A New Atlantic Community:
The European Union, the US and Latin America
Joaquín Roy (editor)
Miami-Florida European Union Center/Jean Monnet Chair, 2015
A New Atlantic Community:
The European Union, the US and Latin America
Joaquín Roy (editor)
Editorial Assistance: Diana Soller and Nilda García
Cover Design by Nohora Tapias
Miami-Florida European Union Center
Jean Monnet Chair, 2015
Co-edition by the Argentine Council of Foreign Relations (CARI),
Buenos Aires, Argentina
Contributors
Beverly Barrett
Sarah L. Beringer
Javier Bonilla Saus
Pedro Caldentey del Pozo
Ángel M. Casas-Gragea
Alejandro Chanona
Lurong Chen
Philippe De Lombaerde
Rita Giacalone
Pedro Isern
Maxime H. A. Larivé
Liliana Lizarazo Rodríguez
María Lorca-Susino
Willem Maas
Joseph A. McKinney
Carlos Malamud
Tamás Novák
Vicente Palacio
Félix Peña
Joaquín Roy
Ana Paula Tostes
Co-Sponsors
The National University of Tres de Febrero (Buenos Aires), the University
ORT (Montevideo, Uruguay), the Real Instituto Elcano (Madrid), the
Fundación Alternativas (Madrid), and the Center for Latin American
Studies of the University of Miami.
The Miami-Florida European Union Center of Excellence
A Partnership of the University of Miami and Florida International University
and
The Jean Monnet Chair of the University of Miami
The Miami-Florida European Union Center of Excellence (M-FEUCE) is one of the
8 Centers of Excellence supported by the European Commission at universities throughout the United States, as part of a broader effort to promote contacts across the Atlantic.
Thus, these EU Centers promote the study of the EU, its institutions and policies and
EU/US relations through teaching programs, scholarly research and outreach activities in
their local and regional communities.
The Jean Monnet Chair of European Integration, awarded by the European Commission’s Jean Monnet Action of the General Directorate of Education and Culture in 2001
to the University of Miami, has been exclusively dedicated to strengthen the teaching and
research of the EU, with a strong specialization on its relations with Latin America and
the Caribbean and comparative regional integration. In 2011, chair was awarded “ad personam”
Miami – Florida
European Union Center
University of Miami
2300 Campo Sano Building, 220C
Coral Gables, FL 33124-2231
Phone: 305-284-3266
Fax: (305) 284 4406
Web: www.miami.edu/eucenter
Jean Monnet Chair Staff
Joaquín Roy (Director)
María Lorca (Research Associate)
Maxime Larivé (Research Associate)
Diana Soller (Editorial Assistant)
Nilda García (Editorial Assistant)
Florida International University
Rebecca Friedman (Co-Director)
International Jean Monnet Chair Editorial Advisors:
Philippe de Lombaerde, UNU/CRIS, Brugge, Belgium
Michelle Egan, American University,
Kurt Hübner, University of British Columbia, Vancouver
Finn Laursen, University of Southern Denmark
John McCormick, Indiana University, Purdue
Félix Peña, Universidad Nacional de Tres de Febrero, Buenos Aires, Argentina
Manuel Porto, University of Coimbra, Portugal
Lorena Ruano, CIDE, Mexico
Eric Tremolada, Universidad del Externado de Colombia, Bogotá, Colombia
Roberto Domínguez, Suffolk University, Boston
Francesc Granell, University of Barcelona
Printed in the United States by Thomson-Shore, Inc.
Copyright 2015.Jean Monnet Chair/University of Miami. All rights reserved. No portion of the contents may be reproduced in any form without written consent of the publisher.
Contents
Preface
A New Atlantic Community: The Background
Joaquín Roy
University of Miam …………………………………………………………….9
I. Background and setting
Regional Economic Integration in the European Union and North America: A
Theoretical Perspective
Joseph A. McKinney
Baylor University, Waco, Texas……………………………………….. 17
Global Political and Economic Restructuring through Free Trade Agreements
(FTAs)
Tamás Novák
Budapest Business School; MTA KRTK Institute for World Economics 27
Trade in Higher Education Services in the TTIP Negotiations and Beyond
Beverly Barrett
University of Houston…………………………………………………. 37
The Price of Energy and its Impact in the Economies of the US and Eurozone:
Implications for the TTIP
María Lorca
University of Miami………………..………………………………….. 49
The TTIP from a German Perspective:
Economic Interests and Political Discourse
Sarah Beringer
University of Nuremberg, Germany…...………………………………65
II. Beyond Economics
TTIP: A Mega-Free Trade Agreement Lost in Translation
Maxime H. A. Larivé
University of Miami…………………………………………………....79
Revisiting the TTIP: the Revenge of Politics
Vicente Palacio
Fundación Alternativas, Madrid……………………………………….91
Symmetries and Asymmetries in Integration Processes
Javier Bonilla and Pedro Isern
ORT University, Montevideo, Uruguay.………………………………101
Trade, Regional Integration, and Free Movement of People
Willem Maas
York University, Canada……….………………………………………111
III. Europe and Latin America
The Crisis of the European Integration Model, and its Implications for Latin
American Integration
Ángel María Casas Gragea and Pedro Caldentey del Pozo
Metropolitan Autonomous University, Mexico, D.F., Mexico; Loyola
University Andalusia, Cordoba,
Spain…………………………………………………………………. 125
The Effect of the TTIP on the BRICS Countries: The Case of Brazil
Ana Paula Tostes
Rio de Janeiro State University...…………………………………..... 135
Health-Related IPR Provisions in FTAs in the Atlantic Community
Liliana Lizarazo, Lurong Chen, and Philippe De Lombaerde
UNU-CRIS, Brugges, Belgium…………………..…………………………………………….....145
The European Union and Latin America: Facing the Drug-Trafficking Challenge
Alejandro Chanona
National Autonomous University of Mexico…...…...…...…...…...…...159
IV. Inside Latin America
Latin American Answers to Mega-Regional Projects: Options and Limits
Rita Giacalone
University of Los Andes, Venezuela…………………………………...175
Regional integration in Latin America: the strategy of ‘convergence in diversity’
and the relations between Mercosur and the Pacific Alliance
Félix Peña
Universidad Nacional de Tres de Febrero, Argentina………………..189
Regional Integration in Latin America: A Diagnosis of the Crisis
Carlos Malamud
Real Instituto Elcano, Madrid…………………………………………199
About the Authors……………………………………………………………...209
Preface
A New Atlantic Community:
The Background
Joaquín Roy
University of Miami
The European Union and Latin America
Several important gatherings and remembrances involving the European
Union, the United States and the Latin America-Caribbean region will take place
this year. On April 10 and 11, 2015, the Seventh Summit of the Americas, with a
focus on “Prosperity with Equity: The Challenge of Cooperation in the Americas”, will be held in Panama City, Panama. It will be attended by the leadership
of the Western Hemisphere. Participants and observers will still remember the
failure of the agreement for the establishment of the Free Trade Area of the
Americas envisioned in Miami two decades ago in 1994, the same year of the
foundation of the North-American Free Trade Agreement formed by the United
States, Canada and Mexico.
On June 11-12, 2015, the highest representatives of 61 European, Latin
American and Caribbean countries are scheduled to meet in Brussels. They comprise one third of the United Nations membership, with a total population of over
1.1 billion and a combined GDP of approximately US$20 trillion. For almost two
decades the two regions have regulated their diverse links through the EU “Strategic Partnership”. This setting complies with the mandate of organizing a biannual summit that customarily has been held since 1990, alternating European and
Latin American capitals. The timing and the choice of the place of the 2015 event
is extremely significant, because it is the first time that this conclave takes place
in the capital of the major institutions of the European Union, the organization
that is considered the most ambitious entity in regional integration and cooperation among states. This event is also the second time that the Latin American/Caribbean side is represented collectively by the Community of Latin American and Caribbean States (CELAC). The preceding meetings were held in Rio
de Janeiro (1999), Madrid (2002), Guadalajara (2004), Vienna (2006), Lima
(2008), Madrid (2010) and Santiago de Chile (2013).
The European Union and the Latin American-Caribbean areas are two
regions that in fact are the most “natural allies” of the planet (along the links of
the United States/Canada with Europe itself), bonded by solid cultural, historical,
economic, and legal ties. Politics is a dimension that remains under study, taking
into account different interpretations of democracy and political approaches. In
the political realm, both regions co-operate very closely at different international
Roy - 10
levels, maintaining an intensive “political dialogue”. They also interchange in
many nuances across a wide regional level, evident also at sub-regional scenarios. For Brussels, Latin America is subdivided along bureaucratic parameters, respecting the sub-regions as self-defined by Latin Americans. From this perspective, the EU (as a whole) deals with the entities known as Central America, the
Andean Community, and MERCOSUR, as well as with the Caribbean. The economic relationship between the European Union and Latin America can be inspected in three sectors: trade, investment and development aid. Each one shows
interesting aspects confirming perceptions and offering backing evidence for the
preferences of each part. The EU is the largest donor of development aid and the
first investor, and the second trade partner after the US.
A Wider Global Picture
This summit of 2015 takes place in the middle of a crucial year in the
economic and political evolution of both continents. 2015 is also the setting of
the full development of a trend-setting project announced in 2003: the planned
Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) between the United States
and the European Union, scheduled by both parties to be finalized at the end of
2015, but many predict it will take longer to be approved. This ambitious operation could ultimately form the largest economic bloc in the planet, the result of an
apparent world-wide frenzy for the establishment of trade agreements as a sign of
effective globalization. Since its announcement, influential governments of Europe have expressed satisfaction with the project and have entrusted the European Commission (holder of the exclusive competence of EU foreign trade) the
mission of drafting an agreement that by law would receive the nod of the deciding EU institutions (the Council and the Parliament). Scholars and media have
already paid considerable attention to the project.
Together, both projects (TTIP and EU-CELAC) could then in turn form a
much larger economic (with political consequences) bloc of formidable world
reach, in what could be termed as an Atlantic Community. The facts and prospects of this triangular scenario are truly impressive in comprehensive terms and
in comparative dimensions. The combined population is over 1.4 billion, 19.8%
of the world. By itself, the EU is the world’s largest trading bloc (almost onefifth of global trade and one-quarter of the global economy). The EU and US together, with a combined population of over 800 million, generate almost half of
global GDP, handle nearly 30 percent of global merchandise trade, about 40 percent of world trade in services, and well over half of foreign direct investment.
The United States directs half of its total foreign direct investment (FDI) toward
the EU, and the EU’s FDI in the U.S. accounts for almost two-thirds of America’s total incoming investment. Approximately 15 million jobs are linked to the
transatlantic economy. Globally, either the EU or the US is the largest trade and
investment partner for almost all other countries in the world. The EU and the
Roy - 11
United States are each other’s leading partners by trade volume (imports plus
exports). Every day, the EU and the U.S. trade goods and services worth $2.7
billion. TTIP could benefit the rest of the world by more than €100 billion.
Issues to Consider
Any analytical and research plan is pressed to consider several fundamental issues of both processes. The most important one is the evaluation of the
European Union itself as a model or reference for effective regional integration.
Is the EU accepted as a cohesive partner by the United States, with full autonomy
to negotiate such a formidable deal? Is the EU the irreplaceable model for effective regional integration in Latin America? Are there any other models in other
parts of the world? What are the domestic obstacles for a deeper integration dimension in Latin America and the Caribbean? What is the negative role of strict
national sovereignty, presidentialism, lack of national social integration, poverty
and inequality? How does populism present opposition to what may be perceived
as loss of sovereignty? How is European investment in Latin America perceived
and received—as a positive, unconditional contribution, or as a reborn example
of “imperialism”? How is the EU democratic conditionality in development aid
programs perceived in Latin America when considering bi-regional pacts with
Latin America/Caribbean? What is the role of the preferred strategy of the United
States in international trade schemes? Is this influence an irresistible force in Latin America?
When considering the role of the United States in negotiating with the
EU, what are the domestic constraints in the US for deeper commitments in international trade and cooperation? What are the “red lines” in Congress and the
White House? How are European regulatory conditions perceived in negotiations
with the US? What is the impact of European basic conditions of the welfare
state regulations on the development of a trade pact with the EU? Will the sensitive fields of health, labor law, and immigration affect the negotiations of the
TTIP? What influence does the calendar of elections in Europe (national and EUwide) and in the United States (mid-term and presidential) have in the development of a trade pact (now and in the future)? Will the US President obtain the
“fast track authority” to sign trade deals? How autonomous is the authority of the
European Commission in negotiating external trade for the whole EU membership?
In sum, when dealing with the multiple aspects of this triangular scenario, observers and researchers must be prepared for long and complex negotiations on both sides of the Atlantic and be ready to witness disappointments and
failures, as well as to certify successes.
In fact, this expanded interpretation of the concept of “transatlantic” relations including Latin America and the Caribbean has been a key factor for the
recognition of our European Union Center and the award of the Jean Monnet
Roy - 12
Chair at the University of Miami, with over US $1.8 million in grants. Our staff
and partners at Florida International University have entrenched themselves in
the study of both bi-continental processes. We have followed them with research,
teaching and publications. This volume is dedicated to the analysis of such diverse developments.
A Seminar and a Monograph
The present monograph reflects the proceedings (with a few additions) of
a seminar under the comprehensive title of “A New Atlantic Community: The
European Union, the US and Latin America”. It was organized by Jean Monnet
Chair of the University of Miami, under the sponsorship of the Miami-Florida
European Union Center of Excellence (a partnership with Florida International
University) and the EU Commission. It was held on Friday, February 27, 2015, at
the School of Business Administration of the University of Miami. The main topics and themes were the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP)
to be agreed between the European Union and the United States and its impact on
Latin America, the relations between the EU and Latin America, and the overall
issues of regional integration and economic cooperation in the Western Hemisphere. This volume, available for free access in the web of the Center, will also
take the form of co-edition published by the Argentine Council of Foreign Relations (CARI) to be distributed in Latin America, and available on their web.
Welcome and introductory words were provided by Douglas Fuller (Associate Dean, College of Arts and Sciences, University of Miami), Rebecca
Friedman (Co-Director, EU Center, Florida International University), and Richard Weisskoff (Chair, Department of International Studies). British Consul General Dave Prodger, Spanish Deputy Consul General Javier Pagalday, and
French Consul General Philippe Letrilliart offered comments. Sessions were
chaired by Markus Thiel (Florida International University), Aimee Kanner
(Florida Atlantic University), Eduardo Elena (Director, Latin American Studies,
University of Miami), and Ambler Moss (University of Miami).
A selection of the themes and issues were grouped in four fundamental
parts responding to general approaches. Part I (“Background and setting”) describes the overall presence of the TTIP. Joseph A. McKinney (Baylor University, Waco, Texas), in “Regional Economic Integration in the European Union and
North America: A Theoretical Perspective” provides a comprehensive analysis of
the major aspects of the bi-continental project crafted by the two partners.
Tamás Novák (Budapest Business School; MTA KRTK Institute for World
Economics), in “Global Political and Economic Restructuring through Free Trade
Agreements (FTAs),” points out the motivations and consequences of today´s
FTAs as a result of the changes in the international political power. Beverly Barrett (University of Houston), in “Trade in Higher Education Services in the TTIP
Negotiations and Beyond”, examines the role of higher education services in
Roy - 13
trade negotiations, due to their dual purposes for employability and to enhance
civil society, as nations cooperate across national boundaries. María Lorca,
University of Miami, in “The Price of Energy and its Impact in the Economies of
the US and Eurozone: Implications for the TTIP,” deals with a crucial sector that
has an extraordinary impact on the overall picture of the plan crafted by these
formidable world powers. Sarah Beringer, University of Nuremberg, Germany,
in “The TTIP Partnership from a German Perspective: Economic Interests and
Political Discourse,” tackles the perception of the TTIP from the point of view of
the most powerful economic and political leadership in Europe, destined to dominate the rest of the negotiations.
Part II is dedicated to topics that spillover beyond the basic scope of the
bi-continental partnership (“Beyond Economics”). Maxime H. A. Larivé (University of Miami), in “TTIP: Creating an Economic NATO or Fermenting European Fears?”, ventures into the sector that would be better treated in a study of
strategic issues, reflecting on two dimensions: the projected benefits of the TTIP
for the EU and the debate and perceptions within the EU about the TTIP. Vicente
Palacio (Fundación Alternativas, Madrid), in “Revisiting the TTIP: the Revenge
of Politics”, remind us that, as the original essence of the EU is based on more
issues than simple trade of goods and financial investments. Javier Bonilla and
Pedro Isern (ORT University, Montevideo, Uruguay), in “Symmetries and
Asymmetries in Integration Processes”, deal with an array of dimensions in a
variety of integration and economic cooperation experiments, with the warning
that with certain actors in certain contexts, integration does not always translate
into optimum results. Willem Maas (York University, Canada), “Trade, Regional Integration, and Free Movement of People," offers an analysis in which the
issue of transnational citizenship becomes central, dealing with concrete examples of accomplishments in Latin America under the influence of the European
precedent.
Part III covers topics dealing with the link between Europe and Latin
America. Ángel María Casas Gragea (Metropolitan Autonomous University,
Mexico, D.F., Mexico) and Pedro Caldentey del Pozo (Loyola University Andalusia, Cordoba, Spain), in “The Crisis of the European Integration Model, and
its Implications for Latin American Integration” venture in the area where doubts
of the adaptation or adoption of the EU model become evident. Ana PaulaTostes
(Rio de Janeiro State University), in “The Effect of the TTIP on the BRICS
Countries: The Case of Brazil,” deals with one of the most important consequences of the TTIP on the emerging powers that are presenting a challenge both
to the United States and to Europe, choosing Brazil as the central focus of analysis. Liliana Lizarazo, Lurong Chen, and Philippe De Lombaerde (UNUCRIS, Bruges, Belgium), in “Health-Related IPR Provisions in FTAs in the Atlantic Community,” ponder why health-related Intellectual Property Rights (IPR)
provisions are seen as so controversial in trade negotiations and how the court
system is facing the problem of balancing this issue with the right to health.
Roy - 14
Alejandro Chanona, of the National Autonomous University of Mexico, in
“The European Union and Latin America: Facing the Drug-Trafficking Challenge”, offers an analysis of the EU-LAC cooperation to fight drug trafficking
combined with dealing with the underlying causes of the problem through druguse prevention and rehabilitation of addicts.
Finally, in Part IV, labeled as “Inside Latin America” but spilling over
the geographical limitations, authors concentrate on several dimensions that pertain to Latin American countries. Rita Giacalone (University of Los Andes,
Venezuela), in “Latin American Answers to Mega-Regional Projects: Options
and Limits,” inquires about the response of Latin America absorbing the impact
of projects like TTIP with the result of generating other alliances inside the area
(convergence of and expanded MERCOSUR with the Pacific Alliance and the
combination of ECO-ALBA-Petrocaribe Zone). Félix Peña (Universidad
Nacional de Tres de Febrero, Argentina) in “Regional integration in Latin America: the strategy of ‘convergence in diversity’ and the relations between Mercosur
and the Pacific Alliance,” proposes the encouragement of an agenda of cooperation provided by all Latin American countries, with the result that its effects
would then transcend the strict regional scope. But, as in most other cases, this
scope will require perseverance, technical imagination and political will. Carlos
Malamud (Real Instituto Elcano, Madrid), in “Regional Integration in Latin
America: a Diagnosis of the Crisis,” presents an analysis of the general integration process, outlining the short- and long-term options for interregional cooperation, as a useful option until a reasonable solution is found to the current issues
the Andean Community (CAN), Mercosur, Unasur, and the Alliance of the Pacific.
Academic and logistical assistance was provided by Diana Soller (Editor
and Research Assistant, University of Miami) and Nilda García (Editor and Research Assistant, University of Miami). Technical assistance was given by Luis
Vidal, James Aggrey and Benjamin De Tullio (Computer Support, College of
Arts and Sciences), and financial control was coordinated by Miguel Ramírez
and Alexis Fernández (Department of International Studies) and Tracy Ehrlich
(College of Arts and Sciences). Program co-sponsors and contributing institutions were the European Commission, the Delegation of the European Union
in the United States, the European Union Studies Association (EUSA, EU-LA
Interest section), the Latin American Studies Association (LASA, Europe-Latin
America Section), the Argentine Council of Internacional Relations (CARI),
the Center for International Business Education and Research (CIBER U.
Miami) and Center for Latin American Studies (CLAS, University of Miami).
Support for participation was also provided by the National University of Tres
de Febrero (Buenos Aires), the University ORT (Montevideo, Uruguay), the
Real Instituto Elcano (Madrid), and the Fundación Alternativas (Madrid).
Special gratitude is due to Pedro A. Gonzalez (President of the Florida
Association of Hispanic Journalists).
I.
Background and Setting
Regional Economic Integration in the European Union and
North America:
a Theoretical Perspective
Joseph A. McKinney
Baylor University
Abstract
Regional economic integration is occurring in Europe and in North America,
driven partly by market forces, but also by policy measures. The process has
been much more formal and policy-driven in the European Union than in North
America. A number of comparative regionalism theories have sought to explain
how economic integration develops differently in different regions. This paper
compares and contrasts the progression of regional economic integration in the
European Union with that in North America, assessing the degree to which various theories can reasonably explain the differences.
Introduction
Regional economic integration occurs naturally when economic agents are free to
engage in trade and investment. But it is also affected by policy measures and by
the establishment of regional institutions. Economic interdependence increases
the need for cooperation in order to provide public goods that are beyond the
scope of one country, and to internalize positive and negative externalities (Keohane 1984). In the case of heterogeneous populations, preferences for policies
and institutions differ across groups, necessitating a weighing of the costs and
benefits of particular integration policies (Alesina and La Ferrara 2005). Through
participation in regional institutions, countries develop a more accurate picture of
what is important to the partner countries, learn what they can expect from each
other, and can develop a higher level of mutual trust (Axelrod 1983).
Transactions costs among nations can also be reduced as countries agree
beforehand on what types of bargains are desirable, and build mechanisms for
challenging forbidden types (Martin and Simmons 1998). Establishment of rules
at the regional level, and monitoring of compliance with them, can provide for a
more favorable business climate by reducing uncertainty (Keohane 1984). However, compliance is costly, and formulation of rules can beyond a point become
counterproductive.
Institutional arrangements can also help to alleviate time inconsistency
problems by allowing politicians to shift to the regional level actions that have
McKinney - 18
short-term costs but long-term benefits, and can also perform a valuable signaling
function that policies are stable (Martin and Simmons 1998). This paper assesses
the degree to which the economic integration and institutional development that
have occurred in the European Union (EU) and the North American Free Trade
Area (NAFTA) can be reasonably explained in each case by existing theories of
regional economic integration.
Formation of European Union Institutions
The institutional arrangements that eventually evolved into the European Union
had their roots in the desire of the world, and particularly the countries of Europe,
to have more peaceful political and economic relations. While European history
is replete with military and economic conflicts, the first half of the twentieth century was particularly devastating. Europe had been at the center of two world
wars, with the period between characterized by economic and financial turbulence. During the interwar period there was little cooperation in economic matters.
Some European intellectuals, such as Altiero Spinelli and Jean Monnet,
envisioned a European federation that, by eliminating national borders, would put
an end to international conflict within Europe (Sporalore 2013). The founding
document of European integration, however, was more modest. The Shuman
Declaration of 9 May 1950 proposed placing the coal and steel industries of
France and West Germany (and other countries that wished to join) under the
control of a supranational High Authority. According to the declaration, “The
solidarity in production thus established will make it plain that any war between
France and Germany becomes not merely unthinkable, but materially impossible” (Shuman Declaration 1950). The European Coal and Steel Community
(ECSC) was formed in 1951 by the Treaty of Paris, and in addition to France and
West Germany included Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands and Luxembourg as
member countries.
In 1957, the Treaty of Rome established a European Common Market
and the European Atomic Energy Community. This treaty provided for the removal of tariffs among the member countries, for establishment of a common
external tariff, and for eventual unrestricted movement of factors of production.
These market liberalization measures triggered a strong inflow of capital into the
member countries that stimulated economic activity and led to a series of enlargements. Membership in the group expanded to include the United Kingdom,
Ireland and Denmark in 1971; Greece in 1981; Spain and Portugal in 1985; Austria, Finland and Sweden in 1995; ten additional countries mainly from Eastern
Europe in 2004; Romania and Bulgaria in 2007; and Croatia in 2013, for a total
membership of 28 countries.
While the institutions of the European Union have taken shape gradually
over time, most of the present-day institutions had their origin in the European
McKinney - 19
Coal and Steel Community. The executive body of the ECSC was a High Authority consisting of nine members. Since the High Authority was truly a decisionmaking body, some member countries were uncomfortable with its supranational
character. Therefore, an Assembly composed of 78 deputies representing national
parliaments was created and given supervisory power. A Council composed of a
representative from each of the member governments was formed, the purpose of
which was “to harmonize the activities of the High Authority and the general
economic policy of the governments” (ECSC Treaty 1951). Finally, a Court of
Justice composed of seven members was constituted to ensure proper interpretation and implementation of the founding treaty.
In 1957, when the European Economic Community and the European
Atomic Energy Community were formed, their institutions were similar to those
of the ECSC but with more powers residing in the Council as direct representative of the national governments. The name of the Common Assembly was
changed to European Parliament in 1962. In 1967 the institutions of the three
communities were merged by implementation of a Merger Treaty, with the executive functions of the High Authority being transferred to the Commission of the
European Communities. In 2002 the Treaty of Paris expired and the High Authority ceased to exist as a legal entity (Europa 2007).
Preliminary moves toward monetary unification among the EC countries
had been made in 1979 through the establishment of the Exchange Rate Mechanism. In 1992 the Treaty on European Union (Maastricht Treaty) was signed and
expanded the role of the supranational institutions (in particular by giving the
European Parliament some co-legislative powers), and set forth a plan for monetary unification and a common currency. The European Central Bank came into
existence in 1998, the euro was established as a unit of account in 1999, and it
became a circulating currency and the official currency of the twelve participating countries (now 19) in 2002. The Treaty on European Union changed the
name of the European Communities to the European Union and established the
concept of European Union citizenship.
An attempt was made through a Convention on the Future of Europe in
2002 to develop a European Union Constitution that would have given additional
supranational powers to the EU institutions. A draft constitution was signed in
2004, but was subsequently rejected in referenda in France and the Netherlands.
Consequently, a less ambitious plan called the Lisbon Treaty was approved. This
treaty, among other things, established a President of the European Council and a
High Representative for Foreign Affairs. It also strengthened the supranational
functions of some of the EU institutions by, for example, giving the European
Commission exclusive competence in the negotiation of trade and investment
treaties, and giving the European Parliament the right to approve or disapprove
trade agreements.
In general, the European Commission serves as the executive body of the
EU and initiates EU legislation. The legislative body of the EU was originally the
McKinney - 20
Council of Ministers, with ministers in the appropriate subject area from each
member country voting on the legislation. The European Parliament had only an
advisory role with regard to legislation. However, in the Maastricht Treaty the
Parliament was given co-decision authority over some issues, and in the Lisbon
Treaty was made co-legislator with the Council on most issues. The Court of Justice interprets, and oversees the implantation of EU legislation.
The EU has gone farther than any other regional economic integration
scheme toward a federal economic system. Significant sovereignty has been ceded to EU institutions concerning matters of regional economic integration. However, the EU remains a long way from a true federal system in this regard. Only
recently, are steps being taken toward a banking union. The lack of a fiscal union
has created strains for the monetary union, in that no automatic stabilizers exist to
make transfers from more prosperous countries to those experiencing recession.
Even with its federalist economic elements, nations in the EU continue to exercise considerable sovereignty with regard to economic issues.
Formation of NAFTA-Related Institutions
The countries of North America, in entering into the North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA), had much more limited aims than those of the EU countries. Its major focus was to remove impediments to trade in goods and services.
In the 1980’s the United States had become frustrated at not being able to get
trade issues such as services trade, agricultural trade, investment measures, and
intellectual property issues onto the agenda for multilateral trade talks. A decision was made to pursue bilateral and regional free trade agreements, both as a
way to put pressure on trading partners to enter into a new round of multilateral
negotiations and as a way to demonstrate that progress on the new issues was
possible. The US-Israel free trade agreement went into effect in 1984, and the
implementing legislation for the agreement stated that the US would consider
requests for such agreements from other countries.
Canada requested a free trade agreement in 1985, negotiations began in
1987, and the US-Canada free trade agreement went into effect in 1989. This
agreement was quite comprehensive and demonstrated that progress was possible
in bilateral negotiations on the issues that the US was pushing for inclusion at the
multilateral level. Mexico requested a free trade agreement with the US in 1990.
Canada soon joined the negotiations, and the North American free trade agreement was signed in 1992, entering into force in 1994.
NAFTA built upon the template of the US-Canada free trade agreement,
but also contained provisions concerning protection of intellectual property and a
controversial chapter on investor-state protections. In side agreements to the
main agreement, environmental and labor issues were for the first time connected
to a free trade agreement. The agreement established several institutions that
McKinney - 21
were, in distinct contrast to those of the EU, minimalist institutions (McKinney
2000).1
A Free Trade Commission oversees the implementation of the agreement
and helps resolve disputes that may arise from application of the agreement. It
consists of the trade ministers of the three countries who meet once a year to discuss the agreement and to deal with any problems. The Free Trade Commission
oversees working groups that look into specific trade issues, and basically focuses on trade facilitation issues arising from the NAFTA.
Besides the general dispute settlement mechanism of NAFTA, there are
specific dispute settlement mechanisms for addressing financial issues, investorstate disputes, and trade remedies. Chapter 11 of NAFTA provides that companies from one of the countries investing in another can sue the federal government of the host country for damages arising from violation of the terms of the
agreement, with the dispute settled through binding arbitration. Chapter 19 of the
agreement provides for binding arbitration of disputes arising from the application of antidumping or countervailing duty laws.
The North American Agreement on Labor Cooperation established a
North American Commission on Labor Cooperation (CLC) with a secretariat
located in Washington, D.C. A council comprised of the labor ministers of the
three countries oversaw the work of the commission. The commission encouraged cooperation and consultation regarding labor issues in North America, and
conducted some studies of North American labor markets. The CLC is, unfortunately, no longer functioning due to lack of funding. National Administrative
Offices in each of the NAFTA countries were established to hear complaints that
member countries are not enforcing their labor laws.2 They may issue a report on
the matter under investigation, and if the issue remains unresolved they may seek
an evaluation from a committee of experts. Should the matter still remain unresolved, theoretically the matter could go to binding arbitration with monetary
enforcement assessment.
The North American Agreement on Environmental Cooperation likewise
established a North American Commission on Environmental Cooperation (CEC)
that is overseen by the environment ministers of the three countries. The CEC
secretariat is located in Montreal, Canada. The CEC has continued to receive
funding, but its budget has recently been reduced. The CEC has conducted some
useful studies on the environment of North America, the first studies looking at
the region as a whole. The CEC is able to self-initiate studies of perceived environmental problems, or respond to requests of private parties to investigate such
problems. The CEC can receive submissions from persons or organizations in
1
The next six paragraphs draw upon information presented in (McKinney 2000).
In recognition of the fact that the US was negotiating a number of bilateral and regional
free trade agreements, in December 2004 the name of the US NAO was changed to Division of Trade Agreement and Technical Cooperation (in the US Department of Labor) to
implement the labor provisions of all of the free trade agreements.
2
McKinney - 22
either of the member countries alleging that a member country is not enforcing
its environmental laws. It studies the issue and may publish a factual record describing the situation. If one country considers that another is engaging in a persistent pattern of failing to enforce its environmental laws, the case can be taken
to binding arbitration with possible monetary enforcement assessment. Both the
NAAEC and the NAALC have a supranationalist element in that some decisions
can be taken by a two-thirds vote of the respective national representatives rather
than through consensus.
Two other NAFTA-related institutions are bilateral rather than trilateral
and deal with environmental issues along the US-Mexico border. A Border Environment Cooperation Commission assesses proposals for the funding of environmental projects in the border region and makes recommendations to the North
American Development Bank (NADBank), which makes loans to fund the approved projects. While some much-needed projects have received NADBank
funding, the institution is grossly underfunded to address environmental needs
along the border.
Theoretical Explanations for Divergent Developments
As described above, regional economic integration has proceeded very differently in Europe and North America, and the resulting institutional arrangements diverge widely. Can these differences be explained by theories of comparative regional integration? To some degree they can.
Economic integration arrangements began in Europe primarily from a
desire to try to ensure peaceful relations. But once the process was underway, it
seems to be explained reasonably well by neofunctionalist political theory initially articulated by Ernst Haas (1968). According to this theory, as countries become economically interdependent with each other, demand increases for rules
and procedures to simplify their interactions. The higher degree of interdependence creates a need for institutions to facilitate cooperation among the participating countries, so as to realize the potential for mutually beneficial gains and to
address negative externalities (Keohane 1984). Institutions can also provide
“voice opportunities” for weaker countries in the relationship to make their views
known and have them acted upon (Grieco 1994). However, certain conditions
are important in determining whether the institutions demanded will be supplied.
The supply of institutions depends upon a high degree of social and political pluralism in the participating countries, a reasonable degree of symmetry among the
countries with regard to this pluralism so that interest groups in the different
countries can unite across national boundaries in pursuit of common goals, and
highly bureaucratized decision-making in the member countries that makes policy-coordination by national civil services more efficient (Mattli and Sweet 2012).
Economic interdependence of the EU countries greatly increased as a result of the common market arrangement, and conditions sufficient for suprana-
McKinney - 23
tional institutions to develop existed. The completion of the internal market under
terms of the 1985 Single European Act further increased economic interdependence, and in 1992 the Treaty on European Union laid the groundwork for monetary union and expanded the role of the supranational institutions. The common
currency and monetary union among the participating countries further increased
their economic interdependence, and the strains arising from the Eurozone crisis
have caused moves toward a banking union and some steps toward fiscal union.
The independence and supranational character of the European Central Bank
have also been strengthened during this time.
In general, there has been a progressive move toward greater supranationalism of the institutions of the European Union as greater economic interdependence has created a demand for stronger regional institutions, and the necessary conditions for calling forth supply of these institutions have generally been
present.
The conditions in North America have been very different than in Europe, and regional economic integration in North America has a distinctly different character. The theory that has considerable explanatory power for North
America is externality theory. According to this theory the demand for regional
institutions depends on both the frequency and the perceived riskiness of transactions among the member countries. Externalities that affect cross-border economic transactions “…arise from economic and political uncertainty as well as financial hazards that market actors may face when dealing with multiple polities and
markets in a region” (Mattli and Sweet 2012: 6). As new opportunities for exchange arise, the demand increases for regional institutions to alleviate these
costs. However, political leaders must be convinced that supplying these institutions is worth the costs in terms of national sovereignty conceded (Mattli and
Sweet 2012).
In contrast to the European Union where positive integration measures
(regional regulations and policies) have been employed, in North America mainly negative integration measures (removal of impediments to trade and investment) have been used. Because the United States has been stable and for the most
part liberal in its trade policies, and therefore has acted as “benevolent hegemon”
in North America, there has not been as much demand for regional institutions as
in Europe. And because each of the three countries of North America has jealously guarded its sovereignty, there has not been a willingness on the part of politicians to develop strong regional institutions.
A third theory that has some explanatory power for both the European
Union and NAFTA is contracting theory. According to this theory, the institutional development of a regional economic integration arrangement will depend
heavily on the original contract agreed (Cooley and Spruyt 2009). In the European Union, the basic documents such as the Treaty of Rome were incomplete
agreements in that they set forth general priorities and objectives, but were not
very specific about how these priorities and objectives were to be achieved. The
McKinney - 24
intention was that the terms of the agreement would subsequently be defined and
perhaps revised according to the wishes of the parties involved, and in view of
changing circumstances. Supranational institutions such as the European Commission and the European Court of Justice were given authority to make decisions that could only be reversed by unanimously agreed treaty revision. Such a
treaty allows for the evolution of institutions and for increases over time in their
supranational authority (Mattli and Sweet 2012).
In contrast, the NAFTA is a more complete treaty spelling out its terms
in great detail. Its purpose was much more limited than that of the Treaty of
Rome in that it aimed only at establishing a free trade area, although it did deal
with much more than tariff elimination in that it addressed nontariff barriers to
trade, investment regulations, and intellectual property protection. Its provisions
are quite specific, however, and there are no supranational institutions that have
the authority to elaborate on or modify them. It has an intergovernmental mode
of governance (Mattli and Sweet 2012).
According to contracting theory, the type of contract upon which a regional integration scheme is founded will be influenced by how asymmetric in
power the contracting parties are, and how willing the parties are to cede national
sovereignty to regional institutions (Cooley and Spruyt 2009). The European Union countries had more power symmetry and were more willing to make concessions of national sovereignty than were the countries of North America. In North
America, the United States dominates the region in terms of economic and political power, so Canada and Mexico insisted on a complete contract with terms
spelled out specifically, with any possible future changes requiring the consent of
each of the countries. Furthermore, the United States had made it clear that it
would cede no national sovereignty to supranational institutions, and therefore a
complete contract was considered necessary by Canada and Mexico to protect
their interests (Mattli and Sweet 2012).
Conclusion
The regional economic integration arrangements of the European Union and
NAFTA have developed in very different ways and have distinctly different institutional structures. The countries of the European Union have chosen to deal with
collective action problems through setting up robust supranational institutions
and delegating to them the authority to make binding decisions. On the other
hand, the countries of North America have chosen to deal with collective action
problems through regional cooperation, jointly exercising authority through minimalist intergovernmental institutions. The different paths chosen on opposite
sides of the Atlantic can be understood through the lenses of neofunctionalist,
externality and contracting theories of comparative regional integration.
McKinney - 25
References
Alesina, Alberto and La Ferrara, Eliana. 2005. “Ethnic Diversity and Economic
Performance.” Journal of Economic Literature 43(3): 762– 800.
Axelrod, Robert. 1983. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.
Cooley, Alexander and Spruyt, Hendrik. 2009. Contracting States: Sovereign
Transfers in International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Europa. 2007. European Union Treaties: An Introduction. Accessed at:
http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/institutional_affairs/treaties/treati
es_introduction_en.htm
European Coal and Steel Community Treaty (ECSC Treaty). 1951. April 18,
1951. 261 U.N.T.S. 140.
Grieco, Joseph M. 1994. “State Interests and International Rule Trajectories: A
Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union.” Paper prepared for delivery at the Symposium on Realism. Washington, DC.
Grieco, Joseph M. 1997. “Systemic Sources of Variation in Regional Institutionalization in Western Europe, East Asia and the Americas,” In John G.
Ruggie (Ed.), The Political Economy of Regionalism (pp. 164-187). New
York: Columbia University Press.
Haas, Ernst. 1968. The Uniting of Europe: Political, Social and Economic Forces, 1950-1957, (2nd edition). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Keohane, Robert O. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the
World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Martin, Lisa and Simmons, Beth. 1998. “Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions.” International Organization 52, no. 4 (729-757).
Mattli, Walter and Sweet, Alex. 2012. “Regional Integration and the Evolution of
the European Polity: On the Fiftieth Anniversary of the Journal of Common Market Studies.” Journal of Common Market Studies 50(S1): 1-17.
McKinney - 26
McKinney, Joseph. 2000. Created from NAFTA: The Structure, Function, and
Significance of the Treaty’s Related Institutions. Armonk, NY: M.E.
Sharpe.
The Schuman Declaration. 1950. Archives of the ministry of foreign affairs Paris,
Secretariat general, inv. 9 May 1950. Nr. 57, ff. 3-6.
Sporalore, Enrico. 2013. “What Is European Integration Really About? A Political Guide for Economists,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27(3):
125-144.
Global Political and Economic Restructuring through Free
Trade Agreements (FTAs)
Tamás Novák
Budapest Business School; MTA KRTK Institute for World Economics
Abstract
Research on deeper economic cooperation by preferential trade agreements
(PTAs) has mostly centered on the economic implications of the PTAs for decades. A number of alternative analyses emphasize the role international power
relations and multilateral institutions play in the formation of regional economic
initiatives either positively or negatively. The new generation of FTAs differs
from earlier waves of similar agreements of the nineteen and twenty centuries.
They are probably much less about economic benefits than geostrategic objectives and global political concerns. It is, however, almost inevitable that in a period of uncertain economic growth “…the ultimate success of the negotiations
and the long-term viability of the arrangements turn more on economic and
commercial considerations” (World Economic Forum 2014: 18).
Introduction
For decades, mainstream research focused almost exclusively on the economic
implications of preferential trade agreements. In most cases ex ante theoretical
studies and impact assessments have emphasized mostly the positive impacts
experienced by the countries participating in such arrangements, while possible
negative outcomes were considered unlikely scenarios.1 Recent international
trade discourse has been dominated by mega-regional trade agreements.2 These
trade agreements can produce widespread and often unforeseen effects on domestic economies, international relations and politics. These impacts are very diffi1
According to the literature, there seems to be a consensus that earlier arrangements in
the nineteenth century were more positive in terms of trade creation while those between
the world wars were mostly trade diverting. But regarding the implications of preferential
trade agreements concluded after World War II there is no consent at all (Mansfield
1999: 593).
2
In this paper the term “mega-regional” FTA is used to mean agreements that in-volve
three or more countries; cover at least 25 percent of global trade flows; and include regulatory commitments rather than trade liberalization (Draper, Lacey, Ramkolowan 2014:
8). From another perspective, these deals can be classified as deep arrangements which
cover several measures beyond tariffs. These agreements also change tariffs but the most
important implications relate to nontariff barriers, regulations and standards, or other similar measures (Lawrence 1996).
Novák - 28
cult to forecast or fully understand given the uncertainties regarding the content
of the final agreements and lack of consent about the impacts of such large-scale
arrangements. Mutually advantageous implications of ambitious free trade
agreements under negotiation, however, cannot be taken for granted.
In the past decade the multilateral system administered by the WTO
came under challenge. A number of rapidly developing countries do not share the
core principles that have underpinned open rules-based commerce or more precisely, they do not accept the rules of Western dominated institutions without
having their say properly heard. Several states consider that traditional institutions of international economic relations and regulation do not take into account
the changing global power relations. Large emerging countries including China,
India or Brazil are becoming increasingly important economic and political players globally (or regionally – Russia); but, their weight is not fully reflected in the
international power relations.3 Most advanced countries consider this development to be a major challenge to the international economic and political system –
the very system they once used to have almost exclusive influence over the
world. These different interests led to either the paralyzation of some international organizations or to their reforms (the IMF is a good example) or to the deadlock of their operations (e.g. the WTO) or to increasing political and security
challenges (Russia).
Given these significant changes, it seems that the declining global hegemony of the US – mostly in terms of economic indicators – and the very poor
economic performance of the European Union, have contributed to the current
wave of regionalism through deep trade deals. It is also most certainly true that
we have entered into a new phase of international power relations.4 The new
mega-deal proposals constitute a new-generation of negotiations aimed at repositioning economies in a more intensified global competition. Other opinions go
further by emphasizing that the new generation of FTAs may be an appropriate
means in managing the challenges of emerging countries. On the other hand,
however, these agreements are feared to undermine the social model of Europe.
The basic question for many analysts and policy makers in Europe is how the
economic problems can be managed in a sustainable way while preserving the
values of the social market economic systems that Europe is justifiably so proud
3
For example, the organizational reform of IMF has been stalled since 2010 by the obstructions imposed by the US Senate. The reform would grant increasing voting powers
to developing countries. See, for example, the latest coverage: Statement by IMF Managing Director Christine Lagarde on IMF Quota and Governance Reforms. For more information see Press Release No.14/568, December 12, 2014 accessible at
http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pr/2014/pr14568.htm
4
As Pascal Lamy, Director-General of WTO in 2012 put it: “The old theories and hypotheses which governed the way we looked at trade in the twentieth century will require
better calibration with the new reality of trade in the twenty-first century.” Article available at: http://www.wto.org/english/news_e/sppl_e/sppl258_e.htm
Novák - 29
of (e.g. labor regulations, environmental protection, health care and pension systems etc.).
Today mega-trade deals seem to be used more extensively to influence
future economic, political and interstate power relations on a global scale. The
uncertainties, however, regarding the impacts of these agreements are significant
and no one can predict the future with much confidence. The economic arguments in support of TTIP (Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership) and
TPP (Trans-Pacific Partnership) seem to be based on wishful thinking – an approach that several times has biased the fair ex ante evaluations of PTAs or deeper economic cooperation (Barbee 2014: 208).
Waves of Free Trade Agreements
The underlying reasons behind the establishment of Free Trade Agreements have
been numerous since the second half of the nineteenth century when the very first
wave of such arrangements was initiated. In addition to the bilateral free trade
agreement between Great Britain and France in 1860, which involved the MFN
clause, several customs unions were also established at the time (AustriaHungary, Germany, Italy etc.) which had led to a remarkable trade liberalization,
an almost complete single market in Europe by the turn of the century, covering a
very large share of the global trade flows. Between the two World Wars a completely different international economic system emerged in which the new regional arrangements had caused trade to divert and eventually separated trade
blocks from each other and, as such, pursued inward looking, trade protectionist
policies. All such initiatives were highly preferential in the time of the Great Depression.
Although expected, economic benefits have always been one of the most
important driving forces behind the waves of regional economic integration, from
time to time, additional interests and objectives would surface. There have been
times when economic benefits were subdued to international political interests.
We witnessed an especially complex set of motives after World War II. Some of
the most important perspectives are as follows: (1) FTAs were often utilized by
larger states to intensify their economic and political influence on smaller countries. A prime example for this type of motivation is the establishment of COMECOM (Council for Mutual Economic Assistance) in order to coordinate the
economic development in Easter Europe, but it goes without saying that control
over this geographically vast economic integration was in the hands of the Soviet
Union. (2) An additional motivating force behind the birth of FTAs was the desire to reduce the collective dependence of groups of states on third parties. Typical examples include the regional initiatives between developing countries during
the fifties and the sixties in order to mitigate their vulnerability in international
economic relations against more developed regions. (3) The establishment of the
European Communities after World War II seems to be the most successful at-
Novák - 30
tempt at managing the security policy challenges posed by the Soviet Union. (4)
In other cases regional arrangements promoted and consolidated domestic economic reforms and democratic transformation. This was the case of the EU integration of Greece, Portugal, and Spain. The waves of enlargement in the European Union have demonstrated that economic integration can usefully serve as the
driving force for political cooperation and as a means of “stability export” both in
economic and political understanding.
While stronger economic ties or broader economic opportunities worked
well in developed Western European countries, economic integration and cooperation between less developed countries were less successful. By the end of the
eighties, several earlier assumptions had changed. Reforms and political transformation had taken place in many parts of the world which created a new
framework for trade agreements. In less developed countries the earlier autarchyoriented, inward-looking policies had changed. Import substitution strategies and
integrations have always faced the same burden: lack of capital, the inability to
obtain the latest technologies, and the scarcity of qualified labor force. These
countries started to become more open towards international economic (trade and
FDI) cooperation. The collapse of the Soviet Union and the economic and political changes in the Soviet space prompted a number of countries to stabilize their
internal transformation by entering the European Union. In addition, in the PostSoviet region we also witnessed several attempts by Russia to create a sort of
economic integration. In this period, the objective of small countries became increasingly centered on the need to align and integrate with a large “center” – it
was expected that several benefits may be associated with this adjustment, including the inflow of FDI, improving export performance and the stabilization of
political systems after transitioning from an autocratic regime to a democratic
one.
Changing Interstate Power Relations and the Role of FTAs
After World War II, the GATT liberalization and the establishment of preferential trade arrangements went hand in hand for several decades and they seemed to
be complementing each other. But, because of the significant changes in the
global business environment and interstate power relations recently, the two processes started to move in completely different directions. These changes had contributed to the emergence of a new wave of regional integration efforts completed
now with several novel features.
(1) In contrast to previous decades, trade liberalization in the manufacturing of goods in the multilateral framework had deepened. As a result, the potential benefits of free trade agreements stemming from the elimination of tariffs
would only make a limited impact in most cases. In other words, the Vinerian
balance of losses and benefits in terms of trade diversion and trade creation –
even in theory – should be small without additional efforts to extend the scope of
Novák - 31
the arrangements. (2) Foreign direct investments of recent years resulted in the
emergence of global value chains that strengthened multiple economic ties not
only between neighboring countries, but across regions and continents. FDI links
and relations became much more convoluted compared to previous decades (centuries) due to the new strategies of large transnational firms. (3) Some of the arrangements made since the nineties started to become deeper and deeper as they
were no longer just about tariff cuts. Non-tariff barriers were also being eliminated or other fields of economic policies were being harmonized. (4) The discrepancy between global liberalization and regional cooperation became even more
evident. Multilateral trade negotiations stalled and very little or no advancement
was made in this regard. (5) Once hailed as the most successful integration effort,
the European Union and most importantly the Eurozone were facing a series of
crises ranging from economic growth problems to income inequalities and social
hardships. (6) The shift in the global economic balance of power intensified after
the turn of the millennium and was coupled with the consequences of the economic crisis unfolding after 2008. It was against this backdrop that negotiations
of mega-regional trade agreements were started with the objective of establishing
deep integration with countries that possess overwhelming shares in global trade
and FDI and place central role in the emerging global value chains – a development that has attracted great attention in recent years from among scholars and
large international economic institutions.5
Due to these changes, the twenty and twenty first century regional trade
agreements or regional arrangements should be fundamentally different from
each other. As Richard Baldwin puts it: “[t]wentieth-century RTAs concern
‘made-here-sold-there’ goods, while 21st century regionalism concern ‘madeeverywhere-sold-there’ goods. The difference means that 21st century RTAs include rules on making goods as well as selling them” (Baldwin 2014: 5). The
mega-regional deals are increasingly thought to be motivated not simply by economic objectives, but more importantly by geopolitical considerations (or simply
by international political objectives) which is not in contradiction with the previously mentioned diverse set of motivations behind earlier trade arrangements.
Referring to more details, the following motives can be identified behind
the large objective of “geopolitics.” (1) In recent years, economic growth in the
world has been uneven. Large emerging countries have experienced rapid economic convergence led by China’s catching up in the past decade, but other states
also have shown growing influence on global economic developments and trade.
China has overtaken the US in term of its share in global GDP (it is measured at
PPP, but it is still an important development).6 As a result, the soft power of
5
See inter alia for example: Interconnected Economies. Benefiting from Global Value
Chains. OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264189560-en; or IMF 2013.
etc.
6
For most recent data see the World Economic Outlook of the IMF see
http://www.imf.org/ external/pubs/ft/weo/2014/02.
Novák - 32
emerging countries and especially that of China may challenge the soft power of
the US and the EU (Stiglitz 2015). (2) The European economy has been struggling since 2008. Lack of economic growth and emerging social problems in a
number of member states are threatening the very foundations of the EU. It
seems that we are not only dealing with temporary economic stagnation affecting
a few countries, but with a rudimentary, systemic problem, the crisis of the Eurozone. As a result, dissatisfaction among the population is increasing, domestic
political challenges are growing and future prospects are unclear.
The emergence of contemporary large deals is explained by the need to
set standards to which emerging nations should adjust if they wanted to benefit
from international economic relations with large industrialized nations. These
new trade arrangements may win some time for the current most developed countries: if these deals succeed, and emerging countries adjust, then they will follow
western rules and comply with liberal market economic principles. Economic
benefits of FTAs – and deeper cooperation – are not at all obvious today. Ex ante
and ex post analyses of FTAs also differ from each other considerably and in recent decades it has been almost impossible to separate the economic impacts of
institutionalization of cooperation (e.g. a free trade agreement) and the impacts of
overall global liberalization (Vetter 2013: 3). While geopolitical motives may be
important from the perspectives of the launching and negotiating mega-regional
trade agreements, these considerations are insufficient to implement them in a
long term sustainable way. In other words, “TTIP at its core is an economic negotiation that in the end will stand or fall on its economic merits” (Hamilton
2014: VII).7
Many decision makers and analysts view the emergence of these agreements as a tool to influence interstate power relations – an approach that seems to
be similar to the race during the Cold War between the West and the East. According to this perspective, the changing economic realities may be influenced by
building blocks that are unified by the unlimited liberalization of economic flows
and regulation. This way the free trade agreements may serve as a means to
strengthen political alliances with long term partners in the developed world.
Building blocks also seem to follow the logic of the interwar period. An important difference from the interwar period is the existence of the WTO, a multilateral institution that may mitigate the risks associated with building blocks –
provided it can function properly. If not, the future of international economic relations and the prospects depend on the reaction of large emerging countries currently not participating in the negotiations.
Here an interesting theoretical notion put forward by Paul Krugman is
worth considering. According to Krugman, if a country with PTA tries to use its
power to influence global trends; this may lead to disastrous consequences if oth7
A recent paper argues that official studies do not offer a solid basis for an informed decision on TTIP. See Capaldo 2014.
Novák - 33
er similar agreements are in place because “the blocs may beggar each other.
That is, the formation of blocs can, in effect, set off a beggar-all trade war that
leaves everyone worse off” (Krugman 1991: 8). According to him, these negative
impacts may only be minimized if trade blocks are few or if there is a very large
number of such arrangements. If there is only one block, then it is global free
trade. He argues that “world welfare is minimized for a world of three trading
blocs” (Krugman 1991: 12). If we consider this, it is remarkable that the share of
TTIP and TPP in terms of global GDP and global trade is over fifty percent (excluding the double counting of the US). From this perspective, the idea of RCEP
(Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership) may attract greater attention in
the future.
Options and Conclusions
If the US led mega-deals fail, it will hurt the image and leadership of advanced
countries in international trade issues in favor of emerging nations, most importantly China. If the deals are successful, developed countries will get additional leadership by setting norms and regulations for large segments of international trade flows (Dube 2014: 17). Taking into account the above considerations, the most important question concerns the response of third countries, especially large emerging countries having a major role in formulating global shifts
and changes. The basic strategies are the following.
1. Wait and see. There are a lot of uncertainties surrounding these deals
especially the TTIP because of the widely different opinions within the European
Union. Most critics are focusing on the ISDS (Investor State Dispute Settlement),
environmental protections or GMO (Genetic Modified Organisms) products. For
third countries, it is reasonable to wait and see what the final outcome of the
agreements concerned will be. The external situation and the negotiation positions may change significantly. It cannot be ruled out that significant concessions
and compromises will be the only solution for consolidating these diverging interests. Just to mention one issue: probably it would be reasonable to abandon the
ISDS in its current form in TTIP negotiations given the very negative opinions
and sentiments of a wide circle of stakeholders.8
2. Disengagement from global trade liberalization. If multilateral trade
negotiations are blocked because of internal conflicts (between advanced and
emerging states) then several countries may become even more disinterested in
international trade liberalization. Mega-trade deals coupled with slow progress in
multilateral trade negotiations could easily result in developing inward-looking
or more protectionist policies in several countries.
8
Among many other proposals see for example: Congressional Financial Services Committee leaders: Exclude ISDS from US-EU deal http://www.bilaterals.org/?congressionalfinancial-services&lang=en#sthash.Q9Kwk01h.dpuf.
Novák - 34
3. Unilateral significant liberalization of excluded countries. This would
serve as a means to mitigate the trade diversion impacts due to mega-deals. Although it is not very likely, theoretically we can construct a framework where outside countries with large liberalization or adjustment efforts can simply eliminate
most of the advantages of the participants in mega-trade deals while preserving
some independence in their regulatory framework (World Economic Forum
2014: 28-29).
4. Joining mega-deals. This is the same strategy that was followed by
mostly smaller countries in earlier decades when they considered it their interest
to swiftly adjust to the rules defined by larger countries. This is a quite reasonable strategy for small states with insufficient domestic factors of production to
boost growth. The situation may be different for large countries, but even in their
case, bilateral negotiations of a certain kind with the EU or the US may be feasible. In fact, this would be the best scenario for advanced nations since this would
mean that large emerging countries are willing to adjust to the rules set by the US
and the EU. As a result the rule setter and rule taker position would not change
much globally.
5. Trade war by establishing new trading blocks. Although trade between
large outside countries is somehow limited mostly for geographical reasons, theoretically, the establishment of other trade deals with the participation of large
countries and nations from the African continent, Far Eastern and South American countries cannot be ruled out. China, India, Indonesia, Russia, Brazil and
Nigeria altogether make up almost 45 percent of the global population. If we accept that mega FTAs currently negotiated are more and more driven by political
and strategic interests and not only by economic ones, the establishment of alternative competing arrangements may be a realistic option.
6. Revitalization of the WTO.As stated in the World Economic Forum
(2014), “[i]f the RTAs and their power asymmetries take over, there is a risk that
the GATT/WTO would go down in future history books as a 70-year experiment
where world trade was rules based instead of power-based” (27). Something similar happened to the IMF before the economic crisis of 2008. Current perspectives for larger engagement of WTO in global trade talks are low. Hopes, however, are realistic given the small steps taken in the Bali ministerial meeting, which
were celebrated loudly. In fact, for the time being, these small agreements saved
the WTO from falling into oblivion. Its future existence is still not based on
strong foundations. The role of IMF in global affairs was revalued due to the
economic crisis. If mega-deals fall short of expectations, the WTO can still serve
as an instrument of global cooperation in international trade.
References
Baldwin, Richard. 2014. Multilateralising 21st Century Regionalism. Paris:
OECD Conference Centre.
Novák - 35
Barbee, Inu and Lester, Simon. 2014. “The TPP and the Future of Trade Agreements.” Latin American Journal of International Trade Law, Vol. 2, Issue
1, pp. 207-225.
Capaldo, Jeronim. 2014. The Trans-Atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership.
European Disintegration, Unemployment and Instability. Global Development and Environment Institute Working Paper No. 14-03.
Draper, Peter and Lacey, Simon and Ramkolowan, Yash. 2014. Mega-Regional
Trade Agreements: Implications for the African, Caribbean, And Pacific
Countries. Ecipe Occasional Paper. No. 2/2014.
Dube, Memory and Draper, Peter. 2014. “Mega-Regional Trade Negotiations:
Implications for Emerging Atlantic Economies,” in Atlantic Currents. An
Annual Report on Wider Atlantic Perspectives and Patterns. Washinton
DC.: The German Marshall Fund of the United States and OCP Policy
Center.
Hamilton, Daniel S. (ed.). 2014. The Geopolitics of TTIP. Repositioning the
Transatlantic Relationship for a Changing World. Washington DC.:
Center for Transatlantic RelationsPaul H. Nitze School of Advanced International Studies, Johns Hopkins University.
Krugman, Paul. 1991. “The Move to Free Trade Zones.” Economic review. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank. November, pp. 5-25.
Lawrence, Robert Z. 1996. Regionalism, Multilateralism, and Deeper Integra
tion. Washington, D.C.: Brookings.
Mansfeld, Edward D. and Milner, Helen V. 1999. “The New Wave of Regionalism.” International Organizations, 53 3, Summer, 589-627.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2015. “The Chinese Century.” Vanity Fair 2015/1, accessed
at: http://www.vanityfair.com/business/2015/01/china-worlds-largesteconomy.
Vetter, Stefan. 2013. The Single European Market. 20 Years on Achievements,
Unfulfilled Expectations & Further Potential. Frankfurt and Main:
Deutsche Bank AG, DB Research.
World Economic Forum. 2014. Mega-regional Trade Agreements. GameChangers or Costly Distractions for the World Trading System? Report
of the Global Agenda Council on Trade & Foreign Direct Investment.
Trade in Higher Education Services
in the TTIP Negotiations and Beyond
Beverly Barrett
University of Houston
Abstract
The unprecedented growth of trade in services over recent years reflects the
composition of the contemporary knowledge economy, in which countries seek a
balance between international cooperation and national competitiveness. Given
the opportunity to further liberalize international trade this paper explains the
negotiating parties’ interests in higher education services within the context of
the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP). This research analyzes how trade in higher education services may be addressed in ongoing negotiations, given the preexisting trade frameworks, and it draws conclusions comparing the interests of countries in Europe and the U.S. to participate in regional integration initiatives for higher education services.
Introduction
The growth of trade in services reflects the composition of the contemporary
knowledge economy, in which partner countries seek a balance between international cooperation and national competitiveness. The United States (U.S.) and
the European Union (EU) are historical trading partners, and they enjoy the largest trade and investment relationship in the world. Given the opportunity to further liberalize international trade this paper explains the negotiating parties’ interests in higher education services within the context of the Transatlantic Trade
and Investment Partnership (TTIP). This research analyzes how trade in higher
education services may or may not be addressed in ongoing negotiations, given
the preexisting trade frameworks, particularly the General Agreement on Trade
in Services (GATS) originally negotiated by the World Trade Organization
(WTO) in 1995. This paper draws conclusions comparing the interest of countries in Europe and the U.S. to participate in regional integration initiatives for
higher education services. The potential inclusion for private education in ongoing trade negotiations is still obscure, and the scarcity of public information may
be a reason for reserved interest in this sector. Public education is not open for
trade liberalization as stated in the GATS.
Given the importance of the services sector in trade agreements, international trade governance has the potential to intersect with higher education poli-
Barrett - 38
cies across countries. This research examines the place of trade in higher education services in Europe and the U.S. in reference to the formal negotiating trade
frameworks. Specifically within the EU, there is uncertainty since the education
sector is not explicitly excluded in the Services Directive, which was adopted in
late 2006 to simplify the provision of business services in the Single Market. At
this time, it is not clear whether higher education services will be part of the
TTIP or related negotiations. An analysis of the foregoing treatment of trade in
services in previously negotiated agreements serves as an important guidepost for
future considerations. International market access for higher education services
and mutual recognition of professional qualifications are two key areas in the
negotiations that are considered in this research.
Recent and Ongoing Mega-Trade Negotiations
Since 2001, the leading associations of higher education in the U.S., Canada, and
Europe have taken the position that their member institutions were committed,
“to reducing obstacles to international trade in higher education using conventions and agreements outside of a trade policy regime” (Joint Declaration 2001).1
The TTIP was announced in the spring of 2013, with the first formal negotiations
taking place from July 8 to 12 in Washington, D.C. Alongside these negotiations
are important developments in multilateral trade. The Trade in Services Agreement (TiSA) is being negotiated with more than 23 members of the WTO, which
comprise 70 percent of global trade in services (European Commission 2015).
The TiSA negotiations, for which the EU countries are represented as one of the
negotiating members, were launched in 2012. The Comprehensive Economic and
Trade Agreement (CETA) was announced by the EU and Canada on October 28,
2013. The CETA may be considered as a prototype for an even larger potential
agreement of the TTIP, and the CETA is expected to increase two-way trade by
23 percent or 26 billion euro (EUA 2014a:9). The Trans-Pacific Partnership
(TPP) has also run ahead of the TTIP negotiations, and the TPP is among twelve
countries in the Pacific Rim. Like CETA, the TPP serves as background to the
TTIP and TiSA negotiations. The TPP negotiations formally began in November
2011, among the U.S. and countries in the Trans-Pacific Strategic Economic
Partnership.
These transatlantic negotiations must be understood in the context of EU
and U.S. trade policies, and in accordance with rules in the WTO. A final TTIP
agreement would be composed of three parts: Market Access, Regulatory Cooperation, and Rules (European Commission 2015a). There are four Modes in negotiations for the supply of services in the GATS and the proposed TTIP, which
1
These leading higher education associations are the American Council on Education
(ACE), Association of Universities and Colleges of Canada (AUCC), Council for Higher
Education Accreditation (CHEA), and European University Association (EUA).
Barrett - 39
are: 1. Cross border supply, 2. Consumption abroad, 3. Commercial presence,
and 4. Presence of natural persons. Higher education services and professionally
mobility policies are considered as part of Mode 4. An electronic educational
service may be considered as part of Mode 1, and the presence on an international campus as part of Mode 3. The EU Member States have already liberalized
many services in the framework of the GATS. The schedules for service liberalization in the TTIP, TiSA, CETA and other recent free trade negotiations are informed by the criteria that negotiators refer to as "GATS-plus." Therefore the
current negotiations of the TTIP and TiSA must build upon concessions already
made in the GATS schedule. It is important to note that in the GATS public services are excluded, which means that public services from state higher education
institutions are excluded from negotiations (EUA 2014 2:4).
Whether the TTIP negotiations lead to liberalization of market access in
higher education services is a key question as the negotiations develop (EUA
2014a). Education is closely tied to national identity, and an identity is political
(Checkel and Katzenstein 2009). In the EU, the balance between national and
regional identity is a delicate equilibrium. Therefore, it is expected that the balance between the state role and a supranational role in higher education and research will be a sensitive public policy issue within the region and across the
transatlantic. Policy diffusion throughout the region has gained momentum over
recent decades (Börzel and Risse 2012). This regional diffusion has been replicated across continents. As Europe has led with regional integration since postWorld War II, starting with economic integration, it is also leading with integration of the knowledge economy (European Commission 1997). The knowledge
economy is composed of higher education services together with research and
innovation policies. The European Union has policies in each area, though education has remained a national competency as delineated in the Maastricht Treaty,
effective November 1, 1993.2
The Lisbon Treaty, effective December 1, 2009, specifies further how
the EU may contribute to the quality of education by encouraging cooperation
across member states.3 While education remains a national competency support2
Treaty of Maastricht signed February 7, 1992 stated in Chapter 3, Article 126, “The
Community shall contribute to the development of quality education by encouraging cooperation between Member States and, if necessary, by supporting and supplementing
their action, while fully respecting the responsibility of the Member States for the content
of teaching and the organization of education systems and their cultural and linguistic
diversity.”
3
The Lisbon Treaty signed December 13, 2007 stated in Article 165, Part 3, Title XII
how the EU may support education,3 as it “shall contribute to the development of quality
education by encouraging cooperation between Member States and, if necessary, by supporting and supplementing their action, while fully respecting the responsibility of the
Member States for the content of teaching and the organization of education systems and
their cultural and linguistic diversity.”
Barrett - 40
ed by the EU, there has been an increased supranational effort in regional cooperation in higher education. Given the global competition in the knowledge society, the EU has taken an increasingly active role in higher education and research
policies. Shared political, economic, and cultural values have resulted in the unprecedented higher education cooperation to create the European Higher Education Area (EHEA), the largest academic mobility initiative in the world. The Bologna Process was initiated in 1999 and established the objectives for the EHEA,
in which the European Commission is a partner alongside 47 sovereign states.
Recognition of the trends of economic globalization, together with internationalization of universities, drives the Bologna Process (Nokkola 2007:223). The European Commission plays a central role in higher education cooperation, supporting the advances in regional integration of this sector thus far. It represents the
interests of the 28 EU member states, and it serves as a facilitating institution for
higher education policy.
Comparatively in the U.S., higher education governance remains institution-centered rather than state-centered in its policy making, and in the U.S.
institutions are accredited by regional peer review associations. In Europe this
accreditation is given from national qualification agencies, in relationship with
the European Association for Quality Assurance (ENQA) in Brussels, Belgium. While in the U.S. peer higher education institution associations accredit
their fellow member institutions (U.S. Dept. of Ed. 2015). In the U.S. the public sector has an important role at the sub-national level among the fifty states
to contribute substantively to financing public universities.
Europe and the United States: Trade in Services and Higher Education
These trade liberalization efforts align with the negotiating parties’ strategic interests. Expanding higher education access and quality, and improving the quality
of the workforce are objectives across countries. The European Commission’s
Europe 2020 economic growth strategy has objectives for higher education
alongside employment, innovation, social cohesion, and environmental sustainability. There have been eight negotiating round meetings since July 2013, with
the most recent being in early February 2015 (USTR 2015). Trade in higher education services is not specifically excluded from the negotiations, according to
US and EU negotiators (EUA 2014 2:4, 3:8). While the EU has the exclusive
competency for the Single Market, and the related Services Directive, it supports
the member states in their competency for higher education policy. There exists
ambiguity on the relevance of the education sector within the Services Directive
for the common market.
Seventy percent of employment in the U.S. is in the services sector (CRS
2014:14). Measured from the year 2000, there is an increasingly positive trend in
trade in services between the U.S and the EU. Trade in services exports reached
$200 billion dollars in 2012, nearly double the level from 2000. Trade in services
Barrett - 41
imports demonstrated another double increase to nearly $150 billion in 2012
(Akhtar and Jones 2014: 14). Except for a slight downturn during the global recession years from 2008 to 2009, trade in services continues on an upward trajectory.
The distinction between the public sector and the private sector in delivering higher educational services is necessary to delineate for the applicability of
future negotiated agreements. As the GATS rules hold in the TTIP negotiations,
in the GATS public services are excluded, which means public sector higher education institutions. Therefore current and future questions center on the place of
private sector higher education and adult education institutions in trade agreements. Stakeholders have concern for how higher education would be treated as
tradable service, if included in future trade agreements.
Market Access to Higher Education and Mutual Recognition of Professional
Qualifications
Taking into account how higher education is considered in various international
trade forums, the GATS addresses twelve service areas, one of which is education. International market access for higher education services and mutual recognition of professional qualifications are two areas where ongoing policy developments are important for higher education services. Content analysis of recently
negotiated agreements provides information about potential content within in the
ongoing TTIP and TiSA negotiations. The CETA addresses mutual recognition
of professional qualifications, and the TiSA is negotiating the short-term professional mobility of service providers (EUA 2014 3:18). In addition, “A Committee
on Mutual Recognition of Professional Qualifications shall also be established
under the Committee on Services and Investment and shall report to that Committee” (CETA 2014:448). The Committee may advise on a Mutual Recognition
Agreement (MRA) or otherwise. In the CETA all professions may be considered
to be part of a MRA. Comparably in the TTIP, only specified professions will be
included in a potential MRA (EUA 2014 3:10). The European Services Forum
(ESF) supports market access to the U.S. by European professional service providers, and the fields for which it advocates for mutual recognition are accounting, architecture, engineering, and legal services (EUA 2014 2:6). Potentially
challenging in the future would be recognition in the U.S. where the fifty states
have unique responsibility for accreditation across professional fields. The lead
U.S. Trade Representative negotiator, Dan Mullaney, for his side, affirmed discussions regarding the professional mobility of architects and engineers (EUA 3
2014:10).
In market access, the exporting country has the responsibility for quality,
and the importing country is not allowed to intervene, according to the Services
Directive. This is contrary to the GATS, which allowed the importing states to
establish quality assurance and accreditation systems that were non-
Barrett - 42
discriminatory (Amaral 2014:16). These inconsistences between the EU Services
Directive and the GATS, regarding exporting and importing countries’ responsibilities in higher education are issues to be addressed in future trade legislation.
The Services Directive supports the Single Market established with the Maastricht Treaty by simplifying business procedures for service providers, and it is
an assertive action taken by the EU to extend the liberalization of services to education. The European Parliament and the European Council adopted the Services Directive on December 2006, and it was fully implemented by the member
states within three years. The treatment of higher education is ambiguous because
the Services Directive does not specifically exclude education broadly, even
though national education systems are excluded. Some explicitly excluded sectors are environment, gambling, health, public health, and security. The Directive
excludes the “Services of General Interest” (SGI), but includes the “Services of
General Economic Interest” (SGEI), and it is difficult to define education in the
appropriate category, particularly since there is no legal basis for their definition
(Amaral 2014:14).
The TTIP considers how professional recognition may be actualized
across participating countries. This makes an extension upon the objectives of the
Bologna Process, for recognition of academic degrees across the 47 participating
countries, to an even greater extent with the intention to ensure professional
recognition intercontinentally (European Commission 2015c). The European
countries and the United States are the largest markets for higher education as a
destination. In Europe the educational exchange program of Erasmus, provided
by the European Commission since 1986, has facilitated international trade in
educational services. Various international education programs, partially supported and monitored by the Institute of International Education (IIE), in the U.S.
are affiliated with the Bureau of Educational and Cultural Affairs (ECA) within
the Department of State. The relationship of higher education to research and
innovation is strong in the promotion of the mobility of students, scholars, and
graduates for employability. The mobility of higher education for coursework
and for research and development (R&D), and professional employment are
complementary and together may be addressed comprehensively. The Congressional Research Service (CRS) has found that:
The treatment of services providers could be another area of focus in
the TTIP negotiations. One issue that the TTIP could address is the licensing and certification of professional services providers. Appropriate credentials are required on both sides of the Atlantic in many fields
such as medicine, insurance, education, and law. In the EU, such services are regulated by the member states, and, in the United States, at
the state level. Thus, providing cross-border services could be challenging for services firms, because even if a services employee is qualified
in one state or EU country, the certification may not be recognized
elsewhere (Akhtar and Jones 2014:14).
Barrett - 43
The European Students Union (ESU) has taken the formal position that it
does not welcome U.S. higher education institutions having open access to the
European higher education market. Similar to the position of the higher education
institutions in the Joint Declaration, this stakeholder would like to limit market
access. Like the audiovisual sector has been taken off the negotiating table, with
pressure from France in particular for cultural protection, the ESU advocates that
higher education access not be a policy issue for negotiations (TTIP ‘threatens’
quality 2014). On market access issues there are stakeholders in higher education
institutions that would like to protect national priority. On mutual recognition of
professional qualifications there are fewer reservations, while national preferences continue to remain strong.
Conclusions
The treatment of higher education services in the GATS has been limited. The
ongoing negotiation of the TTIP and TiSA open possibilities for inclusion of
provisions to liberalize higher education services in the private sector only (since
the public sector services are protected from trade agreements). In the knowledge
economy, higher education services and research innovation gain momentum
from regional and global initiatives to support internationalization. The foregoing
negotiations processes demonstrate the politically important issue areas for attention. The higher education services have not yet been comprehensively addressed
in negotiations. The negotiated trade agreements must be approved by the legislature of each negotiating partner. In the case of the EU, each member state has an
effective veto through the European Parliament. The Lisbon Treaty granted this
institutional authority and veto power over trade agreements to the legislative
body. The U.S. President has not received “fast-track” or Trade Promotion Authority (TPA) from the Congress, which expired in 2007 in the presidency of
George W. Bush. Without the domestic political will these agreements will not
come becomes finalized.
The higher education associations, such as the EUA and its US and Canadian counterparts, and some student stakeholders, concerned with educational
quality represented by the ESU, have advocated to exclude private higher education providers from market access in the agreements. Higher education historically has been of high sensitivity politically. Therefore, stakeholder associations will
pressure national governments to support measures to protect national higher education institutions from what may be viewed as unfair external competition.
There is a distinction between higher education and adult education (or posthigher education) services in the GATS and in the TTIP, as legislation becomes
crafted each may be treated separately. Looking to the future, the extent of TTIP
provisions for education services in market access and mutual recognition of professional qualifications will be highly relevant to the sector.
Barrett - 44
The mega-regional trade and investment agreements strategically seek to
balance a rising Asian presence, led by China, in international trade. They are a
hybrid of regional arrangements and the WTO arrangement, except they do not
include major emerging markets that will dominate world trade in the future,
namely China, India, and Indonesia (Dadush 2015). As these trade agreements
progress, there are risks that developing countries may be sidelined, given their
challenges in matching the regulatory standards requirements (Dadush 2015).
The higher education systems of developing countries are vulnerable to dominance from developed countries’ negotiations (EUA 2014a:9). Negotiating common regulatory standards is more challenging than negotiating tariff reductions,
given strong national prerogatives in traditionally sensitive areas such as agriculture, and in more recently considered areas such as education services.
This analysis has presented an overview of ongoing trade negotiations in
services, specifically for the TTIP alongside the CETA and the TiSA. With an
emphasis on market access and mutual recognition of professional qualifications
in services, the ongoing negotiations will continue to face challenges from stakeholders in the higher education sector that seek to protect this sensitive area from
market access. At this time it is not clear how the private sector providers of
higher education, such as through private institutions abroad and through online
degrees, may be treated in future trade agreements. The public sector service
providers are protected from liberalization through the GATS rules. The dual
purposes of education, to enhance social cohesion and to prepare for employability, are brought into the foreground as nations assess their willing to cooperate
across national boundaries in formal trade agreements. Leading associations of
higher education in the transatlantic community have said, “Higher education
exists to serve the public interest and is not a ‘commodity’,” in affirming their
members’ interests not to pursue further liberalization of the higher education
sector (Joint Declaration 2001). Therefore, any further concessions in the area of
higher education policy are advised to proceed with caution. As has been noted,
there are already avenues for higher education exchange independent of formal
trade agreement frameworks. The place for higher education policy in the expanding economic integration through international trade agreements is still being determined. This analysis has addressed the historical challenges for higher
education services considered as a component of international trade agreements.
References
Amaral, Alberto. 2014. “Cross Border Education: A New Business?” Higher
Education as Commerce: Cross Border Education and the Services Directi-ve. A3ES and CIPES conference Porto, Portugal, October 9-11,
2014.
Amaral, Alberto and Guy Neave. 2008. “On Process, Progress, Success and
Methodology or the Unfolding of the Bologna Process as it Appears to
Barrett - 45
Two Reasonably Benign Observers”, Higher Education Quarterly
62(1/2), 40-62.
Akhtar, Shayerah Ilias and Vivian C. Jones. 2014. “Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) Negotiations.” Congressional Research
Service (CRS) R43387. February 4, 2014.
Batory, Agnes and Nicole Lindstrom. 2011. “The Power of the Purse: Supranational Entrepreneurship, Financial Incentives, and European Higher Education Policy”, Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions, 24(2), 311-329.
Börzel, Tanja A. and Thomas Risse. 2012. “From Europeanisation to Diffusion:
Introduction,” West European Politics 35:1, 1-19.
Checkel, Jeffrey and Peter Katzenstein. 2009. European Identity. New York: Oxford University Press.
Corbett, Anne. 2005. Universities and the Europe of Knowledge: Ideas, Institutions and Policy Entrepreneurship in European Union Higher Education
1955-2005. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.
Comprehensive Economic Trade Agreement (CETA). 2014. Text from October
18, 2013 announcement, accessed at:
http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2014/september/tradoc_152806.pdf.
Dadush, Uri. 2015. Convergence and Divergence in Mega-Regional Trade and
Investment Agreements. Remarks at American University. January 26,
2015.
European Commission. 1997. Towards a Europe of Knowledge. COM (97) 563
Final. Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, the Economic and Social Committee and the Committee
of the Regions. November 12, 1997.
European Commission. 2015a. Trade Policy: EU negotiating texts in TTIP, accessed at: http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/press/index.cfm?id=1230.
European Commission. 2015b. Trade in Services Agreement (TiSA), accessed at:
http://ec.europa.eu/trade/policy/in-focus/tisa/
European Commission. 2015c. The Bologna Process: Setting up the European
Higher Education Area, accessed at:
Barrett - 46
http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/education_training_youth/lifelon
g_learning/c11088_en.htm.
European University Association (EUA). 2014a. Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP). EUA Background Paper, January 2014.
European University Association (EUA). 2014 1, 2, and 3. Work Policy Areas:
International Trade Agreements. Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership (TTIP). Update no. 1, April 2014; Update no. 2, August
2014, Update no. 3, December 2014, accessed at:
http://www.eua.be/eua-work-and-policy-area/building-the-europeanhigher-education-area/international-trade-agreements.aspx.
Joint Declaration on Higher Education and the General Agreement on Trade in
Services (GATS). 2001. American Council on Education (ACE), Association of Universities and Colleges of Canada (AUCC), Council for Higher Education Accreditation (CHEA), and European University Association (EUA). September 28, 2001, accessed at:
http://www.aic.lv/rec/Eng/new_d_en/gats/jointdec.html.
Mexico, Government of. 2014. “Welcome Ceremony for Pacific Alliance Scholarship Students.” Press Release 342. Mexico City, August 1, 2014.
Nokkala, Terhi. 2007. “The Bologna Process and the Role of Higher Education:
Discursive Construction of the European Higher Education Area.” In
Jürgen Enders and Ben Jongbloed (Eds.), Public-Private Dynamics in
Higher Education: Expectations, Developments and Outcomes. Piscataway: Transaction Publishers, 221-245.
Oppenheimer, Andrés. 2012. “New ‘Pacific Alliance’ Bloc May Have a Chance.”
Miami Herald. June 11, 2012.
Spring, Joel. 2009. Globalization of Education: An Introduction. New York:
Routledge.
TTIP ‘threatens’ European education quality, teachers say. 2014. Euractiv.
March 17, 2014, accessed at: http://www.euractiv.com/trade/ttipthreatens-european-educatio-news-534162
U.S. Department of Education. 2015. Accreditation in the U.S.: Specialized Accrediting Agencies, accessed at:
http://www2.ed.gov/admins/finaid/accred/accreditation_pg7.html#Nation
alInstitutional.
Barrett - 47
U.S. Trade Representative (USTR). 2015. Readouts from TTIP Negotiating
Rounds, accessed at: https://ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-tradeagreements/transatlantic-trade-and-investment-partnership/readouts.
Verger, Antoni and Javier Pablo Hermo. 2010. “The governance of higher education regionalisation: comparative analysis of the Bologna Process and
MercoSur‐Educativo.” Globalisation, Societies and Education, 8(1), 105120.
World Trade Organization (WTO). 2015. General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), accessed at:
http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/serv_e/gatsintr_e.htm.
The Price of Energy and its Impact on the Economies of the
United States and Eurozone
María Lorca-Susino
University of Miami
Abstract
Economic history teaches that the price of oil matters because it has a severe and
direct impact on the economic performance of countries. The data shows that
every recession in the Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD) countries in the last 50 years was preceded by a sharp rise in the
price of oil. The world suffered an exorbitant increase in the price of oil (WTI
Crude, real) during the summer of 2008, hitting US$144.64 per barrel. Months
later, a painful worldwide economic slowdown took place. Thus, the United
States learned that it must work hard towards energy independence to break this
correlation between high oil prices and economic recession. While the United
States is working towards finding some energy independence, most countries in
the Eurozone are oil and gas dependent. As the United States and the EU are
about to finalize the Trans-Atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership, the economic performance of both blocks, particularly the Eurozone member states, will
be largely determined by the price of crude oil and the price of the U.S. dollar.
Introduction
Economic history teaches that the price of oil matters because it has a severe and
direct impact on the economic performance of countries. Rising oil prices is
equivalent to a tax increase which leads to a significant slowdown in economic
activity.
The data shows that every recession in the Organization for Economic
Co-Operation and Development (OECD) countries in the last 50 years was preceded by a sharp rise in the price of oil. Curiously, these increases in the price of
oil were the result of armed conflicts. In fact, the four major armed conflicts of
recent years can be linked directly or indirectly to the supply of oil and were immediately followed by economic slowdowns:1 the First Oil Crisis of October of
1973, the Second Oil Crisis of January 1979, the First Gulf War in August 1990,
1
It is not the purpose of this article to elaborate on the nuts and bolts of the relationship
between conflict, oil price and economic slowdown per se. That might be the topic of a
future article.
Lorca - 50
and the Iraq War, or Second Gulf War, of March 2003. Furthermore, the world
suffered an exorbitant increase in the price of oil (WTI Crude, real) during the
summer of 2008, hitting US$144.64 per barrel, and making many wonder if the
world was facing another oil crisis . This episode was followed months later by a
painful worldwide economic slowdown, inflation, increase of unemployment,
and political instability with after-effects that will last for decades.
The U.S. economy is recovering from the Great Recession, but most
countries in the Eurozone and the European Union (EU) are still seeking a way
out. Furthermore, the United States has learned it must work hard towards energy independence to break this correlation between high oil prices and economic
recession. For this reason, the U.S. has been looking for ways to be energy selfsufficient. Between 2005 and 2010 the country's shale-gas industry grew by
45percent per year.
Following the historic high of July 2008, the price of WTI-Crude real
plunged to US$43 in February 2009; reached a high of US$115 in April 2011;
and has been falling ever since. As a consequence, OPEC members are very
nervous, and the drop of the price in oil had especially impacted the economies
of countries such as Saudi Arabia and Venezuela.
Source: MacroTrends. http://www.macrotrends.net/1369/crude-oil-price-historychart
While the United States is working towards finding some energy independence, most countries in the Eurozone are oil and gas dependent. The United
States and the EU are about to finalize the Trans-Atlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership and the economic performance of both blocks, particularly the Eurozone member states, will be largely determined by the price of crude oil and the
price of the U.S. dollar.
Lorca - 51
The Price of Energy: Winners and Losers
The price of oil surged from US$16 per barrel in December 1998 to the all-time
high of US$144 in June of 2008. When the price of oil broke the all-time high of
$140 per barrel on Thursday, June 26, 2008, the Organization of the Petroleum
Exporting Countries (OPEC) predicted that the price of oil would range between
$150 and $170 per barrel in the years to come (Nasseri and Brown 2008). This
extraordinarily high price had a detrimental impact on an already fragile world
economy, forcing governments to work desperately to find ways of reducing the
high energy bill for their economies and people. In fact, these efforts resulted in
an important drop in the price of energy in the United States and a positive impact on the U.S. economy.
Since June 2014, crude oil prices have plunged 30 percent, causing alarm
among the OPEC member states (Zhou 2014). The OPEC members met on
Thanksgiving Day of 2014 to analyze the state of the oil market, which has been
suffering from what some are calling a “global oil glut” due to soaring production in the United States and lackluster demand from struggling economies
around the world. The announcement that followed the meeting stated that OPEC
would maintain oil production at 30 million barrels per day (Hirst 2014) – despite
the objections of desperate members such as Venezuela that wanted a production
cut in order to increase prices. This automatically caused the price of oil to spiral
into a terrific plunge. During that Thanksgiving Day meeting in Vienna, the oil
ministers from OPEC members agreed to live with the effects of the U.S. “fracking” boom and let the markets sort it out (Cooke 2014). They believed that if the
OPEC cuts output to raise the price of oil, it would lose market share. The way to
win this energy war was to allow overproduction to depress prices to the point
where cheap OPEC oil could destroy the profitability of North American producers and force the United States to cut production. Had OPEC maintained prices at
$40 or $50 a barrel, “fracking” would not have become so widespread in the
United States. This time, OPEC is changing this traditional “modus operandi” by
trying to depress oil prices to fight a shale gas revolution that is threatening to
make the OPEC irrelevant.
The case of the OPEC member Venezuela is particularly significant
(Dielh 2014). The drop in the price of oil is having a dangerous impact on the
economy of the country. On November 18, 2014 President Nicolas Maduro ordered $4 billion in loan proceeds from China to be transferred from an off-budget
fund to one counted in the country's international reserves. However, Venezuela
had burned through one third of the Chinese money in one week (Kurmanaev
2014). If the prices do not rise in the short term, the country is heading for default.
Lorca - 52
The Business Cycle and the Price of Crude Oil in the United States and Eurozone: FTAA Impact
In the international petroleum industry, crude oil products are traded on various
oil bourses based on (1) established chemical profiles, (2) delivery locations, and
(3) financial terms. 2 The three most quoted oil products are North America's
West Texas Intermediate crude (WTI), North Sea Brent Crude, and the UAE Dubai Crude.
There are 46 oil exporting countries but the prices of these three oil
products are used as a barometer for the entire petroleum industry. Historically,
all three have traded closely but Brent Crude is typically priced at about $2 over
the WTI Spot price, which is typically priced $5 to $6 above the OPEC Basket
prices as shown in the graph below.
Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration, “Price difference between
Brent
and
WTI
crude
oil
narrowing,”
June
28,
2013.
http://www.eia.gov/todayinener gy/detail.cfm?id=11891
The following graph, with more details on the evolution of spot prices for
WTI, Brent and Dubai/Oman, shows how the price of each company has dropped
significantly while the spread has almost disappeared, both anomalies in this
market.
2
For a detailed guide on the many different types of crude oil visit www.Oilprice.com,
accessed at: http://oilprice.com/Energy/Crude-Oil/A-Detailed-Guide-on-the-Many-Diffe
rent-Types-of-Crude-Oil.html
Lorca - 53
Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration, “Benchmarks play an important
role
in
pricing
crude
oil.”
October
28,
2014
.http://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/de tail.cfm?id=18571
West Texas Intermediate (WTI) or Texas light sweet is a grade of crude
oil used as a benchmark in oil pricing. Brent Crude is a major trading classification of sweet light crude oil that serves as a major benchmark price for purchases
of oil worldwide. Brent Crude is extracted from the North Sea and comprises
Brent Blend, Forties Blend, Oseberg and Ekofisk crudes. 3 Brent is the leading
global price benchmark for Atlantic basin crude oils. It is used to price two thirds
of the world's internationally traded crude oil supplies. The OPEC Reference
Basket (ORB), also referred to as the OPEC Basket, is a weighted average of
prices for petroleum blends produced by OPEC countries. It is used as an important benchmark for crude oil prices. 4 On 15 June 2005, the OPEC basket was
changed to reflect the characteristics of the oil produced by OPEC members. The
Reference Basket currently consists of a weighted average of the following
blends of oil: Saharan Blend from Algeria, Ecuador, Iran Heavy from Islamic
Republic of Iran, Basra Light from Iraq, Kuwait Export from Kuwait, Es Sider
from Libya, Bonny Light from Nigeria, Qatar Marine from Qatar, Arab Light
3
Vantage Point. “Brent crude trading”, Trader Tech, accessed at http://www.tradertech
.com/trading/brent-crude
4
Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries. “OPEC basket price”, accessed at
http://www.opec.org/opec_web/en/data_graphs/40.htm
Lorca - 54
from Saudi Arabia, Murban from UAE, BCF 17 from Venezuela, Girassol from
Angola.5
The barrel of oil is priced in U.S. dollars, which has a number of consequences. First, countries other than the United States have to engage in foreign
exchange transactions to buy U.S. dollars to pay for oil. Second, oil producing
countries receive billions of dollars every day, depending on the price per barrel
and the value of the U.S. dollar. Thus, changes in the price of oil will be felt either on the producers’ or on the buyers’ side (Lorca-Susino 2008).
From 2001 to the summer of 2011, the price of oil was extraordinarily
high, and the value of the U.S. dollar against major currencies was very low.
More specifically, during this period of time, the U.S. dollar depreciated against
the euro while the price of energy was on the rise. In summary, the U.S. dollar
Index has been depreciating significantly while the price of oil has been increasing, as shown in the following graph.
Oil-WTI Crude
Dollar Index
Source: Macrotrends, “Dollar, Gold and Oil Chart - Last Ten Years,” accessed at
http://www.macrotrends.net/1335/dollar-gold-and-oil-chart-last-ten-years
On the buyers’ side, this depreciation of the U.S. dollar helped pay the oil
bill in countries of the Eurozone, the United Kingdom and even China. On the oil
producers’ side, the effect of a cheap U.S. dollar and a high price of crude oil had
a “bipolar” reading. First, oil producing countries have been receiving billions of
dollars every day. Second, since the value of the dollars they have been receiving
5
Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries. “Member countries”, accessed at
http://www.opec.org/opec_web/en/about_us/25.htm
Lorca - 55
had decreased against major currencies, those dollars could buy them fewer
goods and services; that is, the purchasing power of oil producing and exporting
countries decreased. Moreover, since most of the producing countries have their
currencies pegged to the U.S. dollar, the weakness of the U.S. currency also
drove down the value of their own currencies.
This depreciation of the U.S. dollar was at first regarded as a strategic
move by the United States to gain export share and reactivate its economy (Lorca-Susino 2008). However, with respect to the price of oil, the low dollar was not
an advantage because some oil producing and exporting countries were considering the possibility of pricing their barrels in currency other than U.S. dollars (Associated Press 2007). The sagging dollars also put special pressure on oil producing countries with dollar pegs such as Kuwait, which abandoned the dollar peg.
The United Arab Emirates and Saudi Arabia considered substituting this fixed
exchange rate policy for a basket of currencies with a heavy weight on the euro.
As a result, the United States lost some of its economic and political influence in
a very important area of the world.
Understanding the Price of Gas: A Quick Overview
Understanding how the price of a barrel with 42 gallons of oil translates into the
price of gasoline at the pump is not an easy task. On January 5, 2015 the price of
the barrel of WTI oil fell below US$50 and the price of gasoline at U.S. pumps
hovered around US$2.20 per gallon.6
In fact, nowadays, more and more scholars and politicians are trying to
increase the transparency of the oil pricing mechanism, which previously was
understood only by financiers. Unfortunately, governments — particularly in European countries — do not seem to realize the real impact of all the taxes on the
prices paid at the pump and instead blame “speculators” and their contracts in oil
futures markets as decisive factors in driving oil prices.
According to the Energy Information Administration, between 2000 and
2013 the average retail price for a gallon of gasoline in the United States was
US$2.45 and in 2013 the average price was US$3.517. The table below shows the
different costs that contribute to the final price of gasoline at the pump. It is interesting to note how the increase in the price of oil is reflected in the percentage
labeled “crude oil” with an increase of 12 percentages points from 56 percent to
68 percent. Furthermore, it seems that in order to balance out the increase in the
6
Buchele, Mose. 2015. “How crude oil prices drive the cost of gasoline”, State Impact,
26 January 2015, accessed at: http://stateimpact.npr.org/texas/2015/01/26/oil-explainedwhat-is-brent-and-wti/
7 Energy Information Administration. “A primer on gasoline prices”, Energy Information
Administration Prices, accessed at: http://www.eia.gov/energyexplained/index.cfm?page
=gasoline_factors_affecting_prices
Lorca - 56
price of oil, federal and state taxes as well as the costs of distribution and marketing were reduced.
2000 to 2012
Average Retail Price: $2.45
Average barrel price:
Distribution & Marketing
Refining Costs &
Profits
Federal & State
Taxes
Crude Oil
11%
2007
Average Retail Price:
$2.80
Average barrel price:
9%
13%
11%
19%
12%
56%
68%
Source: Energy Information Administration. “A primer on Gasoline Prices.” Energy
Information
Administration
Prices,
access
at:
http://www.eia.gov/energyexplained/index.cfm?page=gasoline_factors_affecting
_prices
The two graphs that follow allow to compare and contrast the weekly
evolution of the average price of all gasoline grades in the U.S. markets from
November 28, 1994 until January 2015 — a period when the average price of gas
was never below US$1 per gallon — and the evolution of the average spot price
for a barrel of crude oil from October 1973 until January 2015.
F.O.B. Cost of Crude Oil Imports from all non-Opec countries (Dollar
per Barrel)
150
100
2014 January
2012…
2010 March
2008 April
2006 May
2004 June
2002 July
2000 August
1998…
1996…
1994…
1992…
1991 January
1989…
1987 March
1985 April
1983 May
1981 June
1979 July
1977 August
1975…
0
1973…
50
Lorca - 57
Source: The data was collected manually from the Energy Information Administration (http://www.eia.doe.gov/) and was recorded in excel to create the above
graph.
In the European Union the price of oil is not only high but exorbitant. In
the EU, the price of fuel at the pump is based on (1) government duty and tax, (2)
the cost of petrol and diesel on the open market, and (3) the costs and profit of
the wholesaler and retailer. 8
In March of 2014, the U.K.-based non-government organization RAC
Foundation released a new report “European fuel prices,” 9 detailing the taxes and
duties on the retail sale of petrol and diesel fuel in the countries of the EU. According to the report, the highest tax burdens on diesel fuel in the EU are found
in Sweden, the UK, and the Netherlands. Motorists in those countries must face
taxes and duties which make up 62 percent, 61 percent, and 61 percent of the retail price of fuel respectively. Correspondingly, the highest taxes on gasoline are
found in the UK, Sweden and Italy, with respective rates of 59 percent, 56 percent, and 55 percent of the price at the pump. On the other hand, the lowest tax
burdens on the retail sale of fuel are found in Luxembourg and Bulgaria. In these
two countries taxes account for “only” 48 percent and 45 percent of petrol and 41
percent and 42 percent on diesel fuel – the lowest rates in Europe. Curiously, the
price of fuels in the UK remains one of the highest in the EU despite the fact that
the pre-sale cost of fuel in the UK is one of the lowest in the region.
The following graph compares the evolution of the price of gasoline in
key EU countries and the United States. This graph shows that the price of gasoline is extremely high in the European continent and that Europeans pay much
8
RAC Foundation. “Taxation as percentage of pump price”, accessed at: http://www.rac
foundation.org/data/taxation-as-percentage-of-pump-price-data-page
9
RAC Foundation. “European fuel prices”, accessed at : http://www.racfoundation.org
/media-centre/euro-fuel-prices,
Lorca - 58
more than U.S. residents when it comes to domestic fuel prices. The reason for
such pronounced difference is that there are massive taxes levied on fuel by the
governments in Europe. In the United States, only 10 percent of what the enduser pays at the pump goes to the government, while in Europe, this rate is
roughly 70 percent.
Retail premium gasoline price
(US$ per gallon including taxes)
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
EU
US
France
Germany
Italy
UK
US
Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration, “Retail Premium Gasoline
Prices, Selected Countries (US dollars per gallon, including taxes).
http://www.eia.gov/countries/
Price of Gasoline and its Impact on Economic Growth: What Can Be Expected?
Energy prices can have powerful and deep impact on a country's economy. First,
energy prices affect the final price of most goods and services due to transport,
electricity, and fuel costs. Thus, if these rise faster than wages, consumers have
less available income. This in turn will have a deep impact on consumer confidence and will result in less consumer spending and business hiring.
While the United States has recovered more strongly from the 2008 crisis
than Europe that is still on a longer slump the U.S. economic recovery remains
relatively weak. Even though stock prices have reached all-time highs, unemployment is still weak and capacity utilization is still below its 2008 level. The
Federal Reserve Board constructs estimates of capacity utilization for industries
in manufacturing, mining, electric and gas utilities.10 For a given industry, the
capacity utilization rate is equal to an output index (seasonally adjusted) divided
10
Federal Reserve Board. “Industrial Capacity and Capacity Utilization”, accessed at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/current/default.htm
Lorca - 59
by a capacity index. This indicator is displayed as a percentage that points to the
overall slack in the economy or a company at a given point in time. If a company
is running at a 70 percent capacity utilization rate, it has room to increase production up to a 100 percent utilization rate without incurring the expensive costs of
building a new plant or facility. Industrial production figures are based on the
monthly raw volume of goods produced by industrial firms. The industrial production and related capacity utilization figures are considered coincident indicators because changes in the levels of these indicators usually reflect similar
changes in overall economic activity that affect gross domestic product (GDP).
The Federal Reserve watches industrial production very closely because it believes that inflation shows itself first at the industrial level, particularly when
supplies of basic materials get tight and the increases in the cost of commodities
and materials will be passed on down the line, ending up with individual consumers of higher-cost finished products.
It is particularly striking to see how during the recession, when the price
of WTI reached an all-time high of close to US$140 per barrel, both industrial
production and capacity utilization suffered a significant drop. Since 2014, the
price of WTI is suffering a significant drop and both indexes are reaching significant highs.
EP
IPI
CU
Source: Economagic, www.economagic.com
Falling gasoline prices are a favorable tailwind for the U.S. Economy.
But the gasoline prices reduction has not been completely felt in the European
Union where consumers have to pay higher prices than in the United States.
Thus, this will be a headwind for the recovery of the block and it will create a
comparative disadvantage for the EU.
For instance, the following graph shows that in the United States the
price of WTI and GDP are inversely correlated. In fact, since 2014, GDP in the
Lorca - 60
United States has been increasing significantly while the price of WTI has been
suffering a major decrease. However, the graph does not reflect such a significant
improvement in the Eurozone.
GDP
WTI Spot
Price
GDP
Europe
Brent Spot
Source: Economagic. www.economagic.com
If the Eurozone cannot take advantage of oil and gasoline price drop,
which is extremely important for the economic growth of the block, its economic
future will be very dubious, particularly because the price of the euro is not going
to make it easy to pay the bill. The following graph shows that the price of WTI
is going down along with the price of the euro.
Lorca - 61
Source: Economagic. www.economagic.com
Final Remarks
The U.S. increased sharply its oil production due to its desire to obtain energy
independence. Back in 2005, the U.S. imported almost 60 percent of its oil needs
from abroad while in 2014, it only needed 30 percent. This means that there is
clearly an oversupply which is causing the prices to drop. Tumbling oil prices
have led investors to lower its pricing assumptions for the two benchmark crude
oils, European Brent and West Texas Intermediate (WTI). This will affect numerous industries around the world, and will have an effect on the business cycle
on both sides of the Atlantic. Industries for which fuel is a direct and significant
cost will see a positive effect from a decrease in the price of oil, as will consumer-dependent businesses in general because lower gasoline prices mean consumers will have more available income to spend on other goods and services. However, oil and gas exploration and production companies and their affiliates will be
badly hurt by lower crude prices. The demand for oil is not very strong. There are
two main reasons for that. On the one hand, a strong dollar is making a lot more
expensive to pay the cost of oil. This is a challenge for countries that buy outside
the U.S. since a weaker domestic currency to a strong dollar will weaken demand
and put downward pressure on falling oil prices. Of particular interest is the case
of the Eurozone for two reasons. First, most of the countries of the euro area are
still facing the challenges of the economic recession. Second, the Eurozone is
facing a significant drop in the price of the euro which makes oil prices more expensive. Therefore, the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership will be
heavily affected by the future changes in the price of this commodity.
Lorca - 62
References
Associated Press. 2013. “Iran planning to stop using U.S. dollar to price oil, central bank governor Says,” International Herald Tribune, 28 March 2013,
accessed at: http://www.iht.com/articles/ap/2007/03/28/business/ASFIN-Malaysia-Iran-Oil-Dollars.php.\
Cooke, Kieran. 2015. “Plummeting oil price casts shadow over fracking's future,”
The Guardian, 6 January 2015, accessed at:
http://www.theguardian.com/environment/2015/jan/06/oil-price-castsshadow-over-frackings-future.
Diehl, Jackson. 2015. “Falling oil prices hit Venezuela, Iran and Russia hard,”
Washington Post, 18 January 2015, accessed at:
http://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/jackson-diehl-falling-oilprices-hit-venezuela-iran-and-russia-hard/2015/01/18/a92ca05a-9cd911e4-bcfb-059ec7a93ddc_story.html.
Fackler, Martin. 2008. “Surging oil and food prices threaten the world economy,
finance ministers warn,” New York Times, 15 June 2008, accessed
at:http://www.nytimes.com/2008/06/15/business/worldbusiness/15minist
ers.html?_r=0.
Hirst, Tomas. 2014. “OPEC votes not to cut production, oil prices plummet,” 21
December 2014, Business Insider, accessed at:
http://www.businessinsider.com/opec-votes-not-to-cut-production-oilprices-plummet-2014-11#ixzz3QnQou5c0.
Kurmanaev, Anatoly. 2014. “Venezuela burns through third of new Chinese
money in a week,” Bloomberg, 27 November 2014, accessed at:
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2014-11-27/venezuela-burns-throughthird-of-new-chinese-money-in-a-week.html.
Lorca-Susino, Maria. 2008. “The US dollar and the Euro: Deus Ex-Machina,”
European Union Miami Analysis (EUMA), Vol. 5, No. 9, April 2008,
accessed at:http://www6.miami.edu/eucenter/LorcaFXMP%20Theory%20Edi.pdf.
Nasseri, Ladene and Mathew Brown. 2008. “Kuwait Says Oil Over $100 is too
high,” Bloomberg.com, 28 June 2008, accessed
at:http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601087&sid=aJoz82F8
6Wis&refer=home
Lorca - 63
The Economist. 2012. “Shale of the century,” 2 June 2012, accessed
at:http://www.economist.com/node/21556242
World Economic Outlook. 2008. “Housing and the business cycle,” International
Monetary Fund, April 2008, accessed at:
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2008/01/pdf/text.pdf
Zhou, Moming. 2014. “Crude extends fourth weekly decline amid supply glut,”
Bloomberg.com, 22 December 2014, accessed at:
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2014-12-22/crude-extendsfourth-weekly-decline-amid-global-supply-glut
The TTIP from a German Perspective: Economic Interests
and Political Discourse
Sarah L. Beringer
Friedrich-Alexander-Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg
Abstract
As Europe’s largest export nation, Germany has strong economic interests in the
proposed Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP), the free trade
agreement currently being negotiated between the European Union and the United States. While its economic performance regarding foreign trade should make
Germany one of the driving forces in the TTIP negotiations, the current political
discourse has, however, been dominated by critics of the initiative, who fear that
a trade contract with the United States would significantly lower German standards mainly in regards to food security, environmental protection and workers’
rights. This paper aims to analyze these diverging influences on the German position in the TTIP negotiations and the overall effects on a potential agreement.
The Context of Recent Efforts for Transatlantic Economic Integration
On February 13, 2013, the heads of the European Union, European Council President Herman Van Rompuy and European Commission President José Manuel
Barroso, announced in a joint communiqué with U.S. President Barack Obama
the launch of bilateral negotiations on a Transatlantic Trade and
Investment
Partnership (TTIP) (European Commission 2013b).
The TTIP is considered the most ambitious trade agreement in history for
several reasons: it is being negotiated between the world’s two biggest economies, which, at the same time, are each other’s most important economic partners. If concluded, TTIP would represent the largest free trade area (FTA) in
terms of GDP, FDI stock and also by population. Considering the scope of current negotiations, TTIP would go far beyond the reduction of conventional trade
barriers and instead include regulatory issues, so-called behind-the-border obstacles, which go far beyond standards in current trade agreements (Akhtar and
Jones 2013: 111ff.).
On the European side, due to its outstanding performance in international
trade, Germany has long been a driving force in the pursuit of transatlantic economic integration. In the mid-1990s, Germany’s then Foreign Minister Klaus
Kinkel proposed a Transatlantic Market Place. Yet, the proposal failed to formalize in the context of post-NAFTA debates in the United States and a focus on
the creation of a Monetary Union by major EU member countries, particularly
France (Braml and Schmucker 2007: 100; Falke 2014: 435).
Beringer - 66
During 2006/2007, German Chancellor Angela Merkel made transatlantic trade a central issue of Germany’s EU presidency and started pushing for a
Transatlantic Free Trade Agreement (TAFTA). This time, however, France openly opposed such an agreement and the U.S. showed little interest in a “Merkel
Initiative” since bilateral relations had cooled down over diplomatic differences
on the war in Iraq (Bram and Schmucker 2007: 101; Schmucker and Mildner
2013).
Yet, some twenty years after Germany’s first push for a transatlantic
FTA, the economic crises in the United States and Europe and the stalemate of
the WTO Doha Development Round have created a favorable political environment for reviving the project. Both, the U.S. government and the European
Commission had been looking for growth measures beyond fiscal and monetary
policy (Falke 2014: 436). At the same time, they needed to find an alternative
way to the multilateral trade agenda, which is stalled due to unbridgeable differences between the positions of industrial nations and certain emerging market
economies.
In this context, this paper will analyze the German stance in this new initiative. After an overview of the scope and content of TTIP, potential gains for
the German economy will be highlighted. This is followed by an analysis of critical issues that have heated the public discussion on TTIP. Lastly, this paper will
investigate how the diverging interests have been influencing the position of the
German government.
The Content of TTIP Negotiations: Making Trade Rules for the 21st Century
The content of current TTIP negotiations has been based on the recommendations of the so-called High-Level Working Group (HLWG), a joint committee set
up by the Transatlantic Economic Council. In its final statement in February
2013, the HLWG suggested that the U.S. and the EU should pursue a trade
agreement which not only targets conventional trade barriers, but also tackles
non-tariff barriers (NTBs) and sets new rules for global economic regulation
(HLWG 2013).
The TTIP negotiations were officially launched on July 8, 2013 and are
organized in three pillars: the first pillar covers issues connected to market access
and therefore deals with conventional trade barriers as well as government procurement (HLWG 2013: 2). Since tariffs and tariff rate quotas (TRQs) are already very low in the EU and the U.S., negotiations in this area will mainly focus
on tariff peaks1 (Fretag et al. 2014: 9).
The second pillar, dubbed “Regulatory Issues and Non-Tariff-Barriers,”
targets primarily behind-the-border obstacles and aims at the alignment of na1
These are mainly recorded for agricultural products, beverages, textiles, and for cars (in
the EU) and small trucks (in the U.S.).
Beringer - 67
tional regulation and standards (HLWG 2013: 3). This area is considered to deliver most of the economic gains. At the same time, it is controversial due to its
impact on national laws and preferences (Schmucker 2014: 22).
The third pillar on “Rules” addresses topics which so far have not been
covered under WTO regulation or need to be modernized. Among these issues
are rules for subsidies, for privileges granted to state-owned enterprises, local
content requirements, as well as provisions on labor and environmental standards
(Falke 2014: 434; HLWG 2013: 5f.).
The transatlantic partners have here clear purpose of modernizing current
international trade rules. Rather than maintaining the ones in former trade agreements which dealt with negotiating preferential market access for so-called “club
goods.” The TTIP and the other Mega Regionals currently under
negotiation
are focusing on facilitating production processes for global value chains.
At the same time, the proposed negotiation structure shows that the TTIP
is laid out to be far more than an economic project. Especially the third negotiation pillar on rules targets measures undertaken by the BIC countries (Brazil, India, China), which the EU and the U.S. have identified as trade distorting, but
were not able to curb on the multilateral level due to opposition from these new
central actors. In times where economic growth mainly occurs in the new mega
markets, the TTIP offers a first mover advantage in setting global economic
standards for the two traditional economic powerhouses and places them ahead
of the new powers in the race for global economic supremacy (Novy 2014;
Schmucker 2014: 20).
Potential Benefits for the German Economy
While the geopolitical dimension adds a new standard for the negotiation of preferential trade agreements, the TTIP’s proposed economic effects alone are
enough to define this initiative as exceptional. The transatlantic economy accounts for over 40 percent of global GDP (PPP) as well as for percent of global
exports and 30 percent of global imports (Hamilton and Quinlan 2014: 20). In
addition, the EU and the U.S. are among each other’s most important trading
partners. While the U.S. received the biggest share of EU exports (17 percent) in
2011, the EU absorbed 19% of U.S. exports, which is a second rank after Canada (Francois et al. 2013: 8).
The interdependence of the world’s two biggest economies is further
shown when looking at
foreign direct investment (FDI). In terms of inward
FDI, the transatlantic economy accounts for 55percent of global stock. For outward FDI the combined shares account for almost 70percent. Since 2010, the EU
was able to attract 56 percent of total U.S. outward FDI. The U.S., conversely,
received 71 percent of EU outward FDI in the year 2012 alone (Hamilton and
Quinlan 2014: 9f., 20). FDI is particularly important in the context of global val-
Beringer - 68
ue chains, since foreign investment is the basis for the establishment of production networks (Felbermayr and Aichele 2014: 2).
Germany plays a central role in this relationship, not least because of the
high degree of openness of the German economy.2 In 2013, exports accounted for
50.6 percent of GDP (BMWi 2014). In 2012, 12 million jobs were supported by
exports, which equaled almost one third of total employment (Felbermayr and
Aichele 2014: 1). In 2013, the U.S. was ranked Germany’s second largest export
destination (8.1percent) just behind other EU member states (BMWi 2014). Reversely, Germany was the fifth largest export market for the U.S. (RGIT 2014:
1). What is striking is the fact that more than 50 percent of bilateral trade flows
have inter-firm character (White House 2011).
On the investment side, Germany was the seventh largest foreign investor in the U.S. in 2013, supporting about 11percent of insourced jobs. The U.S.
was the largest non-European investor in Germany in 2013 with U.S. majorityowned companies accounting for 632,000 German jobs (RGIT 2014: 1f.).
The importance of economic relations with the U.S. combined with Germany’s high degree of export-orientation implies significant benefits that the
TTIP could accrue to Europe’s biggest economy. While experts agree that the
TTIP will overall have positive effects, the exact amount of economic gains is at
the moment hard to quantify since they depend on the models used for calculation, underlying assumptions as well as respective liberalization scenarios.
For Germany, Felbermayr and Aichele (2014: 15ff.) suggest that trade
with the United States would significantly increase under an ambitious3 TTIP
agreement, particularly German gross exports to the American market. They expect the strongest gains for classic German strongholds such as the chemicals,
transport equipment, and machinery sectors. Yet, foreign trade with European
partners would decrease due to trade diversion. The highest gains should come
from the reduction of NTBs and the harmonization of standards, which would
particularly benefit German small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) (Felbermayr et al 2013a: 4).
Looking at overall GDP growth, however, available studies portray a
more modest scenario. Felbermayr and Aichele (2014: 19) estimate German welfare gains in a range between 0.0 percent and 0.28 percent from potential tariff
reductions under the TTIP. For the EU as a whole, the European Commission
(2013a: 32-37) estimates the gains from an ambitious agreement with a GDP increase of 0.58 percent until 2027. Estimates for the U.S. are at 0.39 percent for
the same timeframe.
The same is true when looking at job creation. Felbermayr et al. (2013b:
34-39) estimate that the unemployment rate in Germany would decrease by 0.47
2
With an overall degree of openness at 95 percent (2013), Germany is the most open
economy among the G7 countries.
3
This includes the reduction of tariffs and NTBs as well as the facilitation of FDI and
better access to government procurement markets.
Beringer - 69
percent under an ambitious agreement. Real wages would increase by 2.19 percent. While this is within the European average, other countries, especially the
U.S., Great Britain and the Scandinavian countries would benefit far more in this
regard.
Sticking Points in the German TTIP Debate
Due to the high level of export-orientation of the German economy, free trade
initiatives have in the past created a broad pro-trade coalition consisting of not
only politicians and business representatives, but also the general public. The
TTIP, too, was initially greeted by German stakeholders and because of the
country’s central role in pushing for transatlantic economic integration, most observers expected Germany to lead the way in the negotiation process. While
some controversies in regards to genetically modified organisms (GMO) and
environmental issues were anticipated, many thought the German position would
help to move along troubleshooters like France (Sparding 2014: 1f.).
These predictions were, however, proven wrong. While a survey conducted by the Pew Research Center in cooperation with the Bertelsmann Foundation in April 2014 showed that 55 percent of Germans consider the TTIP to be
overall positive for their country (Pew and Bertelsmann 2014: 5). Thus, some
sticking points have emerged that have the potential to become deal breakers.
The debate centers mainly on the proposed alignment of standards, a potential
investor state dispute settlement (ISDS) mechanism, as well as a suggested lack
of transparency in the negotiation process. While societal groups are the major
critics of these issues, the discussion goes far beyond the anti-globalization
movement (Novy 2014; Sparding 2014: 1).
But why is this debate emerging at a time when the European Commission has just finished negotiating a trade agreement with Canada, the Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA), which already includes many
of these controversial issues? For the majority of controversial topics, discussions
are rooted deeply in different perceptions of the role of state, the functioning of
the legal system, or the general conception of risk (Felbermayr and Aichele 2013:
22). Several studies4 have laid out that the German public shows a high level of
distrust in the American system and the United States per se. Particularly in what
regards food security and quality, environmental safety, labor rights, consumer
protection and even technical norms, Germans view American standards as inferior to not only German but European standards in general (Sparding 2014: 3).
Contrary to the U.S., where regulation is a consequence of scientifically
proven risk, the German philosophy on regulation is based on the so called Precautionary Principle. For the agricultural negotiations of the TTIP, it was expected that this would give the European Commission almost no discretion on
4
E.g. the PEW/Bertelsmann study.
Beringer - 70
critical issues like hormone beef and chlorinated chicken. Yet, Germany’s consumers seem to fear a downward spiral in other health and safety issues related to
the regulation of toxic chemicals and medication (Falke and Felber 2014: 30).
This is also true for technical and environmental standards. Only 10 percent consider American car safety standards as equal, only percent support an alignment
of environmental standards (Pewa and Bertelsmann 2014: 14f.).
A similar picture is emerging when looking at social standards and workers’ rights. The highly influential German Trade Union Federation (DGB 2014:
1ff.) for example, has indicated general support for the TTIP in case it was used
to set new standards for a “fairer globalization.” Yet, it expresses concerns that
German labor standards could be lowered under the TTIP since the United States
have only ratified two out of the eight core labor standards of the International
Labor Organization (ILO). The debate is driven by several cases in which state
governments in the U.S. have used political pressure to prevent the creation of
workers’ councils or unions in subsidiaries of German companies (Inside US
Trade 2014b). The latter incidents have drawn a high degree of public attention
in Germany and have also reinforced fears that German companies would increasingly transfer production jobs to the United States.
An issue that is seen just as critical as new trade regulation and the
alignment of standards is the proposed ISDS mechanism. ISDS protects foreign
investors’ rights in granting them the option to bring claims against a host country before an independent arbitral tribunal.
While Germany has been one of the strongest advocates of bilateral investment treaties (BIT),5 ISDS had never before emerged as a controversial topic.
Yet, the two recent international claims of Swedish energy provider Vatenfall
against German environmental legislation connected to the “Energiewende” have
raised concerns that an ISDS chapter in the TTIP could lead to a flood of claims
from American investors against similar legislation. For decades, the latter have
earned a reputation as greedy “locusts” employing fleets of scrupulous lawyers,
which are able to lever out democratic processes (Sparding 2014: 3, 7). The discussion on ISDS has reached such a degree that it has now spilled over on CETA.
Yet, it is not only the distrust in the U.S. and its system that is driving the opposition to the TTIP in Germany. In recent years, the country has shown an increasing degree of Euro-skepticism. A majority of Germans doubts that the European Commission is negotiating in Germany’s best interest.6 They consider the
5
Germany was the first country to sign a BIT (in 1959 with Pakistan) and has since negotiated over 130.
6
Since the implementation of the Lisbon Treaty in 2009, trade policy making, including
FDI and intellectual
property rights (IPR), is under exclusive EU competence (ToL
Art. 207). Negotiations are conducted by the
Commission, but the European Parliament enjoys far-reaching rights of co-determination since every trade deal needs parliamentary approval. While the Commission has to frequently coordinate with the national
Beringer - 71
Commission’s negotiation style as in-transparent and undemocratic. Also, business lobbyists are perceived to receive preferential access over representatives of
consumer, social and environmental interests (Sparding 2014: 7). Accordingly,
65 percent of Germans declare that negotiations should be conducted by the
German government (Pew and Bertelsmann 2014: 17f.).
The German Government’s Position on the TTIP Controversies: Sit out,
Tackle or Retreat?
The current German government, a coalition of Angela Merkel’s Christian Democratic Party (CDU) and the Social Democratic Party (SPD), has manifested its
support for the TTIP in the coalition agreement signed in November 2013. The
agreement (Bundesregierung 2013: 15f.,168) outlines Germany’s commitment to
the principles of free and fair trade and its aim for a conclusion of the WTO Doha
Development Round, TTIP, and other trade agreements. While acknowledging
the need for the alignment of existing regulation through the TTIP, the agreement, however, also calls for maintaining the current European levels of health,
environmental, social, consumer and data protection standards as well as an inclusion of all ILO core labor standards in EU-FTAs.
The text clearly shows the diverging political focuses of the coalition
parties, with the CDU being considered the voice of Germany’s industry and the
SPD representing unions and civil society groups. But while the Christian Democrats are the senior partner in this so-called Grand Coalition, it has been the SPD
that has dominated Berlin’s position taking on the TTIP following the aforementioned public outcry. One of the loudest voices criticizing the TTIP has been
Economics Minister Sigmar Gabriel. In line with demands from labor unions and
trade critics within his party, he called for an exclusion of ISDS in both, TTIP
and CETA, and even threatened to block the ratification of the latter otherwise
(ICTSD 2014: 14f.).
The main proponents of the TTIP, the business wing of the CDU, on the
other hand, remained silent since the revelations of the NSA spying scandal that
further eroded public trust in the U.S. and, therefore, made supporting GermanU.S. relations politically difficult. While Chancellor Angela Merkel and her
CDU-ministers were rather careful to underscore the government’s continued
support for the TTIP, they have avoided dissenting from the position of their coalition partner. Moreover, the CDU has come under pressure from its own constituencies. In addition to the powerful but defensive farm lobby, representatives of
German SMEs have spoken out against ISDS, claiming that the assessment of
this mechanism is too costly for their businesses and therefore gives big corporations an advantage.
governments of member states, national parliaments only get involved when mixed
agreements are negotiated.
Beringer - 72
Yet, the German government seemingly has not given up on the initiative. In order to enhance the dialogue with civil society representatives, a TTIP
council was created within the Economics Ministry (Sparding 2014: 6, 11). In
addition, trade proponents within the Cabinet were able to change the position of
Sigmar Gabriel and other critics who are now in favor of an inclusion of ISDS
chapters in both the TTIP and the CETA, albeit only in the case of wide-ranging
reforms to the current modus operandi (ICTSD 2014: 14).
In the wake of this political development, the European Commission,
too, has reacted. In March 2014 the Commission temporarily suspended ISDS
negotiations and initiated a public consultation process, which drew nearly
150,000 replies. The proposed reforms are currently under review. However, a
final decision is not to be expected until late in the negotiation process. In addition, the negotiation instructions given to the European Commission by EU
member governments were made public in October 2014 (ICTSD 2015: 4f.).
Conclusion
Due to its general pro-trade standing and a history of pushing for transatlantic
economic integration, Germany was expected to take a lead in the TTIP negotiations. While proponents of this mega regional agreement have been extolling the
potential gains for the export-dependent German economy, public resentments,
which are rooted in a deep distrust towards the United States and its economic
system, have taken over the political discourse.
The outcry against the TTIP reached such a degree that Berlin was forced
to slow down the negotiation process and to develop an alternative strategy,
which included calls for a more transparent negotiation style on part of the European Commission and a drastic modification or even exclusion of the proposed
ISDS mechanism.
Both trade supporters in the German government as well as the European
Commission have recently taken steps to ease this debate. The creation of specific advisory groups on the national and EU level which are aiming at better involving public interests are steps in the right direction. The same is true for the
European Commission’s public consultation process on ISDS.
Yet, given Germany’s weight in Europe, policymakers and negotiators
should consider to go even further beyond conventional trade negotiation approaches in order to save the TTIP in the ambitious form it is currently being negotiated. Neither Germany, nor the EU or the U.S. could risk losing first-mover
advantages in setting global trade standards to third countries and should, therefore, address key concerns more extensively.
Beringer - 73
References
Akhtar, Shayerah Ilias and Jones, Vivian C. 2013. “Proposed Transatlantic Trade
and Investment Partnership (T-TIP): In Brief.” Current Politics and Economics of Europe, 24(1), 107-122.
BMWi (Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft). 2014. “Fakten zum deutschen
Außenhandel 2013.” Berlin.
Braml, Josef and Schmucker, Claudia. 2007. “Barriers in the Atlantic Economic
Area. From TAFTA to a free market; new transatlantic trade initiatives”.
Internationale Politik, 62, 100-103.
Bundesregierung. 2013. “Koalitionsvertrag zwischen CDU, CSU und SPD.” Berlin.
DGB (Deutscher Gewerkschaftsbund). 2014. “DGB Position: Suspend the negotiations for a free trade agreement with the USA.” Berlin.
European Commission. 2013a. “Impact Assessment Report On the Future of EUUS Trade Relations.” Strasbourg.
European Commission. 2013b. “Statement from United States President Barack
Obama, European Council President Herman Van Rompuy and European Commission President José Manuel Barroso.” Brussels, Washington
D.C. http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_MEMO-13-94_en.htm.
Falke, Andreas. 2014. “Pooling Economic Power? Die Transatlantische Handelsund Investitionspartnerschaft (TTIP) als Gegengewicht zum Aufstieg
neuer Wirtschaftsmächte und die Zukunft amerikanischer Weltführungspolitik,” in Hagemann, Steffen; Tönnesmann, Wolfgang; Wilzewski,
Jürgen. (eds), Weltmacht vor neuen Herausforderungen: Die Außenpolitik der USA in der Ära Obama. Trier: WVT.
Falke, Andreas and Felber, Christian. 2014. “TTIP Kontrovers.”.Aus Politik und
Zeitgeschichte, 64(50-51), 25-33.
Felbermayr, Gabriel; Larch, Mario; Flach, Lisandra; Yalcin, Erdal; Benz, Sebastian. 2013a. “Dimensions and Effects of a Transatlantic Free Trade
Agreement Between the EU and US.” Munich: Ifo Institute.
Beringer - 74
Felbermayr, Gabriel; Heid, Benedikt; Lehwald, Sybille. 2013b. “Transatlantic
Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP). Who benefits from a free trade
deal? Macroeconoic Effects”. Gütersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung.
Felbermayr, Gabriel and Aichele, Rahel. 2014. “Transatlantic Free Trade: The
View Point of Germany.” Munich: Ifo Institute.
Francois, Joseph; Manchin, Miriam; Norberg, Hanna; Pindyuk, Olga; Tomberger, Patrick. 2013. “Reducing Transatlantic Barriers to trade and Investment. An Economic Assessment.” London: Centre for Economic Policy
Research.
Freytag, Peter; Draper, Peter; Fricke, Susanne. 2014. “The Impacts of TTIP:
Economic Effects on the Transatlantic Partners, Third Countries and the
Global Trade Order.” Berlin: Konrad Adenauer Stiftung.
Hamilton, Daniel S. and Quinlan, Joseph P. 2014. “The Transatlantic Economy
2014: Annual Survey of Jobs, Trade and Investment between the United
States and Europe.” Washington D.C.: Center for Transatlantic Relations.
HLWG (US-EU High Level Working Group on Jobs and Growth). 2013. “Final
Report.” Brussels.
ICTSD (International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development). 2014.
“Germany Changes Tack on ISDS in EU-Canada Trade Deal.” Bridges
Weekly, 18(41), 14-15.
ICTSD. 2015. “EU Commission Publishes Results of TTIP Public Consultation
on ISDS, Investment Protections.” Bridges Weekly, 19(1), 4-6.
Inside US Trade. 2014a. “Anti-TTIP Petition in EU Garners 1 Million Signatures, Surpassing Key Threshold.” 32(49).
Inside US Trade. 2014b. “German Union Rep Doubtful TTIP Regulatory Goals
Will Yield Worker Gains.”.32(29).
Novy, Dennis. 2014. “TTIP – Is free trade coming to the north Atlantic?” Vox
EU, accessed at: http://www.vox eu.org/article/ttip-free-trade-comingnorth-atlantic.
Beringer - 75
Pew Research and Bertelsmann Foundation. 2014. “Support in Principle for U.S.EU Trade Pact. But Some Americans and Germans Wary of TTIP Details.” Washington D.C., Berlin.
RGIT (Representative of German Industry & Trade). 2014. “German-American
Trade, Investment, And Jobs.”Washington D.C.
Schmucker, Claudia and Mildner, Stormy-Annika. 2013. “Weimar Triangle: the
German View.” February 21. German Council on Foreign Relations, accessed at: https://ip-journal.dgap.org/en/blog/eye-europe/weimartriangle-german-view.
Schmucker, Claudia (2014). “TTIP im Kontext anderer Freihandelsabkommen.”Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte, 64(50-51), 17-23.
Sparding, Peter (2014). “Germany’s Pivotal Role On The Way To TTIP.” Washington D.C.: German Marshall Fund.
The White House (2011). “Fact Sheet: U.S.-German Bilateral Economic Ties.”
June 7, accessed at: http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/2011/06
/07/fact-sheet-us-german-bilateral-economic-ties.
I.
Beyond Economics
TTIP:
A Mega-Free Trade Agreement Lost in Translation?
Maxime H. A. Larivé
EU Center of Excellence of the University of Miami
Abstract
The Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP), initiated in July
2013, has become a sluggish and complex series of negotiation between the EU
and the US. At first this massive bilateral trade agreement was expected to be
quickly completed and agreed. The TTIP consists in removing trade barriers in a
wide range of economic sectors as well as harmonizing some rules, technical
regulation, standards, and approval procedures. According to the European
Commission, the TTIP is projected to boost the EU’s economy by €120 billion; the US economy by €90 billion; and the rest of the world by €100 billion.
Almost two years in, the negotiations on the TTIP are facing serious criticisms
inside Europe. The TTIP has provided the arguments to anti-globalization
movements, fear of decline of democratic foundations, declining national sovereignty, as well as destruction of national/regional identities and cultures. Nevertheless, based on polls produced by Eurobarometer, a majority of European citizens are in favor of the TTIP at the exception of Austria clearly disapproving.
The TTIP is seen as a way to re-launch the transatlantic economy, but mainly
European economies stagnated since the financial crisis. The TTIP is as well a
response to the other trade agreements, like the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP),
and the rise of Asian economies. This paper seeks to reflect on two dimensions:
the projected benefits of the TTIP for the EU and the debate and perceptions
within the EU about the TTIP.
Introduction
The European political elite, as well as the American President and a segment of
the United States legislature seem committed to finalize the negotiations on the
Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) in 2015. The transatlantic
decision to launch negotiations for the implementation of the TTIP was initiated
back in 2013. The Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership, currently under negotiations between the United States (U.S.) and the European Union (EU),
is a massive Free Trade Agreement (FTA) with the purpose to create jobs and
boost investments and trade on both sides of the pond.
The idea behind the TTIP falls under a global reading of power adjustment and shift in global influence of the Euro-Atlantic community. The 2008
Larivé - 80
financial crisis seriously affected the American and European economies and
their overall global influence. The debate over the decline of the US as the
hegemon and ultimately of the future of the liberal order (Ikenberry 2011, Kupchan 2012) raised important questions about the ability of the U.S. to shape global politics as it did during the Bretton Woods period and the 1990s (Culbert 1987,
Ikenberry 1992, Ruggie 1982).
In the case of the EU and its 28 economies, its influence has certainly
declined since then due to the internal economic crises affecting most of its
Member States. For such reason, the TTIP was framed as a mega-FTA relaunching the transatlantic economic engine. The U.S. and the EU are each other’s largest commercial partners especially in services, trade and investments.
The TTIP seeks to advance three core components between the two sides
of the Atlantic: first, to increase market access through the elimination of barriers
to trade and investment in goods, services, and agriculture as well as the further
opening of government procurement markets; second, to enhance regulatory coherence and cooperation; and third, to develop new rules in areas such as foreign
direct investment, intellectual property rights, labor, the environment, and emerging ‘21st century’ areas of trade (e.g., regulating data flows, trade facilitation in a
supply chain environment, and the role of state-owned enterprises) (Akhtar and
Jones 2014). An important dimension of the TTIP is that it is more than establishing the base for a FTA considering the already deep trade relations between
the EU and the US, but rather to implement regulatory alignment between the EU
and the U.S.. “The TTIP negotiations involve two parties with their own sets of
entrenched and advanced regulatory structures” (Aggarwal and Evenett 2013:
553).
The TTIP is not solely about economics, but it is deeply political as well.
In order to understand the complexity behind the long-lasting agreement on the
TTIP, this chapter seeks to explain the link between the desire/commitment by
the members of the Euro-Atlantic Community (U.S., EU, EU-28) and the lack of
popular support in Europe. Has the TTIP been lost in translation? In order to analyze this question, the chapter is structured around two parts: the first one consists in looking at the TTIP in its generality as well as its global constrains; the
second section looks at the European perceptions on the TTIP and their effects on
the ongoing negotiation process.
Mega FTA or Economic NATO?
A Fragmented Global Economy
The TTIP is an illustration of a fragmented global economy and a complex global
trading system (Aggarwal and Evenett 2013). As per Aggarwal and Evenett, the
global economy is facing three challenges since the financial crises: the rise of
protectionism; a continued interest in Free Trade Agreements (FTA); and, the
decline of the World Trade Organization (WTO) since facing the difficult negoti-
Larivé - 81
ations of the Doha round illustrating the tensions between the North and the
South (2013).
Considering the shifting global balance of power, the continuous Eurozone crisis and the sluggish look of European economies several EU Member
States, like the governments in the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, and Germany, were favorable and have been driving the negotiations process. These
Member States want to find a way to rejuvenate the European economic engine
with a long-term vision and a clear search for competitiveness and strengthening
their global positions.
For decades the academic debate has been closely looking at the question
of Regional Trade Agreements (RTAs) versus multilateral trading system
(Baghwati 1992, Manfield and Milner 1997). In the case of the TTIP, the question of re-boosting the transatlantic economy falls under the broad question of
stumbling blocks or building blocks. “With the United States increasingly looking east toward Asia, and the EU increasingly turning inward, the threat of the
transatlantic community being pulled apart is real. But trade negotiations would
reinvigorate the transatlantic alliance” (Barker 2013). Will the TTIP be a positive
agreement, if implemented, for the world and the emerging power? Or will it
contribute to the widening of inequality gaps between the Global North, the Euro-Atlantic community, versus the rest?1
A Transatlantic Economy
Historically, the U.S. and the EU have been competitors and partners in the field
of trade. But with the shifting global order and the lingering economic slowdown
of the European economies, the U.S. and the EU are working on implementing
the TTIP in order to form “a large Euro-Atlantic market and high transatlantic
standards to open other markets and form the core of global standards” (Hamilton
2014a: 27). The TTIP could be a new dimension of the transatlantic partnership.
But Hamilton argues that it is not an ‘economic NATO,’ but rather a second
transatlantic anchor, rooted in deep and growing transatlantic economic integration” (2014a: 32).
The U.S. and the EU are the largest trading partners in the world. In
2013, the bilateral commerce accounted $649billion. The transatlantic economy
is the world largest accounting for three-quarters of global financial markets,
over half of world trade, 50 percent of world gross domestic product, and 41 percent in terms of purchasing power (Hamilton 2014a: 32). The EU exports twice
as many good to the U.S. than it does to China, and the U.S. exports three times
as many goods to Europe as it does to China (Hamilton 2014a: 32).
The previsions for the impacts of the TTIP on American and European
economies are a foreseen growth ranging from 0.5 to two percent of GDP and
1
For more information see Hamilton 2014b.
Larivé - 82
creating around two million jobs (Barker 2013). Barker underscores that “Today,
a third of the tariffs paid by the United States go to Europe. “Zeroing out tariffs
could add $180 billion to both economies” (2013). As argued by Sapiro, Deputy
U.S. Trade Representative from 2009 to 2014, the TTIP is “about establishing
new rules of the road that reflect U.S. and EU core values and high standards. It
also has the potential to cement an even stronger U.S.-EU partnership that could,
over time, create a platform to embrace new TTIP members that qualify and
thereby enhance broader Euro-Atlantic stability and prosperity” (Sapiro 2014).
The slow economic growth, limited job creation, and competition from
emerging markets have contributed to launching transatlantic trade negotiations
in order to eliminate tariff and non-tariff barriers. The argument for the TTIP is
related to the creation of institutional rules in the transatlantic economy. The
TTIP seeks to promote multilateral trade liberalization, establish new rules and
standards at the global level, and respond to the rise of powerful emerging economies such as China and Brazil. The TTIP is framed as being the agreement allowing the creation of jobs on both sides of the Atlantic and boosting the sluggish
European economic engine.
The TTIP is “much more than a free trade agreement,” it is the “next
frontier” according to HR/VP Federica Mogherini (2015). The concept of next
frontier underscores a clear strategic vision behind the largest free trade agreement in world. Trade is one instrument with several facets: on the one hand, it is
a clear component of soft power, as through trade Western values, ideas and
norms can be exported; and, on the other hand, it is about pure geopolitics as it
would allow the Euro-Atlantic community to balance out thanks to an increase of
trade relations and savings on removed trade barriers, and harmonization.
European Perceptions on the TTIP and the Negotiation Process
Two years in the negotiation process of what should have been a technicality,
European citizens are continuously skeptical about the TTIP. Since the collapse
of the financial markets causing a snowball effect over the European economies,
the economic situation of the European continent has been quite difficult. In most
EU Member States, the rise of populist parties2 – right and left combined – illustrates popular and domestic concerns over globalization, global markets, and the
EU itself. In some ways, and in some countries like France, the TTIP has become
a materialization of the global forces imposed on European citizens. This section
is composed of two parts. The first one looks at the European concerns over the
negotiations themselves and what is perceived as opaque-negotiations under the
2
The results of the 2014 European Parliament elections added to the recent elections of
Syriza in Greece and the increasing popularity of extreme-right parties in France, the
Netherlands, Austria, and the UK explain the shift of rhetoric over the TTIP.
Larivé - 83
helm of the European Commission, or Brussels. The second part seeks to look at
the actual European ‘fears’ over the TTIP and its components.
1. The EU versus the Member States?
The negotiations process is already a cause of concerns for many European citizens. As written in the Treaties, the European Commission, or the executive body
of the Union, is the lead negotiator representing the EU-28 in trade negotiations.3
However, during the negotiations, the Commission maintains a strong relationship and discussions with the Member States through the Council of Ministers.4
The European Parliament (EP) was historically kept informed, but with the implementation of the 2009 Treaty of Lisbon, its power in trade negotiations has
increased.5
Until the Treaty of Lisbon, trade negotiations were mostly undertaken
between the Commission and Council of Ministers. The EP was usually excluded. With the Treaty of Lisbon, the EP has grabbed some new powers in expressing its positions and recommendations on trade negotiations. “The explanation
for the EP’s growing informal impact is as follows: as the EP now has to give its
consent at the end of negotiations, the recommendations it issues in nonbinding
resolutions before the negotiations have a similar political weight as the negotiating guidelines from the Council” (Van den Putte et al.2014: 3). In the case of the
TTIP, the EP has now increased its power as the Commission needs to inform the
International Trade Committee (INTA) before and after each round of negotiations (Van den Putte et al. 2014: 3). Once the negotiations are completed the text
ought to be approved by the Council of Ministers and the EP.
Despite a leading effort by an executive body, the Commission, the final
agreement has to be approved by the Council of Ministers, representation of the
EU-28, and the EP, in representation of European citizens. “Parliament must use
its influence on framing TTIP rules,” argued Trade Committee Chair Bernd
Lang, “to ensure that they serve all EU citizens, not just a few economic players
and must therefore insist that the talks are more democratic and more transparent” (European Parliament 2015). In any case, the TTIP has to be ratified by the
European Parliament through a yes or no vote in order to enter into force.
3
The EU external trade policy is one of the strongest elements in EU system of external
relations. It is often defined as the European external ‘single voice.’ Based on the Treaties, the European Commission can negotiate preferential trade agreements (PTAs) with
third states and international organization in the name of the EU and its Member States.
4
Concerning the Council the general ruling and voting process on trade policy is based
on the Qualified Majority Voting (QMV), expect for cultural/audiovisual services (EU’s
cultural and linguistic diversity) and social, education or health services, which have to
be approved by unanimity.
5
With the Treaty of Lisbon, the European Parliament is playing the role of co-legislator
on trade matters.
Larivé - 84
Ultimately, the Commission may run the negotiations, but all the EU institutions are involved in the process. Additionally, the Commission, Council and
the Parliament have tried to have a comprehensive strategy and be as transparent
as possible as illustrated by the number of publications on European institutions’
websites. The common market and international trade are central component of
the EU, which fall under the capacity and authority of the Commission.
In the past, the Commission has negotiated a large number of trade
agreements without taking into account concerns from European citizens. This
one with the US, one of the possible largest trade agreements, seems to resonate
differently among European heads of states and governments and citizens.
Perceptions of the TTIP in Europe and the US
The success in the negotiations of the TTIP could lead to the largest trade agreement in history. The question of domestic politics is important to incorporate
when studying trade agreements and policies (Alt et al. 1987, Milner 1987, Goldstein 1996). The public opinions on both sides of the Atlantic have had a say on
their perceptions of the TTIP.
The TTIP is closely connected to the narrative of globalization (Bhagwati 2004, Stiglitz 2004). Overall European citizens are much divided on their understanding of globalization. They are neither in clear favor or full rejection. As
illustrated in the table below (Table 1), at the EU level 40 percent of European
citizens in 2012 saw globalization as an advantage for their national country,
while 42 percent of them think that globalization represents a threat to national
employment and companies. If one reflects on the perceptions of globalization on
national EU Member States, few European citizens see a clear gain in globalization. Germans, with 53 percent, and Dutch, with 68 percent, are the principal citizens in favor of globalization, while the leader of anti-globalization is France
with 65 percent against followed by Belgium with 57 percent. Only one quarter
of the French citizens perceive globalization as a clear benefit for their country.
Table 1: Which one of the following two statements is closest to your opinion
regarding globalization? (May 2012)
Belgium
France
Globalization represents a good opportunity for (NATIONALITY) companies thanks to the
opening-up of markets
37%
25%
Globalization represents a threat to
employment and
companies in
(OUR COUNTRY)
Do not know
57%
65%
6%
10%
Larivé - 85
Germany
Italy
The Netherlands
Poland
Portugal
Spain
United Kingdom
EU-27
53%
29%
68%
41%
31%
35%
45%
40%
36%
48%
24%
32%
44%
33%
37%
42%
11%
23%
8%
27%
25%
32%
18%
18%
Source: European Commission. 2012. “Globalization.” Eurobarometer Survey.
May [Accessed on January 28, 2015]
According to a recent study conducted in November 2014 by the European
Commission about public opinion on the TTIP, a large majority of the EU-28
have responded favorably to the possibility of the TTIP (see chart 1 below). The
most in favor are Poland (73 percent), the United Kingdom (65 percent), the
Netherlands (74 percent), Malta (75 percent), and Lithuania (79 percent). The EU
average in favor is at 58 percent. The EU Member States the least favorable to
the TTIP are Austria (53 percent), Germany (41 percent), France (33 percent),
and Luxemburg (43 percent). The EU average against the TTIP is at 25 percent.
Overall the public concern remains high in two EU Member States, Austria and
France, and, to a lesser degree, in Germany, the Netherlands, and the UK.
The French scepticism towards the TTIP reflects a cultural dimension and
matches the numbers of Table 1, wherein French citizens are sceptical regarding
the economic benefits of globlization. However, in the case of Germany, the lack
of support vis-à-vis the TTIP does not connect with the perception on
globlization. A recent study produced by the Pew Research Center in 2014
reports that 55 percent of Germans thought that the “TTIP will be a good thing
for the country” and 25 percent did not (2014: 5). In the U.S., a majority thinks
that the TTIP will be good at 53 percent and 20 percent are against it.6
In fact all these numbers illustrate the complexity of the TTIP talks and
multifaceted nature of the treaty. In theory, both sides of the Atlantic agree on the
reduction and even elimination of tariffs barriers on all merchandise traded. The
question of restriction on transatlantic investments is dividing the Atlantic. However the most contentious dimension of the TTIP talks is the question of technological and regulatory standards. Within the issue of standards, Europeans and
especially Germans are very concerned about the protection over the regulation
of data privacy. The U.S. and Germany tend to have similar positive perceptions
of international trade. Both countries have economies closely connected to trade.
In the case of Germany, the country has had trade surplus since 1952. For in6
For more information on the TTIP and European public opinion, see Dullien, et al.
2015.
Larivé - 86
stance as of November 2014, Germany trade surplus was of €17.9billion (Husna
2015).
Chart 1: European Perceptions on the TTIP
Source: European Commission. 2014. “Perceptions on the
Eurobarometer Survey. November [Accessed on January 28, 2015].
TTIP.”
Interestingly enough, the estimation of the overall potential wealth gains
resulting from the TTIP would be made from cutting costs due to bureaucracy
and regulations (Francois 2013). The contention is not about trade, but rather in
the harmonization process. As illustrated by the data (Table 1 and Chart 1), the
main concern is on the harmonization process. The main fear in Europe, for European citizens and other European groups, is that the “TTIP is nothing less than
a new mechanism by which the ‘American system’ will eviscerate European
standards and simply steamroll the European way of life” (Hamilton 2014a: 34).
The main arguments raised by European policy-makers opposing the TTIP are
entrenched in several narratives: concerns about lowering European standards on
food (namely the question on Genetically Modified Food or even chlorine
washed chicken); about the lack of transparence on the negotiation process; and,
about the investor-state dispute settlement mechanism (ISDS) allowing corpora-
Larivé - 87
tions to sue governments if local laws threatened their investments (Barysch
2014).
Ultimately, Americans and Europeans are both agreeing on the fact that
the elimination of trade barriers is a good thing. But the talks become very difficult once both sides lay down their approach on trying to harmonize the regulatory standards.
Concluding Remarks
Part of the successful results of the TTIP negotiations may reside in the political
leadership of the US, the EU-28 and the European institutions in framing the topics embedded in the TTIP and explaining its importance in re-launching the
transatlantic economies. Domestically, several actors in Europe, such as agricultural lobbies, right and left populist parties, and anti-globalization parties, have
had powerful voices and impact in the negations process. Some of the most contentious topics affecting the TTIP negotiations include “investor-state dispute
settlement mechanisms (“ISDS”), cross-border data flows, regulatory cooperation, financial services, agriculture and government procurement, to name a few”
(Sapiro 2014). These points of contentions are a reflection of national concerns
and opposition to the TTIP.
Through the TTIP, the two transatlantic actors are working on boosting
their share in the changing world order and establishing new global standards.
“North Atlantic networks of interdependence have become so dense that they
transcend foreign relations and reach deeply into each other’s societies” (Hamilton 2014a: 25). The TTIP is more than simple trade question. It is a very political
file with domestic impacts and strategic ramifications.
The TTIP, if agreed and adopted, could offer to the US-EU the ability to
maintaining the liberal world order created at the end of World War two. The rise
of China and its dominance of global market are a reality affecting international
norms and values. By combining their trading power, the US and the EU will be
able to balance out rising powers and remain the leaders in global trade. Trade is
more than simple commerce, values, norms and principles are embedded within
this mega-free trade agreement.
References
Aggarwal, Vinod, Evenett, Simon. 2013. “A Fragmenting Global Economy: A
Weakened WTO, Mega FTAs, and Murky Protectionism,” Center for
Economic Policy Research, December.
Aggarwal, Vinod, and Evenett, Simon. 2013. “Debate. A Fragmenting Global
Economy: A Weakened WTO, Mega FTAs, and Murky Protectionism,”
Swiss Political Science Review, 19(4), 550–57.
Larivé - 88
Akhtar, Shayerah and Jones, Vivian. 2014. “Proposed Transatlantic Trade and
Investment Partnership (T-TIP): In Brief.” CRS Report, R43158. June
11.
Alt, James, et al. 1996. “The Political Economy of International Trade: Enduring
Puzzles and an Agenda for Inquiry,” Comparative Political Studies,
29(6), 689-717.
Barysch, Katinka. 2014. “Irrational fear risks depriving Europe of the benefits of
trade,” The Financial Times, November 11.
Barker, Tyson. 2013. “For Transatlantic Trade, This Time Is Different. Why the Latest
U.S.-EU Trade Talks Are Likely to Succeed,” Foreign Affairs. February
26.
Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1992. “Regionalism versus Multilateralism,” The World
Economy, 15(5), 535-56.
Bhagwati, Jagdish. 2004. In Defense of Globalization. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Culbert, Jay. 1987. “Wartime Anglo-American Talks and the Making of the
GATT,” The World Economy, 10(4), 381-399.
Dullien, Sebastian, Garcia, Adriana and Janning, Josef. 2015. “A Fresh Start for
TTIP.” ECFR. Policy Brief. February.
European Council on Foreign Relations. 2015. “European Foreign Policy Scoreboard 2015.” January.
European Parliament. 2015. “Trade committee debate on new recommendations
for TTIP talks,” Press Release. REF: 20150119IPR10301. January 22.
Francois, Joseph. 2013. Reducing Transatlantic Barriers to Trade and Investment: An Economic Assessment. London: Centre for Economic Policy
Research.
Hamilton, Daniel S. 2014a. “Transatlantic Challenges: Ukraine, TTIP and the
Struggle to be Strategic,” Journal of Common Market Studies, 52(Annual
Review), 25-39.
Hamilton, Daniel S. 2014b. “TTIP: What are the implications for emerging powers and the international order?” Bridges Africa, 3(10), December 1.
Larivé - 89
Husna, Rida. 2015. “German trade surplus narrows in November.” Trading Economics. January 9.
Ikenberry, John G. 1992. “A World Economy Restored: Expert Consensus and
the Anglo-American Postwar Settlement,” International Organization,
46(1), 289-321.
Ikenberry, John G. 2011. “The Future of the Liberal World Order. Internationalism
After America,” Foreign Affairs. May/June.
Kupchan, Charles A. 2012. “The Decline of the West: Why America Must Prepare for
the End of Dominance,” The Atlantic, March 20.
Mansfield, Edward, and Milner, Helen. eds. 1997. The Political Economy of Regionalism. New York: Columbia University Press.
Milner, Helen. 1987. “Resisting the Protectionist Temptation: Industry and the
Making of Trade Policy in France and the United States during the
1970s,” International Organization, 41(4), 639-65.
Milner, Helen. 2012. “International Trade,” in Carlnaes, Walter, et. al. (eds),
Handbook of International Relations. Second Edition. London: Sage:
720-45.
Mogherini, Federica. 2015. “Remarks by Federica Mogherini, High Representative of the European Union and Vice-President of the European Commission, at the Brookings Institute,” Brookings Institute, January 20.
Pew Research Center. 2014. “Support in Principle for U.S.-EU Trade Pact. But
some Americans and Germans Wary on TTIP Details,” April 9.
Ruggie, John. 1982. “International Regimes, Transactions and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order,” International Organization, 36(2), 379-415.
Sapiro, Miriam. 2014. “TTIP: A Fresh Start for 2015,” Brookings. Up-Front, December 12.
Stiglitz, Joseph. 2004. Globalization and its Discontents. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.
Larivé - 90
Van den Putte, Lore, De Ville, Ferdi, and Orbie, Jan. 2014. “The European Parliament’s New Role in Trade Policy: Turning power into impact,” CEPS.
Special Report N.89. May.
Washington Post. 2014. “Phony Fears on Trans-Atlantic Trade. A U.S. diplomat
rebukes green misinformation on U.S. food products,” July 22
Revisiting the TTIP: the Revenge of Politics
Vicente Palacio
Fundación Alternativas
Abstract
Two years after their inception, the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) negotiations have reached a critical point on a number of pending
issues that will determine the future balance of power between the US and the
EU. These issues can influence their relative international standing in areas as
diverse as financial power, political influence, social, energy and environmental
policies. The TTIP negotiations are part of a readjustment process from the United States and the European Union in response to a shifting geopolitical environment. A geopolitical landscape marked by a rapid economic and technological
change, the precariousness of certain states’ membership status within the EU,
the declining of oil and commodity prices; in addition to the emergence of new
energy sources, and the repositioning of emerging powers such as China, Russia,
and Brazil in the global arena, calls for a close analysis of American and European responses to the new realities of the twenty-first century. This chapter addresses the convergent and divergent positions these transatlantic partners have
variably taken at the TTIP negotiating table in response to the domestic challenges and geopolitical changes that both currently face.
Introduction
The eighth round of TTIP negotiations of February 2015 should mark a critical
point in an extended process as it will focus on a number of pending issues that
will determine the relationship between the U.S. and the EU and their relative
standing in areas as diverse as global financial power, political influence, and
social, energy, and environmental policy. Both, the evolution of the two parties’
bargaining positions and the reactions of China, Russia, and Brazil to the process
over the two years (since talks were initiated in 2013), suggest that the TTIP
agreement represents an integral step in the realignment of American and European geopolitics. A shift that is occurring at a moment when the U.S. is enjoying
a post-crisis momentum that Europe has yet to achieve. As such, it could well
provide a new road map for international environmental and financial governance.
As negotiations have progressed, each succeeding round has focused less
and less on economic benefits and taken on a greater political dimension. Since it
was first discussed in June 2013, the proposed agreement has increasingly become a means for the partners at the negotiating table to affirm themselves both
Palacio - 92
at home and abroad. However, further progress towards a final agreement is being hampered by three factors: geopolitical shifts, an economic slowdown in
emerging markets, and domestic political and institutional constraints.
Geopolitical Shifts, Emerging Powers, and the TTIP Negotiations
The first factor that should be considered is the fact that geopolitics are taking on
new and unpredictable dimensions as emerging powers such as China, Russia,
and Brazil jockey to improve their positions and forge coalitions (Mead 2014).
Although each of these countries has pursued its own strategy vis-à-vis the U.S.
and the EU, they have all in some way or another attempted to overturn the existing balance of power. On one front, China’s territorial ambitions in Asia have
triggered tensions with both the US and Japan. While on another, Putin’s new
Russia has been playing the geopolitical card for all it is worth in countries that
once formed part of the Soviet Union, testing the resolve of the U.S. and the EU
by seizing Crimea and stoking the flames of civil conflict in Ukraine (Stavridis
2014).
Much has been written regarding the TTIP’s geopolitical importance and
whether it was conceived to serve as a fulcrum with which to rebalance world
power neatly between the US and Europe as a block and emerging powers. As
we well know, trade has never been neutral; it has always been a highly sensitive
matter in international relations. The reservations expressed at the July 2014 Fortaleza Summit by the leaders of BRICS nations (Brazil, Russia, China, India, and
South Africa) regarding the implementation of the TTIP were accompanied by
concrete measures intended to offset the impact of the U.S.-EU agreement: the
establishment of a new global reserve currency and the creation of a new development bank with an initial capital worth US$ 50 billion. Although these countries have not formally expressed their opposition to the TTIP agreement as a
block, they are making it abundantly clear that the type of trade liberalization
supposed by the TTIP agreement has ramifications that transcend the issue of
global trade. The fact that it will not suppose a win-win game for all non-TTIP
countries and there will inevitably be winners and losers, gives it a strong geopolitical dimension on par with other challenging issues such as nuclear nonproliferation, human rights, and climate change.
The TTIP agreement has therefore evolved from being a mere bi-regional
regulatory framework with ramifications for global governance to constituting a
political tool for defending the dominant role of the U.S., Europe (and by extension, NATO) in world affairs. Recent moves on the part of other major world
powers will undoubtedly up the pressure on both TTIP negotiating teams. If the
US and the EU want to save face and successfully assert their role as the joint
institutors of the international rules of good governance, they must reach an
agreement – which it to say practically any kind of agreement – soon. Failure to
do so would result in an enormous loss of credibility and prestige for both. As a
Palacio - 93
result, it could weaken their bargaining positions with China and Russia and undermine the effectiveness of other free trade initiatives such the recently negotiated TPP and The Pacific Alliance and the more established MERCOSUR. Also,
we should not forget that the initiation of negotiations toward a transatlantic partnership coincided with the first signs of a fall in the growth of Brazil’s domestic
market, the deceleration of the Chinese and Russian economies, and the slowdown of commodities prices. BRICS have good reasons to be wary of any regulatory framework devised by the Western countries.
The U.S., the EU, and the Economic Slowdown
The effects of the emerging market slowdown forecast for 2015-16 will have an
impact on the upcoming phase of TTIP negotiations. BRICS countries are now
facing new economic challenges. The IMF lowered forecasts for global economic
growth to 3.5 percent for 2015 and 3.7 percent for 2016, as indicated on its January 2015 World Economic Outlook. This projection stresses the flagging growth
potential of emerging markets. Forecasted growth for China, whose economy is
expected to suffer a gradual slowdown, has been lowered by -0.3 percent to 6.8
percent and growth in Brazil is expected to fall -1.1 percent to 0.3 percent. The
outlook for Russia is even worse: a plunge of -3.5 percent, which, according to
the IMF, will precipitate a deep recession. The IMF report also predicts lower oil
prices and the further depreciation of both the euro and yen. In contrast, the US
economy is expected to grow by 3.6 percent and growth in the Eurozone to slip
slightly (-0.2 percent to 1.2 percent). Although Eurozone countries face the risk
of permanent deflation, they are set to benefit strongly from lower oil prices, the
lower exchange rate of the euro, and an easing of lending conditions. A tightening of the US monetary policy could trigger volatility in the financial markets of
emerging countries (IMF 2015).
These forecasts cannot be expected to have a conclusive impact on the
future of TTIP negotiations, especially in view of the fact that TTIP negotiations
were launched as part of a liberalizing agenda largely conceived and justified
(especially in Europe) as a means of overcoming the crisis and facilitating the
recovery of world economy. However, two considerations should figure strongly
in any long-term U.S.–EU strategy. The first is related to medium and long-term
economic trends (Pascual-Ramsay and Imbernón Sáinz 2014). Over the past decade, BRICS have accounted for close to 50 percent of the world’s growth. They
currently account for 25 percent of world GDP, a proportion expected to peak at
40 percent by 2050. The economic output of China will surpass that of the U.S.
(in nominal terms) by 2050 and the output of Brazil and India will outpace that of
Germany, France, and the UK by 2060 (Wilson et al. 2011). Should the TTIP
agreement collapse, and no other multilateral agreement is reached, and these
forecasts prove to be accurate, it is natural to assume that emerging countries will
forge their own trade agreements, which may not meet the TTIP governance
Palacio - 94
standards. It must also be remembered that the intertwined nature of export and
foreign direct investment flows make it impossible to postulate that a slowdown
of Russia or China would spark greater support for the TTIP agreement in the US
and Europe. In other words, while geopolitics may be a zero-sum game, the
world economy is not. The instrumentalization of world trade rules for geopolitical motives has its limits: as the relative success of the WTO Doha round meeting held in Bali in December 2013 has shown, the agenda for world governance
also matters. Yet, both partners seem trapped between two conflicting political
imperatives: attending to current geopolitical concerns and working responsibly
toward good governance. In this context, it seems reasonable to conclude that
the combination of two new factors (geopolitical challenges and economic slowdown) is not good news for the U.S., the EU, or the TTIP negotiations underway.
The Domestic Factors
The above-mentioned geopolitics and emerging market dynamics aside, domestic
political dynamics will also play a decisive role in TTIP negotiations to be conducted during 2015 and 2016.
U.S.’s backers of the TTIP agreement must overcome substantial domestic resistance, although it is still not clear whether or not it will become a hot issue during the 2016 Presidential election campaign. American congressmen on
both sides of the aisle have repeatedly expressed their opposition to a “fast track”
international trade agreement such as the TTIP or the TTP – without which it is
very difficult to negotiate a meaningful deal. As many left-leaning American voters believe that free trade agreements endanger environmental protection, labor
rights, and import safety standards, Democratic representatives naturally tend to
shy away from political commitments on trade issues that could erode their electoral base of support. Although Republicans may support free trade at a philosophical level, they could be reluctant to support any agreement that would hand
a political victory to President Obama. Furthermore, the call for a renewal of
trade promotion authority (TPA) contained in President Obama’s sixth State of
the Union address delivered on January 20, 2015, was not warmly received.
Obama’s request was fiercely opposed by Democrats such as Harry Reid (majority leader of the Senate at that time) grounded on the argument that support for
fast-track approval would hurt Democrats in the November 2014 midterm elections.
Since the Republicans have retaken control of the Senate, perspectives
for a deal between the President and the Congress on the TPA have not improved, despite Republican pretensions to support free trade. Options for resolving the current gridlock include the possibility of circumventing the fast-track
system provided for in the Trade Act of 1974 by creating specific ad hoc TPAs
that covered only certain countries and specific topics such as the environment,
labor rights, and health and giving a higher profile to congressmen directly in-
Palacio - 95
volved in the negotiations. Nonetheless, given the threat of severe recession now
looming over the U.S.’s European allies, the political and security implications of
the TTIP agreement may yet trigger U.S. bipartisan support for making a deal.
The EU, on the other hand, has never been a geopolitical player in the
sense that the U.S., Russia, and China have assumed that role. It has no grand
strategy of dominion over others and continues to maintain a postmodern perspective on world order; an attitude that will become even more deeply entrenched while the Eurozone struggles to recover and the current North-South
gap within Europe remains unabridged. Therefore, no geopolitical sense of urgency to rush to a final agreement can be expected to arise in Europe in the short
term.
Resistance in Europe to a liberalizing trade pact can be largely attributed
to the effects of low growth rates, high unemployment (especially in states along
the continent’s southern periphery), a rise in protectionist sentiment, social unrest, and a general climate of political disaffection. Despite official efforts to sell
the agreement as a mechanism for spurring growth and restoring the European
economy, public awareness rests on the idea that the current economic hardships
are largely the result of the economic and financial integration that left European
economies exposed to the collateral effects of the American Great Recession.
Such perception serves as a deal breaker on any attempt to implement a “liberal”
approach.
The eighth round of talks took place from February 2nd to the 6th, 2015 in
Brussels under the leadership of EU Trade Commissioner Cecilia Malmström
and U.S. Trade Representative Michael Froman. However, lingering doubts
about the feasibility of the € 315 billion Juncker plan have generated skepticism
in Europe (especially in Southern European countries and France) regarding
both: the much-trumpeted but fairly anemic European economic “recovery” and
the real benefits of a trade deal with the US that may well imply high social
costs. Europe’s institutional framework could also slow down the negotiations to
the point that they eventually derailed. Given the high sensitivity, of sector lobbies in member states and European citizens hit by the crisis, on issues involving
banks and big corporations, the European Parliament – the only EU institution
whose members are directly responsible to European voters - will undoubtedly
play a decisive role in the process.
Although negotiators have made progress on points such as technical
trade barriers, state-owned enterprises, customs and trade facilitation, and telecom services, they have yet to overcome differences regarding issues Europeans
perceive as critical such as labor rights, consumer safety regulations, and environmental protection.
It is therefore no surprise that sensitive points will be negotiated at the
highest political level. The first among them is the inclusion of an investor-state
dispute settlement (ISDS) mechanism, by which foreign investors may bring cases against the countries in which they have invested before an arbitration tribunal
Palacio - 96
should they feel their financial interests have been harmed or discriminated
against. The devil is in the details when it comes to democracy, transparency,
environmental protection, labor rights, and consumer protection. Given the close
integration of the U.S. and the EU financial markets, the financial sector regulation—especially when currently targeting unregulated derivatives and similar
instruments—is bound to be a make-or-break issue from the European perspective (EU Commission 2014). The present opinion in Europe is that any deal failing to safeguard Europe’s financial resilience from future crises, similar to the
subprime crisis of 2008, would not be worth signing. Apart from the give and
take of negotiations regarding the inclusion of an ISDS instrument or the agriculture, audiovisual, and financial sectors, there is also the economic climate to consider. While the European Parliament’s International Trade Committee (INTA) is
expected to present a resolution on TTIP at the May 2015 plenary session, any
serious deterioration of economic conditions in the Eurozone could completely
derail negotiations.
Paradoxically, the European Parliament, a frequently criticized and undervalued institution, will have the final word on the sensitive issues yet to be
resolved during the last round of the TTIP process. Under pressure by European
civil society organizations, INTA chairman Bernd Lange forced the public release of the European Council’s mandate to negotiate, which had been keep under wraps until the fall of 2014. This was a first step forward in terms of closing a
transparency gap that has loomed over the negotiations since the beginning (EU
Commission 2015). However, no agreement will be possible without cross-party
consensus within the EP. In principle, the TTIP agreement enjoys the support of
majority groups in the European Parliament (the center-right European People’s
Party, the Progressive Alliance of Liberals and Democrats for Europe, and the
European Conservatives and Reformists), which all regard the deal as a means of
promoting employment and growth in Europe. However, groups that focus on
highly sensitive environmental or social issues such as the Greens and the United
Left have respectively distanced themselves from the process or outwardly rejected it (Pavón Losada 2014). As they remain very reluctant to accept many
proposed tenets of TTIP and continue to strongly demand standards protecting
the rights of workers and the environment and the inclusion of binding common
regulation of transatlantic financial transactions, the Socialists could assume the
role of bridge-builder between the two sides. Given that a comprehensive TTIP
agreement would need to be ratified by all 28 member states of the European Union, approaching the Greens and left-leaning MEPs who currently reject the deal
and attempt to build strong coalitions on this issue would appear to be a good
strategy for easing the path to parliamentary ratification. In particular, in the light
of the strong gains made by these forces at the national level during elections in
Greece and the forecasted success of their Spanish counterparts in the upcoming
Spanish general elections. In any case, it appears that consensus on the desirability of a transatlantic agreement will be more difficult to achieve in Europe, where
Palacio - 97
geopolitical positioning does not have the importance it could be expected to assume during ratification debates in the US Congress.
What can we learn from the domestic shortfalls of the countries and the
barriers that have prevented them from reaching a consensus over the last two
years? Put fairly simple, Americans and Europeans are moving in the same direction but playing on different chessboards. Their most irresolvable differences are
related to labor rights, environmental protection, and the regulation of financial
markets – issues at the very top of the global governance agenda. Trade is, and
has always been, an element of national strategy, the ramifications of which extend beyond mere economics (Froman 2014); it is nothing less than “politics by
other means.” Whereas the TTIP agreement may be perceived as a question of
geopolitical leverage from an American perspective, it is viewed in the EU as an
opportunity to further the implementation of good governance practices. Some
voices in Europe have called for an accelerated, minimalist deal focusing mainly
on the elimination of remaining non-tariff barriers (Dullen and Janning 2015).
However, given that such a treaty would do little more than underline the differences between their socio-economic models, geopolitical concerns, and visions
of global governance, it might not be the best option for either of the negotiating
partners, especially in terms of their international leverage. If Europeans want to
lead this process somewhere, it would be more advantageous for them to draw a
few clear red lines on politically controversial issues such structural regulation
than to sign a hurried, minimalist treaty that would offer only dubious, or at best,
modest benefits.
Conclusion: Geopolitics and Beyond
Since President Obama and the European Commission announced their intention
to start the transatlantic trade negotiations in February 2013 strong political factors have had a continual impact on such process. Current differences between
the two prospective partners stem largely from the divergent ways in which political factors are affecting them: the economic and social post-crisis circumstances
that inform their respective positions are radically different.
The success of the TTIP agreement is imperiled by least three factors:
marked geopolitical shifts, uncertainty generated by the slowdown of emerging
markets, and political and institutional constraints imposed by the U.S. Congress,
the European Parliament, the governments of various European states, and last
but not least, civil society organizations on both sides of the Atlantic. Firstly, recent moves by the leaders of major emerging powers such as Russia, China, and
Brazil within their spheres of influence and their critical positioning on TTIP exclusions, have added a sense of drama and urgency to transatlantic relations.
From their perspective, the U.S. is using both the TTIP negotiations and the concept of transatlantic trade as geopolitical tools. For the Obama administration,
free trade agreements such as the TTIP and the TTP are part of a broader strate-
Palacio - 98
gic campaign to secure American global dominance. A successfully negotiated
TTIP agreement would mean replacing an antiquated trade system dating back to
the end of World War II with a web of cutting-edge agreements that ensured the
U.S. position as the linchpin of world trade. In contrast, for the EU—which lacks
a “strategic culture”—the TTIP is generally perceived as an additional means of
bringing an end to the economic crisis, defining new economic, social, and environmental models, and shaping global governance. Secondly, the emerging market slowdown forecasted for 2015-16 could have an impact on the upcoming
phase of TTIP negotiations in that it will exacerbate the atmosphere of political
uncertainty in which positions taken by the US, Europe, and other economic superpowers will be developed. The slowdown of the BRICS economies leaves the
U.S. in particular with the dilemma as to whether it would be more advantageous
to play the geopolitical card for all it is worth or to promote global governance
and world economic recovery.
Thirdly, various forces within the U.S. Congress, the European Parliament and the governments of European states are mounting opposition to the
agreement. It will not be easy to resolve the current impasse caused by differences over the possible inclusion of structural regulations that have become hot
issues on both sides of the Atlantic such as an ISDS clause and strong guarantees
for labor rights and environmental standards. Given the lingering effects of the
economic crisis in Europe, the regulation of financial markets is crystallizing into
a European requisite for any serious deal that may be eventually struck.
The final phase of negotiations will be extremely challenging. However,
even if the upcoming trade negotiations fall short of delivering a speedy agreement in 2015 or expectations are lowered, the idea of forging a transatlantic partnership should not be abandoned. U.S. negotiators need to realize that given the
current political and social situation in Europe, any deal that could further imperil
a European economic and social “acquis” already sorely tested by the current
crisis is out of the question. To ease the way for future negotiations and the eventual ratification of the treaty by the EU Parliament and the EU member states,
any red lines drawn by EU negotiators should be pegged to clear regulatory pillars.
Once again, we are facing the revenge of politics. The consequences of
abandoning efforts to reach a comprehensive agreement or signing a devaluated
deal would likely be quite similar: either move would transmit a negative signal
to emerging powers, harm the geopolitical leverage of both partners, and reduce
the prospects for global governance on issues that go beyond trade. The problem
negotiators face at this point is that the window of opportunity for pursuing a
third option is rapidly narrowing.
References
Dullen, Sebastian, and Janning, Josef. 2015. “A Fresh Start for TTIP.” ECFR
Palacio - 99
Policy Brief. February 2015, accessed at http://www.ecfr.eu/page/-/ECF
R124_-_TTIP.pdf.
EU Commission. 2014. “EU-US Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership.
Cooperation on financial and services regulation,” 27.1. 2014.
EU Commission. 2015. “European Commission publishes legal texts as part of
transparency initiative.” Brussels 7 January 205, accessed at http://trade
.ec.europa.eu/doclib/press/index.cfm?id=1231.
Froman,, Michael B. 2014. “The Strategic Logic of Trade. New Rules of the Road for the
Global Market.”Foreign Affairs, November-December 2014.
International Monetary Fund. 2015. “World Economic Report.” January 2015,
accessed at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2015/update/01/.
Mead, Walter Russell. 2014. “The Return of Geopolitics. The Revenge of the
Revisionist Powers.” Foreign Affairs, May-June 2014.
Pascual-Ramsay, Angel and Imbernón Sáinz, Álvaro. 2014. “The World in 2030:
Global Trends and Risks That Will Shape the World over the Next 20
Years.” ESADEgeo. Position paper 36. October.
Pavón Losada, Juan Antonio. 2014. “European Parliament and the TTIP: final
stage of the EU US negotiations.” Fundación Alternativas. Opex Memorandum Nº 190/2014.
Stavridis, James. 2014. “Vladimir Putin Hates the TTIP.” Foreign Policy, 19 November 2014.
Wilson, Dominic et al. 2011. “The BRICs 10 Years On: Halfway through the
Great Transformation.” Goldman Sachs, Global Economics Paper No.
208. 7 December 2011.
Symmetries and Asymmetries in Integration Processes:
The New Atlantic Community
Javier Bonilla Saus
Pedro Isern Munne
Universidad ORT Uruguay
Abstract
Integration processes are beneficial and necessary. However, we must stress the
fact that for certain actors in certain contexts, integration does not always translate into optimum results. For example, we can reasonably think that there will be
negative consequences for a small country with high-quality institutions (such as
Uruguay) if it integrates with larger countries with low-quality institutions.
Moreover, this problem is not solved by subsuming a complex and opaque area
(such as MERCOSUR –Southern Common Market) under a larger and transparent agreement (such as a potential one between MERCOSUR and the European
Union). Can countries with solid, transparent institutions successfully integrate
with countries with weak, corrupt institutions? Can this hypothetical integration
process really be so simple?
Introduction
Both in the academic and business spheres, we almost systematically underline
without so much as a second thought “the benefits” that integration processes
“naturally” bring about.
This "optimistic" approach to integration most probably stems from a
view held by international trade specialists - a view that is tinged with an understandable concern about encouraging free trade.
However, the integration of countries or regions (even only in terms of
trade) is not something that can be a priori considered good or bad. To illustrate,
the final outcome of an integration process like the one we are addressing here,
taking into account the number of actors involved, depends on a myriad of complex variables. We could tentatively summarize these variables as follows: (a) the
European Union (EU) internal policy; (b) the United States (US) internal policy;
(c) variables that are truly intangible and that we could call Latin American
Countries (LAC) “internal policies,” are yet to be determined. They mainly regard Brazil’s position, MERCOSUR (Southern Common Market), the Pacific
players that still have to be fully identified, and special situations such as the Cuban question that has just gained prominence. Other variables to consider are, (d)
the commercial, economic, political conditions under which the EU and the US
Bonilla and Isern - 102
negotiations occur today; (e) the current state of negotiations between the US and
LAC; and (f) the current state of negotiations between the EU and LAC.
Evidently, there are clear asymmetries among these points: a, b, and d,
are presumably more important than the others. Moreover, we are aware that if
we were to carry out an analysis of the variables that are, in turn, included in each
point, the whole exercise would make little –if any– sense.
So, it seems pertinent to proceed in a more descriptive way and narrow
the topic to questions about the traits that a satisfactory integration process
should display. With more epistemological modesty, we will try to answer fundamental questions such as: With whom, how, and for what reasons, should integration take place?
The potential “New Atlantic Community” creates great possibilities that
encourage exploring –at least partially– some conceptual aspects of these three
questions. For this, we must revise various explicit and implicit concepts that will
come into play if this initiative effectively moves forward.
Addressing Problematic Issues
The first problematic element that we should question is the idea that geography
(taken as the territorial “closeness” between countries) is the main factor in determining which will be the best placed actors in a successful integration process.
We are aware that history seems to contradict our position, but we believe that when the idea of “closeness” intervenes in an integration process that it
is used to hide the fact that integration among countries rests in a form of proximity that is much more important than geography. Geographical “closeness”
hide the importance of pre-existing historical or cultural dimensions (linguistic,
religious, political, etc.), rather than strictly geographical proximity. Even though
most cases of integration have taken place between countries “close” to each other, a careful examination of these cases shows that “geographical closeness” allows for more complex forms of “closeness” and that the latter ends up playing a
greater role in successful integration processes.
Integration experiences such as Central America Free Trade (CAFTA) or
the Nordic Council, which are seemingly based on adjacency and close territorial
vicinity, are in fact based on pre-existing common political or cultural experiences. Everything indicates that the prior, long coexistence under the Captaincy
General of Guatemala during colonial times is what upheld the cohesion of the
Central American integration experience during the twentieth century.1
The integration of the Nordic countries is a slightly different case. These
countries created a Nordic Council in 1952, which is an inter-parliamentary co1
Panama is not part of CAFTA because it came into being by separating from New Granada, an independent from the Captaincy of Guatemala.
Bonilla and Isern - 103
operation and integration experience. In this case, geographical closeness may
also be invoked.2 But, its historical precedent comes from the existence, in the
fifteenth century, of the Kalmar Union that joined the “Scandinavian” and “Nordic” people all together. And later, throughout the next three centuries, they were
all grouped into two kingdoms: Denmark and Norway under one crown and
Sweden under another. In sum, the “Nordic Council” is based on a common history more than on geographical closeness.
A second point we should stress is that we also intend to purposely leave
out two arguments that are most often cited by economists and international trade
specialists as the foundation of a “good integration process.” These bases are
built on two overused ideas. On the one hand, is the idea that an integration process is essentially a process of “trade” (or at best, of “economies”) with successive and more encompassing stages? Political, institutional, and cultural issues
are only relevant if they affect the integration of “trade.” In this sense, it is important to recall and link to our topic the impressive concept of development of
William Easterly in The Tyranny of Experts: Economists, Dictators, and the Forgotten Rights of the Poor (2013).
As we will see, the European Union is an example that contradicts this
vision because, from its outset, it contemplated horizons of integration that went
far beyond trade. The European Coal and Steel Community, the backbone of European construction, goes beyond the production of coal and steel and addresses
trade and political aspects linked with these industrial sectors.
In an opposite way, initiatives like NAFTA (North American Free Trade
Agreement) only aimed for what would be a “second tier” trade arrangement
among three markets: a simple free trade agreement that merely transcended the
typical “preferential treatments” and never intended on going beyond that.3
On the other hand, so as to eventually have the conceptual tools that
would allow us to identify what a “good integration process” looks like we must
also question another integration “cliché.” We are all familiar with the claim
about the need for economies that join an integration process to have “a reasonably high degree of complementarity.” This expression has a classic interpreta-
2
But in a much less obvious way than in the previous example. Here we have the peculiarity of Denmark being geographically contiguous to “continental” Europe, just like Estonia and Latvia were and who, only under Soviet pressure, cut ties with the Scandinavian world and became part of the Soviet word. There are also other territories that are relatively distant –like Greenland– who, being dependent, were always part of this peculiar
Nordic “integration”.
3
This is different from MERCOSUR, which was initially thought of as an integration
process for a Customs Union but ended up being so imperfect that it boasts a lower degree of liberalization than a Free Trade Agreement. See a good paper written by Baldwin
(1993).
Bonilla and Isern - 104
tion.4 But, it must be explained. We know this reasoning is antiquated and blatantly false: it is not true that, in order to integrate successfully, country A must
be efficient in producing a good that country B lacks, and vice versa. This belief
is set in the Ricardian thought mentioned in the footnote below.
The creation of the Latin American Integration Association (ALADI)
was an integration process that was based on finding complements. We must note
that here, “complement” is a euphemism. In fact, this idea of integration implies
the absence of competition. That is, country “A” produces a good that country
“B” does not have, and country “B” produces a good that country “A” does not
have. Therefore, the producers of both goods find the size of their markets has
grown – markets that are, in fact “protected.”
To sum up, we are trying to set aside some of the most overused bases of
the integration discourse before we introduce the main thesis of this article. We
only intend to analyse the importance and effects of two elements that are often
overlooked and seldom put together when studying the terms and effects that integration processes can jumpstart. These are: (i) the relative size of the economies that will integrate (exclusively in relation to each other); and, (ii) the degree
of efficacy of the existing rule of law and the relative institutional quality of the
(formal) legal systems and (informal) regulatory systems that operate in the two
societies in question.
Economic Scale and Institutional Quality: Symmetries and Asymmetries in
the Integration Processes
As mentioned above, in this section we are going to analyse the idea that the benefits and drawbacks for two hypothetical countries in an integration process depend on two main variables: (i) the relative size of the economies; and, (ii) the
quality of each country’s institutional and legal system.
The relative size reflects the different economic weight of each country
in relation to the other. The institutional quality reflects the efficacy of the legal
system and the ability of laws, political-business leaders, and bureaucracies to
carry out an efficient and reasonable integration agreement. This also includes
the ability of different civil societies to control the dynamics of this agreement.
It is generically possible to claim (and it is almost obvious) that integration is a good thing when it involves two or more actors of high institutional
quality; it is neutral or bad when it involves actors of high and low institutional
quality; and it is bad or very bad when it involves actors of low institutional quality. At the same time, our approach considers that the size of the actors is as important as the institutional quality when it comes to judging the convenience of
4
The idea of trade “complementarity” between two countries comes from Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage. To summarize, “complementarity” arises because England
produces textiles efficiently and Portugal produces wine efficiently. Ricardo’s two economies would be, in current terms, two “complementary” economies.
Bonilla and Isern - 105
integration. And at this point, a similar obvious claim can be repeated: countries
whose economies are similar in size seem to foster more promising integration
processes. However, things are hardly ever this simple.
Some illustrative examples will help clarify “an integration process” between two countries using their relative economic scales and institutional quality.5
Case 1: Can an Integration Process that Involves a Large Economy Lodged
in a Country with High-Quality Institutions and one or More Small Countries with Low-Quality Rule of Law Be Promising?
Here is an example: with CAFTA, a country with high institutional quality such
as the United States has fostered an integration process with small economies
lodged in countries of low and very low institutional quality (with the sole exception of Costa Rica).
We can rightly assume that the institutional shortcomings of Guatemala,
Costa Rica, El Salvador, Honduras, and Nicaragua will neither harm nor enrich
the institutional quality of the integration process, nor will they greatly affect the
United States “civic life.”6 At the same time, apart from the benefits brought
about by trade relations, possible coordination of production, and other economic
developments; obviously the larger economy’s greater respect for the law and its
legal organization will become an incentive7 for smaller economies with weaker
institutions to improve and strengthen themselves.
But in general terms, and setting aside the concepts questioned at the beginning of this work, we can conclude that in this case we can foresee an integration process that will benefit all actors.
Case 2: Can Countries with Small Economies and Good Institutions Truly
Benefit from Integrating with Large Countries with Bad Institutions?
5
We are not taking into account cases in which the countries’ two traits (economic scale
and institutional quality) coincide.
6
We must note that even in countries with solid institutions do procedures and modus
operandi manage to filter in and operate outside the law. For example, Mexico’s immigration, drug trafficking, and organized crime does affect the United States However, this
does not lead us to question the United States’ overall institutional quality and rule of
law.
7
Experience shows that the legal organization of countries and their institutional systems
are complex historical products. Although the integration with economies and societies
that have more organized legal systems and show more respect for the law should have a
positive effect, we cannot be naïve and say that, for example, Central American countries´ institutional shortcomings will disappear.
Bonilla and Isern - 106
In many ways, this second case is the “opposite” of the previous case. Uruguay’s
complex situation is a historical example of this scenario. It is a very small economy that is lodged in a society where the rule of law and institutions are generally of relatively high quality. From 1991 to the present day, Uruguay has endured
an integration process with two much larger economies (Argentina is 9.6 times
larger than Uruguay and Brazil is 40 times larger than Uruguay) that are lodged
in countries with permanent lack of legal guarantees, institutional weakness and
general disregard for the law (including the laws that are directly related to and
were agreed on in the integration process).
This scenario proves difficult for a small country with a relatively high
institutional quality. The larger economies tend to impose conditions on the
smaller economy. And this is aggravated because the larger economies disregard
the rules they had agreed to and constantly behave in an arbitrary manner. Argentina’s trade policy (not to mention other policies) with Uruguay over the last five
years is proof of this. The integration process may be interrupted or simply left to
expire and be abandoned by the least favoured country. However, we must note
that in this case, it is the weaker country. Then, it seems to be clear that the mainstream approach to the benefits of trade blocks lacks a better and careful understanding as North, Wallis and Weingast have argued (2009, 2013).
Case 3: What Prospects are there for an Integration Process Involving Two
Large Economies of Different Institutional Quality, Where One Actor’s Institutional Organization Is Much Less Developed than the Others?
This could be the case of a hypothetical integration between the United States
and China or India. Taking into account that this example is farfetched –for now–
we could imagine that disagreements stemming from differences in institutional
quality and respect for the law would move into more political spheres. When
“great powers” clash, the economic dimension and geopolitical strength tend to
minimize the regulating role of laws. Even the recourse to international law and
multilateral institutions is difficult due to the scale of the economies in question.
The current trade development between the aforementioned countries indicates that, even though they are far from any type of integration, the disregard
of American laws, the use of falsification, the disrespect for patents, etc., especially by China, have become constant sources of conflict. Could they become an
important problem of legal control for the United States?
Could the United States’ better laws have a greater influence over the institutional framework of integration than China’s feeble ones? In economies of
this scale, we could expect political pressures to arise – far from the debate on
integration. For example, China is the largest bondholder of the United States
Treasury. This point is relevant because our intuition tells us that if there are two
equal actors and one has good institutions and the other has weak institutions, the
bad institutions would have more influence over a possible integration process.
Bonilla and Isern - 107
That is, an obscure bureaucracy’s ability to veto or boycott would be greater that
a transparent bureaucracy’s ability to influence. Integrating large economies is
difficult, but we must hope that ultimately, political power would seemingly
manage the conflicts created by the great economy of lower institutional quality.
Case 4: What Would Happen in an Integration Process Involving Two Small
Economies, One with High-Quality Institutions and the other with LowQuality Ones?
This case would once again show that when the economic scale of the countries
is similar, the integration process tends to turn into a political struggle. In this
struggle, the country with higher-quality institutions puts up a political fight so
that the country with lower-quality institutions respects the established rules.
It is difficult to find a convincing historical example to illustrate this
8
case. Despite what is presented in the footnote, because we are dealing with relatively small economies, the country with higher-quality institutions may find it
relatively easy to use in its favour the existing legal tools that are available in the
supranational.
Case 5: What Would Become of the Integration of Large Economies, both
with Good Institutions?
This scenario is particularly pertinent here. Setting aside difficulties related to
trade issues, we could say that this case presupposes the existence of necessary
but not sufficient conditions to create an institutional framework that brings both
actors into a positive sum game. Given the complex nature of the EU and the
United States, the final negotiations of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership (TTIP) will soon show to what extent a promising set of necessary
conditions –that is, the high quality of US and EU’s institutions– will prove to be
a strong starting point for the arrangement to succeed.
Other Cases
It is possible to come up with more combinations of the two variables we are interested in. For example, a large country integrating with a small one, both with
low-quality institutions; a large economy with high-quality institutions integrating with a small economy also with high-quality institutions, etc. But, given the
narrow scope of this work, we cannot outline all the possible combinations and
their peculiarities.
8
The example of Costa Rica and Nicaragua entails an institutional relationship between a
small country with good institutions and a small country with bad institutions. When
faced with a country of equal weight, it is difficult that the push for a transparent institutional framework be greater than the ability to hinder its creation.
Bonilla and Isern - 108
An Exception: the European Union
The European Union is the most sophisticated and relevant integration process to
date. This agreement has developed different expressions (fiscal, trade, legal,
monetary) and its comparative value makes it analytically relevant to us. Europe
is composed by large, medium, and small countries, and countries with highquality, some with medium-quality institutions and a few with low-quality institutions.
The European experience is also relevant for another reason. As mentioned above, integration processes are invariably carried out following rules that
were set by their potential members’ political leaders and bureaucracies. It may
be true that the institutional quality of an integration process cannot be greater
than the sum of the quality of its parts. That is, if countries A, B, and C are structurally corrupt and inefficient, the new agreement will most likely be corrupt and
inefficient.
But, the opposite is not necessarily true: transparent and efficient countries can undertake an integration process that ends up having a lower institutional quality than those of its members. In some ways, the European Union is an
example of this. Even though it has achieved a sophisticated and complex level
of integration, disputes over certain issues remain unsolved. For example, the
development of a European defence system has not been able to overcome the
resistance posed by national military structures.
Facing the Possibility of the New Atlantic Community
The possible EU / US / LAC integration will certainly translate into an opportunity to improve LAC institutions. We could say it is almost obvious that an integration process among these three actors will bring about positive consequences. As in the case of the incorporation of former Soviet-bloc countries to the EU,
it is likely that the creation of regional institutions would –to a certain extent–
strengthen laws and mechanisms of control, and inject some degree of transparency and efficiency into the unreliable legal framework of most Latin American
countries.
If countries like Uruguay were to look for “exit options” from arrangements like MERCOSUR, these options would have to be moderate enough so as
not to distress its larger members (Brazil and Argentina). With this in mind, is it
true that a way out of MERCOSUR would be to blend it into an even greater
trade and investment society, such as EU-MERCOSUR, where Argentina and
Brazil would have main roles in negotiations? Would this “Atlantic Community”
not generate the same problematic logic for small or relatively small countries
with high-quality institutions, like Chile, Uruguay, or Costa Rica? In other
words: in a negotiation with the United States or the EU, what is good for MERCOSUR, will be necessarily good for Uruguay as well?
Bonilla and Isern - 109
The complexities of this initiative are obviously enormous. Maybe we
should resort to new proposals. One proposal entails exploring the idea of creating “optimum institutional areas,” stemming from Robert Mundell’s concept of
an “optimum currency area.” According to Mundell an optimum monetary area
is:
“The geographic area in which a single currency would create
the greatest economic benefit. While traditionally each country
has maintained its own separate currency, work by Robert Mundell in the 1960s theorizes that this may not be the most efficient
economic arrangement. In particular, countries which share
strong economic ties may benefit from a common currency. This
allows for closer integration of capital markets and facilitates
trade. However, a common currency results in a loss of each
country's ability to direct fiscal and monetary policy interventions to stabilize their economies” (1961: 660).
Undoubtedly, this arrangement would not be simple. What would an “optimum institutional area” look like? How should we define it? It is an integration
process involving two (or more) actors with at least one common “convergence”
indicator: size or institutional quality – or lacking that, with asymmetries of size
or institutional quality that do not harm one or more of the actors.
In short, what we dare to call an “optimum institutional area” would be
nothing less than the joint determination from all the countries participating in
the integration process of a minimum institutional quality of integration – an integration that is agreed on by all its members. In other words, we are referring to
an institutional quality that, apart from being agreed on by every member, will
inevitably end up being supranational.
What we are referring to – even though we refer to it as an “optimum institutional area”– is an institutional arrangement similar to what has emerged
from Brussels for the European Union over the last decades. Whether or not this
arrangement is possible or even imaginable for our New Atlantic Community – it
is a different matter.
References
Baldwin, Robert. 1993. A Domino Theory of Regionalism, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Working Paper, No. 4465. September.
Easterly, William. 2013. The Tyranny of Experts: Economists, Dictators, and the
Forgotten Rights of the Poor. New York: Basic Books.
Mundell, Robert. 1961. A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas. The American
Bonilla and Isern - 110
Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4, 657–665.
North, Douglass, John Wallis, Barry Weingast. 2009. Violence and Social Or
ders. A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass, John Wallis, Steven B. Webb and Barry Weingast 2013. In the
Shadow of Violence. Politics, Economics, and the Problems of Development, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Trade, Regional Integration, and Free Movement of People
Willem Maas
York University / European University Institute1
Abstract
A building block of regional integration in Europe has been the development of
supranational rights, particularly the rights of citizens of member states to live
elsewhere in the community. Since the first free movement rights in the early
1950s, the concept of a common EU citizenship has hardened into law, most famously in the Court of Justice’s oft-repeated assertion that “Union citizenship is
destined to be the fundamental status of nationals of the Member States.” By contrast, efforts to foster the free movement of people in groupings such as
CARICOM, the Andean Community, MERCOSUR, and UNASUR have so far
been relatively modest. Nevertheless, actors within each of those organizations
have or are considering supranational rights, thus it is useful to ask about the prospects of common free movement rights and perhaps eventually citizenship, focused foremost on the right of member state nationals to live and work elsewhere
within the community. The paper’s underlying argument is that successful and
stable regional integration efforts must include free movement rights for people.
Introduction
In a speech at Yale University about the Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership (TTIP) currently being negotiated between Europe and the United
States, the European Commission Vice-President Viviane Reding argued that “a
single market requires fundamental changes in which nation states cooperate.
They must abolish their prerogative to establish border controls, excise customs
duties, guarantee the free movement of people, goods, services and capital, etc.
Overall, they must guarantee each of their own citizens and of every other member state of the European Union the same, Europe-wide enforceable rights.”
(Reding 2013) This idea that free movement of persons is central to the European
project, and perhaps also other regional integration efforts, is something I find
persuasive because I have been making similar arguments for a while (Maas
2005; 2007; 2009; 2013a; 2014a; 2014b).
The argument is that, alongside the economic logic of integration, European leaders share a political commitment to creating a common community of
1
This research was supported by a Marie Curie International Incoming Fellowship within
the 7th European Community Framework Programme. Thanks to the European University
Institute for hosting my research and to Jean Monnet Professor Joaquín Roy, University
of Miami, for inviting me to participate in this workshop.
Maas - 112
people, and that this commitment has gradually resulted in the creation of a
common citizenship. The most important rights of the supranational citizenship
involve free movement rights to live and work anywhere within the common territory, which is the foundation of a political community. Though always in tension with the desires of member state governments to maintain control over their
borders and to decide who can live within their territory, the right of EU citizens
to live anywhere within the EU is vigorously defended by central institutions
such as the Commission and the Court. While it works in the European context,
the relationship between trade agreements, regional integration, and free movement of people elsewhere is not always clear.
In this short paper I counterpoise the example of EU citizenship and nascent efforts in Latin America to develop forms of regional citizenship, to argue
that successful and deeply rooted regional integration efforts must include free
movement rights for people, and not simply the free movement of goods, capital,
and services. The paper proceeds as follows: in the next section, I sketch the development of free movement rights in Europe. Then, I discuss some efforts to
develop such rights in the Americas, emphasizing the distinct political dynamics
at work in the two contexts. Then I raise some questions about the applicability
of the European model in the Americas, before concluding with some brief
thoughts about the role of national governments and supranational institutions in
pursuing freer movement of people and a common citizenship in regional integration efforts.
Free Movement in Europe
The postwar federalist determination to introduce a supranational European citizenship to supplement national citizenship was reflected in statements such as
Winston Churchill’s 1949 call for a “sense of enlarged patriotism and common
citizenship” for Europeans. The previous year, at a conference bringing together
hundreds of Europe’s most important leaders and thinkers, Churchill had said:
“We hope to reach again a Europe…in which men will be proud to say ‘I am a
European.’ We hope to see a Europe where men of every country will think as
much of being a European as of belonging to their native land. And wherever
they go in this wide domain they will truly feel ‘Here I am at home’.” The 1950
Schuman Declaration spoke of “common foundations for economic development
as a first step in the federation of Europe” a common market would create “a
wider and deeper community” and “lead to the realization of the first concrete
foundation of a European federation.” The resulting 1951 Paris Treaty resolved
“to establish, by creating an economic community, the foundation of a broad and
independent community” – and alongside the treaty’s free trade provisions also
provided free movement for workers in the fields covered by the treaty – which
were expanded significantly in the 1957 Treaty of Rome. Despite the gradual
growth of European rights from the 1950s onward, EU citizenship’s legal status
Maas - 113
was confirmed only in the Maastricht Treaty, which entered into force in 1993.
To some extent, this can be seen as a terminological delay. Indeed, Commissioner Davignon argued in 1979 that “the status of ‘Community citizen’ [was] officially recognized from the moment when the Treaties granted rights to individuals and the opportunity of enforcing them by recourse to a national or Community court” (Maas 2007).
The Treaties of Paris and Rome already prohibited any discrimination
based on nationality among nationals of the member states, but the transformation of free movement rights from being defined and promoted in economic
terms to being placed at the core of a new European citizenship was gradual. Free
movement rights for workers were first justified in terms of enabling the free
movement of labor and then as a measure to complete the single market. But they
were extended and expanded even after the workers’ movement sufficient to
support the common market had been achieved. This broadening of individual
rights coincided with the growth of EU citizenship, which took decades to reach
fruition—from postwar discussions to the Maastricht Treaty. Despite substantial
support in the 1970’s for introducing European citizenship, the Community’s
first enlargement (the UK, Ireland, and Denmark in 1973) stymied the process,
but the two subsequent enlargements (Greece in 1981, Spain and Portugal in
1986) reinvigorated it. The eventual adoption of EU citizenship resulted not from
Commission pressure but rather from bargaining among member states—
including the three new Mediterranean members—and between member states
and the European Parliament. With the Single European Act (SEA) in 1987, the
Parliament had gained the power of co-decision, which helps explaining why the
member states could afford to ignore the Parliament’s citizenship proposals before the SEA but accepted them in the discussions preceding Maastricht. Today
approximately 14 million Europeans live in another EU member state, and intraEuropean migration increasingly resembles internal rather than international migration.
Free Movement in Latin America
The introduction and expansion of free movement rights culminating in a common citizenship took decades to achieve in Europe. Analogous efforts in Latin
America are nascent and will likely require many years, and similar political
commitment. Currently the largest regional cross-border – not including internal
migration, which can often be at least as important as international migration
(Maas 2013b) – migrant communities are the Colombians in Venezuela and Ecuador, Nicaraguans in Costa Rica, Haitians in the Dominican Republic, and Paraguayans, Bolivians, and Chileans in Argentina, together accounting for over half
(about 2.2 million) of the total 4.09 million intra-Latin American migrants (IOM
2012). This is, however, still less than the number of Latin American-born individuals residing in the European Union, around 4.29 million. Of these nearly 4.3
Maas - 114
million Latin Americans in Europe, well over half reside in Spain (over 2.6 million people, chiefly from Ecuador, Colombia, Argentina, Bolivia, Peru, Venezuela, Brazil, the Dominican Republic, Uruguay, and Paraguay), with the next most
important destinations the United Kingdom (424,000 individuals, chiefly from
Jamaica and Brazil), Italy (358,000 individuals, chiefly from Ecuador and Peru),
the Netherlands (335,000 individuals, chiefly from Suriname and the Netherlands
Antilles), and France (156,000 individuals, chiefly from Haiti). Thus we can see
both historical ‘brain drain’ to Europe (chiefly Spain) and North America (chiefly the United States) as well as more recent intra-regional migration.
There have been various efforts over the years to promote free movement
of people within Latin America. The most advanced of these efforts are found in
CARICOM and in UNASUR, which is in the process of consolidating the previous efforts of the Andean Community and of MERCOSUR:
CARICOM
The Treaty of Chaguaramas established the Caribbean Community and Common
Market in 1973, superseding the Caribbean Free Trade Association, which in turn
had replaced the West Indies Federation. The Revised Treaty of Chaguaramas
establishing the Caribbean Community, including the CARICOM Single Market
and Economy (CSME), was signed in 2001. According to the article 45 of the
revised treaty: “Member States commit themselves to the goal of the free movement of their nationals within the Community” (CARICOM 2001). Free movement of people is seen as “an essential factor in an ever closer union among the
people of CARICOM Member States.” Article 45 on free movement “entails the
right to seek employment in any Member State and the elimination of the need
for work permits and permits of stay,” but its implementation has been subject to
constant delays.2 Of particular note is the CARICOM passport, which is a common format that has been gradually introduced since 2005 and, according to an
official press release “is seen as a defining symbol of regionalism” (CARICOM
2009). Despite this rhetoric, however, the development of freedom of movement
within CARICOM appears relatively limited.
Andean Community
The Andean Pact was created by Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, and Peru by
the Cartagena Agreement of 1969 and renamed the Andean Community (Spanish: Comunidad Andina) in 1996. Chile became an observer in 1976, while Venezuela joined in 1973 but left again in 2006 to join MERCOSUR. The Communi2
For
more
information
see
document
http://www.caricom.org/jsp/single_market/freemovementskills_socialsecurity.pdf
table,
http://www.caricom.org/jsp/single_market/fulloperationalisationfreemovement.pdf.
at:
and
and
Maas - 115
ty’s Decisión 504 of 2001 created a standard-format Andean passport for use in
the member countries. Furthermore, in Decisión 545 the Community approved an
Andean Labor Migration Instrument which provides for the relative free movement of workers between member states, as well as banning discrimination based
on nationality against workers from other Community member states. In terms of
its provisions, Decisión 545 resembles the early free movement provisions of the
European Union.
MERCOSUR
In 1991, Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay signed the Treaty of Asunción, creating the Southern Common Market, or MERCOSUR. The 1994 Protocol of Ouro Preto amended the Treaty of Asunción and transformed MERCOSUR from a Free Trade Area into a Customs Union. Free movement rights
within MERCOSUR started in 2002 when the member states signed the Residence Agreement, which finally entered into force in 2009 after ratification by
Paraguay’s Senate. The Agreement is intended to resolve the situation of irregular migrants from within the region and “has transformed the migration regime
for South Americans” because nationals of member or associate states “may reside and work for a period of two years in another member state if they have an
identification document and a clean criminal record” (Acosta, Arcarazo and
Geddes 2014).
Similar to the early years of European integration, the Agreement also
provides “the right to work and equal treatment in working conditions, family
reunion or access to education for children”; and it is even more generous than
the early European free movement provisions because “sufficient resources do
not represent a condition sine qua non” and the “permit may then be transformed
into a permanent one after two years” if applicants can prove they have sufficient
resources to sustain themselves in the territory of the host state. Bolivia (which is
in the process of becoming a full member) along with Chile, Colombia, and Peru
also observe the Residence Agreement. Venezuela became a full member in 2012
but (as of this writing) has not yet implemented the Agreement, nor have Associate members Ecuador, Guyana and Suriname.
Besides the Residence Agreement, of particular note within MERCOSUR is the Citizenship Statute, signed in 2010, which provides an action plan
for full implementation on common citizenship on the thirtieth anniversary of the
signing of the Treaty of Asunción, in 2021. The Citizenship Statute has three
main objectives: free movement of people within the region; equal civil, social,
cultural, and economic rights and freedoms for citizens of member states (comparable to non-discrimination on the basis of nationality); and equal conditions of
access to work, health, and education (MERCOSUR 2010). Although the Statute
sets some parameters for achieving these objectives, its decision-making procedures appear to be largely intergovernmental, based on bargaining between the
Maas - 116
member states. Thus a prediction based on the European experience is that further institutionalization will be necessary for these objectives to be realized.
UNASUR
The Union of South American Nations, usually known by its Spanish acronym
UNASUR (Unión de Naciones Suramericanas; Portuguese: União de Nações
Sul-Americanas, UNASUL; Dutch: Unie van Zuid-Amerikaanse Naties, UZAN),
is a consolidation of MERCOSUR and the Andean Community – both discussed
above – together with every other country on the South American continent except for the French Guiana, which is an overseas territory of France. In the area
of migration, there is a policy of officially welcoming but covertly rejecting irregular migrants, which seems paradoxical when viewed from the lens of Europe
or North America, where the official discourse emphasizes rejection while the
reality is more liberal (Acosta Arcarazo and Freier forthcoming).
The UNASUR treaty lists one of the Union’s objectives as “the consolidation of a South American identity through the progressive recognition of the
rights of nationals of a Member State resident in any of the other Member States,
in order to achieve a South American citizenship” (Art. 3i), and this idea is frequently repeated by government leaders. Most recently at the December 2014
summit, UNASUR general secretary Ernesto Samper emphasized that “We have
approved the concept of South American citizenship. This should be the greatest
register of what has happened”. UNASUR citizenship includes creating a “single
passport” and common educational rules to give South Americans the right to
live, work, and study in any UNASUR country, similar to free movement within
the EU (Robertson 2014). Together, the Andean Community, MERCOSUR, and
UNASUR provide an exciting venue for the potential development of a continent-wide supranational citizenship.
Future Prospects
A key reason for the success of European integration is the rise of individual free
movement rights, which gives concrete rights and entitlements to citizens of all
EU member states and prohibits discrimination based on nationality (Maas
2013c). Despite this success, however, the limits to European citizenship remain
evident – such as the limited extent to which EU citizens have rights to access
social assistance in a member state other than that of their nationality
(Verschueren 2014). In any case, the “right of EU citizens to enjoy full social
rights in their host state is closely related to their engagement in the performance
of economic activities, as either workers, self-employed or service providers”
(Mantu 2013: 463). Within North America, Canada’s travel visas for citizens of
Mexico are an affront to the idea of creating a common community and the egre-
Maas - 117
gious misregulation of Mexican immigration to the United States also shows the
limits of NAFTA free movement provisions. However, free movement efforts in
Latin America show more promise.
One difficulty in comparing current developments in Latin America with
the historical development of free movement rights and citizenship in the European Union is that concepts such as democracy appear to be understood differently in the two regions. For example, central governments in MERCOSUR appear
“less committed to democratic consolidation based on citizenship and social inclusion than the EU assumes and, as a result, EU pro-democracy policies resonate less than expected. Local civil society actors, in contrast, do identify with
EU understandings of democracy” (Grugel 2007). This matters because introducing a concept of ‘citizenship’ – as MERCOSUR and UNASUR do explicitly and
the Andean Community and CARICOM do at least implicitly by focusing on free
movement rights for workers – means negotiating not only intergovernmental
agreements and photo opportunities for heads of state and government but also
procedures and practices which will impact individuals throughout the region.
Across Latin America, the construction of a citizenry has long been tied to the
nation-building project yet, despite efforts to develop ‘modern’ citizenship, “the
boundaries of citizenship in the region have been circumscribed by racial, spatial,
class-based, and gendered hierarchies,” the development of civil and political
rights is hampered by weak democratic institutions and rule of law, and social
rights reflect persistent poverty, inequality, and lack of universal access to basic
social services (Meltzer and Rojas 2014: 253).
The initial drafts for the TTIP negotiations pay passing mention of free
movement for individuals, but focus mostly on mobility that is useful to business,
such as intra-corporate transfers.3 Similarly, despite promises in early drafts, the
final treaty text of CETA, the agreement between the European Union and Canada, also does not mention a general free movement right for individuals but limits
mobility provisions to temporary workers connected with business.4 This relative
absence of free movement provisions in the two trade agreements is regrettable,
because inclusion would likely have strengthened the popular support for the
agreements, as well as intensifying the benefits of freer trade. This is because the
volume of trade increases greatly the more people know each other.
As John Helliwell has shown, the effect of a border is many times greater
than that of geography or distance: one explanation for so-called “border effects”
emphasizes that it is “cheaper and easier to operate within networks of shared
norms and trust, and that the density of such networks declines with distance,
especially as one crosses national borders” (Helliwell 2002). Networks and
shared norms depend on two features: first, the movements of people, because
3
For more detailed information see http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/press/index.cfm?id=1
230.
4
For more detailed information access
http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2014/september/tradoc_152806.pdf.
Maas - 118
personal contacts establish and maintain networks and trust; second, formal institutions to supplement informal personal networks.5 So, too, we should expect that
trade agreements will be more effective if they include provisions for the freer
movement of people, not simply the freer movement of goods or capital. Furthermore, besides their anticipated positive effects on regional integration, free
trade agreements might become more politically palatable if ordinary citizens can
see the benefits not just for businesses and large corporations but also for themselves and others like them. This means that free movement should not simply be
for goods or services or capital but also for people.
As the experience of NAFTA shows, alongside that of the emerging free
movement regimes in Latin America, such a transition will not be easy to
achieve. However, the counterexample of Europe provides some grounds for optimism, although in Europe the decades-long process of ever-expanding free
movement rights culminating in European citizenship, though supported by national political leaders committed to creating a shared community, was guided
and amplified by strong supranational executive (European Commission) and
judicial (European Court) authorities, which for the moment are non-existent or
embryonic in the Americas. The prediction, therefore, is that it will be difficult
for free movement of persons in the Americas to quickly come to resemble internal rather than international migration, as has happened in Europe. Examples
ranging from the denaturalization of Dominicans of Haitian origin to the continuing problematic status of Mexicans in the United States – contrast the hardening
of the US-Mexico border with the softening and outright removal of border controls within Europe’s Schengen zone – support this thesis, although the rhetoric
of free movement and shared citizenship in CARICOM, the Andean Community,
MERCOSUR, and UNASUR may yet prove such pessimism unwarranted.
Conclusion
A key element of regional integration in Europe has been the development of
supranational rights and a common European citizenship. Since the first free
movement rights for coal and steel workers in the early 1950’s, supranational
rights for EU citizens have been extended to ever greater categories of people,
reflected in the European Court’s oft-repeated assertion that “Union citizenship is
destined to be the fundamental status of nationals of the Member States.” By contrast, efforts to foster individual free movement in CARICOM, the Andean
Community, MERCOSUR, and UNASUR have so far been relatively modest.
Nevertheless, each of those integration efforts are considering supranational
rights, thus it is useful to ask about the prospects of common rights and perhaps
5
Under formal institutions, Helliwell includes “laws and the administration of justice, the
design and implementation of standards, and the efficiency and quality of essential services, including (especially) health and education but also including the classic utilities –
water, heat, light, power, and communications.”
Maas - 119
eventually citizenship, focused foremost on the right of member state nationals to
live and work elsewhere within the community.
This paper has argued that successful regional integration requires states
to extend free movement rights to individuals, rather than simply promoting the
free movement of goods, services, or capital. Against the backdrop of EU citizenship, the paper assessed current efforts underway in Latin America to create
regional rights, including most notably free movement rights and citizenship
analogous to those found in Europe. A tentative conclusion is that, while supranational rights are difficult to achieve, they help provide legitimacy for what
would otherwise be simply free trade agreements with no benefits for ordinary
citizens and therefore that the rise of common free movement rights perhaps coupled with a common citizenship is an important indicator for the success of regional integration beyond mere trade agreements.
References
Acosta Arcarazo, Diego, and Luisa Feline Freier. forthcoming. “Turning the Immigration Policy Paradox Upside Down? Populist Liberalism and Discursive Gaps in South America.” International Migration Review.
Acosta Arcarazo, Diego, and Andrew Geddes. 2014. “Transnational Diffusion or
Different Models? Regional Approaches toMigration Government in the
European Union and Mercosur.” European Journal of Migration and Law
16 (1): 19-44.
CARICOM. 2001. Rvised Treaty of Chaguaram as Establishing the Caribbean
Community Including the CARICOM Single Market and Economy, access at http://www.caricom.org/jsp/community/revised_treaty-text.pdf.
CARICOM. 2009. “Belize Becomes Twelfth Member State to Issue CARICOM
Passport”, March 17th, accessed at http://www.caricom.org/jsp
/pressreleases/pres86_09.jsp.
Grugel, Jean. 2007. “Democratization and Ideational Diffusion: Europe, Mercosur and Social Citizenship.” Journal of Common Market Studies 45
(1): 43-68.
Helliwell, John F. 2002. Globalization and Well Being. Vancouver: UBC Press.
IOM. 2012. “Migratory Routes and Dynamics between Latin American and Caribbean (LAC) Countried and between the LAC Region and the European
Union.” http://www.migracion-ue-alc.eu.
Maas - 120
Maas, Willem. 2005. “The Genesis of European Rights.” Journal of Common
Market Studies 43 (5): 1009-25.
———. 2007. Creating European Citizens, Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.
———. 2009. “Unrespected, Unequal, Hollow? Contingent Citizenship and Reversible Rights in the European Union.” Columbia Journal of European
Law 15 (2): 265-80.
———. 2013a. “Equality and Free Movement of People.” In Democratic Citizenship and the Free Movement of People, edited by Willem Maas. Leiden: Martinus Nijhoff.
———.2013b. “Free Movement and Discrimination: Evidence fromEurope, the
United States, and Canada.” European Journal of Migration and Law 15
(1): 91-110.
———. 2013c. “Varities of Multilevel Citizenship.” In Multilevel Citizenship,
edited by Willem Maas. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
———. 2014a. “European Union Citizenship in Retrospect and Prospect.” In
Routledge Handbook of Global Citizenship Studies, edited by Engin Isin
and Peter Nyers, 409-17. London: Routledge.
———. 2014b. “EU Citizenship’s Origins, Evolution, and Political Objectives.”
German Law Journal 15 (5): 797-819.
Mantu, Sandra. 2013. “Concepts of Time and European Citizenship.” European
Journal of Migration and Law 15 (4): 447-64.
Meltzer, Judy, and Cristina Rojas. 2014. "Transformations in Imaginings and
Practices of Citizenship in Latin America." In Routledge Handbook of
Global Citizenship Studies, edited by Engin Isin adnd Peter Nyers, 25364. London: Routledge.
MERCOSUR. 2010. Estatuto de la Ciudadania del MERCOSUR: Plan de Accion, accessed at http://www.mercosur.int/innovaportal/file/28080/1/
DEC_064-2010_ES_Estatuto_de_Cidadania.pdf
Maas - 121
Reding, Viviane. 2013.”What’s the Deal with the EU-US Free Trade Agreement?”, October 30. Access at http://europa.eu/rapid/pressrelease_SPEECH-13-865_en.htm.
Robertson, Ewan. 2014. “UNASUR Moves toward Continental Freedom of
Movement.” Venezuelanalysis.com, December 5. http://venezuelanalysis
.com/news/11057.
Verschueren, Herwig. 2014. “Free Movement or Benefit Tourism: The Unreasonable Burden of Brey.” European Journal of Migration and Law 16
(2): 147-79.
II.
Europe and Latin America
The Crisis of the European Integration Model
and its Implications for Latin American Integration
Ángel M. Casas-Gragea
Metropolitan Autonomous University of Mexico
Pedro Caldentey del Pozo
Loyola University Andalusia
Abstract
The internal tensions and questions raised around the survival of the Economic
and Monetary Union are among the main manifestations of the global crisis in
the European Union (EU). The flaws in the Euro design are not the only problem
that the EU is facing. There is an open debate surrounding common policies,
budgetary mechanisms and institutional governance that are threatening the principles and method of the European integration model. This context suggests that
the neo-functionalist theoretical indicators of regional integration have been losing analytical and explanatory power in what concerns understanding the strategic role of regional integration, especially in presence of the many questions that
have arisen in recent years in Europe and in Latin America. The hypothesis of
this article is that the crisis is directly affecting the theory of the European integration model, and indirectly affecting the method. In turn, this has an effect on
the depth and continuity of the regional integration processes in Latin American
countries that have taken European integration model as a reference for their own
integration.
Introduction
Since the establishment of the Euro in 1998, the European integration began to
face an internal crisis regarding its own goals and challenges. This translated into
at least fifteen years of crisis of the European Union (EU). The launch of this
single currency seemed to be the culmination of an economic integration on its
way to the next theoretical stage: political integration. European regional integration is compared to a bicycle that, in order to remain upright, must continue to
move forward. Europe, therefore, must continue pedaling through a logical path
traced by theory in order to gradually achieve its goals. After the Euro, what
would seem to be the next stage in this cycling tour was the political integration
of the EU members. However, the bicycle now seems to have interrupted its
gradual march forward, and seems to have veered away from its integrationist
course. In the current context, the European countries are weathering deep economic and social crises —and in more than one case, also political. It would
seem that the European integration is partially at fault to be blamed for this prob-
Casas and Caldentey - 126
lem, especially since it has shown little ability to find common solutions. Or at
least, the proposed solutions from Brussels do not seem to suit the belief system
that neo-functionalism has theoretically offered, inspired by the ideals set forth
by Jean Monnet and the rest of the Founding Fathers. It would seem that national
interests, especially German interests, weigh more heavily than the Community’s
welfare; that is, economic interests under a liberal approach.
The crisis calls into question the neo-functionalist theoretical perspective
that could serve as a tool to interpret the evolution of European regional integration. It also situates the European countries at a series of crucial crossroads that
could lead the European Union to a different destination, away from the logic of
the integration model that not long ago it was heading towards. Some people
would say that this is the end of a willful and solidary —Socratic and Christian—
European integration; others would say that it is nothing more than a demonstration of Europe’s pragmatism and individualism (Madariaga 1962: 50).
Undoubtedly, the European integration has raised interest and curiosity in
Latin America. The process of European integration has been a benchmark for
those in Latin America, like the Central American Integration System (SICA),
the Andean Community (CAN) and the Southern Common Market (MERCOSUR). The EU founded an integration model heir to a historical momentum
and ideas incited at the time by Monnet and subsequently by neo-functionalism.
The European regional integration has accomplished many goals since its
birth/conception, and it is because of this success that the regional process has
earned the category of universal regional integration model. And, this is why the
EU has served as an example that nourished the theoretical analysis, conceptual
frameworks and methods on the regional integration literature. The EU displays a
model, for many quasi sacrosanct, based on the transferring of sovereignty, the
creation of supranational institutions, the development of mutual interests, and
the search for prosperity and peace for all member states. The post-liberal regionalist processes —the Bolivarian Alliance for the Peoples of Our America
(ALBA) and the Union of South American Nations (UNASUR), for instance,
seem to move away from some of the principles of the aforementioned European
construction. Therefore, the troubled European integration is also in crisis as a
reference model for Latin American integration.
This context suggests that the neo-functionalist theoretical keys to Regional Integration have been losing analytical and explanatory power in understanding the strategic role of regional integration. Especially, in the presence of
the many questions that have come up in recent years in Europe and in Latin
America. The hypothesis of this article is that the crisis is directly affecting the
theory of the European Integration model, and indirectly affecting the method.1
1
The analysis presented in this article is inspired by previous work by Romero and
Caldentey regarding the keys to understanding the European regional integration process
(Romero and Caldentey 2010).
Casas and Caldentey - 127
In turn, this has an effect on the depth and continuity of the regional integration
processes in Latin American countries that have taken European Integration as a
reference for their own integration.
European Economic Integration and the Crisis: an Incomplete Task
After the Second World War, prominent political leaders —Jean Monnet, Robert
Schuman, Konrad Adenauer— had the vision and initiative to use regional integration to transform a devastated Europe into the EU it is today. Their fundamental objective was to create in Europe a land of prosperity, solidarity and peace.
The Schuman Declaration of May 9, 1950 states: "Europe will not be made all at
once, or according to a single plan. It will be built through concrete achievements
which first create a de facto solidarity" (Schuman 1950).
The European integration project has gradually increased and grown until
2007, when the last of its most recent members joined —besides Croatia in 2013.
What in 1952 began as a coal and steel common market has now become an imperfect economic and monetary union linked together by a common currency.
Throughout this period, country membership has grown from six to 28. As Monnet once stated, “Within these vast country conglomerates, the common interest
was too imprecise and the common disciplines were too relaxed. It was necessary
to start with more pragmatic and, at the same time, more ambitious actions: an
audacious and targeted attack on national sovereignties” (2010: 311).
This integration process, unlike others taking place in the rest of the
world, did not only pursue commercial goals; it also had economic, social, and
political aims. This was a trend intuitively defined from the early years by the
Founding Fathers. Subsequently, and based on the European experience, the political and economic science scholars, close to the heat of the reality, conceptualized and created logical steps for the countries that wanted to walk the path of
deep regional integration. They aimed at understanding the center of gravity that
had pulled the European integration process into motion. But the question now is
whether or not the regional integration method and model they proposed in order
to achieve the economic, political and social goals for building an integrated
community, are universal and mechanical truths for other regions such as Latin
America.
Therefore, economically, the EU Single Market —under the 1987 Single
European Act— had to be followed by an economic and then a monetary union;
consequently, a single currency was introduced for most of the EU members. The
existence of the Euro has brought changes in the European monetary institutions,
as well as in the monetary policy of the member-states.
There are pending tasks that the 2008 crisis has fiercely forced onto the
negotiations table. However, until now, there have been only timid attempts for
resolution. There are still items on the To Do List, such as: the harmonization of
tools and practices to ensure that monetary policy is truly unique, and the crea-
Casas and Caldentey - 128
tion of a system that allows for the national central banks to implement a decentralized monetary policy and to make the most of national peculiarities. That is, a
comprehensive common policy that should support the employment, growth, and
stability of the community as a whole, while paying attention to the particularities of the member countries.
Although, it is known, the crisis has exposed the economic and monetary
union in the EU as an incomplete regional integration stage. The telluric forces
that triggered the crisis of 2008 have seriously damaged the European edifice,
revealing its vulnerabilities. Now the cracks have allowed the architects to identify where the construction failures are. However, the countries are not arriving at
a consensus on how to approach the building repairs. As a consequence, they are
not taking actions that are aligned to the community logic (model and method)
that is drawn by neo-functionalism and the spillover effect (Hurrell 1995: 59-61).
Presently, a more effective policy would be to implement common financial tools
and community fiscal integration. All these implications further reduce national
sovereignty —more Europe; but, the political will has not come this far yet. It
gives the impression that the structure is propped up by scaffolding while the
next course of action is determined.
As the British leaders have proposed more than once, the best course of
action would be to fortify the European building from different bases: a free trade
zone and intergovernmental cooperation, nothing more. This was precisely the
British position during the large EU expansion in 2004. The discussion among
the members was either to follow the way of incremetalism or the way to deep
integration stages and common policies. The Anglo-European Dream seems impossible, but who knows? In hindsight, it is possible to see that Germany and the
other member-states interest in the markets of Eastern European countries look
for the achievement of wider expansion, thus sacrificing depth.
But beyond the traditional British case, now other EU member-states are
also showing interest in curbing the logic of the progress of integration through
the strengthening of supranational institutions. Some examples are the discussion
about the nationalization of some policies covered by the common budget; the
unilateral announcements of the adjustment of internal policies adopted in the
Schengen framework; the factual modification of decision-making outside the
EU institutions; or the lack of progress towards a common fiscal policy.
European Integration and Political Crisis: an Increasingly Faraway Task
In the 1950’s, the European integration was forged by guaranteeing prosperity
and peace through supranational institutions and decisions that were based on the
common interests of member-states. And since its birth, the EU has aspired to
achieve political integration to ultimately become a regional state, that is, a new
political entity different from the traditional nation state. But, the problems and
obstacles that the EU has been facing do not seem to augur a politically integrat-
Casas and Caldentey - 129
ed Europe in the short term. As Monnet stated: “All my reflections and observations lead me to conclude what is already my profound conviction: the effort that
the western European countries make to raise to the challenge of the circumstances, the danger that threatens us and the American effort, need to become a
true European effort, only possible if a Western federation were to exist” (2010:
310).
As mentioned already in this work, the process of the European integration inspires neo-functionalism. The authors of this article are convinced that in
order for regional integration to be successful and beneficial to each of its member-states, it is necessary to build supranational institutions to which in certain
matters the states cede part of their sovereignty. Under this approach, the traditional nation-state, the main institution of modern political order, loses its
strength.
The neo-functionalists believe in the spillover effect. When members of
an integrationist group are creating greater interdependence among each other,
the ensuing process of cooperation between these countries will inevitably lead to
integration of a higher and deeper order; not only economic but also political.
The mechanical process is to go from a customs union to an economic and monetary union and from a complete economic integration to political integration
(Hurrell 1995).
Despite the fact that the EU is the inspiration for this neo-functionalist
approach, starting from the Nice Summit in December 2000, the EU has faced
serious difficulties to further the deepening of its integration process. Progress in
the EU seems to have become increasingly intergovernmental because matters of
high policy remain in the hands of the European Council and the Council of the
EU. Autonomous and supranational institutional platforms, like the European
Commission or the European Parliament, still lack decision-making capacity.
Under the logic of neo-functionalism, it is difficult to explain the current dynamic of the EU next to its challenges, questions, and deepening integration. However, many scholars and politicians, despite understanding the current reality, still
cling to the idea that the integration progress is irreversible. Now, more than ever
before, the belief in the idea of irreversibility is being challenged by less dogmatic approaches.
On the way to political integration, and after its recent expansion —for
historical reasons and to maintain the balance of power— the EU has kept supranational and intergovernmental institutions that limit Germany’s hegemonic action; but also, to timidly move towards more democratic forms of decisionmaking. The distribution of votes according to each country’s population gives
greater democratic legitimacy to the European process. Naturally, however, it
ends up favoring Germany, the country with the largest population among member-states, while at the same time eroding the previously accepted hegemonic
balance of power in Europe. If it has not already, it could produce the FrancoGerman alliance that has historically been the backbone of the European integra-
Casas and Caldentey - 130
tion process. In 1952, Michel Debré pointed out that "for the sake of Germany
itself, Europe must not become a German Europe" (Monnet 2010: 411). A Europe, the German Europe, should be avoided because it will not bring anything
good to Europe. In the context of the current crisis, this idea has often been repeated on Debré’s same track. "In 1953 the novelist Thomas Mann appealed to
an audience of students in Hamburg to strive for ‘not a German Europe but a European Germany’. This stirring pledge was endlessly repeated at the time of
German unification. Today we have a variation that few foresaw: a European
Germany in a German Europe” (Beck 2013: vii-viii).
Existing institutions, beyond the lack of genuine democratic supranational institutions, do not limit Germany’s hegemonic capacity. However, they keep
it relatively under the control of other EU countries. The European project has
been made viable since the end of World War II, therefore, because of the dominance of the non-democratic criteria in the European Council, in the Council of
the EU, and also to a lesser extent, in the Parliament.
Latin America, the Model of European Integration and the Crisis
The process and model of the European integration for many years has had a special echo in Latin America. Politicians have taken European integration as a
buzzword to try and give credibility to the rhetoric on their own discourses on
regional integration. And, it must be said, they have achieved little success on
reaching the goals of their own regional integration process and in the impact on
Latin American peoples’ welfare. In most cases, the intellectual, political and
economic elite in Latin American countries have adopted speeches, looks and
aspirations from abroad. This created a foreign-focused view of integration —
especially attentive to the European model— that is common in the region. Latin
America holds this approach due to its Socratic-Christian heritage that hails from
Europe, which rhetorically aligns the Latin American system of beliefs regarding
integration with the Mediterranean and Continental European views of integration (Madariaga 1962: 50-65).
Because of the referential power of the European integration, neofunctionalism has been the theoretical base for many of the integration processes
in Latin America. SICA, CAN, and MERCOSUR are clear examples of its influence on the Latin American regional processes of integration. Such European
influence is notable in their original institutional design and in their group goals.
However, in the praxis of these processes —when it is necessary to implement
the method— visible outcomes have been just a few and those few results have
slowly been fading since the nineties. Their regional integration agreements have
not really grown out of the field of theoretical proposal and aspirations.
However, other regional groups around the world have often questioned
the European integration model and method. In the work A Grand Illusion? An
Essay on Europe, published in 1996, the historian Tony Judt values the achieve-
Casas and Caldentey - 131
ments of the European integration but attributes them to a unique and unrepeatable fact in history that does not respond to a logic (a model) that can be projected
indefinitely into the future. For Judt, the European integration as a model is an
illusion. Although the author does not mention the European integration as a reference model for others, it is clear to us that he would consider it another illusion
(Judt 2011: 3-44). As Tanja A. Börzel reminds us, the early studies of compared
regionalism revealed that the integration effort of developing countries that took
European integration as a model remained largely ineffective. Ernest B. Haas
goes even further in his works published in the 1970’s, declaring the invalidity of
the model (Börzel 2011: 7).
Independently from what has been previously stated, the idea of regional
integration is incredibly powerful in the Latin American imaginary from the
nineteenth century onwards —La Patria Grande (the Great Homeland). This is
why regional integration groups from the past have survived, and in the last decade, new ones have been created, as ALBA and UNASUR. These new South
American integration processes are presented as a regional proposal with economic, political and social goals, but without a supranational institutional structure that allows for the fulfillment of these deep and wide integrationist aspirations. Malamud and Gardini even argue that regional integration is no longer an
option for Latin America, and the space left available from the disappearance of a
deep regional integration model is being occupied by the rhetoric of politicians.
And this rhetoric is neither a model nor a method (2012: 131).
There is no true reproduction of the European method in any of these integration processes conceived to respond to the aspirations of the Latin American
integrationist tradition. ALBA seeks to free itself from the European model and
has created a different one. As such, the European integration model is still in the
foreground in Latin America. In the cases of SICA, CAN and MERCOSUR,
where the European model is still kept as a reference, the designed method has
been approached ineffectively. Moreover, in the new aspirations like UNASUR,
the European method benchmark disappears even in rhetoric. Surely this shows a
referential loss of the European integration model considered as valid for Latin
American countries.
Conclusions
The European process launched by the Founding Fathers more than five decades
ago conceived to end war in Europe once and for all, is in crisis. As a consequence, the theoretical model that stemmed intuitively from the process, and the
method to make it work, are also in trouble. The search for peace has seemed to
lose strength as a leitmotiv for the process. Also, the idea of reunification after
the fall of the Berlin Wall, that could somehow be an updated version of the motivation for peace, is also weakened. The theoretical framework for regional integration no longer has the analytical and explanatory power to face the many
Casas and Caldentey - 132
questions that have come up in recent years. At the end of the twentieth century,
the duties of economic European integration seemed largely fulfilled, and it
looked like the process had matured enough to enter into its next stage, political
union. Therefore, it is paradoxical that European integration has entered into a
crisis from which it still has not recovered, and which has only deepened since
the 2008 crisis and aftermath.
Given the above, we can say that the crisis faced by the European integration model has become an almost incontestable fact, undoubtedly amplifying
the economic and social crisis in its member-states since 2008. European integration has thus emerged as a process unable to consolidate through consensus its
own progress, as measured by the goals set by the countries. And it is not able to
respond —from the supranational space— to the problems faced by member
countries.
This calls into question the neo-functionalists’ ideas, Monnet himself,
and of course any understanding that attempts to generalize and systematize the
current progress of the European regional integration. When there is a crack in
the belief system on which European integration has been built, instead of more
integration, Europe has less integration. This leads us to wonder whether there
could be a real regional integration with a theoretical framework and method different than the one proposed by neo-functionalism and Monnet. The sub-regional
integration processes in Latin America are certainly suffering the effects of the
theoretical and practical references to the European process, as well as the
changes in the relations between the European Union and Latin America.
References
Beck, Ulrich. 2013. German Europe. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Börzel, Tanja A. 2011. “Comparative Regionalism: A New Research Agenda”,
KFG Working Paper Series, 28, Aug.
Garton Ash, Tomothy. 2012. “Britain is standing on a ledge, while Europe
screams, ‘Don’t do it!’”, The Guardian, 21 Nov., accessed at: http://www
.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2012/nov/21/budget-summit-dual-coreeurope.
Hurrell, Andrew. 1995. “Regionalism in Theoretical Perspective”, in Fawcett,
Louise and Hurrell, Andrew (eds), Regionalism in World Politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 37-73.
Judt, Tony. 2011. A Grand Illusion? An Essay on Europe. New York: New York
University Press.
Casas and Caldentey - 133
Madariaga, Salvador de. 1962. Latin America Between the Eagle and the Bear.
New York: Praeger.
Malamud, Andrés and Gardini, Gian Luca. 2012. “Has Regionalism Peaked? The
Latin American Quagmire and its Lessons”, The International Spectator,
47 (1), 116-133.
Monnet, Jean. 2010. Memorias. Madrid: Encuentro.
Romero Rodríguez, José Juan, and Caldentey del Pozo, Pedro. 2010, “Claves
para comprender el proceso europeo de integración regional. Una revisión”, in Caldentey del Pozo, Pedro and Romero, José Juan (eds), El SICA y la UE. La integración regional en perspectiva comparada. San
Salvador: Fundación ETEA para el Desarrollo y la Cooperación, 385425.
Schuman, Robert. 1950. “The Schuman Declaration”, Speech in the Salon de
l’Horloge at Quai d’Orsay, Paris, 9 May, accessed at:
http://europa.eu/about-eu/basic-information/symbols/europeday/schuman-declaration/index_en.htm.
Teruel, Ana. 2015. “Delors sugiere a Reino Unido que abandone la UE”, El País,
28 Dec., accessed at:
http://internacional.elpais.com/internacional/2012/12/28/actualidad/1356
717262_835768.html.
The Effect of the TTIP on the BRICS Countries:
The Case of Brazil
Ana-Paula Tostes
Rio de Janeiro State University (UERJ)
Abstract
This paper seeks to evaluate the potential impact of the Transatlantic Trade and
Investment Partnership (TTIP) on the BRICS countries. One of the responses to
the economic international crisis was the European Union (EU) and the United
States decision to create a High-Level Working Group (HLWG) in order to boost
transatlantic trade and investment between super powers. The inter-regional initiative was to adopt a more creative, flexible, and "open-minded attitude" in order
to find solutions for advancing negotiations between the trade partners. This initiative emerged at the 2011 EU-US Summit, where leaders instructed the Transatlantic Economic Council to establish the HLWG, whose mandate is to identify
and assess options for strengthening transatlantic trade and investment. Then, the
largest bilateral trade agreement in the world appeared as the "agreement of the
century": the TTIP. This raises two important questions: What impact will the
agreement have on the relations between BRICS countries? What alternative
strategies do they have to face a new balance of power?
Introduction
Two major events challenged the balance of power at the turn of the century: the
rise of emerging markets such as the BRICS countries (Brazil, Russia, India,
China and South Africa), and the unpredicted international economic crisis,
which affected the two largest world economic powers: the European Union
(EU) and the United States (U.S.). More specifically, China has emerged as a
player that must be taken into consideration when talking about international politics nowadays. One can say that China has changed the International Division of
Labor (IDL), as large economies, such as the U.S., and emerging markets, such
as Brazil, depend on Chinese imports and exports.
It is no coincidence that there have been several initiatives on transatlantic cooperation between the EU and the U.S. – between their corporations and
their governments – since 1995. The foundation of a New Transatlantic Agenda
(NTA) and the Transatlantic Regulatory Cooperation (TRC) initiatives has contributed to the progress of reducing costs for businesses and consumers in a few
sectors of the economy in both regions. Since then, a number of advances have
Tostes - 136
quietly been made.1 The global crisis accelerated cooperation efforts and led European and American leaders to instruct the Transatlantic Economic Council to
establish a new joint High-Level Working Group (HLWG) in 2011. The HLWG
serves to identify and assess opportunities for strengthening transatlantic trade
and investment, especially in areas that have the greatest potential to support jobs
creation and growth. Its primary goal was to respond to the specific characteristics of transatlantic economic relations “by identifying policies and measures” to
increase the EU-U.S. trade and investment and foster “mutually beneficial job
creation,” economic growth, and international competitiveness. The leaders’
main concern was to minimize the impact of the U.S. crisis and the sovereign
debt crisis in the Eurozone on inter-regional trade. The hidden goal however, is
to join forces to face the new international scenario, in which China has become
both a key partner and a potential threat at the same time.
The Very First Boost
Together, the EU and the US have the largest bilateral trade and investment volumes in the world: roughly 31 percent of world trade and over 49 percent of the
world GDP is concentrated in these two regions. Approximately one trillion dollars in goods and services are traded between the two each year and they invest
nearly US$ 4 trillion in each other’s economies. All of this supports around 13
million jobs on both sides of the Atlantic.
The EU-U.S. HLWG was founded to enhance transatlantic trade and investment between the EU and the U.S. by adopting a more “flexible” and “openminded attitude” towards the development of solutions for negotiations on trade.
The HLWG establishment, however, coincided with the emergence of several
new outlooks on trade in the aftermath of the failed multilateral trade negotiations during the World Trade Organization (WTO) Doha Round. In this context,
the 2012 report of the Transatlantic Task Force on trade focused on the need for a
new understanding of several aspects of transatlantic relations. The acceleration
of negotiations looked for a deeper bilateral transatlantic economic integration as
an essential procedure to recover from the economic crisis. The report remarked
that the EU and the U.S. could “exercise the leadership required to kick-start
global trade liberalization, strengthening the multilateral trading system” (GMF
2012). However, the acceptance of common principles and standards has been
perceived as a key initiative to boost trade and investment between Europe and
the U.S.; the exact same method was used in the EU to consolidate its common
market. Indeed, since the 1990s, both the US and European multinational companies have expressed divergent views on what is the best way to regulate goods
1
A comprehensive study on different activities and sectors that could be regulated is still
in progress. Even so, it has been confirmed that the areas that will be affected include
antitrust or competition procedures, consumer protection, environmental regulations,
manufactured and industrial products, etc.
Tostes - 137
and service markets, as regulations are considered the main barrier to transatlantic trade. The main reason why these companies seek to achieve greater harmonization in standards and regulatory procedures is to reduce the costs arising from
the need to comply with two different sets of regulations and standards. Regulatory cooperation is an umbrella concept that incorporates a broad range of activities.
As one of the most ambitious initiatives aimed at achieving strong convergences and aligning policies, the TTIP emerged as the largest inter-regional
agreement, which earned the title of “the agreement of the 21st century.”
As other economic and political heavyweights look for new joint projects
in the East, the EU and the U.S. have accelerated negotiations aimed at constructing a free avenue for trade and investment cooperation as a major goal in their
own foreign policies. The Obama administration’s economic policy treats the
creation of high-standard trade rules as a vital issue for the global economy. The
TTIP is expected to reduce the costs companies incur while engaging in transoceanic trade, which will make products and services less expensive. Although it
is still too early to assess the impact of this bilateral partnership on third countries, corporations and business groups from the BRICS countries are becoming
concerned with the future preferences of the EU and the U.S. negotiators.
What are the Promises that Have Been Made?
Contrary to what happened over the past two decades, progress in emerging markets is now slow. Currently, advanced economies are growing more and emerging economies are growing less. However, China is, as always, the exception
among the BRICS. Its growth forecast pointed to acceleration over the course of
the year, after achieving a growth rate of 7.7 percent in 2013 (est.).
The U.S. has also demonstrated its strength once again. It has obtained
positive results in the housing industry, business investments, and employment.
The housing industry grew at an annual rate of 12.9 percent in May 2013 (Thomas 2013), which represented the fourth consecutive quarter with a double-digit
growth. The U.S. unemployment rate dropped to 7.3 percent on August 2013,
which was the lowest it has been since December 2008. Furthermore, Europe
soon started to join the U.S.’s recovery.
In addition to showing signs of recovery, the EU and the U.S. appear
ready to deepen their economic partnership. Once the TTIP is in place, gains are
expected to reach 86 billion euros per year for the EU and 65 billion euros for the
U.S. European business executives say that 80 percent of the benefits of the
agreement would result from the reduction of regulatory burdens and bureaucracy, as well as from the opening up of the services and public procurement markets. Once the deal is fully implemented, it is expected that every year, an average European household would earn an extra €545 and the European economy
would be boosting its GDP approximately 0.5 percent a year.
Tostes - 138
It is estimated that EU corporations will sell an additional €187 billion of
goods and services a year to the U.S. This is good news for jobs. Surveys commissioned by Bertelsmann Foundation revealed, however, that incomes in the
U.S. would rise 13.4 percent per capita thanks to the TTIP, whereas those in Europe would only increase 5 percent. Even with this unequal distribution of the
agreement’s benefits, Europe will lose more if the TTIP does not go through,
since it has fewer options compared to the United States. Around 43 percent of
Americans believe that the TTIP will help the U.S. compete with China, and
therefore, support its approval.
Overcoming its internal asymmetries will not be an easy task for the EU.
Europe is experiencing serious problems of competitiveness due to the economic
difficulties countries in the south of the continent, such as Greece, are having.
Furthermore, there are major differences in the financial rules and exchange rate
policies that will have to be revisited in order to comply with the TTIP. Finally,
the EU’s institutional procedures on treaties require all stages of negotiation to be
approved, which takes time.
In this scenario, according to the Trade Regulator Cooperation report, it is
important to take note of two policy options that can indeed bolster cooperation.
The initiatives to reinforce these two policies have demonstrated their capacity to
vitalize transatlantic cooperation: (1) attracting high-level political support, and
(2) dramatically increasing the involvement of legislators (the U.S. Congress and
the European Parliament).
The first policy is related to the creation of the Transatlantic Economic
Council (TEC) in April 2007. The Council was designed, in part, to generate the
kind of high-level political support that previous initiatives lacked. In other
words, the institutionalization of cooperation can create conditions that are more
conducive to defining the terms for the partnership’s development, by clarifying
what steps are needed to reach an agreement and identifying the limits of procedures that must be improved.
The second policy is quite important considering the predominance of
the executive branches as a driving force for cooperation. The involvement of the
legislative branch could facilitate the harmonization of regulations. Regulation of
standards and measures are necessary in both domestic and international markets.
In an increasingly integrated transatlantic market, Parliaments will be called upon
to balance the often-competing demands of trade expansion and barrier reduction, on the one hand, and domestic health and safety concerns on the other.
The Obama administration clearly seeks to make this partnership a more
popular and visible initiative. Thanks to the president Obama’s efforts, the cooperation debate, which began quietly, is no longer a matter of importance only for
the country’s political elite. Indeed, the increased involvement of legislators can
provide the democratic impulse needed to overcome the TTIP criticism in the
U.S.
Tostes - 139
Brazil and China in the Context of the BRICS
The BRICS countries joined to form a group of emerging economies that aimed
to introduce changes to the liberal international order established after World
War II. The group’s creation has led to the reordering of international coalitions,
the search for new opportunities to pool interests, and the optimization of efforts
on development and economic growth in the existing liberal order. It is no coincidence that most of the BRICS countries have vast territories, large populations,
and a varying number of neighbors with whom they need to accommodate their
interests. Another important element is that the BRICS countries are natural regional leaders, which can be involved in regional integration efforts. They also
face problems of poverty and inequality anchored in historical processes of social
divisions left by the legacy of dictatorships and longstanding poverty. Their indexes on human development and inequality reflect the violent past and social
unrest these countries experienced throughout their history, which differ significantly from the data of developed countries. This means that the BRICS group
must have a dual purpose: in addition to improving their position in the international market, they need to solve parallel problems involving domestic policy
reforms, social policy adjustments, decreasing violence, poverty and inequality.
The decision to create a common development bank was developed during the fourth BRICS Summit held in New Delhi in 2012, which was subsequently announced at the group’s fifth Summit in Durban in 2013, and finally plans
were put into motion at the sixth Summit in Brazil in 2014. The BRICS bank was
created with the purpose of increasing the weight of the BRICS countries in the
global governance of international finance institutions, which could represent an
improvement of multilateral strategies of the emerging powers.
In regards to trade, the last two decades have been very lucrative for both
Brazil and China. Thus, Brazil must address the asymmetries in its bilateral exchange with China through changes to its industrial and innovation policies, such
as new legislation (tax reform, for example) and development agencies to increase the competitiveness of Brazilian firms and add value to its exports. Although domestic political battles and institutional imperfections are a major
source of Brazil’s lack of competitiveness, Brazil’s trade policy has been lacking
a more liberalizing agenda. Furthermore, to increase their absorptive capacity for
foreign direct investments, both China and Brazil would benefit enormously from
strengthening institutions capable of curbing corruption through checks and balances.
Brazil’s geography is abundant in natural resources and has excellent environmental conditions which could be used to enhance the role of agriculture as
a component of its "soft power" strategy. In addition, to the abundance of mineral
resources and arable land, it has additional resources that can be used by Southern American countries. Like Brazil, China will continue to benefit from a strong
Tostes - 140
domestic market and a sophisticated industrial economy in the future. However,
the agreements between China and Brazil are still limited, as both countries’
maintain strong trade relations with the EU and the US.
According to a FitchRatings report from 2012 entitled “China's Economic Rise Provides Mixed Benefits for Latin America,” overall, Latin America has
benefited from its relationship with China, as it has brought higher commodity
prices, increased growth and investment, and improved their governments’ finances. However, as a result of Latin America's specialization in commodities
and China's transition into a higher value-added manufacturing exporter, 92 percent of Latin American exports to China were commodities, according to the
FitchRatings in 2010. Therefore, Latin America’s long-term position in this partnership is weak, other sources for growth and trade, such as services, should be
pursued.
China is Brazil’s main trading partner; it was the destination of approximately 19 percent of Brazilian exports (followed by US, 10.2 percent and Argentina, 8.1 percent) in 2013. However, Brazil is not listed as one of China’s top ten
trading partners. Although the two countries are partners in the BRICS, they do
not seem to be building a typical South-South relationship. As Pereira and Neves
(2011) have remarked, “the two countries do not constitute a South-South exchange (a balanced exchange between developing countries), as official Brazilian
rhetoric may suggest, but rather an increasingly North-South relationship — with
Brazil as an exporter of commodities and an importer of manufactured goods
from China.” In 2013, the top three Brazilian products and their derivatives exported to China were soybean (50 percent), iron ore and concentrates (28 percent), and oil and derivatives (6.7 percent). Conversely, the top three imports
from China were machinery and electrical appliances and parts (30 percent), machinery and mechanical appliances and parts (20 percent), and inorganic and organic chemicals (6 percent) (China-Brazil Update 2014). On the one hand, strong
trade relations do exist between China and Brazil, which has led the Brazilian
government to invest in strategic sectors, such as industry and technology. On the
other hand, the goals and features characterizing South-South cooperation are not
present in this relationship. This complex scenario demands a change in attitude
or focus from Brazil in order to face this rising Asian giant, instead of expecting
China not to pursue the optimization of its advantages in the global economy.
Brazil in the Context of the US-EU Partnership
The TTIP follows the trend of focusing foreign policy on regionalism. The
BRICS countries are clearly grounded in regional political alliances, while, at the
same time, they seek to develop multilateral relationships. The goal of joining
free trade zones is far from being just the privilege of the wealthier nations as
before. On 2012, Colombia, Mexico, Chile and Peru signed the Pacific Alliance
agreement, which established zero tariffs for 90 percent of goods traded between
Tostes - 141
them. Chile and Peru joined the group of countries involved in the Transpacific
Trade Partnership (TPP) negotiations, which includes nine countries on both
sides of the Pacific Ocean and promises to boost trade with Asia. Brazil, on the
other hand, has been trying hard to play a leadership role in MERCOSUR and
enhance the consolidation of the common market since 1990’s.
Brazilian foreign policy is constrained by its involvement in MERCOSUR and its relations with Argentina. Argentina buys most of Brazil’s semimanufactured export products, but, is currently experiencing a domestic crisis
that is affecting its imports from Brazil. As Argentina is Brazil’s third largest
trading partner, behind China and the US, every drop in Argentina’s economic
growth or retraction of its economy means a loss of several millions of dollars in
foreign trade for Brazil. The slowdown of the Argentine economy in 2012 made
Brazilian exports fall 20.7 percent, according to economic consultants in Buenos
Aires. The most affected sectors by the decline were the auto parts industry, agricultural machinery and electronics, among others.
MERCOSUR has become less of a project of regional economic integration and trade, and more of a political forum in recent years. After the barring of
Paraguay in 2012 and the admittance of Venezuela as a full member, MERCOSUR has been seen as a political platform rather than a framework for regional development. However, the worse may be yet to come. According to Peña
(2014), the future of MERCOSUR can be directly associated to the development
of both multilateral instruments, like the WTO, and interregional ones, including
the TTIP and the TPP. Even considering that the impact of TTIP on Latin American countries will vary, members of MERCOSUR, such as Brazil, would suffer
from the adoption of new standards and intellectual property rights rules. The
success of the two major transoceanic treaties will affect other multilateral mechanisms for regulating trade, which means that the global multilateral trade system
is about to be impacted to an extent that cannot be foreseen yet.
Brazil’s situation is so complex that even if MERCOSUR accelerates
talks with the EU, cooperation with Europe will still take years to materialize.
When Brazil was classified as an upper middle-income country, it lost some of
the advantages it had in its trade relations with the EU, which turns the acceleration of the MERCOSUR-EU negotiations into a matter of survival. The WTO
Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) reduced import tariffs on a number of
items sold by developing nations. The recent loss brought by Brazil’s change in
status still needs to be calculated and new strategies need to be found urgently. In
2012, Brazil was the third largest beneficiary, with sales of US$ 2.3 billion, behind India and Thailand. In all, the U.S. concedes this advantage to 127 countries
and territories under the GSP. As a result of the change, approximately 3,500
products used by the Brazilian auto parts, construction, chemical, steel, capital
goods and food industries now have to contend with full tariffs.
Moreover, Brazilian exports of steel, machinery, fuel, beef and cotton
now face greater competition when selling to Europe, as the US produces the
Tostes - 142
same products. For airplanes and cars, products manufactured in Brazil come up
against strong competition in the US from European products, and from US
products in the EU. Brazil's growing trade deficit increases the urgency for the
country to make new deals. Indeed, there are two potential scenarios for Brazil: it
can either bring new life into MERCOSUR, or it can look for a way out of it.
There is no road in between. While Chile and Peru are signing free trade and bilateral agreements with the US, the EU and China, Brazil shyly continues to wait
for MERCOSUR to make a move.
The EU is an important market for Brazilian commodities. In 2012, Brazil exports to Europe totaled US$ 48.8 billion to Europe, of which US$ 24.3 billion were commodities, namely agricultural products. Altogether, the European
market was the destination of 20 percent of Brazilian exports. In the 1990’s, that
figure was more than 30 percent. However, during fifteen years of negotiation,
both sides have missed deadlines and compromises. Even so, there are new expectations that talks will move faster in 2015, which could be decisive for Brazil.
If they do not, there is a possibility that preference will be given to the U.S. as an
exporter of agricultural commodities to the European market, which will directly
affect the Brazilian economy. In this context, Brazil has just assumed the rotating
presidency of MERCOSUR and thus, it is in a good position to make concrete
advances on the free trade agenda. This could be a good opportunity for breathing new life into inter-regional cooperation.
Final Notes
There is a disconnection today between the way business operates beyond borders and the methods governments use to pursue international trade. A comprehensive joint action to regulate international trade among big corporations, global
economic groups, and governments is obviously at needed. The EU and the U.S.
already control about half of the supply of services in the world and account for
one third of the global trade of goods. Although the two economic superpowers
are still recovering from the crisis, there are reasons to believe that the TTIP will
accelerate and achieve new forms of cooperation between the regions, and generate millions of euros of savings for companies. While the full consequences of
the TTIP are still unknown, it is clear that the two major powers are pushing
ahead with transoceanic agreements in order to establish a new global commercial order in which the balance of power would be completely different from predictions on the rise of the East.
References
Ahearn, Raymond J. 2009.“Transatlantic Regulatory Cooperation: Background
and Analysis.” CRS Report RL34735, August 2009, accessed at: http://
www.fas.org/sgp/crs/row/RL34717.pdf.
Tostes - 143
Indo Asian News Service. 2012. “China's trade with Latin America grew in
2011.” Accessed at: http://in.news.yahoo.com/chinas-trade-latinamerica-grew-2011-050334275.html.
China-Brazil Update. 2014. Conselho Empresarial Brasil-China, - 10th Edition,
accessed at: http://www.cebc.org.br/sites/default/files/digital_chinabrazil_update_ed10_digital_final_04.11.2014_0.pdf.
European Commission.2011. “EU-US summit: fact sheet on high-level working
group on jobs and growt.” Memo/11/843 Washington, November
2011, accessed at: http://www.spiegel.de/international/world/opinionwill-china-s-rise-spoil-the-trans-atlantic-relationship-a-788109druck.html.
Felbermayr, Gabriel et al. 2015. “Potential impacts of the Transatlantic Trade and
Investment Partnership (TTIP) on developing and emerging economies.” Ifo Institute, Munich & Institute for Applied Economic Research (IAW), Tubingen, January 2015, accessed at: http://www.iaw.
edu/tl_files/dokumente/Study-Summary-2015-TTIP-ifo_iaw.pdf.
FitchRating. Accessed at: https://www.fitchratings.com/web/en/dynamic/fitchhome.jsp.
Final Report High Level Working Group on Jobs and Growth. 2013. February,
accessed at:
Http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2013/february/tradoc_150519.pdf
.
Florini, Ann. 2011. “Rising Asian Powers and Changing Global Governance.”
International Studies Review 13, 24–33.
Gallagher, Kevin and Porzecanski, Roberto. 2010. The Dragon in the Room:
China and the Future of Latin American Industrialization. RedwoodCA: Stanford University Press.
Ministério das Relações Exteriores. 2011. Brasil e China no Reordenamento das
Relações Internacionais: Desafios e Oportunidades. Brasília: Fundação Alexandre Gusmão.
Pena, Félix. 2014. “The Negotiation of the TTIP: a Preliminary View from the
Deep South.” In: Roy, Joaquín and Dominguez, Roberto (Eds.) 2014.
The TTIP: The Transatlantic Partnership between the European Union
Tostes - 144
and the United States. Miami-Florida European Union Center/Jean
Monnet Chair, 185-196.
Pereira, Carlos and Neves, Joao 2011. “Brazil and China: South-South Parternership or North-South Competition?” Policy Paper Foreign Policy at
Brookings, 26, March.
Pew Research Center. 2014. “Support in Principle for U.S.-EU Trade Pact. Bertelsmann Foundation.” Accessed at:
http://www.pewglobal.org/files/2014/04/Pew-Research-CenterBertelsmann-Foundation-U.S.-Germany-Trade-Report-FINALWednesday-April-9-2014.pdf.
The German Marshall Fund of the United States. 2012. “High-level Transatlantic
Task Force calls for a new era of Transatlantic trade leadership.” Accessed at: http://www.gmfus.org/commentary/high-level-transatlantictask-force-calls-new-era-transatlantic-trade-leadership.
Thomas, Leigh. 2013. “OECD sees Europe joining U.S. recovery, emerging markets sluggish.” Reuters edition, accessed at:
http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/09/03/us-oecd-economyidUSBRE9820AG20130903.
Transatlantic Trade & Investment Partnership Advisory Group Meeting Report.
2014. Accessed at:
http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2014/december/tradoc_152937.pdf.
Health-Related IPR Provisions in FTAs in the Atlantic
Community
Liliana Lizarazo Rodríguez
Independent Legal Consultant
Lurong Chen
UNU-CRIS
Philippe De Lombaerde
UNU-CRIS1
Abstract
This chapter addresses Intellectual Propriety Rights (IPR) clauses in FTAs in the
Atlantic Community that impact the right to health. The chapter also discusses
why health-related IPR provisions are so controversial in trade negotiations and
how national (and regional) courts are trying to solve the problem of balancing
IPRs and the right to health.
Introduction
Since the 1990s, Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) which seek to deepen bilateral,
inter-regional and region-to-country economic relations have proliferated in the
Atlantic Community. Some regional groupings such as the Andean Community
of Nations (CAN) or MERCOSUR have lost some terrain and sometimes had to
adapt their rules to allow the signature of FTAs by their member states. Simultaneously, trade agendas have been politicized and the social agendas are more
prominent in new groupings such as UNASUR. Other new regional groupings
such as the Pacific Alliance or the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) projects continue to focus on trade, strengthen IPR, seek International Technology Transfer (ITT) and go beyond the standards of the World Trade
Organization (WTO). In the area of health, the main issues at stake are global
access to medicines and global IPR protection in order to stimulate R&D (Mercurio 2006:38-40; Sell 2011).
IPR Clauses in FTAs and the Right to Health
The new generation of FTAs includes some conditionality related to the duty to
respect human rights (HR) (Bartels 2008), but the EU and the U.S. HR conditionality in FTAs refers mostly to first generation rights, giving Economic, Social
1
The authors thank Yentl Clijmans and Jania Silva for their help with data collection.
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 146
and Cultural Rights (ESCR) only a marginal role except for some labor standards
of the International Labor Organization (ILO) included in the US FTAs.
The ESCR Committee of the UN2 and other organisms such as the World
Health Organization (WHO) have identified potential negative effects of TradeRelated Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS+)3 clauses in the EU and
the US FTAs and expressed doubts on whether increased protection of IPRs effectively supports R&D in health for the general benefit (’t Hoen 2003; UNESCR Committee 2010: 10-1; Ely 2003). In fact, instead of recognizing the positive effects of TRIPS+ protection of IPR on innovation (Mercurio 2010), their
possible detrimental effects on the access to medicines have been identified as
follows: (i) broadening patentability or the ever greening of pharmaceutical patents, (i.e. the registration of new forms and new uses of known substances to
extend the patent by modifying the molecules which “do not significantly improve the therapeutic effect of medicines”); (ii) restricting patent oppositions,
seeking to avoid “patent applications that do not fulfil the requirements in national legislation for granting the patents;” (iii) extension of patents beyond the
TRIPS protection; (iv) introduction of Test Data Exclusivity and a PatentRegistration Linkage; and (v) IP enforcement requirements (e.g. by seizing generics in transit) (UNDP-UNAIDS 2012; Nasu 2010).
The Doha Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health of 2001 (DD 2001)
sought to enhance flexibility to the TRIPS enforcement in case of a public health
crises in developing countries (Crook 2005: 545, 550; UNDP-UNAIDS 2012;
Roffe and Spennemann 2006:85-6). Although in the Special 301 Report4 of 2013
the U.S. recognized the scope DD 2001, it did it under the condition that “market
access barriers that U.S. pharmaceutical and medical device companies face in
many countries” had being reduced (USTR 2013:22-3).
Until 1994, when NAFTA and the European Economic Area were
signed, no FTAs included binding IPR rules yet. The CAN was a pioneer in including IPR rules into its regulation but the scope of these rules is not clear (Kohl
et al. 2013). Table 1 offers a panoramic view of the inclusion of IPR clauses in
FTAs in the Atlantic Community and indicates whether they are binding or nonbinding. These results should be carefully analyzed provided that in recent years,
IPR-related investment rules are being included in FTAs as it is the case of Canadian FTAs. The table shows a clear trend over time: binding clauses on IPR are
becoming a constant in FTAs. A more detailed analysis should confirm the idea
2
The right to health is recognized in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (UDHR)
(25) and in the International Covenant of ESCR (ICESCR) (12). General Comment 14 of
the ICESCR Committee defined the content, implementation and enforcement of the international right to health.
3
TRIPS+ clauses increase the protection of IPR beyond the parameters of the TRIPS (see
Horn et al 2009).
4
The annual global review of IPR protection and enforcement by the Office of the US
Trade Representative (USTR).
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 147
that the EU and the U.S. include binding TRIPS+ clauses whereas south-south
FTAs agreements include binding clauses while staying within the TRIPS
framework.
TRIPS+ clauses in FTAs involving the EU and the US are strongly contested by some emerging economies but IPR protection through investment
clauses has been a low profile mechanism. This new modality of TRIPS+ clauses
by means of including IPR in the definition of investment in the Bilateral Investment Treaties (BITs) and in some investment clauses of FTAs represent a
threat to the DD2001 because it opens new ways to protect IPR (investor-state
dispute settlement mechanism for investments involving IPR, market value compensation for losses and prohibition of direct and indirect expropriation) at the
cost of universal access to medicines (Benedict 2012; see also Ruse-Khan
2011b, 2014a).
Table 1: IPR provisions in FTAs in the Atlantic Community
FTAs entered into
force in:
1950s
1960s
1970s
1980s
1990s
2000s
2010s
Total:
Number of
FTAs in
sample:
1
1
6
2
16
25
13
64
Of which FTAs,
without IPR
with nonclauses
binding IPR
clauses
1
0
1
0
6
0
1
1
10
0
9
3
2
0
30
4
with binding
IPR clauses
0
0
0
0
6
13
11
30
Sources:
Kohl
et
al.
(2013)
(FTAs
until
2011),
http://rtais.wto.org/UI/PublicAllRTAList.aspx, and texts of FTAs taken from
government websites.
The Economic Importance of Pharmaceutical Trade and Investment
Health-related IPR provisions matter from an economic perspective because of
their effect on the cost of medicines (Andia 2011; as quoted in Lamprea
2013:28). Price controls of medicines have been proposed by governments, mostly designed by taking as a reference a basket of international prices to guarantee a
good allocation of governmental resources. Another issue is the development of
generic medicines once patents expire.
Recently, the development of bio-generics has led to even more complexity than with chemical generics; biological medicines represent almost 30
percent of the pharmaceutical market in some countries where they are mostly
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 148
financed by the public health systems (Minsalud 2014). In this market, the discussion on patent flexibility is less relevant than the technological capacity of
developing countries to regulate these processes and to produce bio-similars. The
U.S. and the EU and their biotechnological industries are expressing concerns
about the enforcement of the DD 2001 in this respect and they are addressing
these issues to the WTO as they concern not only IPR but also Technical Barriers
to Trade (TBT).
In Latin-America, some countries are trying to regulate the market to allow the commercialization of bio-similars, but it remains a huge challenge and
therefore, regional (and south-south) cooperation is being proposed to deepen
market regulation and production without the intervention of U.S. and EU pharmaceuticals and strong emerging economies such as India and Brazil are leading
the way (Feijó et al. 2012, 2014; Lage 2011).
One of the main foci of the TTIP is the regulation of the pharmaceutical
sector, seeking to reach a better coordination between the European Medicines
Agency (EMA) and the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA), at the level
of technical requirements for good manufacturing practices and quality (Goyens
2014). Although both parties have a strong IPR system and seek to keep health
expenditures under control, 5 with the TTIP they aim at harmonizing regulations
to improve access to complex medicines with special reference to generics (biosimilars).
It is not easy to quantify the economic relevance of the pharmaceutical
sector in all its aspects, but when looking at trade of the two major players in the
Atlantic Community, we see that exports of pharmaceuticals represent approx. 4
percent of total trade for the EU and 3 percent for the U.S. (figure 1). The trend is
slightly upward in both cases, although these percentages are sensitive to price
movements on raw materials and energy markets. Based on OECD figures, we
calculate that the pharmaceutical sector represents approximately 5,6 percent of
EU’s outward FDI position, while the corresponding figure for the U.S. would be
1,1 percent. A relevant fact is that multinational pharmaceutical companies receive much of their revenues as service payments for their IPR.
Figure 1: Share of
pharmaceuticals in total
exports of the EU and
the US (%), 2003-2013
Sources: EUROSTAT,
European Commission
5
For more detailed information of what is at stake in the Pharmaceuticals in TTIP please
access
http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2015/january/tradoc_153010.4.7%20Pharmaceutical
s.pdf.
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 149
and International Trade Administration, US Department of Commerce (HS30).
Looking at the structure of the Atlantic pharmaceutical trade (table 2),
some observations arise: first, the relative importance of intra-regional trade for
the EU, NAFTA and UNASUR seems to be slowly decreasing (i.e. the relative
importance of extra-regional trade flows is increasing). Second, the U.S. has reduced its trade dependence on the EU. Third, MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance have been sourcing relatively more from the EU and relatively less from the
U.S. over the last decade. Fourth, both MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance
saw the share of intra-regional sourcing decrease in the 2000s, after which it has
stabilized or even recovered slightly.
Table 2: Structure of pharmaceutical imports (SITC 54), by origin (2013-2000)
2013
EU27
EU27
66,73
%
49,68
%
55,30
%
45,98
%
46,72
%
57,95
%
EU27
Mercosur
NAFTA
Pacific Alliance
UNASUR
USA
2010
EU27
2000
68,85
%
46,27
%
59,01
%
42,01
%
43,13
%
61,65
%
EU27
EU27
69,79
Mercosur
NAFTA
Pacific Alliance
UNASUR
USA
Mercosur
0,22%
6,98%
0,65%
5,63%
8,01%
0,29%
Mercosur
0,31%
NAFTA
15,28
%
20,39
%
11,49
%
27,16
%
20,77
%
5,93%
Pacific
Alliance
0,18%
UNASU
R
0,22%
4,66%
8,62%
0,57%
0,73%
3,56%
7,54%
6,63%
11,25%
0,53%
0,31%
Pacific
Alliance
0,17%
UNASU
R
0,31%
4,43%
8,46%
0,51%
0,51%
3,45%
7,74%
6,72%
11,46%
0,27%
NAFTA
14,30
%
23,40
%
12,36
%
30,52
%
23,69
%
6,81%
0,46%
0,29%
Mercosur
0,11%
NAFTA
16,24
Pacific
Alliance
0,10%
UNASU
R
0,11%
6,79%
0,45%
5,74%
8,04%
USA
14,21
%
16,15
%
6,55%
22,85
%
15,93
%
USA
13,56
%
17,70
%
6,69%
26,42
%
17,78
%
USA
15,80
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 150
Mercosur
NAFTA
Pacific Alliance
UNASUR
USA
%
45,69
%
59,99
%
37,84
%
41,89
%
68,93
%
9,37%
0,38%
7,93%
11,02%
0,21%
%
24,73
%
18,02
%
30,92
%
24,51
%
6,14%
7,38%
12,23%
0,60%
0,52%
7,23%
11,93%
10,75%
16,13%
0,56%
0,25%
%
19,14
%
13,32
%
25,88
%
17,52
%
Note: Read horizontally, the table shows the relative importance of imports by
origin (as % of total imports).
Source: UN COMTRADE.
The Growing Role of National Courts in Balancing IPR and the Right to
Health
The tensions between IPR and the right to health concern the trade partners of the
US and the EU but also the WTO because national courts are often aligning with
goals of the WHO and the UN (MDGs, SDGs) that seek universal coverage in
health-care. This situation is challenging the international status quo where most
of the IPR regulations are binding rules, whereas ESCR such as the right to
health are not globally enforced due to lack of sanctions (Crook 2005:538; Van
Hees 2004).
Certain courts in Latin America are worldwide recognized as very active
in the defense of ESCR; in some cases also regional courts (i.e. Andean Tribunal
of Justice (ATJ))6 have protected ESCR over trade and investment. These courts
are part of the globalization of HR phenomenon, understood as a growing judicial adjudication on HR matters (Tushnet 2008; Kennedy 2006; Stone and Matthews 2008; Bomhoff 2008), as a consequence of the emergence of constitutions
where ESCR are included with more binding force than before following the
guidelines of the UDHR and the ICESCR (ICJ 2008; Landau 2014).7 TRIPS+
clauses are therefore facing a new challenge at the national (regional) level of
emerging countries, mostly from Latin America where the judiciary privileges
6
ATJ ruled that the patent registration of proof data for medicines would threaten free
competition and the right to access to medicines by extending patents (Ruling 114-AI2004; quoted by Uribe 2007: 115). CAN modified its decisions to allow the signature of
the FTAs of Colombia and Peru with the US and with the EU (Saura 2013; Helfer and
Alter 2014).
7
Certain constitutional rules address health care and have been the basis of the judicial
enforceability of the right to health (Bonilla 2014; Ely and Parra 2009; ICJ 2008;
Rodríguez 2011).
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 151
constitutions, UDHR and ICESCR over WTO rules. Moreover, some national
courts in emerging economies are pushing for a strict regulation of the market of
medicines, seeking equality and efficient public resource allocation by avoiding
paying exorbitant prices for medicines (see ruling C313/14 of the Colombian
Constitutional Court (CCC).
There is empirical evidence from Colombia, Brazil and Argentina, where
rights-based judicial adjudication has been crucial in the enforcement of ESCR
and in particular in the protection of the right to health (Byrne 2009; Narula
2011; Bonilla 2014; Lunes et al 2012; Mæstad et. al. 2011). Countries such as
Brazil and Argentina have even delayed the signature of FTAs with the U.S. and
the EU, among other reasons because of the TRIPS+ clauses of these agreements.
In Brazil, some landmark cases of annulling patents for constitutional reasons8
are a concern as well as lawsuits “filed by Brazil’s National Industrial Property
Institute (INPI) seeking to invalidate or shorten the term of certain “mailbox”
patents for pharmaceutical and agrochemical products” (USTR 2014:49).
The U.S. has also been expressing concerns about Brazil (and Peru) because of the “proliferation of counterfeit pharmaceuticals manufactured, sold and
distributed” (USTR 2014:20). Argentina (since 1996) and Chile remain on the
priority watch list because of the existence of “unfair commercial use or unauthorized disclosure of test and other data generated to obtain marketing approval
for pharmaceutical products.” Chile, despite the existence of the U.S. FTA, is
also urged to implement a more expedite patent system for pharmaceutical products (USTR 2014:44).
In Colombia, the CCC held that FTAs should be enforced and interpreted
in accordance with the protection of constitutional rights, especially the right to
health (Lizarazo et al. 2014; Kingah et al. 2014). The negotiations of the COLEU FTA were controversial because IPR clauses were closer to the parameters of
EU legislation (TRIPS+) at the cost of the DD 2001 (Ifarma and FMS 2009; Seuba 2009: 65-8). The final version of the EU FTA conditioned its enforcement to
the respect of the general interest and the DD 2001 is an interpretative parameter
for public health issues (Seuba and García 2010). Colombia also remains on the
watch list of the USTA because it is limiting the patentability of some pharmaceuticals and there are also some concerns about data protection (USTR
2014:50).
Another pending issue is the seizure of generic medicines in transit from
India to Brazil by EU countries because they are seen as an obstruction to the
enforcement of the right to health to the benefit of trade (Stelen et al 2012; Mercurio 2012). Conflicts about border seizures, IPR protection in cases of compul8
A lawsuit was presented eg against the patent of Abbott Laboratories for being granted
under the ‘pipeline mechanism’ (i.e. revalidation of patents already granted elsewhere
without following the Brazilian procedure) and despite the fact that the generic was validated by the WHO (http://business-humanrights.org/en/abbott-laboratories-lawsuit-rebrazil-patent-law-access-to-medicines).
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 152
sory licensing and potential TBT in bio-generic regulations are being presented
before the WTO Dispute Settlement Mechanism (DSM) where the relevance of
HR agreements and in particular of the DD 2001 remains unclear, in strong contrast with national courts where the ICESCR is gaining relevance vis-à-vis WTO
law.
Conclusions
In the Atlantic Community, the EU and the U.S. appear as the leading IPR holders, suppliers of regulations and producers of pharmaceutics. The TTIP emerges
as a new way to coordinate rules but faces opposition of Latin-American countries. The UNASUR in particular, under Brazil’s leadership, is trying to support
the development of a market for pharmaceuticals far from the TRIPS+ regulations. Although the Pacific Alliance emerges as a grouping which is more
aligned with FTAs of the EU and the U.S., countries such as Chile and Colombia
are also trying to develop the market of bio-generics in order to keep their public
health expenditures under control. It remains unclear whether they have the institutional capacity to regulate and produce bio-generics. New TBT standards as
promoted by the U.S. and the EU through the TTIP represent new challenges for
these Latin America countries.
The consolidation of national activist courts supported by the UN, WHO
and NGOs in the defense of ESCR and the rise of emerging economies, open
new perspectives for the goal of balancing IPR and the right to health at the benefit of most vulnerable populations and without affecting innovation. Overprotection of IPR holders in combination with non-coordinated intervention of
different judicial authorities at different levels are creating legal uncertainty and
the costs of litigation may also affect social policy goals. In fact, the balancing of
IPR with the right to health, as it was intended by DD 2001, is provoking contradictory rulings at different levels (international, national and regional) which is
related to overlapping levels of regulation (national constitutional level, FTAs,
regional integration groupings, WHO, WTO, EU etc.).
References
Abbott, F.M. 2007. The Problems of Intellectual Property in Latin America and
How to Address Them. Santiago: UN-ECLAC –GTZ.
Checkel and Katzenstein Bartels, L. 2008. The Application of Human Rights
Conditionality in the EU’s Bilateral Trade Agreements and Other Trade
Arrangements with Third Countries. Brussels: EU Parliament.
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 153
Benedict, A. 2012. “Intellectual Property in Investment Agreements: More
“Teeth” for Foreign Investors’ IP Rights, Less for Access to Medicines,”
accessed at
http://blogs.law.harvard.edu/billofhealth/2012/09/18/intellectualproperty-in-investment-agreements-more-teeth-for-foreign-investorss-iprights-less-for-access-to-medicines/.
Bomhoff, J. 2008. “Balancing, the Global and the Local: Judicial Balancing as a
Problematic Topic in Comparative (Constitutional) Law,” Hastings International and Comparative Law Review, 31(2).
Bonilla, D. 2014. Constitutionalism of the Global South. The Activist Tribunals
of India, South Africa and Colombia. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Byrne, I. 2009. “Enforcing the Right to Health: Innovative Lessons from Domestic Courts,” in Clapham, A. et al. (eds) Realizing the right to health, 52538.
Crook. 2005. “Balancing intellectual property protection with the human right to
health,” Berkeley Journal of International Law, 23(3), 524-550.
Ely, A. and Parra-Vera, O. 2009. “How Do Courts Set Health Policy? The Case
of the Colombian Constitutional Court,” PlosMedicine, 6(2), 147-50.
Ely, A. 2003. “Not Just a Tragedy: Access to Medications as a Right under International Law,” Boston University International Law Journal, 21, 325-71.
Feijo, V., Sandorff, E., Siemak, B. and Halbert, R. 2012. “Potential Regulatory
and Commercial Environment for Biosimilars in Latin America,” Value
in Health Regional Issues, 1, 228– 34.
Feijó, V. et al. 2014. “Recomendaciones para la reglamentación de biosimilares y
su implementación en Latinoamérica,” Generics and Biosimilars Initiative Journal, 3(3).
Goyens, M. 2014. “How will TTIP affect the health of Europeans?,” accessed at
http://www.beuc.eu/blog/how-will-ttip-affect-the-health-of-europeans/.
Grosse Ruse-Khan, H. 2011b. “Protecting Intellectual Property under BITs,
FTAs, and TRIPS,” in K. Miles and C. Brown (eds), Evolution In Investment Treaty Law And Arbitration, CUP, 485-515.
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 154
Grosse Ruse-Khan, H. 2011c. “The International Law Relation between TRIPS
and Subsequent TRIPS-Plus FTAs,” Journal of Intellectual Property
Law, 18(2).
Grosse Ruse-Khan, H. 2014a. “Litigating Intellectual Property Rights In Investor-State Arbitration,” Max Planck Institute for Innovation and Competition Research Paper, (14-13).
Helfer, L. and Alter, K. 2014. “The Influence of the Andean Intellectual Property
Regime on Access to Medicines in Latin America,” in Dreyfuss, R.
and Rodríguez, C. (eds.) Balancing Wealth and Health: Global Administrative Law and the Battle over Intellectual Property and Access to Medicines in Latin America. New York: Oxford University Press, 247-262.
Horn, H. et al. 2009. “Beyond the WTO? An Anatomy of EU and US Preferential Trade Agreements,” Bruegel Blueprint Series, (VII).
IFarma and Fundación Misión Salud. 2009. Impact of the EU Andean Trade
Agreement on Access to Medicines in Colombia. Bogotá: IFarma.
ICJ 2008. Courts and the Legal Enforcement of economic, social and cultural
rights: Comparative experiences of justiciability. Geneva: International
Commission of Jurists.
Iunes, R., Cubillos, L. and Escobar, M. 2012. “Universal Health Coverage and
Litigation In Latin America,” (178), The World Bank, accessed at
www.worldbank.org/enbreve.
Kennedy, D. 2006. “Three Globalizations of Law and Legal Thought: 18502000,” in D.M. Trubek and A. Santos (eds), The New Law and Development: A Critical Appraisal, CUP, 19-73.
Kingah, S., Lizarazo, L. and De Lombaerde, P. 2014. “Constitutional Courts as
Bulwarks against the Erosion of Social and Economic Rights through
Free Trade Agreements: Colombia and South Africa Compared,” Manchester Journal of International Economic Law, 11(3), 331-366.
Kohl, T., S. Brakman, and J.H. Garretsen. 2013. "Do trade agreements stimulate
international trade differently? Evidence from 296 trade agreements," CESifo Working Paper, (4243).
Lage, A. 2011. “Desarrollo Farmaceútico Global y Acceso a Medicamentos: Temas Críticos de Ética y Equidad,” MEDICC Review, 13(3).
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 155
Lamprea, E. 2013. “Colombia's Right-to-Health Litigation in a Context of Health
Care Reform,” in Gross, A. and Flood, C. (eds) The Right to Health at
the Public/Private Divide: A Global Comparative Study. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Landau, D. 2014. “A Dynamic Theory of Judicial Role,” Boston College Law
Review, 55(5): art. 4.
Lizarazo, L., De Lombaerde, P., Ortiz, J.F., Parra, A. and Rettberg, A. 2014.
“Constitutional Aspects of FTAs: A Colombian Perspective,” European
Law Journal, 20(6), 824-847.
Mæstad, O., Rakner, L. and Motta Ferraz, O.L. 2011. “Assessing the impact of
health rights litigation: A comparative analysis of Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Costa Rica, India and South Africa,” in Ely, A. and Gloppen, S.
(eds) Litigating health rights. Can courts bring more justice to health?
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 273-303.
Mercurio, B. 2006. “Resolving the Public Health Crisis in the Developing
World,” Northwestern Journal of International Human Rights, 5(1).
Mercurio B. 2010. “Reconceptualising the Debate on Intellectual Property Rights
and Economic Development,” Law and Development Review, 3(1), art. 3.
Mercurio, B. 2012. “‘Seizing’ Pharmaceuticals In Transit: Analysing the WTO
Dispute That Wasn’t,” International and Comparative Law Quarterly,
61, 389–426.
Minsalud. 2014. ABC of Biothec Drugs. Bogotá: Ministerio de Salud y Protección Social.
Narula, S. 2011. “The Rights-Based Approach to Intellectual Property and Access to Medicine: Parameters and Pitfalls,” NYU School of Law Public
Law Research Paper, (11-60).
Nasu, H. 2010. “Public Law Challenges to the Regulation of Pharmaceutical Patents in the US Bilateral Free Trade Agreement,” in Pogge, T. et al. (eds)
Incentives for Global Public Health: Patent Law and Access to Essential
Medicines, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 101-32.
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 156
Rodríguez, C. 2011. “Beyond the Courtroom: The Impact of Judicial Activism on
Socioeconomic Rights in Latin America,” Texas Law Review, 89(7),
1669-1698.
Roffe, P. and Spennemann, C. 2006. “The impact of FTAs on public health policies and TRIPS flexibilities,” International Journal of Intellectual Property Management, 1(1-2), 75-93.
Saura, J. 2013. “Implicaciones de derechos humanos en el tratado de libre comercio entre Colombia y Unión Europea,” INDRET Revista para el Análisis del Derecho, (4), 1-25.
Sell, S. 2011. “Trips Was Never Enough: Vertical Forum Shifting, FTAs, Acta,
and TPP,” Journal of Intellectual Property Law, 18, 447-78.
Seuba, H.X. 2009. La Protección de la Salud en el Nuevo Acuerdo de Asociación
entre la Comunidad Andina (o Algunos de sus Miembros) y la Comunidad Europea a la Luz de sus Disposiciones en Materia de Propiedad Intelectual y Experiencias Recientes. Lima: HAI-AIS.
Seuba, X. and García, J.F. 2010. “Propiedad Intelectual y Salud Pública en el
AdA entre la UE y Colombia y Perú,” Puentes, ICTSD, 11(3).
Stelen, M., Guise, R. and Shaver, L. 2012. “Why Are Generic Drugs Being Held
Up in Transit? Intellectual Property Rights, International Trade, and the
Right to Health in Brazil and Beyond,” Journal of Law, Medicine & Ethics, (summer), 197-205.
Stone Sweet, A. and Mathews, J. 2008. “Proportionality, Balancing and Global
Constitutionalism,” Columbia Journal of Transnational Law, 47, 73-165.
’t Hoen, E.F. 2003, “TRIPS, Pharmaceutical Patents and Access to Essential
Medicines: Seattle, Doha and Beyond,” accessed at
http://www.who.int/intellectualproperty/topics/ip/tHoen.pdf.
Tushnet, M. 2008. “The Inevitable Globalization of Constitutional Law,” Harvard Public Law Working Paper, (09-06).
UNDP-UNAIDS. 2012. “The Potential Impact of FTAs on Public Health,” Issue
Brief, UNDP-UNAIDS.
UN-ESCR Committee. 2010. Concluding Observations of the Committee on
Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (E/C.12/COL/CO/5).
Lizarazo, Chen and De Lombaerde - 157
Uribe, A.M. 2007. “Los ‘Beneficios’ del TLC: Las Consecuencias para la Biodiversidad y el Sistema de Propiedad Intelectual de Colombia,” Revista
Pensamiento Jurídico, (18), 103-23.
USTR. 2013/2014. Special 301 Report. Washington: USTR.
Van Hees, F. 2004. Protection v. Protectionism. The Use of Human Rights Arguments in the Debate for and against the Liberalisation of Trade. Åbo
Akademi: Åbo.
The European Union and Latin America: Facing the DrugTrafficking Challenge*
Alejandro Chanona
National Autonomous University of Mexico
Abstract
In recent decades, the fight against drug trafficking has been one of the most
important issues in the relations between the European Union (EU) and Latin
America and the Caribbean (LAC). The growing focus on this question is
fed by the new challenges that drugs and their dynamic impose on both regions. EU-LAC cooperation to fight drug trafficking promotes a balanced,
comprehensive vision that recognizes the importance of combatting drugs
through policies designated to intercept narcotics and strengthen national
institutions, but also to deal with the underlying causes of the problem
through programs that include drug-use prevention, rehabilitation of addicts,
and alternative development programs in producing countries. The EU-LAC
relations in this area can contribute to the development and implementation
of alternative policies in the framework of the world debate about the limits
of the traditional paradigm for fighting drug trafficking. Despite this opportunity, an analysis of cooperation projects in this field reveals the gap between the discourse and implementation, not only in terms of resources, but
also of approach. And this is because the logic of limiting the amount of
drugs that leave Latin America for Europe continues to prevail.
Introduction
Cooperation to fight drug trafficking and consumption has gradually been
incorporated into the European Union (EU)-Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) agenda since the mid-1990’s. In contrast with traditional views
like the so-called “war on drugs,” which has focused on combatting production and emphasizing a prohibitionist approach banning drugs, EU-LAC
*
This paper presents some preliminary results of an ongoing research project “Facing
Transnational Organized Crime: Comparative Study of Regional Strategies”, National
Autonomous University of Mexico (UNAM).
Chanona - 160
cooperation conceives of illegal drugs as a social and security problem requiring a comprehensive policy response.
A first look at the EU-LAC counter-narcotics cooperation paradigm
suggests that it should support the non-traditional efforts of many Latin
American countries facing the drug problem. Moreover, in the framework of
the debates about the failure of punitive responses, based on eradication,
prohibition, and criminalization of consumption, the European “harm reduction” model prioritizing prevention, medical treatment, and partial decriminalization of drug use could be a point of reference for a renewed strategy
against drugs.
Yet, bi-regional cooperation against narcotics faces different constraints: the different inter- and intra-regional perceptions of the drug problem and how to deal with it; the inexistence of a single voice and common
strategy on drugs in LAC; the limited resources for bi-regional cooperation
programs; and the pre-eminence of the focus on combatting cocaine production in the Andean countries.
The European Model: Harm Reduction
According to the 2014 European Drug Report, drug consumption in the
EU remains stable: around 14.1 million people are taking or have at some
point used cocaine; 10.6 million, ecstasy; and 73.6 million, cannabis
(EMCDDA 2014:13). Nevertheless, overdoses continue to be the main
cause of death among young people, and concern exists about the growing
use of synthetic drugs and the “new psychoactive substances.” It is also important to point out that the EU countries are no longer just drug consumers:
they have become producers of cannabis and synthetic drugs, thus making
the problem more complex.
According to the European Commission (2011), “illicit drugs are a
major threat to the health and safety of individuals and societies in the EU.”
Therefore, for EU members, drug trafficking and consumption are related to
public security issues (health and well-being).
In the EU, member country governments continue to shoulder the
responsibility for drug policy design and implementation. Over the last 20
years, they have developed frameworks for EU action to coordinate drug
policies and create a common framework to make national strategies consistent and strengthen cooperation.
In 2003, the EU adopted “harm reduction” as a common principle for drafting EU drug strategy for 2005-2012; the approach was adopted
in December 2004. Harm reduction is an alternative answer to drug prob-
Chanona - 161
lems that seeks to reduce the harm associated with illicit drug use and develop specific programs focused on the life-threatening conditions of drug
users, as well as prevention, rehabilitation, and reintegration policies.
Therefore, national strategies are increasingly oriented around this model.
According to the 2014 EMCDDA report, a trend seems to be emerging toward countries focusing on penalizing supply rather than possession of
these substances.
Hence, European drug policy aims to take a balanced, integrated approach to the drug problem combining demand reduction and supply reduction measures (European Commission 2011; Council of the European Union
2012). The European Council has specified two general aims regarding
drugs: 1) complementing national actions in preventing and reducing drug
use to contribute to attaining high levels of health protection and well-being;
and 2) taking action against drug production, cross-border trafficking, and
the diversion of precursors.
The 2013-2020 EU Drug Strategy is structured around these policy
areas and three crosscutting themes:
1) Coordination: police cooperation and coordination within the EU, improving Europol capacities and border controls in the framework of
the European Area of Freedom, Security and Justice;
2) International cooperation: identifying European Neighborhood countries as a priority as well as the need to address old and emerging trafficking routes such as those in West Africa.
3) Research, information, monitoring, and evaluation: through the European Monitoring Centre for Drugs and Drug Addiction (European Union 2012; EMCDDA 2013).
The European Union Action Plan on Drugs (2013-2016) states that two
fundamental objectives exist within the EU legal framework: reducing both drug
use and supply. Likewise, it seeks to effectively reduce the age at which users
begin to consume these substances. In sum, the main approach in the region for
reducing demand is the harm reduction model. Member states still have different
opinions about drug policy and priorities, and gaps still exist in anti-narcotics
actions, especially among nations like Italy, Spain, and some Eastern European
countries, where criminal groups are more active. These differences make it difficult for the EU to adopt common positions in international bodies and in discussions with third parties, including Latin America (Gratius 2012).
Latin America’s “War on Drugs”
Latin America and the Caribbean have a long history of fighting drug trafficking.
Prohibitionist policies centered on the head-on fight against the production and
Chanona - 162
transportation of illicit drugs became important after 1973, with Richard Nixon’s
“War on Drugs.” This approach became more and more entrenched after the end
of the Cold War, when the fight against drug trafficking became one of the most
important items on the inter-American agenda.
However, an assessment of the “war on drugs” in Latin America shows its
limits: between 1999 and 2010, coca leaf and cocaine production decreased by 50
percent in Colombia, but has increased in Peru and Bolivia (during the same period
the land used for drug cultivation practically doubled in Peru) (Gratius 2012).
There has been a worrying increase in cocaine consumption in South America,
especially in Brazil. The number of past-year cocaine users in South America was
estimated at almost 2 million in the period 2004-2005 and 3.35 million in 2012
(UNODC 2014: 36). Moreover, drug trafficking is one of the main factors behind increased criminal violence in the region, particularly in Central America,
Mexico, Venezuela, Brazil, and Colombia. With a homicide rate of 26.5 per
100,000 people, Central America is the most insecure area in the world (UNODC
2013:33).
Drug trafficking challenges the national security of the Latin
American countries in different ways. A state’s response capabilities vis-àvis this threat depend on its institutional strengths, its location on the map
of criminal activity (producing, consuming, and transit countries), and the
mechanisms it uses to deal with them.
The complex problem of drug trafficking in Latin America has
generated a variety of responses at national, sub-regional, and hemispheric
levels. It is important to note that, in all cases, the need to promote comprehensive policies to combat this threat is recognized, but, historically,
governments prioritized the traditional model centered on the use of force.
For many countries in the region, drug trafficking is the main threat
to national security, and the armed forces have been incorporated into a
variety of activities in the war on drugs: border enforcement, prohibition
activities, the arrest of criminal leaders, and public security. With their respective differences, Mexico, Guatemala, Honduras, Peru, Brazil, and Colombia are examples of these policies. But for other countries, like Chile
or Uruguay, the drug problem remains on the public security agenda. The
Uruguayan government has even gone as far as to decriminalize cannabis,
regulating its production and commercialization.
At the hemispheric level, since the 1980s, Latin American countries have promoted regional cooperation against drug trafficking in the
framework of the Organization of American States. The first initiatives
were intended to create multilateral mechanisms opposed to U.S. unilateral policies. In particular, emphasis was on the principle of shared responsibility and regional counter-narcotics cooperation. The establishment
Chanona - 163
of the Inter-American Drug Abuse Control Commission (CICAD) in 1986,
the approval of the first Anti-Drug Strategy in the hemisphere in 1996, and
the creation of the Multilateral Evaluation Mechanism in 1998 were part
of this dynamic (Chanona 2011).
The principle of shared responsibility, the promotion of multilateral cooperation, and the commitment to adopt comprehensive policies against drug
trafficking are elements of the Hemispheric Plan of Action against Transnational
Organized Crime (2006); the Hemispheric Drug Strategy (2010); and the Hemispheric Plan of Action on Drugs 2011-2015 (2011). Nevertheless, until now, hemispheric cooperation against drug trafficking and consumption has had limits. A
coordinating mechanism is still lacking, and sub-regional initiatives have been
playing a more important role in the fight against organized crime.
Bi-Regional Cooperation
Latin America and the European Union share values and principles that are the
core of their bi-regional partnership. In the area of security, both regions have
adopted the broad concept of multidimensional security and share values like
solidarity, cooperation, multilateralism, respect for human rights, and shared responsibility on drug issues.
Both regions agree that fighting drug trafficking and consumption requires international cooperation and an “integrated, multidisciplinary and balanced approach combining drug demand reduction and drug supply reduction
measures” (EU-CELAC Quito Declaration 2013).
In response to the challenge of increased cocaine consumption in European countries, in 1995, the Specialized High-Level Political Dialogue on Drugs
with the Andean Community was established. In the case of the Caribbean
Community, a strategic area for moving drugs to Europe, the Barbados Action
Plan was put into effect in 1996 with the participation of the United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime and the CICAD.
At the bi-regional level, the EU-LAC Coordination and Cooperation Mechanism on Drugs was formally launched in 1998,1 with the aim of fostering institutional strengthening and the development of national and regional policies to allow the countries to deal with the drug problem. Its action plan, known also as
the Panama Action Plan, was approved in 1999. Since that time, both regions
have worked in key areas including:
x Demand reduction: exchange of information on drug policies, prevention
and treatment activities;
x Supply reduction: joint actions to identify and dismantle organized crime
1
Since December 2011, with the creation of the Community of Latin American and Caribbean States (Comunidad de Estados Latinoamericanos y Caribeños, or CELAC), the
term “LAC” has been replaced by “CELAC.”
Chanona - 164
x
x
x
groups, strengthening judicial cooperation; promoting alternative
development projects to coca plantations;
Mutual technical assistance programs on capacity-building (police,
customs, judicial action);
The establishment of drug observatories, with the aim of creating an
integrated system of drug information, collecting comparable indicators on
production, consumption, trafficking, chemical precursors, and moneylaundering;
Strengthening maritime cooperation, particularly with the Caribbean through the Barbados Plan of Action;
x Technical dialogue on precursor chemicals; and
x Improved capacities against money laundering, with special attention to Andean and Caribbean countries (EEAS 2014).
The Cooperation Program between Latin America and the European
Union of Drug Policies (COPOLAD) was established in 2009. Based on
the idea of promoting an inclusive and balanced anti-drug strategy, the
program has four components: 1) consolidation of the EU-LAC Coordination and Cooperation Mechanism on Drugs; 2) consolidation of the national
drugs observatories; 3) capacity-building in demand reduction (prevention,
treatment, rehabilitation, and harm reduction) and 4) capacity-building in
supply reduction (law enforcement and alternative development). For 20102014, the EU had originally earmarked €6 million for the project. In March
2013, that budget increased by a little over half a million euros (Council of
the European Union 2013; COPOLAD 2015).
In 2009, a program was also launched with the aim of fighting the
criminal networks along the cocaine route, which includes 36 countries of
Latin America, the Caribbean and East Africa, with a budget of €50 million, making it one of the EU’s priority programs. Four of the seven components of the Cocaine Route Program are open for CELAC countries:2
the Program on the Prevention of the Diversion of Drug Precursors in the
Latin American and Caribbean Region (PRELAC); the Airport Communication Programme (AIRCOP) to intercept cocaine shipments; cooperation
with the American Police Community (AMERIPOL)3 to strengthen cooperation of law enforcement and judicial and prosecuting authorities; and
cooperation with the Financial Action Task Force of South America
2
African countries participate in the other three programs: Anti-Money Laundering and
Financial Crime Initiatives in West Africa (AML), the Seaport Cooperation Project
(SEACOP), and the West African Police Information System (WAPIS).
3
Members: Colombia, Bolivia, Brazil, Ecuador, Peru, Panama, Martinique, Barbados,
and Trinidad and Tobago.
Chanona - 165
(GAFISUD), to deal with money laundering and financial crime (Council
of the European Union 2013;European Union 2015).
The most recent meeting of the Coordination and Cooperation
Mechanism on Drugs took place in 2012 in Brussels. In addition to reiterating its commitment to cooperation for reducing both demand and supply,
the EU and the LAC emphasized the importance of facing down the new
challenges linked to chemical precursors and the diversification of synthetic drugs.
Table 1. EU-LAC Cooperation Programs on Drugs (2004-2015)
Program
COPOLAD
42 months from
December 2010.
PRELAC I
March 2009February 2012
PRELAC II
February 2012February 2015
EU-LAC Intelligence Sharing
Working Group
2006-2009
EU-LAC Cities
in Partnership
Objectives
Bi-Regional
To strengthen capacities and encourage the
process of elaborating drugs policies in
LAC.
To strengthen trans-regional capacities to
prevent the diversion of chemical substances. Supporting international cross-border cooperation.
Budget (Euros)
6,574,786.74 (EU)
Total: 2.437.075
90% (EU)
10% (UNODC)
To strengthen the relationship between private sector and control authorities. Complement other EU initiatives.
Total: 3.061.300
98 % (EU)
2% (UNODC)
To increase the exchange of operational intelligence.
514.504 (EU)
To improved policy decisions at the city
level on the quality and coverage of drug
treatment, rehabilitation and harm reduction.
1.400.000 (EU)
Multi-regional: LAC and West Africa
Law enforcement and intelligence cooperation to reduce the amount of cocaine destined for or transiting Africa (interdiction
capabilities)
800.000
2007-2010
COLACAO
2006-2010
Cocaine Route
Law enforcement to fight against international criminal networks.
50,000,000 (EU)
Chanona - 166
2009-today
36 countries
Source: Own elaboration based on Gratius, 2012; EEAS, 2014; EEAS
2014a; COPOLAD,2015; CICAD, Proyecto PRELAC, Council of the European Union, 2013 and European Union, 2015.
Despite these links, bi-regional cooperation to fight drugs has different limits, among them:
a) The impact and the perceptions of drug trafficking are so different in both
regions: while in an important number of Latin American countries drug
trafficking is a national security concern, for EU members the drug problem
is seen as linked to public health and public security.
b) There is no single voice or common strategy on drugs in Latin America and
the Caribbean (Gratius 2012). The region’s complexity makes it difficult
for all the countries to participate in cooperation programs, and the tendency is to emphasize sub-regional and bilateral activities. The challenge for
the Latin American and Caribbean countries continues to be how to reconcile the different strategies.
c) The perception of EU members on drug trafficking from LAC. Europe accounted for 24 percent of all cocaine users worldwide (UNODC 2013).
This explains why the EU has been prioritizing sub-regional and bilateral cooperation programs with Andean countries (Colombia, Peru, and
Bolivia as cocaine producers).
When we analyze the EU-LAC cooperation programs on drugs during
last decade, we note the preeminence of programs with the Andean and the Caribbean countries over the bi-regional ones. For example: 1) the special trade
preferences to Andean and Central American countries under the “GSP-Drugs
scheme;” 2) sub-regional programs with the Andean Community such as: Combating Illegal Drugs in the Andean Community (PRADICAN), funded with €3.25
million; and the Support for the Andean Community in the Area of Synthetic
Drugs Project (DROSICAN), with €2.55 million to fight synthetic drugs; 3) subregional programs with the Caribbean Community, such as: CARICOM Regional
Demand Reduction (€ 800.000), Support Capacity Building for LawEnforcement Agencies (€ 400.000) and Institutional support to the CARICOM
Implementation Agency for Crime and Security (IMPACS) in its role to inform
policy development (€ 800.000); and 4) alternative development projects and
programs to fight against drugs in Bolivia, with total funding of €119 million
from 1999 to 2013; Peru with €32 million from 2014 to 2017 and Colombia,
which has received around €165 million for peace laboratories and regional de-
Chanona - 167
velopment (CICAD 2007; Gratius 2012; EEAS 2014a; European Commission
2007; European Commission 2013).
Table 2.EU Bilateral Cooperation Programs on Drugs (1998-2015)
Program
Colombia
Peace Laboratory in Magdalena Medio I (2002) II (2003) and III (2006)
Regional Development for
Peace and Stability I and II
Peace Laboratory
Montes de María (2008)
New Peace Territories (2010)
Bolivia
PRAEDAC: Alternative Development in Bolivia
(1998-2006)
APEMIN II
(January 2004-July 2010)
Support for the Control of Coca Production in Bolivian Society
(started in 2008)
Sector Budget Support to the National Integral Development with Coca
(started in 2008)
Integral Study of the Coca Leaf
(2008-2010)
PISCO: Institutional Strengthening to Combat drug Trafficking
(Agreement 2011)
Alternative Development Programs
2014-2020
Peru
Anti-drug Program
(2014-2017)
Venezuela
DROGASTOP
2011-2013
Budget (Euros)
92,000,000
34,600,000
8,000,000
30,400,000
19,000,000
(77% of
total)
7,000,000
10,000,000
26,000,000
1,000,000
9,000,000
25,000,000
32,0000,000
Total:
6,300,000
3,300,000
from the EU
Source: Own elaboration based on Gratius, 2012, EEAS 2014a; EEAS,
2014b; European Commission, 2007a, European Commission, 2010; European Commission, 2011a; European Commission, 2013; European Commission, 2014 and Europe Aid.
Chanona - 168
Thus, although in its discourse, the EU identifies LAC as “strategic
partners” against drug trafficking and insists on the importance of strengthening bi-regional cooperation and promoting comprehensive policies against
illicit drugs, the reality is that the Europeans prefer sub-regional and bilateral
agreements and programs, centered in controlling cocaine and synthetic drug
production and trafficking. In a study for the European Parliament, Susanne
Gratius (2012) revealed that most of the EU projects in LAC are designed to
reduce drug supply. According to her data, 102 out of 13 projects focus on
reducing supply.
Conclusions
EU interest in anti-narcotics cooperation arises out of different factors. Outstanding among them is the damage caused by drug consumption in terms of
addiction and death, the increase of synthetic drug production in the EU, and
concerns about violence levels in Latin America and the Caribbean linked to
organized crime activities. For their part, the Latin American countries have
found in the Europeans a key partner for fostering a comprehensive vision in
the face of the organized crime challenge. Since the 1980s, the Latin Americans have emphasized shared responsibility among producing, transit, and
consuming countries, as well as the importance of multilateral cooperation to
deal with these challenges.
The evaluation of EU-LAC cooperation in the fight against drugs
shows that, despite good intentions, the tendency has been to emphasize the
fight against production and transportation of drugs from Latin America to
the EU. What distinguishes this strategy is the use of instruments of greater
scope, including issues linked to institutional strengthening, the rule of law,
police institutions, the development of intelligence capabilities, and actions
against money laundering, and boosting international cooperation.
In the first years of bi-regional cooperation on drug issues, the differences between the EU discourse on a balanced focus and that of the United
States, which put greater emphasis on prohibition, were noteworthy. However, the United States has recognized shared responsibility and fosters programs that include the institutional strengthening of Latin American countries to face down this challenge. The EU, meanwhile, has broadened out its
programs focusing on preventing drugs from arriving to its shores.
The EU and the United States share concerns about chemical precursors, the production of new synthetic drugs, and the importance of slowing
the flow of drugs to their countries. At the same time, it is fundamental that
Latin America and the Caribbean continue to emphasize with their partners
Chanona - 169
the need to develop cooperation directed at the structural roots of drug trafficking and the violence it engenders. In the current context, given the limits
of the prohibitionist paradigm for fighting drug trafficking, alternatives are
being debated and the comprehensive, balanced approach to LAC-EU cooperation may be a reference point. The challenge is making sure the comprehensive approach translates into specific public policies. For the time being,
we must not lose sight of the fact that in many Latin American countries, the
priority is immediate answers in the face of the insecurity crisis and violence.
This leads to strengthening policies centered on the use of force. For this reason, in the short term, the European vision of reducing damages will continue to be used in a “complementary” way, through notions like citizens’ security or prevention and rehabilitation policies. For its part, given the concern
about increased use of synthetic drugs and psychoactive substances, and in a
context of limited resources, the EU is going to focus more attention on its
close neighbors in Eastern Europe and will continue to bet on broader projects like the Cocaine Route Programme aimed at preventing drugs from
crossing its borders.
References
CICAD. Proyecto PRELAC, accessed at:
http://www.cicad.oas.org/apps/Document.aspx?Id=1530.
CIDAD.2007. Draft Speech for Demand Reduction Training Workshop and
Meeting of Caribbean National Observatories on Drugs 10 to 14 September 2007 “EU support and Strategy for the Caribbean,” Washington:
CICAD.
Chanona, Alejandro. 2011. “Regional security governance in the Americas: the
Organization of American States,” in: Kirchner and Dominguez (eds.).
The Security Governance of Regional Organizations. UK: Routledge.
Council of the European Union. 2012. Brussels Declaration. Adopted on 5 June
2012 by the fourteenth High Level Meeting of the Coordination and Cooperation Mechanism on Drugs between the European Union and the
Community of Latin America and Caribbean States (CELAC). Brussels,
12 June 2012. 10719/12.
Council of the European Union. 2013. EU-CELAC Coordination and Cooperation Mechanism on Drugs – Annual Report June 2012 - May 2013. Brussels, 21 June 2013.
Chanona - 170
COPOLAD. 2015. COPOLAD Official website, accessed at:
https://www.copolad.eu.
Europe Aid. Fighting Drugs. PRAEDAC: Alternative Development in Bolivia,
acceded at: http://ec.europa.eu/europeaid/documents/casetudies/bolivia_praedac_en.pdf.
EU-CELAC. 2013. Quito Declaration. EU-CELAC Co-Operation and CoOrdination Mechanism on Drugs, Ministerial Meeting, 13 June 2013.
European Commission. 2007. Andean Community. Regional Strategy Paper
2007-2013. Brussels. 12 April 2007, accessed at:
http://eeas.europa.edu/colombia/csp/07_13_en.pdf.
European Commission. 2007a. Colombia Country Strategy Paper 2007-2013.
Brussels. 28 March 2007, accessed at:
http://eeas.europa.edu/colombia/csp/07_13_en.pdf.
European Commission. 2010. Memorandum to the DCI Committee Concerning
the Annual Action Programme Covered by the Programming Document
Country Strategy Paper 2007 – 2013 for the Development Cooperation
Instrument in favor of Colombia for 2010. Brussels.
European Commission. 2011. Towards a Stronger European Response to Drugs.
Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and
the Council COM (2011) 689/2.
European Commission. 2011a. EU - Colombia: main areas of development cooperation. Press Release, Brussels, 19 August 2013.
European Commission. 2013. New EU funding to help the fight against drugs in
Bolivia. Press Release, Brussels, 28 October 2011.
European Commission. 2014. EU Commissioner announces significant new funding for Peru during visit. Press Release, Brussels, 21 July 2014.
European Council. 2013. EU Action Plan on Drugs 2013-2016. Official Journal
of the European Union. 20 November 2013.
European External Action Service (EEAS), The Contribution of the EU to the
Implementation of the Panama Action Plan on Drugs, accessed at:
http://eeas.europa.eu/drugs/cocaine_en.htm.
Chanona - 171
EEAS. 2014a. Latin America and the Caribbean Co-operation Projects, accessed
at: http://www.eeas.europa.eu/la/drugs/projects_lac_en.pdf.
EEAS. 2014b. EU Commissioner announces significant new funding for Peru
during visit, 21June 2014, accessed at:
http://eeas.europa.eu/delegations/peru/press_corner/all_news/news/2014/
2014_07_21_en.htm.
European Monitoring Centre for Drugs and Drug Addiction (EMCDDA). 2013.
European Drug Report, Trends and Development, Luxemburg: EMCDDA.
EMCDDA. 2014. European Drug Report, Trends and Development, Luxemburg:
EMCDDA.
European Union. 2012. EU Drug Strategy (2013-20), Official Journal of the European Union. 29 December 2012.
European Union. 2015. Cocaine Route Programme, official website accessed at:
http://www.cocaineroute.eu.
Gratius, Susanne. 2012. Europe and Latin America: Combating Drugs and Drug
Trafficking. Brussels: European Parliament.
RESDAL. 2014. Atlas Comparativo de la Seguridad y la Defensa en América
Latina. Edición 2014. Buenos Aires: RESDAL.
UNODC. 2011. The Transatlantic Cocaine Market. Research Paper. Vienna:
UNODC.
UNODC. 2013. Global Study on Homicide. Trends, Context, Data. Vienna:
UNODC.
UNODC. 2014. World Drug Report 2014. New York: UNODC.
III.
Inside Latin America
Latin American Answers to Mega-Regional Projects:
Options and Limits
Rita Giacalone
Universidad de Los Andes, Venezuela
Abstract
European negotiations with the US leading to a mega transatlantic project and
similar mega-trade deals in Asia-Pacific were answered with three Latin American projects – the MERCOSUR-Pacific Alliance convergence, supported by
Chile-Brazil; the ECO-ALBA-Petrocaribe Zone promoted by Venezuela; and
acceleration of MERCOSUR-enlargement with Venezuela, Bolivia, and Ecuador.
This article analyses the agreements’ geo-economic and geopolitical options and
limits.
Introduction
By 2000, the principle of reciprocity, upon which the General Agreement on
Trade and Tariffs (GATT) had been built after World War II, was no longer in
operation (Halperin 2004). Since the 1960s and 1970s, free trade zones and custom unions formed by developing nations, and generalized schemes of preferences adopted by developed nations had been exempted from no discriminating
against trade by the rest. During the nineties, bilateral and regional trade agreements increased in number and generated the phenomenon of the “spaghetti
bowl.” The start of the Doha Round (2001) opened the possibility of bringing
order and coherence to the multilateral system, but trade in agriculture derailed
negotiations, which have stagnated since 2005 (Giacalone 2007).
Multilateral negotiations have been surpassed by technological change that
diminishes distance, accelerates communications, and allows big business to relocate productive activities in the most competitive environments. Fragmented
production chains and intra-industry and intra- company trade have augmented
together with associated services (Kotschwar 2014).
Besides the stagnation of multilateral negotiations and the increase in regional and bilateral trade agreements, in 2008 the global crisis reduced the price
and volume of exports and reverted investment flux (ALADI 2012; CEPAL
2009), with negative consequences for all nations. Presently, the United States
(US) and the European Union (EU), which together represent 46 percent of global GDP and 25 percent of world trade (Kotschwar 2014), are negotiating a megatrade deal (the TransAtlantic Trade and Investment Partnership, TTIP) to revert
those consequences.
Giacalone - 176
Felbermayr et al. (2013) and Roy and Dominguez (2014) studied the impact of the TTIP on Latin America, while Gayá and Rozemberg (2014) analysed
its consequences upon the Southern Common Market (MERCOSUR). In this article, we look at the geo-economic and geopolitical options and limits of the Latin American projects that emerged in response to mega-trade negotiations: the
MERCOSUR-Pacific Alliance (PA) convergence, supported by Chile-Brazil; the
ECO-ALBA-Petrocaribe Zone promoted by Venezuela; and the enlargement of
MERCOSUR with Venezuela, Bolivia, and Ecuador, originally supported by
Brazil, and now by Argentina and Venezuela. All these projects represent efforts
to model the region’s global insertion according to the interests of their respective proponents.
The MERCOSUR Enlargement
This process effectively started with the approval of Venezuela’s entry to the
agreement (2006), which was not achieved until 2012. To this day, Venezuela is
still going through a period of adapting tariffs and norms for MERCOSUR. For
Venezuela, this was a geopolitical project to create a Regional Mega-State by
enlarging MERCOSUR with Venezuela, Bolivia, Ecuador, and Cuba (Dieterich
2007: 30, quoted in González 2007: 12). MERCOSUR’s enlargement was also a
Brazilian economic project that began with the 1994 proposal to integrate tariffs
and institutional structures of the Andean Community (CAN) (Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, and Venezuela) and MERCOSUR (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay) into a South American Trade Zone. By 2004, this goal was
not achieved, but Brazil established the South American Community of Nations –
later converted into the Southern Union of Nations -- and CAN members signed
trade agreements with MERCOSUR and became associate members.
Venezuela’s entry increased the population, natural resources, GDP, and
intra- MERCOSUR trade (Coelho et al. 2006). Ghazalian (2013) estimated the
effects upon trade of commodities of converting associates into full members,
and found that enlargement would increase exports from previous members to
associates but not in the opposite direction. This trend is confirmed by trade between Venezuela and MERCOSUR since 2006.
In spite of Venezuelan geopolitical interest in MERCOSUR, its impact has
been bigger in the economic field and Brazil, whose trade balance with Venezuela in 2008 amounted to 5.7 billion dollars, with a 4.6 billion surplus (Aragao
2009). The Venezuelan entry also meant the possibility of Argentina balancing
the power of Brazil in MERCOSUR, the agreement’s projection toward the Caribbean (González Urrutia 2007: 15, 9), and gains in energy security. But, the
contradictory political and ideological goals of Venezuela and the rest of the
members weakened the group (Gantz 2013: 216).
Since 2012, MERCOSUR enlargement has accelerated in response to new
regional and international contexts. At the MERCOSUR summit meeting in Bra-
Giacalone - 177
silia, the protocol for Bolivian admission was signed (Geffner 2014: 7). This is
hailed as a defensive measure against the EU and the US that strengthens the negotiating power of MERCOSUR (Parlamento del Sur2013), but is an overstatement because Bolivia continues individual negotiations with the EU (Los Tiempos 2013), and together with Ecuador it increases MERCOSUR’s GDP only by 2
percent (Guillén 2013). The move looks like a political decision to shift the internal balance of MERCOSUR by reducing Brazil and Argentina’s relative
weight, because it will mean less percentage of GDP, territory, and population
for them (Cimadamore and Rodriguez 2013: 124).
If originally Brazil promoted MERCOSUR enlargement due to economic
reasons, now Brazil prefers convergence with the PA while Argentina and Venezuela push for association with the Alternativa Bolivariana para Nuestra América
(ALBA)-Petrocaribe, and the Caribbean Community (CARICOM). During the
2014 MERCOSUR Summit, Brazil proposed to shorten the time for establishing
a common South American market which will be reached in 2019 due to the
trade agreements between MERCOSUR and associates. Brazil wants to accelerate the process with PA members to counter the effects of the global crisis. Argentina and Venezuela prefer instead negotiations with ALBA-Petrocaribe
(Scharfenberg 2014; BID-INTAL 2015: 89-96) and an agreement with the Eurasian Union (Primicias24 2014), while Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay want one
with the EU (Yakovleva 2014). Internal disagreements continue to limit the geopolitical weight of an enlarged MERCOSUR.
MERCOSUR-PA Convergence
By mid- 2013, ECLAC data rendered a 5 percent combined growth index for the
PA (established in 2012) against 2.9 percent for MERCOSUR, and while intraregional trade in MERCOSUR fell 9.4 percent during 2012, in the PA it grew 1.3
percent (Oppenheimer 2013), though volume and value of MERCOSUR trade
are bigger (Geffner 2014). A meeting between the foreign ministers of MERCOSUR and the PA (Cartagena 2014) ended with a declaration that echoed a
previous document by former Chilean President Ricardo Lagos and former Brazilian President Lula (Da Silva and Lagos 2014; MERCOSUR ABC 2014). Both
recommended a Latin American regional project with a pragmatic and economic
orientation, based on the links established between MERCOSUR and PA by
companies and economic groups.
Since 2009, ECLAC has recommended the convergence of trade agreements in Latin America. In 2014, it was considered urgent due to the global trend
to establish mega-trade agreements (Rosales 2014: 8). MERCOSUR-PA convergence is expected to precipitate convergence among other agreements, increase
the negotiating power of the region, strengthen productive activities and trade,
and counter the fall of exports in extra-regional markets (Rosales 2014: 28-30).
Giacalone - 178
The Brazilian-Chilean proposal can be linked to the fact that they followed
similar development models under their military regimes – Brazil inspired by
German neoliberalism with state intervention, and Chile by the Chicago School
that favoured retraction of the state from the economy (Ramírez 2012: 77). Both
changed from heterodox to orthodox policies when confronted with high inflation, fiscal and external imbalances, and failure of import substituting industrialization (Fosu 2013). As a result, Brazil occupies an intermediate position between
governments with neoliberal and statist development models (Lima 2013).
Brazil, the largest South American economy in GDP and trade, the most
industrialized and with the biggest business companies, prefers exclusive regional trade arrangements to sell goods and services among its asymmetrical regional
partners. Chile, a medium economy with a smaller domestic market that limits
scale economies and high technology industrialization, prefers open trade
schemes. While Brazil became the axis of a MERCOSUR custom union, Chile
signed a variety of North-South and South-South Free Trade Agreements
(FTAs).
Under the government of Dilma Rousseff, Brazilian industry reduced its
exports and lost part of the domestic market to Chinese imported goods. This is
attributed to the overvaluation of the Brazilian currency and lack of industrial
competitiveness. To protect its industry Brazil has distanced itself from the
World Trade Organization – which in 1995 substituted GATT --, has not signed
North-South FTA, and is isolated from global productive chains (Veiga et al.
2013: 37-38). EU-US negotiations and similar processes in the Pacific would
mean reduction of MERCOSUR agribusiness exports, loss of FDI, trade diversion for MERCOSUR goods in Latin American Pacific nations participating in
those negotiations, and less exports to China and India (Gayá and Rozemberg
2014). These facts are leading Brazil to look for alternatives.
The geo-economic options of MERCOSUR-PA derive from their weight –
MERCOSUR with a population of 282 million, a GDP of 3.300 billion dollars
and a total trade of 824.658 million, and the PA with a 3.000 billion GDP and 50
percent of total Latin American trade. Together they represent 85 percent of Latin American population, 91 percent of its GDP, and more than 80 percent of its
trade (MERCOSUR ABC 2014). Their members cover an area from the Mexican
Gulf to the Southern Atlantic and Pacific Oceans that facilitates relations with the
US, the EU, and China.
In 2013 exports of goods from the PA to MERCOSUR were similar in
value to exports from MERCOSUR to the PA, and included more value-added
goods (Rosales 2014: 44, 56). Mexico, Colombia, Chile, Brazil, and Argentina
were the nations with more potential for intra-industry trade and for inserting
themselves in intraregional production chains (Rosales 2014: 53). Summarising,
MERCOSUR sells to the PA goods with more value added and the PA does the
same to MERCOSUR, creating the basis for intra-industry trade and productive
chains between them (Carta Mensual 2013). Additionally, the economic success
Giacalone - 179
of the PA may generate a larger market for MERCOSUR goods, or displace them
by similar ones due to the external agreements signed by PA members (Peyrani
and Geffner 2014: 24), and FDI from MERCOSUR to the PA and contrariwise,
in 2013 reached 1,220 million dollars and 4,077 million, with Chile representing
more than 50 percent of PA’s FDI to MERCOSUR (Rosales 2014: 71-72).
MERCOSUR-PA convergence has limits in terms of intraregional trade,
productive integration, and private sector confidence in economic institutions.
Obstacles to intraregional trade are the diversity of bilateral trade preferences and
norms of origin, and the lack of infrastructure in transport and communication
(Ulloa and Marambio 2014). Though intraregional trade in manufactures is growing, it is of final goods. This shows little intraregional productive integration because productive integration increases trade in intermediate goods and associated
services among interconnected enterprises (CEPAL 2014: 69). In extra-regional
chains, Latin America has low participation in segments of global production of
manufactured goods (Blyde 2014). Also it occupies a low position in global index of respect for private property rights that varies from Venezuela, with the
lowest scoring in the region (Rosales 2014: 38), to the opposite situation in Chile
and Peru. MERCOSUR-PA convergence will not mean convergence of countries images, so FDI will probably follow existing patterns of location.
MERCOSUR-PA represents all South America and it looks similar to the
MERCOSUR-CAN proposal, but the PA is stronger than CAN and Mexico and
creates a second economic axis besides Brazil. The geopolitical weight of the
group depends on the congruence of Brazilian and Mexican objectives, so if they
can assume concerted positions, the geopolitical consequences could be far
reaching.
If the amount of population provides room for scale economies and growth
in domestic consumption, its geopolitical impact varies with the number of nations included, which may increase because the PA has its own enlargement program as shown by ongoing negotiations with Central American nations. Members represent votes in regional and multilateral organizations, an important consideration for Brazil which wants a permanent seat in the United Nations Security
Council.
ECO-ALBA-Petrocaribe
Venezuela considered ALBA the hard core of regional integration based on ideological and political affinity of members (Alcalá 2011, in Giacalone 2013: 149150), but now is making effective its entry to MERCOSUR and pushing for the
incorporation of Bolivia and Ecuador (El Informador 2013). This is considered a
pragmatic movement given the impact of the global crisis on oil prices, but it can
be an ideological alternative to the PA too.
Giacalone - 180
In March 2013, Bolivia, Cuba, Ecuador, Nicaragua, and Venezuela1 signed
an Economic Complementary Agreement (ACE 70) of ALADI (SELA 2013: 17).
SELA (2013) links this decision with the Venezuelan need to convert its trade
agreements into ACEs because after its adaptation period Venezuela will have to
negotiate them through MERCOSUR. Venezuela declared its intention of linking
ACE 70 to Petrocaribe, CARICOM and MERCOSUR (ALBA-TCP/Petrocaribe
2013). The ALBA’s Summit Meeting (2014) stated the objective of designing
strategies and actions to make viable an Economic Complementary Zone made
up by ALBA/Petrocaribe/CARICOM/MERCOSUR (Periodico 26 2014), and
MERCOSUR established a mechanism to promote the ECO-Zone (SELA 2014:
25). The Venezuelan proposal coincides with a Brazilian economic expansion
project in the Caribbean (SELA 2015). Both clash with Mexico’s economic and
geopolitical intentions of deepening its trade agreements in the region.
ECO-ALBA is expected to combine natural resources in energy and land
for agriculture. However, economic complementarity between ALBA and the
rest is low, and should be established first within ALBA, which is a political and
only secondarily economic cooperation organization (SELA 2013: 24; Giacalone
2013). Also Petrocaribe is an oil cooperation agreement with geopolitical objectives, whose trade component derives from the need of oil-importing nations to
repay debts with Venezuela through barter-type agreements.
The geo-economic limits of the ECO-ALBA-Petrocaribe Zone are several.
First, is the situation of Venezuela, affected by a severe economic downturn (Geffner 2014). The fall of international oil prices has cut down Venezuelan financial resources for cooperation and foreign investment and reduced the cost for
client nations of importing oil from other sources. The zone allows Venezuela to
import goods and services without employing dollars, and Nicaragua and Bolivia
to replace political will for certainty in their exports to Venezuela. Secondly,
member nations belong to different regional agreements namely Nicaragua is
member of ALBA, the Central American Economic Integration System (SIECA),
and two North-South FTAs (CAFTA-DR and CARIFORUM-UE). Englishspeaking nations of Petrocaribe belong to CARICOM and CARIFORUM-UE.
Petrocaribe has 19 members; ALBA, 8; CARICOM, 14; and an enlarged
MERCOSUR, 7. As some are simultaneously members of ALBA and Petrocaribe, Petrocaribe and CARICOM, and ALBA and MERCOSUR, the final total is
25 nations, a significant voting bloc in regional and multilateral institutions,
though it implies long and complex negotiations to establish an agreement. The
fact that Venezuela considers ALBA a geopolitical instrument to displace US
hegemony in the region limited its attraction for Central American and Caribbean
governments -- only five became ALBA members (Altmann 2009) --, and this
may also limit the attraction of members and FDI to ECO-ALBA.
1
ALBA members Antigua-Barbuda, St. Vincent, and St. Kitts-Nevis did not sign because
they are not members of ALADI.
Giacalone - 181
Options and Limits
Options and Limits of Latin American Regional Projects
GEO-ECONOMIC
OPTIONS
GEO-ECONOMIC
LIMITS
GEOPOLITICAL
OPTIONS
GEOPOLITICAL
LIMITS
ENLARGED
MERCOSUR
To develop regional productive
chains and attract
FDI
Little effect of Bolivia and Ecuador’s
entry on MERCOSUR’s GDP
More gains by core
economies than by
new members may
exacerbate asymmetry
Fewer actors may
accelerate its establishment
Internal disagreements weaken external projection
MERCOSUR-PA
To develop regional and global productive chains and
attract FDI
Clashes between
divergent economic models may
weaken compliance
Increased importance if Brazil
and Mexico agree
in common positions
Opposition by
ALBA members of
MERCOSUR
ECO-ALBAPETROCARIBE
To combine natural
resources (energy,
land, etc.)
Internal diversity in
participation in trade
agreements
Little economic
complementarity
Ideological and political orientation of
Venezuela
A large number of
members means
more voting power
in regional and multilateral organizations
Venezuelan economic problems
may compromise
viability and external projection
Summarising, ECO-ALBA-Petrocaribe is the most ambitious and most difficult
project to negotiate. MERCOSUR-PA convergence has economic importance
and may have geopolitical clout if it puts Brazil and Mexico side by side at negotiations. An enlarged MERCOSUR may be concluded faster but has less geopolitical and economic importance, due to internal disagreements and the ideological-political orientation of ALBA members. These are potential developments
because so far we find: ALBA converted into ACE 70, and promoting a complementarity economic zone with Petrocaribe/CARICOM/MERCOSUR; a project
of MERCOSUR-PA convergence, which has produced two joint meetings; and
MERCOSUR enlargement with Venezuela and Bolivia.
Finally, the most important factor in determining options and limits is Brazil because MERCOSUR’s choice will depend on the decision of its largest
Giacalone - 182
economy. Brazilian promotion of South-South negotiations since the 2000s created marginal new trade in Africa and with BRICS/IBSA (Oliveira and Onuki
2013: 3). However, if South-South trade grew from 8 percent of total trade in
1990 to 28 percent in 2012, this was due to Asian-Pacific rather than Brazilian
exports (Rosales 2014: 19-21). Thus, Brazilian external coalitions may be instruments of soft-balancing against developed nations and multilateral institutions, but add little in economic terms (Oliveira and Onuki 2013: 10).
Presently, Brazil has to choose between either making its industry more
competitive (Oliveira and Onuki 2013) or to enlarging its political power in the
international scene (Veiga et al. 2013). The former needs Brazilian participation
in global production chains and the latter rests on a South-South orientation. Brazil may move either way but also sign as many regional agreements as possible,
like Brazilian business have suggested (Giacaglia 2013: 109). Brazil may simultaneously negotiate convergence with PA, complementarity with ALBAPetrocaribe/CARICOM, and proceed with MERCOSUR enlargement. These
moves are possible because all projects strive to include MERCOSUR and Brazil
could not opt for the status quo because of the potential negative effects of the
mega-trade deals (Gayá and Rozemberg 2014).
In conclusion, all these Latin American projects have geo-economic potentialities. Geopolitically, their potentialities are fewer – they represent more votes
but internal disagreements prevent an external united front. However, the decision to negotiate them is positive because it recognises the need for concerted
actions and may help turn ideological extreme positions into more pragmatic regional interests.
References
ALADI. 2012. Los efectos de la crisis económica internacional en el comercio
exterior de la ALADI. Montevideo: ALADI/SEC/di2218.4, accessed at:
http://aladi.org/boletin/documentos/2218_4.pdf.
ALBA-TCP – Petrocaribe. 2013. “Declaración de los Jefes de Estado y de Gobierno de los países miembros.” II Cumbre Extraordinaria ALBA-TCP
/PETROCARIBE, Caracas, Venezuela – December 17, accessed at:
http://alba-tcp.org/contenido/declaracion-de-los-jefes-de-estado-y-degobierno-de-los-paises-miembros-de-alba-ypetrocar.
Alcalá, Y. 2011. “Hugo Chávez: UNASUR garantiza permanencia de nueva independencia Suramericana.” Correo del Orinoco, accessed at:
http://correodelorinoco.gob.ve.
Altmann, Josette. 2009. “El ALBA, Petrocaribe y Centroamérica: ¿intereses comunes?” Nueva Sociedad 219: 127-144.
Giacalone - 183
Aragao, Thiago de. 2009. “The significance of Venezuela´s admission to Mercosur” affaires- strategiques.info November 10, accessed at:
http://affaires-strategiques.info/spip.php?article2297.
BID-INTAL. 2015. Informe MERCOSUR19 (Segundo semestre 2013- Primer
semestre 2014) Buenos Aires: BID-INTAL.
Blyde, Juan. 2014. (Coord.) Fábricas sincronizadas. América Latina y el Caribe
en la era de las cadenas globales de valor. Washington, D.C.: IADB.
Carta Mensual. 2013. “El MERCOSUR y la Alianza del Pacífico.” No. 206 (October). Buenos Aires: BID-INTAL.
CEPAL. 2009. Panorama de la inserción internacional de América Latina. Crisis y espacios de cooperación regional. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL, accessed at: http://cepal.org/es/publicaciones/panorama-de-la-insercioninternacional-de-america-latina-y-el-caribe-2008-2009-crisis.
CEPAL. 2014. Integración regional. Hacia una estrategia de cadenas de valor
inclusivas. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
Cimadamore, Alberto, Rodriguez, Adriana. 2013. “La adhesión de Venezuela y
la gestión institucional de las asimetrías en el MERCOSUR,” Comentario Internacional 13: 115-154.
Coelho, Allesandro, Lima, María Lucía P., Cury, Samir; Goldbaum, Sergio.
2006. “Impacts of Venezuela´s Accession to Mercosur: An Applied General Equilibrium Evaluation,” accessed at: http://academia.edu/3417399
/Impacts_of_Venezuelas_accession_to_the_Mercosur_an_applied_gener
al_equilibrium_evaluation.
Da Silva, Lula, Lagos, Ricardo. 2014. “América Latina: Dos océanos, una voz.”
El País, June 10, accessed at: http://puntolatino.ch/es/alianza-delpacifico/7201-2014-prensa-america-latina-dos-oceanos-una-voz-lula-dasilva-ricardo-lagos.
Dieterich, Heinz. 2007. Interview to Heinz Dieterich by Fernando Arellano Ortiz,
accessed at: http://rebelion.org.
El Informador. 2013. “Venezuela propone ampliar la alianza ALBAMERCOSUR.” March 25, accessed at:
Giacalone - 184
http://informador.com.mx/economia/2013/ 446618/6/venezuela-proponeampliar-alianza-alba-mercosur.htm.
“Eventual convergencia entre Alianza del Pacífico y MERCOSUR.” 2014. Boletín sobre Integración de América Latina y el Caribe (SELA) 202 (September): 2-3.
Felbermayr, Gabriel; Heid, Benedikt; Lehwald, Sybille. 2013. Transatlantic
Trade and Investment Pertnership (TTIP). Who benefits from a Free
Trade Deal? Gutersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung, accessed at: http://iadb
.org/intal/intalcdi/PE/2014/13541.pdf.
Fosu, Augustin. 2013. “Achieving Development Success. Lessons from the Developing World.” Helsinki: UNU-WIDER.
Gantz, David A. 2013. Liberalizing International Trade After Doha: Multilateral, Plurilateral, Regional, and Unilateral Initiatives. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Gayá, Romina, Rozemberg, Ricardo. 2014. “Los Mega Acuerdos: nuevas reglas,
nuevos actores. Impactos sobre el MERCOSUR”. Buenos Aires: Cámara
de Exportadores de la República Argentina, August 13, accessed at:
http://cera.org.ar/new-site/descargarArchivo.php?idioma_code=es.
Geffner, Maximiliano. 2014. “Dos modelos en debate: Mercosur ampliado y la
Alianza del Pacífico.” Buenos Aires: ISA-FLACSO, July, accessed at:
http://isanet.org/Web/Conferences/FLACSOISA%20BuenosAires%202014/Archive/95b339f7-8cfd-4a99-a8414c66cfae3f0d.pdf
Ghazalian, Pascal. 2013. “Mercosur enlargement: Predicting the effects on trade
in primary agricultural commodities” Economic Change and Restructuring 46 (3): 277-297.
Giacalone, Rita. 2007. “Participación de los países en desarrollo en las negociaciones agrícolas de la Ronda de Doha” Revista BCV XXI (1): 77-107.
Giacalone, Rita. 2013. “Venezuela en UNASUR: Integración regional y discurso
político,” Desafíos 25 (1): 129-163.
Giaccaglia, Clarisa. 2010. “La influencia de los actores domésticos en la política
exterior brasileña durante el gobierno de Lula da Silva,” Confines 6 (12):
95-121.
Giacalone - 185
González Urrutia, Edmundo. 2007. La incorporación de Venezuela al MERCOSUR: Implicaciones políticas en el plano internacional. Caracas: ILDIS,
accessed at: http://library.fes.de/pdf-files/bueros/caracas/o5550.pdf.
Guillén, Stella. 2013. “Paraguay frente al MERCOSUR y a la Alianza del Pacífico,” Observatorio de Economía Internacional, March, accessed at:
http://www.cadep.org.py/uploads/2013/03/Articulo-SG-impresion.pdf.
Halperin, Marcelo. 2004. Los principios jurídicos del multilateralismo económico. Buenos Aires: El Autor.
Kotschwar, Barbara. 2014. “Los mega-acuerdos: nuevos actores y nuevas reglas,” Boletín Informativo Techint 345: 8-21. Los Tiempos. 2013. “Bolivia anuncia ingreso al MERCOSUR sin dejar CAN.” (La Paz), June 21,
accessed at: http://lostiempos.com/diario/actualidad/economia/2013062
1/bolivia-anuncia-ingreso-al-mercosur-sin-dejar-can_217691_468773
.html.
Lima, Maria R. Soares de. 2013. “Relaḉoes Internacionais: A Nova Agenda SulAmericana e o Brasil” Lua Nova 90: 167-201.
MERCOSUR ABC. 2014. “Reunión informativa Mercosur-Alianza del Pacífi
co.”MercosurABC 479 November 27, accessed at: http://mercosurabc.
com.
“MERCOSUR se expande con Venezuela y Bolivia.” 2012. La Voz (Argentina)
December 7, accessed at: http://lavoz.com.ar/noticias/politica/mercosurse-expande-con-venezuela-bolivia08122012b.
Oliveira, Amancio de; Onuki, Janina. 2013. “Politica externa brasileira e Relaḉoes Sul-Sul.” Sao Paulo: CAECI-USP. Working Paper.
Oppenheimer, Andrés. 2013. “la Alianza del Pacífico saca ventaja al MERCOSUR,” La Nación, May 28, accessed at: http://lanacion.com.ar.
Parlamento del Sur. 2013. “Bolivia se encamina a ser miembro pleno del MERCOSUR,” accessed at: http://parlamentodelmercosur.org/innovaportal/
v/8269/1/parlasur/bolivia_se_encamina_a_ser_miembro_pleno_del_
mercosur.html.
Giacalone - 186
“Países de la ALBA crean zona económica común y un banco de desarrollo.”
2012. Caracas: IX Reunión de ALBA, February 5, accessed at: http://
bolpress.com.
Peyrani, Julio; Geffner, Maximiliano. 2013. “Dos modelos en debate: Mercosur
ampliado y la Alianza del Pacífico.” Análisis Nº 1 (agosto). Buenos
Aires: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung (FES) –CEPES, accessed at: http://fes.org
.ar/Publicaciones/2013/CEPES_08-2013.pdf.
Primicias24. 2014. “Rafael Ramírez: Esperamos el ingreso pleno de Bolivia al
MERCOSUR para 2015.”Primicias24.com, December 17, accessed at:
http://primicias24.com/nacionales/rafael-ramirez-esperamos-el-ingresopleno-de-bolivia-al-mercosur-para-2015.
Ramirez, Hernán. 2012. “Confluệncias e matizes nos programas econộmicos das
ditaduras brasileira y chilena,” Confluenze 4 (2).
Rosales, Osvaldo. 2014. La Alianza del Pacífico y el MERCOSUR: hacia la convergencia en la diversidad. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL, accessed at:
http://repositorio.cepal.org/handle/11362/37304
Scharfenberg, Ewald. 2014. “La agenda política opaca el carácter comercial de
MERCOSUR en Caracas,” El País, July 29, accessed at:
http://internacional.elpais.com/internacional/2014/07/29/actualidad .
SELA. 2013. ALBA-TCP como mecanismo de cooperación de alcance regional.
Caracas: SELA. SP/Di Nº 4-13.
SELA. 2014. Evolución de la Alianza Bolivariana para los Pueblos de Nuestra
América- Tratado de los Pueblos (ALBA-TCP). Caracas: SELA. SP/Di
Nº 4-14.
SELA. 2015. “El acercamiento entre EEUU y Cuba y sus implicaciones para
América Latina.” Servicio Informativo. January 15, accessed at: http://
sela.org/view/index.asp?ms=258&pageMs=26402&item_id=127191.
Periódico26. 2014. “Thirteen ALBA-TCP Meeting Approves Final Declaration.” December 14, accessed at: http://periodico26.cu/index.php/en/prin
cipal-es-2/25057-thirteenth-alba-tcp-summit-approves-final-declaration.
Ulloa Urrutia, Alfie, Marambio, Sebastian. 2014. “Latinoamérica y el Caribe,
desafíos comerciales
de la región y una agenda para la integración.”
In Foxley, Alejandro and Stallings, Barbara (Eds.) Economías latinoa-
Giacalone - 187
mericanas. Cómo avanzar más allá del ingreso medio. Santiago de Chile: CIEPLAN, accessed at:
http://cieplan.org/media/publicaciones/archivos/352/Economias_Latinoa
mericanas_Como_Avanzar_mas_alla_del_ Ingreso_Medio.pdf.
Veiga, Pedro da Motta, Rios, Sandra, Naidin, Leane. 2013. “Políticas comercial e
industrial e hiperativismo do primeiro bienio Dilma.” Rio de Janeiro:
CINDES. Texto 35.
Yakovleva, Nailya. 2014. “Latin American integration in the mirror of MERCOSUR” Russian Council. Latin America and the Caribbean//Analysis,
September 2, accessed at: http://russiancouncil.ru/en/inner/?id=4277.
Regional Integration in Latin America: The Strategy of
“Convergence in Diversity” and the Relations between
MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance
Félix Peña
Universidad Nacional de Tres de Febrero (UNTREF)
Abstract
Convergence and confrontation are two different strategic options that have been
evoked with respect to the relation between MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance. Choosing one or the other transcends the level of the economic and the
commercial, and deeply affects the political. Their impact is closely related with
regional governance and the achievement of a climate of harmony functional to
democracy and to the economic and social development of member countries.
The idea of convergence in diversity has been proposed as central to the development of a strategy to joint work among the member countries of both integration processes. The different agreements and measures eventually adopted by
member countries of both schemes could contribute to the goal of achieving a
reasonable degree of regional governance. Showing that this is possible might be
a worthy goal to nourish the agenda of cooperation between all Latin American
countries. Its effects would then transcend the regional scope.
From the Founding Moments to a Sustainable Integration Process
Reconciling different and even conflicting interests and views among nations of
the same geographic region has never been an easy task. However, it is a necessary condition to develop sustainable strategies and policies for regional economic integration, including joint trade negotiations with third nations, particularly if
they are embodied in agreements and institutions intended to be permanent.
In a way, the foundation is the easy stage of an integration process among nations of the same region. For example, in the case of MERCOSUR –and this
could eventually be the case of the Pacific Alliance– the hardest part was not
necessarily signing the founding agreement in 1991. The initial moment requires,
of course, strategic vision and political skill; but, it also requires luck. Many initiatives succumb or loose vitality in this first stage which, however, can last several years.
Calling the attention at the international level is a common occurrence in the
founding moments of the integration processes between nations and, as a result, it
generates great expectations. For example, it happened in 1969 with the signing
of the Agreement of Cartagena, which was the result of a very strong involve-
Peña - 190
ment of the then presidents of Chile and Colombia. In its initial stage and for
some years, the so-called Andean Group managed to concentrate much international attention, especially when it adopted, in December 1970, its foreign investment regime known as Decision N° 24.
The high expectations that are normally generated by the launch of and international integration agreement between Latin American countries have usually
led to frustrations, sometimes very difficult to overcome. Something like this
happened over fifty years ago with the launch of the Latin American Free Trade
Association (LAFTA), then replaced in 1980 by the Latin American Integration
Association (LAIA). Different regional integration experiences –and not only in
Latin America– have taught us the difficulty of sustaining in the long run the reciprocity of interests that support the associative pact. Sooner or later what could
be called the ‘curve of disenchantment’ starts to show, often caused by the fact
that not all participating countries continue to view the corresponding agreement
as a generator of mutual gains. At this point is where the loss of effectiveness,
efficiency, and legitimacy of the rules originating in the founding agreement begins, often through a trickle effect (Peña 2014a).
Particularly, changes in the realities at the regional level –sometimes as a result of changes at the global level or even at the national level of member countries– present a test for the effectiveness of the mechanisms implemented for the
conciliation of national interests among the members of an integration process.
This may also have an impact on the effectiveness of the common rules that have
been agreed. An example of this can be portrayed in the evolution of the Andean
Group and its main joint body – the Board of the Cartagena Agreement– which
lost efficacy and even legitimacy after a founding period with a favorable external context and affinity of values and interests between the member countries.
Then, the decline began with the withdrawal of Chile and after the transformation
into the Andean Community of Nations (CAN); eventually, the original enthusiasm was gradually eroded.
The situation may be more complicated when a founding moment characterized by the affinity of values and interests –a situation of like-minded countries–
is later followed by periods of significant differences between the partners, even
if temporary. It also becomes more difficult when no effective mechanism for the
conciliation of interests is established to help achieve a dynamic balance between
the different national interests, when these do not necessarily converge. In this
regard, the role of the ‘independent facilitator’ in the decision-making process is
critical and provides a guarantee for those participating countries with a smaller
endowment of relative power. The relatively short history of MERCOSUR
shows, at different moments, interesting examples of this. It is even possible to
formulate the hypothesis that the absence or weakness of effective mechanisms
to facilitate the coordination of national interests has been one of the reasons that
would explain the recurring difficulties that MERCOSUR had, and still has, to
adapt to the effects of the internal and contextual changes dynamic that have
Peña - 191
characterized the relations between its member countries –Argentina and Brazil
in particular– since the integration process was launched.
Factors that Could Contribute to a Sustainable Integration Process
Which are then some of the factors that could help sustain over time the political
will of a group of sovereign nations to work together, within the scope of an integration process intended to be permanent? Without the concurrence of these factors it seems difficult for a voluntary process of integration –in the sense of systematic joint work between sovereign nations– to be sustainable in the long run.
From the different Latin American experiences it seems that three factors
should be considered carefully.
The first one is the ability to adapt the original integration project to the frequent changes in the political and economic conditions of the member countries,
including also the external environment, both regional and global.
The second aspect is the density and quality of the economic and, above all,
production networks that are developed as a result of the commitments made in
the framework of the integration process.
And a third factor, strongly linked to the previous one, is the quality of the
ground rules as measured by their effectiveness (ability to penetrate reality), their
efficacy (ability to produce the results) and their social legitimacy (the ability to
take into account, through the process of rule-making, the social interests of all
member countries, reflecting thus a dynamic picture of perception of mutual
gains).
There are at least three relevant aspects that could be of importance to facilitate the practice of the difficult art of achieving sustainable equilibrium points in
any institutional agreement among nations of a same geographic region. Especially if they aspire to develop a permanent multidimensional cooperation process with strong emphasis on trade and productive integration, such as is the case
of MERCOSUR and now of the Pacific Alliance.
The first aspect is the articulation of the strategies for development and international integration of a country with the requirements of the corresponding regional or multilateral agreement. Among many others, an example in this regard
are the trade policies needed to be applied in view of the combination of offensive and defensive interests of the firms and social sectors of a country along
with the legal commitments relating, in particular, to the access to the respective
domestic market and trade protection. In times of global economic crisis with a
relative decline of international trade flows, the natural tendency of every country
could be to protect the jobs of its population. Often, this is done covertly and
with such legal subtlety that it becomes difficult for those eventually affected by
the policy of one of the partners to prove that the agreed rules have been violated.
Other times, violations are done overtly and this affects the international credibil-
Peña - 192
ity of the country applying the measures contrary to the agreement, and could
eventually have a negative impact on the effectiveness of the integration process.
The second relevant aspect is the articulation between the different preferential agreements in which countries can participate, including the commitments
made at the global-multilateral level. In fact, it is increasingly common for a
country to participate simultaneously, or to aspire to do so, in different regional
and preferential trade agreements concluded, at least formally, within the multilateral framework of the WTO. This may eventually trigger the need to achieve
equilibrium points between the commitments made in the different agreements
and the respective national interests. Achieving such balance also depends on the
concessions and the rules agreed upon in each of the agreements. In particular, it
depends on the actual goals and the political and strategic scope of each concrete
regional preferential agreement.
Finally, the third aspect is the articulation between the requirements of the
short and the long term, both in the national strategies and in the international
commitments taken on by a country. What can be observed on this respect, at
least in recent years, is an effect of growing erosion of the distinction between
short and long term interests resulting, among other factors, from the close link
between trade and productive investment, which is reflected in the new forms of
organizing production at a multinational level. In fact, the fragmentation of production in different modalities of transnational value chains is generating a great
difficulty to distinguish between the short and long term effects when a country
applies restrictive trade policies. Depending on how they are applied, even when
theoretically, such measures would impact only short term trade flows. In addition, they may also have a strong effect on investment decisions in the corresponding country as a result of the appraisal that is made on the convenience of
operating from its market within the context of a transnational value chain. The
uncertainty regarding trade flows can then affect productive investment decisions
that, while aimed for the long-term, also have a bearing on the short-term. In the
automotive industry, for example, it can lead investors to prefer those countries
within a region that, together with market size and level of industrial development, provide assurance of the fluidity of cross-border trade flows.
The Relationship between MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance
An issue that is worth monitoring closely is the relationship that has developed between the two main Latin American preferential spaces: the Pacific Alliance and MERCOSUR (Foxley and Meller 2014). It is a matter
of economic interest, but also of strong geopolitical connotations. It should
be noted that the relations among several countries of the Pacific Alliance
with MERCOSUR countries, and particularly with Argentina and Brazil,
are very close at all levels and transcend trade.
Peña - 193
Hence, the importance of raising the question of whether these two regional
preferential spaces will complement each other or if, on the contrary, will challenge views still prevails. It is a question that could take time to find an answer
that is based on solid arguments and not only on ideological or emotional ones.
Among other reasons, time could be necessary in order to have a clearer picture
of which are the effective commitments that are eventually manifested in the
space of the Pacific Alliance and to appreciate the true scope of the present ‘metamorphosis’ of MERCOSUR. This is, the effects resulting especially from
changes in its membership, the convenience of capitalizing on the experience
gained since its creation, and its recommendable adaptation to national, regional
and global realities different from those of the time of its creation (Boletín
Techint 2014).
Until now, the Pacific Alliance could be the equivalent to the process of
building a house. The willingness to do so exists and the plans are being approved. But, the actual construction will take time, which in turn may be impacted by the dynamics of change of the external environment. MERCOSUR is also
the equivalent of a house under construction –the current experience of the EU
shows that this is a constant reality of voluntary integration processes among
sovereign nations (Friedmann 2015; Van Middelaar 2013) – but, it already needs
to be expanded and adjusted to the new realities of its owners and the environment in which they live.
Both constructions are developed within the broader institutional frameworks
that exist in the region. All of them aim to ensure regional governance, in terms
of peace and political stability, and not just in the economic aspect. These are, in
particular, the frameworks of the LAIA and the UNASUR –and to some extent
also that of the CELAC–. Additionally, there are also regional institutions such as
the ECLAC and the CAF-Development Bank of Latin America that can play a
very useful role in facilitating the articulation between both integration processes
(Peña 2014b).
How to get both processes to complement each other, generating a convergence of development and trade policies and also achieving a growing number of
transnational production networks? This is perhaps the central question on which
to base the future articulation between MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance
from now on, while maximizing the installed capacity within the scope of the
regional institutions mentioned above.
The Strategic Idea of Convergence in Diversity
As stated earlier, one can reflect on the latest initiative that has been raised in
terms of Latin American regional integration (Peña 2014b). It comes at a time
when the multilateral trading system is still unable to offer interesting negotiating
perspectives, beyond the efforts at the WTO Ministerial Conference in Bali and,
Peña - 194
most recently, the launch of the negotiating process aimed at concluding a plurilateral agreement on environmental assets.
But even if the outlook of such perspectives became more optimistic, the initiative that has arisen within the scope of the Pacific Alliance is opportune, as it
can lead to a renewal of the methods for the enhancement of the regional space in
terms of the productive development of each country and of their insertion in
global economic competition.
This initiative was proposed on June 20, 2014, in Punta Mita, Mexico, where
the Ninth Summit of the Pacific Alliance (Chile, Colombia, Peru and Mexico)
took place (Peña 2014c). Among other things, it was agreed "to hold an informative ministerial meeting on the Pacific Alliance with countries members of
MERCOSUR." Moreover, "with the same informative spirit," the Presidents
agreed to "conduct a seminar of academics, businessmen, entrepreneurs and senior officials of the Pacific Alliance, MERCOSUR and other countries of the region, including Central America and the Caribbean."
The initiative of Punta Mita opens a window of opportunity for the discussion
of the strategic idea of “convergence in diversity,” presented by the new government of Chile.
We must keep in mind that convergence and confrontation were, until Punta
Mita, the two main alternatives evoked by the relation between MERCOSUR and
the Pacific Alliance. It is clear that choosing one or the other transcends the economic and the commercial and deeply affects the political, as their impact is
closely related with regional governance and the predominance of a climate of
harmony functional to democracy and to the economic and social development of
the member countries.
It is important to have accurate data on the reality of the relations between the
countries of both regional spaces. Hence, the relevance of the publication of the
ECLAC report entitled "The Pacific Alliance and Mercosur. Towards convergence in diversity” (only in Spanish) (CEPAL 2014), which provides the necessary information for an approach based on the reality of the relations between
MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance.
The report was specially prepared to be presented at the Seminar on "Dialogue on Regional Integration: Pacific Alliance and Mercosur," which was held
on November 24, 2014 in Santiago de Chile (Peña 2014d), based on the agreements reached in the Punta Mita Summit. The seminar was held with the presence of the public and the media; and it was opened by the President of Chile. In
her opening remarks she urged for dialogue and to "dream out loud." The initial
presentation was made by the Chancellor of Chile, in where he outlined the main
strategic ideas of convergence in diversity and the objectives of the dialogue that
was to take place at the Seminar. In this regard, it should be noted that the Ministers of Foreign Affairs of the member countries of both schemes had a working
meeting two weeks earlier, in Cartagena de Indias, Colombia, in which the central theme of the seminar was addressed.
Peña - 195
The abovementioned ECLAC report helps verify the density of the network of
agreements and existing relations between the countries from the Alliance and
MERCOSUR. It is a network that has intensified in recent decades, especially in
some of its connections, such as those in the bilateral trade between Chile, Peru
and Colombia, on the one hand, and Brazil and Argentina, on the other. For example, the partial agreements signed between these countries, within the framework of the LAIA, and the relations between MERCOSUR and the Andean
Community of Nations, have already produced a complete tariff reduction between Chile and MERCOSUR countries (100 percent). The percentages are also
high in the cases of Peru (88 percent) and Colombia (90 percent). Another relevant fact is that in 2013 intra-MERCOSUR trade represented 14 percent of the
global trade of its member countries, while intra-Alliance trade represented only
3.5 percent. In the first case, the percentages are much more significant if one
considers the trade of manufactures. In turn, exports of the countries of the Alliance to MERCOSUR are higher than intra-Alliance (in 2013, intra-Alliance exports were US$19,500 million whereas those destined to MERCOSUR totaled
US$23,700 million). Chile, Colombia and Mexico exported more to MERCOSUR than to the Alliance countries. Additionally, data on the trade of services
and investments –even if incomplete– reveals the intensity of the relations between the Pacific Alliance and MERCOSUR countries, especially with Argentina
and Brazil.
As a result of the rich dialogue generated at the Seminar in Santiago de Chile
it became clear that participants value the idea of "convergence in diversity."
They view it as the most appropriate strategy in the current global economic and
political context and as a reflection of how much has been gained in the relations
between its members after more than fifty years of regional integration efforts.
As pointed out from the beginning of the Seminar, first by President Bachelet
and later by Chancellor Muñoz, convergence does not imply unifying the two
integration schemes nor engaging in tariff negotiations (without prejudice to
strengthening the existing ones within the scope of the LAIA). It does imply,
however, recognizing and respecting the differences between the objectives and
the methods of both schemes, and also even between the trade and development
strategies and policies of its member countries.
Various issues were identified as deserving priority action. These were mentioned by several participants of the Dialogue of Santiago and also in the ECLAC
report. Among others, the main ones were: physical connectivity; trade facilitation; production linkages and SME participation in them. Moreover, student exchanges, including reciprocal internships between companies; the development
of tourism; diagnostic capabilities on global economic competition; innovation
and scientific and technological development, and monitoring and participation
in international trade negotiations, both at the global multilateral level and at the
interregional level.
Peña - 196
With regard to the relations with other regions, the need to coordinate positions on events of importance for Latin America (for example with China and the
EU) was pointed out. In some of these cases the Community of Latin American
and Caribbean States (CELAC) has a central role in coordinating the positions of
the countries of the region. The coordination of positions in relation to the G20
meetings and the Conference on Climate Change (COP21), to be held in Paris in
December of 2015, was also mentioned.
In our opinion, the meeting left positive results. The first of these was to place
MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance, each with its own objectives and methodologies, in the broader context. Adding to the dialogue the strong more recent
challenges that are emerging at the global level and of the opportunities that are
opening up for a region that counts, as one of its main assets, the fact that it belongs both to the Pacific and to the Atlantic and that has a significant potential
for developing products and services linked with agribusiness, energy and mining, among others (Lula and Lagos 2014). The second result was to identify
those issues and sectors where it is feasible to have shared approaches between
all or some of the countries of both schemes. And the third result was to show
that the dialogue and the exchange of views with the participation of representatives from governments, production and labor sectors and the academia, is the
most recommended way to expand the agenda for the construction of a region in
which convergence in diversity predominates.
Some Conclusions
Perhaps the main challenge that was posed as a result of the Santiago de Chile
Seminar is to devise and recognize the need to develop short agendas and road
maps for the priority areas of future joint action between the members of the different integration schemes. It is a challenge that involves governments but also
business, labor and academic institutions.
On that occasion it was also confirmed that the existing institutional framework of the region opens a wide range of possibilities in terms of the areas
through which to harness the momentum and pursue the development of those
joint actions identified, as well as of those that are favored in the future.
If inserted in common institutional and regulatory frameworks, such as the
LAIA at the regional Latin American level, or a renewed and strengthened WTO
at the global multilateral level, this would neutralize the systemic fragmentation
trends observed today.
It is an idea that may be central so that the agreements that are being negotiated contribute to the goal of achieving reasonable guidelines for regional and
global governance. It involves reconciling the partial scope approaches with a
joint vision that is essential for promoting world trade in a favorable context for
peace and political stability and, at the same time, for the economic and social
development of all countries.
Peña - 197
Showing that this is possible might be a worthy goal to nourish the agenda of
cooperation between Latin American countries. Its effects would then transcend
the regional scope. It will require, however, a good dose of perseverance, technical imagination and political will.
References
Boletín Informativo Techint. 2014. “Los mega acuerdos de comercio y el futuro
del MERCOSUR.” Boletín Techint, n° 35 November, accessed at: http://
www.boletintechint.com/boin/OpenFile.asp?file=pdf\BOP345.pdf.
CEPAL. 2014. La Alianza del Pacífico y el Mercosur. Hacia una Convergencia
en la Diversidad. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL, accessed at:
http://repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/handle/11362/37304/S1420838_es.
pdf?sequence =1.
Foxley, Alejandro and Meller, Patricio (eds). 2014. Alianza del Pacífico: En el
proceso de integración latinoamericana. Santiago de Chile: CIEPLANBID, accessed at: http://www.cieplan.org/media/publicaciones/archivos
/340/Libro_Completo.pdf.
Friedmann, George. 2015. Flash Points. The Emerging Crisis in Europe. New
York: Doubleday.
Lula da Silva, Luiz Inácio and Lagos, Ricardo. 2014. “América Latina: dos océanos, una voz.” Diario El País, Madrid, accessed at:
http://elpais.com/elpais/2014/06/11/opinion/1402515021_275792.html.
Peña, Félix. 2014a. “The curve of disenchantment: Factors that often lead to frustration in the processes of regional integration.” Newsletter FP January
2014, accessed at:
http://www.felixpena.com.ar/index.php?contenido=negotiations&neagno
=report/2014-01-factors-that-often-lead-to-frustration.
Peña, Félix. 2014b. América Latina entre la convergencia o la fragmentación.
CEPES-FES, accessed at:
http://www.felixpena.com.ar/index.php?contenido=wpapers&wpagno=d
ocumentos/2014-12-america-latina-entre-la-convergencia-ofragmentacion, and in English available from: http://
www.felixpena.com.ar/index.php?contenido=wpapers&wpagno=docume
ntos/2015-latin-america-between-convergence-and-fragmentation. php.
Peña, Félix. 2014c. “Convergence and productive articulation at regional level: A
timely initiative arising from the recent Summit of the Pacific Alliance.”
Peña - 198
Newsletter FP July 2014, accessed at:
http://www.felixpena.com.ar/index.php?contenido=negotiations&neagno
=report/2014-07-convergence-productive-articulation-regional-level.
Peña, Félix. 2014d. “Results of a timely and constructive dialogue: Progress towards a regional strategy for convergence in diversity.” Newsletter FP
December 2014, accessed at: http://www.felixpena.com.ar/index.php?
contenido=negotiations&neagno=report/2014-12-progress-towardsregional-strategy-for-convergence-in-diversity.
Van Middelaar, Luuk. 2013. The Passage to Europe. How a Continent Became a
Union. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.
Regional Integration in Latin America:
A Diagnosis of the Crisis
Carlos Malamud
UNED – Real Instituto Elcano
Abstract
Initiatives built around what is known as ‘political concertation,’ whose theoretical basis is the so-called ‘post-neoliberal integration’ have pushed the integration
process into a permanent headlong rush forward. This analysis aims to present a
general diagnosis of the integration process and describe the short and long-term
options for interregional cooperation. Cooperation in different spheres could be a
useful option to the current issues among the various players involved until a solution is found – the Andean Community (CAN) and MERCOSUR within UNASUR, and MERCOSUR and the Pacific Alliance–. From this perspective, this
paper analyses the emergence of the Alliance in relation to its capacity to be, or
to come to be, a catalyst for the future of integration.
Introduction
In Latin America there is a universal consensus among political, economic and
social players about the positive virtues of regional integration. The process is
seen as a catalyst for economic growth and as an important instrument to reduce
national inequalities and increase social cohesion. The problem with this is the
cost of integration and the necessary effort involved, as there is a common belief
–even promoted by the governments themselves– that the process is not only inevitable but a sure winner also.
If progress towards regional integration is to be made, Latin American
countries should tackle a number of reforms to facilitate the convergence of their
institutions and economies which, at the same time, can help them escape the
middle-income trap. But for that to happen it would be necessary to clarify the
objectives, sort out the goals and dispense with the rhetoric that usually accompanies the process, without jettisoning politics, without which progress is impossible.
From the rhetoric point of view, the idea of integration is usually accompanied by the concept of the Patria Grande, the ancestral voice that assures that a
successful process throughout the region is inevitable. Thus, the idea is that certain teleological and ahistorical instincts have forged a feeling of regional belonging that has existed since the beginning of times UNASUR’s founding treaty (UNASUR 2008) notes that one of its leading aims is to affirm regional identity as a ‘dynamic factor in international relations.’ Regional integration sometimes appears to be more a question of reaffirming an identity than of converging
Malamud - 200
interests.
Once beyond the first threshold of unanimity, the problems appear, concerning answers to basic definitions almost completely lacking. What is to be
integrated? What sort of integration is required? In what political, economic and
energy issues is progress to be made? Should all countries integrate simultaneously?
The lack of clear answers to these questions has led to sharp divergences
in the integration process. Half way through the first decade of the 21st century,
coinciding with the surge in the cost of energy products, energy was presented as
the catalyst of integration. The prevailing belief was that the mere existence of
state-owned hydrocarbon companies would make things easier. But, in the same
way that the process began, it ended by fizzling out. Sometimes the correct questions were just not made, while others the medium and long term inquiries were
ignored, although both are vital in questions such as these.
The weaknesses of the plans for regional integration are clear in the G20, even with a strong Latin American presence. The region has been incapable
of speaking with a single voice. The presence of Argentina, Brazil and Mexico
has not been sufficient to hammer out a common position with the rest of the region in regards to the most pressing issues of the international economic and financial agenda. The same can be said about the negotiations with China and the
EU. All the intergovernmental talks with China are bilateral. With the EU, the
situation is somewhat more complicated, despite the initial European position of
only negotiating with regional or sub regional integration entities, such as the
CAN, MERCOSUR or the Central American Integration System (SICA). At the
end, an Association Agreement was the only reached with Central America,
while the remaining accords were signed with four individual countries: Chile
and Mexico, on the one hand, and Colombia and Peru, on the other. It is no coincidence that these four countries are the founding members of the Pacific Alliance. Overcoming its original misgivings, Ecuador is on the verge of finalising
its negotiation with the EU in similar terms to Colombia and Peru.
Regional Integration in Crisis
If one were to define the present state of Latin American integration it could only
be described as in crisis. Latin America is more than ever a divided region. It is
not a split into opposing blocs but separated by multiple divisions, which are difficult to bring together. A result of this crisis is that the CAN has practically dissolved since Venezuela’s exit in 2006.
It is striking that Latin America has such an overabundance of regional
integration schemes –Community of Latin American and Caribbean States
(CELAC), UNASUR, MERCOSUR, CAN, SICA, Bolivarian Alliance for the
Peoples of our America (ALBA), Pacific Alliance, and many more– all of them
incapable of cooperating efficiently with each other. To the contrary, they merely
Malamud - 201
indulge in a constant headlong rush forward, with new initiatives remaining incapable of resolving the problems faced by their predecessors.
Since the beginning of the 21st century, the integration process, which until then had revolved around trade and the economy, has shifted towards political
cooperation. The stance of certain regional governments regarding free trade and
the Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) prompted the creation of ALBA
and the signing by Cuba, Venezuela and Bolivia of the People's Trade Agreement
(TCP).
Although politics cannot be relegated to the side-lines in this type of processes, the excessive politicisation of Latin American integration, heightened by
the presidentialism character of many regimes in the area and their consequent
bent for presidential diplomacy, has tainted institutions such as MERCOSUR.
The creation of UNASUR and CELAC as purely political bodies is a good example of the phenomenon.
Free trade was at the heart of integration since the creation of the Latin
American Free Trade Association (LAFTA) in 1960 until its demise in 1980. At
the high point of imports-substitution industrialisation policies, both frontiers and
customs barriers were the main obstacle to the expansion of intraregional trade
and integration. The weakness of intraregional trade is proverbial and that is precisely one of integration’s main weaknesses.
In the absence of common interests there is a weaker incentive to generate synergies. Intraregional trade accounts for around 19 percent of Latin American and Caribbean foreign trade, far below Asia-Pacific’s 56 percent and the
EU’s 70 percent (Eclac 2014b). According to Eclac, in 2013/14 the highest proportion of intra sub-regional trade was recorded by the Central American Common Market, at 23.1 percent the only sub-region above the regional average
(Eclac 2014a). At the opposite extreme is the CAN at 8.5 percent, while MERCOSUR is at 14.6 percent. In relation to Latin American intraregional trade and
based on 2011 data, while the Pacific Alliance came in at 11.8 percent, MERCOSUR reached 26.2 percent.
The Obstacles to Integration
The weakness of the current integration process can be approached from a number of angles. Several interpretations are made from a clearly discursive, mainly
political stance, with a self-exculpatory purpose. The idea is to justify the scant
progress achieved by pointing to the process’ novel character while in fact it is as
old as Europe’s. Another explanation is that integration is failing to progress because of the frontal opposition of outside forces, namely the US and, to a lesser
extent, the EU: if Latin America has been unable to integrate it is because foreign
powers are preventing it. However, what the current regional fragmentation
proves is that it is more difficult now than in the past to make most countries
agree regarding certain issues on the international agenda or in votes in suprana-
Malamud - 202
tional bodies such as the UN and the OAS.
By attributing the lack of success to the novelty of the process or to foreign conspiracies, the debate on the current state of integration is delayed indefinitely. Although the issue is widely disputed in academic circles, it should be
subject to a profound intergovernmental debate both regionally and sub regionally. At the same time, the issue should be dealt openly, at a national level, by Latin America’s governments and societies.
A contrary effect to the desired objective has also been caused by ‘presidential diplomacy.’ The excessively central role played by presidents in foreign
policy, along with the hyper-presidentialism prevailing in most of the countries,
debases that of the technical experts, advisors and specialists. The trend was further aggravated at the time of the so-called ‘turn to the left’ because of the belief
that a greater coincidence between politics and ideology would not only facilitate
integration but also speed it up.
Despite the hopes laced on political convergence, things did not turn out
as expected. Halfway through the first decade of the 21st century, when the process was at its peak and it was thought that the personal chemistry between presidents would pave the way for success, a number of bilateral conflicts broke out.
In contrast to the past, they were no longer connected to traditional border disputes, but to economic and political motives, as in the paper-mill spat between
Argentina and Uruguay.
Finally, we should not disregard the prevalent idea that integration can
only bring benefits, with no costs or sacrifices involved for either countries or
societies, particularly those with lower economic growth or social cohesion. This
also leads to the premise that integration must simultaneously involve all the
countries in the region. At the medium and long term these ideas make integration more difficult because they have a negative effect on the convergence process and on the efforts each government should make. Along with overblown
rhetoric, there are two further significant hindrances to integration: overblown
nationalism and an absence of leadership (Malamud 2010).
The emergence of nationalism was simultaneous in all Latin American
republics at the start of the 19th century and was a key factor in the formation of
their national identities. Since then, nationalism has permeated all political ideologies, from the far right to the far left. Even indigenism has absorbed a strongly
nationalistic component. Nationalism has distorted the idea of sovereignty in the
region. Sovereignty is usually understood as territorial sovereignty, the fatherland
and its values, rather than civic sovereignty. As for regional integration, progress
is impossible without relinquishing a minimum of sovereignty to supranational
institutions.
The absence of leadership makes it difficult for integration processes to
progress significantly. Neither of the two major countries, Brazil and Mexico, has
been willing to take on the costs of leading the process, arguing, among other
reasons, that their governments possessed only limited resources. Hugo Chávez
Malamud - 203
attempted to fill the leadership void by investing a large volume of funds and
even political capital in the venture. But, the Bolivarian attempt to monopolize
integration was rejected by a number of countries. Following Chávez’s death the
project has been further questioned, although not openly so far.
The absence of leadership has been aggravated by the historical disagreements between Brazil and Mexico. This is the reason why no answer has
been found to what should be the subject of regional integration: Latin America
or South America? The latter is Brazil’s preferred option, as it excludes Mexico.
The reasoning of Itamaraty, both public and private, is that following the signing
of the North America Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) Mexico turned its back
on Latin America. In contrast, Latin America is Mexico’s favoured option, despite its involvement being marginal and merely rhetorical for quite some time.
The vision of South American integration should not conceal the imbalances between Brazil and the other countries of South America, as is evident in
MERCOSUR, where the small countries complain about how they are treated by
the big ones. Brazil has a common frontier with all of the region’s countries, except Chile and Ecuador. But imbalances are evident when comparing sizes, surfaces areas, income and per capita income. Hence, a regional integration process
focused on Latin America and with Brazil and Mexico as its main promoters
would diminish Brazil’s image as South America’s hegemonic power, behaving
much like the US, which is an image that deeply distresses the Brazilian elites.
The Roles of UNASUR and CELAC: How Useful Are they for Integration?
Over the past decade two regional integration bodies have emerged, in different
but overlapping geographical areas, although in both blocks political dialogue
has been more important than other considerations. Both have been presented as
models for ‘post-neoliberal regionalism,’ with this theoretical perspective even
being used to justify their coexistence. Furthermore, some experts on regional
integration view the coexistence of MERCOSUR, UNASUR and CELAC positively, as concentric circles, which might boosts more than hinder integration.
UNASUR was created in 2008 with all South American countries involved while the CELAC was set up in 2010. Although a large number of countries belong to both organisations, on this occasion neither the links nor the coordination mechanisms between the two were decided upon. Neither did anyone
take any time to explain why the two were necessary simultaneously.
Their coexistence poses future serious problems. For how long can the
fiction that the simultaneous existence of UNASUR and CELAC reinforces integration rather than weakening it be sustained? If South American, Latin American and Caribbean countries wish to move ahead in this way they will have to
decide at some point what to do and which agreement to suppress. If they opt for
Latin American it will be UNASUR that will have to disappear, despite having a
far better and more complex political-administrative structure. But the region’s
Malamud - 204
governments must promote a broader debate on the future of integration and start
to make the necessary decisions.
The primacy of political dialogue over economic or commercial considerations is evident in the inception of UNASUR. According to its founding charter, “the Union of South American Nations has as its aim to build, in a participatory and consensual manner, a space for integration and union in the cultural,
social, economic and political spheres among its peoples, prioritising political
dialogue, social policies, education, energy, infrastructures, financing and the
environment, among others, with the object of eliminating socioeconomic inequality, achieve social inclusion and citizen participation, strengthen democracy
and reduce asymmetries in the framework of strengthening the sovereignty and
independence of States” (UNASUR 2008). UNASUR began by focusing on political dialogue and the creation of sectorial councils. There are currently 12
South American councils, which deal with a large number of issues, although
none of them tackles trade.
UNASUR initially implemented some important initiatives to resolve internal problems in certain countries, such as the regional crisis in Bolivia or the
military uprising against Rafael Correa in Ecuador. The initiatives were carried
out from the perspective that the countries in UNASUR would be able to solve
their own problems without resorting to outside help. However, UNASUR was
either unwilling or unable to intervene in bilateral conflicts. In all cases the solution was reached in extraordinary presidential summits, in emergency sessions
rather than through standard institutional mechanisms. Over the past two years
UNASUR’s mediating role has declined, as was made evident in the attempt for
dialogue between the government of Nicolás Maduro and the Venezuelan opposition.
CELAC was also the convergence of two distinct initiatives. On the one
hand, Mexico was interested in regaining its prominence in Latin America, while,
on the other, Venezuela and the ALBA countries, with Cuba to the fore, aimed to
recreate the Organisation of American States (OAS) but excluding the US and
Canada. Its main achievement was to get Cuba back into a Latin American institution, although it did not return to any continental body since Havana did not
request its re-admittance to the OAS.
The Current Situation and the Emergence of the Pacific Alliance
Beyond anything that can be said about the originality and specificity of Latin
American integration, in the medium to long terms the coexistence of two institutions such as UNASUR and CELAC, more than promoting integration, has given
rise to an almost insurmountable obstacle to the intended objective. The rhetoric
of the patria grande has led to the belief that this institutional coexistence is actually an instance of Latin American richness and creativity. However, what it
actually denotes is the lack of definition about what it is that should be integrat-
Malamud - 205
ed.
The formal constitution of the Pacific Alliance changed some things and
introduced some interesting novelties (Malamud 2012). The Alliance’s impact
has been greater following Hugo Chávez’s exit from the Latin American scene,
as his strong regional leadership has had no successor. Simultaneously, Venezuela’s serious economic difficulties have prevented its government from continuing
to finance a particular integration project led by the ALBA.
The Alliance’s creation has reintroduced, first, the centrality of trade and
the economy to integration. Following the creation of ALBA and the demise of
ALCA, free trade was condemned, political convergence took centre stage and
the concept of post-neoliberal or post-capitalist regionalism began to gain
ground, ushered in by open regionalism.
Secondly, and based on pure pragmatism, the Alliance resolved the question of what to integrate: Latin America or South America? Among the four
founder members there are three South American countries and one North American nation. Among those with the status of observers, who may be the next
members, there are two Central American nations: Costa Rica and Panama. The
Alliance’s existence is a challenge to Brazil and its South American project.
Third, it has reinvigorated the role of companies and private entrepreneurs in the integration process, after having been relegated by the excessive statism of a large number of the region’s governments. The Pacific Alliance’s Business Council is formally linked to the organisation. As for the role to be played
by entrepreneurs in the regional integration process, the good news was the resolution of the border dispute between Chile and Peru by the International Court of
Justice at The Hague and the response of the two parties involved.
Another important initiative to foster the free circulation of capitals and
services is the Integrated Latin American Market (MILA), made up of the stock
exchanges of Bogotá, Lima and Santiago and which have just been joined by
Mexico. With the latter, their market capitalisation adds up to US$1.2 billion,
compared with Brazil’s US$1.5 billion (IADB 2014). A significant hindrance is
the lack of sufficiently harmonised regulations and sufficiently coordinated supervisors. A greater regional integration of financial institutions would increase
competition and the quality of regional financial services.
The Difficult Relations between the Pacific Alliance, MERCOSUR and ALBA
The Alliance’s main objectives are: (1) to build, on a participatory and consensual basis, a well-integrated space to steadily progress towards the free circulation
of goods, services, capital and people; (2) foster growth, development and competitiveness to ensure greater well-being, overcome socioeconomic inequality
and enhance social inclusion; and (3) to become a platform for political coordination, and economic and commercial integration, and for the region’s projection in
the rest of the world, with a particular focus on Asia-Pacific. The Alliance has a
Malamud - 206
large potential because its members share the same economic model, have compatible monetary and exchange rate policies and strong financial institutions.
In contrast to other regional or sub regional integration projects, the Alliance’s four member countries have signed free-trade agreements (FTA) with
each other, along with the many FTAs they have signed with much of the rest of
the world, starting with the US and the EU. The degree of openness the Alliance
economies have attained contrasts with those of MERCOSUR and ALBA.
For a variety of reasons the Alliance has caused a feeling of rejection
among the ALBA countries and a degree of indifference, or even disdain, of certain MERCOSUR countries such as Argentina and Brazil. The Alliance emergence has led the ALBA to seek a common position to face up to it. Thus, it is
promoting an economic zone for “shared and complementary development, in
solidarity, respecting asymmetries, beyond mere trade,” to which it hopes to attract CARICOM and MERCOSUR.
The proliferation of statements along with the markets’ preferences for
the potential of the Alliance’s members led to talk of a conflict between the Pacific and the Atlantic, or between the Alliance and MERCOSUR. In fact, the
slowdown in the Brazilian economy was contrasted with the success of the new
regional powers (with Colombia having recently overtaken Argentina to third
place in the regional ranking), increasing the bitterness of the criticism by both
Argentina and Brazil.
Conclusions
The first conclusion should be that regional integration is in crisis and that the
entire region’s governments –or at least the major ones– should promote a profound debate about the integration characteristics and process. To do this, the
current state of fragmentation must be recognised and presented not as a catastrophe but as an opportunity to embark on a systematic search for viable solutions. One of the most important questions to be answered is about the object of
integration, what is to be integrated, because this issue cannot be left to the vagaries of fate or to the good intentions of those involved in such a delicate situation.
From this perspective, it is obvious that integration should not be presented simply as a process for the construction of an identity. Integration should
basically revolve around the convergence of different national interests to a point
where solid institutions can be built. It is not only a case of fomenting the convergence of policies or ideologies but also of the need to allow the coexistence of
different natures that are able to cohabit in the same integration bodies without
having to engage in open conflict with their opponents.
Contrary to what has been affirmed of late, that the significant progress
achieved over the past decade by UNASUR and the CELAC has been due to the
region’s progressive governments, in reality the fact is that this has been one of
Malamud - 207
the process’s main weaknesses. This is not because these governments are of a
specific political bent but because of the implied uniformity. Regional integration
is not speeded up by governments coinciding in their ideologies but by the possibility of starting to share permanent interests. These national interests are above
any circumstantial change brought about by the existence of different governments, especially bearing in mind that one of the chief characteristics of democracy is the peaceful alternation of power. It is necessary to definitively discard
integration proposals that serve to justify certain specific ideological models. In
this respect, the so-called ‘post-neoliberal regionalism’ has acted as a justification for the swing towards political convergence and the relegation of trade and
the economy as the backbone interconnecting the region. In fact, what integration
requires are long-term proposals to help focus on issues from a strategic perspective, simultaneously incorporating politics with trade and the economy.
The emergence of the Pacific Alliance has shaken up the regional integration scene. It has served not only to again bring up the question of what is the
object of integration –South America or Latin America– and to resolve it through
direct action, but also to again bring to the fore the role of trade and the economy
along with that of private initiative.
References
Eclac, 2014a. Latin America and the Caribbean in the world economy 2013: A
sluggish post crisis, mega trade negotiations and value chains; scope for regional action. Santiago: United Nations.
Eclac, 2014b. Cepalstat. Santiago: United Nations. Accessed at:
http://estadisticas.cepal.org/cepalstat/WEB_CEPALSTAT/Portada.asp?idio
ma=i
IADB, 2014. MILA: fortaleciendo la integración financiera, accessed at: http://
www.iadb.org/es/temas/comercio/mila-fortaleciendo-la-integracionfinanciera,6839.html.
Malamud, Carlos, 2010, Populismos latinoamericanos. Los tópicos de ayer, de
hoy y de siempre, Ed. Nobel, Oviedo.
Malamud, Carlos, 2012. La Alianza del Pacífico: un revulsivo para la integración
regional en América Latina, Real Instituto Elcano, ARI 46/2012, accessed
at: http://www.realinstitutoelcano.org/wps/portal/rielcano/contenido?WCM_
GLOBAL_CONTEXT=/elcano/elcano_es/zonas_es/america+latina/ari462012.
UNASUR, 2008. Tratado constitutive de la union de naciones suramericanas.
Brasil.
About the Authors
Beverly Barrett is an international policy specialist. Her research interests include international political economy, regional integration, and governance with
particular emphasis on higher education policy and economic development. She
completed her doctorate in International Studies at the University of Miami,
where she participated in a fellowship with the European Union Center of Excellence. She completed her M.A. at Johns Hopkins University School of Advanced
International Studies (SAIS) in Bologna, Italy and Washington, D.C. Professional experiences in public affairs include assignments with the U.S. House of Representatives, the White House Office of Cabinet Affairs, and the U.S. Department
of State in Helsinki, Finland as well as with the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
She graduated from Vanderbilt University, B.S. cum laude in Human and Organizational Development. Currently Dr. Barrett is a clinical assistant professor in
Global Studies in the business school at the University of Houston.
Sarah L. Beringer is a Lecturer and Research Fellow at the Department of International Studies at Friedrich-Alexander-University Erlangen-Nuremberg,
Germany. In 2012/2013 she was a Visiting Scholar at Florida International University, Miami, USA. Her research focuses on issues in International Political
Economy, particularly international trade. She studied Business Administration
and Social Sciences in Nuremberg, Germany and Gainesville, FL, USA and
earned a master’s degree in Business Administration and a doctorate in Economics and Social Sciences from Friedrich-Alexander-University ErlangenNuremberg.
Javier Bonilla Saus is a/the Chair of Political Science at the School of Management and Social Sciences of Universidad ORT- Uruguay. Since 2005 he has been
Academic Coordinator of International Studies. He graduated in Economics and
Sociology at the French Universities of Paris VIIII and Paris X. He undertook
studies of Economic History at the Ecole Pratique des Hautes Etudes with Prof.
Pierre Vilar. He obtained his master’s degree in Economics and his D.E.A
(Diplôme d`Etudes Approfondies) from the University of Paris X. He has taught
since 1972 “Political Theory”, “Development problems in Latin America”, “International Politics” and “Methodology of Social Sciences” at Universidad
Autónoma de México, Universidad Metropolitana, Tecnológico de Monterrey,
and FLACSO.
Pedro Caldentey del Pozo is a full-time professor of Economics at Loyola University Andalusia and researcher and the director of the ETEA Foundation for
Development and Cooperation in Spain. He earned his Ph.D. in Economics and
Business from the University of Cordoba, Spain. He was Chief Advisor to the
Spain-SICA Fund from 2007 to 2011 at the General Secretariat of the Central
American Integration System (SICA), El Salvador. He has lent his expertise as a
About the Authors - 210
consultant for the European Union, SICA, the Economic Commission for Latin
America and the Caribbean (ECLAC), for the Spanish Agency for International
Development Cooperation (AECID), and for the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).
Ángel M. Casas-Gragea is a full-time professor of Economics at the Metropolitan Autonomous University in Mexico City. He has been distinguished for his
research and academic work as a member of the National System of Researchers
by the National Council of Science and Technology of Mexico. Dr. CasasGragea earned his Ph.D. in Economics at the University of Cordoba, Spain. He
also holds a master’s in International Relations from the Andean University Simon Bolivar, Ecuador. He has taught a diversity of graduate and undergraduate
student bodies as a visiting professor in Latin American and European universities. He also has extensive experience (omit ‘in’) managing cooperation projects
as a technical specialist at the Spanish Agency for International Development
Cooperation.
Alejandro Chanona received his Ph.D. in government and his master’s in Western European political studies from the University of Essex, England. He is a
Professor of the School of Political and Social Sciences of the National Autonomous University of Mexico (UNAM), where he also founded the Centre of European Studies. He is a member of (omit ‘the’) Mexico’s National System of Researchers; his research fields include regional integration, comparative regionalism and international security. Professor Chanona has also participated in EU
Garnet Research Projects and is a member of the Civil Society Reflection Group
on Global Development Perspectives. His latest book is Tendencias de la Política
Medioambiental en la Unión Europea y América del Norte: ¿Integración o
Cooperación?, 2014.
Lurong Chen is a Research Fellow at the United Nations University Institute on
Comparative Regional Integration Studies (UNU-CRIS) in Bruges (Belgium). He
holds a Ph.D. in International Relations, with specialization in international economics from the Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva (IUHEI, Genève). His current research interests are centered on Asian regionalism, production sharing and economic integration, and trade in services. He recently published in the Journal of Policy Modeling, International Area Studies Review, Integration & Trade, and South African Journal of Economics.
Philippe De Lombaerde is the Associate Director of UNU-CRIS. He is also a
Visiting Lecturer at the University of Maastricht. Previously he worked as Associate Professor of International Economics at the Universidad Nacional de Colombia (Bogotá), Researcher and Lecturer at the University of Antwerp and Researcher at the National Institute of Development Administration (Bangkok). Dr.
About the Authors - 211
De Lombaerde studied economics and political science at the universities of
Ghent, Brussels, Antwerp and Aachen. He recently edited the four-volume Regionalism (Sage, London, 2013) (with F. Söderbaum), and published in: Journal
of Policy Modeling, Journal of Common Market Studies, International Migration
Review, Integration & Trade, and Globalizations.
Rita Giacalone is a Professor of Economic History, Department of Economics,
Universidad de Los Andes (Venezuela), and Coordinator of GRUDIR (Regional
Integration Research Group). She was the Director of the School of Political Science, Coordinator of REDINRE (ALFA Program network of European and Latin
American universities), and Editor of Revista Venezolana de Ciencia Política.
She has been a Visiting Professor at the University of Pennsylvania, Instituto
Tecnológico de Estudios Superiores de Monterrey, Universidad Autónoma de
México, Universidad de La Plata (Argentina), and Stockholm University. She
holds a Ph.D. (History, Indiana University) and has been the beneficiary of a
Fulbright-Hayes Scholarship. Her latest publications (are these books?) include
“Anti-Americanism and Trade Policy in Brazil and France” (co-author: Gerry
Alons) Revista Iberoamericana (Stockholm) 43 (1-2) (2013), and “La integración
sudamericana entre el modelo europeo y la política exterior brasileña” in E.
Tremolada (Ed.) Repensando la integración y las integraciones (Bogotá: Universidad Externado de Colombia, 2013).
Pedro Isern is a Professor of Latin American Contemporary History at the Department of International Studies of Universidad ORT-Uruguay. He is one of the
Editors of Letras Internacionales, the online bi-monthly publication of the Department and Co-coordinator of the Seminar of the Departament of International
Affairs. Professor Isern has a master’s degree in Political Theory from the London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE), a master’s in Economics
and Political Science (Eseade, Argentina) and B.A. in Political Science (Universidad de San Andrés, Buenos Aires, Argentina. Professor Isern has been a Visiting Professor at Universidad Los Andes (Santiago, Chile), and an Associate Researcher at CIPPEC (Center for the Implementation of Public Policies Promoting
Equity and Growth, Buenos Aires-Argentina). He is in the process of publishing,
with Javier Bonilla Saus, a book on Populism. He has compiled (book?) “La experiencia chilena: consensos para el desarrollo” and co-authored, with Mauricio
Rojas, Mitos del Milenio.
Maxime H. A. Larivé, Ph.D., is a Research Associate at the EU Center of Excellence at the University of Miami. He received his Ph.D. in International Studies
at the University of Miami with a dissertation entitled “From Promoting Security
to Enforcing it: The European Security Strategy during the Solana Period.” Prior
he graduated from the University of Nice (France) with a B.A. in History and
Geography, and a MA in Political Sciences from Suffolk University (Boston,
About the Authors - 212
MA). Ensuing his Ph.D. he completed a Post-Doctoral Fellowship as a Jean
Monnet Fellow (2012-13). He has published in several peer-reviewed journals
like European Security and his book, Debating European Security and Defense
Policy, was published in October 2014 with Ashgate. Dr. Larivé also writes
weekly commentaries on the EU and transatlantic relations for Politipond.
Liliana Lizarazo Rodríguez is currently an independent legal consultant and an
advisor to a Belgian Law Firm. Previously she worked as a Ph.D. Researcher at
the University of Ghent, Lecturer at the Universidad del Rosario, and as a lawyer
in Colombia. She holds a Ph.D. in Law from the University of Ghent. She has
published on the legal aspects of economic regulation and reform, IMF conditionality, health policies, trade and investment policies, and on constitutional adjudication and ESC rights. She recently published (Sub: Her work was recently
published) in the European Law Journal, the Manchester Journal of International Economic Law, and Colombia Internacional.
María Lorca-Susino holds a Ph.D. in International Studies from the University
of Miami, where she previously earned a M.A. degree in Economics and a MBA
in Finance. Dr. Lorca is currently a lecturer in the Departments of Economic and
International Studies at the University of Miami. She is also an Associate Editor
at the European Union Center of Excellence at the University of Miami wherein
she has been publishing her research in a series of papers since January 2006.
She is the author of the book The euro in the 21st century: Economic crisis and
financial uproar (Ashgate Pub.). Her research deals with the issues of the euro,
economic integration, and economics. Her publications are available at
www.marialorcasusino.com.
Willem Maas (PhD Yale), Jean Monnet Chair at York University (Canada) and
currently Marie Skłodowska-Curie Fellow at the European University Institute
(Italy), is the author of Creating European Citizens, which argues that European
integration involves not only economic cooperation but also a political project of
transcending borders and building a European community of people; editor of
Democratic Citizenship and the Free Movement of People, which challenges the
normal way of thinking about free movement by identifying barriers and disincentives to free movement, against citizenship's promise of equality; and editor of
Multilevel Citizenship, which disputes the dominant narrative of citizenship as a
homogeneous status bestowed only by nation-states, considering overlapping
jurisdictions, sub- or supranational citizenships, and shared governance. Professor Maas co-founded the American Political Science Association’s Migration and
Citizenship Section and is writing on multilevel governance and the future of
European citizenship in comparative perspective.
About the Authors - 213
Joseph A. McKinney is the Ben H. Williams Professor of International Economics at Baylor University in Texas. He received his B.A. degree from Berea College, and his M.A. and Ph.D. degrees from Michigan State University. Prior to
joining Baylor University he served on the faculty of the University of Virginia.
He has been Exchange Professor to Seinan Gakuin University in Fukuoka, Japan,
and Fulbright Senior Scholar in the United Kingdom and in Canada. He has provided expert testimony on trade policy issues before such agencies as the United
States International Trade Commission and the United States Trade Deficit Review Commission, and before the Trade Subcommittee of the U.S. House Ways
and Means Committee. He is a frequent participant in international conferences,
and has published articles and books on a variety of international trade policy
issues. He serves on the editorial board of the Journal of Transatlantic Studies.
Carlos Malamud is Professor of American History at Spain’s Universidad
Nacional de Educación a Distancia (UNED) in Madrid, and Senior Analyst for
Latin America at the Elcano Royal Institute. He has been Visiting Fellow at Saint
Antony’s College, Oxford University, at the Universidad de los Andes in Colombia (Corona Chair) and at the Universidad Di Tella in Buenos Aires. Between
1986 and 2002 he directed the Latin American Programme at the Instituto Universitario Ortega y Gasset, of which he was also deputy chairman. He has been a
lecturer at Madrid’s Universidad Complutense de Madrid and CEU San Pablo
and is a member of the advisory board of the Cultural Institute of the MAPFRE
Foundation. He currently combines his work as a historian with that of analyst on
Latin American politics and international relations.
Tamás Novák is Associate Professor at Budapest Business School and senior
research fellow in the Centre for Economic and Regional Studies of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences. He was an Austrian Marshall Plan Foundation Fellow
at the Center for Transatlantic Relations, Paul H. Nitze School of Advanced International Studies (SAIS), Johns Hopkins University and Deputy Director of the
Institute of World Economics in Budapest. His main field of research and teaching over the past twenty years has been centered on the different aspects of social
and economic transition and policies of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) with
particular focus on Hungary, the V4 countries, and the Western Balkans. He has
published widely on global economic issues with special emphasis on transition
economies and economic convergence. Tamas received his Ph.D. in International
Relations and M.A. in Economics from the Budapest University of Economics.
Vicente Palacio holds a Ph.D. from the University Complutense of Madrid and
currently serves as Deputy Director of the Observatory of Spanish Foreign Policy, Fundación Alternativas. He has directed and coordinated research for the
Cabinet of the Spanish President and the Ministry of Foreign Affairs and Cooperation. Palacio has been Associate Professor of International Relations at Syra-
About the Authors - 214
cuse University in Madrid and a Visiting Fellow and Researcher at Harvard University’s Department of Government. He is the author of dozens of analyses and
articles on the subjects of Spanish and EU foreign policy, Transatlantic Relations
and EU–Latin American relations. Recent publications include the report (Italics
or quotations for reports? stylistic preference) “The State of the European Union
2014: How citizens deal with these times of crisis”, and “The New European Parliament, towards economic recovery” (Fundación Alternativas - Friedrich Ebert
Stiftung, 2014). He is a frequent contributor to El PAIS and CNN’s Spanish language news channel.
Félix Peña is Director of the Master in International Trade Relations at Universidad Nacional de Tres de Febrero (UNTREF); Director of the Institute of International Trade-ICBCFoundation; and Member of the Board of CARI. He has a
Law degree from the Universidad del Litoral in Santa Fe; a doctorate degree in
Law from the Universidad de Madrid and a European Law degree from the Catholic University of Louvain, Belgium. He served as Undersecretary of Foreign
Trade in the Argentina’s Ministry of Economics. Previously, he was Undersecretary of Economic Integration in the Ministry of Foreign Affairs, in charge of
Mercosur affairs. Previously he was Deputy Manager for Integration at IADB;
Undersecretary of Economic International Relations in the Ministry of Foreign
Affairs; and Director of INTAL- IADB. For his publications consult
www.felixpena.com.ar
Joaquín Roy. Lic. Law, University of Barcelona, 1966; Ph.D, Georgetown University, 1973. He is a Jean Monnet Professor and Director of University of Miami European Union Center of Excellence. He has published over 200 academic
articles and reviews, and he is the author or editor of 40 books, among them Cuba, the U.S. and the Helms-Burton Doctrine: International Reactions (University
of Florida Press, 2000), The European Union and Regional Integration (Miami:
EU Center, 2005), Towards the Completion of Europe (Miami: EU Center, 2006)
and A Historical Dictionary of the European Union (Scarecrow Press / Rowman
& Littlefield, 2006), The dollar and the euro (Ashgate, 2007), The Cuban Revolution (1959-2009): its relationship with Spain, the European Union and the
United States (New York: Palgrave/McMillan, 2009), Lisbon Fado: The EU under reform (Miami: EU Center, 2009), and The State of the Union(s) (Miami: EU
Center, 2012). He has also published over 1,600 columns and essays. He was
awarded the Encomienda of the Order of Merit by King Juan Carlos of Spain.
Ana Paula Tostes is currently an Associate Professor in the Department of International Relations at the Rio de Janeiro State University (UERJ) and chair of
the Graduate Program of International Relations (PPGRI-UERJ) since 2012. She
has previously worked as Adjunct Professor in the Department of political science at University of São Paulo (USP) and was Assistant Professor in the De-
About the Authors - 215
partment of political science and James Madison College at Michigan State University (MSU). She received her Ph.D. degree from IUPERJ in Political Science.
Her main research interest is European studies. She has published many articles
in refereed journals and three books: European Union: the political power of the
law (Renovar Press, 2004), co-edited the book Justice and Democratic Transnational Processes (Humanitas Press, 2005), and the book American Studies in
perspective: international relations, foreign policy and ideologies (Appris Press,
2013).