of transportation at the Cape, road transportation competed
with water transportation in (olland. That is perhaps why comparisons of wagons between the
two regions show – as in Table – that wagon ownership were wide‐spread in the Cape Colony,
even amongst the poorest of farmers.
Table 5: Comparisons of the frequency of household wagon ownership across various regions
Region
Class
Cape Colony
Cape Colony
Cape Colony
Cape Colony
Leeuwarderadeel
Leeuwarderadeel
Leeuwarderadeel
Source
Date
1711‐
1750
Own
Own
Own
Own
De Vries
De Vries
De Vries
Notes: Leeuwarderadeel is a municipality in Friesland, the Netherlands. Own refers to own calculations, Own
calculations from MOOC ‐series. See discussion in Chapter .
Colonial probate inventories created a stir in the United States in
with the publication of
Arming America: the Origins of a National Gun Culture by Michael Bellesiles. Bellesiles
claimed that American gun culture did not have its roots in America s colonial period but
emerged only during and after the Civil War; that during the colonial and antebellum periods,
average gun ownership was low and proficiency in use poor. Consequent research, however,
showed that Bellesiles had fabricated evidence and that his conclusions were false Main,
.
Lindgren and (eather
, for example, conclude that there were high numbers of guns in
seventeenth and eighteenth‐century America, and lists the ownership proportions calculated
from a number of probate samples. )t is these figures which is included in Table to compare
gun ownership at the Cape with those of other areas.
Table 6: Comparisons of the frequency of household gun ownership across various regions
Region
Source
Cape Colony
Cornwall
Kent
Own
Overton
Overton
Cape Colony
New England
Middle Colonies
Own
Jones
Jones
Date
1690‐
1719
1765‐
1784
8
1720‐
1749
1774
South
Jones
Cape Colony
Maryland and
Virginia
Own
Gunston (all
Database
1740‐
1800
1740‐
1810
Notes: Gunstan (all Database can be accessed at http://www.gunstonhall.org/library/probate/index.htm
[Accessed: November
]. Own refers to own calculations, Own calculations from MOOC ‐series. See
discussion in Chapter .
)t is clear that gun ownership in the American South were significantly higher than the other
colonies in the North America as well as the Cape Colony. Gun ownership in the Cape Colony
more closely reflected ownership in the northern territories, and both regions were significantly
above the ownership share of Cornwall and Kent in England.
The results here suggest that the average Cape farmer invested a large share of their surplus into
capital goods, owning capital goods at similar levels to those of the fastest growing economies of
north‐western Europe and the settler economies of North America. Yet, different to Europe but
akin to the Southern colonies of North America, Cape Colony settlers invested a large share of
their savings in slaves. )nvestment in slaves was a priority for Cape settlers. The next section
finds a novel way to show these ownership priorities.
Composition of assets
One way to identify ownership priorities amongst Cape households is shown in Figure . The
data is calculated as follows: the number of product varieties owned by each household is
counted there are
households owning none of the twenty‐eight products and one household
owning
of the
products . The households are then grouped by the number of product
varieties owned and the groups ranked from zero to twenty‐eight on the x‐axis . The
ownership priority is then calculated as a proportion of the full list. )n Figure , the products
are categorized by four types, commodities, productive assets, basic household products and
luxury household products.
A visual analysis reveals interesting trends: the first products owned by the majority of
households tend to be slaves, cattle, horses and sheep. Wagons, classified here as a productive
asset, resemble a very similar trend to that of cattle and horses.
Next follow the basic household products. The strange incidence of trousers suggests that it is
measured imprecisely; the likelihood that a person with only
products owned a pair of
trousers was higher than with any greater number of products. This suggests that individual
clothing items was listed akin to an inferior good: the higher the level of wealth, the less it was
reported.
5
Categories 23-27 are merged because of very few observations.
This makes sense once the raw data is considered: for poorer individuals, trousers are often enumerated as a
separate item, while for richer individuals trousers are presumably included in “a cupboard of clothes”, for
example.
9
6
Together with basic household products, four productive assets also appear at this stage: guns,
ploughs, buckets and spades. This is not unexpected, given the multiple uses of buckets and
spades in the household.
Figure 2: Ownership priorities of item ownership over 20 products, categorized into four
groups
The next cluster of goods is household luxuries – irons, books, mirrors, paintings, timepieces,
snuff‐boxes and bird cages. The likelihood of owning a luxury product rises sharply after the th
product is owned. Gold rings are the exception. While the likelihood of owning a gold ring rises
quite early, it flattens off towards the end of the sample, probably owing to it not being captured
well in the data.
The expensive productive assets – anvil, bench vice, corn sieve, brandy still and boats – are the
final category to appear. )t is perhaps surprising that these are acquired only after luxury
products, but points to an important predisposition at the Cape: large, productive assets were
owned by an elite few, appearing below luxury products on the farmers list of consumption
investment priorities. As discussed later, only slaves, and to some extent wagons, were
consumption priorities for the non‐elite.
Table summarises the product incidence by group. Seven groups of ownership are defined.
Commodities were the first assets acquired by poor households. Of those owning four or fewer
items, % owned cattle, % horses and % slaves. (ousehold necessities, such as chairs,
7
There is a correlation of 0.58 between the number of items owned and the ownership of slaves (which is used
as a proxy for welfare above). Not all the “poor” as measured by the spread of items owned are thus necessarily
those with few slaves, and vice versa. Nevertheless, the trends reported in Table 4 are similar when slave
ownership rather than counted items is used as ranking.
10
buckets and beds were also obtained at an early stage, while household luxuries and productive
assets had a very low incidence amongst the poor. Yet, even amongst the poorest some luxury
products could be found – in the poorest category, . % owned a book, . % owned a clock or
watch, % owned a mirror, and surprisingly % owned gold rings. Compare this to the
extremely low incidence of productive assets for this group: while . % owned a gun, only
. % owned a spade, and fewer than % owned an anvil, bench vice or brandy still.
Table 7: Incidence of products by group
Products
0‐4
5‐8
9‐12
13‐16
17‐20
21‐24
25‐28
Total
N
542
666
671
455
174
62
7
2577
26.8%
31.0%
25.1%
22.1%
3.0%
0.0%
0.4%
8.9%
1.1%
10.3%
0.2%
15.9%
0.7%
0.6%
0.7%
3.3%
1.8%
14.2%
18.6%
24.7%
2.4%
10.5%
8.1%
5.2%
4.6%
6.1%
0.7%
5.0%
52.0%
59.3%
55.4%
50.5%
19.7%
0.3%
1.2%
53.0%
13.8%
40.2%
2.7%
53.2%
0.9%
2.3%
5.6%
19.8%
8.9%
30.0%
56.3%
12.8%
20.7%
14.9%
11.1%
7.4%
18.5%
31.7%
3.5%
4.5%
77.2%
62.7%
64.4%
53.2%
46.1%
2.5%
1.8%
88.2%
46.6%
54.1%
8.6%
61.7%
1.9%
7.0%
22.7%
48.1%
24.3%
61.5%
87.3%
12.1%
51.1%
24.4%
15.4%
14.6%
34.0%
53.2%
12.8%
10.3%
97.6%
64.2%
69.2%
57.6%
58.2%
13.8%
2.6%
95.4%
63.5%
62.9%
28.6%
70.1%
3.3%
13.6%
50.1%
73.4%
43.5%
84.2%
95.4%
18.0%
74.7%
44.6%
34.7%
31.0%
49.9%
79.1%
29.2%
21.8%
99.4%
82.8%
87.4%
75.3%
77.0%
35.1%
4.0%
95.4%
80.5%
76.4%
53.4%
90.8%
17.8%
31.6%
75.9%
83.3%
69.0%
94.8%
97.1%
21.3%
85.1%
62.1%
52.3%
46.0%
71.8%
95.4%
39.1%
24.1%
98.4%
95.2%
98.4%
93.5%
95.2%
74.2%
14.5%
100.0%
95.2%
90.3%
80.6%
100.0%
56.5%
56.5%
93.5%
98.4%
59.7%
100.0%
100.0%
14.5%
95.2%
80.6%
83.9%
61.3%
88.7%
100.0%
56.5%
29.0%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
85.7%
57.1%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
42.9%
85.7%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
71.4%
100.0%
100.0%
100.0%
85.7%
85.7%
100.0%
85.7%
42.9%
65.7%
57.7%
57.1%
49.3%
35.7%
7.6%
2.1%
64.5%
35.2%
45.4%
13.9%
54.3%
4.2%
8.7%
24.0%
39.6%
23.1%
50.7%
67.3%
16.8%
40.7%
26.7%
20.5%
17.1%
30.6%
46.4%
13.8%
11.2%
Slaves
Cattle
Horses
Sheep
Ploughs
Corn sieves
Boats
Buckets
Spades
Guns
Brandy stills
Wagons
Anvil
Bench vice
Balance
Fire‐tong
Oven
Bedstead
Chairs
Trousers
Irons
Books
Timepieces
Snuff‐box
Paintings
Mirrors
Bird cage
Gold rings
Cape households reinvested their savings predominantly in acquiring additional cattle, sheep
and horses, or in purchasing slaves. Only the elite would reinvest their savings in productive
assets; slaves, therefore, must have offered poorer farmers higher yields than investments in
other productive assets, a question we turn to next.
Capital investment
Adam Smith first observed that wealth is created through specialisation and surplus trading.
Smith s wealth accumulation assumes, of course, that free trade is possible and that few
11
limitations exist as to the type of production that may occur. Both assumptions could be rejected
in the Cape economy: trade in the three most important Cape commodities was only possible
where it involved a monopsonist buyer, the Company. The Company could dictate market prices,
vying for as low a price as the market could possibly provide. Furthermore, the Company
prohibited manufacturing activity and disallowed any private traders of goods to find alternative
export markets for Cape goods. To the extent that farmers were market‐oriented, their
investment choices would have been influenced by these market limitations.
The current consensus is that these mercantilist institutions would have had a detrimental
impact on Cape economic performance. Even Smith
in his treatise, The Wealth of Nations,
notes: The government of an exclusive company of merchants is, perhaps, the worst of all
governments for any country whatever )V. . . Referring to the Dutch colonies, Smith
concludes: The progress of some of them, therefore, though it has been considerable, in
comparison with that of almost any country that has been long peopled and established, has
been languid and slow in comparison with that of the greater part of new colonies )V. .
.
The living standards reflected in the
probate products support Smith s notion that the
progress ... has been considerable relative to those of other established regions. Cape farmers,
on average, owned more possessions than those regions of (olland and England for which
comparative figures are available see Fourie
. )t is, however, Smith s second belief – that
progress ... has seen languid and slow in comparison with that of the greater part of new
colonies – that requires further attention. Undoubtedly, Cape settlers were no worse off relative
to settlers of the North American colonies for which probates are available. Yet, perhaps Smith s
reference here refers not to contemporaneous living standards, but rather to the growth
potential of the colonies or, in other words, the colonies development trajectories.
The mercantilist institutions imposed by the Company, primarily the prohibition on
manufacturing and private trade and the system of monopoly contracts, ensured that agriculture
and its spin‐off industries were the main productive activities at the Cape. And in view of the
relatively abundant and inexpensive land of the interior , the average settler, at least after
when the interior opened, had little alternative but to channel all investment into increasing the
extensive margin on farms. Most of the farmers investment was in the form of additional
agricultural commodities, predominantly cattle and sheep; as the ownership priorities above
reflect, only a small elite of farmers, mostly those located close to the market in Cape Town,
would invest in productive assets that would improve the intensive margin of farms.
The prevalence of agricultural commodities – reflected by the decreasing prices of cattle and
sheep over the course of the eighteenth century – and inexpensive land in the interior resulted
in rapid population growth. The large households of Cape settlers further bolstered the labour
supply. )t was presumably this labour that was most often used for the value‐added processes of
eighteenth century agricultural production: churning milk into butter and tail fat into soap and
candles, and the treatment of animal skins into hides. A ready market existed in Cape Town for
these commodities; butter, tallow, candles and soap were victuals prized by the passing ships
Neumark,
.
8
In contrast to the relatively high capital costs of wheat and wine farming, cattle farming – with land leased from
the Company annually – provided an affordable alternative for young settlers (Neumark 1956). The low barriers
to enter pastoral farming also explain the dearth of wage labourers in the Colony.
12
But apart from investments in agricultural commodities, settlers also invested in slaves. While
the first slaves already arrived at the Cape in
, slaves were not widely dispersed amongst
settlers until the take‐off of viticulture at the beginning of the eighteenth century. Viticulture
required economies of scale and in the absence of large numbers of wage labourers, the
Company decided to encourage slave imports as a way to keep farmers input costs to a
minimum, with a view to address the constant objections against the low prices set by the
Company. (owever, slaves soon became an important investment for Cape settlers and, as many
scholars have noted, the backbone of the Cape economy. Not only did slaves satisfy the
demands of viticulture, but they also offered economies of scope on pastoral farms; the
pervasiveness of slaves in the country‐side reflects the usefulness of slaves as substitute for
capital goods even in the households of the less affluent. Slaves were also a potential source of
leisure. Slave labour substituted the farmers own need to actively engage in farm labour, often
allowing them to act only as overseer of work. Such a rational consumption choice dictated by
a backward‐bending labour supply curve was also prevalent in pre‐industrial Britain Allen and
Weisdorf,
. At a certain level of income, the benefits derived from additional consumer
goods simply did not outweigh the benefits derived from leisure. Such leisure substitution, of
course, could also have been in the form of scouting, hunting or raiding, which were frequent
frontier activities. Slave and household labour – and, Khoisan indentured labour, probably
underrepresented in the data although statistical evidence for this is virtually nonexistent – thus
provided sufficient returns to discourage investment in other capital goods for the average
farmer.
Evidence of proto‐industry
But behind this seemingly simple production structure, a gradual process of Cape proto‐
industrialisation emerged. This is not easy to detect, and the availability of quantitative evidence
in the opgaafrolle explains why most historians have neglected its impact. Constrained by
Company policies, the Cape economy did not follow the same trajectory as in other proto‐
industrial economies: the virtual paucity of productive assets in non‐agriculturally related
industries that were often the first to develop in a proto‐industrial economy – like spinning and
weaving – reflects an economy principally specialised in agriculture. Whereas Dutch and English
households would diversify into spinning and weaving, only three inventories in the sample of
Cape probates report a spinning wheel spinnewiel or weaving loom weefstoel . 9
Yet, Cape settlers did diversify into other by‐employment. Figure provides evidence of the
industry‐related equipment available on farms by showing the composition of equipment types
in the inventories. The figure reports only equipment that was clearly defined by type. Of the
observations of some type of equipment in the inventories,
do not list any type and are
thus classified as unknown and excluded here. Note that only equipment
gereedschap / gereetschap was searched for. The figure therefore excludes all the products
that should be classified as equipment, but that would be listed separately such as anvils and
bench vices included in our above analysis . The importance of carpentry equipment probably
shows that smaller items – such as chisels – would more easily have been bundled together
under one category heading, in this case timmermansgereedschap .
9
Willem ten Damme in 1714 (MOOC 8/2.117), Pieter Willem Regnault in 1765 (MOOC 8/11.42) and Hand
Diederik Mohr in 1785 (MOOC 8/19.7).
13
F)GURE : The composition of equipment types recorded in the
inventories
What is clear from Figure is the bias in favour of equipment types that augmented agricultural
production. Carpentry and woodworking equipment features prominently with
% of
equipment types, followed by smithy
% , masonry and construction
% , and gardening
% equipment. There are also several entries for cooper and wagonmaking‐equipment. The
low occurrence of pottery, printing, watch‐making and glass‐making equipment, for example,
depicts the dearth of non‐agricultural output.
Figure shows the percentage of inventories ranked by product ownership, which includes
carpentry equipment. The white line represents the number of inventories shown on the
secondary y‐axis . Carpentry equipment is predominantly owned by individuals that already
own several product items, i.e. wealthy individuals. A strong, positive correlation between
equipment ownership and wealth corroborates this. The same trends are visible if all
equipment types are included.
The point is that equipment ownership – and thus the
diversification of production – is mostly restricted to the upper echelons of Cape settler society,
those settlers who owned several slaves.
10
There is some evidence that certain types of equipment follow a different distribution. Shoemakingequipment, specifically, are rather equally distributed across the spectrum of product groups. The low absolute
number of shoemakers, however, does not permit a robust interpretation of this trend.
14
F)GURE : Share of carpentry equipment found in the inventories ranked on the x‐axis by the
number of products found in the inventories
Overton et al.
report a similar rise in proto‐industrial by‐employment in England during
the seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries. Their results suggest that – counter to De Vries s
concept of an industrious revolution where specialisation would occur on farms driven by a
greater demand for marketable items – by‐employment or the diversification of production
increased systematically as output increased. While by‐employment is typically modelled as a
risk‐averse farmer mentality, Overton et al
: ‐
argue that in England by‐employment
was a means of maximising household income rather than avoiding risk by which capitalist
entrepreneurs can make the most money .
Company policies certainly interfered with the process of proto‐industrialisation at the Cape.
Apart from vinification and brandy making, the only industries higher up the value chain that
was actively promoted by the Company van Zyl,
, Jooste,
, the barriers to entry in
other formal sectors were insurmountable. The Company, for example, offered only one beer
brewing license, sold to a distillery in Newlands. Even though the quality of the beer was
occasionally considered too poor for consumption, the profits earned through licensing ensured
that the Company would not consider competition in a free market a viable alternative. The
system of monopoly contracts created absurd situations; De Kock
:
notes the curse of a
resident of Cape Town who had a farm in the vicinity of the capital but could not use his own
flour for bread. (e was bound by law to sell his corn to the monopolist, and the price which he
received for it would not suffice to re‐purchase half of it in bread .
Such policies limited the specialisation of non‐agricultural production in urban centres and
constrained value‐added production to the wealthiest farmer entrepreneurs who could realise
some economies of scale. Jan Martin Vogel, whose inventory was compiled on April
, was
15
one such wealthy settler. Vogel owned
houses and farms. On one of these farms, in addition
to the standard items to be found in the five‐room house, his inventory lists an outside garden
house, a carriage house, a pigsty and stables, the inventory lists a lime pen kalkhok , a hay
barn hooijschuur , a pharmacy aphoteequers winkel , a carpenters shop timmermans
winkel , a smithy smitswinkel , a wheelwright wagenmakers winkel and a millhouse
molenhuis .
Such diversification explains why farmers continued to invest in slaves, even as slave prices
continued to increase vis‐a‐vis other forms of capital. Slave labour – in contrast to other capital
goods – was ideal to cope with the diverse array of activities on the farms. While specialisation
may have occurred within slave ranks on the farms, with some slaves assigned specific tasks,
this was only a second‐best solution.
Consequences of slavery
The ownership of slaves yielded high returns on private capital, but in the long‐run harmed the
Cape s growth potential. A shortage of labour had resulted in labour‐saving capital investments
first in Britain during the )ndustrial Revolution Allen,
and later in the North American
colonies where slaves were absent . This resulted in new innovations and technology that
increased labour productivity. Where farmers substituted labour‐substituting investments with
slaves, though, there was little incentive to improve labour productivity. Smith noted this effect
in
, saying slaves, however, are very seldom inventive; and all the most important
improvements, either in machinery, or in the arrangement and distribution of work which
facilitate and abridge labour, have been the discoveries of freemen Smith,
, )V. . .
Slavery had put the Cape economy on a high plateau.
Engerman and Sokoloff
note another consequence of slavery that would affect its long‐
run development trajectory. Engerman and Sokoloff suggest that the mechanism through which
initial factor endowments affect later development is inequality. Severe initial inequality would
result in growth‐debilitating institutions, such as low access to education, low levels of
immigration, disenfranchisement, and property rights favouring the elite. Low levels of
inequality would result in high levels of educational attainment, the extension of the franchise,
immigration and property right protection for all.
)n Engerman and Sokoloff s model, initial inequality arises from the type of climate and the size
of the native population: a temperate climate with a small native population would likely result
in low initial inequality whereas a tropical climate with a large native population would likely
result in severe initial inequality. These initial factor endowments are less relevant in the case of
the Cape Colony; the Cape was situated in a temperate climate and, although there was a sizable
native population, the policies of the Company prevented settlers from enslaving them. Rather,
the skills brought to the Cape by the arrival of French (uguenots Fourie and Von Fintel,
b
and the demand for wines from the passing ships Boshoff and Fourie,
shifted production
towards viticulture, a labour‐intensive crop.
The Company invested in slavery as a way to circumvent the shortage of labour on the farms.
Slaves created a highly unequal Cape society during the eighteenth century Fourie and von
Fintel,
, Fourie and von Fintel,
a . As predicted by Engerman and Sokoloff, this high
inequality would reinforce growth‐debilitating institutions at the Cape, notably the choice to
limit European immigration at the start and middle of the eighteenth century. )n
the
16
Company officials in Cape Town requested that immigration to the Colony be discouraged as the
objectives of the Cape settlement, to supply produce for passing ships, had been met as a result
of the extension of the frontier. And again, in
s, the Company – now with the support of a
number of prominent settler farmers – discouraged European immigration because slave labour
could fulfil all the labour requirements the farmers might have.
Slavery was only abolished in
with the slaves remaining on the farms until at least
.
Even after emancipation, de facto labour contracts and practices continued mostly as before
which meant that the institutions of the eighteenth century were entrenched in Cape society.
The extent to which these institutions influenced later South African development is more
contentious; the temptation is large to draw parallels between the high inequality of the
eighteenth century Cape settlers and indentured labourers after emancipation. Perhaps these
early institutions moved with Cape farmers on their Great Trek into the interior of South Africa
in
and were reinforced by the discovery of diamonds and gold at the end of the nineteenth
century which also made use of cheap, indentured labour on the mines . The causal link
connecting early inequality to twentieth century Apartheid is even more questionable. Yet, there
is little doubt that slavery contributed to high inequality that perpetuated the institutions of a
wealthy but static eighteenth century Cape economy. Following the Engerman‐Sokoloff
hypothesis, these institutions created during Dutch colonialism – the racism and racial
inequality in the distribution of political, economic and ideological power – contributed most,
directly and indirectly, to the inequality in [South Africa s present] income distribution
Terreblanche,
:
.
Conclusions
The decision to substitute expensive European wage labour for imported slave labour proved to
be advantageous to the European settlers in the short‐run but had negative long‐run
implications for Cape society. As the low incidence of capital equipment show, Cape farmers
invested surplus savings in purchasing slaves rather than labour‐saving investments in capital
equipment. )n other societies – notably those of England, (olland and the North American
colonies – labour‐saving investments would give rise to new technologies and innovations that
would propel labour to higher productivity. Slave labour, benefiting from economies of scale and
scope on farms, resulted in a prosperous eighteenth century settler community. Probate
inventories discussed here reveal high comparative wealth levels for the average farmer. Yet,
slavery lacked the additional incentives for improvement, innovation and productivity growth.
The Cape did not experience an )ndustrious Revolution similar to that of North‐West Europe,
not because of incapacity, but because the majority of movable assets were owned in dead
capital , i.e. slaves.
Not only did slavery result in a static economy, but it also created a highly unequal society.
Severe initial inequality, according to Engerman and Sokoloff, results, through various channels,
in growth‐debilitating institutions. While the Cape did not adhere to the traditional
requirements for a highly unequal society in the Engerman‐Sokoloff hypothesis – a tropical
climate and a large native population – the labour‐intensive production function of viticulture
was created through settler skills and ship demand. This necessitated more labour, and the
Company decided, in an attempt to reduce the input costs of farmers in order to maintain high
profit margins, rather encourage slave imports than European immigrants. Again, the benefits of
this policy were in the short run. )n fact, at a meeting in
of the Cape Policy Council, several
17
members suggested the low cost as reason for favouring slave imports. Only one member, D.M.
Pasques de Chavonnes, recommended that European immigration may, in the long‐run, be more
beneficial for Cape society. Against the power of short‐run Company and settler profits, his
ideas held little sway.
The highly unequal society which arose began to instil institutions that would be detrimental to
growth: first in limiting immigration of Europeans, later in restricted property rights and low
access to education for the emancipated slaves. )n addition, inequality congealed along racial
lines, creating various growth‐debilitating informal ideological? institutions, which paved the
way for a highly unequal Apartheid South Africa of the twentieth century. And the effects of
these institutions linger on in post‐Apartheid South Africa: Charles Feinstein
:
, in his
conclusion, notes that South Africa s past will exert a powerful influence on its present and
future for a long time to come .
References
ALLEN, R. C. 2009. The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective, Cambridge, UK,
Cambridge University Press.
ALLEN, R. C. & WEISDORF, J. L. 2011. Was there an ‘industrious revolution’ before the industrial
revolution? An empirical exercise for England, c. 1300-1830. Economic History Review, 64,
715-729.
BELLESILES, M. 2000. Arming America: The Origins of a National Gun Culture, New York, Alfred A.
Knopf.
BOSHOFF, W. H. & FOURIE, J. 2010. The significance of the Cape trade route to economic activity in
the Cape Colony: a medium-term business cycle analysis. European Review of Economic
History, 14, 469-503.
CARR, L. G. & WALSH, L. S. 1988. The Standard of Living in the Colonial Chesapeake. The William
and Mary Quarterly, 45, 135-159.
DE KOCK, M. H. 1924. Economic History of South Africa, Cape Town, Juta.
DE VRIES, J. 1974. The Dutch Rural Economy in the Golden Age, 1500-1700, New Haven, Yale
University Press.
DE ZWART, P. 2011. Real wages at the Cape of Good Hope: a long-term perspective, 1652-1912.
Stellenbosch: Economic Society of South Africa conference.
DEAN, D., NFA, A. H., OVERTON, M. & WHITTLE, J. 2004. Production and Consumption in English
Households, 1600-1750, London, Routledge.
FEINSTEIN, C. 2005. An Economic History of South Africa, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
FOURIE, J. 2011. The nature and growth of wealth in the Cape Colony: measurements from probate
inventories. Stellenbosch: Stellenbosch University.
FOURIE, J., ROSS, R. & VILJOEN, R. 2011. Literacy at Cape missionary stations. Stellenbosch:
Stellenbosch University.
FOURIE, J. & VAN ZANDEN, J. L. 2011. GDP in the Dutch Cape Colony: the national accounts of a
slave-based society. Stellenbosch: University of Stellenbosch.
FOURIE, J. & VON FINTEL, D. 2010. The dynamics of inequality in a newly settled, pre-Industrial
society: Evidence from Cape Colony tax records. Cliometrica, 4, 229-267.
FOURIE, J. & VON FINTEL, D. 2011a. A History with Evidence: Income Inequality in the Dutch Cape
Colony. Economic History of Developing Regions, 26, 16-48.
FOURIE, J. & VON FINTEL, D. 2011b. Settler skills and colonial development. ERSA Working Paper
213.
JONES, A. H. 1980. Wealth of a Nation to Be: The American Colonies on the Eve of the Revolution,
New York, Columbia University Press.
JOOSTE, G. J. 1973. Die Geskiedenis van Wynbou en Wynhandel in die Kaapkolonie, 1753-1795.
Masters dissertation, Stellenbosch University.
KRZESINKSKI-DE WIDT, A. 2002. Die Boedelinventarisse van erflaters in die distrik Stellenbosch
1679-1806, Stellenbosch, Stellenbosch Museum.
LIEBENBERG, H., CLAYTON, F., FAASEN, K., VAN AS, E., VAN DER MERWE, J., RALL, M. &
MEYER, I. 2007. The inventories of the Orphan Chamber of the Cape of Good Hope. In:
WORDEN, N. (ed.) Contingent Lives: Social Identity and Material Culture in the VOC World.
Cape Town: University of Cape Town.
18
LINDGREN, J. T. & HEATHER, J. L. 2002. Counting Guns in Early America. William & Mary Law
Review, 43, 1777-1842.
MAIN, G. L. 2002. Many Things Forgotten: The Use of Probate Records in "Arming America". The
William and Mary Quarterly, 59, 211-216.
NEUMARK, S. D. 1956. Economic influences on the South African frontier, 1652-1836, Stanford,
Stanford University Press.
SHERIDAN, R. B. 1965. The Wealth of Jamaica in the Eighteenth Century Economic History Review,
18, 292-311
SMITH, A. 1776. The Wealth of Nations. In: CANNON, E. (ed.). London: 1904: Methuen & Co., Ltd.
SOKOLOFF, K. L. & ENGERMAN, S. L. 2000. History Lessons. Journal of Economic Perspectives,
14, 217-232.
TANAP. 2010. Context: History of the Orphan Chamber of the Cape of Good Hope [Online].
www.tanap.net.
TERREBLANCHE, S. 2002. A History of inequality in South Africa 1652-2002, Pietermaritzburg,
University of Natal Press.
VAN DUIN, P. & ROSS, R. 1987. The Economy of the Cape Colony in the 18th Century, Leiden, The
Centre for the Study of European Expansion.
VAN ZYL, D. J. 1974. Kaapse Wyn en Brandewyn, 1795-1860, Cape Town and Pretoria, HAUM.
WEATHERILL, L. 1988. Consumer behaviour and material culture in Britain, 1660-1760, London and
New York, Routledge.
19