Transparency’s Witness
Andrew Barry
Pre-publication copy
Published in Material Politics: Disputes along the Pipeline,
Chichester: Wiley-Blackwell, 2013, 57-74
In his 1896 essay “The Secret and the Secret Society”, Georg Simmel noted the
progressive openness of the state or, as he expressed it, "publicity's invasion of the affairs
of state". This invasion had occurred to: "such an extent that, by now, governments
officially publish facts without whose secrecy, prior to the nineteenth century, no regime
seemed possible" (Simmel 1950: 336). Today, the question of the openness of the state
has been framed in a particular way; for many the idea and practice of transparency has
become critical for efforts to promote good governance. Transparency is a term,
according to Christopher Hood, that has attained quasi-religious significance in debate
over governance and institutional design: “Since the 1980s the word has appeared in the
litanies of countless institutional-reform documents and mission statements… it is the
pervasive jargon of business governance as well as that of governments and international
bodies, and has been used almost to saturation point in all of those domains over the
past decade” (Hood 2006: 3). Hood traces the demand for openness in government back
to the work of Spinoza, Rousseau and Bentham. Bentham, in particular, drew an
opposition between publicity and secrecy for “the best project prepared in darkness,
would excite more alarm than the worst, under the auspicies of publicity” (Bentham
1839: 310).
If the recent enthusiasm for transparency is simply the latest stage in a long evolutionary
process, of ‘publicity’s invasion’, then what is new? Certainly, there is the prevalence of
the term’s usage. Hood does not seek to explain why transparency (rather than, say,
openness) has become a preferred term, but he does make an important observation:
although the term has become pervasive it has also been promoted as a critical element
in the recent development of transnational economic governance. In this respect, the oil
economy is not unique in being subject to the claim that transparency might help address
some of the difficulties and criticisms that it faces and the risks that it poses (Fisher 2010,
Garsten and de Montoya 2008, Gupta 2008, Hajer 2009, Hood and Heald 2006, Jasanoff
2006b, Neyland 2007, 2011). The global finance industry has equally been a focus for
calls for greater transparency (Best 2005, 2007), while national governments and
international bodies such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World
Trade Organization (WTO) have also sought to demonstrate that they are more
transparent than before (Woods 2001, Larner 2009). But what is unique about the case of
oil, I would suggest, is the stark contrast between the opacity of the way in which the
multinational oil industry is said to have operated in the past, and the transparency of the
manner that it is expected to act in the future.
One feature of transparency is that it is applicable not just to the activities of
governments but also to the operations of all organizations, including business.
Moreover, according to its supporters, the progressive extension of the application of the
principle should not be a threat to commerce, nor does it necessarily entail a restriction
on commercial activity, or ‘the invasion’ of publicity into the world of business. On the
contrary, the implementation of transparency is said to provide the basis on which the
information necessary for the proper function of free markets would become readily
available. In this way, the practice of transparency has acquired a series of functions and
multiple meanings (Grossman et al 2008). First, transparency is expected to allow
investors to make rational judgments concerning the strength of both commercial and
public organizations, without having to gain access to insider knowledge. In these
circumstances, transparency needs to be actively promoted. Indeed, “a generation of
economists has shown that markets and deliberative processes do not automatically
produce all the information people need to make informed choices concerning goods
and services” (Fung et al 2007: 6). Secondly, the operation of the principle of
transparency appears to establish a distinction between a domain within which more or
less free markets exist and a domain external to their operation (Callon 1998b). In effect,
the enactment of transparency is expected to establish a boundary between the legitimate
domain of commerce and the market on the one hand, and the illegitimate territory of
corruption and state crime on the other. Transparency is necessary if corruption is to be
reduced, information is to flow more freely, organizations are to be held accountable,
and free markets are to flourish.
Thirdly, in so far as it is directed towards the activities of governments, transparency is
thought to foster public accountability for “effective accountability requires mechanisms
for steady and reliable information and communication between decision-makers and
stakeholders” (Held and Koenig-Archibugi 2005: 3). It is not just a matter of making
information public, but a matter of molding institutions into forms that are able to
perform it (Power 1997, 2007a, Strathern 2000). Transparency is thus expected to foster
the development of the kind of persons and institutions that are in a position to use and
assess the credibility of any information that is published. The operation of transparency,
thus, should lead not just to the production of information, but transformation in the
identities and conduct of persons and organizations. It is, in short, a technique of
governmentality, a device intended to “articulate actions: [to] act or [to] make others act”
(Muniesa et al 2007: 2).
Simmel's essay, however, points to two further key issues. One is indicated by his
metaphor of invasion to describe the effect of openness on the state. In describing
openness in these terms, Simmel complicates the terms of the opposition between
transparency and secrecy, and tradition and innovation. For Simmel, it was not openness,
but secrecy that was "mankind's greatest achievement". Increasing openness and
increasing secrecy both demanded innovation, in opposition to a past in which neither
concept had so much salience. Openness did not reduce secrecy, he argued, but
intensified the demand for it. "Real secrecy", Simmel argued, only began historically with
the development of greater openness. Yet, in his view, secrecy was valuable, while
openness was not: "In comparison with the childish stage in which every conception is
expressed at once, and every undertaking is accessible to the eyes of all, the secret
produces an immense enlargement of life: numerous contents of life cannot emerge in
the presence of full publicity" (Simmel 1950: 330). The development of practices of
openness does not, therefore, reduce a given reservoir of secrets. Rather, it transforms
the nature of what is kept secret, and what is valuable to keep secret and what is not.
Moreover, the development of practices of openness coincides with the development of
practices of secrecy. Indeed, this is not surprising. For when so much is out in the open,
what is not acquires a new and arguably greater value (Strathern 2000: 310). Conversely,
the growing prevalence of secrecy heightens the importance of openness, channeling
attention towards objects that were invisible but subsequently come into public view
(Taussig 1999: 56).
Secondly, as Simmel observes, in a world of openness, it is not just openness but secrecy
itself that has to be achieved. Secrecy may rely on the use of law, through technology
(such as screens and firewalls), through economic control, through the deployment of
cultural capital, or through the threat of violence. Just as transparency is associated with
certain assemblages of persons and objects and devices (such as a free press, accounting
procedures and disclosure requirements, public reports, debates and forums, etc.),
promoted through the work of particular institutions, there also exist devices of secrecy.
Simmel's essay points us towards an interest in the history of such devices and the
interconnections between the histories of openness and secrecy. Like deviance for
Foucault, corruption, bribery, illegality and so on are implicitly spoken about in practices
of transparency, but often through their absence, or in the margins of texts (Foucault
1979).
It would be a mistake, then, to assume that greater transparency simply leads to less
secrecy, or vice versa. In what follows I make two sets of preliminary observations. The
first is that the practice of transparency raises questions and may lead to passionate
disputes not only about what is and what is not published, but about the processes by
which public information is generated. As sociologists of scientific knowledge have
shown, published scientific papers provide a very limited report of the messy processes
of the research that they purport to describe (Collins 1985, Law 2004). In effect, they
direct the reader away from what has been called the circumstances of their production
(Latour and Woolgar 1986: 240, Latour 1987). The same can be said, as we shall see, of
the kinds of reports produced in response to the demand for transparency. The exercise
of transparency may lead to questions about how the information that is published has
been produced or circulated (see Strathern 1991: xxii). Critics may try to uncover the
truth about the process that has generated what has been made transparent, acting in the
manner of critical sociologists of science. But in turn, those who attempt to uncover the
truth that lies behind the façade of transparency may provoke questions about the lack of
transparency of their own practices. This leads to the generation of further secrets. As
Deleuze and Guattari observe, those who are expert in finding secrets tend themselves to
act in secret: “From an anecdotal standpoint, the perception of the secret is the opposite
of the secret, but from the standpoint of the concept it is part of it. What counts is the
perception of the secret must necessarily be secret itself: the spy, the voyeur, the
blackmailer, the author of anonymous letters are no less secretive than what they are in a
position to disclose” (1987: 287).
A second observation is that transparency points inevitably to the existence of a domain
of activity about which it is thought that information has not yet been or might never be
made public, whether intentionally or not (Simmel 1950, Stoler 2009: 3, Gross 2010).
Gaps may become apparent between that which is rendered transparent and that which
may or may not be widely known but which, it is believed, will never officially become
public knowledge. Thus, instead of having the effect of reducing the finite quantity of
matters that are not made public, the operations of transparency have the potential to
highlight the existence of a vast range of matters that never will be made public (Barry
2006, McGoey 2007, 2009, MacIntosh and Quattrone 2010, Hetherington 2011),
including matters that will not even be accessed by the most skilful social researchers
(Quattrone 2006). Formal demands for transparency are therefore likely to co-exist with
the circulation of rumours and ‘public secrets’ about matters that are not and may never
officially become public knowledge, but which are nonetheless widely known (Taussig
1999). In the course of this research I was made privy to numerous such rumours and
public secrets, some of which are probably true and many of which are probably not, but
which cannot in either case be published. Whereas the information produced to meet the
requirements of transparency is traceable, and therefore is expected to render institutions
accountable, the origins of public secrets, as well as specific rumours, are indeterminate
(Kwinter 2001: 126). The exercise of transparency does not reduce the importance of
rumour, but rather gives it a new yet unacknowledged significance.
If the virtues of the principle of transparency are widely diffused, the principle is thought
to have particular relevance to the extractive industries in general, and the oil industry in
particular. Why has the principle of transparency acquired so much significance in
relation to the politics and economy of oil? According to many commentators, countries
with abundant oil resources have often failed to achieve good or sustainable levels of
economic growth (Auty 1993, 2005, Sachs and Warner 2001, Le Billon 2005). Indeed,
given the ease with which wealth can be extracted through the production of oil, the
governments of oil-rich states have often been able to maintain public acquiescence by
increasing state expenditure to unsustainable and spectacular levels in the short term
(Coronil 1997, Karl 1997, Bannon and Collier 2003). The possession of this valuable
resource has therefore not generally led to broad-based economic development and the
establishment of democracy, but has all too frequently been correlated with economic
stagnation, state repression, an absence of democratic freedoms and civil war: “the link
between natural resource abundance and the propensity for civil strife is now well
established” (Auty 2005: 29; Collier and Hoeffler 2005, Humphreys et al 2007). This state
of affairs is known as the ‘resource curse’. To be sure, the existence, prevalence and
causes of the resource curse are all contested (Rosser 2006: 58, Ross 2001, Haber and
Menaldo 2011). For some analysts, the presence of abundant natural resources such as
oil leads to irrational behaviour, while for others it leads to what are claimed to be
rational forms of economic behaviour such as corruption, looting, or the provision of
financial support for coups d’états. According to some writers, an abundance of oil
resources fosters foreign military intervention, while others stress how it may lead to
rising political risks for foreign investors (Jensen and Johnston 2011) or is likely to
weaken state institutions (Karl 1997).
Yet whatever the causes and form of the resource curse, most commentators agree that
the promotion of greater transparency provides a good way of beginning to address it
(Collier and Hoeffler 2005: 632, Humphreys et al 2007, Swanson et al 2003, Le Billon
2005: 24). For if the oil economy can be become more transparent, it is argued, then two
critically important and desirable developments will follow: it should prove easier to
reduce the level of corruption; and civil society will possess the information required to
hold the governments of oil-producing countries to account. In this context,
transparency appears to function primarily as a ‘market device’ (Callon et al 2007). It is
expected to make possible certain forms of economic calculation, while reducing the
likelihood of those non-market forms of economic calculation associated with corruption
and violence.
The arguments of the economists of the resource curse have been influential as we shall
see in the first part of the chapter. However, in the second part of this chapter I argue
that, in relation to the extractive industries, the project of transparency – the Extractive
Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI) – has been understood to be as much a
practical experiment in normative political theory as in economics. The aim of those who
promote the virtues of transparency is not just to address the lack of economic
information, and to foster the development of a market economy, but also to address the
lack of development of civil society. The operation of revenue transparency entails not
just the development of literary devices (displays of revenue payments, for example), but
also the presence of witnesses, the cultivation of forms of ethical conduct through
seminars, guidebooks and forums, as well as the existence of appropriate institutions. At
the same time, in relation to both cases, transparency takes the form of a public
experiment (Schaffer 2005), in which the witnesses to the experiment are not just
economists and political theorists, but also ‘civil society’, ‘stakeholders’, auditors, and the
international community. In short, the development of transparency is expected to lead
to the formation of a society and, in turn, this society will foster its progressive
development in the future.
Moreover, particular public experiments in transparency are intended as exemplars which
can be subsequently imitated elsewhere. A global society, concerned with the issue of
revenue transparency, is formed through the replication and adaptation of a local model
(Tarde 2001 [1890], Latour 2005b, Barry 2006). In effect, transparency operates along the
borders between economic and political life. On the one hand, the implementation of
transparency is expected to affect a form of politicization of the economy that is
measured, limited and rational. On the other hand, revenue transparency is intended to
channel disagreements towards the specific question of economic calculation. A story
that economists tell about natural resources – ‘the resource curse’ – is taken to have
profound and wider implications for the public politics of knowledge.
Although EITI represents a systematic attempt to render the oil economy more
transparent, it cannot be taken as representative of the operation of transparency in the
oil industry in general. For while the EITI has been directed towards quite specific,
limited and technical issues, the transparency of the BTC pipeline turned out be much
more wide-ranging and ambitious, involving a vast range of different experts and forms
of knowledge production. Moreover, whereas the transnational experiment of revenue
transparency occurred in under carefully controlled conditions, both in Azerbaijan and
elsewhere, the transnational experiment in transparency associated with the BTC entailed
the formation of a more complex and evolving series of political spaces, stretching across
three countries, and along a route 1760km in length.
Resource Curse
In 2003 a team of economists from Columbia University visited the West African state
of São Tomé e Príncipe (STP) in order to consider the impact of oil revenues on the
economy.i This visit might seem surprising. After all, São Tomé, a small island state with
approximately 160,000 inhabitants had yet, at this time, to receive any revenues from the
production of oil. Indeed, following the exploration of offshore fields lying between STP
and Nigeria, there was an expectation that oil production might begin as soon as 2012, or
even 2010, but by 2007 this expectation had faded (Weszkalnys 2011).
Gisa Weszkalnys has argued that, despite having no revenues from oil production, STP
might be regarded as an exemplary oil state. Together with Nigeria, STP signed the Abuja
declaration (2004), committing both countries to transparency in relation to the
countries’ Joint Development Zone. On the advice of the Columbia University
economists, the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), the IMF and the
World Bank, STP also adopted a Petroleum Management Law and a National Oil
Account in order to invest oil revenues for future economic development. It had, in
other words, anticipated the arrival of the oil economy and acted to prevent its
potentially negative consequences. The transformation required was more than merely
institutional. As Weszkalnys notes, “anticipatory activities have not stopped on the level
of the state, the law or institutional reform. What is especially needed… is the creation of
civil society and good governance, including a ‘change in mentality’” (Weszkalnys 2007:
3, see also Weszkalnys 2008).
While STP has yet to receive any oil revenues, the Columbia University project made it
clear that it could, in certain respects, become a model to be replicated elsewhere. As well
as the Petroleum Management Law, the project led “to the design and execution of a
National Forum, through which to inform citizens about the country's oil revenues and
to solicit their views on how they might be spent”. The project also precipitated “the
formulation of a plan of action for sustainable economic development” and the
publication of a substantial volume (co-authored by, amongst others, the Nobel Prize
winning economist, Joseph Stiglitz, and Jeffrey Sachs, Director of the Columbia
University Earth Institute) which offered a theoretical and practical guide to other
countries with substantial natural resource wealth. The book contained the Petroleum
Management Law as a template for others to consider. Central to the claims made for the
STP model was the idea of openness. The problem that STP could avoid was clear
enough:
“The central problem facing resource-rich countries may be easily stated: various
individuals wish to divert as much of that endowment as possible for their own
private benefit. Modern economic theory has analyzed the generic problem of
inducing agents (here government officials) to act in the interests of those they
are supposed to serve (the principals, here citizens more generally). Agency
problems arise whenever information is imperfect, and hence there is a need to
emphasize transparency, or improving the openness and availability of
information in the attempt to control corruption.” (Humphreys et al 2007: 26)
Although the idea of transparency is widespread, economic analyses of the so-called
‘resource curse’ (Auty 1993, Bannon and Collier 2003) have provided it with an
influential justification. In this argument, countries possessing a wealth of non-renewable
natural resources (typically associated with the oil, gas and mining industries) experience
a series of problems that frequently lead to lower rates of growth than those occurring in
countries with smaller endowments of natural resources. The Columbia University
authors insisted, in particular, that the presence of such resources induced rent-seeking
behaviour on the part of governments and elites. At best, this was likely to lead to a lack
of investment and interest in other sectors of economic activity including, for example,
agriculture and manufacturing, as well as public services such as health and education. It
meant, furthermore, that states would be less reliant on taxation revenues and “when
citizens are untaxed they sometimes have less information about state activities and, in
turn, may demand less from nation states” (Humphrey et al 2007: 11). Moreover, rentseeking opportunities frequently lead to widespread corruption and, in many cases,
violent conflict, as different groups or foreign governments seek to gain control over
revenues. Given these opportunities, the conduct of a coup d’état, for example, can be
understood as a form of rational economic action. Indeed, one of the Columbia authors
identified no less than six distinct mechanisms leading to natural resource conflicts: the
‘greedy outsiders mechanism’, three variants of the ‘greedy rebels mechanism’, the
‘grievance mechanism’, the ‘feasibility mechanism’, and the ‘weak state
mechanism’(Humphreys 2005: 533).
The Columbia University project was not primarily an analysis of a specific example.
Rather, it was a modest and practical intervention, based on the analysis of the resource
curse, which formed an element of a much wider series of efforts, also involving the
World Bank, intended to improve petroleum governance in STP. In the context of this
analysis, the Columbia team had little to say about the colonial and post-colonial political
history of STP: history remained outside the frame of economic analysis (Callon 1998b).
Commenting on a coup d’état by army officers in July 2003, for example, Ricardo Soares
de Oliveira notes that “most analysts gave exclusive coverage to the perceived linkage
with the oil contracts (a view aided by the coup spokesman’s constant references to oil
and social justice) and all but forgot the country’s coup-prone past and the older
grievances of São-Tomean society” (Soares de Oliveira 2007: 239, Weszkalnys 2009).
Indeed, recent discussions of STP focus almost exclusively on oil, failing to attend other
aspects of political and economic life in the country, or the ways in which the notion of
the resource curse itself intersects with draws upon “familiar ideas about, and instances
of, illicit wealth, appropriations of state property, or simply seemingly self-perpetuating
patterns of social inequality” (Weszkalnys 2011). In short, the strength of the Columbia
approach did not derive from its attention to the specificity of STP and its history, but
rather from its effort to transform the São Tomean economy into a particular example of
a more general problem (the resource curse), and as a test site for a set of devices that
were expected to reduce the level of resource conflicts not just in São Tome, but
wherever they occurred. In effect, STP was conceived of as something of an ‘island
laboratory’ (Greenhough 2006) for natural resource economics, an experimental site that
would come to demonstrate the effectiveness of economic analysis in practice (Mitchell
2005: 297).
Disclosure
São Tomé is not an isolated case, however. It is one of 23 countries signed up to EITI,
originally launched by British Prime Minister, Tony Blair, at the World Summit on
sustainable development in Johannesburg in 2002. The initiative promoted transparency
as central to the solution of the economic and political problems associated with the
development of the oil, gas and mining industries in developing countries. Technically,
EITI operates according to a principle of double disclosure: governments are expected to
disclose what payments they receive from the extractive industries, and the extractive
industries disclose what they pay to governments. These payments can be made through
a variety of means. For example, EITI reports for Azerbaijan (one of the few countries
to have submitted a full report) break down payments into the following categories:
monetary inflow as government’s entitlement in foreign companies’ production stream;
payments in kind (of both crude oil and gas) expressed in barrels of oil and cubic metres
of gas; bonuses; transportation tariffs; acreage fees; royalties; profit taxes; other taxes, as
well as taxes paid by local Azeri companies (Moore Stephens 2007). In practice, the
payments made under each of these separate headings are aggregated. This means that
nothing is recorded regarding payments to specific companies unless there is agreement
from both the government and the companies concerned. Moreover, there is no
indication as to whether payments in kind (of oil and gas) by companies to the
Azerbaijan government resulted in any delivery of actual oil and gas. Published figures do
not reveal whether the Azerbaijan government sold oil and gas back to the companies
prior to delivery, resulting in an increased cash revenue payment. Moreover, if this were
the case, the price paid by the oil companies to the government is not recorded (EITI
2012a).
The demands of EITI are, therefore, very specific. They record one set of transactions in
the circulation of natural resource revenues according to international accounting
standards. They do not say anything either about the expenditure of such revenues by
government or about NGOs funded directly or indirectly by the extractive industries.
Nor do they record payments (in cash or in kind) along the oil production value chain
such as payments to local subcontractors. Furthermore, while auditors provide an
account of any discrepancy between the figures provided by governments and
companies, this does not necessarily imply that all the figures are accurate or complete. If
the aim is to reduce imperfections in the availability of information, then the reduction
achieved is real but also quite modest. As a representation of the natural resource
economy of a nation-state, the reports provided by the EITI process have been limited.ii
Given this observation, a number of countries might stand out as exemplary in their
transparency, or in the level of their aspirations to greater transparency in the future. One
is Mongolia, which was said by an informant to have produced a particularly clear way of
presenting information. Another is Timor-Leste, which has embraced the idea of revenue
management as well as transparency.iii A third is Nigeria, which was the first country to
“make reporting of payments by all extractive companies and revenues received by
government legally binding under national legislation” (EITI 2012b: 2). The extension of
the principle of transparency occurs both by enacting a general model and meeting the
demands of validation, and also through the imitation and modification of exemplary
cases. As we might also say in Tardean terms, invention, a process of political and
economic invention in this case, occurs along a pathway of imitative modification (Tarde
2001 [1890], Barry and Thrift 2007).
The narrowness and specificity of the Transparency Initiative suggests a number of
responses. Harry West and Todd Sanders’, for example, have ventured that “in the
globe’s constituent localities, key words such as transparency, conveying notions of trust,
openness and fairness, must dance endlessly across the same terrain as vernacular key
words expressing suspicion, hiddenness, and treachery” (West and Sanders 2003: 12).
Certainly in Azerbaijan it is easy enough to hear stories of oil revenues actually spent by
the government. ‘Public secrets’, which may or may not be true, are unsurprisingly
common. Ethnographic studies of post-socialist societies have provided rich accounts of
the multiple forms of corruption, networking and favours in post-Soviet economic life
(Ledeneva 1998, Humphrey 2003). Historical and sociological studies of the Caucasus, in
particular, have documented the failure of national governments to exercise control over
local elites in Georgia and Azerbaijan during the Soviet era (Suny 1994). Georgi
Derluguian argues that, following their appointment during the Soviet period, Heyder
Aliev and Eduard Shevardnadze “realized that their primary aim had to be to placate
Moscow while consolidating their local power base by appointing local clients”
(Derluguian 2005: 201, cf. Hibou 2004).
West and Sanders focus on the opposition and relation between transparency and
suspicion (or openness and conspiracy). This is, however, only part of the story of
transparency. Their essay concentrates on the production and circulation of rumour and
suspicion, demonstrating in their words “how tenous, even illusive, trust is… in the
midst of the turbulent transformations defining post-socialist societies” (West and
Sanders 2003: 11). While this may be true in general, what is striking about the
Transparency Initiative is not that its operation necessarily conceals anything, but that it
is not expected to reveal much. It does not necessarily hide the truth, but leaves a huge
amount unsaid. It allows a vast space of discretion: the realm of what one chooses not to
know, does not investigate, or deliberately overlooks. On one occasion before traveling
to the Caucasus, I met with some officials working for the Department for International
Development in London. As I left the building one of them offered me some words of
wisdom: you have to avoid listening to rumour. His advice is one working definition of
how to exercise discretion, a necessary feature of transparency.
But if transparency is rendered so specific in its focus, it is, therefore, also achievable.
One official noted that the Azeribaijan government found little difficulty in signing up to
the Transparency Initiative because the Oil Fundiv was already transparent and so did not
require any substantial changes in the way in which it operated.v Since then, Azerbaijan,
in conjunction with BP and other companies, has taken a leading role in the
Transparency Initiative. It was the first country to be validated – and therefore publicly
recognized – as transparent by the time of the biannual EITI conference at Doha in
February 2009. According to a different assessment, the corruption perception index
produced by Transparency International, Azerbaijan was 143rd in the same year
(Transparency International 2009). It is quite possible that Azerbaijan, when its
performance is assessed in different ways, can both lead the development of practices of
transparency and yet, at the same time, not be transparent at all (cf Guliyev and
Akhrarkhodjaeva 2009).
Assembling Civil Society
In any case, the primary issue for the Oil Fund was not how to produce an account of
the payments received from international oil companies, which was easy enough, but
how to produce the right kind of witnesses, including stakeholders, oil companies, DFID
and NGOs who might accept these claims as true.vi This problem was also central to the
preoccupations of EITI and its NGO supporters, including the Open Society Institute:
“Accountability, transparency, and public oversight require the creation of checks
and balances and a separation of powers among an array of institutions
established to oversee the overflow of oil and natural gas revenues. They also
demand input from civil society and the creation of a powerful sense of public
ownership of the revenues… the chances for success of these funds would be
improved by strengthening parliamentary oversight, improving budgetary
transparency, and establishing independent citizens’ advisory councils to raise public
awareness about and conduct monitoring of the countries’ oil and gas revenues.”
(Caspian Revenue Watch 2003: 6, emphases added)
Viewed in this way, what was central to the Transparency Initiative was not just the
publication of information, but the progressive collection of persons who would be able
to have input into, monitor and exercise oversight over the transparency process (see
also World Bank 2008: 77-78. It implied the creation of a triangular relationship between
government, the oil companies — both of whom published information — and NGOs
who exercised oversight over what information was published. One Azeri NGO
informant expressed the problem in terms of the need to create a space within which
public discussion was possible and ‘information sharing’ could take place.vii The problem
in Azerbaijan was that NGOs did not necessarily behave in this way. A few took
oppositional positions, rejecting the existence of oil industry developments that were
already in process. Other NGOs, conversely, were said to be more or less directly
associated with the government (cf Wilson 2005). Some were cautious about what they
said in public. A few sought to uncover, through their own investigations, what they
believed to be the true story of the ways villagers had been deceived by the government,
for example by changing land ownership records. Such investigations went far beyond
the limited demands of the Transparency Initiative. The difficulty that those supporting
the Initiative confronted was how to foster an appropriate form of critical engagement
with the problem of how to measure and manage oil revenues rather than, for example,
to confront the government directly. In effect, ‘civil society’ had to emerge in a form
through which it could perform the specific role expected of it.
Moreover, during this period, opposition to the Azerbaijan government was weak.
Although reports from the Organisation for Security and Cooperation in Europe
(OSCE) Election Observation Missions reported that elections in Azerbaijan failed to
meet OSCE standards for democratic elections (OSCE 2003), Western observers argued
that there was no credible alternative to the government of Heyder Aliev (see also
Cheterian 2010). In Georgia, by contrast, accounts of electoral fraud in 2003 had played a
critical role in the Rose Revolution that led to the fall of the Shevardnadze government
(Mitchell 2009: 58-62, Companjen 2010).viii Unlike in Azerbaijan, Western governments
considered Georgian civil society to be already sufficiently developed for a change of
government to be possible. In these circumstances, the principle of transparency could
be applied not just to the apparatus of oil revenue payments, as it was in Azerbaijan, but
to the apparatus of elections (cf Coles 2004).ix
The behaviour, freedom and capacity of civil society are considered critical to the success
of the Transparency Initiative. In 2006 it was agreed that countries that had signed up to
EITI would, in general, need to be ‘validated’ by 2010. To this end, what was termed ‘a
validation grid’ was agreed upon, against which countries would be assessed. This grid set
out eighteen validation criteria including, for example: #2 ‘has the government
committed to work with civil society and companies on implementation’; #5 ‘has the
government established a multi-stakeholder group to oversee EITI implementation’; #6
‘is civil society engaged with this process’, #8 ‘did the government remove any obstacles
to EITI implementation’, #13 ‘has the government ensured that government reports are
based on audited accounts to international standards’ (EITI 2006). Each of these grid
indicators was expanded on further so that, for example, ‘civil society groups involved in
EITI should be operationally, and in policy terms, independent of government or the
private sector’ (ibid.: 14). The ‘validation grid’ additionally addressed the need for
‘outreach by the multi-stakeholder group to wider civil society groups… including
coalitions (e.g. a local Publish What You Pay Coalition), ‘informing them of the
government’s commitment to implement EITI, and the central role of companies and
civil society’. On the basis of these criteria, Azerbaijan was judged to have met the
requirements for validation. However, the auditors noted that the government had not
fully established a regular multi-stakeholder group (#5): “In taking a view regarding
Azerbaijan’s compliance with this indicator, we have considered the wording of this IAT
very carefully and considered the historical context of the EITI process in Azerbaijan.
We believe that whilst Azerbaijan’s previous institutional structure for EITI
implementation enabled the achievement of the EITI’s key objective, namely the regular
publication of EITI reports without unexplained discrepancies, the formation of a
permanent MSG will enable stronger multi stake holder engagement in overseeing the
strategic development of the EITI in Azerbaijan” (Coffey 2009: A1-1).
Three observations follow from this. First, the validation process makes clear that the
Transparency Initiative is expected to be performative. It is intended to foster the
creation of the kind of civil society or public sphere imagined by Western social and
political theorists such as David Held and Mary Kaldor (e.g. Held and Koenig-Archibugi
2005). Writing on the Azerbaijan-Armenian conflict over Nagorno Karabakh, Kaldor
argued that civil society and transparency provided the solution to the problem of
conflict resolution: “[international organizations] could strengthen civil society to a much
greater degree in the peace process so as to stimulate public discussion and mobilize
greater public support” (Kaldor 2007: 179). A similar logic is embodied in EITI. It is a
device intended to foster the formation of a civil society prepared to engage in public
discussion. According to a high-level panel set up to advise BP on the development of
Caspian oil, BP's transparency could have an "important and positive impact" on the
"free exchange of ideas" in Georgia and Azerbaijan (BTC/CDAP 2003: 13). In this
context, transparency turned out to be a political device as well as an economic one.
Kaldor and Held’s notion of civil society derived not from natural resource economics
but, at least in part, from relations with civil society organisations in Eastern Europe in
the 1970s and 1980s and the theoretical resources of post-Frankfurt school critical theory
(Habermas 1990).
Secondly, although it is concerned with a wide set of issues such as civil society
engagement, and the existence of government ‘obstacles’, the validation process
addresses these issues in a particular way. Validation was conducted by auditors whose
names were chosen by the Azerbaijan government from a list drawn up by the EITI
secretariat and board, which did not include any Azerbaijani nationals. In this way, the
validation process would not be contaminated by too much knowledge of local
complexities, prejudices or conflicts of interest. In Azerbaijan I carried out research in
conjunction with an anthropologist, Farideh Heyat, who already had conducted her own
ethnographic fieldwork in Azerbaijan (Heyat 2002) as well as a number of interviews
with NGOs interested in the development of the oil industry. In these circumstances, I
immediately gathered the excess of detail that is typical of field work. Once, after a long
interview with a member of an NGO, Heyat criticized me for not asking more probing
and critical questions about the personal connections between the NGO and the Aliev
government. For the anthropologist, what was external and hidden (the ‘realm of
suspicion’ to use West and Sanders’ term) was of greater interest than what was in the
open and merely presented to us. What was performed for our benefit pointed to the
existence of social relations beneath (Strathern 2000). Our research highlighted the
existence of things that were difficult to make public (Quattrone 2006).
Thirdly, if the validation process has a quasi-Habermasian logic, seeking to forge a space
within which rational debate concerning matters of public interest can occur, the
existence of that space is confirmed in a particular, technical way. In conducting the
validation process quickly and without substantial local knowledge, validation will leave
much unknown, and therefore unreportable. Seen in this context, the audited accounts
produced by the Transparency Initiative are arguably less important than the political
assembly that needs to exist for these figures to be examined. The logic of the
Transparency Initiative, for many of those associated with it, is that this political
assembly or civil society forum will progressively learn to ask the right questions,
gradually demanding more information about other matters beyond the narrow remit of
EITI itself (concerning, for example, production sharing agreements, concessions,
taxation, bonuses and so on). The technicality of the issues that civil society needs to be
concerned with are important, partly because they are technicalities and civil society, if it
is to properly function as such, needs to concern itself with technicalities (Schulz 2005).
There is an echo here of an argument put forward by the late nineteenth-century French
sociologist, Gabriel Tarde. In L’Opinion et la Foule, Tarde looks forward to the day when
the public would read and digest social statistics rather than indulge in the highly
contagious imitative and affective forms of behaviour characteristic of street
demonstrations “ irresistibly drawn by a force with no counterbalance” (Tarde 2006
[1901]: 16). The Transparency Initiative embodies this political logic. It is expected to
provide a technical solution to the management of affect, a preventative cure to the
contagious forms of imitative behaviour that Tarde saw in the late nineteenth-century
urban crowd (Salmon 2005, Toscano 2007, Borch 2012). Transparency, in effect, is a
device intended to foster the formation of a rational civil society and a rational
government, albeit in embryonic form. Conflict resolution between government and civil
society is expected to occur not by opening up a potentially uncontrollable space of
antangonism resulting in the kinds of violent clashes between police and demonstrators
that have occurred on the streets of Baku, but by focusing protagonists on the mundane
problem of how to generate and verify particular matters of fact (Shapin and Schaffer
1985). In effect, transparency both addresses an on-going political situation and is
intended to contain and manage it in a particular form. Debate should begin, in this view,
through the examination of particular and limited details, not with wider demands for
social justice and the redistribution of wealth (Rancière 1998, 2006). The enactment of
revenue transparency would not reveal that much in the short term, but it would be the
basis, it was claimed, for a different political future.
A Public Experiment
Talk of the importance of transparency has certainly become pervasive, not least in
relation to discussions of the extractive industries. Yet it would be a mistake to equate
transparency, as Christopher Hood suggests, with an all-encompassing regime of
surveillance (Hood 2006: 8-9). And Stephen Collier argues persuasively that the same
could be said of neo-liberal economic reform programmes in the post-Soviet period:
“The tools of the new economics of regulation were invented precisely as a new form of
critical visibility through which intransigent things, embedded norms, and patterns of
social provisioning could be brought into view, down to minute technical details, as the
product of a prior governmentality that had to be rationalised. And this rationalisation is
designed to take shape precisely through the selective and in some cases quite limited
deployment of… microeconomic devices” (Collier 2011: 242, emphasis added). Collier’s
observation could also be made about the principle of revenue transparency; indeed what
is striking about the operation of EITI is that it appears to reveal rather little.
Yet if we focus not on what the implementation of revenue transparency is expected to
reveal but on what it is expected to perform or do, then this remark becomes less of a
paradox. Three observations follow. First, it is important to recognize that the
implementation of transparency in the extractive industries takes an evolving and
experimental form. As an experiment, revenue transparency is intended not only to effect
a progressive transformation in the world within which it is conducted, but also to
persuade others that the results of this experiment are both true and valuable. It is
precisely in its lack of transparency, as we have seen, that Azerbaijan has provided a
particularly suitable location for the experimental application of transparency in practice.
Secondly, and at the same time, oil turns out to be not just another industry whose
operations can and should become transparent, but one that is perceived to be acutely in
need of or receptive to transparency; for it is the lack of transparency of the oil economy
that is thought by some economists to be at the root of the economic problems of many
oil-producing states. Thirdly, transparency implies not only the publication of specific
information but also the formation of a society, a public, that is in a position to recognize
and to assess the value of – and if necessary to modify – the information that is made
public. The operation of transparency is addressed to local as well as global witnesses, yet
these local witnesses are expected to be properly assembled, and their presence validated.
There is thus a circular relation between the constitution of political assemblies and
accounts of the oil economy: one brings the other into being (Mitchell 2011). Extractive
industry transparency is not just intended to make information public, but to govern the
constitution of a public that is interested in being informed (see Chapter 5).
While there has been a great deal of interest, especially on the part of economists, in the
potential value of transparency as a solution to the problem of the resource curse, the
significance of transparency for any account of the contemporary politics of oil is much
wider than this. In part the progressively increasing desire for transparency has been
driven by the conjunction of intersecting and competing demands made by international
organisations, institutional investors (Clark and Hebb 2005) and multinational
companies, as well as civil society organizations such as Revenue Watch and the Open
Society Institute. In part it has been governed by the enactment of a growing range of
national and international principles, conventions and regulations, as well as national
legislation (Abbott and Snidal 2000, Agrawal 2005, Fairhead and Leach 2003, Djelic and
Sahlin-Anderson 2006, Jessop 2008). A number of international agreements and
principles that demand certain degrees of transparency have come to have special
importance to the politics of oil. In addition to the EITI (2003), they include the Åarhus
convention on public information disclosure (1998), the OECD guidelines on
Multinational Enterprises (2000),x the Equator Principles (2003)xi and the UN declaration
on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples (UN 2007). Moreover, projects supported by
International Financial Institutions such as the World Bank and the European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) are expected to conform to the operating
principles and guidelines of these institutions, which also enshrine the principle of
transparency. This evolving nexus of guidelines, principles, agreements, laws and codes
of practice constitute an overlapping and uneven series that both modify and supplement
existing national legislation, and that in practice may either contradict or complement
each other.xii
Having explored the operation of EITI in relation to the specific question of revenue
transparency, from Chapter 5 onwards I turn to consider how the development of the
BTC pipeline was subject to a much wider set of expectations for transparency. The
contrast between the narrow range of information made public through the development
EITI and the vast quantity of information made public in the period prior to and during
the construction of the BTC pipeline was remarkable. The BTC pipeline, as we shall see,
was to be materially invisible, but the invisibility of the pipe itself, following construction,
coexisted with its informational visibility. Whereas the political experiment of revenue
transparency took place under carefully controlled conditions in Azerbaijan, the political
experiment of BTC was, in comparison, conducted across a more heterogeneous and less
well regulated space, stretching across three countries.
Before examining the transparency of the BTC project in greater detail in later chapters, I
turn in Chapter 4 to consider a further dimension of its politics. This revolves around the
broader concern, which flourished from the mid 1990s on, with the ethical conduct of
the oil industry, and especially its social and environmental responsibility. I highlight, in
particular, how social and environmental responsibility came to be understood during
this period as something that had to be demonstrated in public in order to be guaranteed.
At the same time, I contrast these performances with the work of radical critics who
focused their attention on what they took to be specific instances of unethical or
irresponsible conduct on the part of the industry, while expanding the politics onto a
larger plane.
http://www.earthinstitute.columbia.edu/cgsd/STP/
One response to this limitation is to gather more information and associate EITI with a wider
range of interventions. This is the approach, termed ‘EITI++’ proposed by the World Bank.
“[This] will provide governments with a slate of options including technical assistance and
capacity building for improving the management of resource-related wealth for the benefit of the
poor. Through technical assistance, EITI++ aims to improve the quality of contracts for
countries, monitoring operations and the collection of taxes and royalties. It will also improve
economic decisions on resource extraction, managing price volatility, and investing revenues
i
ii
effectively for national development”. World Bank press release 2008/269/AFR, Washington 12
April 2008.
iii
http://eiti.org/TimorLeste (last accessed March 2013)
That is, the fund set up to receive revenue payments. A substantial fraction of payments made
by oil companies to the Azerbaijan government takes the form of tax, which is not recorded.
v Interview, Baku, June 2004.
vi Interview, Baku, June 2004
vii Interview, Baku, June 2004.
viii For an account of the history of corruption and organised crime in Georgia during in the postSoviet period, see Kukhianidze (2009).
ix Interviews and field notes, Tbilisi, March 2004, Baku, June 2004.
x The guidelines contain numerous references to the need for transparency as a means of
preventing corruption and bribery, for example:
http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/43/29/48004323.pdf
xi The equator principles are described as, “A financial industry benchmark for determining,
assessing and managing social and environmental risk in project financing”. Those institutions
that adopt the principles, “recognise the importance of transparency with regard to the
implementation of the Equator Principles (EPs)” http://www.equator-principles.com/
xii In principle, it would be possible to trace some of the negotiations and compromises that have
led to this particular body of international agreements and laws— in other words, to demonstrate
its relation to politics. Yet in practice firms, investors, international institutions and NGOs tend
to treat this evolving regulatory constellation as the non-political foundation which governs, but
does not determine, what should or should not be rendered transparent. Nonetheless, the
provisional quality of such guidelines and laws means that the distinction between law and
politics may be hard to sustain. In this respect, this body of law and soft law appears quite
different from the specific case of administrative law analysed by Bruno Latour (2009). On the
relation between legal and political disagreement, see Waldron (1999b).
iv